fbpx
Wikipedia

Praxeology

In philosophy, praxeology or praxiology (/ˌpræksiˈɒləi/; from Ancient Greek πρᾶξις (praxis) 'deed, action', and -λογία (-logia) 'study of') is the theory of human action, based on the notion that humans engage in purposeful behavior, contrary to reflexive behavior and other unintentional behavior.

French social philosopher Alfred Espinas gave the term its modern meaning, and praxeology was developed independently by two principal groups: the Austrian school, led by Ludwig von Mises, and the Polish school, led by Tadeusz Kotarbiński.[1]

Origin and etymology

Coinage of the word praxeology (praxéologie) is often credited to Louis Bourdeau, the French author of a classification of the sciences, which he published in his Théorie des sciences: Plan de Science intégrale in 1882:

On account of their dual natures of specialty and generality, these functions should be the subject of a separate science. Some of its parts have been studied for a long time, because this kind of research, in which man could be the main subject, has always presented the greatest interest. Physiology, hygiene, medicine, psychology, animal history, human history, political economy, morality, etc. represent fragments of a science that we would like to establish, but as fragments scattered and uncoordinated have remained until now only parts of particular sciences. They should be joined together and made whole in order to highlight the order of the whole and its unity. Now you have a science, so far unnamed, which we propose to call Praxeology (from πραξις, action), or by referring to the influence of the environment, Mesology (from μεσος, environment).[2]

However, the term was used at least once previously (with a slight spelling difference), in 1608, by Clemens Timpler in his Philosophiae practicae systema methodicum:

There was Aretology: Following that Praxiology: which is the second part of the Ethics, in general, commenting on the actions of the moral virtues.[3]

It was later mentioned by Robert Flint in 1904 in a review of Bourdeau's Théorie des sciences.[4]

The modern definition of the word was first given by Alfred V. Espinas (1844–1922),[5] the French philosopher and sociologist; he was the forerunner of the Polish school of the science of efficient action. The Austrian school of economics was based on a philosophical science of the same kind.

With a different spelling, the word was used by the English psychologist Charles Arthur Mercier (in 1911), and proposed by Knight Dunlap to John B. Watson as a better name for his behaviorism.[6][page needed] Watson rejected it. But the Chinese physiologist of behavior, Zing-Yang Kuo (b. 1898) adopted the term in 1935.[7][page needed] It was also used by William McDougall (in 1928 and later).[8][full citation needed]

Previously the word praxiology, with the meaning Espinas gave to it, was used by Tadeusz Kotarbiński (in 1923). Several economists, such as the Ukrainian, Eugene Slutsky (1926) used it in his attempt to base economics on a theory of action. It was also used by Austrian economist Ludwig von Mises (1933), Russian Marxist Nikolai Bukharin (1888–1938) during the Second International Congress of History of Science and Technology in London (in 1931), and Polish scholar Oscar Lange (1904–1965) in 1959, and later.[citation needed]

The Italian philosopher, Carmelo Ottaviano, was using the Italianised version, prassiologia, in his treatises starting from 1935, but in his own way, as a theory of politics. After the Second World War the use of the term praxeology spread widely. After the emigration of Mises to the US his pupil Murray Rothbard defended the praxeological approach. A revival of Espinas's approach in France was revealed in the works of Pierre Massé (1946), the eminent cybernetician, Georges Théodule Guilbaud (1953), the Belgian logician, Leo Apostel (1957), the cybernetician, Anatol Rapoport (1962), Henry Pierron, psychologist and lexicographer (1957), François Perroux, economist (1957), the social psychologist, Robert Daval (1963), the well-known sociologist, Raymond Aron (1963) and the methodologists, Abraham Antoine Moles and Roland Caude (1965).[citation needed]

Under the influence of Tadeusz Kotarbiński, praxeology flourished in Poland. A special "Centre of Praxeology" (Zaklad Prakseologiczny) was created under the organizational guidance of the Polish Academy of Sciences, with its own periodical (from 1962), called at first Materiały Prakseologiczne (Praxeological Papers), and then abbreviated to Prakseologia. It published hundreds of papers by different authors, and the materials for a special vocabulary edited by Professor Tadeusz Pszczolowski, the leading praxeologist of the younger generation. A sweeping survey of the praxeological approach is to be found in the paper by the French statistician Micheline Petruszewycz, "A propos de la praxéologie".[9]

Ludwig von Mises was influenced by several theories in forming his work on praxeology, including Immanuel Kant's works, Max Weber's work on methodological individualism, and Carl Menger's development of the subjective theory of value.[10]

Philosopher of science Mario Bunge published works of systematic philosophy that included contributions to praxeology.[11]: 407 

Austrian economics

Austrian economics in the tradition of Ludwig von Mises relies heavily on praxeology in the development of its economic theories.[12] Mises considered economics to be a sub-discipline of praxeology.[13] Austrian School economists, following Mises, use praxeology and deduction, rather than empirical studies, to determine economic principles. According to these theorists, with the action axiom as the starting point, it is possible to draw conclusions about human behavior that are both objective and universal. For example, the notion that humans engage in acts of choice implies that they have preferences, and this must be true for anyone who exhibits intentional behavior.[citation needed]

Advocates of praxeology also say that it provides insights for the field of ethics.[14]

Subdivisions

In 1951, Murray Rothbard divided the subfields of praxeology as follows:

A. The Theory of the Isolated Individual (Crusoe Economics)
B. The Theory of Voluntary Interpersonal Exchange (Catallactics, or the Economics of the Market)
1. Barter
2. With Medium of Exchange
a. On the Unhampered Market
b. Effects of Violent Intervention with the Market
c. Effects of Violent Abolition of the Market (Socialism)
C. The Theory of War – Hostile Action
D. The Theory of Games (Game Theory) (e.g., von Neumann and Morgenstern)
E. Unknown

At the time, topics C, D, and E were regarded by Rothbard as open research problems.[15]

Criticisms

Thomas Mayer has argued that, because praxeology rejects positivism and empiricism in the development of theories, it constitutes nothing less than a rejection of the scientific method. For Mayer, this invalidates the methodologies of the Austrian school of economics.[16][17] Austrians argue that empirical data itself is insufficient to describe economics; that consequently empirical data cannot falsify economic theory; that logical positivism cannot predict or explain human action; and that the methodological requirements of logical positivism are impossible to obtain for economic questions.[18][12] Ludwig von Mises in particular argued against empiricist approaches to the social sciences in general, because human events are unique and non-repeatable, whereas experiments in the physical sciences are necessarily reproducible.[18]

However, economist Antony Davies argues that because statistical tests are predicated on the independent development of theory, some form of praxeology is essential for model selection; conversely, praxeology can illustrate surprising philosophical consequences of economic models.[19]

Bunge dismissed von Mises's version of praxeology as "nothing but the principle of maximization of subjective utility—a fancy version of egoism".[11]: 394  Bunge, who was also a fierce critic of pseudoscience, warned that when "conceived in extremely general terms and detached from both ethics and science, praxiology has hardly any practical value".[11]: 394 

See also

References

  1. ^ Ryan, Leo V.; Nahser, F. Byron; Gasparski, Wojciech, eds. (2002). Praxiology and pragmatism. Praxiology: the international annual of practical philosophy and methodology. Vol. 10. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers. pp. 7–9. ISBN 978-0765801678. OCLC 49617735.
  2. ^ Bourdeau, Louis (1882). "Théorie des sciences: Plan de Science intégrale". Lilliad - Université de Lille - Sciences et Technologies. Tome Second: 463. Retrieved 4 February 2017. À raison de leur double caractère de spécialité et de généralité, les fonctions doivent constituer l'objet d'une science distincte. Quelques—unes de ses parties ont été étudiées de bonne heure, car ce genre de recherches, dont l'homme pouvait se faire le sujet principal, a présenté de tout temps le plus vif intérêt. La physiologie, l'hygiène, la médecine, la psychologie, l'histoire des animaux, l'histoire humaine, l'économie politique, la morale, etc., représentent des fragments de la science que nous voudrions établir; mais fragments, épars et sans coordination, sont restés a l'état de sciences particulières. Il faudrait les rapprocher et en faire un tout afin de mettre en lumière l'ordre de l'ensemble et son unité. On aurait alors une… science, innommée jusqu'ici et que nous proposons d'appeler Praxéologie (de πραξις, action), ou, en se référant a l'influence des milieu, Mésologie (de μεơος, milieu).
  3. ^ Timpler, Clemens (1608). Philosophiae practicae systema methodicum. Vol. libris IV pertractatam. Hanoviae: Apud Gulielmum Antonio. p. 388. Retrieved 4 February 2017. Fuit Aretologia: Sequitur Praxiologia: quæ est altera pars Ethicæ, tractans generaliter de actionibus moralibus.
  4. ^ Flint, Robert (1904). Philosophy as Scientia Scientiarum. Edinburgh. pp. 254–55.
  5. ^ Ostrowski, Jean J. (July–September 1967). "Notes biographiques et bibliographiques sur Alfred Espinas". Review Philosophique de la France et de l'Étranger (3): 385–91.
  6. ^ Watson, John B. Behaviourism: The Early Years. Vol. 4.
  7. ^ Edited by Murchison, Carl Allanmore, The Journal of Psychology, Volumes 3–4, 1935
  8. ^ McDougall, William (1928). The Battle of Behaviorism: An Exposition and an Exposure. p. 35.
  9. ^ In 'Mathématiques et Sciences Humaines', Paris, Centre de mathématique sociale et de statistique-École Pratique des Hautes Études, No. 11. Ete, 1965, pp. 11–18, and a rejoinder 'Réponse a un appel' by J. Ostrowski, ibid,, No. 19, Ete, 1967, pp. 21–26
  10. ^ Selgin, George A. (1987). "Praxeology and Understanding: An Analysis of the Controversy in Austrian Economics". Review of Austrian Economics. 2: 22. Retrieved 4 February 2017.
  11. ^ a b c Bunge, Mario (2016). Between Two Worlds: Memoirs of a Philosopher-Scientist. Springer Biographies. Berlin; New York: Springer-Verlag. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-29251-9. ISBN 9783319292502. OCLC 950889848.
  12. ^ a b Rothbard, Murray N. (1976). "Praxeology: The Methodology of Austrian Economics". The Foundations of Modern Austrian Economics. pp. 19–39.
  13. ^ Mises, Ludwig von (1957). "Psychology and Thymology". Theory and History. pp. 272.
  14. ^ Rothbard, Murray N. "Praxeology, value judgments, and public policy." The Foundations of Modern Austrian Economics (1976): 89–114.
  15. ^ Murray N. Rothbard. "Praxeology: Reply to Mr. Schuller", American Economic Review, December 1951, pp. 943–46.
  16. ^ Mayer, Thomas (Winter 1998). "Boettke's Austrian critique of mainstream economics: An empiricist's response" (PDF). Critical Review. 12 (1–2): 151–71. doi:10.1080/08913819808443491.(subscription required)
  17. ^ "Rules for the study of natural philosophy", Newton 1999, pp. 794–96, from Book 3, The System of the World.
  18. ^ a b Mises, Ludwig von (2003). Epistemological Problems of Economics. Translated by Reisman, George (3rd ed.). Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 0-945466-36-6. Retrieved 31 January 2022.
  19. ^ Davies, Antony (12 September 2012). "Complementary Approaches". Cato Unbound. Retrieved 27 December 2016.

Further reading

Austrian school

Polish school

praxeology, philosophy, praxeology, praxiology, from, ancient, greek, πρᾶξις, praxis, deed, action, λογία, logia, study, theory, human, action, based, notion, that, humans, engage, purposeful, behavior, contrary, reflexive, behavior, other, unintentional, beha. In philosophy praxeology or praxiology ˌ p r ae k s i ˈ ɒ l e dʒ i from Ancient Greek prᾶ3is praxis deed action and logia logia study of is the theory of human action based on the notion that humans engage in purposeful behavior contrary to reflexive behavior and other unintentional behavior French social philosopher Alfred Espinas gave the term its modern meaning and praxeology was developed independently by two principal groups the Austrian school led by Ludwig von Mises and the Polish school led by Tadeusz Kotarbinski 1 Contents 1 Origin and etymology 2 Austrian economics 2 1 Subdivisions 2 2 Criticisms 3 See also 4 References 5 Further reading 5 1 Austrian school 5 2 Polish schoolOrigin and etymology EditCoinage of the word praxeology praxeologie is often credited to Louis Bourdeau the French author of a classification of the sciences which he published in his Theorie des sciences Plan de Science integrale in 1882 On account of their dual natures of specialty and generality these functions should be the subject of a separate science Some of its parts have been studied for a long time because this kind of research in which man could be the main subject has always presented the greatest interest Physiology hygiene medicine psychology animal history human history political economy morality etc represent fragments of a science that we would like to establish but as fragments scattered and uncoordinated have remained until now only parts of particular sciences They should be joined together and made whole in order to highlight the order of the whole and its unity Now you have a science so far unnamed which we propose to call Praxeology from pra3is action or by referring to the influence of the environment Mesology from mesos environment 2 However the term was used at least once previously with a slight spelling difference in 1608 by Clemens Timpler in his Philosophiae practicae systema methodicum There was Aretology Following that Praxiology which is the second part of the Ethics in general commenting on the actions of the moral virtues 3 It was later mentioned by Robert Flint in 1904 in a review of Bourdeau s Theorie des sciences 4 The modern definition of the word was first given by Alfred V Espinas 1844 1922 5 the French philosopher and sociologist he was the forerunner of the Polish school of the science of efficient action The Austrian school of economics was based on a philosophical science of the same kind With a different spelling the word was used by the English psychologist Charles Arthur Mercier in 1911 and proposed by Knight Dunlap to John B Watson as a better name for his behaviorism 6 page needed Watson rejected it But the Chinese physiologist of behavior Zing Yang Kuo b 1898 adopted the term in 1935 7 page needed It was also used by William McDougall in 1928 and later 8 full citation needed Previously the word praxiology with the meaning Espinas gave to it was used by Tadeusz Kotarbinski in 1923 Several economists such as the Ukrainian Eugene Slutsky 1926 used it in his attempt to base economics on a theory of action It was also used by Austrian economist Ludwig von Mises 1933 Russian Marxist Nikolai Bukharin 1888 1938 during the Second International Congress of History of Science and Technology in London in 1931 and Polish scholar Oscar Lange 1904 1965 in 1959 and later citation needed The Italian philosopher Carmelo Ottaviano was using the Italianised version prassiologia in his treatises starting from 1935 but in his own way as a theory of politics After the Second World War the use of the term praxeology spread widely After the emigration of Mises to the US his pupil Murray Rothbard defended the praxeological approach A revival of Espinas s approach in France was revealed in the works of Pierre Masse 1946 the eminent cybernetician Georges Theodule Guilbaud 1953 the Belgian logician Leo Apostel 1957 the cybernetician Anatol Rapoport 1962 Henry Pierron psychologist and lexicographer 1957 Francois Perroux economist 1957 the social psychologist Robert Daval 1963 the well known sociologist Raymond Aron 1963 and the methodologists Abraham Antoine Moles and Roland Caude 1965 citation needed Under the influence of Tadeusz Kotarbinski praxeology flourished in Poland A special Centre of Praxeology Zaklad Prakseologiczny was created under the organizational guidance of the Polish Academy of Sciences with its own periodical from 1962 called at first Materialy Prakseologiczne Praxeological Papers and then abbreviated to Prakseologia It published hundreds of papers by different authors and the materials for a special vocabulary edited by Professor Tadeusz Pszczolowski the leading praxeologist of the younger generation A sweeping survey of the praxeological approach is to be found in the paper by the French statistician Micheline Petruszewycz A propos de la praxeologie 9 Ludwig von Mises was influenced by several theories in forming his work on praxeology including Immanuel Kant s works Max Weber s work on methodological individualism and Carl Menger s development of the subjective theory of value 10 Philosopher of science Mario Bunge published works of systematic philosophy that included contributions to praxeology 11 407 Austrian economics EditAustrian economics in the tradition of Ludwig von Mises relies heavily on praxeology in the development of its economic theories 12 Mises considered economics to be a sub discipline of praxeology 13 Austrian School economists following Mises use praxeology and deduction rather than empirical studies to determine economic principles According to these theorists with the action axiom as the starting point it is possible to draw conclusions about human behavior that are both objective and universal For example the notion that humans engage in acts of choice implies that they have preferences and this must be true for anyone who exhibits intentional behavior citation needed Advocates of praxeology also say that it provides insights for the field of ethics 14 Subdivisions Edit In 1951 Murray Rothbard divided the subfields of praxeology as follows A The Theory of the Isolated Individual Crusoe Economics B The Theory of Voluntary Interpersonal Exchange Catallactics or the Economics of the Market 1 Barter 2 With Medium of Exchangea On the Unhampered Market b Effects of Violent Intervention with the Market c Effects of Violent Abolition of the Market Socialism dd dd C The Theory of War Hostile Action D The Theory of Games Game Theory e g von Neumann and Morgenstern E UnknownAt the time topics C D and E were regarded by Rothbard as open research problems 15 Criticisms Edit Thomas Mayer has argued that because praxeology rejects positivism and empiricism in the development of theories it constitutes nothing less than a rejection of the scientific method For Mayer this invalidates the methodologies of the Austrian school of economics 16 17 Austrians argue that empirical data itself is insufficient to describe economics that consequently empirical data cannot falsify economic theory that logical positivism cannot predict or explain human action and that the methodological requirements of logical positivism are impossible to obtain for economic questions 18 12 Ludwig von Mises in particular argued against empiricist approaches to the social sciences in general because human events are unique and non repeatable whereas experiments in the physical sciences are necessarily reproducible 18 However economist Antony Davies argues that because statistical tests are predicated on the independent development of theory some form of praxeology is essential for model selection conversely praxeology can illustrate surprising philosophical consequences of economic models 19 Bunge dismissed von Mises s version of praxeology as nothing but the principle of maximization of subjective utility a fancy version of egoism 11 394 Bunge who was also a fierce critic of pseudoscience warned that when conceived in extremely general terms and detached from both ethics and science praxiology has hardly any practical value 11 394 See also Edit Look up praxeology in Wiktionary the free dictionary Action theory philosophy Action theory sociology Behavioral economics Decision theory Methodological individualism Philosophy of economics Philosophy of social science Rationalism ThymologyReferences Edit Ryan Leo V Nahser F Byron Gasparski Wojciech eds 2002 Praxiology and pragmatism Praxiology the international annual of practical philosophy and methodology Vol 10 New Brunswick NJ Transaction Publishers pp 7 9 ISBN 978 0765801678 OCLC 49617735 Bourdeau Louis 1882 Theorie des sciences Plan de Science integrale Lilliad Universite de Lille Sciences et Technologies Tome Second 463 Retrieved 4 February 2017 A raison de leur double caractere de specialite et de generalite les fonctions doivent constituer l objet d une science distincte Quelques unes de ses parties ont ete etudiees de bonne heure car ce genre de recherches dont l homme pouvait se faire le sujet principal a presente de tout temps le plus vif interet La physiologie l hygiene la medecine la psychologie l histoire des animaux l histoire humaine l economie politique la morale etc representent des fragments de la science que nous voudrions etablir mais fragments epars et sans coordination sont restes a l etat de sciences particulieres Il faudrait les rapprocher et en faire un tout afin de mettre en lumiere l ordre de l ensemble et son unite On aurait alors une science innommee jusqu ici et que nous proposons d appeler Praxeologie de pra3is action ou en se referant a l influence des milieu Mesologie de meơos milieu Timpler Clemens 1608 Philosophiae practicae systema methodicum Vol libris IV pertractatam Hanoviae Apud Gulielmum Antonio p 388 Retrieved 4 February 2017 Fuit Aretologia Sequitur Praxiologia quae est altera pars Ethicae tractans generaliter de actionibus moralibus Flint Robert 1904 Philosophy as Scientia Scientiarum Edinburgh pp 254 55 Ostrowski Jean J July September 1967 Notes biographiques et bibliographiques sur Alfred Espinas Review Philosophique de la France et de l Etranger 3 385 91 Watson John B Behaviourism The Early Years Vol 4 Edited by Murchison Carl Allanmore The Journal of Psychology Volumes 3 4 1935 McDougall William 1928 The Battle of Behaviorism An Exposition and an Exposure p 35 In Mathematiques et Sciences Humaines Paris Centre de mathematique sociale et de statistique Ecole Pratique des Hautes Etudes No 11 Ete 1965 pp 11 18 and a rejoinder Reponse a un appel by J Ostrowski ibid No 19 Ete 1967 pp 21 26 Selgin George A 1987 Praxeology and Understanding An Analysis of the Controversy in Austrian Economics Review of Austrian Economics 2 22 Retrieved 4 February 2017 a b c Bunge Mario 2016 Between Two Worlds Memoirs of a Philosopher Scientist Springer Biographies Berlin New York Springer Verlag doi 10 1007 978 3 319 29251 9 ISBN 9783319292502 OCLC 950889848 a b Rothbard Murray N 1976 Praxeology The Methodology of Austrian Economics The Foundations of Modern Austrian Economics pp 19 39 Mises Ludwig von 1957 Psychology and Thymology Theory and History pp 272 Rothbard Murray N Praxeology value judgments and public policy The Foundations of Modern Austrian Economics 1976 89 114 Murray N Rothbard Praxeology Reply to Mr Schuller American Economic Review December 1951 pp 943 46 Mayer Thomas Winter 1998 Boettke s Austrian critique of mainstream economics An empiricist s response PDF Critical Review 12 1 2 151 71 doi 10 1080 08913819808443491 subscription required Rules for the study of natural philosophy Newton 1999 pp 794 96harvnb error no target CITEREFNewton1999 help from Book 3 The System of the World a b Mises Ludwig von 2003 Epistemological Problems of Economics Translated by Reisman George 3rd ed Ludwig von Mises Institute ISBN 0 945466 36 6 Retrieved 31 January 2022 Davies Antony 12 September 2012 Complementary Approaches Cato Unbound Retrieved 27 December 2016 Further reading EditAustrian school Edit Selgin George A December 1988 Praxeology and understanding an analysis of the controversy in Austrian Economics The Review of Austrian Economics 2 1 19 58 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 378 1506 doi 10 1007 BF01539297 Smith George H 2008 Praxeology In Hamowy Ronald ed The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism Thousand Oaks CA SAGE Publications Cato Institute pp 387 88 doi 10 4135 9781412965811 n239 ISBN 9781412965804 LCCN 2008009151 OCLC 750831024 Polish school Edit Gasparski Wojciech W 1992 Praxiology The International Annual of Practical Philosophy and Methodology New Brunswick NJ Transaction Publishers OCLC 611063114 Kotarbinski Tadeusz 1965 1955 Praxiology An Introduction to the Sciences of Efficient Action Oxford New York Pergamon Press ISBN 9780080101101 OCLC 825097 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Praxeology amp oldid 1134429739, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.