fbpx
Wikipedia

Friedrich Hayek

Friedrich August von Hayek CH FBA (/ˈhək/ HY-ək, German: [ˈfʁiːdʁɪç ˈʔaʊɡʊst fɔn ˈhaɪɛk] ; 8 May 1899 – 23 March 1992), often referred to by his initials F. A. Hayek, was an Austrian-British polymath, whose areas of interest included economics, political philosophy, psychology, and intellectual history.[2][3][4][5] Hayek shared the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences with Gunnar Myrdal for work on money and economic fluctuations, and the interdependence of economic, social and institutional phenomena.[6] His account of how prices communicate information is widely regarded as an important contribution to economics that led to him receiving the prize.[7][8][9]

Friedrich Hayek
Born
Friedrich August von Hayek

(1899-05-08)8 May 1899
Died23 March 1992(1992-03-23) (aged 92)
Freiburg im Breisgau, Baden-Württemberg, Germany
CitizenshipAustrian (1899–1938)
British (1938–1992)
Education
Spouses
Helen Berta Maria von Fritsch
(m. 1926, divorced)
Helene Bitterlich
(m. 1950)
ChildrenChristine Maria Felicitas von Hayek (daughter)
Laurence Hayek (son)[1]
Parent(s)August von Hayek (father)
Felicitas von Juraschek (mother)
Relatives
Academic career
Institution
Field
School or
tradition
Austrian School
Influences
Contributions
Awards
Information at IDEAS / RePEc
Signature

During his teenage years, Hayek fought in World War I. He later said this experience, coupled with his desire to help avoid the mistakes that led to the war, drew him into economics.[10][11] He earned doctoral degrees in law in 1921 and political science in 1923 from the University of Vienna.[10][12] He subsequently lived and worked in Austria, Great Britain, the United States, and Germany. He became a British citizen in 1938.[13] His academic life was mostly spent at the London School of Economics, later at the University of Chicago, and the University of Freiburg. He is widely considered a major contributor to the Austrian School of Economics.[14][15]

Hayek had considerable influence on a variety of political movements of the 20th century, and his ideas continue to influence thinkers from a variety of political backgrounds today.[16][17][18] Although sometimes described as a conservative,[19] Hayek himself was uncomfortable with this label and preferred to be thought of as a classical liberal.[20][21] As the co-founder of the Mont Pelerin Society he contributed to the revival of classical liberalism in the post-war era.[22] His most popular work, The Road to Serfdom, has been republished many times over the eight decades since its original publication.[23][24]

Hayek was appointed a Member of the Order of the Companions of Honour in 1984 for his academic contributions to economics.[25][26] He was the first recipient of the Hanns Martin Schleyer Prize in 1984.[27] He also received the Presidential Medal of Freedom in 1991 from President George H. W. Bush.[28] In 2011, his article "The Use of Knowledge in Society" was selected as one of the top 20 articles published in the American Economic Review during its first 100 years.[29]

Life edit

Early life edit

Friedrich August von Hayek was born in Vienna to August von Hayek and Felicitas Hayek (née von Juraschek). Both of his parents had Czech family surnames and Czech ancestry.[30][31] The surname Hayek is the Germanized spelling of the Czech surname Hájek.[26] Hayek traced his paternal Czech ancestry to an ancestor with the surname "Hagek" who came from Prague in the 1500s.[32]

His father, born in 1871, also in Vienna, was a medical doctor employed by the municipal ministry of health.[33] August was a part-time botany lecturer at the University of Vienna.[6] Friedrich was the oldest of three brothers, Heinrich (1900–1969) and Erich (1904–1986), who were one-and-a-half and five years younger than he was.[34]

His father's career as a university professor influenced Hayek's goals later in life.[35] Both of his grandfathers, who lived long enough for Hayek to know them, were scholars.[36] Franz von Juraschek was a leading economist in Austria-Hungary and a close friend of Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, one of the founders of the Austrian School of Economics.[37] Hayek's paternal grandfather, Gustav Edler von Hayek, taught natural sciences at the Imperial Realobergymnasium (secondary school) in Vienna. He wrote works in the field of biological systematics, some of which are relatively well known.[38]

On his mother's side, Hayek was second cousin to the philosopher Ludwig Wittgenstein.[39] His mother often played with Wittgenstein's sisters and had known him well. As a result of their family relationship, Hayek became one of the first to read Wittgenstein's Tractatus Logico-Philosophicus when the book was published in its original German edition in 1921.[40] Although he met Wittgenstein on only a few occasions, Hayek said that Wittgenstein's philosophy and methods of analysis had a profound influence on his own life and thought.[41] In his later years, Hayek recalled a discussion of philosophy with Wittgenstein when both were officers during World War I.[42] After Wittgenstein's death, Hayek had intended to write a biography of Wittgenstein and worked on collecting family materials and later assisted biographers of Wittgenstein.[43] He was related to Wittgenstein on the non-Jewish side of the Wittgenstein family. Since his youth, Hayek frequently socialized with Jewish intellectuals, and he mentions that people often speculated whether he was also of Jewish ancestry. That made him curious, so he spent some time researching his ancestors and found out that he had no Jewish ancestors within five generations.[44]

Hayek displayed an intellectual and academic bent from a very young age and read fluently and frequently before going to school.[13][45] However, he did quite poorly at school, due to the lack of interest and problems with teachers.[46] He was at the bottom of his class in most subjects and once received three failing grades, in Latin, Greek, and mathematics.[46] He was very interested in theater, even attempting to write some tragedies, and biology, regularly helping his father with his botanical work.[47] At his father's suggestion, as a teenager he read the genetic and evolutionary works of Hugo de Vries and August Weismann and the philosophical works of Ludwig Feuerbach.[48] He noted Goethe as the greatest early intellectual influence.[47] In school, Hayek was much taken by one instructor's lectures on Aristotle's ethics.[49] In his unpublished autobiographical notes, Hayek recalled a division between him and his younger brothers who were only a few years younger than him, but he believed that they were somehow of a different generation. He preferred to associate with adults.[45]

In 1917, Hayek joined an artillery regiment in the Austro-Hungarian Army and fought on the Italian front.[50] Hayek suffered damage to his hearing in his left ear during the war[51] and was decorated for bravery. He also survived the 1918 flu pandemic.[52]

Hayek then decided to pursue an academic career, determined to help avoid the mistakes that had led to the war. Hayek said of his experience: "The decisive influence was really World War I. It's bound to draw your attention to the problems of political organization". He vowed to work for a better world.[53]

Education edit

At the University of Vienna, Hayek initially studied mostly philosophy, psychology and economics.[15] The university allowed students to choose their subjects freely and there was not much obligatory written work, or tests except main exams at the end of the study.[54] By the end of his studies Hayek became more interested in economics, mostly for financial and career reasons; he planned to combine law and economics to start a career in diplomatic service.[55] He earned doctorates in law and political science in 1921 and 1923 respectively.[15]

For a short time, when the University of Vienna closed he studied in Constantin von Monakow's Institute of Brain Anatomy, where Hayek spent much of his time staining brain cells.[56] Hayek's time in Monakow's lab and his deep interest in the work of Ernst Mach inspired his first intellectual project, eventually published as The Sensory Order (1952).[57][56] It located connective learning at the physical and neurological levels, rejecting the "sense data" associationism of the empiricists and logical positivists.[57] Hayek presented his work to the private seminar he had created with Herbert Furth called the Geistkreis.[58]

During Hayek's years at the University of Vienna, Carl Menger's work on the explanatory strategy of social science and Friedrich von Wieser's commanding presence in the classroom left a lasting influence on him.[48] Upon the completion of his examinations, Hayek was hired by Ludwig von Mises on the recommendation of Wieser as a specialist for the Austrian government working on the legal and economic details of the Treaty of Saint-Germain-en-Laye.[59] Between 1923 and 1924, Hayek worked as a research assistant to Professor Jeremiah Jenks of New York University, compiling macroeconomic data on the American economy and the operations of the Federal Reserve.[60] He was influenced by Wesley Clair Mitchell and started a doctoral program on problems of monetary stabilization but didn't finish it.[61] His time in America wasn't especially happy. He had very limited social contacts, missed the cultural life of Vienna, and was troubled by his poverty.[62] His family's financial situation deteriorated significantly after the War.[63]

Initially sympathetic to Wieser's democratic socialism, Hayek found Marxism rigid and unattractive, and his mild socialist phase lasted until he was about 23.[64] Hayek's economic thinking shifted away from socialism and toward the classical liberalism of Carl Menger after reading von Mises' book Socialism.[59] It was sometime after reading Socialism that Hayek began attending von Mises' private seminars, joining several of his university friends, including Fritz Machlup, Alfred Schutz, Felix Kaufmann and Gottfried Haberler, who were also participating in Hayek's own more general and private seminar. It was during this time that he also encountered and befriended noted political philosopher Eric Voegelin, with whom he retained a long-standing relationship.[65]

London School of Economics edit

With the help of Mises, in the late 1920s, he founded and served as director of the Austrian Institute for Business Cycle Research before joining the faculty of the London School of Economics (LSE) in 1931 at the behest of Lionel Robbins.[66] Upon his arrival in London, Hayek was quickly recognised as one of the leading economic theorists in the world and his development of the economics of processes in time and the co-ordination function of prices inspired the ground-breaking work of John Hicks, Abba P. Lerner and many others in the development of modern microeconomics.[67]

In 1932, Hayek suggested that private investment in the public markets was a better road to wealth and economic co-ordination in Britain than government spending programs as argued in an exchange of letters with John Maynard Keynes, co-signed with Lionel Robbins and others in The Times.[68][69] The nearly decade long deflationary depression in Britain dating from Winston Churchill's decision in 1925 to return Britain to the gold standard at the old pre-war and pre-inflationary par was the public policy backdrop for Hayek's dissenting engagement with Keynes over British monetary and fiscal policy.[70] Keynes called Hayek's book Prices and Production "one of the most frightful muddles I have ever read", famously adding: "It is an extraordinary example of how, starting with a mistake, a remorseless logician can end in Bedlam".[71]

Notable economists who studied with Hayek at the LSE in the 1930s and 1940s include Arthur Lewis, Ronald Coase, William Baumol, John Maynard Keynes, CH Douglas, John Kenneth Galbraith, Leonid Hurwicz, Abba Lerner, Nicholas Kaldor, George Shackle, Thomas Balogh, L. K. Jha, Arthur Seldon, Paul Rosenstein-Rodan and Oskar Lange.[72][73][33] Some were supportive and some were critical of his ideas. Hayek also taught or tutored many other LSE students, including David Rockefeller.[74]

Unwilling to return to Austria after the Anschluss brought it under the control of Nazi Germany in 1938, Hayek remained in Britain. Hayek and his children became British subjects in 1938.[75] He held this status for the remainder of his life, but he did not live in Great Britain after 1950. He lived in the United States from 1950 to 1962 and then mostly in Germany, but also briefly in Austria.[76]

In 1947, Hayek was elected a Fellow of the Econometric Society.[77]

The Road to Serfdom edit

Hayek was concerned about the general view in Britain's academia that fascism was a capitalist reaction to socialism and The Road to Serfdom arose from those concerns.[78] The title was inspired by the French classical liberal thinker Alexis de Tocqueville's writings on the "road to servitude".[79] It was first published in Britain by Routledge in March 1944 and was quite popular, leading Hayek to call it "that unobtainable book" also due in part to wartime paper rationing.[80] When it was published in the United States by the University of Chicago in September of that year, it achieved greater popularity than in Britain.[81] At the instigation of editor Max Eastman, the American magazine Reader's Digest also published an abridged version in April 1945, enabling The Road to Serfdom to reach a far wider audience than academics. The book is widely popular among those advocating individualism and classical liberalism.[82]

Chicago edit

In 1950, Hayek left the London School of Economics. After spending the 1949–1950 academic year as a visiting professor at the University of Arkansas, Hayek was conferred professorship by the University of Chicago, where he became a professor in the Committee on Social Thought.[83] Hayek's salary was funded not by the university, but by an outside foundation, the William Volker Fund.[84]

Hayek had made contact with many at the University of Chicago in the 1940s, with Hayek's The Road to Serfdom playing a seminal role in transforming how Milton Friedman and others understood how society works.[85] Hayek conducted a number of influential faculty seminars while at the University of Chicago and a number of academics worked on research projects sympathetic to some of Hayek's own, such as Aaron Director, who was active in the Chicago School in helping to fund and establish what became the "Law and Society" program in the University of Chicago Law School.[86] Hayek, Frank Knight, Friedman and George Stigler worked together in forming the Mont Pèlerin Society, an international forum for neoliberals.[87] Hayek and Friedman cooperated in support of the Intercollegiate Society of Individualists, later renamed the Intercollegiate Studies Institute, an American student organisation devoted to libertarian ideas.[76][88]

Although they shared most political beliefs, disagreeing primarily on question of monetary policy,[89] Hayek and Friedman worked in separate university departments with different research interests and never developed a close working relationship.[90] According to Alan O. Ebenstein, who wrote biographies of both of them, Hayek probably had a closer friendship with Keynes than with Friedman.[91]

Hayek received a Guggenheim Fellowship in 1954.[92][93]

Another influential political philosopher and German-speaking exile at the University of Chicago at the time was Leo Strauss, but according to his student Joseph Cropsey who also knew Hayek, there was no contact between the two of them.[94]

After editing a book on John Stuart Mill's letters he planned to publish two books on the liberal order, The Constitution of Liberty and "The Creative Powers of a Free Civilization" (eventually the title for the second chapter of The Constitution of Liberty).[95] He completed The Constitution of Liberty in May 1959, with publication in February 1960. Hayek was concerned that "with that condition of men in which coercion of some by others is reduced as much as is possible in society".[96] Hayek was disappointed that the book did not receive the same enthusiastic general reception as The Road to Serfdom had sixteen years before.[97]

He left Chicago mostly because of financial reasons, being concerned about his pension provisions.[98] His primary source of income was his salary, and he received some additional money from book royalties but avoided other lucrative sources of income for academics such as writing textbooks.[99] He spent a lot on his frequent travels. [99] He regularly spent summers in Austrian Alps, usually in the Tyrolean village Obergurgl where he enjoyed mountain climbing, and also visited Japan four times with additional trips to Tahiti, Fiji, Indonesia, Australia, New Caledonia and Ceylon.[100] After his divorce, his financial situation worsened.[101]

Freiburg and Salzburg edit

From 1962 until his retirement in 1968, he was a professor at the University of Freiburg, West Germany, where he began work on his next book, Law, Legislation and Liberty. Hayek regarded his years at Freiburg as "very fruitful".[102] Following his retirement, Hayek spent a year as a visiting professor of philosophy at the University of California, Los Angeles, where he continued work on Law, Legislation and Liberty, teaching a graduate seminar by the same name and another on the philosophy of social science.[63] Preliminary drafts of the book were completed by 1970, but Hayek chose to rework his drafts and finally brought the book to publication in three volumes in 1973, 1976 and 1979.[103]

Hayek became a professor at the University of Salzburg from 1969 to 1977 and then returned to Freiburg.[13] When Hayek left Salzburg in 1977, he wrote: "I made a mistake in moving to Salzburg". The economics department was small, and the library facilities were inadequate.[104]

Although Hayek's health suffered, and he fell into a depressionary bout, he continued to work on his magnum opus, Law, Legislation and Liberty in periods when he was feeling better.[105]

Nobel Memorial Prize edit

On 9 October 1974, it was announced that Hayek would be awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics with Swedish economist Gunnar Myrdal, with the reasons for selection being listed in a press release.[106] He was surprised at being given the award and believed that he was given it with Myrdal to balance the award with someone from the opposite side of the political spectrum.[107] The Sveriges-Riksbank Nobel Prize in Economics was established in 1968, and Hayek was the first non-Keynesian economist to win it.

Among the reasons given, the committee stated, Hayek "was one of the few economists who gave warning of the possibility of a major economic crisis before the great crash came in the autumn of 1929."[106] The following year, Hayek further confirmed his original prediction. An interviewer asked, "We understand that you were one of the only economists to forecast that America was headed for a depression, is that true?" Hayek responded, "Yes."[108] However, no textual evidence has emerged of "a prediction".[109][110] Indeed, Hayek wrote on 26 October 1929, three days before the crash, "at present there is no reason to expect a sudden crash of the New York stock exchange. ... The credit possibilities/conditions are, at any rate, currently very great, and therefore it appears assured that an outright crisis-like destruction of the present high [price] level should not be feared."[111][112]

During the Nobel ceremony in December 1974, Hayek met the Russian dissident Aleksandr Solzhenitsyn.[113] Hayek later sent him a Russian translation of The Road to Serfdom.[107] He spoke with apprehension at his award speech about the danger the authority of the prize would lend to an economist,[114] but the prize brought much greater public awareness to the then controversial ideas of Hayek and was described by his biographer as "the great rejuvenating event in his life".[115]

British politics edit

In February 1975, Margaret Thatcher was elected leader of the British Conservative Party. The Institute of Economic Affairs arranged a meeting between Hayek and Thatcher in London soon after.[116] During Thatcher's only visit to the Conservative Research Department in the summer of 1975, a speaker had prepared a paper on why the "middle way" was the pragmatic path the Conservative Party should take, avoiding the extremes of left and right. Before he had finished, Thatcher "reached into her briefcase and took out a book. It was Hayek's The Constitution of Liberty. Interrupting our pragmatist, she held the book up for all of us to see. 'This', she said sternly, 'is what we believe', and banged Hayek down on the table".[117]

Despite the media depictions of him as Thatcher's guru and power behind the throne, the communication between him and the Prime Minister was not very regular, they were in contact only once or twice a year.[118] Besides Thatcher, Hayek also made a significant influence on Enoch Powell, Keith Joseph, Nigel Lawson, Geoffrey Howe and John Biffen.[119]

Hayek gained some controversy in 1978 by praising Thatcher's anti-immigration policy proposal in an article which ignited numerous accusations of anti-Semitism and racism because of his reflections on the inability of assimilation of Eastern European Jews in the Vienna of his youth.[119] He defended himself by explaining that he made no racial judgements, only highlighted the problems of acculturation.[120]

In 1977, Hayek was critical of the Lib–Lab pact in which the British Liberal Party agreed to keep the British Labour government in office. Writing to The Times, Hayek said: "May one who has devoted a large part of his life to the study of the history and the principles of liberalism point out that a party that keeps a socialist government in power has lost all title to the name 'Liberal'. Certainly no liberal can in future vote 'Liberal'".[121] Hayek was criticised by Liberal politicians Gladwyn Jebb and Andrew Phillips, who both claimed that the purpose of the pact was to discourage socialist legislation.

Lord Gladwyn pointed out that the German Free Democrats were in coalition with the German Social Democrats.[122] Hayek was defended by Professor Antony Flew, who stated that—unlike the British Labour Party—the German Social Democrats had since the late 1950s abandoned public ownership of the means of production, distribution and exchange and had instead embraced the social market economy.[123]

In 1978, Hayek came into conflict with Liberal Party leader David Steel, who claimed that liberty was possible only with "social justice and an equitable distribution of wealth and power, which in turn require a degree of active government intervention" and that the Conservative Party were more concerned with the connection between liberty and private enterprise than between liberty and democracy. Hayek claimed that a limited democracy might be better than other forms of limited government at protecting liberty, but that an unlimited democracy was worse than other forms of unlimited government because "its government loses the power even to do what it thinks right if any group on which its majority depends thinks otherwise".

Hayek stated that if the Conservative leader had said "that free choice is to be exercised more in the market place than in the ballot box, she has merely uttered the truism that the first is indispensable for individual freedom while the second is not: free choice can at least exist under a dictatorship that can limit itself but not under the government of an unlimited democracy which cannot".[124]

Hayek supported Britain in the Falklands War, writing that it would be justified to attack Argentinian territory instead of just defending the islands, which earned him a lot of criticism in Argentina, a country which he also visited several times. He was also displeased by the weak response of the United States to the Iran hostage crisis, claiming that an ultimatum should be issued and Iran bombed if they do not comply. He supported Ronald Reagan's decision to keep high defence spending, believing that a strong US military is a guarantee of world peace and necessary to keep the Soviet Union under control.[125] President Reagan listed Hayek as among the two or three people who most influenced his philosophy and welcomed him to the White House as a special guest.[126] Senator Barry Goldwater listed Hayek as his favourite political philosopher and congressman Jack Kemp named him an inspiration for his political career.[127]

Recognition edit

In 1980, Hayek was one of twelve Nobel laureates to meet with Pope John Paul II "to dialogue, discuss views in their fields, communicate regarding the relationship between Catholicism and science, and 'bring to the Pontiff's attention the problems which the Nobel Prize Winners, in their respective fields of study, consider to be the most urgent for contemporary man'"[128]

Hayek was appointed a Member of the Order of the Companions of Honour (CH) in the 1984 Birthday Honours by Elizabeth II on the advice of British Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher for his "services to the study of economics".[25][26] Hayek had hoped to receive a baronetcy and after being awarded the CH sent a letter to his friends requesting that he be called the English version of Friedrich (i.e. Frederick) from now on. After his twenty-minute audience with the Queen, he was "absolutely besotted" with her according to his daughter-in-law Esca Hayek. Hayek said a year later that he was "amazed by her. That ease and skill, as if she'd known me all my life". The audience with the Queen was followed by a dinner with family and friends at the Institute of Economic Affairs. When later that evening Hayek was dropped off at the Reform Club, he commented: "I've just had the happiest day of my life".[26]

In 1991, President George H. W. Bush awarded Hayek the Presidential Medal of Freedom, one of the two highest civilian awards in the United States, for a "lifetime of looking beyond the horizon".[129]

Death edit

Hayek died on 23 March 1992, aged 92, in Freiburg, Germany and was buried on 4 April in the Neustift am Walde cemetery in the northern outskirts of Vienna according to the Catholic rite.[130] In 2011, his article "The Use of Knowledge in Society" was selected as one of the top 20 articles published in The American Economic Review during its first 100 years.[29]

The New York University Journal of Law and Liberty holds an annual lecture in his honor.[131]

Work and views edit

Business cycle edit

 
Parts of a business cycle
 
Actual business cycle

Ludwig von Mises had earlier applied the concept of marginal utility to the value of money in his Theory of Money and Credit (1912) in which he also proposed an explanation for "industrial fluctuations" based on the ideas of the old British Currency School and of Swedish economist Knut Wicksell.[132] Hayek used this body of work as a starting point for his own interpretation of the business cycle, elaborating what later became known as the Austrian theory of the business cycle.[133] Hayek spelled out the Austrian approach in more detail in his book, published in 1929, an English translation of which appeared in 1933 as Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle. There, Hayek argued for a monetary approach to the origins of the cycle. In his Prices and Production (1931), Hayek argued that the business cycle resulted from the central bank's inflationary credit expansion and its transmission over time, leading to a capital misallocation caused by the artificially low interest rates.[134] Hayek claimed that "the past instability of the market economy is the consequence of the exclusion of the most important regulator of the market mechanism, money, from itself being regulated by the market process".[135]

Hayek's analysis was based on Eugen Böhm von Bawerk's concept of the "average period of production" and on the effects that monetary policy could have upon it.[136] In accordance with the reasoning later outlined in his essay "The Use of Knowledge in Society" (1945), Hayek argued that a monopolistic governmental agency like a central bank can neither possess the relevant information which should govern supply of money, nor have the ability to use it correctly.[137]

In 1929, Lionel Robbins assumed the helm of the London School of Economics (LSE).[66] Eager to promote alternatives to what he regarded as the narrow approach of the school of economic thought that then dominated the English-speaking academic world (centered at the University of Cambridge and deriving largely from the work of Alfred Marshall), Robbins invited Hayek to join the faculty at LSE, which he did in 1931.[138] According to Nicholas Kaldor, Hayek's theory of the time-structure of capital and of the business cycle initially "fascinated the academic world" and appeared to offer a less "facile and superficial" understanding of macroeconomics than the Cambridge school's.[139]

Also in 1931, Hayek crititicized John Maynard Keynes's Treatise on Money (1930) in his "Reflections on the pure theory of Mr. J.M. Keynes"[140] and published his lectures at the LSE in book form as Prices and Production.[141] For Keynes, unemployment and idle resources are caused by a lack of effective demand, but for Hayek they stem from a previous unsustainable episode of easy money and artificially low interest rates.[135] Keynes asked his friend Piero Sraffa to respond. Sraffa elaborated on the effect of inflation-induced "forced savings" on the capital sector and about the definition of a "natural" interest rate in a growing economy (see Sraffa–Hayek debate).[142] Others who responded negatively to Hayek's work on the business cycle included John Hicks, Frank Knight and Gunnar Myrdal, who, later on, would share the Sveriges-Riksbank Prize in Economics with him.[143] Kaldor later wrote that Hayek's Prices and Production had produced "a remarkable crop of critics" and that the total number of pages in British and American journals dedicated to the resulting debate "could rarely have been equalled in the economic controversies of the past".[139]

Hayek's work, throughout the 1940s, was largely ignored, except for scathing critiques by Nicholas Kaldor.[139][144] Lionel Robbins himself, who had embraced the Austrian theory of the business cycle in The Great Depression (1934), later regretted having written the book and accepted many of the Keynesian counter-arguments.[145]

Hayek never produced the book-length treatment of "the dynamics of capital" that he had promised in the Pure Theory of Capital.[146] At the University of Chicago, Hayek was not part of the economics department and did not influence the rebirth of neoclassical theory that took place there (see Chicago school of economics).[83] When in 1974 he shared the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics with Myrdal, the latter complained about being paired with an "ideologue". Milton Friedman declared himself "an enormous admirer of Hayek, but not for his economics.[147] Milton Friedman also commented on some of his writings, saying "I think Prices and Production is a very flawed book. I think his [Pure Theory of Capital] is unreadable. On the other hand, The Road to Serfdom is one of the great books of our time".[145]

Economic calculation problem edit

Building on the earlier work of Mises and others, Hayek also argued that while in centrally planned economies an individual or a select group of individuals must determine the distribution of resources, these planners will never have enough information to carry out this allocation reliably. This argument, first proposed by Max Weber and Ludwig von Mises, says that the efficient exchange and use of resources can be maintained only through the price mechanism in free markets (see economic calculation problem).[148]

In 1935, Hayek published Collectivist Economic Planning, a collection of essays from an earlier debate that had been initiated by Mises. Hayek included Mises's essay in which Mises argued that rational planning was impossible under socialism.[149]

Socialist Oskar Lange responded by invoking general equilibrium theory, which they argued disproved Mises's thesis. They noted that the difference between a planned and a free market system lay in who was responsible for solving the equations.[150] They argued that if some of the prices chosen by socialist managers were wrong, gluts or shortages would appear, signalling them to adjust the prices up or down, just as in a free market.[151] Through such a trial and error, a socialist economy could mimic the efficiency of a free market system while avoiding its many problems.[152]

Hayek challenged this vision in a series of contributions. In "Economics and Knowledge" (1937), he pointed out that the standard equilibrium theory assumed that all agents have full and correct information, and how, in his mind, in the real world different individuals have different bits of knowledge and furthermore some of what they believe is wrong.[153]

In "The Use of Knowledge in Society" (1945), Hayek argued that the price mechanism serves to share and synchronise local and personal knowledge, allowing society's members to achieve diverse and complicated ends through a principle of spontaneous self-organization. He contrasted the use of the price mechanism with central planning, arguing that the former allows for more rapid adaptation to changes in particular circumstances of time and place.[154] Thus, Hayek set the stage for Oliver Williamson's later contrast between markets and hierarchies as alternative co-ordination mechanisms for economic transactions.[155] He used the term catallaxy to describe a "self-organizing system of voluntary co-operation". Hayek's research into this argument was specifically cited by the Nobel Committee in its press release awarding Hayek the Nobel prize.[106]

Investment and choice edit

Hayek made breakthroughs in the choice theory, and examined the inter-relations between non-permanent production goods and "latent" or potentially economic permanent resources, building on the choice theoretical insight that "processes that take more time will evidently not be adopted unless they yield a greater return than those that take less time".[156]

Philosophy of science edit

During World War II, Hayek began the Abuse of Reason project. His goal was to show how a number of then-popular doctrines and beliefs had a common origin in some fundamental misconceptions about the social science.[157]

Ideas were developed in The Counter-Revolution of Science in 1952 and in some of Hayek's later essays in the philosophy of science such as "Degrees of Explanation" (1955) and "The Theory of Complex Phenomena" (1964).[158]

In Counter-Revolution, for example, Hayek observed that the hard sciences attempt to remove the "human factor" to obtain objective and strictly controlled results:

[T]he persistent effort of modern Science has been to get down to "objective facts," to cease studying what men thought about nature or regarding the given concepts as true images of the real world, and, above all, to discard all theories which pretended to explain phenomena by imputing to them a directing mind like our own. Instead, its main task became to revise and reconstruct the concepts formed from ordinary experience on the basis of a systematic testing of the phenomena, so as to be better able to recognize the particular as an instance of a general rule.

— Friedrich Hayek, The Counter-Revolution of Science (Chapter II, "The Problem and the Method of the Natural Sciences")

Meanwhile, the soft sciences are attempting to measure human action itself:

The social sciences in the narrower sense, i.e., those which used to be described as the moral sciences, are concerned with man's conscious or reflected action, actions where a person can be said to choose between various courses open to him, and here the situation is essentially different. The external stimulus which may be said to cause or occasion such actions can of course also be defined in purely physical terms. But if we tried to do so for the purposes of explaining human action, we would confine ourselves to less than we know about the situation.

— Friedrich Hayek, The Counter-Revolution of Science (Chapter III, "The Subjective Character of the Data of the Social Sciences")

He notes that these are mutually exclusive and that social sciences should not attempt to impose positivist methodology, nor to claim objective or definite results:[159]

Psychology edit

Hayek's first academic essay was a psychological work titled 'Contributions to the Theory of the Development of Consciousness' (Beiträge zur Theorie der Entwicklung des Bewußtseins) In The Sensory Order: An Inquiry into the Foundations of Theoretical Psychology (1952), Hayek independently developed a "Hebbian learning" model of learning and memory—an idea he first conceived in 1920 prior to his study of economics. Hayek's expansion of the "Hebbian synapse" construction into a global brain theory received attention in neuroscience, cognitive science, computer science, and evolutionary psychology by scientists such as Gerald Edelman, Vittorio Guidano and Joaquin Fuster.[160][161][162]

The Sensory Order can be viewed as a development of his attack on scientism. Hayek posited two orders, namely the sensory order that we experience and the natural order that natural science revealed. Hayek thought that the sensory order actually is a product of the brain. He described the brain as a very complex yet self-ordering hierarchical classification system, a huge network of connections. Because of the nature of the classifier system, richness of our sensory experience can exist. Hayek's description posed problems to behaviorism, whose proponents took the sensory order as fundamental.[157]

International Relations edit

Hayek was a lifelong federalist. He joined several pan-European and pro-federalist movements throughout his career, and called for federal ties between the U.K. and Europe, and between Europe and the United States. After the 1950s, when the Cold War began in earnest, Hayek largely kept his federalist proposals out of the public sphere, although he did propose to federate Jerusalem as late as the 1970s.[163]

Hayek argued that closer economic ties without closer political ties would lead to more problems because interest groups in nation-states would best be able to counter the internationalization of markets that comes with closer economic ties by appealing to nationalism.[164] Much of his time in the pro-federalist and pan-European groups was spent arguing with pro-federal and pan-European democratic socialists over the proper extent of a world federal government. Hayek argued that such a world government should do little more than act as a negative check on national sovereignties and serve as a focal point for collective defense.[165]

As the Cold War heated up, Hayek grew more hawkish and he pushed his federal proposals onto the backburner in favor of more traditional public policy proposals that acknowledged and respected the sovereignty of nation-states.[166] Yet Hayek never disavowed his famous call for "the abrogation of national sovereignties"[167] and his lifetime of work in the area of international relations continues to attract attention from scholars searching for federalist answers to contemporary problems in international relations.[168][169][170][171]

Social and political philosophy edit

Two traditions in the theory of liberty edit

In the latter half of his career, Hayek made a number of contributions to social and political philosophy which he based on his views on the limits of human knowledge and the idea of spontaneous order in social institutions. He argues in favour of a society organised around a market order in which the apparatus of state is employed almost (though not entirely) exclusively to enforce the legal order (consisting of abstract rules and not particular commands) necessary for a market of free individuals to function. These ideas were informed by a moral philosophy derived from epistemological concerns regarding the inherent limits of human knowledge. Hayek argued that his ideal individualistic and free-market polity would be self-regulating to such a degree that it would be "a society which does not depend for its functioning on our finding good men for running it".[172]

He discusses the contrasting traditions of liberty—British and French—in the theory of freedom. The British tradition, influenced by thinkers like David Hume and Adam Smith, emphasizes the organic growth of institutions and the spontaneous evolution of society. It recognizes that political order arises from the cumulative experience and success of individuals, rather than from deliberate design. In contrast, the French tradition, rooted in Cartesian rationalism, seeks to construct a utopia based on a belief in the unlimited powers of human reason. The French tradition, that Hayek called constructivist rationalism, gained influence over time, partly due to its assumptions about human ambition and pride. However, according to Hayek, the British tradition, with its emphasis on the gradual development of civilization and the role of individual freedom, provides a more valid theory of liberty.[172][173][174]

Spontaneous order edit

Hayek viewed the free price system not as a conscious invention (that which is intentionally designed by man), but as spontaneous order or what Scottish philosopher Adam Ferguson referred to as "the result of human action but not of human design".[175] For instance, Hayek put the price mechanism on the same level as language, which he developed in his price signal theory.[176]

Hayek attributed the birth of civilisation to private property in his book The Fatal Conceit (1988).[177] He explained that price signals are the only means of enabling each economic decision maker to communicate tacit knowledge or dispersed knowledge to each other to solve the economic calculation problem.[177] Alain de Benoist of the Nouvelle Droite (New Right) produced a highly critical essay on Hayek's work in an issue of Telos, citing the flawed assumptions behind Hayek's idea of "spontaneous order" and the authoritarian and totalising implications of his free-market ideology.[178]

Hayek's concept of the market as a spontaneous order has been applied to ecosystems to defend a broadly non-interventionist policy.[179] Like the market, ecosystems contain complex networks of information, involve an ongoing dynamic process, contain orders within orders and the entire system operates without being directed by a conscious mind.[180] On this analysis, species takes the place of price as a visible element of the system formed by a complex set of largely unknowable elements. Human ignorance about the countless interactions between the organisms of an ecosystem limits our ability to manipulate nature.[181]

Hayek's price signal concept is in relation to how consumers are often unaware of specific events that change market, yet change their decisions, simply because the price goes up. Thus pricing communicates information.[182]

Criticism of collectivism edit

Hayek was one of the leading academic critics of collectivism in the 20th century.[13] In Hayek's view, the central role of the state should be to maintain the rule of law, with as little arbitrary intervention as possible.[96] In his popular book The Road to Serfdom (1944) and in subsequent academic works, Hayek argued that socialism required central economic planning and that such planning in turn leads towards totalitarianism.[183]

In The Road to Serfdom, Hayek wrote:

Although our modern socialists' promise of greater freedom is genuine and sincere, in recent years observer after observer has been impressed by the unforeseen consequences of socialism, the extraordinary similarity in many respects of the conditions under "communism" and "fascism".[184]

Hayek posited that a central planning authority would have to be endowed with powers that would impact and ultimately control social life because the knowledge required for centrally planning an economy is inherently decentralised, and would need to be brought under control.[149]

Though Hayek did argue that the state should provide law centrally, others have pointed out that this contradicts his arguments about the role of judges in "discovering" the law, suggesting that Hayek would have supported decentralized provision of legal services.[185]

Hayek also wrote that the state can play a role in the economy, specifically in creating a safety net, saying:

There is no reason why, in a society which has reached the general level of wealth ours has, the first kind of security should not be guaranteed to all without endangering general freedom; that is: some minimum of food, shelter and clothing, sufficient to preserve health. Nor is there any reason why the state should not help to organize a comprehensive system of social insurance in providing for those common hazards of life against which few can make adequate provision.[186]

"The Denationalization of Money" is one of his literary works, in which he advocated the establishment of competitions in issuing moneys.[187]

Social safety nets edit

With regard to a social safety net, Hayek advocated "some provision for those threatened by the extremes of indigence or starvation due to circumstances beyond their control" and argued that the "necessity of some such arrangement in an industrial society is unquestioned—be it only in the interest of those who require protection against acts of desperation on the part of the needy".[188] Summarizing Hayek's views on the topic, journalist Nicholas Wapshott has argued that "[Hayek] advocated mandatory universal health care and unemployment insurance, enforced, if not directly provided, by the state".[189] Critical theorist Bernard Harcourt has argued further that "Hayek was adamant about this".[190] In 1944, Hayek wrote in The Road to Serfdom:

There is no reason why in a society which has reached the general level of wealth which ours has attained [that security against severe physical privation, the certainty of a given minimum of sustenance for all; or more briefly, the security of a minimum income] should not be guaranteed to all without endangering general freedom. There are difficult questions about the precise standard which should thus be assured... but there can be no doubt that some minimum of food, shelter, and clothing, sufficient to preserve health and the capacity to work, can be assured to everybody. Indeed, for a considerable part of the population of England this sort of security has long been achieved.
Nor is there any reason why the state should not assist... individuals in providing for those common hazards of life against which, because of their uncertainty, few individuals can make adequate provision. Where, as in the case of sickness and accident, neither the desire to avoid such calamities nor the efforts to overcome their consequences are as a rule weakened by the provision of assistance—where, in short, we deal with genuinely insurable risks—the case for the state's helping to organize a comprehensive system of social insurance is very strong. There are many points of detail where those wishing to preserve the competitive system and those wishing to supersede it by something different will disagree on the details of such schemes; and it is possible under the name of social insurance to introduce measures which tend to make competition more or less effective. But there is no incompatibility in principle between the state's providing greater security in this way and the preservation of individual freedom. Wherever communal action can mitigate disasters against which the individual can neither attempt to guard himself nor make the provision for the consequences, such communal action should undoubtedly be taken.[191]

In 1973, Hayek reiterated in Law, Legislation and Liberty:

There is no reason why in a free society government should not assure to all, protection against severe deprivation in the form of an assured minimum income, or a floor below which nobody need to descend. To enter into such an insurance against extreme misfortune may well be in the interest of all; or it may be felt to be a clear moral duty of all to assist, within the organised community, those who cannot help themselves. So long as such a uniform minimum income is provided outside the market to all those who, for any reason, are unable to earn in the market an adequate maintenance, this need not lead to a restriction of freedom, or conflict with the Rule of law.[192]

Political theorist Adam James Tebble has argued that Hayek's concession of a social minimum provided by the state introduces a conceptual tension with his epistemically derived commitment to private property rights, free markets, and spontaneous order.[193]

Criticism of "social justice" edit

Although Hayek believed in a society governed by laws, he disapproved of the notion of "social justice". He compared the market to a game in which "there is no point in calling the outcome just or unjust"[194] and argued that "social justice is an empty phrase with no determinable content".[195] Likewise, "the results of the individual's efforts are necessarily unpredictable, and the question as to whether the resulting distribution of incomes is just has no meaning".[196] He generally regarded government redistribution of income or capital as an unacceptable intrusion upon individual freedom, saying that "the principle of distributive justice, once introduced, would not be fulfilled until the whole of society was organized in accordance with it. This would produce a kind of society which in all essential respects would be the opposite of a free society".[195]

Liberalism and skepticism edit

Arthur M. Diamond argues Hayek's problems arise when he goes beyond claims that can be evaluated within economic science. Diamond argued:

The human mind, Hayek says, is not just limited in its ability to synthesize a vast array of concrete facts, it is also limited in its ability to give a deductively sound ground to ethics. Here is where the tension develops, for he also wants to give a reasoned moral defense of the free market. He is an intellectual skeptic who wants to give political philosophy a secure intellectual foundation. It is thus not too surprising that what results is confused and contradictory.[197]

Chandran Kukathas argues that Hayek's defence of liberalism is unsuccessful because it rests on presuppositions that are incompatible. The unresolved dilemma of his political philosophy is how to mount a systematic defence of liberalism if one emphasizes the limited capacity of reason.[198] Norman P. Barry similarly notes that the "critical rationalism" in Hayek's writings appears incompatible with "a certain kind of fatalism, that we must wait for evolution to pronounce its verdict".[199] Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz argue that the element of paradox exists in the views of Hayek. Noting Hayek's vigorous defense of "invisible hand" evolution that Hayek claimed created better economic institutions than could be created by rational design, Friedman pointed out the irony that Hayek was then proposing to replace the monetary system thus created with a deliberate construct of his own design.[200] John N. Gray summarized this view as "his scheme for an ultra-liberal constitution was a prototypical version of the philosophy he had attacked".[201] Bruce Caldwell wrote that "[i]f one is judging his work against the standard of whether he provided a finished political philosophy, Hayek clearly did not succeed", although he thinks that "economists may find Hayek's political writings useful".[202]

Dictatorship and totalitarianism edit

Hayek sent António de Oliveira Salazar a copy of The Constitution of Liberty (1960) in 1962. Hayek hoped that his book—this "preliminary sketch of new constitutional principles"—"may assist" Salazar "in his endeavour to design a constitution which is proof against the abuses of democracy".[203]

Hayek visited Chile in the 1970s and 1980s during the Government Junta of general Augusto Pinochet and accepted being appointed Honorary Chairman of the Centro de Estudios Públicos, the think tank formed by the economists who transformed Chile into a free market economy.[203]

Asked about the military dictatorship of Chile by a Chilean interviewer, Hayek is translated from German to Spanish to English as having said the following:

As long term institutions, I am totally against dictatorships. But a dictatorship may be a necessary system for a transitional period. [...] Personally I prefer a liberal dictatorship to democratic government devoid of liberalism. My personal impression—and this is valid for South America—is that in Chile, for example, we will witness a transition from a dictatorial government to a liberal government.[103]

In a letter to the London Times, he defended the Pinochet regime and said that he had "not been able to find a single person even in much maligned Chile who did not agree that personal freedom was much greater under Pinochet than it had been under Allende".[204][205] Hayek admitted that "it is not very likely that this will succeed, even if, at a particular point in time, it may be the only hope there is", but he explained that "[i]t is not certain hope, because it will always depend on the goodwill of an individual, and there are very few individuals one can trust. But if it is the sole opportunity which exists at a particular moment it may be the best solution despite this. And only if and when the dictatorial government is visibly directing its steps towards limited democracy".

For Hayek, the distinction between authoritarianism and totalitarianism has much importance and he was at pains to emphasise his opposition to totalitarianism, noting that the concept of transitional dictatorship which he defended was characterised by authoritarianism, not totalitarianism. For example, when Hayek visited Venezuela in May 1981, he was asked to comment on the prevalence of totalitarian regimes in Latin America. In reply, Hayek warned against confusing "totalitarianism with authoritarianism" and said that he was unaware of "any totalitarian governments in Latin America. The only one was Chile under Allende". For Hayek, the word "totalitarian" signifies something very specific, namely the intention to "organize the whole of society" to attain a "definite social goal" which is stark in contrast to "liberalism and individualism".[206] He claimed that democracy can also be repressive and totalitarian; in The Constitution of Liberty he often refers to Jacob Talmon's concept of totalitarian democracy.

Immigration, nationalism and race edit

Hayek was skeptical about international immigration and supported Thatcher's anti-immigration policies.[119] In Law, Legislation and Liberty he elaborated:

Freedom of migration is one of the widely accepted and wholly admirable principles of liberalism. But should this generally give the stranger a right to settle down in a community in which he is not welcome? Has he a claim to be given a job or be sold a house if no resident is willing to do so? He clearly should be entitled to accept a job or buy a house if offered to him. But have the individual inhabitants a duty to offer either to him? Or ought it to be an offence if they voluntarily agree not to do so? Swiss and Tyrolese villages have a way of keeping out strangers which neither infringe nor rely on any law. Is this anti-liberal or morally justified? For established old communities I have no certain answers to these questions.[207]

He was mainly preoccupied with practical problems concerning immigration:

There exist, of course, other reasons why such restrictions appear unavoidable so long as certain differences in national or ethnic traditions (especially differences in the rate of propagation) exist-which in turn are not likely to disappear so long as restrictions on migration continue. We must face the fact that we here encounter a limit to the universal application of those liberal principles of policy which the existing facts of the present world make unavoidable.[208]

He was not sympathetic to nationalist ideas and was afraid that mass immigration might revive nationalist sentiment among domestic population and ruin the postwar progress that was made among Western nations.[209] He additionally explained:

However far modern man accepts in principle the ideal that the same rules should apply to all men, in fact he does concede it only to those whom he regards as similar to himself, and only slowly learns to extend the range of those he does accept as his likes. There is little legislation can do to speed up this process and much it may do to reverse it by re-awakening sentiments that are already on the wane.[209]

Despite his opposition to nationalism, Hayek made numerous controversial and inflammatory comments about specific ethnic groups. Answering an interview question about people he cannot deal with he mentioned his dislike of Middle Eastern populations, claiming they were dishonest, and also expressed "profound dislike" of Indian students at London School of Economics, saying that were usually "detestable sons of Bengali moneylenders".[210] He claimed that his attitude is not based on any racial feeling.[210] During World War II he discussed the possibility of sending his children to the United States but was concerned that they might be placed with a "coloured family".[211] In a later interview, questioned about his attitude towards Black people, he said laconically that he "did not like dancing Negroes"[212] and on another occasion he ridiculed the decision to award the Nobel Peace Prize to Martin Luther King Jr.[213] He also made negative comments about awarding the Prize to Ralph Bunche, Albert Luthuli, and his LSE colleague W. Arthur Lewis who he described as an "unusually able West Indian negro".[213] In 1978 Hayek made a month-long visit to South Africa (his third) where he gave numerous lectures, interviews, and met prominent politicians and business leaders, unconcerned about possible propagandistic effect of his tour for Apartheid regime. He expressed his opposition to some of the government policies, believing that publicly funded institutions should treat all citizens equally, but also claimed that private institutions have the right to discriminate. Additionally, he condemned the "scandalous" hostility and interference of the international community in South African internal affairs.[214] He further explained his attitude:

People in South Africa have to deal with their own problems, and the idea that you can use external pressure to change people, who after all have built up a civilization of a kind, seems to me morally a very doubtful belief.[215]

While Hayek gave somewhat ambiguous comments on the injustices of Apartheid and proper role of the state, some of his Mont Pelerin colleagues, such as John Davenport and Wilhelm Röpke, were more ardent supporters of South African government and criticized Hayek for being too soft on the subject.[216]

Inequality and class edit

Hayek claimed that the idea that "all men are born equal" is untrue because evolution and genetic differences have created "boundless variety of human nature". He emphasized the importance of nature, complaining that it became too fashionable to ascribe all human differences to environment.[217] Hayek defended economic inequality, believing that the existence of wealthy class is important not only for economic reasons—accumulating capital and directing investments—but also for political, cultural, scientific and conservationist goals which are often financed and promoted by philanthropists. Since the market mechanism cannot provide for all societal needs, some of which are outside of economic calculation, existence of wealthy individuals guarantees the efficiency and pluralism in their development and realization, which could not be guaranteed in the case of state monopoly.[218] Individual wealth offers independence and can create intellectual, moral, political and artistic leaders which are not employed and influenced by the state.[219] According to Hayek the society benefits from having a hereditary wealthy class because individuals born in it don't have to devote their energy to earning a living and can devote themselves to other purposes such as experimenting with different ideas, hobbies and lifestyles which can later be adopted by broader society.[220] In The Constitution of Liberty he wrote:

Yet is it really so obvious that the tennis or golf professional is a more useful member of society than the wealthy amateurs who devoted their time to perfecting these games? Or that the paid curator of a public museum is more useful than a private collector? Before the reader answers these questions too hastily, I would ask him to consider whether there would ever have been golf or tennis professionals or museum curators if wealthy amateurs had not preceded them. Can we not hope that other new interests will still arise from the playful explorations of those who can indulge in them for the short span of a human life? It is only natural that the development of the art of living and of the non-materialistic values should have profited most from the activities of those who had no material worries.[221]

He contrasted individuals who inherited wealth, with upper class values and education, with the nouveau riche who often use their wealth in more vulgar ways.[220] He decried the disappearance of such leisured aristocratic class, claiming that contemporary Western elites are usually business groups that lack intellectual leadership and coherent "philosophy of life" and use their wealth mostly for economic purposes.[222]

Hayek was against high taxes on inheritance, believing that it is natural function of the family to transmit standards, traditions and material goods. Without transmission of property, parents might try to secure the future of their children by placing them in prestigious and high-paying positions, as was customary in socialist countries, which creates even worse injustices.[223] He was also strongly against progressive taxation, noting that in most countries additional taxes paid by the rich amount to insignificantly small amount of total tax revenue and that the only major result of the policy is "gratification of the envy of the less-well-off".[224] He also claimed that it is contrary to the idea of equality under the law and against democratic principle that the majority should not impose discriminatory rules against the minority.[225][226]

Criticism edit

Hayek's views on social welfare policies have also been the subject of criticism. Critics contend that his opposition to government intervention in the economy fails to recognize the need for social safety nets and other forms of support for vulnerable populations. Furthermore, it has been argued that his views on welfare policy contradict his views on social justice.[227]

Hayek's argument in The Road to Serfdom has been criticized as a slippery slope argument and therefore fallacious.[228] However, others have argued that this is a fundamental misunderstanding of the book and Hayek's point is about what central planning directly entails, not what it is likely to lead to.[229]

Influence and recognition edit

 
An elderly Hayek in 1981

Hayek's influence on the development of economics is widely acknowledged. With regard to the popularity of his Nobel acceptance lecture, Hayek is the second-most frequently cited economist (after Kenneth Arrow) in the Nobel lectures of the prize winners in economics. Hayek wrote critically there of the field of orthodox economics and neo-classical modelisation.[230] A number of Nobel Laureates in economics, such as Vernon Smith and Herbert A. Simon, recognise Hayek as the greatest modern economist.[231] Another Nobel winner, Paul Samuelson, believed that Hayek was worthy of his award, but nevertheless claimed that "there were good historical reasons for fading memories of Hayek within the mainstream last half of the twentieth century economist fraternity. In 1931, Hayek's Prices and Production had enjoyed an ultra-short Byronic success. In retrospect hindsight tells us that its mumbo-jumbo about the period of production grossly misdiagnosed the macroeconomics of the 1927–1931 (and the 1931–2007) historical scene".[232] Despite this comment, Samuelson spent the last 50 years of his life obsessed with the problems of capital theory identified by Hayek and Böhm-Bawerk, and Samuelson flatly judged Hayek to have been right and his own teacher Joseph Schumpeter to have been wrong on the central economic question of the 20th century, the feasibility of socialist economic planning in a production goods dominated economy.[233]

Hayek is widely recognised for having introduced the time dimension to the equilibrium construction and for his key role in helping inspire the fields of growth theory, information economics and the theory of spontaneous order. The "informal" economics presented in Milton Friedman's massively influential popular work Free to Choose (1980) is explicitly Hayekian in its account of the price system as a system for transmitting and co-ordinating knowledge. This can be explained by the fact that Friedman taught Hayek's famous paper "The Use of Knowledge in Society" (1945) in his graduate seminars.

In 1944, he was elected as a Fellow of the British Academy[234] after he was nominated for membership by Keynes.[235]

Harvard economist and former Harvard University President Lawrence Summers explains Hayek's place in modern economics: "What's the single most important thing to learn from an economics course today? What I tried to leave my students with is the view that the invisible hand is more powerful than the [un]hidden hand. Things will happen in well-organized efforts without direction, controls, plans. That's the consensus among economists. That's the Hayek legacy".[236]

By 1947, Hayek was an organiser of the Mont Pelerin Society, a group of classical liberals who sought to oppose socialism. Hayek was also instrumental in the founding of the Institute of Economic Affairs, the right-wing libertarian and free-market think tank that inspired Thatcherism. He was in addition a member of the conservative and libertarian Philadelphia Society.[237]

Hayek had a long-standing and close friendship with philosopher of science Karl Popper, who was also from Vienna. In a letter to Hayek in 1944, Popper stated: "I think I have learnt more from you than from any other living thinker, except perhaps Alfred Tarski".[238] Popper dedicated his Conjectures and Refutations to Hayek. For his part, Hayek dedicated a collection of papers, Studies in Philosophy, Politics, and Economics, to Popper and in 1982 said that "ever since his Logik der Forschung first came out in 1934, I have been a complete adherent to his general theory of methodology".[239] Popper also participated in the inaugural meeting of the Mont Pelerin Society. Their friendship and mutual admiration do not change the fact that there are important differences between their ideas.[240]

Hayek also played a central role in Milton Friedman's intellectual development. Friedman wrote:

My interest in public policy and political philosophy was rather casual before I joined the faculty of the University of Chicago. Informal discussions with colleagues and friends stimulated a greater interest, which was reinforced by Friedrich Hayek's powerful book The Road to Serfdom, by my attendance at the first meeting of the Mont Pelerin Society in 1947, and by discussions with Hayek after he joined the university faculty in 1950. In addition, Hayek attracted an exceptionally able group of students who were dedicated to a libertarian ideology. They started a student publication, The New Individualist Review, which was the outstanding libertarian journal of opinion for some years. I served as an adviser to the journal and published a number of articles in it....[241]

While Friedman often mentioned Hayek as an important influence, Hayek rarely mentioned Friedman.[242] He deeply disagreed with Chicago School methodology, quantitative and macroeconomic focus, and claimed that Friedman's Essays in Positive Economics was as dangerous a book as Keynes' General Theory.[243] Friedman also claimed that despite some Popperian influence Hayek always retained basic Misesian praxeological view which he found "utterly nonsensical".[244] He also noted that he admired Hayek only for his political works and disagreed with his technical economics; he called Prices and Production a "very flawed book" and The Pure Theory of Capital "unreadable". [245] There were occasional tensions at the Mont Pelerin meetings between the Hayek's and Friedman's followers that sometimes threatened to split the Society.[89] Although they worked at the same university and shared political beliefs, Hayek and Friedman rarely collaborated professionally and were not close friends.[91]

Hayek's greatest intellectual debt was to Carl Menger, who pioneered an approach to social explanation similar to that developed in Britain by Bernard Mandeville and the Scottish moral philosophers in the Scottish Enlightenment. He had a wide-reaching influence on contemporary economics, politics, philosophy, sociology, psychology and anthropology. For example, Hayek's discussion in The Road to Serfdom (1944) about truth, falsehood and the use of language influenced some later opponents of postmodernism.[246]

Some radical libertarians had a negative view of Hayek and his milder form of liberalism. Ayn Rand disliked him, seeing him as a conservative and compromiser.[247] In a letter to Rose Wilder Lane in 1946 she wrote:

Now to your question: 'Do those almost with us do more harm than 100% enemies?' I don't think this can be answered with a flat 'yes' or 'no,' because the 'almost' is such a wide term. There is one general rule to observe: those who are with us, but merely do not go far enough are the ones who may do us some good. Those who agree with us in some respects, yet preach contradictory ideas at the same time, are definitely more harmful than 100% enemies. As an example of the kind of 'almost' I would tolerate, I'd name Ludwig von Mises. As an example of our most pernicious enemy, I would name Hayek. That one is real poison.[248]

Hayek made no known written references to Rand.[249]

Wikipedia co-founder Jimmy Wales was influenced by Hayek's ideas on spontaneous order and the Austrian School of economics, after being exposed to these ideas by Austrian economist and Mises Institute Senior Fellow Mark Thornton.[250]

In the 21st century, some libertarian political scientists argue that Hayek would be in favor of Bitcoin and cryptocurrencies due to its resistance to political pressure and due to Hayek's emphasis of sound money and competition in currencies.[251] They also argue that cryptocurrency and Bitcoin serve as a "Hayekian Escape," a method that the people can use to escape the government's currency monopoly.[252]

Relation to conservatism edit

Hayek received new attention in the 1980s and 1990s with the rise of conservative governments in the United States, United Kingdom and Canada. After winning the 1979 United Kingdom general election, Margaret Thatcher appointed Keith Joseph, the director of the Hayekian Centre for Policy Studies, as her secretary of state for industry in an effort to redirect parliament's economic strategies. Likewise, David Stockman, Ronald Reagan's most influential financial official in 1981, was an acknowledged follower of Hayek.[253]

Although usually identified as a conservative liberal or a liberal conservative,[254] Hayek published an essay, "Why I Am Not a Conservative" (included as an appendix to The Constitution of Liberty), in which he criticized certain aspects of conservatism from a liberal perspective. Edmund Fawcett summarizes Hayek's critique as follows:

Conservatives, on Hayek’s account, suffered from the following weaknesses. They feared change unduly. They were unreasonably frightened of uncontrolled social forces. They were too fond of authority. They had no grasp of economics. They lacked the feel for “abstraction” needed for engaging with people of different outlooks. They were too cozy with elites and establishments. They gave in to jingoism and chauvinism. They tended to think mystically, much as socialists tended to overrationalize. They were, last, too suspicious of democracy.[255]

Hayek identified himself as a classical liberal, but noted that in the United States it had become almost impossible to use "liberal" in its original definition and the term "libertarian" was used instead.[256] He also found libertarianism as a term "singularly unattractive" and offered the term "Old Whig" (a phrase borrowed from Edmund Burke) instead. In his later life, he said: "I am becoming a Burkean Whig".[257] Whiggery as a political doctrine had little affinity for classical political economy, the tabernacle of the Manchester School and William Gladstone.[258]

In his 1956 preface to The Road to Serfdom, Hayek summarized all his disagreements with conservatism in this way:

Conservatism, though a necessary element in any stable society, is not a social program; in its paternalistic, nationalistic, and poweradoring tendencies it is often closer to socialism than true liberalism; and with its traditionalistic, anti-intellectual, and often mystical propensities it will never, except in short periods of disillusionment, appeal to the young and all those others who believe that some changes are desirable if this world is to become a better place. A conservative movement, by its very nature, is bound to be a defender of established privilege and to lean on the power of government for the protection of privilege. The essence of the liberal position, however, is the denial of all privilege, if privilege is understood in its proper and original meaning of the state granting and protecting rights to some which are not available on equal terms to others.

Samuel Brittan, concluded in 2010 that "Hayek's book [The Constitution of Liberty] is still probably the most comprehensive statement of the underlying ideas of the moderate free market philosophy espoused by neoliberals".[259] Brittan adds that although Raymond Plant (2009) comes out in the end against Hayek's doctrines, Plant gives The Constitution of Liberty a "more thorough and fair-minded analysis than it has received even from its professed adherents". As a neo-liberal, he helped found the Mont Pelerin Society, a prominent neo-liberal think tank where many other minds, such as Mises and Friedman gathered.[260][259]

Although Hayek is likely a student of the neo-liberal school of libertarianism,[261] he is nonetheless influential in the conservative movement, mainly for his critique of collectivism.[24]

Policy discussions edit

Hayek's ideas on spontaneous order and the importance of prices in dealing with the knowledge problem inspired a debate on economic development and transition economies after the fall of the Berlin wall. For instance, economist Peter Boettke elaborated in detail on why reforming socialism failed and the Soviet Union broke down.[262] Economist Ronald McKinnon uses Hayekian ideas to describe the challenges of transition from a centralized state and planned economy to a market economy.[263] Former World Bank Chief Economist William Easterly emphasizes why foreign aid tends to have no effect at best in books such as The White Man's Burden: Why the West's Efforts to Aid the Rest Have Done So Much Ill and So Little Good.[264]

Since the 2007–2008 financial crisis, there is a renewed interest in Hayek's core explanation of boom-and-bust cycles, which serves as an alternative explanation to that of the savings glut as launched by economist and former Federal Reserve Chair Ben Bernanke. Economists at the Bank for International Settlements, e.g. William R. White, emphasize the importance of Hayekian insights and the impact of monetary policies and credit growth as root causes of financial cycles.[265] Andreas Hoffmann and Gunther Schnabl provide an international perspective and explain recurring financial cycles in the world economy as consequence of gradual interest rate cuts led by the central banks in the large advanced economies since the 1980s.[266][267] Nicolas Cachanosky outlines the impact of American monetary policy on the production structure in Latin America.[268]

In line with Hayek, an increasing number of contemporary researchers sees expansionary monetary policies and too low interest rates as mal-incentives and main drivers of financial crises in general and the subprime market crisis in particular.[269][270] To prevent problems caused by monetary policy, Hayekian and Austrian economists discuss alternatives to current policies and organizations. For instance, Lawrence H. White argued in favor of free banking in the spirit of Hayek's "Denationalization of Money".[271] Along with market monetarist economist Scott Sumner,[272] White also noted that the monetary policy norm that Hayek prescribed, first in Prices and Production (1931) and as late as the 1970s,[273][274] was the stabilization of nominal income.[138]

Hayek's ideas find their way into the discussion of the post-Great Recession issues of secular stagnation. Monetary policy and mounting regulation are argued to have undermined the innovative forces of the market economies. Quantitative easing following the financial crises is argued to have not only conserved structural distortions in the economy, leading to a fall in trend-growth. It also created new distortions and contributes to distributional conflicts.[275]

Central European politics edit

In the 1970s and 1980s, the writings of Hayek were a major influence on some of the future postsocialist economic and political elites in Central and Eastern Europe. Supporting examples include the following:

There is no figure who had more of an influence, no person had more of an influence on the intellectuals behind the Iron Curtain than Friedrich Hayek. His books were translated and published by the underground and black market editions, read widely, and undoubtedly influenced the climate of opinion that ultimately brought about the collapse of the Soviet Union.[276]

— Milton Friedman (Hoover Institution)

The most interesting among the courageous dissenters of the 1980s were the classical liberals, disciples of F.A. Hayek, from whom they had learned about the crucial importance of economic freedom and about the often-ignored conceptual difference between liberalism and democracy.[277]

— Andrzej Walicki (History, Notre Dame)

Estonian Prime Minister Mart Laar came to my office the other day to recount his country's remarkable transformation. He described a nation of people who are harder-working, more virtuous—yes, more virtuous, because the market punishes immorality—and more hopeful about the future than they've ever been in their history. I asked Mr. Laar where his government got the idea for these reforms. Do you know what he replied? He said, "We read Milton Friedman and F.A. Hayek."[278]

— United States Representative Dick Armey

I was 25 years old and pursuing my doctorate in economics when I was allowed to spend six months of post-graduate studies in Naples, Italy. I read the Western economic textbooks and also the more general work of people like Hayek. By the time I returned to Czechoslovakia, I had an understanding of the principles of the market. In 1968, I was glad at the political liberalism of the Dubcek Prague Spring, but was very critical of the Third Way they pursued in economics.[279]

— Václav Klaus (former President of the Czech Republic)

Personal life edit

 
Hayek's grave in Neustifter Friedhof, Vienna

In August 1926, Hayek married Helen Berta Maria von Fritsch (1901–1960), a secretary at the civil service office where he worked. They had two children together.[280] Upon the close of World War II, Hayek restarted a relationship with an old girlfriend, who had married since they first met, but kept it secret until 1948. Hayek and Fritsch divorced in July 1950 and he married his cousin[281] Helene Bitterlich (1900–1996)[282] just a few weeks later, after moving to Arkansas to take advantage of permissive divorce laws.[283] His wife and children were offered settlement and compensation for accepting a divorce. The divorce caused some scandal at LSE, where certain academics refused to have anything to do with Hayek.[283] In a 1978 interview to explain his actions, Hayek stated that he was unhappy in his first marriage and as his wife would not grant him a divorce he had taken steps to obtain one unilaterally.[284]

For a time after his divorce, Hayek rarely visited his children, but kept up more regular contact with them in his older years after moving to Europe.[281][285] Hayek's son, Laurence Hayek (1934–2004) was a distinguished microbiologist.[286] His daughter Christine was an entomologist at the British Museum of Natural History, and she cared for him during his last years, when he had declining health.[285][287]

Hayek had a lifelong interest in biology and was also concerned with ecology and environmental protection. After being awarded his Nobel Prize, he offered his name to be used for endorsements by World Wildlife Fund, National Audubon Society, and the National Trust, a British conservationist organisation. Evolutionary biology was simply one of his interests in natural sciences. Hayek also had an interest in epistemology, which he often applied to his own thinking, as a social scientist. He held that methodological differences in the social sciences and in natural sciences were key to understanding why incompetent policies are often allowed.[288][289]

Hayek was brought up in a non-religious setting and decided from age 15 that he was an agnostic.[47]

He died in 1992 in Freiburg, Germany, where he had lived since leaving Chicago in 1961. Despite his advanced age by the 1980s, he continued to write, even purportedly finishing a book, The Fatal Conceit, in 1988, although its actual authorship is unclear.[13][290]

Legacy and honours edit

 
A street sign named for Hayek in Freiburg im Breisgau, Germany

Hayek's intellectual presence has remained evident in the years following his death, especially in the universities where he had taught, namely the London School of Economics, the University of Chicago and the University of Freiburg. His influence and contributions have been noted by many. A number of tributes have resulted, many established posthumously:

Notable works edit

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ "Laurence Hayek: Microbiologist who in later life commemorated his father's work". The Times: 31. 6 August 2004.
  2. ^ Ebenstein, Alan O. (2003). Hayek's Journey : the mind of Friedrich Hayek (First Palgrave Macmillan ed.). New York: Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 978-1403960382.
  3. ^ Caldwell, Bruce (2004). Hayek's Challenge : an intellectual biography of F.A. Hayek. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ISBN 0-226-09193-7.
  4. ^ Schmidtz, David; Boettke, Peter (Summer 2021). "Friedrich Hayek". Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy.
  5. ^ Gamble, Andrew (1996). Hayek: The Iron Cage of Liberty. Routledge. p. 1. ISBN 978-0-367-00974-8.
  6. ^ a b Bank of Sweden (1974). "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1974".
  7. ^ Skarbek, David (March 2009). (PDF). Review of Austrian Economics. 22 (1): 109–112. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.207.1605. doi:10.1007/s11138-008-0069-x. S2CID 144970753. Archived from the original (PDF) on 27 July 2011.
  8. ^ "Friedrich August von Hayek – Facts". nobelprize.org. Retrieved 30 June 2017.
  9. ^ Rothbard, Murray N. (28 January 2010). "Hayek and the Nobel Prize". Mises Institute. Retrieved 30 June 2017.
  10. ^ a b "Friedrich A. Hayek". Mises Institute. 20 June 2014. Retrieved 3 September 2019.
  11. ^ "Keynes v Hayek: Giants of economics". BBC. 3 August 2011. Retrieved 4 September 2019.
  12. ^ "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1974". NobelPrize.org. Retrieved 4 September 2019.
  13. ^ a b c d e Peter G. Klein (18 August 2014). "Biography of F.A. Hayek (1899–1992)". Mises Institute.
  14. ^ . www-news.uchicago.edu. Archived from the original on 11 March 2022. Retrieved 3 September 2019.
  15. ^ a b c "Commanding Heights : The Chicago School | on PBS". www.pbs.org. Retrieved 3 September 2019.
  16. ^ Burczak, Theodore A. (12 October 2006). Socialism after Hayek. University of Michigan Press. ISBN 978-0472069514.
  17. ^ "Conservatives Need to Reread Their Hayek". American Enterprise Institute – AEI. Retrieved 23 February 2023.
  18. ^ van der Vossen, Bas (2022), "Libertarianism", The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Winter 2022 ed.), retrieved 23 February 2023
  19. ^ CLITEUR, PAUL B. (1990). "Why Hayek is a Conservative". ARSP: Archiv für Rechts- und Sozialphilosophie / Archives for Philosophy of Law and Social Philosophy. 76 (4): 467–478. ISSN 0001-2343. JSTOR 23681094.
  20. ^ Caldwell, Bruce (1 September 2020). "The Road to Serfdom after 75 Years". Journal of Economic Literature. 58 (3): 720–748. doi:10.1257/jel.20191542. ISSN 0022-0515. S2CID 201350365.
  21. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. (2011). "Why I am not a Conservative". The Constitution of Liberty (Definitive ed.). The University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0-226-31539-3.
  22. ^ Schrepel, Thibault (January 2015). "Friedrich Hayek's Contribution to Antitrust Law and Its Modern Application". ICC Global Antitrust Review: 199–216. SSRN 2548420.
  23. ^ Ormerod, Paul (2006). "The fading of Friedman". prospectmagazine.co.uk. Retrieved 31 August 2019.
  24. ^ a b Catlin, George (1944). "The Road to Serfdom". Nature. 154 (3911): 473–474. Bibcode:1944Natur.154..473C. doi:10.1038/154473a0. S2CID 4071358.
  25. ^ a b "No. 49768". The London Gazette (Supplement). 16 June 1984. p. 4.
  26. ^ a b c d Ebenstein 2001, p. 305.
  27. ^ . Archived from the original on 25 February 2014. Retrieved 30 April 2013.
  28. ^ George H.W. Bush (18 November 1991). "Remarks on Presenting the Presidential Medal of Freedom Awards".
  29. ^ a b Arrow, Kenneth J.; Bernheim, B. Douglas; Feldstein, Martin S.; McFadden, Daniel L.; Poterba, James M.; Solow, Robert M. (2011). "100 Years of the American Economic Review: The Top 20 Articles". American Economic Review. 101 (1): 1–8. doi:10.1257/aer.101.1.1. hdl:1721.1/114169.
  30. ^ Alan Ebenstein (2003). Friedrich Hayek: A Biography. p. 12.
  31. ^ Caldwell Bruce; Klausinger, Hansjörg (2021). "F. A. Hayek's genealogy" (PDF). Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE). CHOPE Working Paper (2021–06). Durham, NC. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3844091.
  32. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 12, 312.
  33. ^ a b Ebenstein 2001, pp. 62, 248, 284.
  34. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 7.
  35. ^ Ebenstein 2001, pp. 7–8.
  36. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 20.
  37. ^ Note: Von Juraschek was a statistician and was later employed by the Austrian government.
  38. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 8.
  39. ^ Janik, Allan. Family Relationships and Family Resemblances: Hayek and Wittgenstein.
  40. ^ Erbacher, Christian. Friedrich August von Hayek's Draft Biography of Ludwig Wittgenstein.
  41. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 245.
  42. ^ Hayek on Hayek: an autobiographical dialogue, By Friedrich August Hayek, Routledge, 1994, p. 51
  43. ^ Young Ludwig: Wittgenstein's life, 1889–1921, Brian McGuinness, Oxford University Press, 2005 p. xii
  44. ^ Hayek on Hayek: an autobiographical dialogue, By Friedrich August Hayek, Routledge, 1995, p. 53.
  45. ^ a b Ebenstein 2001, p. 9.
  46. ^ a b Ebenstein 2001, p. 14.
  47. ^ a b c Ebenstein 2001, p. 13.
  48. ^ a b "UCLA Oral History 1978 Interviews with Friedrich Hayek, pp. 32–38". 10 March 2001. Retrieved 14 September 2011.
  49. ^ Kresge, Stephen; Wenar, Leif (2005). Hayek on Hayek: An Autobiographical Dialogue. Routledge. p. 39. ISBN 978-0226320625.
  50. ^ Friedrich August von Hayek, link
  51. ^ David Gordon (8 May 2009). "Friedrich Hayek as a Teacher".
  52. ^ Adam James Tebble, F.A. Hayek (Continuum, 2010), p. 2, ISBN 978-0826435996
  53. ^ Deirdre N. McCloskey (2000). How to Be Human: Though an Economist. U of Michigan Press. p. 33. ISBN 978-0472067442.
  54. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 28.
  55. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 22.
  56. ^ a b Some Reflection on Hayek's The Sensory Order, Caldwell, 2004
  57. ^ a b The Sensory Order (1952) on learning
    • Backhaus, Jurgen G. (2005). Entrepreneurship, Money and Coordination: Hayek's Theory of Cultural Evolution. Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 48. ISBN 978-1845427955.
    • Richard Arena; Agnès Festré; Nathalie Lazaric, eds. (2012). Handbook of Knowledge and Economics. Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 133. ISBN 978-1781001028.
  58. ^ kanopiadmin (30 July 2014). "The Viennese Connection: Alfred Schutz and the Austrian School". Mises Institute. Retrieved 2 January 2019.
  59. ^ a b French, Douglas (2013), Leeson, Robert (ed.), "Hayek and Mises", Hayek: A Collaborative Biography: Part 1 Influences, from Mises to Bartley, Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics Series, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 80–92, doi:10.1057/9781137328564_6, ISBN 978-1137328564, retrieved 28 April 2021
  60. ^ A. J. Tebble, F.A. Hayek, Continuum International Publishing Group, 2010, pp. 4–5
  61. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 33.
  62. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 35.
  63. ^ a b Leeson, Robert (2018). Hayek: A Collaborative Biography.
  64. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 23.
  65. ^ Federici, Michael. Eric Voegelin: The Restoration of Order, ISI Books, 2002, p. 1
  66. ^ a b . 23 January 2013. Archived from the original on 23 January 2013. Retrieved 28 April 2021.
  67. ^ Baxendale, Toby (25 October 2010). "The Battle of the Letters: Keynes v Hayek 1932, Skidelsky v Besley 2010". The Cobden Centre. Retrieved 14 September 2011.
  68. ^ "Info" (PDF). thinkmarkets.files.wordpress.com. 2010.
  69. ^ Malcolm Perrine McNair, Richard Stockton Meriam, Problems in business economics, McGraw-Hill, 1941, p. 504
  70. ^ Hayek (1945). Reader's Digest Road to Serfdom. Reader's Digest.
  71. ^ Keynes v Hayek: Two economic giants go head to head Business–BBC News, 2 August 2011.
  72. ^ Galbraith, J.K. (1991). "Nicholas Kaldor Remembered". Nicholas Kaldor and Mainstream Economics: Confrontation or Convergence?. New York: St. Martin's Press. ISBN 978-0312053567.
  73. ^ "Sir Arthur Lewis Autobiography". Nobelprize.org. Retrieved 14 September 2011.
  74. ^ . Archived from the original on 6 July 2009.
  75. ^ "No. 34541". The London Gazette. 12 August 1938. p. 5182.
  76. ^ a b Brittan, Samuel (2004). "Hayek, Friedrich August (1899–1992)". Oxford Dictionary of National Biography (online ed.). Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/ref:odnb/51095. (Subscription or UK public library membership required.)
  77. ^ "Election of Fellows, 1947". Econometrica. 16 (1): 117–122. January 1948. JSTOR 1914293.
  78. ^ kanopiadmin (18 August 2014). "The Road to Serfdom". Mises Institute. Retrieved 28 April 2021.
  79. ^ Ebenstein, p. 116.
  80. ^ Ebenstein, p. 128.
  81. ^ A.J. Tebble, F.A. Hayek, Continuum International Publishing Group, 2010, p. 8
  82. ^ Beam, Christopher (3 January 2011). "The Trouble With Liberty". New York Magazine. New York Media, LLC. Retrieved 7 November 2015.
  83. ^ a b Mitch, David (2015), Leeson, Robert (ed.), "Morality versus Money: Hayek's Move to the University of Chicago", Hayek: A Collaborative Biography: Part IV, England, the Ordinal Revolution and the Road to Serfdom, 1931–50, Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 215–255, doi:10.1057/9781137452603_7, ISBN 978-1137452603, retrieved 28 April 2021
  84. ^ Compton, John (2020). The End of Empathy. Oxford University Press.
  85. ^ Milton and Rose Friedman, Two Lucky People: Memoirs (Chicago: U. of Chicago Press, 1998)
  86. ^ Ross B. Emmett (2010). The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics. Edward Elgar Publishing. pp. 164, 200, 266–267. ISBN 978-1849806664.
  87. ^ Friedman, Milton (1951). "Neo-Liberalism and its Prospects". Farmand: 89–93.
  88. ^ Johan Van Overtveldt, The Chicago School: How the University of Chicago Assembled the Thinkers Who Revolutionized Economics and Business (2006) pp. 7, 341–46
  89. ^ a b Ebenstein 2001, p. 270.
  90. ^ Van Horn, Robert (2015), Leeson, Robert (ed.), "Hayek and the Chicago School", Hayek: A Collaborative Biography: Part V Hayek's Great Society of Free Men, Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 91–111, doi:10.1057/9781137478245_3, ISBN 978-1137478245, retrieved 28 April 2021
  91. ^ a b Ebenstein 2001, p. 267.
  92. ^ "John Simon Guggenheim Foundation | Friedrich August von Hayek". Retrieved 28 April 2021.
  93. ^ Biography 17 July 2012 at the Wayback Machine at LibertyStory.net
  94. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 253.
  95. ^ Ebenstein, p. 195.
  96. ^ a b F.A. Hayek, The Constitution of Liberty (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1960)
  97. ^ Ebenstein, p. 203.
  98. ^ F.A. Hayek, on the Occasion of the Centenary of His Birth, Ronald Hamowy, Cato Institute
  99. ^ a b Ebenstein 2001, p. 209.
  100. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 218.
  101. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 209-210.
  102. ^ Ebenstein, p. 218.
  103. ^ a b Caldwell, Bruce; Montes, Leonidas (26 September 2014). "Friedrich Hayek and his visits to Chile" (PDF). The Review of Austrian Economics. 28 (3): 261–309. doi:10.1007/s11138-014-0290-8. S2CID 189953475.
  104. ^ Ebenstein, p. 254.
  105. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 251-253.
  106. ^ a b c "The Prize in Economics 1974". Nobelprize.org. 9 October 1974. Retrieved 14 September 2011.
  107. ^ a b Ebenstein, p. 263.
  108. ^ Leeson, Robert (1975). Gold & Silver Newsletter. Springer. ISBN 978-3319952192.
  109. ^ Klausinger, H. (2010). "Hayek on Practical Business Cycle Research A Note". In H. Hagemann; T. Nishizawa; Y. Ikeda (eds.). Austrian Economics in Transition: From Carl Menger to Friedrich Hayek.
  110. ^ Klausinger, H. (2012), "Editorial Notes", The Collected Works of F. A. Hayek, by F. A. Hayek, Klausinger, H. (ed.), vol. VII: Business Cycles
  111. ^ "Translation of Quote in the blog: "Hayek and the Stock Market Crash of 1929: So Much for His Predictive Powers"". 18 December 2011.
  112. ^ Hayek, Friedrich August (26 October 1929), Monatsberichte des Österreichen Institutes für Konjunkturforschung (PDF), p. 182
  113. ^ "The Road from Serfdom: An Interview with F.A. Hayek". Reason.com. 1 July 1992. Retrieved 28 April 2021.
  114. ^ "Friedrich August von Hayek – Banquet Speech". Nobelprize.org. 10 December 1974. Retrieved 14 September 2011.
  115. ^ Ebenstein, p. 261.
  116. ^ Richard Cockett, Thinking the Unthinkable. Think-Tanks and the Economic Counter-Revolution, 1931–1983 (Fontana, 1995), pp. 174–76.
  117. ^ John Ranelagh, Thatcher's People: An Insider's Account of the Politics, the Power, and the Personalities (Fontana, 1992), p. ix.
  118. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 291-292.
  119. ^ a b c Ebenstein 2001, p. 293.
  120. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 294.
  121. ^ "Letters to the Editor: Liberal pact with Labour", The Times (31 March 1977), p. 15.
  122. ^ "Letters to the Editor: Liberal pact with Labour", The Times (2 April 1977), p. 15.
  123. ^ "Letters to the Editor: German socialist aims", The Times (13 April 1977), p. 13.
  124. ^ "Letters to the Editor: The dangers to personal liberty", The Times (11 July 1978), p. 15.
  125. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 300-301.
  126. ^ Martin Anderson, "Revolution" (Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1988), p. 164
  127. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 207-208.
  128. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 301.
  129. ^ a b Nasar, Sylvia (19 November 1991). "Business Profile; Neglected Economist Honored by President". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 27 April 2021.
  130. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 317.
  131. ^ . NYU Journal of Law & Liberty. Archived from the original on 17 May 2014. Retrieved 15 May 2014.
  132. ^ Mises, Ludwig (1912). Theory of Money and Credit.
  133. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1931). Prices and Production.
  134. ^ The Austrian Theory of Business Cycles: Old Lessons For Modern Economic Policy?, Oppers, International Monetary Fund
  135. ^ a b Hayek, Friedrich (2012). Good Money: Part 2. University of Chicago Press. p. 202. ISBN 978-0226321196.
  136. ^ See the chapter "The collaboration with Keynes and the controversy with Hayek,", Heinz D. Kurz and Neri Salvadori, "Piero Sraffa's contributions to economics," in Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa's Legacy in Economics, ed. H.D. Kurz, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000), pp. 3–24. ISBN 978-0521580892
  137. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1989). The Collected Works of F.A. Hayek. University of Chicago Press. p. 202. ISBN 978-0226320977.
  138. ^ a b White, Lawrence H. (2008). "Did Hayek and Robbins Deepen the Great Depression?". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 40 (4). Wiley-Blackwell: 751–768. doi:10.1111/j.1538-4616.2008.00134.x. JSTOR 25096276.
  139. ^ a b c Nicholas Kaldor (1942). "Professor Hayek and the Concertina-Effect". Economica. 9 (36): 359–382. doi:10.2307/2550326. JSTOR 2550326.
  140. ^ F.A. Hayek, "Reflection on the pure theory of money of Mr. J.M. Keynes," Economica, 11, S. 270–95 (1931).
  141. ^ F.A. Hayek, Prices and Production 12 August 2014 at the Wayback Machine, (London: Routledge, 1931).
  142. ^ P. Sraffa, "Dr. Hayek on Money and Capital," Economic Journal, 42, S. 42–53 (1932).
  143. ^ Bruce Caldwell, Hayek's Challenge: An Intellectual Biography of F.A. Hayek (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2004), p. 179. ISBN 0226091937
  144. ^ Nicholas Kaldor (1939). "Capital Intensity and the Trade Cycle". Economica. 6 (21): 40–66. doi:10.2307/2549077. JSTOR 2549077.
  145. ^ a b R. W. Garrison, "F.A. Hayek as 'Mr. Fluctooations:' In Defense of Hayek's 'Technical Economics'", Hayek Society Journal (LSE), 5(2), 1 (2003).
  146. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1941). Pure Theory of Capital.
  147. ^ Hayek and Friedman: Head to Head, Garrison, Auburn University
  148. ^ Mises, Ludwig. Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth.
  149. ^ a b Hayek, Friedrich (1935). Collectivist Economic Planning. G. Routledge. ISBN 978-1610161626.
  150. ^ Lange, O 1967 The Computer and the Market in Socialism
  151. ^ Lange, 1938, On the Economic Theory of Socialism, University of Minnesota Press
  152. ^ Milton Friedman, 'Lange on Price Flexibility and Employment', Essays in Positive Economics.
  153. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1937). Economics and Knowledge.
  154. ^ Hein Schreuder, "Coase, Hayek and Hierarchy", In: S. Lindenberg et Hein Schreuder, dir., Interdisciplinary Perspectives on Organization Studies, Pergamon Press
  155. ^ Douma, Sytse and Hein Schreuder, 2013. "Economic Approaches to Organizations". 5th edition. London: Pearson, ISBN 978-0273735298
  156. ^ The Pure Theory of Capital (pdf), Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1941/2007 (Vol. 12 of the Collected Works): p. 90.
  157. ^ a b Caldwell, Bruce. "Hayek, Friedrich August von (1899–1992)." The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Third Edition. Eds. Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume. Palgrave Macmillan, 2018.
  158. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1952). The Counter-Revolution of Science.
  159. ^ Röpke, Wilhelm. The Moral Foundations of Civil Society. Transaction Publishers. ISBN 978-1412837859 – via Google Books.
  160. ^ Gerald Edelman, Neural Darwinism, 1987, p. 25
  161. ^ Joaquin Fuster, Memory in the Cerebral Cortex: An Empirical Approach to Neural Networks in the Human and Nonhuman Primate. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1995, pp. 87–88
  162. ^ Joaquin Fuster, "Network Memory", Trends in Neurosciences, 1997. Vol. 20, No. 10. (Oct.): 451–459.
  163. ^ van de Haar, Edwin. ""Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek: Federation as Last Resort"" (PDF). Cosmos + Taxis: Studies in Emergent Order. Retrieved 14 October 2022.
  164. ^ Hayek, Friedrich. The Road to Serfdom. The Collected Works of F. A. Hayek. University of Chicago Press. Retrieved 14 October 2022.
  165. ^ Rosenboim, Or (2014). ""Barbara Wootton, Friedrich Hayek and the debate on democratic federalism in the 1940s"". The International History Review. 36 (5): 894–918. doi:10.1080/07075332.2013.871320. JSTOR 24703266. S2CID 154887466. Retrieved 14 October 2022.
  166. ^ van de Haar, Edwin. ""Hayekian Spontaneous Order and the International Balance of Power"" (PDF). The Independent Review. Retrieved 14 October 2022.
  167. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (17 April 2017). "The Economic Conditions of Interstate Federalism". Foundation for Economic Education (originally published in New Commonwealth Quarterly, V, No. 2 (September, 1939), 131–49). Retrieved 14 October 2022.
  168. ^ Nientiedt, Daniel. ""F. A. Hayek and the World of Tomorrow: The Principles of International Federalism"" (PDF). Cosmos + Taxis: Studies in Emergent Order. Retrieved 14 October 2022.
  169. ^ Masini, Fabio. ""Hayek's Federalism and the Making of European Integration"" (PDF). Cosmos + Taxis: Studies in Emergent Order. Retrieved 14 October 2022.
  170. ^ Christensen, Brandon. ""Reviving the Libertarian Interstate Federalist Tradition: The American Proposal"" (PDF). The Independent Review. Retrieved 14 October 2022.
  171. ^ Spieker, Jorg (2014). ""F.A. Hayek and the Reinvention of Liberal Internationalism"". The International History Review. 36 (5): 919–942. doi:10.1080/07075332.2014.900814. S2CID 143713445. Retrieved 14 October 2022.
  172. ^ a b Hayek, Friedrich August (1980). Individualism and economic order (Reprint ed.). Chicago London: the University of Chicago press. ISBN 0-226-32093-6.
  173. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. von (2011). The constitution of liberty: the definitive edition. Chicago, Ill.: Univ. of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0-226-31539-3.
  174. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. von (2012). Law, legislation and liberty: a new statement of the liberal principles of justice and political economy. London (u.a.): Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-52229-8.
  175. ^ Ferguson, Adam (1767). An Essay on the History of Civil Society. Project Gutenberg: T. Cadell, London. p. 205.
  176. ^ Ebeling, Richard M. (6 January 2018). "Price Is the Only Language that Everyone Speaks | Richard M. Ebeling". fee.org. Retrieved 28 April 2021.
  177. ^ a b Hayek, Friedrich (1988). The Fatal Conceit.
  178. ^ de Benoist, Alain (1998). "Hayek: A Critique". Telos. 1998 (110): 71–104. doi:10.3817/1298110071. S2CID 219203705.
  179. ^ Lamey, Andy (24 September 2014). "Ecosystems as Spontaneous Orders". SSRN 2501745.
  180. ^ Lamey, Andy (24 September 2014). "Ecosystems as Spontaneous Orders". pp. 2–11. SSRN 2501745.
  181. ^ Lamey, Andy (24 September 2014). "Ecosystems as Spontaneous Orders". pp. 12–13. SSRN 2501745.
  182. ^ (PDF). Fraser Institute. Archived from the original (PDF) on 28 April 2021. Retrieved 28 April 2021.
  183. ^ Chang, Ha-Joon (2014). "4". Economics: The User's Guide. London: Penguin Books Limited. ISBN 978-0718197032.
  184. ^ Hayek, F.A. The Road to Serfdom, Ch. 9
  185. ^ Stringham, Edward; Zywicki, Todd (20 January 2011). "Hayekian Anarchism". SSRN 1744364.
  186. ^ "Hayek on Social Insurance". The Washington Post.
  187. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1976). The Denationalization of Money.
  188. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (2011) [1960]. Hamowy, Ronald (ed.). The Constitution of Liberty (Definitive ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. p. 405. ISBN 978-0-226-31539-3.
  189. ^ Wapshott, Nicholas (2011), Keynes Hayek: The Clash That Defined Modern Economics, New York: W.W. Norton & Company, p. 291
  190. ^ Harcourt, Bernard (12 September 2012). "How Paul Ryan enslaves Friedrich Hayek's The Road to Serfdom". The Guardian. Retrieved 27 December 2014.
  191. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (2007) [1944]. Caldwell, Bruce (ed.). The Road to Serfdom (Definitive ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. pp. 147–148. ISBN 978-0226320557.
  192. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1976). Law, Legislation and Liberty. Vol. 2. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. p. 87. ISBN 978-0226320830.
  193. ^ Tebble, Adam James (2009). "Hayek and social justice: a critique". Critical Review of International Social and Political Philosophy. 12 (4): 581–604. doi:10.1080/13698230903471343. S2CID 145380847.
  194. ^ The Mirage of Social Justice, chap. 10
  195. ^ a b The Mirage of Social Justice, chap. 12
  196. ^ The Constitution of Liberty, chap. 6
  197. ^ Diamond, Arthur M. (Fall 1980). "F.A. Hayek on Constructivism and Ethics". The Journal of Libertarian Studies. IV/4: 353–365.
  198. ^ Kukathas, Chandran (1990). Hayek and Modern Liberalism. Oxford University Press. p. 215.
  199. ^ N.P. Barry(1994), "The road to freedom – Hayek's social and economic philosophy," in Birner, J., and van Zijp, R. (eds) Hayek, Co-ordination and Evolution – His Legacy in Philosophy, Politics, Economics and the History of Ideas, pp. 141–163. London: Routledge.
  200. ^ Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz, "Has Government Any Role in Money?" (1986)
  201. ^ John Gray, "The Friedrich Hayek I knew, and what he got right – and wrong" (30 July 2015)
  202. ^ Bruce Caldwell, Hayek's Challenge: An Intellectual Biography of F.A. Hayek (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2004), pp. 347–348
  203. ^ a b Farrant, Andrew; McPhail, Edward; Berger, Sebastian (2012). "Preventing the "Abuses" of Democracy: Hayek, the "Military Usurper" and Transitional Dictatorship in Chile?". American Journal of Economics and Sociology. 71 (3): 513–538. doi:10.1111/j.1536-7150.2012.00824.x.
  204. ^ Greg Grandin, professor of history, New York University, Empire's Workshop: Latin America, the United States, and the Rise of the New Imperialism, pp. 172–173, Metropolitan, 2006, ISBN 0805077383.
  205. ^ Dan Avnôn, Liberalism and its Practice, p. 56, Routledge, 1999, ISBN 0415193540.
  206. ^ "Preventing the "Abuses" of Democracy: Hayek, the "Military Usurper" and Transitional Dictatorship in Chile?" (PDF). The American Journal of Economics and Sociology.
  207. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1979) Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume 3: The Political Order of a Free People. Routledge 1982. p. 195
  208. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1979) Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume 3: The Political Order of a Free People. Routledge 1982. p. 56
  209. ^ a b Hayek, Friedrich (1976) Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume 2: The Mirage of Social Justice. Routledge 1982. p 58)
  210. ^ a b Ebenstein 2001, p. 390.
  211. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 295.
  212. ^ Leeson, Robert (2015) Hayek: A Collaborative Biography: Part II, Austria, America and the Rise of Hitler, 1899–1933. Palgrave Macmillan, 2015. p. 112
  213. ^ a b Leeson, Robert (2018) Hayek: A Collaborative Biography: Part XV: The Chicago School of Economics, Hayek's 'Luck' and the 1974 Nobel Prize for Economic Science. Palgrave Macmillan, 2015. p. 175
  214. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 299.
  215. ^ Leeson, Robert (2015) Hayek: A Collaborative Biography: Part II, Austria, America and the Rise of Hitler, 1899–1933. Palgrave Macmillan, 2015. p. 85
  216. ^ Slobodian, Quinn (2018) Globalists: The End of Empire and the Birth of Neoliberalism. Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, p. 154
  217. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1960) The Constitution of Liberty. Routledge, 2006. p. 76
  218. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1960) The Constitution of Liberty. Routledge, 2006. p. 109
  219. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1960) The Constitution of Liberty. Routledge, 2006. p. 111
  220. ^ a b Hayek, Friedrich (1960) The Constitution of Liberty. Routledge, 2006. p. 110
  221. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1960) The Constitution of Liberty. Routledge, 2006. p. 113
  222. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1960) The Constitution of Liberty. Routledge, 2006. p. 112
  223. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1960) The Constitution of Liberty. Routledge, 2006. p. 80
  224. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1960) The Constitution of Liberty. Routledge, 2006. p. 270
  225. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1960) The Constitution of Liberty. Routledge, 2006. p. 269
  226. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1960) The Constitution of Liberty. Routledge, 2006. p. 273
  227. ^ Tebble, Adam James (1 December 2009). "Hayek and social justice: a critique". Critical Review of International Social and Political Philosophy. 12 (4): 581–604. doi:10.1080/13698230903471343. ISSN 1369-8230. S2CID 145380847.
  228. ^ Fukuyama, Francis (6 May 2011). "Friedrich A. Hayek, Big-Government Skeptic". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 25 February 2023.
  229. ^ Boettke, Peter J. (1995). "Hayek's the Road to Serfdom Revisited: Government Failure in the Argument against Socialism". Eastern Economic Journal. 21 (1): 7–26. ISSN 0094-5056. JSTOR 40325611.
  230. ^ Skarbek, David (2009). "F.A. Hayek's Influence on Nobel Prize Winners". Review of Austrian Economics. 22 (1): 109–112. doi:10.1007/s11138-008-0069-x. S2CID 144970753.
  231. ^ Smith
    • Smith, Vernon (1999). "Reflections on Human Action after 50 years" (PDF). Cato Journal. 19 (2). Hayek, in my view, is the leading economic thinker of the 20th century.
    Simon
    • Simon, Herbert (1981). The Sciences of the Artificial (2nd ed.). Cambridge: The MIT Press. No one has characterized market mechanisms better than Friedrich von Hayek: 41 
  232. ^ Samuelson, Paul A (2009). "A few remembrances of Friedrich von Hayek (1899–1992)". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 69: 1–4. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2008.07.001.
  233. ^ The collected scientific papers of Paul A. Samuelson, Volume 5, p. 315.
  234. ^ Fritz Machlup, Essays on Hayek, Routledge, 2003. p. 14.
  235. ^ Sylvia Nasar, Grand Pursuit: The Story of Economic Genius, Simon and Schuster, 2011, p. 402
  236. ^ Lawrence Summers, quoted in The Commanding Heights: The Battle Between Government and the Marketplace that Is Remaking the Modern World, by Daniel Yergin and Joseph Stanislaw. New York: Simon & Schuster. 1998, pp. 150–151.
  237. ^ (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 18 January 2012. Retrieved 5 May 2012.
  238. ^ See Hacohen, 2000.
  239. ^ See Weimer and Palermo, 1982
  240. ^ See Birner, 2001, and for the mutual influence they had on each other's ideas on evolution, Birner 2009
  241. ^ Milton & Rose Friedman, Two Lucky People: Memoirs (U. of Chicago Press), 1998. p. 333
  242. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 266.
  243. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 271.
  244. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 272.
  245. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 81.
  246. ^ e.g., Wolin 2004
  247. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 275.
  248. ^ Berliner, M.S. (ed.), Letters of Ayn Rand. New York, Dutton, 1995. p 299
  249. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 274.
  250. ^ "Wikipedia's Model Follows Hayek". The Wall Street Journal. 15 April 2009.
  251. ^ Phaneuf, Emile. "Hayek and Bitcoin | AIER". www.aier.org. Retrieved 28 March 2024.
  252. ^ Pollock, Alex J. (30 March 2022). "Are Cryptocurrencies the Great Hayekian Escape? – Alex J. Pollock". Law & Liberty. Retrieved 28 March 2024.
  253. ^ Kenneth R. Hoover, Economics as Ideology: Keynes, Laski, Hayek, and the Creation of Contemporary Politics (2003), p. 213
  254. ^ Söderbaum, Jakob E:son (2020). Modern konservatism: Filosofi, bärande idéer och inriktningar i Burkes efterföljd. Borås: Recito. pp. 38, 116–117, 269. ISBN 978-91-7765-497-1.
  255. ^ Fawcett, Edmund (2018). Liberalism: The Life of an Idea (2 ed.). Princeton University Press. p. 327. ISBN 9780691180380.
  256. ^ Hazlett, Thomas W. (1 September 1979). "F. A. Hayek: Classical Liberal | Thomas W. Hazlett". fee.org. Retrieved 28 April 2021.
  257. ^ Bogus, Carl (2011). Buckley. Bloomsbury Publishing USA. ISBN 978-1608193554.
  258. ^ E.H.H. Green, Ideologies of Conservatism. Conservative Political Ideas in the Twentieth Century (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2004), p. 259.
  259. ^ a b Samuel Brittan, "The many faces of liberalism," ft.com, 22 January 2010
  260. ^ . Archived from the original on 14 February 2016. Retrieved 28 April 2021.
  261. ^ Hoerber, Thomas (2019), Hoerber, Thomas; Anquetil, Alain (eds.), "The Roots of Neoliberalism in Friedrich von Hayek", Economic Theory and Globalization, Cham: Springer International Publishing, pp. 169–194, doi:10.1007/978-3-030-23824-7_8, ISBN 978-3030238247, S2CID 202307278, retrieved 28 April 2021
  262. ^ Boettke, Peter J. (2002). Why Perestroika Failed: The Politics and Economics of Socialist Transformation. Routledge. ISBN 978-1134886319. Retrieved 2 January 2019.
  263. ^ McKinnon, Ronald (1992). "Spontaneous Order on the Road Back from Socialism: An Asian Perspective". American Economic Review. 82 (2). American Economic Association: 31–36. JSTOR 2117371.
  264. ^ Easterly, William (2006). The White Man's Burden: Why the West's Efforts to Aid the Rest Have Done So Much Ill and So Little Good. Penguin Books. ISBN 978-1101218129.
  265. ^ White, William R. (2009). "Modern Macroeconomics is on the Wrong Track" (PDF). Finance & Development. International Monetary Fund.
  266. ^ Hoffmann, Andreas; Schnabl, Gunther (2011). "A Vicious Cycle of Manias, Crises and Asymmetric Policy Responses – An Overinvestment View". The World Economy. 34 (3). Wiley: 382–403. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9701.2011.01334.x. S2CID 153097003. SSRN 1513171.
  267. ^ Schnabl, Gunther; Hoffmann, Andreas (2008). "Monetary Policy, Vagabonding Liquidity and Bursting Bubbles in New and Emerging Markets – An Overinvestment View" (PDF). The World Economy. 31 (9). Wiley: 1226–1252. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9701.2008.01126.x. S2CID 154603748. SSRN 1018342.
  268. ^ Cachanosky, Nicolas (2014). "The Effects of U.S. Monetary Policy in Colombia and Panama (2002–2007)". The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance. Vol. 54, no. 3. Elsevier. pp. 428–436. SSRN 2170566.
  269. ^ Brunnermeier, Markus K.; Schnabel, Isabel (9 June 2016). "12. Bubbles and Central Banks: Historical Perspectives". In Bordo, Michael D.; Eitrheim, Øyvind; Flandreau, Marc; Qvigstad, Jan F. (eds.). Central Banks at a Crossroads: What Can We Learn from History?. New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-1107149663.
  270. ^ Taylor, John B. (2007). Housing and Monetary Policy (PDF) (Report). NBER Working Papers. Vol. 13682. National Bureau of Economic Research.
  271. ^ "Lawrence H. White on Monetary Policy, Free Banking and the Financial Crisis | Mercatus". mercatus.org. 13 December 2011. Retrieved 19 September 2016.
  272. ^ Sumner, Scott B. (2014). "Nominal GDP Targeting: A Simple Rule to Improve Fed Performance" (PDF). Cato Journal. Vol. 34, no. 2. Cato Institute. pp. 315–337. Retrieved 24 July 2019.
  273. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (2008). Salerno, Joseph T. (ed.). (PDF). Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute. p. 297. ISBN 978-1933550220. Archived from the original (PDF) on 31 July 2020. Retrieved 24 July 2019.
  274. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (9 April 1975). "A Discussion with Friedrich A. von Hayek" (PDF) (Interview). Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute. pp. 12–13. ISBN 0844731900.
  275. ^ Hoffmann, Andreas; Schnabl, Gunther (2016). "Adverse Effects of Unconventional Monetary Policy" (PDF). Cato Journal. 36 (3). Cato Institute.
  276. ^ "Transcript for: Friedrich Hayek". pbs.org. Retrieved 14 February 2015.
  277. ^ Andrzy Walicki, "Liberalism in Poland", Critical Review, Winter, 1988, p. 9.
  278. ^ Dick Armey, "Address at the Dedication of the Hayek Auditorium", Cato Institute, Washington, DC, 9 May 1995.
  279. ^ Vaclav Klaus, "No Third Way Out: Creating a Capitalist Czechoslovakia", Reason, 1990, (June): 28–31.
  280. ^ Ebenstein, p. 44.
  281. ^ a b Ebenstein 2001, p. 169.
  282. ^ Ebenstein, p. 169.
  283. ^ a b Ebenstein, p. 155.
  284. ^ . The Hayek Interviews. Event occurs at 48:50. Archived from the original on 31 August 2021. Retrieved 31 August 2021.
  285. ^ a b Ebenstein 2001, p. 297.
  286. ^ "Laurence Hayek". The Independent. 7 September 2004.
  287. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 316.
  288. ^ Beck, Naomi (December 2009). "In Search of the Proper Scientific Approach: Hayek's Views on Biology, Methodology, and the Nature of Economics". Science in Context. 22 (4): 567–585. doi:10.1017/S0269889709990160. ISSN 1474-0664. PMID 20509429. S2CID 46364934.
  289. ^ Ebenstein 2001, p. 225.
  290. ^ . 22 June 2008. Archived from the original on 22 June 2008. Retrieved 1 June 2022.
  291. ^ "Hayek". www.lsesu.com.
  292. ^ Ellis, Lydia. . Oxford Hayek Society. Archived from the original on 4 March 2016. Retrieved 6 November 2015.
  293. ^ "Housing Crisis: Should Urban Areas Grow Up or Grow Out to Keep Housing Affordable?". Cato Institute. 29 November 2016. Retrieved 27 April 2021.
  294. ^ . Theihs.org. Archived from the original on 16 July 2009. Retrieved 14 September 2011.
  295. ^ "Economics | F.A. Hayek Essay Awards". Economics. Retrieved 27 April 2021.
  296. ^ "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1974". NobelPrize.org. Retrieved 27 April 2021.
  297. ^ . Hayekfund.com. Archived from the original on 20 September 2011. Retrieved 14 September 2011.
  298. ^ "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1974". NobelPrize.org. Retrieved 27 April 2021.
  299. ^ "Friedrich August von Hayek | Orden Pour le Mérite". www.orden-pourlemerite.de. Retrieved 27 April 2021.
  300. ^ "Companion of Honour, 1984, Awarded by Queen Elizabeth II".
  301. ^ "Reply to a parliamentary question" (PDF) (in German). p. 885. Retrieved 24 February 2013.
  302. ^ "F. A. Hayek Scholarship in Political Science or Economics" (PDF).
  303. ^ Hayek, F.A. (1978). Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume. University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0226320861. Retrieved 14 September 2011 – via Google Books.
  304. ^ Hayek, F.A. (1978). Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume. University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0226320830. Retrieved 14 September 2011 – via Google Books.
  305. ^ Hayek, F.A. (1981). Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume 3: The Political Order of a Free People. University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0226320908.
  306. ^ Alan Ebenstein: Investigation: The Fatal Deceit 12 February 2008 at the Wayback Machine. Liberty 19:3 (March 2005)
  307. ^ Ian Jarvie (Editor), Karl Milford (Editor), David Miller (Editor) (2006), Karl Popper: a Centenary Assessment Vol. 1: Life and Times, and Values in a World of Facts, pp. 120, 295, ISBN 978-0754653752

Bibliography edit

  • Birner, Jack (2001). "The mind-body problem and social evolution," CEEL Working Paper 1-02.
  • Birner, Jack, and Rudy van Zijp, eds. (1994). Hayek: Co-ordination and Evolution: His legacy in philosophy, politics, economics and the history of ideas[ISBN missing]
  • Birner, Jack (2009). "From group selection to ecological niches. Popper's rethinking of evolutionary theory in the light of Hayek's theory of culture", in S. Parusnikova & R.S. Cohen eds. (Spring 2009). "Rethinking Popper", Boston Studies in the Philosophy of Science. Vol. 272
  • Boettke, Peter J. (1995). "Hayek's the Road to Serfdom Revisited: Government Failure in the Argument against Socialism". Eastern Economic Journal. 21 (1): 7–26. JSTOR 40325611.
  • Brittan, Samuel (2004). "Hayek, Friedrich August (1899–1992)". Oxford Dictionary of National Biography (online ed.). Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/ref:odnb/51095. (Subscription or UK public library membership required.)
  • Caldwell, Bruce (2005). Hayek's Challenge: An Intellectual Biography of F.A. Hayek[ISBN missing]
  • Caldwell, Bruce (1997). "Hayek and Socialism". Journal of Economic Literature. 35 (4): 1856–1890. JSTOR 2729881.
  • Cohen, Avi J. (2003). "The Hayek/Knight Capital Controversy: the Irrelevance of Roundaboutness, or Purging Processes in Time?" History of Political Economy 35(3): 469–490. ISSN 0018-2702 Fulltext: online in Project Muse, Swetswise and Ebsco
  • Clavé, Francis (2015). "Comparative Study of Lippmann's and Hayek's Liberalisms (or neo-liberalisms)". The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought. 22 (6): 978–999. doi:10.1080/09672567.2015.1093522. S2CID 146137987.
  • Doherty, Brian (2007). Radicals for Capitalism: A Freewheeling History of the Modern American Libertarian Movement[ISBN missing]
  • Douma, Sytse and Hein Schreuder, (2013). "Economic Approaches to Organizations". 5th edition. London: Pearson, ISBN 978-0273735298
  • Ebeling, Richard M. (March 2004). (The Freeman
  • Ebeling, Richard M. (March 2001). "F.A. Hayek: A Biography" Ludwig von Mises Institute
  • Ebeling, Richard M. (May 1999). "Friedrich A. Hayek: A Centenary Appreciation" The Freeman
  • Ebenstein, Alan (2001). Friedrich Hayek: A Biography. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan Trade. ISBN 978-0312233440.
  • Feldman, Jean-Philippe (1999). "Hayek's Critique of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights". Journal des Économistes et des Études Humaines. 9 (4): 1145–6396. doi:10.2202/1145-6396.1172.
  • Frowen, S. ed. (1997). Hayek: economist and social philosopher
  • Gamble, Andrew (1996). The Iron Cage of Liberty, an analysis of Hayek's ideas[ISBN missing]
  • Goldsworthy, J.D. (1986). "Hayek's Political and Legal Philosophy: An Introduction" [1986] SydLawRw 3; 11(1) Sydney Law Review 44
  • Gray, John (1998). Hayek on Liberty[ISBN missing]
  • Hacohen, Malach (2000). Karl Popper: The Formative Years, 1902–1945[ISBN missing]
  • Hamowy, Ronald (2008). "Hayek, Friedrich A. (1899–1992)". The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage; Cato Institute. pp. 218–220. doi:10.4135/9781412965811.n131. ISBN 978-1412965804. LCCN 2008009151. OCLC 750831024.
  • Horwitz, Steven (2005). "Friedrich Hayek, Austrian Economist". Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27(1): 71–85. ISSN 1042-7716 Fulltext: in Swetswise, Ingenta and Ebsco
  • Issing, O. (1999). Hayek, currency competition and European monetary union[ISBN missing]
  • Jones, Daniel Stedman. (2012) Masters of the Universe: Hayek, Friedman, and the Birth of Neoliberal Politics (Princeton University Press; 424 pages)
  • Kasper, Sherryl (2002). The Revival of Laissez-Faire in American Macroeconomic Theory: A Case Study of Its Pioneers. Chpt. 4
  • Kley, Roland (1994). Hayek's Social and Political Thought. Oxford Univ. Press.[ISBN missing]
  • Leeson, Robert, ed. Hayek: A Collaborative Biography, Part I: Influences, from Mises to Bartley (Palgrave MacMillan, 2013), 241 pages[ISBN missing]
  • Muller, Jerry Z. (2002). The Mind and the Market: Capitalism in Western Thought. Anchor Books.[ISBN missing]
  • Marsh, Leslie (Ed.) (2011). Hayek in Mind: Hayek's Philosophical Psychology. Advances in Austrian Economics. Emerald[ISBN missing]
  • O'Shea, Jerry (2020). 'Hayek's Spiritual Science', Modern Intellectual History, First View, pp. 1–26, doi:10.1017/S1479244320000517
  • Pavlík, Ján (2004). nb.vse.cz 16 February 2012 at the Wayback Machine. F.A. von Hayek and The Theory of Spontaneous Order. Professional Publishing 2004, Prague, profespubl.cz
  • Plant, Raymond (2009). The Neo-liberal State Oxford University Press, 312 pages[ISBN missing]
  • Pressman, Steven (2006). Fifty major economists (2nd ed.). London: Routledge.
  • Rosenof, Theodore (1974). "Freedom, Planning, and Totalitarianism: The Reception of F.A. Hayek's Road to Serfdom", Canadian Review of American Studies
  • Samuelson, Paul A. (2009). "A Few Remembrances of Friedrich von Hayek (1899–1992)", Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 69(1), pp. 1–4. Reprinted at J. Bradford DeLong <eblog
  • Samuelson, Richard A. (1999). "Reaction to the Road to Serfdom." Modern Age 41(4): 309–317. ISSN 0026-7457 Fulltext: in Ebsco
  • Schreuder, Hein (1993). "Coase, Hayek and Hierarchy", In: S. Lindenberg & Hein Schreuder, eds., Interdisciplinary Perspectives on Organization Studies, Oxford: Pergamon Press[ISBN missing]
  • Shearmur, Jeremy (1996). Hayek and after: Hayekian Liberalism as a Research Programme. Routledge.[ISBN missing]
  • Tebble, Adam James (2009). "Hayek and social justice: a critique". Critical Review of International Social and Political Philosophy. 12 (4): 581–604. doi:10.1080/13698230903471343. S2CID 145380847.
  • Tebble, Adam James (2013). F A Hayek. Bloomsbury Academic. ISBN 978-1441109064. OCLC 853506722
  • Touchie, John (2005). Hayek and Human Rights: Foundations for a Minimalist Approach to Law. Edward Elgar[ISBN missing]
  • Vanberg, V. (2001). "Hayek, Friedrich A von (1899–1992)," International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, pp. 6482–6486. doi:10.1016/B0-08-043076-7/00254-0
  • Vernon, Richard (1976). "The 'Great Society' and the 'Open Society': Liberalism in Hayek and Popper". Canadian Journal of Political Science. 9 (2): 261–276. doi:10.1017/s0008423900043717. S2CID 146616606.
  • Wapshott, Nicholas (2011). Keynes Hayek: The Clash That Defined Modern Economics, (W.W. Norton & Company) 382 pages ISBN 978-0393077483; covers the debate with Keynes in letters, articles, conversation, and by the two economists' disciples
  • Weimer, W., and Palermo, D., eds. (1982). Cognition and the Symbolic Processes. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. Contains Hayek's essay, "The Sensory Order after 25 Years" with "Discussion"
  • Wolin, Richard. (2004). The Seduction of Unreason: The Intellectual Romance with Fascism from Nietzsche to Postmodernism. Princeton University Press, Princeton.[ISBN missing]

Introductions edit

Primary sources edit

  • Hayek, Friedrich. The Collected Works of F.A. Hayek, ed. W.W. Bartley, III and others (University of Chicago Press, 1988–); "Plan of the Collected Works of F.A. Hayek" for 19 volumes; vol 2 excerpt and text search; vol 7 2012 excerpt.

External links edit

friedrich, hayek, friedrich, august, hayek, german, ˈfʁiːdʁɪç, ˈʔaʊɡʊst, fɔn, ˈhaɪɛk, 1899, march, 1992, often, referred, initials, hayek, austrian, british, polymath, whose, areas, interest, included, economics, political, philosophy, psychology, intellectual. Friedrich August von Hayek CH FBA ˈ h aɪ e k HY ek German ˈfʁiːdʁɪc ˈʔaʊɡʊst fɔn ˈhaɪɛk 8 May 1899 23 March 1992 often referred to by his initials F A Hayek was an Austrian British polymath whose areas of interest included economics political philosophy psychology and intellectual history 2 3 4 5 Hayek shared the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences with Gunnar Myrdal for work on money and economic fluctuations and the interdependence of economic social and institutional phenomena 6 His account of how prices communicate information is widely regarded as an important contribution to economics that led to him receiving the prize 7 8 9 Friedrich HayekCH FBABornFriedrich August von Hayek 1899 05 08 8 May 1899Vienna Cisleithania Austria HungaryDied23 March 1992 1992 03 23 aged 92 Freiburg im Breisgau Baden Wurttemberg GermanyCitizenshipAustrian 1899 1938 British 1938 1992 EducationUniversity of Vienna Dr jur 1921 Dr rer pol 1923 SpousesHelen Berta Maria von Fritsch m 1926 divorced wbr Helene Bitterlich m 1950 wbr ChildrenChristine Maria Felicitas von Hayek daughter Laurence Hayek son 1 Parent s August von Hayek father Felicitas von Juraschek mother RelativesGustav von Hayek grandfather Ludwig Wittgenstein cousin Academic careerInstitutionLondon School of Economics 1931 1950 University of Chicago 1950 1962 University of Freiburg 1962 1968 1978 1992 University of Salzburg 1969 1977 FieldEconomicsPolitical scienceJurisprudencePhilosophyPsychologySchool ortraditionAustrian SchoolInfluencesActon Belloc Bohm Bawerk Burke Darwin Eucken Ferguson Fetter Freud Gibbon Hume Jefferson Keynes Locke Mach Mandeville Marx Maistre Menger Mill Mises Nietzsche Paine Popper Rousseau Schmitt Sidney Smith Spann Tocqueville Tucker Twain Voltaire Wicksell Wieser WittgensteinContributionsEconomic calculation problemCatallaxyDispersed knowledgePrice signalSpontaneous orderAustrian Business Cycle TheoryHayek Hebb modelAwardsNobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences 1974 Member of the Order of the Companions of Honour 1984 Presidential Medal of Freedom 1991 Information at IDEAS RePEcSignature During his teenage years Hayek fought in World War I He later said this experience coupled with his desire to help avoid the mistakes that led to the war drew him into economics 10 11 He earned doctoral degrees in law in 1921 and political science in 1923 from the University of Vienna 10 12 He subsequently lived and worked in Austria Great Britain the United States and Germany He became a British citizen in 1938 13 His academic life was mostly spent at the London School of Economics later at the University of Chicago and the University of Freiburg He is widely considered a major contributor to the Austrian School of Economics 14 15 Hayek had considerable influence on a variety of political movements of the 20th century and his ideas continue to influence thinkers from a variety of political backgrounds today 16 17 18 Although sometimes described as a conservative 19 Hayek himself was uncomfortable with this label and preferred to be thought of as a classical liberal 20 21 As the co founder of the Mont Pelerin Society he contributed to the revival of classical liberalism in the post war era 22 His most popular work The Road to Serfdom has been republished many times over the eight decades since its original publication 23 24 Hayek was appointed a Member of the Order of the Companions of Honour in 1984 for his academic contributions to economics 25 26 He was the first recipient of the Hanns Martin Schleyer Prize in 1984 27 He also received the Presidential Medal of Freedom in 1991 from President George H W Bush 28 In 2011 his article The Use of Knowledge in Society was selected as one of the top 20 articles published in the American Economic Review during its first 100 years 29 Contents 1 Life 1 1 Early life 1 2 Education 1 3 London School of Economics 1 4 The Road to Serfdom 1 5 Chicago 1 6 Freiburg and Salzburg 1 7 Nobel Memorial Prize 1 8 British politics 1 9 Recognition 1 10 Death 2 Work and views 2 1 Business cycle 2 2 Economic calculation problem 2 3 Investment and choice 2 4 Philosophy of science 2 5 Psychology 2 6 International Relations 2 7 Social and political philosophy 2 7 1 Two traditions in the theory of liberty 2 7 2 Spontaneous order 2 7 3 Criticism of collectivism 2 7 4 Social safety nets 2 7 5 Criticism of social justice 2 7 6 Liberalism and skepticism 2 7 7 Dictatorship and totalitarianism 2 7 8 Immigration nationalism and race 2 7 9 Inequality and class 2 8 Criticism 3 Influence and recognition 3 1 Relation to conservatism 3 2 Policy discussions 3 3 Central European politics 4 Personal life 5 Legacy and honours 6 Notable works 7 See also 8 References 8 1 Bibliography 8 1 1 Introductions 8 2 Primary sources 9 External linksLife editEarly life edit Friedrich August von Hayek was born in Vienna to August von Hayek and Felicitas Hayek nee von Juraschek Both of his parents had Czech family surnames and Czech ancestry 30 31 The surname Hayek is the Germanized spelling of the Czech surname Hajek 26 Hayek traced his paternal Czech ancestry to an ancestor with the surname Hagek who came from Prague in the 1500s 32 His father born in 1871 also in Vienna was a medical doctor employed by the municipal ministry of health 33 August was a part time botany lecturer at the University of Vienna 6 Friedrich was the oldest of three brothers Heinrich 1900 1969 and Erich 1904 1986 who were one and a half and five years younger than he was 34 His father s career as a university professor influenced Hayek s goals later in life 35 Both of his grandfathers who lived long enough for Hayek to know them were scholars 36 Franz von Juraschek was a leading economist in Austria Hungary and a close friend of Eugen von Bohm Bawerk one of the founders of the Austrian School of Economics 37 Hayek s paternal grandfather Gustav Edler von Hayek taught natural sciences at the Imperial Realobergymnasium secondary school in Vienna He wrote works in the field of biological systematics some of which are relatively well known 38 On his mother s side Hayek was second cousin to the philosopher Ludwig Wittgenstein 39 His mother often played with Wittgenstein s sisters and had known him well As a result of their family relationship Hayek became one of the first to read Wittgenstein s Tractatus Logico Philosophicus when the book was published in its original German edition in 1921 40 Although he met Wittgenstein on only a few occasions Hayek said that Wittgenstein s philosophy and methods of analysis had a profound influence on his own life and thought 41 In his later years Hayek recalled a discussion of philosophy with Wittgenstein when both were officers during World War I 42 After Wittgenstein s death Hayek had intended to write a biography of Wittgenstein and worked on collecting family materials and later assisted biographers of Wittgenstein 43 He was related to Wittgenstein on the non Jewish side of the Wittgenstein family Since his youth Hayek frequently socialized with Jewish intellectuals and he mentions that people often speculated whether he was also of Jewish ancestry That made him curious so he spent some time researching his ancestors and found out that he had no Jewish ancestors within five generations 44 Hayek displayed an intellectual and academic bent from a very young age and read fluently and frequently before going to school 13 45 However he did quite poorly at school due to the lack of interest and problems with teachers 46 He was at the bottom of his class in most subjects and once received three failing grades in Latin Greek and mathematics 46 He was very interested in theater even attempting to write some tragedies and biology regularly helping his father with his botanical work 47 At his father s suggestion as a teenager he read the genetic and evolutionary works of Hugo de Vries and August Weismann and the philosophical works of Ludwig Feuerbach 48 He noted Goethe as the greatest early intellectual influence 47 In school Hayek was much taken by one instructor s lectures on Aristotle s ethics 49 In his unpublished autobiographical notes Hayek recalled a division between him and his younger brothers who were only a few years younger than him but he believed that they were somehow of a different generation He preferred to associate with adults 45 In 1917 Hayek joined an artillery regiment in the Austro Hungarian Army and fought on the Italian front 50 Hayek suffered damage to his hearing in his left ear during the war 51 and was decorated for bravery He also survived the 1918 flu pandemic 52 Hayek then decided to pursue an academic career determined to help avoid the mistakes that had led to the war Hayek said of his experience The decisive influence was really World War I It s bound to draw your attention to the problems of political organization He vowed to work for a better world 53 Education edit At the University of Vienna Hayek initially studied mostly philosophy psychology and economics 15 The university allowed students to choose their subjects freely and there was not much obligatory written work or tests except main exams at the end of the study 54 By the end of his studies Hayek became more interested in economics mostly for financial and career reasons he planned to combine law and economics to start a career in diplomatic service 55 He earned doctorates in law and political science in 1921 and 1923 respectively 15 For a short time when the University of Vienna closed he studied in Constantin von Monakow s Institute of Brain Anatomy where Hayek spent much of his time staining brain cells 56 Hayek s time in Monakow s lab and his deep interest in the work of Ernst Mach inspired his first intellectual project eventually published as The Sensory Order 1952 57 56 It located connective learning at the physical and neurological levels rejecting the sense data associationism of the empiricists and logical positivists 57 Hayek presented his work to the private seminar he had created with Herbert Furth called the Geistkreis 58 During Hayek s years at the University of Vienna Carl Menger s work on the explanatory strategy of social science and Friedrich von Wieser s commanding presence in the classroom left a lasting influence on him 48 Upon the completion of his examinations Hayek was hired by Ludwig von Mises on the recommendation of Wieser as a specialist for the Austrian government working on the legal and economic details of the Treaty of Saint Germain en Laye 59 Between 1923 and 1924 Hayek worked as a research assistant to Professor Jeremiah Jenks of New York University compiling macroeconomic data on the American economy and the operations of the Federal Reserve 60 He was influenced by Wesley Clair Mitchell and started a doctoral program on problems of monetary stabilization but didn t finish it 61 His time in America wasn t especially happy He had very limited social contacts missed the cultural life of Vienna and was troubled by his poverty 62 His family s financial situation deteriorated significantly after the War 63 Initially sympathetic to Wieser s democratic socialism Hayek found Marxism rigid and unattractive and his mild socialist phase lasted until he was about 23 64 Hayek s economic thinking shifted away from socialism and toward the classical liberalism of Carl Menger after reading von Mises book Socialism 59 It was sometime after reading Socialism that Hayek began attending von Mises private seminars joining several of his university friends including Fritz Machlup Alfred Schutz Felix Kaufmann and Gottfried Haberler who were also participating in Hayek s own more general and private seminar It was during this time that he also encountered and befriended noted political philosopher Eric Voegelin with whom he retained a long standing relationship 65 London School of Economics edit With the help of Mises in the late 1920s he founded and served as director of the Austrian Institute for Business Cycle Research before joining the faculty of the London School of Economics LSE in 1931 at the behest of Lionel Robbins 66 Upon his arrival in London Hayek was quickly recognised as one of the leading economic theorists in the world and his development of the economics of processes in time and the co ordination function of prices inspired the ground breaking work of John Hicks Abba P Lerner and many others in the development of modern microeconomics 67 In 1932 Hayek suggested that private investment in the public markets was a better road to wealth and economic co ordination in Britain than government spending programs as argued in an exchange of letters with John Maynard Keynes co signed with Lionel Robbins and others in The Times 68 69 The nearly decade long deflationary depression in Britain dating from Winston Churchill s decision in 1925 to return Britain to the gold standard at the old pre war and pre inflationary par was the public policy backdrop for Hayek s dissenting engagement with Keynes over British monetary and fiscal policy 70 Keynes called Hayek s book Prices and Production one of the most frightful muddles I have ever read famously adding It is an extraordinary example of how starting with a mistake a remorseless logician can end in Bedlam 71 Notable economists who studied with Hayek at the LSE in the 1930s and 1940s include Arthur Lewis Ronald Coase William Baumol John Maynard Keynes CH Douglas John Kenneth Galbraith Leonid Hurwicz Abba Lerner Nicholas Kaldor George Shackle Thomas Balogh L K Jha Arthur Seldon Paul Rosenstein Rodan and Oskar Lange 72 73 33 Some were supportive and some were critical of his ideas Hayek also taught or tutored many other LSE students including David Rockefeller 74 Unwilling to return to Austria after the Anschluss brought it under the control of Nazi Germany in 1938 Hayek remained in Britain Hayek and his children became British subjects in 1938 75 He held this status for the remainder of his life but he did not live in Great Britain after 1950 He lived in the United States from 1950 to 1962 and then mostly in Germany but also briefly in Austria 76 In 1947 Hayek was elected a Fellow of the Econometric Society 77 The Road to Serfdom edit Main article The Road to Serfdom Hayek was concerned about the general view in Britain s academia that fascism was a capitalist reaction to socialism and The Road to Serfdom arose from those concerns 78 The title was inspired by the French classical liberal thinker Alexis de Tocqueville s writings on the road to servitude 79 It was first published in Britain by Routledge in March 1944 and was quite popular leading Hayek to call it that unobtainable book also due in part to wartime paper rationing 80 When it was published in the United States by the University of Chicago in September of that year it achieved greater popularity than in Britain 81 At the instigation of editor Max Eastman the American magazine Reader s Digest also published an abridged version in April 1945 enabling The Road to Serfdom to reach a far wider audience than academics The book is widely popular among those advocating individualism and classical liberalism 82 Chicago edit In 1950 Hayek left the London School of Economics After spending the 1949 1950 academic year as a visiting professor at the University of Arkansas Hayek was conferred professorship by the University of Chicago where he became a professor in the Committee on Social Thought 83 Hayek s salary was funded not by the university but by an outside foundation the William Volker Fund 84 Hayek had made contact with many at the University of Chicago in the 1940s with Hayek s The Road to Serfdom playing a seminal role in transforming how Milton Friedman and others understood how society works 85 Hayek conducted a number of influential faculty seminars while at the University of Chicago and a number of academics worked on research projects sympathetic to some of Hayek s own such as Aaron Director who was active in the Chicago School in helping to fund and establish what became the Law and Society program in the University of Chicago Law School 86 Hayek Frank Knight Friedman and George Stigler worked together in forming the Mont Pelerin Society an international forum for neoliberals 87 Hayek and Friedman cooperated in support of the Intercollegiate Society of Individualists later renamed the Intercollegiate Studies Institute an American student organisation devoted to libertarian ideas 76 88 Although they shared most political beliefs disagreeing primarily on question of monetary policy 89 Hayek and Friedman worked in separate university departments with different research interests and never developed a close working relationship 90 According to Alan O Ebenstein who wrote biographies of both of them Hayek probably had a closer friendship with Keynes than with Friedman 91 Hayek received a Guggenheim Fellowship in 1954 92 93 Another influential political philosopher and German speaking exile at the University of Chicago at the time was Leo Strauss but according to his student Joseph Cropsey who also knew Hayek there was no contact between the two of them 94 After editing a book on John Stuart Mill s letters he planned to publish two books on the liberal order The Constitution of Liberty and The Creative Powers of a Free Civilization eventually the title for the second chapter of The Constitution of Liberty 95 He completed The Constitution of Liberty in May 1959 with publication in February 1960 Hayek was concerned that with that condition of men in which coercion of some by others is reduced as much as is possible in society 96 Hayek was disappointed that the book did not receive the same enthusiastic general reception as The Road to Serfdom had sixteen years before 97 He left Chicago mostly because of financial reasons being concerned about his pension provisions 98 His primary source of income was his salary and he received some additional money from book royalties but avoided other lucrative sources of income for academics such as writing textbooks 99 He spent a lot on his frequent travels 99 He regularly spent summers in Austrian Alps usually in the Tyrolean village Obergurgl where he enjoyed mountain climbing and also visited Japan four times with additional trips to Tahiti Fiji Indonesia Australia New Caledonia and Ceylon 100 After his divorce his financial situation worsened 101 Freiburg and Salzburg edit From 1962 until his retirement in 1968 he was a professor at the University of Freiburg West Germany where he began work on his next book Law Legislation and Liberty Hayek regarded his years at Freiburg as very fruitful 102 Following his retirement Hayek spent a year as a visiting professor of philosophy at the University of California Los Angeles where he continued work on Law Legislation and Liberty teaching a graduate seminar by the same name and another on the philosophy of social science 63 Preliminary drafts of the book were completed by 1970 but Hayek chose to rework his drafts and finally brought the book to publication in three volumes in 1973 1976 and 1979 103 Hayek became a professor at the University of Salzburg from 1969 to 1977 and then returned to Freiburg 13 When Hayek left Salzburg in 1977 he wrote I made a mistake in moving to Salzburg The economics department was small and the library facilities were inadequate 104 Although Hayek s health suffered and he fell into a depressionary bout he continued to work on his magnum opus Law Legislation and Liberty in periods when he was feeling better 105 Nobel Memorial Prize edit On 9 October 1974 it was announced that Hayek would be awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics with Swedish economist Gunnar Myrdal with the reasons for selection being listed in a press release 106 He was surprised at being given the award and believed that he was given it with Myrdal to balance the award with someone from the opposite side of the political spectrum 107 The Sveriges Riksbank Nobel Prize in Economics was established in 1968 and Hayek was the first non Keynesian economist to win it Among the reasons given the committee stated Hayek was one of the few economists who gave warning of the possibility of a major economic crisis before the great crash came in the autumn of 1929 106 The following year Hayek further confirmed his original prediction An interviewer asked We understand that you were one of the only economists to forecast that America was headed for a depression is that true Hayek responded Yes 108 However no textual evidence has emerged of a prediction 109 110 Indeed Hayek wrote on 26 October 1929 three days before the crash at present there is no reason to expect a sudden crash of the New York stock exchange The credit possibilities conditions are at any rate currently very great and therefore it appears assured that an outright crisis like destruction of the present high price level should not be feared 111 112 During the Nobel ceremony in December 1974 Hayek met the Russian dissident Aleksandr Solzhenitsyn 113 Hayek later sent him a Russian translation of The Road to Serfdom 107 He spoke with apprehension at his award speech about the danger the authority of the prize would lend to an economist 114 but the prize brought much greater public awareness to the then controversial ideas of Hayek and was described by his biographer as the great rejuvenating event in his life 115 British politics edit In February 1975 Margaret Thatcher was elected leader of the British Conservative Party The Institute of Economic Affairs arranged a meeting between Hayek and Thatcher in London soon after 116 During Thatcher s only visit to the Conservative Research Department in the summer of 1975 a speaker had prepared a paper on why the middle way was the pragmatic path the Conservative Party should take avoiding the extremes of left and right Before he had finished Thatcher reached into her briefcase and took out a book It was Hayek s The Constitution of Liberty Interrupting our pragmatist she held the book up for all of us to see This she said sternly is what we believe and banged Hayek down on the table 117 Despite the media depictions of him as Thatcher s guru and power behind the throne the communication between him and the Prime Minister was not very regular they were in contact only once or twice a year 118 Besides Thatcher Hayek also made a significant influence on Enoch Powell Keith Joseph Nigel Lawson Geoffrey Howe and John Biffen 119 Hayek gained some controversy in 1978 by praising Thatcher s anti immigration policy proposal in an article which ignited numerous accusations of anti Semitism and racism because of his reflections on the inability of assimilation of Eastern European Jews in the Vienna of his youth 119 He defended himself by explaining that he made no racial judgements only highlighted the problems of acculturation 120 In 1977 Hayek was critical of the Lib Lab pact in which the British Liberal Party agreed to keep the British Labour government in office Writing to The Times Hayek said May one who has devoted a large part of his life to the study of the history and the principles of liberalism point out that a party that keeps a socialist government in power has lost all title to the name Liberal Certainly no liberal can in future vote Liberal 121 Hayek was criticised by Liberal politicians Gladwyn Jebb and Andrew Phillips who both claimed that the purpose of the pact was to discourage socialist legislation Lord Gladwyn pointed out that the German Free Democrats were in coalition with the German Social Democrats 122 Hayek was defended by Professor Antony Flew who stated that unlike the British Labour Party the German Social Democrats had since the late 1950s abandoned public ownership of the means of production distribution and exchange and had instead embraced the social market economy 123 In 1978 Hayek came into conflict with Liberal Party leader David Steel who claimed that liberty was possible only with social justice and an equitable distribution of wealth and power which in turn require a degree of active government intervention and that the Conservative Party were more concerned with the connection between liberty and private enterprise than between liberty and democracy Hayek claimed that a limited democracy might be better than other forms of limited government at protecting liberty but that an unlimited democracy was worse than other forms of unlimited government because its government loses the power even to do what it thinks right if any group on which its majority depends thinks otherwise Hayek stated that if the Conservative leader had said that free choice is to be exercised more in the market place than in the ballot box she has merely uttered the truism that the first is indispensable for individual freedom while the second is not free choice can at least exist under a dictatorship that can limit itself but not under the government of an unlimited democracy which cannot 124 Hayek supported Britain in the Falklands War writing that it would be justified to attack Argentinian territory instead of just defending the islands which earned him a lot of criticism in Argentina a country which he also visited several times He was also displeased by the weak response of the United States to the Iran hostage crisis claiming that an ultimatum should be issued and Iran bombed if they do not comply He supported Ronald Reagan s decision to keep high defence spending believing that a strong US military is a guarantee of world peace and necessary to keep the Soviet Union under control 125 President Reagan listed Hayek as among the two or three people who most influenced his philosophy and welcomed him to the White House as a special guest 126 Senator Barry Goldwater listed Hayek as his favourite political philosopher and congressman Jack Kemp named him an inspiration for his political career 127 Recognition edit In 1980 Hayek was one of twelve Nobel laureates to meet with Pope John Paul II to dialogue discuss views in their fields communicate regarding the relationship between Catholicism and science and bring to the Pontiff s attention the problems which the Nobel Prize Winners in their respective fields of study consider to be the most urgent for contemporary man 128 Hayek was appointed a Member of the Order of the Companions of Honour CH in the 1984 Birthday Honours by Elizabeth II on the advice of British Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher for his services to the study of economics 25 26 Hayek had hoped to receive a baronetcy and after being awarded the CH sent a letter to his friends requesting that he be called the English version of Friedrich i e Frederick from now on After his twenty minute audience with the Queen he was absolutely besotted with her according to his daughter in law Esca Hayek Hayek said a year later that he was amazed by her That ease and skill as if she d known me all my life The audience with the Queen was followed by a dinner with family and friends at the Institute of Economic Affairs When later that evening Hayek was dropped off at the Reform Club he commented I ve just had the happiest day of my life 26 In 1991 President George H W Bush awarded Hayek the Presidential Medal of Freedom one of the two highest civilian awards in the United States for a lifetime of looking beyond the horizon 129 Death edit Hayek died on 23 March 1992 aged 92 in Freiburg Germany and was buried on 4 April in the Neustift am Walde cemetery in the northern outskirts of Vienna according to the Catholic rite 130 In 2011 his article The Use of Knowledge in Society was selected as one of the top 20 articles published in The American Economic Review during its first 100 years 29 The New York University Journal of Law and Liberty holds an annual lecture in his honor 131 Work and views editBusiness cycle edit Main article Austrian business cycle theory nbsp Parts of a business cycle nbsp Actual business cycle Ludwig von Mises had earlier applied the concept of marginal utility to the value of money in his Theory of Money and Credit 1912 in which he also proposed an explanation for industrial fluctuations based on the ideas of the old British Currency School and of Swedish economist Knut Wicksell 132 Hayek used this body of work as a starting point for his own interpretation of the business cycle elaborating what later became known as the Austrian theory of the business cycle 133 Hayek spelled out the Austrian approach in more detail in his book published in 1929 an English translation of which appeared in 1933 as Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle There Hayek argued for a monetary approach to the origins of the cycle In his Prices and Production 1931 Hayek argued that the business cycle resulted from the central bank s inflationary credit expansion and its transmission over time leading to a capital misallocation caused by the artificially low interest rates 134 Hayek claimed that the past instability of the market economy is the consequence of the exclusion of the most important regulator of the market mechanism money from itself being regulated by the market process 135 Hayek s analysis was based on Eugen Bohm von Bawerk s concept of the average period of production and on the effects that monetary policy could have upon it 136 In accordance with the reasoning later outlined in his essay The Use of Knowledge in Society 1945 Hayek argued that a monopolistic governmental agency like a central bank can neither possess the relevant information which should govern supply of money nor have the ability to use it correctly 137 In 1929 Lionel Robbins assumed the helm of the London School of Economics LSE 66 Eager to promote alternatives to what he regarded as the narrow approach of the school of economic thought that then dominated the English speaking academic world centered at the University of Cambridge and deriving largely from the work of Alfred Marshall Robbins invited Hayek to join the faculty at LSE which he did in 1931 138 According to Nicholas Kaldor Hayek s theory of the time structure of capital and of the business cycle initially fascinated the academic world and appeared to offer a less facile and superficial understanding of macroeconomics than the Cambridge school s 139 Also in 1931 Hayek crititicized John Maynard Keynes s Treatise on Money 1930 in his Reflections on the pure theory of Mr J M Keynes 140 and published his lectures at the LSE in book form as Prices and Production 141 For Keynes unemployment and idle resources are caused by a lack of effective demand but for Hayek they stem from a previous unsustainable episode of easy money and artificially low interest rates 135 Keynes asked his friend Piero Sraffa to respond Sraffa elaborated on the effect of inflation induced forced savings on the capital sector and about the definition of a natural interest rate in a growing economy see Sraffa Hayek debate 142 Others who responded negatively to Hayek s work on the business cycle included John Hicks Frank Knight and Gunnar Myrdal who later on would share the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economics with him 143 Kaldor later wrote that Hayek s Prices and Production had produced a remarkable crop of critics and that the total number of pages in British and American journals dedicated to the resulting debate could rarely have been equalled in the economic controversies of the past 139 Hayek s work throughout the 1940s was largely ignored except for scathing critiques by Nicholas Kaldor 139 144 Lionel Robbins himself who had embraced the Austrian theory of the business cycle in The Great Depression 1934 later regretted having written the book and accepted many of the Keynesian counter arguments 145 Hayek never produced the book length treatment of the dynamics of capital that he had promised in the Pure Theory of Capital 146 At the University of Chicago Hayek was not part of the economics department and did not influence the rebirth of neoclassical theory that took place there see Chicago school of economics 83 When in 1974 he shared the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics with Myrdal the latter complained about being paired with an ideologue Milton Friedman declared himself an enormous admirer of Hayek but not for his economics 147 Milton Friedman also commented on some of his writings saying I think Prices and Production is a very flawed book I think his Pure Theory of Capital is unreadable On the other hand The Road to Serfdom is one of the great books of our time 145 Economic calculation problem edit Main article Economic calculation problem Building on the earlier work of Mises and others Hayek also argued that while in centrally planned economies an individual or a select group of individuals must determine the distribution of resources these planners will never have enough information to carry out this allocation reliably This argument first proposed by Max Weber and Ludwig von Mises says that the efficient exchange and use of resources can be maintained only through the price mechanism in free markets see economic calculation problem 148 In 1935 Hayek published Collectivist Economic Planning a collection of essays from an earlier debate that had been initiated by Mises Hayek included Mises s essay in which Mises argued that rational planning was impossible under socialism 149 Socialist Oskar Lange responded by invoking general equilibrium theory which they argued disproved Mises s thesis They noted that the difference between a planned and a free market system lay in who was responsible for solving the equations 150 They argued that if some of the prices chosen by socialist managers were wrong gluts or shortages would appear signalling them to adjust the prices up or down just as in a free market 151 Through such a trial and error a socialist economy could mimic the efficiency of a free market system while avoiding its many problems 152 Hayek challenged this vision in a series of contributions In Economics and Knowledge 1937 he pointed out that the standard equilibrium theory assumed that all agents have full and correct information and how in his mind in the real world different individuals have different bits of knowledge and furthermore some of what they believe is wrong 153 In The Use of Knowledge in Society 1945 Hayek argued that the price mechanism serves to share and synchronise local and personal knowledge allowing society s members to achieve diverse and complicated ends through a principle of spontaneous self organization He contrasted the use of the price mechanism with central planning arguing that the former allows for more rapid adaptation to changes in particular circumstances of time and place 154 Thus Hayek set the stage for Oliver Williamson s later contrast between markets and hierarchies as alternative co ordination mechanisms for economic transactions 155 He used the term catallaxy to describe a self organizing system of voluntary co operation Hayek s research into this argument was specifically cited by the Nobel Committee in its press release awarding Hayek the Nobel prize 106 Investment and choice edit Hayek made breakthroughs in the choice theory and examined the inter relations between non permanent production goods and latent or potentially economic permanent resources building on the choice theoretical insight that processes that take more time will evidently not be adopted unless they yield a greater return than those that take less time 156 Philosophy of science edit See also The Counter Revolution of Science During World War II Hayek began the Abuse of Reason project His goal was to show how a number of then popular doctrines and beliefs had a common origin in some fundamental misconceptions about the social science 157 Ideas were developed in The Counter Revolution of Science in 1952 and in some of Hayek s later essays in the philosophy of science such as Degrees of Explanation 1955 and The Theory of Complex Phenomena 1964 158 In Counter Revolution for example Hayek observed that the hard sciences attempt to remove the human factor to obtain objective and strictly controlled results T he persistent effort of modern Science has been to get down to objective facts to cease studying what men thought about nature or regarding the given concepts as true images of the real world and above all to discard all theories which pretended to explain phenomena by imputing to them a directing mind like our own Instead its main task became to revise and reconstruct the concepts formed from ordinary experience on the basis of a systematic testing of the phenomena so as to be better able to recognize the particular as an instance of a general rule Friedrich Hayek The Counter Revolution of Science Chapter II The Problem and the Method of the Natural Sciences Meanwhile the soft sciences are attempting to measure human action itself The social sciences in the narrower sense i e those which used to be described as the moral sciences are concerned with man s conscious or reflected action actions where a person can be said to choose between various courses open to him and here the situation is essentially different The external stimulus which may be said to cause or occasion such actions can of course also be defined in purely physical terms But if we tried to do so for the purposes of explaining human action we would confine ourselves to less than we know about the situation Friedrich Hayek The Counter Revolution of Science Chapter III The Subjective Character of the Data of the Social Sciences He notes that these are mutually exclusive and that social sciences should not attempt to impose positivist methodology nor to claim objective or definite results 159 Psychology edit Hayek s first academic essay was a psychological work titled Contributions to the Theory of the Development of Consciousness Beitrage zur Theorie der Entwicklung des Bewusstseins In The Sensory Order An Inquiry into the Foundations of Theoretical Psychology 1952 Hayek independently developed a Hebbian learning model of learning and memory an idea he first conceived in 1920 prior to his study of economics Hayek s expansion of the Hebbian synapse construction into a global brain theory received attention in neuroscience cognitive science computer science and evolutionary psychology by scientists such as Gerald Edelman Vittorio Guidano and Joaquin Fuster 160 161 162 The Sensory Order can be viewed as a development of his attack on scientism Hayek posited two orders namely the sensory order that we experience and the natural order that natural science revealed Hayek thought that the sensory order actually is a product of the brain He described the brain as a very complex yet self ordering hierarchical classification system a huge network of connections Because of the nature of the classifier system richness of our sensory experience can exist Hayek s description posed problems to behaviorism whose proponents took the sensory order as fundamental 157 International Relations edit Hayek was a lifelong federalist He joined several pan European and pro federalist movements throughout his career and called for federal ties between the U K and Europe and between Europe and the United States After the 1950s when the Cold War began in earnest Hayek largely kept his federalist proposals out of the public sphere although he did propose to federate Jerusalem as late as the 1970s 163 Hayek argued that closer economic ties without closer political ties would lead to more problems because interest groups in nation states would best be able to counter the internationalization of markets that comes with closer economic ties by appealing to nationalism 164 Much of his time in the pro federalist and pan European groups was spent arguing with pro federal and pan European democratic socialists over the proper extent of a world federal government Hayek argued that such a world government should do little more than act as a negative check on national sovereignties and serve as a focal point for collective defense 165 As the Cold War heated up Hayek grew more hawkish and he pushed his federal proposals onto the backburner in favor of more traditional public policy proposals that acknowledged and respected the sovereignty of nation states 166 Yet Hayek never disavowed his famous call for the abrogation of national sovereignties 167 and his lifetime of work in the area of international relations continues to attract attention from scholars searching for federalist answers to contemporary problems in international relations 168 169 170 171 Social and political philosophy edit Two traditions in the theory of liberty edit In the latter half of his career Hayek made a number of contributions to social and political philosophy which he based on his views on the limits of human knowledge and the idea of spontaneous order in social institutions He argues in favour of a society organised around a market order in which the apparatus of state is employed almost though not entirely exclusively to enforce the legal order consisting of abstract rules and not particular commands necessary for a market of free individuals to function These ideas were informed by a moral philosophy derived from epistemological concerns regarding the inherent limits of human knowledge Hayek argued that his ideal individualistic and free market polity would be self regulating to such a degree that it would be a society which does not depend for its functioning on our finding good men for running it 172 He discusses the contrasting traditions of liberty British and French in the theory of freedom The British tradition influenced by thinkers like David Hume and Adam Smith emphasizes the organic growth of institutions and the spontaneous evolution of society It recognizes that political order arises from the cumulative experience and success of individuals rather than from deliberate design In contrast the French tradition rooted in Cartesian rationalism seeks to construct a utopia based on a belief in the unlimited powers of human reason The French tradition that Hayek called constructivist rationalism gained influence over time partly due to its assumptions about human ambition and pride However according to Hayek the British tradition with its emphasis on the gradual development of civilization and the role of individual freedom provides a more valid theory of liberty 172 173 174 Spontaneous order edit Main article Spontaneous order Hayek viewed the free price system not as a conscious invention that which is intentionally designed by man but as spontaneous order or what Scottish philosopher Adam Ferguson referred to as the result of human action but not of human design 175 For instance Hayek put the price mechanism on the same level as language which he developed in his price signal theory 176 Hayek attributed the birth of civilisation to private property in his book The Fatal Conceit 1988 177 He explained that price signals are the only means of enabling each economic decision maker to communicate tacit knowledge or dispersed knowledge to each other to solve the economic calculation problem 177 Alain de Benoist of the Nouvelle Droite New Right produced a highly critical essay on Hayek s work in an issue of Telos citing the flawed assumptions behind Hayek s idea of spontaneous order and the authoritarian and totalising implications of his free market ideology 178 Hayek s concept of the market as a spontaneous order has been applied to ecosystems to defend a broadly non interventionist policy 179 Like the market ecosystems contain complex networks of information involve an ongoing dynamic process contain orders within orders and the entire system operates without being directed by a conscious mind 180 On this analysis species takes the place of price as a visible element of the system formed by a complex set of largely unknowable elements Human ignorance about the countless interactions between the organisms of an ecosystem limits our ability to manipulate nature 181 Hayek s price signal concept is in relation to how consumers are often unaware of specific events that change market yet change their decisions simply because the price goes up Thus pricing communicates information 182 Criticism of collectivism edit Hayek was one of the leading academic critics of collectivism in the 20th century 13 In Hayek s view the central role of the state should be to maintain the rule of law with as little arbitrary intervention as possible 96 In his popular book The Road to Serfdom 1944 and in subsequent academic works Hayek argued that socialism required central economic planning and that such planning in turn leads towards totalitarianism 183 In The Road to Serfdom Hayek wrote Although our modern socialists promise of greater freedom is genuine and sincere in recent years observer after observer has been impressed by the unforeseen consequences of socialism the extraordinary similarity in many respects of the conditions under communism and fascism 184 Hayek posited that a central planning authority would have to be endowed with powers that would impact and ultimately control social life because the knowledge required for centrally planning an economy is inherently decentralised and would need to be brought under control 149 Though Hayek did argue that the state should provide law centrally others have pointed out that this contradicts his arguments about the role of judges in discovering the law suggesting that Hayek would have supported decentralized provision of legal services 185 Hayek also wrote that the state can play a role in the economy specifically in creating a safety net saying There is no reason why in a society which has reached the general level of wealth ours has the first kind of security should not be guaranteed to all without endangering general freedom that is some minimum of food shelter and clothing sufficient to preserve health Nor is there any reason why the state should not help to organize a comprehensive system of social insurance in providing for those common hazards of life against which few can make adequate provision 186 The Denationalization of Money is one of his literary works in which he advocated the establishment of competitions in issuing moneys 187 Social safety nets edit Main articles Social insurance and Social safety netWith regard to a social safety net Hayek advocated some provision for those threatened by the extremes of indigence or starvation due to circumstances beyond their control and argued that the necessity of some such arrangement in an industrial society is unquestioned be it only in the interest of those who require protection against acts of desperation on the part of the needy 188 Summarizing Hayek s views on the topic journalist Nicholas Wapshott has argued that Hayek advocated mandatory universal health care and unemployment insurance enforced if not directly provided by the state 189 Critical theorist Bernard Harcourt has argued further that Hayek was adamant about this 190 In 1944 Hayek wrote in The Road to Serfdom There is no reason why in a society which has reached the general level of wealth which ours has attained that security against severe physical privation the certainty of a given minimum of sustenance for all or more briefly the security of a minimum income should not be guaranteed to all without endangering general freedom There are difficult questions about the precise standard which should thus be assured but there can be no doubt that some minimum of food shelter and clothing sufficient to preserve health and the capacity to work can be assured to everybody Indeed for a considerable part of the population of England this sort of security has long been achieved Nor is there any reason why the state should not assist individuals in providing for those common hazards of life against which because of their uncertainty few individuals can make adequate provision Where as in the case of sickness and accident neither the desire to avoid such calamities nor the efforts to overcome their consequences are as a rule weakened by the provision of assistance where in short we deal with genuinely insurable risks the case for the state s helping to organize a comprehensive system of social insurance is very strong There are many points of detail where those wishing to preserve the competitive system and those wishing to supersede it by something different will disagree on the details of such schemes and it is possible under the name of social insurance to introduce measures which tend to make competition more or less effective But there is no incompatibility in principle between the state s providing greater security in this way and the preservation of individual freedom Wherever communal action can mitigate disasters against which the individual can neither attempt to guard himself nor make the provision for the consequences such communal action should undoubtedly be taken 191 In 1973 Hayek reiterated in Law Legislation and Liberty There is no reason why in a free society government should not assure to all protection against severe deprivation in the form of an assured minimum income or a floor below which nobody need to descend To enter into such an insurance against extreme misfortune may well be in the interest of all or it may be felt to be a clear moral duty of all to assist within the organised community those who cannot help themselves So long as such a uniform minimum income is provided outside the market to all those who for any reason are unable to earn in the market an adequate maintenance this need not lead to a restriction of freedom or conflict with the Rule of law 192 Political theorist Adam James Tebble has argued that Hayek s concession of a social minimum provided by the state introduces a conceptual tension with his epistemically derived commitment to private property rights free markets and spontaneous order 193 Criticism of social justice edit Although Hayek believed in a society governed by laws he disapproved of the notion of social justice He compared the market to a game in which there is no point in calling the outcome just or unjust 194 and argued that social justice is an empty phrase with no determinable content 195 Likewise the results of the individual s efforts are necessarily unpredictable and the question as to whether the resulting distribution of incomes is just has no meaning 196 He generally regarded government redistribution of income or capital as an unacceptable intrusion upon individual freedom saying that the principle of distributive justice once introduced would not be fulfilled until the whole of society was organized in accordance with it This would produce a kind of society which in all essential respects would be the opposite of a free society 195 Liberalism and skepticism editArthur M Diamond argues Hayek s problems arise when he goes beyond claims that can be evaluated within economic science Diamond argued The human mind Hayek says is not just limited in its ability to synthesize a vast array of concrete facts it is also limited in its ability to give a deductively sound ground to ethics Here is where the tension develops for he also wants to give a reasoned moral defense of the free market He is an intellectual skeptic who wants to give political philosophy a secure intellectual foundation It is thus not too surprising that what results is confused and contradictory 197 Chandran Kukathas argues that Hayek s defence of liberalism is unsuccessful because it rests on presuppositions that are incompatible The unresolved dilemma of his political philosophy is how to mount a systematic defence of liberalism if one emphasizes the limited capacity of reason 198 Norman P Barry similarly notes that the critical rationalism in Hayek s writings appears incompatible with a certain kind of fatalism that we must wait for evolution to pronounce its verdict 199 Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz argue that the element of paradox exists in the views of Hayek Noting Hayek s vigorous defense of invisible hand evolution that Hayek claimed created better economic institutions than could be created by rational design Friedman pointed out the irony that Hayek was then proposing to replace the monetary system thus created with a deliberate construct of his own design 200 John N Gray summarized this view as his scheme for an ultra liberal constitution was a prototypical version of the philosophy he had attacked 201 Bruce Caldwell wrote that i f one is judging his work against the standard of whether he provided a finished political philosophy Hayek clearly did not succeed although he thinks that economists may find Hayek s political writings useful 202 Dictatorship and totalitarianism edit nbsp Wikiquote has quotations related to Friedrich Hayek and dictatorship Hayek sent Antonio de Oliveira Salazar a copy of The Constitution of Liberty 1960 in 1962 Hayek hoped that his book this preliminary sketch of new constitutional principles may assist Salazar in his endeavour to design a constitution which is proof against the abuses of democracy 203 Hayek visited Chile in the 1970s and 1980s during the Government Junta of general Augusto Pinochet and accepted being appointed Honorary Chairman of the Centro de Estudios Publicos the think tank formed by the economists who transformed Chile into a free market economy 203 Asked about the military dictatorship of Chile by a Chilean interviewer Hayek is translated from German to Spanish to English as having said the following As long term institutions I am totally against dictatorships But a dictatorship may be a necessary system for a transitional period Personally I prefer a liberal dictatorship to democratic government devoid of liberalism My personal impression and this is valid for South America is that in Chile for example we will witness a transition from a dictatorial government to a liberal government 103 In a letter to the London Times he defended the Pinochet regime and said that he had not been able to find a single person even in much maligned Chile who did not agree that personal freedom was much greater under Pinochet than it had been under Allende 204 205 Hayek admitted that it is not very likely that this will succeed even if at a particular point in time it may be the only hope there is but he explained that i t is not certain hope because it will always depend on the goodwill of an individual and there are very few individuals one can trust But if it is the sole opportunity which exists at a particular moment it may be the best solution despite this And only if and when the dictatorial government is visibly directing its steps towards limited democracy For Hayek the distinction between authoritarianism and totalitarianism has much importance and he was at pains to emphasise his opposition to totalitarianism noting that the concept of transitional dictatorship which he defended was characterised by authoritarianism not totalitarianism For example when Hayek visited Venezuela in May 1981 he was asked to comment on the prevalence of totalitarian regimes in Latin America In reply Hayek warned against confusing totalitarianism with authoritarianism and said that he was unaware of any totalitarian governments in Latin America The only one was Chile under Allende For Hayek the word totalitarian signifies something very specific namely the intention to organize the whole of society to attain a definite social goal which is stark in contrast to liberalism and individualism 206 He claimed that democracy can also be repressive and totalitarian in The Constitution of Liberty he often refers to Jacob Talmon s concept of totalitarian democracy Immigration nationalism and race edit Hayek was skeptical about international immigration and supported Thatcher s anti immigration policies 119 In Law Legislation and Liberty he elaborated Freedom of migration is one of the widely accepted and wholly admirable principles of liberalism But should this generally give the stranger a right to settle down in a community in which he is not welcome Has he a claim to be given a job or be sold a house if no resident is willing to do so He clearly should be entitled to accept a job or buy a house if offered to him But have the individual inhabitants a duty to offer either to him Or ought it to be an offence if they voluntarily agree not to do so Swiss and Tyrolese villages have a way of keeping out strangers which neither infringe nor rely on any law Is this anti liberal or morally justified For established old communities I have no certain answers to these questions 207 He was mainly preoccupied with practical problems concerning immigration There exist of course other reasons why such restrictions appear unavoidable so long as certain differences in national or ethnic traditions especially differences in the rate of propagation exist which in turn are not likely to disappear so long as restrictions on migration continue We must face the fact that we here encounter a limit to the universal application of those liberal principles of policy which the existing facts of the present world make unavoidable 208 He was not sympathetic to nationalist ideas and was afraid that mass immigration might revive nationalist sentiment among domestic population and ruin the postwar progress that was made among Western nations 209 He additionally explained However far modern man accepts in principle the ideal that the same rules should apply to all men in fact he does concede it only to those whom he regards as similar to himself and only slowly learns to extend the range of those he does accept as his likes There is little legislation can do to speed up this process and much it may do to reverse it by re awakening sentiments that are already on the wane 209 Despite his opposition to nationalism Hayek made numerous controversial and inflammatory comments about specific ethnic groups Answering an interview question about people he cannot deal with he mentioned his dislike of Middle Eastern populations claiming they were dishonest and also expressed profound dislike of Indian students at London School of Economics saying that were usually detestable sons of Bengali moneylenders 210 He claimed that his attitude is not based on any racial feeling 210 During World War II he discussed the possibility of sending his children to the United States but was concerned that they might be placed with a coloured family 211 In a later interview questioned about his attitude towards Black people he said laconically that he did not like dancing Negroes 212 and on another occasion he ridiculed the decision to award the Nobel Peace Prize to Martin Luther King Jr 213 He also made negative comments about awarding the Prize to Ralph Bunche Albert Luthuli and his LSE colleague W Arthur Lewis who he described as an unusually able West Indian negro 213 In 1978 Hayek made a month long visit to South Africa his third where he gave numerous lectures interviews and met prominent politicians and business leaders unconcerned about possible propagandistic effect of his tour for Apartheid regime He expressed his opposition to some of the government policies believing that publicly funded institutions should treat all citizens equally but also claimed that private institutions have the right to discriminate Additionally he condemned the scandalous hostility and interference of the international community in South African internal affairs 214 He further explained his attitude People in South Africa have to deal with their own problems and the idea that you can use external pressure to change people who after all have built up a civilization of a kind seems to me morally a very doubtful belief 215 While Hayek gave somewhat ambiguous comments on the injustices of Apartheid and proper role of the state some of his Mont Pelerin colleagues such as John Davenport and Wilhelm Ropke were more ardent supporters of South African government and criticized Hayek for being too soft on the subject 216 Inequality and class edit Hayek claimed that the idea that all men are born equal is untrue because evolution and genetic differences have created boundless variety of human nature He emphasized the importance of nature complaining that it became too fashionable to ascribe all human differences to environment 217 Hayek defended economic inequality believing that the existence of wealthy class is important not only for economic reasons accumulating capital and directing investments but also for political cultural scientific and conservationist goals which are often financed and promoted by philanthropists Since the market mechanism cannot provide for all societal needs some of which are outside of economic calculation existence of wealthy individuals guarantees the efficiency and pluralism in their development and realization which could not be guaranteed in the case of state monopoly 218 Individual wealth offers independence and can create intellectual moral political and artistic leaders which are not employed and influenced by the state 219 According to Hayek the society benefits from having a hereditary wealthy class because individuals born in it don t have to devote their energy to earning a living and can devote themselves to other purposes such as experimenting with different ideas hobbies and lifestyles which can later be adopted by broader society 220 In The Constitution of Liberty he wrote Yet is it really so obvious that the tennis or golf professional is a more useful member of society than the wealthy amateurs who devoted their time to perfecting these games Or that the paid curator of a public museum is more useful than a private collector Before the reader answers these questions too hastily I would ask him to consider whether there would ever have been golf or tennis professionals or museum curators if wealthy amateurs had not preceded them Can we not hope that other new interests will still arise from the playful explorations of those who can indulge in them for the short span of a human life It is only natural that the development of the art of living and of the non materialistic values should have profited most from the activities of those who had no material worries 221 He contrasted individuals who inherited wealth with upper class values and education with the nouveau riche who often use their wealth in more vulgar ways 220 He decried the disappearance of such leisured aristocratic class claiming that contemporary Western elites are usually business groups that lack intellectual leadership and coherent philosophy of life and use their wealth mostly for economic purposes 222 Hayek was against high taxes on inheritance believing that it is natural function of the family to transmit standards traditions and material goods Without transmission of property parents might try to secure the future of their children by placing them in prestigious and high paying positions as was customary in socialist countries which creates even worse injustices 223 He was also strongly against progressive taxation noting that in most countries additional taxes paid by the rich amount to insignificantly small amount of total tax revenue and that the only major result of the policy is gratification of the envy of the less well off 224 He also claimed that it is contrary to the idea of equality under the law and against democratic principle that the majority should not impose discriminatory rules against the minority 225 226 Criticism edit Hayek s views on social welfare policies have also been the subject of criticism Critics contend that his opposition to government intervention in the economy fails to recognize the need for social safety nets and other forms of support for vulnerable populations Furthermore it has been argued that his views on welfare policy contradict his views on social justice 227 Hayek s argument in The Road to Serfdom has been criticized as a slippery slope argument and therefore fallacious 228 However others have argued that this is a fundamental misunderstanding of the book and Hayek s point is about what central planning directly entails not what it is likely to lead to 229 Influence and recognition edit nbsp An elderly Hayek in 1981 Hayek s influence on the development of economics is widely acknowledged With regard to the popularity of his Nobel acceptance lecture Hayek is the second most frequently cited economist after Kenneth Arrow in the Nobel lectures of the prize winners in economics Hayek wrote critically there of the field of orthodox economics and neo classical modelisation 230 A number of Nobel Laureates in economics such as Vernon Smith and Herbert A Simon recognise Hayek as the greatest modern economist 231 Another Nobel winner Paul Samuelson believed that Hayek was worthy of his award but nevertheless claimed that there were good historical reasons for fading memories of Hayek within the mainstream last half of the twentieth century economist fraternity In 1931 Hayek s Prices and Production had enjoyed an ultra short Byronic success In retrospect hindsight tells us that its mumbo jumbo about the period of production grossly misdiagnosed the macroeconomics of the 1927 1931 and the 1931 2007 historical scene 232 Despite this comment Samuelson spent the last 50 years of his life obsessed with the problems of capital theory identified by Hayek and Bohm Bawerk and Samuelson flatly judged Hayek to have been right and his own teacher Joseph Schumpeter to have been wrong on the central economic question of the 20th century the feasibility of socialist economic planning in a production goods dominated economy 233 Hayek is widely recognised for having introduced the time dimension to the equilibrium construction and for his key role in helping inspire the fields of growth theory information economics and the theory of spontaneous order The informal economics presented in Milton Friedman s massively influential popular work Free to Choose 1980 is explicitly Hayekian in its account of the price system as a system for transmitting and co ordinating knowledge This can be explained by the fact that Friedman taught Hayek s famous paper The Use of Knowledge in Society 1945 in his graduate seminars In 1944 he was elected as a Fellow of the British Academy 234 after he was nominated for membership by Keynes 235 Harvard economist and former Harvard University President Lawrence Summers explains Hayek s place in modern economics What s the single most important thing to learn from an economics course today What I tried to leave my students with is the view that the invisible hand is more powerful than the un hidden hand Things will happen in well organized efforts without direction controls plans That s the consensus among economists That s the Hayek legacy 236 By 1947 Hayek was an organiser of the Mont Pelerin Society a group of classical liberals who sought to oppose socialism Hayek was also instrumental in the founding of the Institute of Economic Affairs the right wing libertarian and free market think tank that inspired Thatcherism He was in addition a member of the conservative and libertarian Philadelphia Society 237 Hayek had a long standing and close friendship with philosopher of science Karl Popper who was also from Vienna In a letter to Hayek in 1944 Popper stated I think I have learnt more from you than from any other living thinker except perhaps Alfred Tarski 238 Popper dedicated his Conjectures and Refutations to Hayek For his part Hayek dedicated a collection of papers Studies in Philosophy Politics and Economics to Popper and in 1982 said that ever since his Logik der Forschung first came out in 1934 I have been a complete adherent to his general theory of methodology 239 Popper also participated in the inaugural meeting of the Mont Pelerin Society Their friendship and mutual admiration do not change the fact that there are important differences between their ideas 240 Hayek also played a central role in Milton Friedman s intellectual development Friedman wrote My interest in public policy and political philosophy was rather casual before I joined the faculty of the University of Chicago Informal discussions with colleagues and friends stimulated a greater interest which was reinforced by Friedrich Hayek s powerful book The Road to Serfdom by my attendance at the first meeting of the Mont Pelerin Society in 1947 and by discussions with Hayek after he joined the university faculty in 1950 In addition Hayek attracted an exceptionally able group of students who were dedicated to a libertarian ideology They started a student publication The New Individualist Review which was the outstanding libertarian journal of opinion for some years I served as an adviser to the journal and published a number of articles in it 241 While Friedman often mentioned Hayek as an important influence Hayek rarely mentioned Friedman 242 He deeply disagreed with Chicago School methodology quantitative and macroeconomic focus and claimed that Friedman s Essays in Positive Economics was as dangerous a book as Keynes General Theory 243 Friedman also claimed that despite some Popperian influence Hayek always retained basic Misesian praxeological view which he found utterly nonsensical 244 He also noted that he admired Hayek only for his political works and disagreed with his technical economics he called Prices and Production a very flawed book and The Pure Theory of Capital unreadable 245 There were occasional tensions at the Mont Pelerin meetings between the Hayek s and Friedman s followers that sometimes threatened to split the Society 89 Although they worked at the same university and shared political beliefs Hayek and Friedman rarely collaborated professionally and were not close friends 91 Hayek s greatest intellectual debt was to Carl Menger who pioneered an approach to social explanation similar to that developed in Britain by Bernard Mandeville and the Scottish moral philosophers in the Scottish Enlightenment He had a wide reaching influence on contemporary economics politics philosophy sociology psychology and anthropology For example Hayek s discussion in The Road to Serfdom 1944 about truth falsehood and the use of language influenced some later opponents of postmodernism 246 Some radical libertarians had a negative view of Hayek and his milder form of liberalism Ayn Rand disliked him seeing him as a conservative and compromiser 247 In a letter to Rose Wilder Lane in 1946 she wrote Now to your question Do those almost with us do more harm than 100 enemies I don t think this can be answered with a flat yes or no because the almost is such a wide term There is one general rule to observe those who are with us but merely do not go far enough are the ones who may do us some good Those who agree with us in some respects yet preach contradictory ideas at the same time are definitely more harmful than 100 enemies As an example of the kind of almost I would tolerate I d name Ludwig von Mises As an example of our most pernicious enemy I would name Hayek That one is real poison 248 Hayek made no known written references to Rand 249 Wikipedia co founder Jimmy Wales was influenced by Hayek s ideas on spontaneous order and the Austrian School of economics after being exposed to these ideas by Austrian economist and Mises Institute Senior Fellow Mark Thornton 250 In the 21st century some libertarian political scientists argue that Hayek would be in favor of Bitcoin and cryptocurrencies due to its resistance to political pressure and due to Hayek s emphasis of sound money and competition in currencies 251 They also argue that cryptocurrency and Bitcoin serve as a Hayekian Escape a method that the people can use to escape the government s currency monopoly 252 Relation to conservatism edit Hayek received new attention in the 1980s and 1990s with the rise of conservative governments in the United States United Kingdom and Canada After winning the 1979 United Kingdom general election Margaret Thatcher appointed Keith Joseph the director of the Hayekian Centre for Policy Studies as her secretary of state for industry in an effort to redirect parliament s economic strategies Likewise David Stockman Ronald Reagan s most influential financial official in 1981 was an acknowledged follower of Hayek 253 Although usually identified as a conservative liberal or a liberal conservative 254 Hayek published an essay Why I Am Not a Conservative included as an appendix to The Constitution of Liberty in which he criticized certain aspects of conservatism from a liberal perspective Edmund Fawcett summarizes Hayek s critique as follows Conservatives on Hayek s account suffered from the following weaknesses They feared change unduly They were unreasonably frightened of uncontrolled social forces They were too fond of authority They had no grasp of economics They lacked the feel for abstraction needed for engaging with people of different outlooks They were too cozy with elites and establishments They gave in to jingoism and chauvinism They tended to think mystically much as socialists tended to overrationalize They were last too suspicious of democracy 255 Hayek identified himself as a classical liberal but noted that in the United States it had become almost impossible to use liberal in its original definition and the term libertarian was used instead 256 He also found libertarianism as a term singularly unattractive and offered the term Old Whig a phrase borrowed from Edmund Burke instead In his later life he said I am becoming a Burkean Whig 257 Whiggery as a political doctrine had little affinity for classical political economy the tabernacle of the Manchester School and William Gladstone 258 In his 1956 preface to The Road to Serfdom Hayek summarized all his disagreements with conservatism in this way Conservatism though a necessary element in any stable society is not a social program in its paternalistic nationalistic and poweradoring tendencies it is often closer to socialism than true liberalism and with its traditionalistic anti intellectual and often mystical propensities it will never except in short periods of disillusionment appeal to the young and all those others who believe that some changes are desirable if this world is to become a better place A conservative movement by its very nature is bound to be a defender of established privilege and to lean on the power of government for the protection of privilege The essence of the liberal position however is the denial of all privilege if privilege is understood in its proper and original meaning of the state granting and protecting rights to some which are not available on equal terms to others Samuel Brittan concluded in 2010 that Hayek s book The Constitution of Liberty is still probably the most comprehensive statement of the underlying ideas of the moderate free market philosophy espoused by neoliberals 259 Brittan adds that although Raymond Plant 2009 comes out in the end against Hayek s doctrines Plant gives The Constitution of Liberty a more thorough and fair minded analysis than it has received even from its professed adherents As a neo liberal he helped found the Mont Pelerin Society a prominent neo liberal think tank where many other minds such as Mises and Friedman gathered 260 259 Although Hayek is likely a student of the neo liberal school of libertarianism 261 he is nonetheless influential in the conservative movement mainly for his critique of collectivism 24 Policy discussions edit Hayek s ideas on spontaneous order and the importance of prices in dealing with the knowledge problem inspired a debate on economic development and transition economies after the fall of the Berlin wall For instance economist Peter Boettke elaborated in detail on why reforming socialism failed and the Soviet Union broke down 262 Economist Ronald McKinnon uses Hayekian ideas to describe the challenges of transition from a centralized state and planned economy to a market economy 263 Former World Bank Chief Economist William Easterly emphasizes why foreign aid tends to have no effect at best in books such as The White Man s Burden Why the West s Efforts to Aid the Rest Have Done So Much Ill and So Little Good 264 Since the 2007 2008 financial crisis there is a renewed interest in Hayek s core explanation of boom and bust cycles which serves as an alternative explanation to that of the savings glut as launched by economist and former Federal Reserve Chair Ben Bernanke Economists at the Bank for International Settlements e g William R White emphasize the importance of Hayekian insights and the impact of monetary policies and credit growth as root causes of financial cycles 265 Andreas Hoffmann and Gunther Schnabl provide an international perspective and explain recurring financial cycles in the world economy as consequence of gradual interest rate cuts led by the central banks in the large advanced economies since the 1980s 266 267 Nicolas Cachanosky outlines the impact of American monetary policy on the production structure in Latin America 268 In line with Hayek an increasing number of contemporary researchers sees expansionary monetary policies and too low interest rates as mal incentives and main drivers of financial crises in general and the subprime market crisis in particular 269 270 To prevent problems caused by monetary policy Hayekian and Austrian economists discuss alternatives to current policies and organizations For instance Lawrence H White argued in favor of free banking in the spirit of Hayek s Denationalization of Money 271 Along with market monetarist economist Scott Sumner 272 White also noted that the monetary policy norm that Hayek prescribed first in Prices and Production 1931 and as late as the 1970s 273 274 was the stabilization of nominal income 138 Hayek s ideas find their way into the discussion of the post Great Recession issues of secular stagnation Monetary policy and mounting regulation are argued to have undermined the innovative forces of the market economies Quantitative easing following the financial crises is argued to have not only conserved structural distortions in the economy leading to a fall in trend growth It also created new distortions and contributes to distributional conflicts 275 Central European politics edit In the 1970s and 1980s the writings of Hayek were a major influence on some of the future postsocialist economic and political elites in Central and Eastern Europe Supporting examples include the following There is no figure who had more of an influence no person had more of an influence on the intellectuals behind the Iron Curtain than Friedrich Hayek His books were translated and published by the underground and black market editions read widely and undoubtedly influenced the climate of opinion that ultimately brought about the collapse of the Soviet Union 276 Milton Friedman Hoover Institution The most interesting among the courageous dissenters of the 1980s were the classical liberals disciples of F A Hayek from whom they had learned about the crucial importance of economic freedom and about the often ignored conceptual difference between liberalism and democracy 277 Andrzej Walicki History Notre Dame Estonian Prime Minister Mart Laar came to my office the other day to recount his country s remarkable transformation He described a nation of people who are harder working more virtuous yes more virtuous because the market punishes immorality and more hopeful about the future than they ve ever been in their history I asked Mr Laar where his government got the idea for these reforms Do you know what he replied He said We read Milton Friedman and F A Hayek 278 United States Representative Dick Armey I was 25 years old and pursuing my doctorate in economics when I was allowed to spend six months of post graduate studies in Naples Italy I read the Western economic textbooks and also the more general work of people like Hayek By the time I returned to Czechoslovakia I had an understanding of the principles of the market In 1968 I was glad at the political liberalism of the Dubcek Prague Spring but was very critical of the Third Way they pursued in economics 279 Vaclav Klaus former President of the Czech Republic Personal life edit nbsp Hayek s grave in Neustifter Friedhof Vienna In August 1926 Hayek married Helen Berta Maria von Fritsch 1901 1960 a secretary at the civil service office where he worked They had two children together 280 Upon the close of World War II Hayek restarted a relationship with an old girlfriend who had married since they first met but kept it secret until 1948 Hayek and Fritsch divorced in July 1950 and he married his cousin 281 Helene Bitterlich 1900 1996 282 just a few weeks later after moving to Arkansas to take advantage of permissive divorce laws 283 His wife and children were offered settlement and compensation for accepting a divorce The divorce caused some scandal at LSE where certain academics refused to have anything to do with Hayek 283 In a 1978 interview to explain his actions Hayek stated that he was unhappy in his first marriage and as his wife would not grant him a divorce he had taken steps to obtain one unilaterally 284 For a time after his divorce Hayek rarely visited his children but kept up more regular contact with them in his older years after moving to Europe 281 285 Hayek s son Laurence Hayek 1934 2004 was a distinguished microbiologist 286 His daughter Christine was an entomologist at the British Museum of Natural History and she cared for him during his last years when he had declining health 285 287 Hayek had a lifelong interest in biology and was also concerned with ecology and environmental protection After being awarded his Nobel Prize he offered his name to be used for endorsements by World Wildlife Fund National Audubon Society and the National Trust a British conservationist organisation Evolutionary biology was simply one of his interests in natural sciences Hayek also had an interest in epistemology which he often applied to his own thinking as a social scientist He held that methodological differences in the social sciences and in natural sciences were key to understanding why incompetent policies are often allowed 288 289 Hayek was brought up in a non religious setting and decided from age 15 that he was an agnostic 47 He died in 1992 in Freiburg Germany where he had lived since leaving Chicago in 1961 Despite his advanced age by the 1980s he continued to write even purportedly finishing a book The Fatal Conceit in 1988 although its actual authorship is unclear 13 290 Legacy and honours edit nbsp A street sign named for Hayek in Freiburg im Breisgau Germany Hayek s intellectual presence has remained evident in the years following his death especially in the universities where he had taught namely the London School of Economics the University of Chicago and the University of Freiburg His influence and contributions have been noted by many A number of tributes have resulted many established posthumously The Hayek Society a student run group at the London School of Economics was established in his honour 291 The Oxford Hayek Society founded in 1983 is named after Hayek 292 The Cato Institute named its lower level auditorium after Hayek who had been a Distinguished Senior Fellow at Cato during his later years 293 The auditorium of the school of economics in Universidad Francisco Marroquin in Guatemala is named after him The Hayek Fund for Scholars 294 of the Institute for Humane Studies provides financial awards for academic career activities of graduate students and untenured faculty members The Ludwig von Mises Institute holds a lecture named after Hayek every year at its Austrian Scholars Conference and invites notable academics to speak about subjects relating to Hayek s contributions to the Austrian School George Mason University has an economics essay award named in honour of Hayek 295 The Mercatus Center a free market think tank also at George Mason University who has a philosophy politics and economics program of study named for Hayek The Mont Pelerin Society has a quadrennial economics essay contest named in his honour Hayek was awarded honorary degrees from Rikkyo University University of Vienna and University of Salzburg 296 Hayek has an investment portfolio named after him The Hayek Fund 297 invests in corporations who financially support free market public policy organisations 1974 Austrian Decoration for Science and Art 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences Sweden 298 1977 Pour le Merite for Science and Art Germany 299 1983 Honorary Ring of Vienna 1984 Honorary Dean of WHU Otto Beisheim School of Management 1984 Hanns Martin Schleyer Prize 1984 Member of the Order of the Companions of Honour United Kingdom 300 1990 Grand Gold Medal with Star for Services to the Republic of Austria 301 1991 Presidential Medal of Freedom United States 129 1994 The FA Hayek Scholarship in Economics or Political Science University of Canterbury The scholarship supports students toward study for an honours or master s degree in the Economics or Political Science at the university It was established in 1994 by a gift from entrepreneur Alan Gibbs 302 Notable works editMain article Friedrich Hayek bibliography The Road to Serfdom 1944 Individualism and Economic Order 1948 The Constitution of Liberty 1960 The Definitive Edition 2011 Description and preview Law Legislation and Liberty 3 volumes Volume I Rules and Order 1973 303 Volume II The Mirage of Social Justice 1976 304 Volume III The Political Order of a Free People 1979 305 The Fatal Conceit The Errors of Socialism 1988 Note that the authorship of The Fatal Conceit is under scholarly dispute 306 The book in its published form may actually have been written entirely by its editor W W Bartley III and not by Hayek 307 See also editNeoliberalism Constructivist epistemology Hayek Lecture Fear the Boom and Bust a series of music videos produced by the Mercatus Center in which Keynes and Hayek take part in a rap battle Global financial system which describes the financial system consisting of institutions and regulators that act on the international level History of economic thought Liberalism in Austria John Maynard KeynesReferences edit Laurence Hayek Microbiologist who in later life commemorated his father s work The Times 31 6 August 2004 Ebenstein Alan O 2003 Hayek s Journey the mind of Friedrich Hayek First Palgrave Macmillan ed New York Palgrave Macmillan ISBN 978 1403960382 Caldwell Bruce 2004 Hayek s Challenge an intellectual biography of F A Hayek Chicago University of Chicago Press ISBN 0 226 09193 7 Schmidtz David Boettke Peter Summer 2021 Friedrich Hayek Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy Gamble Andrew 1996 Hayek The Iron Cage of Liberty Routledge p 1 ISBN 978 0 367 00974 8 a b Bank of Sweden 1974 The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1974 Skarbek David March 2009 F A Hayek s Influence on Nobel Prize Winners PDF Review of Austrian Economics 22 1 109 112 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 207 1605 doi 10 1007 s11138 008 0069 x S2CID 144970753 Archived from the original PDF on 27 July 2011 Friedrich August von Hayek Facts nobelprize org Retrieved 30 June 2017 Rothbard Murray N 28 January 2010 Hayek and the Nobel Prize Mises Institute Retrieved 30 June 2017 a b Friedrich A Hayek Mises Institute 20 June 2014 Retrieved 3 September 2019 Keynes v Hayek Giants of economics BBC 3 August 2011 Retrieved 4 September 2019 The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1974 NobelPrize org Retrieved 4 September 2019 a b c d e Peter G Klein 18 August 2014 Biography of F A Hayek 1899 1992 Mises Institute Aaron Director Founder of the field of Law and Economics www news uchicago edu Archived from the original on 11 March 2022 Retrieved 3 September 2019 a b c Commanding Heights The Chicago School on PBS www pbs org Retrieved 3 September 2019 Burczak Theodore A 12 October 2006 Socialism after Hayek University of Michigan Press ISBN 978 0472069514 Conservatives Need to Reread Their Hayek American Enterprise Institute AEI Retrieved 23 February 2023 van der Vossen Bas 2022 Libertarianism The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy Winter 2022 ed retrieved 23 February 2023 CLITEUR PAUL B 1990 Why Hayek is a Conservative ARSP Archiv fur Rechts und Sozialphilosophie Archives for Philosophy of Law and Social Philosophy 76 4 467 478 ISSN 0001 2343 JSTOR 23681094 Caldwell Bruce 1 September 2020 The Road to Serfdom after 75 Years Journal of Economic Literature 58 3 720 748 doi 10 1257 jel 20191542 ISSN 0022 0515 S2CID 201350365 Hayek Friedrich A 2011 Why I am not a Conservative The Constitution of Liberty Definitive ed The University of Chicago Press ISBN 978 0 226 31539 3 Schrepel Thibault January 2015 Friedrich Hayek s Contribution to Antitrust Law and Its Modern Application ICC Global Antitrust Review 199 216 SSRN 2548420 Ormerod Paul 2006 The fading of Friedman prospectmagazine co uk Retrieved 31 August 2019 a b Catlin George 1944 The Road to Serfdom Nature 154 3911 473 474 Bibcode 1944Natur 154 473C doi 10 1038 154473a0 S2CID 4071358 a b No 49768 The London Gazette Supplement 16 June 1984 p 4 a b c d Ebenstein 2001 p 305 Hanns Martin Schleyer Stiftung Stiftungs Preise Archived from the original on 25 February 2014 Retrieved 30 April 2013 George H W Bush 18 November 1991 Remarks on Presenting the Presidential Medal of Freedom Awards a b Arrow Kenneth J Bernheim B Douglas Feldstein Martin S McFadden Daniel L Poterba James M Solow Robert M 2011 100 Years of the American Economic Review The Top 20 Articles American Economic Review 101 1 1 8 doi 10 1257 aer 101 1 1 hdl 1721 1 114169 Alan Ebenstein 2003 Friedrich Hayek A Biography p 12 Caldwell Bruce Klausinger Hansjorg 2021 F A Hayek s genealogy PDF Duke University Center for the History of Political Economy CHOPE CHOPE Working Paper 2021 06 Durham NC doi 10 2139 ssrn 3844091 Ebenstein 2001 p 12 312 a b Ebenstein 2001 pp 62 248 284 Ebenstein 2001 p 7 Ebenstein 2001 pp 7 8 Ebenstein 2001 p 20 Note Von Juraschek was a statistician and was later employed by the Austrian government Ebenstein 2001 p 8 Janik Allan Family Relationships and Family Resemblances Hayek and Wittgenstein Erbacher Christian Friedrich August von Hayek s Draft Biography of Ludwig Wittgenstein Ebenstein 2001 p 245 Hayek on Hayek an autobiographical dialogue By Friedrich August Hayek Routledge 1994 p 51 Young Ludwig Wittgenstein s life 1889 1921 Brian McGuinness Oxford University Press 2005 p xii Hayek on Hayek an autobiographical dialogue By Friedrich August Hayek Routledge 1995 p 53 a b Ebenstein 2001 p 9 a b Ebenstein 2001 p 14 a b c Ebenstein 2001 p 13 a b UCLA Oral History 1978 Interviews with Friedrich Hayek pp 32 38 10 March 2001 Retrieved 14 September 2011 Kresge Stephen Wenar Leif 2005 Hayek on Hayek An Autobiographical Dialogue Routledge p 39 ISBN 978 0226320625 Friedrich August von Hayek link David Gordon 8 May 2009 Friedrich Hayek as a Teacher Adam James Tebble F A Hayek Continuum 2010 p 2 ISBN 978 0826435996 Deirdre N McCloskey 2000 How to Be Human Though an Economist U of Michigan Press p 33 ISBN 978 0472067442 Ebenstein 2001 p 28 Ebenstein 2001 p 22 a b Some Reflection on Hayek s The Sensory Order Caldwell 2004 a b The Sensory Order 1952 on learning Backhaus Jurgen G 2005 Entrepreneurship Money and Coordination Hayek s Theory of Cultural Evolution Edward Elgar Publishing p 48 ISBN 978 1845427955 Richard Arena Agnes Festre Nathalie Lazaric eds 2012 Handbook of Knowledge and Economics Edward Elgar Publishing p 133 ISBN 978 1781001028 kanopiadmin 30 July 2014 The Viennese Connection Alfred Schutz and the Austrian School Mises Institute Retrieved 2 January 2019 a b French Douglas 2013 Leeson Robert ed Hayek and Mises Hayek A Collaborative Biography Part 1 Influences from Mises to Bartley Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics Series London Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 80 92 doi 10 1057 9781137328564 6 ISBN 978 1137328564 retrieved 28 April 2021 A J Tebble F A Hayek Continuum International Publishing Group 2010 pp 4 5 Ebenstein 2001 p 33 Ebenstein 2001 p 35 a b Leeson Robert 2018 Hayek A Collaborative Biography Ebenstein 2001 p 23 Federici Michael Eric Voegelin The Restoration of Order ISI Books 2002 p 1 a b WIFO About WIFO 23 January 2013 Archived from the original on 23 January 2013 Retrieved 28 April 2021 Baxendale Toby 25 October 2010 The Battle of the Letters Keynes v Hayek 1932 Skidelsky v Besley 2010 The Cobden Centre Retrieved 14 September 2011 Info PDF thinkmarkets files wordpress com 2010 Malcolm Perrine McNair Richard Stockton Meriam Problems in business economics McGraw Hill 1941 p 504 Hayek 1945 Reader s Digest Road to Serfdom Reader s Digest Keynes v Hayek Two economic giants go head to head Business BBC News 2 August 2011 Galbraith J K 1991 Nicholas Kaldor Remembered Nicholas Kaldor and Mainstream Economics Confrontation or Convergence New York St Martin s Press ISBN 978 0312053567 Sir Arthur Lewis Autobiography Nobelprize org Retrieved 14 September 2011 Interview with David Rockefeller Archived from the original on 6 July 2009 No 34541 The London Gazette 12 August 1938 p 5182 a b Brittan Samuel 2004 Hayek Friedrich August 1899 1992 Oxford Dictionary of National Biography online ed Oxford University Press doi 10 1093 ref odnb 51095 Subscription or UK public library membership required Election of Fellows 1947 Econometrica 16 1 117 122 January 1948 JSTOR 1914293 kanopiadmin 18 August 2014 The Road to Serfdom Mises Institute Retrieved 28 April 2021 Ebenstein p 116 Ebenstein p 128 A J Tebble F A Hayek Continuum International Publishing Group 2010 p 8 Beam Christopher 3 January 2011 The Trouble With Liberty New York Magazine New York Media LLC Retrieved 7 November 2015 a b Mitch David 2015 Leeson Robert ed Morality versus Money Hayek s Move to the University of Chicago Hayek A Collaborative Biography Part IV England the Ordinal Revolution and the Road to Serfdom 1931 50 Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics London Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 215 255 doi 10 1057 9781137452603 7 ISBN 978 1137452603 retrieved 28 April 2021 Compton John 2020 The End of Empathy Oxford University Press Milton and Rose Friedman Two Lucky People Memoirs Chicago U of Chicago Press 1998 Ross B Emmett 2010 The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics Edward Elgar Publishing pp 164 200 266 267 ISBN 978 1849806664 Friedman Milton 1951 Neo Liberalism and its Prospects Farmand 89 93 Johan Van Overtveldt The Chicago School How the University of Chicago Assembled the Thinkers Who Revolutionized Economics and Business 2006 pp 7 341 46 a b Ebenstein 2001 p 270 Van Horn Robert 2015 Leeson Robert ed Hayek and the Chicago School Hayek A Collaborative Biography Part V Hayek s Great Society of Free Men Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics London Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 91 111 doi 10 1057 9781137478245 3 ISBN 978 1137478245 retrieved 28 April 2021 a b Ebenstein 2001 p 267 John Simon Guggenheim Foundation Friedrich August von Hayek Retrieved 28 April 2021 Biography Archived 17 July 2012 at the Wayback Machine at LibertyStory net Ebenstein 2001 p 253 Ebenstein p 195 a b F A Hayek The Constitution of Liberty London Routledge amp Kegan Paul 1960 Ebenstein p 203 F A Hayek on the Occasion of the Centenary of His Birth Ronald Hamowy Cato Institute a b Ebenstein 2001 p 209 Ebenstein 2001 p 218 Ebenstein 2001 p 209 210 Ebenstein p 218 a b Caldwell Bruce Montes Leonidas 26 September 2014 Friedrich Hayek and his visits to Chile PDF The Review of Austrian Economics 28 3 261 309 doi 10 1007 s11138 014 0290 8 S2CID 189953475 Ebenstein p 254 Ebenstein 2001 p 251 253 a b c The Prize in Economics 1974 Nobelprize org 9 October 1974 Retrieved 14 September 2011 a b Ebenstein p 263 Leeson Robert 1975 Gold amp Silver Newsletter Springer ISBN 978 3319952192 Klausinger H 2010 Hayek on Practical Business Cycle Research A Note In H Hagemann T Nishizawa Y Ikeda eds Austrian Economics in Transition From Carl Menger to Friedrich Hayek Klausinger H 2012 Editorial Notes The Collected Works of F A Hayek by F A Hayek Klausinger H ed vol VII Business Cycles Translation of Quote in the blog Hayek and the Stock Market Crash of 1929 So Much for His Predictive Powers 18 December 2011 Hayek Friedrich August 26 October 1929 Monatsberichte des Osterreichen Institutes fur Konjunkturforschung PDF p 182 The Road from Serfdom An Interview with F A Hayek Reason com 1 July 1992 Retrieved 28 April 2021 Friedrich August von Hayek Banquet Speech Nobelprize org 10 December 1974 Retrieved 14 September 2011 Ebenstein p 261 Richard Cockett Thinking the Unthinkable Think Tanks and the Economic Counter Revolution 1931 1983 Fontana 1995 pp 174 76 John Ranelagh Thatcher s People An Insider s Account of the Politics the Power and the Personalities Fontana 1992 p ix Ebenstein 2001 p 291 292 a b c Ebenstein 2001 p 293 Ebenstein 2001 p 294 Letters to the Editor Liberal pact with Labour The Times 31 March 1977 p 15 Letters to the Editor Liberal pact with Labour The Times 2 April 1977 p 15 Letters to the Editor German socialist aims The Times 13 April 1977 p 13 Letters to the Editor The dangers to personal liberty The Times 11 July 1978 p 15 Ebenstein 2001 p 300 301 Martin Anderson Revolution Harcourt Brace Jovanovich 1988 p 164 Ebenstein 2001 p 207 208 Ebenstein 2001 p 301 a b Nasar Sylvia 19 November 1991 Business Profile Neglected Economist Honored by President The New York Times ISSN 0362 4331 Retrieved 27 April 2021 Ebenstein 2001 p 317 About NYU Journal of Law amp Liberty Archived from the original on 17 May 2014 Retrieved 15 May 2014 Mises Ludwig 1912 Theory of Money and Credit Hayek Friedrich 1931 Prices and Production The Austrian Theory of Business Cycles Old Lessons For Modern Economic Policy Oppers International Monetary Fund a b Hayek Friedrich 2012 Good Money Part 2 University of Chicago Press p 202 ISBN 978 0226321196 See the chapter The collaboration with Keynes and the controversy with Hayek Heinz D Kurz and Neri Salvadori Piero Sraffa s contributions to economics in Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa s Legacy in Economics ed H D Kurz Cambridge Cambridge University Press 2000 pp 3 24 ISBN 978 0521580892 Hayek Friedrich 1989 The Collected Works of F A Hayek University of Chicago Press p 202 ISBN 978 0226320977 a b White Lawrence H 2008 Did Hayek and Robbins Deepen the Great Depression Journal of Money Credit and Banking 40 4 Wiley Blackwell 751 768 doi 10 1111 j 1538 4616 2008 00134 x JSTOR 25096276 a b c Nicholas Kaldor 1942 Professor Hayek and the Concertina Effect Economica 9 36 359 382 doi 10 2307 2550326 JSTOR 2550326 F A Hayek Reflection on the pure theory of money of Mr J M Keynes Economica 11 S 270 95 1931 F A Hayek Prices and Production Archived 12 August 2014 at the Wayback Machine London Routledge 1931 P Sraffa Dr Hayek on Money and Capital Economic Journal 42 S 42 53 1932 Bruce Caldwell Hayek s Challenge An Intellectual Biography of F A Hayek Chicago University of Chicago Press 2004 p 179 ISBN 0226091937 Nicholas Kaldor 1939 Capital Intensity and the Trade Cycle Economica 6 21 40 66 doi 10 2307 2549077 JSTOR 2549077 a b R W Garrison F A Hayek as Mr Fluctooations In Defense of Hayek s Technical Economics Hayek Society Journal LSE 5 2 1 2003 Hayek Friedrich 1941 Pure Theory of Capital Hayek and Friedman Head to Head Garrison Auburn University Mises Ludwig Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth a b Hayek Friedrich 1935 Collectivist Economic Planning G Routledge ISBN 978 1610161626 Lange O 1967 The Computer and the Market in Socialism Lange 1938 On the Economic Theory of Socialism University of Minnesota Press Milton Friedman Lange on Price Flexibility and Employment Essays in Positive Economics Hayek Friedrich 1937 Economics and Knowledge Hein Schreuder Coase Hayek and Hierarchy In S Lindenberg et Hein Schreuder dir Interdisciplinary Perspectives on Organization Studies Pergamon Press Douma Sytse and Hein Schreuder 2013 Economic Approaches to Organizations 5th edition London Pearson ISBN 978 0273735298 The Pure Theory of Capital pdf Chicago University of Chicago Press 1941 2007 Vol 12 of the Collected Works p 90 a b Caldwell Bruce Hayek Friedrich August von 1899 1992 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Third Edition Eds Steven N Durlauf and Lawrence E Blume Palgrave Macmillan 2018 Hayek Friedrich 1952 The Counter Revolution of Science Ropke Wilhelm The Moral Foundations of Civil Society Transaction Publishers ISBN 978 1412837859 via Google Books Gerald Edelman Neural Darwinism 1987 p 25 Joaquin Fuster Memory in the Cerebral Cortex An Empirical Approach to Neural Networks in the Human and Nonhuman Primate Cambridge MIT Press 1995 pp 87 88 Joaquin Fuster Network Memory Trends in Neurosciences 1997 Vol 20 No 10 Oct 451 459 van de Haar Edwin Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek Federation as Last Resort PDF Cosmos Taxis Studies in Emergent Order Retrieved 14 October 2022 Hayek Friedrich The Road to Serfdom The Collected Works of F A Hayek University of Chicago Press Retrieved 14 October 2022 Rosenboim Or 2014 Barbara Wootton Friedrich Hayek and the debate on democratic federalism in the 1940s The International History Review 36 5 894 918 doi 10 1080 07075332 2013 871320 JSTOR 24703266 S2CID 154887466 Retrieved 14 October 2022 van de Haar Edwin Hayekian Spontaneous Order and the International Balance of Power PDF The Independent Review Retrieved 14 October 2022 Hayek Friedrich 17 April 2017 The Economic Conditions of Interstate Federalism Foundation for Economic Education originally published in New Commonwealth Quarterly V No 2 September 1939 131 49 Retrieved 14 October 2022 Nientiedt Daniel F A Hayek and the World of Tomorrow The Principles of International Federalism PDF Cosmos Taxis Studies in Emergent Order Retrieved 14 October 2022 Masini Fabio Hayek s Federalism and the Making of European Integration PDF Cosmos Taxis Studies in Emergent Order Retrieved 14 October 2022 Christensen Brandon Reviving the Libertarian Interstate Federalist Tradition The American Proposal PDF The Independent Review Retrieved 14 October 2022 Spieker Jorg 2014 F A Hayek and the Reinvention of Liberal Internationalism The International History Review 36 5 919 942 doi 10 1080 07075332 2014 900814 S2CID 143713445 Retrieved 14 October 2022 a b Hayek Friedrich August 1980 Individualism and economic order Reprint ed Chicago London the University of Chicago press ISBN 0 226 32093 6 Hayek Friedrich A von 2011 The constitution of liberty the definitive edition Chicago Ill Univ of Chicago Press ISBN 978 0 226 31539 3 Hayek Friedrich A von 2012 Law legislation and liberty a new statement of the liberal principles of justice and political economy London u a Routledge ISBN 978 0 415 52229 8 Ferguson Adam 1767 An Essay on the History of Civil Society Project Gutenberg T Cadell London p 205 Ebeling Richard M 6 January 2018 Price Is the Only Language that Everyone Speaks Richard M Ebeling fee org Retrieved 28 April 2021 a b Hayek Friedrich 1988 The Fatal Conceit de Benoist Alain 1998 Hayek A Critique Telos 1998 110 71 104 doi 10 3817 1298110071 S2CID 219203705 Lamey Andy 24 September 2014 Ecosystems as Spontaneous Orders SSRN 2501745 Lamey Andy 24 September 2014 Ecosystems as Spontaneous Orders pp 2 11 SSRN 2501745 Lamey Andy 24 September 2014 Ecosystems as Spontaneous Orders pp 12 13 SSRN 2501745 Essential Hayek PDF Fraser Institute Archived from the original PDF on 28 April 2021 Retrieved 28 April 2021 Chang Ha Joon 2014 4 Economics The User s Guide London Penguin Books Limited ISBN 978 0718197032 Hayek F A The Road to Serfdom Ch 9 Stringham Edward Zywicki Todd 20 January 2011 Hayekian Anarchism SSRN 1744364 Hayek on Social Insurance The Washington Post Hayek Friedrich 1976 The Denationalization of Money Hayek Friedrich 2011 1960 Hamowy Ronald ed The Constitution of Liberty Definitive ed Chicago University of Chicago Press p 405 ISBN 978 0 226 31539 3 Wapshott Nicholas 2011 Keynes Hayek The Clash That Defined Modern Economics New York W W Norton amp Company p 291 Harcourt Bernard 12 September 2012 How Paul Ryan enslaves Friedrich Hayek s The Road to Serfdom The Guardian Retrieved 27 December 2014 Hayek Friedrich 2007 1944 Caldwell Bruce ed The Road to Serfdom Definitive ed Chicago University of Chicago Press pp 147 148 ISBN 978 0226320557 Hayek Friedrich 1976 Law Legislation and Liberty Vol 2 Chicago University of Chicago Press p 87 ISBN 978 0226320830 Tebble Adam James 2009 Hayek and social justice a critique Critical Review of International Social and Political Philosophy 12 4 581 604 doi 10 1080 13698230903471343 S2CID 145380847 The Mirage of Social Justice chap 10 a b The Mirage of Social Justice chap 12 The Constitution of Liberty chap 6 Diamond Arthur M Fall 1980 F A Hayek on Constructivism and Ethics The Journal of Libertarian Studies IV 4 353 365 Kukathas Chandran 1990 Hayek and Modern Liberalism Oxford University Press p 215 N P Barry 1994 The road to freedom Hayek s social and economic philosophy in Birner J and van Zijp R eds Hayek Co ordination and Evolution His Legacy in Philosophy Politics Economics and the History of Ideas pp 141 163 London Routledge Milton Friedman and Anna J Schwartz Has Government Any Role in Money 1986 John Gray The Friedrich Hayek I knew and what he got right and wrong 30 July 2015 Bruce Caldwell Hayek s Challenge An Intellectual Biography of F A Hayek Chicago University of Chicago Press 2004 pp 347 348 a b Farrant Andrew McPhail Edward Berger Sebastian 2012 Preventing the Abuses of Democracy Hayek the Military Usurper and Transitional Dictatorship in Chile American Journal of Economics and Sociology 71 3 513 538 doi 10 1111 j 1536 7150 2012 00824 x Greg Grandin professor of history New York University Empire s Workshop Latin America the United States and the Rise of the New Imperialism pp 172 173 Metropolitan 2006 ISBN 0805077383 Dan Avnon Liberalism and its Practice p 56 Routledge 1999 ISBN 0415193540 Preventing the Abuses of Democracy Hayek the Military Usurper and Transitional Dictatorship in Chile PDF The American Journal of Economics and Sociology Hayek Friedrich 1979 Law Legislation and Liberty Volume 3 The Political Order of a Free People Routledge 1982 p 195 Hayek Friedrich 1979 Law Legislation and Liberty Volume 3 The Political Order of a Free People Routledge 1982 p 56 a b Hayek Friedrich 1976 Law Legislation and Liberty Volume 2 The Mirage of Social Justice Routledge 1982 p 58 a b Ebenstein 2001 p 390 Ebenstein 2001 p 295 Leeson Robert 2015 Hayek A Collaborative Biography Part II Austria America and the Rise of Hitler 1899 1933 Palgrave Macmillan 2015 p 112 a b Leeson Robert 2018 Hayek A Collaborative Biography Part XV The Chicago School of Economics Hayek s Luck and the 1974 Nobel Prize for Economic Science Palgrave Macmillan 2015 p 175 Ebenstein 2001 p 299 Leeson Robert 2015 Hayek A Collaborative Biography Part II Austria America and the Rise of Hitler 1899 1933 Palgrave Macmillan 2015 p 85 Slobodian Quinn 2018 Globalists The End of Empire and the Birth of Neoliberalism Harvard University Press Cambridge MA p 154 Hayek Friedrich 1960 The Constitution of Liberty Routledge 2006 p 76 Hayek Friedrich 1960 The Constitution of Liberty Routledge 2006 p 109 Hayek Friedrich 1960 The Constitution of Liberty Routledge 2006 p 111 a b Hayek Friedrich 1960 The Constitution of Liberty Routledge 2006 p 110 Hayek Friedrich 1960 The Constitution of Liberty Routledge 2006 p 113 Hayek Friedrich 1960 The Constitution of Liberty Routledge 2006 p 112 Hayek Friedrich 1960 The Constitution of Liberty Routledge 2006 p 80 Hayek Friedrich 1960 The Constitution of Liberty Routledge 2006 p 270 Hayek Friedrich 1960 The Constitution of Liberty Routledge 2006 p 269 Hayek Friedrich 1960 The Constitution of Liberty Routledge 2006 p 273 Tebble Adam James 1 December 2009 Hayek and social justice a critique Critical Review of International Social and Political Philosophy 12 4 581 604 doi 10 1080 13698230903471343 ISSN 1369 8230 S2CID 145380847 Fukuyama Francis 6 May 2011 Friedrich A Hayek Big Government Skeptic The New York Times ISSN 0362 4331 Retrieved 25 February 2023 Boettke Peter J 1995 Hayek s the Road to Serfdom Revisited Government Failure in the Argument against Socialism Eastern Economic Journal 21 1 7 26 ISSN 0094 5056 JSTOR 40325611 Skarbek David 2009 F A Hayek s Influence on Nobel Prize Winners Review of Austrian Economics 22 1 109 112 doi 10 1007 s11138 008 0069 x S2CID 144970753 Smith Smith Vernon 1999 Reflections on Human Action after 50 years PDF Cato Journal 19 2 Hayek in my view is the leading economic thinker of the 20th century Simon Simon Herbert 1981 The Sciences of the Artificial 2nd ed Cambridge The MIT Press No one has characterized market mechanisms better than Friedrich von Hayek 41 Samuelson Paul A 2009 A few remembrances of Friedrich von Hayek 1899 1992 Journal of Economic Behavior amp Organization 69 1 4 doi 10 1016 j jebo 2008 07 001 The collected scientific papers of Paul A Samuelson Volume 5 p 315 Fritz Machlup Essays on Hayek Routledge 2003 p 14 Sylvia Nasar Grand Pursuit The Story of Economic Genius Simon and Schuster 2011 p 402 Lawrence Summers quoted in The Commanding Heights The Battle Between Government and the Marketplace that Is Remaking the Modern World by Daniel Yergin and Joseph Stanislaw New York Simon amp Schuster 1998 pp 150 151 Distinguished Members of The Philadelphia Society PDF Archived from the original PDF on 18 January 2012 Retrieved 5 May 2012 See Hacohen 2000 See Weimer and Palermo 1982 See Birner 2001 and for the mutual influence they had on each other s ideas on evolution Birner 2009 Milton amp Rose Friedman Two Lucky People Memoirs U of Chicago Press 1998 p 333 Ebenstein 2001 p 266 Ebenstein 2001 p 271 Ebenstein 2001 p 272 Ebenstein 2001 p 81 e g Wolin 2004 Ebenstein 2001 p 275 Berliner M S ed Letters of Ayn Rand New York Dutton 1995 p 299 Ebenstein 2001 p 274 Wikipedia s Model Follows Hayek The Wall Street Journal 15 April 2009 Phaneuf Emile Hayek and Bitcoin AIER www aier org Retrieved 28 March 2024 Pollock Alex J 30 March 2022 Are Cryptocurrencies the Great Hayekian Escape Alex J Pollock Law amp Liberty Retrieved 28 March 2024 Kenneth R Hoover Economics as Ideology Keynes Laski Hayek and the Creation of Contemporary Politics 2003 p 213 Soderbaum Jakob E son 2020 Modern konservatism Filosofi barande ideer och inriktningar i Burkes efterfoljd Boras Recito pp 38 116 117 269 ISBN 978 91 7765 497 1 Fawcett Edmund 2018 Liberalism The Life of an Idea 2 ed Princeton University Press p 327 ISBN 9780691180380 Hazlett Thomas W 1 September 1979 F A Hayek Classical Liberal Thomas W Hazlett fee org Retrieved 28 April 2021 Bogus Carl 2011 Buckley Bloomsbury Publishing USA ISBN 978 1608193554 E H H Green Ideologies of Conservatism Conservative Political Ideas in the Twentieth Century Oxford Oxford University Press 2004 p 259 a b Samuel Brittan The many faces of liberalism ft com 22 January 2010 F A Hayek MPS Archived from the original on 14 February 2016 Retrieved 28 April 2021 Hoerber Thomas 2019 Hoerber Thomas Anquetil Alain eds The Roots of Neoliberalism in Friedrich von Hayek Economic Theory and Globalization Cham Springer International Publishing pp 169 194 doi 10 1007 978 3 030 23824 7 8 ISBN 978 3030238247 S2CID 202307278 retrieved 28 April 2021 Boettke Peter J 2002 Why Perestroika Failed The Politics and Economics of Socialist Transformation Routledge ISBN 978 1134886319 Retrieved 2 January 2019 McKinnon Ronald 1992 Spontaneous Order on the Road Back from Socialism An Asian Perspective American Economic Review 82 2 American Economic Association 31 36 JSTOR 2117371 Easterly William 2006 The White Man s Burden Why the West s Efforts to Aid the Rest Have Done So Much Ill and So Little Good Penguin Books ISBN 978 1101218129 White William R 2009 Modern Macroeconomics is on the Wrong Track PDF Finance amp Development International Monetary Fund Hoffmann Andreas Schnabl Gunther 2011 A Vicious Cycle of Manias Crises and Asymmetric Policy Responses An Overinvestment View The World Economy 34 3 Wiley 382 403 doi 10 1111 j 1467 9701 2011 01334 x S2CID 153097003 SSRN 1513171 Schnabl Gunther Hoffmann Andreas 2008 Monetary Policy Vagabonding Liquidity and Bursting Bubbles in New and Emerging Markets An Overinvestment View PDF The World Economy 31 9 Wiley 1226 1252 doi 10 1111 j 1467 9701 2008 01126 x S2CID 154603748 SSRN 1018342 Cachanosky Nicolas 2014 The Effects of U S Monetary Policy in Colombia and Panama 2002 2007 The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance Vol 54 no 3 Elsevier pp 428 436 SSRN 2170566 Brunnermeier Markus K Schnabel Isabel 9 June 2016 12 Bubbles and Central Banks Historical Perspectives In Bordo Michael D Eitrheim Oyvind Flandreau Marc Qvigstad Jan F eds Central Banks at a Crossroads What Can We Learn from History New York Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 1107149663 Taylor John B 2007 Housing and Monetary Policy PDF Report NBER Working Papers Vol 13682 National Bureau of Economic Research Lawrence H White on Monetary Policy Free Banking and the Financial Crisis Mercatus mercatus org 13 December 2011 Retrieved 19 September 2016 Sumner Scott B 2014 Nominal GDP Targeting A Simple Rule to Improve Fed Performance PDF Cato Journal Vol 34 no 2 Cato Institute pp 315 337 Retrieved 24 July 2019 Hayek Friedrich 2008 Salerno Joseph T ed Prices and Production and Other Works on Money the Business Cycle and the Gold Standard PDF Auburn AL Ludwig von Mises Institute p 297 ISBN 978 1933550220 Archived from the original PDF on 31 July 2020 Retrieved 24 July 2019 Hayek Friedrich 9 April 1975 A Discussion with Friedrich A von Hayek PDF Interview Washington D C American Enterprise Institute pp 12 13 ISBN 0844731900 Hoffmann Andreas Schnabl Gunther 2016 Adverse Effects of Unconventional Monetary Policy PDF Cato Journal 36 3 Cato Institute Transcript for Friedrich Hayek pbs org Retrieved 14 February 2015 Andrzy Walicki Liberalism in Poland Critical Review Winter 1988 p 9 Dick Armey Address at the Dedication of the Hayek Auditorium Cato Institute Washington DC 9 May 1995 Vaclav Klaus No Third Way Out Creating a Capitalist Czechoslovakia Reason 1990 June 28 31 Ebenstein p 44 a b Ebenstein 2001 p 169 Ebenstein p 169 a b Ebenstein p 155 Armen A Alchian interviews Friedrich A Hayek Part I The Hayek Interviews Event occurs at 48 50 Archived from the original on 31 August 2021 Retrieved 31 August 2021 a b Ebenstein 2001 p 297 Laurence Hayek The Independent 7 September 2004 Ebenstein 2001 p 316 Beck Naomi December 2009 In Search of the Proper Scientific Approach Hayek s Views on Biology Methodology and the Nature of Economics Science in Context 22 4 567 585 doi 10 1017 S0269889709990160 ISSN 1474 0664 PMID 20509429 S2CID 46364934 Ebenstein 2001 p 225 Liberty The Fatal Deceit 22 June 2008 Archived from the original on 22 June 2008 Retrieved 1 June 2022 Hayek www lsesu com Ellis Lydia About the Oxford Hayek Society Oxford Hayek Society Archived from the original on 4 March 2016 Retrieved 6 November 2015 Housing Crisis Should Urban Areas Grow Up or Grow Out to Keep Housing Affordable Cato Institute 29 November 2016 Retrieved 27 April 2021 Hayek Fund for Scholars Institute For Humane Studies Theihs org Archived from the original on 16 July 2009 Retrieved 14 September 2011 Economics F A Hayek Essay Awards Economics Retrieved 27 April 2021 The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1974 NobelPrize org Retrieved 27 April 2021 Hayekfund com Hayekfund com Archived from the original on 20 September 2011 Retrieved 14 September 2011 The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1974 NobelPrize org Retrieved 27 April 2021 Friedrich August von Hayek Orden Pour le Merite www orden pourlemerite de Retrieved 27 April 2021 Companion of Honour 1984 Awarded by Queen Elizabeth II Reply to a parliamentary question PDF in German p 885 Retrieved 24 February 2013 F A Hayek Scholarship in Political Science or Economics PDF Hayek F A 1978 Law Legislation and Liberty Volume University of Chicago Press ISBN 978 0226320861 Retrieved 14 September 2011 via Google Books Hayek F A 1978 Law Legislation and Liberty Volume University of Chicago Press ISBN 978 0226320830 Retrieved 14 September 2011 via Google Books Hayek F A 1981 Law Legislation and Liberty Volume 3 The Political Order of a Free People University of Chicago Press ISBN 978 0226320908 Alan Ebenstein Investigation The Fatal Deceit Archived 12 February 2008 at the Wayback Machine Liberty 19 3 March 2005 Ian Jarvie Editor Karl Milford Editor David Miller Editor 2006 Karl Popper a Centenary Assessment Vol 1 Life and Times and Values in a World of Facts pp 120 295 ISBN 978 0754653752 Bibliography edit Birner Jack 2001 The mind body problem and social evolution CEEL Working Paper 1 02 Birner Jack and Rudy van Zijp eds 1994 Hayek Co ordination and Evolution His legacy in philosophy politics economics and the history of ideas ISBN missing Birner Jack 2009 From group selection to ecological niches Popper s rethinking of evolutionary theory in the light of Hayek s theory of culture in S Parusnikova amp R S Cohen eds Spring 2009 Rethinking Popper Boston Studies in the Philosophy of Science Vol 272 Boettke Peter J 1995 Hayek s the Road to Serfdom Revisited Government Failure in the Argument against Socialism Eastern Economic Journal 21 1 7 26 JSTOR 40325611 Brittan Samuel 2004 Hayek Friedrich August 1899 1992 Oxford Dictionary of National Biography online ed Oxford University Press doi 10 1093 ref odnb 51095 Subscription or UK public library membership required Caldwell Bruce 2005 Hayek s Challenge An Intellectual Biography of F A Hayek ISBN missing Caldwell Bruce 1997 Hayek and Socialism Journal of Economic Literature 35 4 1856 1890 JSTOR 2729881 Cohen Avi J 2003 The Hayek Knight Capital Controversy the Irrelevance of Roundaboutness or Purging Processes in Time History of Political Economy 35 3 469 490 ISSN 0018 2702 Fulltext online in Project Muse Swetswise and Ebsco Clave Francis 2015 Comparative Study of Lippmann s and Hayek s Liberalisms or neo liberalisms The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22 6 978 999 doi 10 1080 09672567 2015 1093522 S2CID 146137987 Doherty Brian 2007 Radicals for Capitalism A Freewheeling History of the Modern American Libertarian Movement ISBN missing Douma Sytse and Hein Schreuder 2013 Economic Approaches to Organizations 5th edition London Pearson ISBN 978 0273735298 Ebeling Richard M March 2004 F A Hayek and The Road to Serfdom A Sixtieth Anniversary Appreciation The Freeman Ebeling Richard M March 2001 F A Hayek A Biography Ludwig von Mises Institute Ebeling Richard M May 1999 Friedrich A Hayek A Centenary Appreciation The Freeman Ebenstein Alan 2001 Friedrich Hayek A Biography Basingstoke Palgrave Macmillan Trade ISBN 978 0312233440 Feldman Jean Philippe 1999 Hayek s Critique of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines 9 4 1145 6396 doi 10 2202 1145 6396 1172 Frowen S ed 1997 Hayek economist and social philosopher Gamble Andrew 1996 The Iron Cage of Liberty an analysis of Hayek s ideas ISBN missing Goldsworthy J D 1986 Hayek s Political and Legal Philosophy An Introduction 1986 SydLawRw 3 11 1 Sydney Law Review 44 Gray John 1998 Hayek on Liberty ISBN missing Hacohen Malach 2000 Karl Popper The Formative Years 1902 1945 ISBN missing Hamowy Ronald 2008 Hayek Friedrich A 1899 1992 The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism Thousand Oaks CA Sage Cato Institute pp 218 220 doi 10 4135 9781412965811 n131 ISBN 978 1412965804 LCCN 2008009151 OCLC 750831024 Horwitz Steven 2005 Friedrich Hayek Austrian Economist Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27 1 71 85 ISSN 1042 7716 Fulltext in Swetswise Ingenta and Ebsco Issing O 1999 Hayek currency competition and European monetary union ISBN missing Jones Daniel Stedman 2012 Masters of the Universe Hayek Friedman and the Birth of Neoliberal Politics Princeton University Press 424 pages Kasper Sherryl 2002 The Revival of Laissez Faire in American Macroeconomic Theory A Case Study of Its Pioneers Chpt 4 Kley Roland 1994 Hayek s Social and Political Thought Oxford Univ Press ISBN missing Leeson Robert ed Hayek A Collaborative Biography Part I Influences from Mises to Bartley Palgrave MacMillan 2013 241 pages ISBN missing Muller Jerry Z 2002 The Mind and the Market Capitalism in Western Thought Anchor Books ISBN missing Marsh Leslie Ed 2011 Hayek in Mind Hayek s Philosophical Psychology Advances in Austrian Economics Emerald ISBN missing O Shea Jerry 2020 Hayek s Spiritual Science Modern Intellectual History First View pp 1 26 doi 10 1017 S1479244320000517 Pavlik Jan 2004 nb vse cz Archived 16 February 2012 at the Wayback Machine F A von Hayek and The Theory of Spontaneous Order Professional Publishing 2004 Prague profespubl cz Plant Raymond 2009 The Neo liberal State Oxford University Press 312 pages ISBN missing Pressman Steven 2006 Fifty major economists 2nd ed London Routledge Rosenof Theodore 1974 Freedom Planning and Totalitarianism The Reception of F A Hayek s Road to Serfdom Canadian Review of American Studies Samuelson Paul A 2009 A Few Remembrances of Friedrich von Hayek 1899 1992 Journal of Economic Behavior amp Organization 69 1 pp 1 4 Reprinted at J Bradford DeLong lt eblog Samuelson Richard A 1999 Reaction to the Road to Serfdom Modern Age 41 4 309 317 ISSN 0026 7457 Fulltext in Ebsco Schreuder Hein 1993 Coase Hayek and Hierarchy In S Lindenberg amp Hein Schreuder eds Interdisciplinary Perspectives on Organization Studies Oxford Pergamon Press ISBN missing Shearmur Jeremy 1996 Hayek and after Hayekian Liberalism as a Research Programme Routledge ISBN missing Tebble Adam James 2009 Hayek and social justice a critique Critical Review of International Social and Political Philosophy 12 4 581 604 doi 10 1080 13698230903471343 S2CID 145380847 Tebble Adam James 2013 F A Hayek Bloomsbury Academic ISBN 978 1441109064 OCLC 853506722 Touchie John 2005 Hayek and Human Rights Foundations for a Minimalist Approach to Law Edward Elgar ISBN missing Vanberg V 2001 Hayek Friedrich A von 1899 1992 International Encyclopedia of the Social amp Behavioral Sciences pp 6482 6486 doi 10 1016 B0 08 043076 7 00254 0 Vernon Richard 1976 The Great Society and the Open Society Liberalism in Hayek and Popper Canadian Journal of Political Science 9 2 261 276 doi 10 1017 s0008423900043717 S2CID 146616606 Wapshott Nicholas 2011 Keynes Hayek The Clash That Defined Modern Economics W W Norton amp Company 382 pages ISBN 978 0393077483 covers the debate with Keynes in letters articles conversation and by the two economists disciples Weimer W and Palermo D eds 1982 Cognition and the Symbolic Processes Lawrence Erlbaum Associates Contains Hayek s essay The Sensory Order after 25 Years with Discussion Wolin Richard 2004 The Seduction of Unreason The Intellectual Romance with Fascism from Nietzsche to Postmodernism Princeton University Press Princeton ISBN missing Introductions edit Boudreaux Donald J 2014 The Essential Hayek ISBN missing Butler Eamonn 2012 Friedrich Hayek The Ideas and Influence of the Libertarian Economist ISBN missing Primary sources edit Hayek Friedrich The Collected Works of F A Hayek ed W W Bartley III and others University of Chicago Press 1988 Plan of the Collected Works of F A Hayek for 19 volumes vol 2 excerpt and text search vol 7 2012 excerpt External links edit nbsp Wikiquote has quotations related to Friedrich Hayek nbsp Wikimedia Commons has media related to Friedrich von Hayek Friedrich Hayek on Nobelprize org nbsp with the Nobel lecture 11 December 1974 The Pretence of Knowledge Register of the Friedrich A von Hayek Papers at the Hoover Institution Archives Friedrich Hayek publications indexed by Google Scholar Friedrich August Hayek 1899 1992 The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics Library of Economics and Liberty 2nd ed Liberty Fund 2008 F A Hayek at Curlie Portraits of Friedrich Hayek at the National Portrait Gallery London nbsp Friedrich von Hayek in German from the online archive of the Osterreichische Mediathek Works by or about Friedrich Hayek at Internet Archive Portals nbsp Austria nbsp Economics nbsp History nbsp Liberalism nbsp Libertarianism nbsp Philosophy nbsp Politics Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Friedrich Hayek amp oldid 1220107736, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.