fbpx
Wikipedia

Austrian School

The Austrian School is a heterodox[1][2][3] school of economic thought that advocates strict adherence to methodological individualism, the concept that social phenomena result exclusively from the motivations and actions of individuals. Austrian school theorists hold that economic theory should be exclusively derived from basic principles of human action.[4][5][6]

The Austrian School originated in late-19th- and early-20th-century Vienna with the work of Carl Menger, Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, Friedrich von Wieser, and others.[7] It was methodologically opposed to the Historical School (based in Germany), in a dispute known as Methodenstreit, or methodology struggle. Current-day economists working in this tradition are located in many different countries, but their work is still referred to as Austrian economics. Among the theoretical contributions of the early years of the Austrian School are the subjective theory of value, marginalism in price theory and the formulation of the economic calculation problem, each of which has become an accepted part of mainstream economics.[8]

Since the mid-20th century, mainstream economists have been critical of the modern-day Austrian School and consider its rejection of mathematical modeling, econometrics and macroeconomic analysis to be outside mainstream economics, or "heterodox". In the 1970s, the Austrian School attracted some renewed interest after Friedrich Hayek shared the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences with Gunnar Myrdal.[9]

History

 
Jean-Baptiste Say. The French Liberal School of Political Economy is an intellectual ancestor of Austrian School of Economics.

Etymology

The Austrian School owes its name to members of the German historical school of economics, who argued against the Austrians during the late-19th century Methodenstreit ("methodology struggle"), in which the Austrians defended the role of theory in economics as distinct from the study or compilation of historical circumstance. In 1883, Menger published Investigations into the Method of the Social Sciences with Special Reference to Economics, which attacked the methods of the historical school. Gustav von Schmoller, a leader of the historical school, responded with an unfavorable review, coining the term "Austrian School" in an attempt to characterize the school as outcast and provincial.[10] The label endured and was adopted by the adherents themselves.[11]

First wave

The school originated in Vienna in the Austrian Empire. Carl Menger's 1871 book Principles of Economics is generally considered the founding of the Austrian School. The book was one of the first modern treatises to advance the theory of marginal utility. The Austrian School was one of three founding currents of the marginalist revolution of the 1870s, with its major contribution being the introduction of the subjectivist approach in economics.[12][page needed]

Despite such claim, John Stuart Mill had used value in use in this sense in 1848 in Principles of Political Economy,[13] where he wrote: "Value in use, or as Mr. De Quincey calls it, teleologic value, is the extreme limit of value in exchange. The exchange value of a thing may fall short, to any amount, of its value in use; but that it can ever exceed the value in use, implies a contradiction; it supposes that persons will give, to possess a thing, more than the utmost value which they themselves put upon it as a means of gratifying their inclinations."[14]

While marginalism was generally influential, there was also a more specific school that began to coalesce around Menger's work, which came to be known as the "Psychological School", "Vienna School", or "Austrian School".[15] Menger's contributions to economic theory were closely followed by those of Eugen Böhm von Bawerk and Friedrich von Wieser. These three economists became what is known as the "first wave" of the Austrian School. Böhm-Bawerk wrote extensive critiques of Karl Marx in the 1880s and 1890s and was part of the Austrians' participation in the late 19th-century Methodenstreit, during which they attacked the Hegelian doctrines of the historical school.

Early 20th century

Frank Albert Fetter (1863–1949) was a leader in the United States of Austrian thought. He obtained his PhD in 1894 from the University of Halle and then was made Professor of Political Economy and Finance at Cornell in 1901. Several important Austrian economists trained at the University of Vienna in the 1920s and later participated in private seminars held by Ludwig von Mises. These included Gottfried Haberler,[16] Friedrich Hayek, Fritz Machlup,[17] Karl Menger (son of Carl Menger),[18] Oskar Morgenstern,[19] Paul Rosenstein-Rodan,[20] Abraham Wald,[21] and Michael A. Heilperin,[22] among others, as well as the sociologist Alfred Schütz.[23]

Later 20th century

By the mid-1930s, most economists had embraced what they considered the important contributions of the early Austrians.[1] Fritz Machlup quoted Hayek's statement that "the greatest success of a school is that it stops existing because its fundamental teachings have become parts of the general body of commonly accepted thought".[24] Sometime during the middle of the 20th century, Austrian economics became disregarded or derided by mainstream economists because it rejected model building and mathematical and statistical methods in the study of economics.[25] Mises' student Israel Kirzner recalled that in 1954, when Kirzner was pursuing his PhD, there was no separate Austrian School as such. When Kirzner was deciding which graduate school to attend, Mises had advised him to accept an offer of admission at Johns Hopkins because it was a prestigious university and Fritz Machlup taught there.[26]

After the 1940s, Austrian economics can be divided into two schools of economic thought and the school "split" to some degree in the late 20th century. One camp of Austrians, exemplified by Mises, regards neoclassical methodology to be irredeemably flawed; the other camp, exemplified by Friedrich Hayek, accepts a large part of neoclassical methodology and is more accepting of government intervention in the economy.[27] Henry Hazlitt wrote economics columns and editorials for a number of publications and wrote many books on the topic of Austrian economics from the 1930s to the 1980s. Hazlitt's thinking was influenced by Mises.[28] His book Economics in One Lesson (1946) sold over a million copies and he is also known for The Failure of the "New Economics" (1959), a line-by-line critique of John Maynard Keynes's General Theory.[29]

The reputation of the Austrian School rose in the late 20th century due in part to the work of Israel Kirzner and Ludwig Lachmann at New York University and to renewed public awareness of the work of Hayek after he won the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences.[30] Hayek's work was influential in the revival of laissez-faire thought in the 20th century.[31][32]

Split among contemporary Austrians

Economist Leland Yeager discussed the late 20th-century rift and referred to a discussion written by Murray Rothbard, Hans-Hermann Hoppe, Joseph Salerno and others in which they attack and disparage Hayek. Yeager stated: "To try to drive a wedge between Mises and Hayek on [the role of knowledge in economic calculation], especially to the disparagement of Hayek, is unfair to these two great men, unfaithful to the history of economic thought". He went on to call the rift subversive to economic analysis and the historical understanding of the fall of Eastern European communism.[33]

In a 1999 book published by the Ludwig von Mises Institute,[34] Hoppe asserted that Rothbard was the leader of the "mainstream within Austrian Economics" and contrasted Rothbard with Nobel Laureate Friedrich Hayek, whom he identified as a British empiricist and an opponent of the thought of Mises and Rothbard. Hoppe acknowledged that Hayek was the most prominent Austrian economist within academia, but stated that Hayek was an opponent of the Austrian tradition which led from Carl Menger and Böhm-Bawerk through Mises to Rothbard. Austrian economist Walter Block says that the Austrian School can be distinguished from other schools of economic thought through two categories—economic theory and political theory. According to Block, while Hayek can be considered an Austrian economist, his views on political theory clash with the libertarian political theory which Block sees as an integral part of the Austrian School.[35]

Both criticism from Hoppe and Block to Hayek apply to Carl Menger, the founder of the Austrian School. Hoppe emphasizes that Hayek, which for him is from the English empirical tradition, is an opponent of the supposed rationalist tradition of the Austrian School; Menger made strong critiques to rationalism in his works in similar vein as Hayek's.[36] He emphasized the idea that there are several institutions which were not deliberately created, have a kind of "superior wisdom" and serve important functions to society.[37][36][38] He also talked about Burke and the English tradition to sustain these positions.[36]

When saying that the libertarian political theory is an integral part of the Austrian School and supposing Hayek is not a libertarian, Block excludes Menger from the Austrian School too since Menger seems to defend broader state activity than Hayek—for example, progressive taxation and extensive labour legislation.[39]

Economists of the Hayekian view are affiliated with the Cato Institute, George Mason University (GMU) and New York University, among other institutions. They include Peter Boettke, Roger Garrison, Steven Horwitz, Peter Leeson and George Reisman. Economists of the Mises–Rothbard view include Walter Block, Hans-Hermann Hoppe, Jesús Huerta de Soto and Robert P. Murphy, each of whom is associated with the Mises Institute[40] and some of them also with academic institutions.[40] According to Murphy, a "truce between (for lack of better terms) the GMU Austro-libertarians and the Auburn Austro-libertarians" was signed around 2011.[41][42]

Influence

Many theories developed by "first wave" Austrian economists have long been absorbed into mainstream economics.[43] These include Carl Menger's theories on marginal utility, Friedrich von Wieser's theories on opportunity cost and Eugen Böhm von Bawerk's theories on time preference, as well as Menger and Böhm-Bawerk's criticisms of Marxian economics.[44]

Former American Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan said that the founders of the Austrian School "reached far into the future from when most of them practiced and have had a profound and, in my judgment, probably an irreversible effect on how most mainstream economists think in this country".[45] In 1987, Nobel Laureate James M. Buchanan told an interviewer: "I have no objections to being called an Austrian. Hayek and Mises might consider me an Austrian but, surely some of the others would not".[46]

Currently, universities with a significant Austrian presence are George Mason University,[47] New York University, Grove City College, Loyola University New Orleans and Auburn University in the United States; King Juan Carlos University in Spain;[48] and Universidad Francisco Marroquín in Guatemala.[49][50] Austrian economic ideas are also promoted by privately funded organizations such as the Mises Institute[51] and the Cato Institute.[52]

Methodology

The Austrian School theorizes that the subjective choices of individuals including individual knowledge, time, expectation and other subjective factors cause all economic phenomena. Austrians seek to understand the economy by examining the social ramifications of individual choice, an approach called methodological individualism. It differs from other schools of economic thought, which have focused on aggregate variables, equilibrium analysis and societal groups rather than individuals.[53]

In the 20th and 21st centuries, economists with a methodological lineage to the early Austrian School developed many diverse approaches and theoretical orientations. Ludwig von Mises organized his version of the subjectivist approach, which he called "praxeology", in a book published in English as Human Action in 1949.[54]: 3  In it, Mises stated that praxeology could be used to deduce a priori theoretical economic truths and that deductive economic thought experiments could yield conclusions which follow irrefutably from the underlying assumptions. He wrote that conclusions could not be inferred from empirical observation or statistical analysis and argued against the use of probabilities in economic models.[55]

Since Mises' time, some Austrian thinkers have accepted his praxeological approach while others have adopted alternative methodologies.[56] For example, Fritz Machlup, Friedrich Hayek and others did not take Mises' strong a priori approach to economics.[57] Ludwig Lachmann, a radical subjectivist, also largely rejected Mises' formulation of Praxeology in favor of the verstehende Methode ("interpretive method") articulated by Max Weber.[53][58]

In the 20th century, various Austrians incorporated models and mathematics into their analysis. Austrian economist Steven Horwitz argued in 2000 that Austrian methodology is consistent with macroeconomics and that Austrian macroeconomics can be expressed in terms of microeconomic foundations.[59] Austrian economist Roger Garrison writes that Austrian macroeconomic theory can be correctly expressed in terms of diagrammatic models.[60] In 1944, Austrian economist Oskar Morgenstern presented a rigorous schematization of an ordinal utility function (the Von Neumann–Morgenstern utility theorem) in Theory of Games and Economic Behavior.[61]

Fundamental tenets

In 1981, Fritz Machlup listed the typical views of Austrian economic thinking as such:[62]

  • Methodological individualism: in the explanation of economic phenomena, we have to go back to the actions (or inaction) of individuals; groups or "collectives" cannot act except through the actions of individual members. Groups don't think; people think.
  • Methodological subjectivism: in the explanation of economic phenomena, we have to go back to judgments and choices made by individuals on the basis of whatever knowledge they have or believe to have and whatever expectations they entertain regarding external developments and especially the perceived consequences of their own intended actions.
  • Tastes and preferences: subjective valuations of goods and services determine the demand for them so that their prices are influenced by (actual and potential) consumers.
  • Opportunity costs: the costs with which producers and other economic actors calculate reflect the alternative opportunities that must be foregone; as productive services are employed for one purpose, all alternative uses have to be sacrificed.
  • Marginalism: in all economic designs, the values, costs, revenues, productivity and so on are determined by the significance of the last unit added to or subtracted from the total.
  • Time structure of production and consumption: decisions to save reflect "time preferences" regarding consumption in the immediate, distant, or indefinite future and investments are made in view of larger outputs expected to be obtained if more time-taking production processes are undertaken.

He included two additional tenets held by the Mises branch of Austrian economics:

  • Consumer sovereignty: the influence consumers have on the effective demand for goods and services and through the prices which result in free competitive markets, on the production plans of producers and investors, is not merely a hard fact but also an important objective, attainable only by complete avoidance of governmental interference with the markets and of restrictions on the freedom of sellers and buyers to follow their own judgment regarding quantities, qualities and prices of products and services.
  • Political individualism: only when individuals are given full economic freedom will it be possible to secure political and moral freedom. Restrictions on economic freedom lead, sooner or later, to an extension of the coercive activities of the state into the political domain, undermining and eventually destroying the essential individual liberties which the capitalistic societies were able to attain in the 19th century.

Contributions to economic thought

Opportunity cost

The opportunity cost doctrine was first explicitly formulated by the Austrian economist Friedrich von Wieser in the late 19th century.[63] Opportunity cost is the cost of any activity measured in terms of the value of the next best alternative foregone (that is not chosen). It is the sacrifice related to the second best choice available to someone, or group, who has picked among several mutually exclusive choices.[64] Although a more ephemeral scarcity, expectations of the future must also be considered. Quantified as time preference, opportunity cost must also be valued with respect to one’s preference for present versus future investments. [65]

Opportunity cost is a key concept in mainstream economics and has been described as expressing "the basic relationship between scarcity and choice".[66] The notion of opportunity cost plays a crucial part in ensuring that resources are used efficiently.[67]

Capital and interest

The Austrian theory of capital and interest was first developed by Eugen Böhm von Bawerk. He stated that interest rates and profits are determined by two factors, namely supply and demand in the market for final goods and time preference.[68]

Böhm-Bawerk's theory equates capital intensity with the degree of roundaboutness of production processes. Böhm-Bawerk also argued that the law of marginal utility necessarily implies the classical law of costs.[68] Some Austrian economists therefore entirely reject the notion that interest rates are affected by liquidity preference.[69]

Inflation

In Mises's definition, inflation is an increase in the supply of money:[70]

In theoretical investigation there is only one meaning that can rationally be attached to the expression Inflation: an increase in the quantity of money (in the broader sense of the term, so as to include fiduciary media as well), that is not offset by a corresponding increase in the need for money (again in the broader sense of the term), so that a fall in the objective exchange-value of money must occur.[71]

Hayek pointed out that inflationary stimulation exploits the lag between an increase in money supply and the consequent increase in the prices of goods and services:

And since any inflation, however modest at first, can help employment only so long as it accelerates, adopted as a means of reducing unemployment, it will do so for any length of time only while it accelerates. "Mild" steady inflation cannot help—it can lead only to outright inflation. That inflation at a constant rate soon ceases to have any stimulating effect, and in the end merely leaves us with a backlog of delayed adaptations, is the conclusive argument against the "mild" inflation represented as beneficial even in standard economics textbooks.[72]

Economic calculation problem

The economic calculation problem refers to a criticism of planned economies which was first stated by Max Weber in 1920. Mises subsequently discussed Weber's idea with his student Friedrich Hayek, who developed it in various works including The Road to Serfdom.[73][74] What the calculation problem essentially states is that without price signals, the factors of production cannot be allocated in the most efficient way possible, rendering planned economies inefficacious.

Austrian theory emphasizes the organizing power of markets. Hayek stated that market prices reflect information, the totality of which is not known to any single individual, which determines the allocation of resources in an economy. Because socialist systems lack the individual incentives and price discovery processes by which individuals act on their personal information, Hayek argued that socialist economic planners lack all of the knowledge required to make optimal decisions. Those who agree with this criticism view it as a refutation of socialism, showing that socialism is not a viable or sustainable form of economic organization. The debate rose to prominence in the 1920s and 1930s and that specific period of the debate has come to be known by historians of economic thought as the socialist calculation debate.[75]

Mises argued in a 1920 essay "Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth" that the pricing systems in socialist economies were necessarily deficient because if the government owned the means of production, then no prices could be obtained for capital goods as they were merely internal transfers of goods in a socialist system and not "objects of exchange", unlike final goods. Therefore, they were unpriced and hence the system would be necessarily inefficient since the central planners would not know how to allocate the available resources efficiently.[75] This led him to write "that rational economic activity is impossible in a socialist commonwealth".[76]

Business cycles

The Austrian theory of the business cycle (ABCT) focuses on banks' issuance of credit as the cause of economic fluctuations.[77] Although later elaborated by Hayek and others, the theory was first set forth by Mises, who posited that fractional reserve banks extend credit at artificially low interest rates, causing businesses to invest in relatively roundabout production processes which leads to an artificial "boom". Mises stated that this artificial "boom" then led to a misallocation of resources which he called "malinvestment" - which eventually must end in a "bust".[77]

Mises surmised how government manipulation of money and credit in the banking system throws savings and investment out of balance, resulting in misdirected investment projects that are eventually found to be unsustainable, at which point the economy has to rebalance itself through a period of corrective recession.[78] Austrian economist Fritz Machlup summarized the Austrian view by stating, "monetary factors cause the cycle but real phenomena constitute it."[79] For Austrians, the only prudent strategy for government is to leave money and the financial system to the free market's competitive forces to eradicate the business cycle's inflationary booms and recessionary busts, allowing markets to keep people's saving and investment decisions in place for well-coordinated economic stability and growth.[78]

A Keynesian would suggest government intervention during a recession to inject spending into the economy when people are not. However, the heart of Austrian macroeconomic theory states the government "fine tuning" through expansions and contractions in the money supply orchestrated by the government are actually the cause of business cycles because of the differing impact of the resulting interest rate changes on different stages in the structure of production.[79] Austrian economist Thomas Woods further supports this view by arguing it is not consumption, but rather production that should be emphasized. A country cannot become rich by consuming, and therefore, by using up all their resources. Instead, production is what enables consumption as a possibility in the first place, since a producer would be working for nothing, if not for the desire to consume.[80]

Central banks

According to Ludwig von Mises, central banks enable the commercial banks to fund loans at artificially low interest rates, thereby inducing an unsustainable expansion of bank credit and impeding any subsequent contraction and argued for a gold standard to constrain growth in fiduciary media.[77] Friedrich Hayek took a different perspective not focusing on gold but focusing on regulation of the banking sector via strong central banking.[81]

Criticism

General

Mainstream economists generally reject modern-day Austrian economics, and argue that modern-day Austrian economists are excessively averse to the use of mathematics and statistics in economics.[82] Austrian opposition to mathematization extends to economic theorizing only, as they argue that human behavior is too variable for overarching mathematical models to hold true across time and context. Austrians do, however, support analyzing revealed preference via mathematization to aid business and finance.[83]

Economist Paul Krugman has stated that Austrians are unaware of holes in their own thinking because they do not use "explicit models".[84]

Economist Benjamin Klein has criticized the economic methodological work of Austrian economist Israel M. Kirzner. While praising Kirzner for highlighting shortcomings in traditional methodology, Klein argued that Kirzner did not provide a viable alternative for economic methodology.[85] Economist Tyler Cowen has written that Kirzner's theory of entrepreneurship can ultimately be reduced to a neoclassical search model and is thus not in the radical subjectivist tradition of Austrian praxeology. Cowen states that Kirzner's entrepreneurs can be modeled in mainstream terms of search.[86]

Economist Jeffrey Sachs argues that among developed countries, those with high rates of taxation and high social welfare spending perform better on most measures of economic performance compared to countries with low rates of taxation and low social outlays. He concludes that Friedrich Hayek was wrong to argue that high levels of government spending harms an economy and "a generous social-welfare state is not a road to serfdom but rather to fairness, economic equality and international competitiveness".[87]

Economist Bryan Caplan has noted that Mises has been criticized for overstating the strength of his case in describing socialism as "impossible" rather than as something that would need to establish non-market institutions to deal with the inefficiency.[88]

Methodology

Critics generally argue that Austrian economics lacks scientific rigor and rejects scientific methods and the use of empirical data in modelling economic behavior.[89][90] Some economists describe Austrian methodology as being a priori or non-empirical.[82][91][92]

Economist Mark Blaug has criticized over-reliance on methodological individualism, arguing it would rule out all macroeconomic propositions that cannot be reduced to microeconomic ones, and hence reject almost the whole of received macroeconomics.[93]

Economist Thomas Mayer has stated that Austrians advocate a rejection of the scientific method which involves the development of empirically falsifiable theories.[90][92] Furthermore, economists have developed numerous experiments that elicit useful information about individual preferences.[94][95]

Although economist Leland Yeager is sympathetic to Austrian economics, he rejects many favorite views of the Misesian group of Austrians, in particular "the specifics of their business-cycle theory, ultra-subjectivism in value theory and particularly in interest-rate theory, their insistence on unidirectional causality rather than general interdependence, and their fondness for methodological brooding, pointless profundities, and verbal gymnastics".[96]

Economist Paul A. Samuelson wrote in 1964 that most economists believe that economic conclusions reached by pure logical deduction are limited and weak.[97] According to Samuelson and Caplan, Mises' deductive methodology also embraced by Murray Rothbard and to a lesser extent by Mises' student Israel Kirzner was not sufficient in and of itself.[91]

Business cycle theory

Mainstream economic research regarding Austrian business cycle theory finds that it is inconsistent with empirical evidence. Noted economists such as Gordon Tullock,[98] Milton Friedman[99][100] and Paul Krugman[101] have said that they regard the theory as incorrect. Austrian economist Ludwig Lachmann noted that the Austrian theory was rejected during the 1930s:

The promise of an Austrian theory of the trade cycle, which might also serve to explain the severity of the Great Depression, a feature of the early 1930s that provided the background for Hayek's successful appearance on the London scene, soon proved deceptive. Three giants – Keynes, Knight and Sraffa – turned against the hapless Austrians who, in the middle of that black decade, thus had to do battle on three fronts. Naturally it proved a task beyond their strength.[102]

Theoretical objections

Some economists have argued that Austrian business cycle theory requires bankers and investors to exhibit a kind of irrationality because the Austrian theory posits that investors will be fooled repeatedly (by temporarily low interest rates) into making unprofitable investment decisions.[98][103] Milton Friedman objected to the policy implications of the theory, stating the following in a 1998 interview:

I think the Austrian business-cycle theory has done the world a great deal of harm. If you go back to the 1930s, which is a key point, here you had the Austrians sitting in London, Hayek and Lionel Robbins, and saying you just have to let the bottom drop out of the world. You've just got to let it cure itself. You can't do anything about it. You will only make it worse. You have Rothbard saying it was a great mistake not to let the whole banking system collapse. I think by encouraging that kind of do-nothing policy both in Britain and in the United States, they did harm.[104]

Empirical objections

In 1969, Milton Friedman examined the history of business cycles in the United States and wrote that there "appears to be no systematic connection between the size of an expansion and of the succeeding contraction", contradicting business cycle theories (such as the Austrian business cycle theory) which rely on that premise.[99] He analyzed the issue using newer data in 1993, and again reached the same conclusion.[100] Referring to Friedman's discussion of the business cycle, Austrian economist Roger Garrison argued that Friedman's empirical findings are "broadly consistent with both Monetarist and Austrian views" and goes on to argue that although Friedman's model "describes the economy's performance at the highest level of aggregation, Austrian theory offers an insightful account of the market process that might underlie those aggregates".[105]

See also

Notes and references

  1. ^ a b Boettke, Peter J.; Peter T. Leeson (2003). "28A: The Austrian School of Economics 1950–2000". In Warren Samuels; Jeff E. Biddle; John B. Davis (eds.). A Companion to the History of Economic Thought. Blackwell Publishing. pp. 446–52. ISBN 978-0-631-22573-7.
  2. ^ "Heterodox economics: Marginal revolutionaries". The Economist. December 31, 2011. from the original on February 22, 2012. Retrieved February 22, 2012.
  3. ^ Denis, Andy (2008). "Dialectics and the Austrian School: A Surprising Commonality in the Methodology of Heterodox Economics?". The Journal of Philosophical Economics. 1 (2): 151–173. Retrieved 19 May 2022.
  4. ^ Carl Menger, Principles of Economics, online at "Principles of Economics". 18 August 2014. Retrieved 2020-04-01.
  5. ^ Heath, Joseph (1 May 2018). Zalta, Edward N. (ed.). The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. Metaphysics Research Lab, Stanford University. Retrieved 1 May 2018 – via Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy.
  6. ^ Ludwig von Mises. Human Action, p. 11, "Purposeful Action and Animal Reaction". Referenced 2011-11-23.
  7. ^ Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of economic analysis, Oxford University Press 1996, ISBN 978-0195105599.
  8. ^ Birner, Jack; van Zijp, Rudy (1994). Hayek, Co-ordination and Evolution: His Legacy in Philosophy, Politics, Economics and the History of Ideas. London, New York: Routledge. p. 94. ISBN 978-0-415-09397-2.
  9. ^ Meijer, G. (1995). New Perspectives on Austrian Economics. New York: Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-12283-2.
  10. ^ "Menger's approach – haughtily dismissed by the leader of the German Historical School, Gustav Schmoller, as merely "Austrian," the origin of that label – led to a renaissance of theoretical economics in Europe and, later, in the United States." Peter G. Klein, 2007; in the Foreword to Principles of Economics, Carl Menger; trns. James Dingwall and Bert F. Hoselitz, 1976; Ludwig von Mises Institute, Alabama; 2007; ISBN 978-1-933550-12-1
  11. ^ von Mises, Ludwig (1984) [1969]. The Historical Setting of the Austrian School of Economics (PDF). Ludwig von Mises Institute. (PDF) from the original on 2014-06-24.
  12. ^ Keizer, Willem (1997). Austrian Economics in Debate. New York: Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-14054-6.
  13. ^ Ahiakpor, J.C.W. (2003): Classical Macroeconomics. Some Modern Variations and Distortions, Routledge, p. 21
  14. ^ Mill, J.S. (1848): Principles of Political Economy
  15. ^ Kirzner, Israel M. (1987). "Austrian School of Economics". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. 1: 145–51.
  16. ^ Salerno, Joseph T. (1 August 2007). "Biography of Gottfried Haberler (1901-1995)". Mises Institute. from the original on 2014-09-14.
  17. ^ "Biography of Fritz Machlup". from the original on 5 July 2013. Retrieved 16 June 2013.
  18. ^ "About Karl Menger - Department of Applied Mathematics - IIT College of Science - Illinois Institute of Technology". www.iit.edu. from the original on 29 October 2013. Retrieved 1 May 2018.
  19. ^ "Guide to the Oskar Morgenstern Papers, 1866-1992 and undated". Rubenstein Library. Duke University. from the original on 2012-10-17.
  20. ^ "Rodan; Paul Rosenstein (1902-1985); political economist". Archive at London School of Economics.
  21. ^ Oskar Morgenstern (Oct 1951). "Abraham Wald, 1902–1950". Econometrica. The Econometric Society. 19 (4): 361–67. doi:10.2307/1907462. JSTOR 1907462.
  22. ^ "Studies in Economic Nationalism". 18 August 2014.
  23. ^ Kurrild-Klitgaard, Peter (Summer 2003). "The Viennese Connection: Alfred Schutz and the Austrian School" (PDF). Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. 6 (2): 35–67. doi:10.1007/s12113-003-1018-y. S2CID 154202208. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2022-10-09. Retrieved 2022-08-19.
    • Kurrild-Klitgaard, Peter (2001). "On Rationality, Ideal Types and Economics: Alfred Schütz and the Austrian School". The Review of Austrian Economics. 14 (2/3): 119–143. doi:10.1023/A:1011199831428. S2CID 33060092.

  24. ^ "Ludwig von Mises: A Scholar Who Would Not Compromise". 15 December 2004. from the original on 2014-09-14. Retrieved 2014-09-13. Homage to Mises by Fritz Machlup 1981
  25. ^ Backhouse, Roger E (January 2000). "Austrian economics and the mainstream: View from the boundary". The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. 3 (2): 31–43. doi:10.1007/s12113-000-1002-8. S2CID 154604886. from the original on 2017-02-10. Retrieved 2017-01-24. Hayek did not fall out of favor because he was not Keynesian (neither are Friedman or Lucas) but because he was perceived to be doing neither rigorous theory nor empirical work
  26. ^ Kirzner, Israel. "Interview of Israel Kirzner". Ludwig von Mises Institute. from the original on 9 September 2013. Retrieved 17 June 2013.
  27. ^ kanopiadmin (30 July 2014). "The Hayek and Mises Controversy: Bridging Differences - Odd J. Stalebrink" (PDF). mises.org. (PDF) from the original on 14 November 2012. Retrieved 1 May 2018.
  28. ^ "Remembering Henry Hazlitt". The Freeman. Archived from the original on 2013-01-13. Retrieved 2013-03-11.
  29. ^ "Biography of Henry Hazlitt". Ludwig von Mises Institute. from the original on 2012-01-28. Retrieved 2013-03-11.
  30. ^ Meijer, Gerrit, ed. (1995). New Perspectives on Austrian Economics. New York: Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-12283-2. OCLC 70769328.
  31. ^ Raico, Ralph (2011). "Austrian Economics and Classical Liberalism". mises.org. Ludwig von Mises Institute. from the original on 19 May 2011. Retrieved 27 July 2011. despite the particular policy views of its founders ... Austrianism was perceived as the economics of the free market
  32. ^ Kasper, Sherryl Davis (2002). The Revival of Laissez-faire in American Macroeconomic Theory. Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 66. ISBN 978-1-84064-606-1.
  33. ^ Yaeger, Leland (2011). Is the Market a Test of Truth and Beauty?: Essays in Political Economy. Ludwig von Mises Institute. pp. 93 ff.
  34. ^ Hoppe, Hans-Hermann (1999). 15 Great Austrian Economists – Murray Rothbard (PDF). Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute. pp. 223 ff. (PDF) from the original on 2014-10-07.
  35. ^ "Dr. Walter Block: Austrian vs Chicago Schools". Mises Canada : Rothbard School 2014. from the original on 18 May 2015. Retrieved 3 December 2014.
  36. ^ a b c Menger, Carl. Investigations into the Methods of the Social Sciences (PDF). pp. 173–175. (PDF) from the original on 2017-02-11.
  37. ^ Menger, Carl. Investigations into the Methods of the Social Sciences (PDF). pp. 146–147. (PDF) from the original on 2017-02-11.
  38. ^ Menger, Carl. Investigations into the Methods of the Social Sciences (PDF). p. 91. (PDF) from the original on 2017-02-11.
  39. ^ Ikeda, Yukihiro. Carl Menger's Liberalism Revisited (PDF). (PDF) from the original on 2017-02-16.
  40. ^ a b "Senior Fellows, Faculty Members, and Staff". Mises.org. from the original on July 28, 2013. Retrieved July 21, 2013.
  41. ^ "In Defense of the Mises Institute". consultingbyrpm.com. from the original on 26 August 2017. Retrieved 1 May 2018.
  42. ^ Yeager, Leland (2011). Is the Market a Test of Truth and Beauty?. Ludwig von Mises Institute. p. 103. ISBN 9781610164214.
  43. ^ It has also influenced related disciplines such as Law and Economics, see. K. Grechenig, M. Litschka, Law by Human Intent or Evolution? Some Remarks on the Austrian School of Economics' Role in the Development of Law and Economics, European Journal of Law and Economics (EJLE) 2010, vol. 29 (1), pp. 57–79.
  44. ^ kanopiadmin (2011-03-14). "The Austrian School's Critique of Marxism". Mises Institute. Retrieved 2019-02-02.
  45. ^ Greenspan, Alan. "Hearings before the U.S. House of Representatives' Committee on Financial Services". U.S. House of Representatives' Committee on Financial Services. Washington D.C.. 25 July 2000.
  46. ^ "An Interview with Laureate James Buchanan". Austrian Economics Newsletter. 9 (1). Fall 1987. from the original on 2014-09-14. Retrieved 2022-08-19.
  47. ^ Boettke, Peter J.; Coyne, Christopher J. (2015). The Oxford handbook of Austrian economics. Oxford. p. 500. ISBN 9780199811762. OCLC 905518129.
  48. ^ Matarán López, Cristóbal (2021-01-26). "The Austrian school of Madrid". The Review of Austrian Economics. doi:10.1007/s11138-021-00541-0. S2CID 234027221.
  49. ^ "Generations of the Austrian School". European Center of Austrian Economics Foundation.
  50. ^ Deist, Jeff (2017-11-24). "Gabriel Calzada on Free-Market Education in Latin America". Mises Institute.
  51. ^ "About the Mises Institute". Mises.org. from the original on July 28, 2013. Retrieved July 21, 2013.
  52. ^ "Austrian Economics | Cato Institute".
  53. ^ a b White, Lawrence H. (2003). The Methodology of the Austrian School Economists (revised ed.). Ludwig von Mises Institute. from the original on 2014-02-23.
  54. ^ Ludwig von Mises, Nationalökonomie (Geneva: Union, 1940); Human Action (Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute, [1949] 1998)
  55. ^ "The Ultimate Foundation of Economic Science by Ludwig von Mises". Mises.org. from the original on 2012-10-29. Retrieved 2012-08-13.
  56. ^ Caldwell, Bruce J. (1984). "Praxeology and its Critics: an Appraisal" (PDF). History of Political Economy. 16 (3): 363–79. doi:10.1215/00182702-16-3-363.
  57. ^ Langlois, Richard N. (1985). (PDF). Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology. 3: 225–235. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2013-10-05. Retrieved 2012-12-06.
  58. ^ Lachmann, Ludwig (1973). (PDF). Institute of Economic Affairs. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2014-12-16. Retrieved 2014-12-16.
  59. ^ Horwitz, Steven: Microfoundations and Macroeconomics: An Austrian Perspective (2000)|Routledge
  60. ^ Garrison, Roger (1978). (PDF). Institute for Humane Studies. Archived from the original (PDF) on 16 December 2014. Retrieved 5 October 2015.
  61. ^ Von Neumann, John and Morgenstern, Oskar. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, New Jersey. Princeton University Press. 1944
  62. ^ Machlup, Fritz (1981). "Homage to Mises". Hillsdale College. pp. 19–27. from the original on 30 October 2013. Retrieved 8 August 2013.
  63. ^ Kirzner, Israel M.; Lachman, Ludwig M. (1986). Subjectivism, intelligibility and economic understanding: essays in honor of Ludwig M. Lachmann on his eightieth birthday (Illustrated ed.). Macmillan. ISBN 978-0-333-41788-1.
  64. ^ "Opportunity Cost". Investopedia. from the original on 14 September 2010. Retrieved 2010-09-18.
  65. ^ Ammous, Saifedean (2021). The Fiat Standard: The Debt Slavery Alternative to Human Civilization (Printed ed.). Saif House. ISBN 978-1544526478.
  66. ^ James M. Buchanan (2008). "Opportunity cost". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online (Second ed.). from the original on 2012-01-18. Retrieved 2010-09-18.
  67. ^ "Opportunity Cost". Economics A–Z. The Economist. from the original on 9 October 2010. Retrieved 2010-09-18.
  68. ^ a b Böhm-Bawerk, Eugen Ritter von; Kapital Und Kapitalizns. Zweite Abteilung: Positive Theorie des Kapitales (1889). Translated as Capital and Interest. II: Positive Theory of Capital with appendices rendered as Further Essays on Capital and Interest.
  69. ^ Oppers, Stefan Erik. "The Austrian Theory of Business Cycless: Old Lessons for Modern Economic Policy?" (PDF). International Monetary Fund. International Monetary Fund. Retrieved 28 October 2022.
  70. ^ von Mises, Ludwig (1980). "Economic Freedom and Interventionism". In Greaves, Bettina B. (ed.). Economics of Mobilization. Sulphur Springs, West Virginia: The Commercial and Financial Chronicle. from the original on 2014-09-14. Inflation, as this term was always used everywhere and especially in this country, means increasing the quantity of money and bank notes in circulation and the quantity of bank deposits subject to check. But people today use the term "inflation" to refer to the phenomenon that is an inevitable consequence of inflation, that is the tendency of all prices and wage rates to rise. The result of this deplorable confusion is that there is no term left to signify the cause of this rise in prices and wages. There is no longer any word available to signify the phenomenon that has been, up to now, called inflation [...] As you cannot talk about something that has no name, you cannot fight it. Those who pretend to fight inflation are in fact only fighting what is the inevitable consequence of inflation, rising prices. Their ventures are doomed to failure because they do not attack the root of the evil. They try to keep prices low while firmly committed to a policy of increasing the quantity of money that must necessarily make them soar. As long as this terminological confusion is not entirely wiped out, there cannot be any question of stopping inflation.
  71. ^ The Theory of Money and Credit, Mises (1912, [1981], p. 272)
  72. ^ Hayek, Friedrich August (1984). 1980s Unemployment and the Unions: Essays on the Impotent Price Structure of Britain and Monopoly in the Labour Market. Institute of Economic Affairs. ISBN 9780255361736.
  73. ^ Von Mises, Ludwig (1990). Economic calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth (PDF). Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 0-945466-07-2. (PDF) from the original on 23 September 2008. Retrieved 2008-09-08.
  74. ^ F. A. Hayek, (1935), "The Nature and History of the Problem" and "The Present State of the Debate," om in F. A. Hayek, ed. Collectivist Economic Planning, pp. 1–40, 201–43.
  75. ^ a b . Archived from the original on February 18, 2009. Retrieved May 20, 2020.
  76. ^ Ludwig von Mises. "The Principle of Methodological Individualism". Human Action. Ludwig von Mises Institute. from the original on 22 April 2009. Retrieved 2009-04-24.
  77. ^ a b c America's Great Depression, Murray Rothbard
  78. ^ a b Ebeling, Richard (2016). Austrian Economics and Public Policy: Restoring Freedom and Prosperity. Fairfax, VA: The Future of Freedom Foundation. p. 217.
  79. ^ a b Hughes, Arthur Middleton (March 1997). "The recession of 1990: An Austrian explanation". The Review of Austrian Economics. 10 (1): 107–123. doi:10.1007/BF02538145. ISSN 0889-3047. S2CID 154412906.
  80. ^ Woods, Thomas (2018). Meltdown: The Classic Free-Market Analysis of the 2008 Financial Crisis. Washington, D.C.: Regnery Publishing, Inc.
  81. ^ White, Lawrence H. (1999). "Why Didn't Hayek Favor Laissez Faire in Banking?" (PDF). History of Political Economy. 31 (4): 753–769. doi:10.1215/00182702-31-4-753. Archived (PDF) from the original on 12 April 2013. Retrieved 11 April 2013.
  82. ^ a b White, Lawrence H. (2008). "The research program of Austrian economics". Advances in Austrian Economics. Emerald Group Publishing Limited: 20.
  83. ^ Chad (2016-12-23). "How Do We Calculate Value?". Mises Institute. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  84. ^ Krugman, Paul (7 April 2010). "The Conscience of a Liberal: Martin And The Austrians". The New York Times. from the original on 23 September 2011. Retrieved 2011-09-21.
  85. ^ Klein, Benjamin. "Book review: Competition and Entrepreneurship" (by Israel M. Kirzner, University of Chicago Press, 1973) Journal of Political Economy. Vol. 83: No. 6, 1305–06, December 1975.
  86. ^ Cowen, Tyler (May 2003). "Entrepreneurship, Austrian Economics, and the Quarrel Between Philosophy and Poetry". Review of Austrian Economics. 16 (1): 5–23. doi:10.1023/A:1022958406273. S2CID 7971011.
  87. ^ Sachs, Jeffrey (October 2006). "The Social Welfare State, Beyond Ideology". Scientific American. 295 (5): 42. doi:10.1038/scientificamerican1106-42. PMID 17076081. from the original on 2008-10-14. Retrieved 2008-06-20.
  88. ^ Caplan, Bryan (2004). "Is socialism really "impossible"?". Critical Review. 16: 33–52. doi:10.1080/08913810408443598. S2CID 143580702.
  89. ^ White, Lawrence H. (2008). "The research program of Austrian economics". Advances in Austrian Economics. Emerald Group Publishing Limited: 20.
  90. ^ a b "Rules for the study of natural philosophy", from Book 3, The System of the World.
  91. ^ a b Samuelson, Paul A. (September 1964). "Theory and Realism: A Reply". The American Economic Review. American Economic Association: 736–39. Well, in connection with the exaggerated claims that used to be made in economics for the power of deduction and a priori reasoning ... – I tremble for the reputation of my subject. Fortunately, we have left that behind us.
  92. ^ a b Mayer, Thomas (Winter 1998). "Boettke's Austrian critique of mainstream economics: An empiricist's response" (PDF). Critical Review. Routledge. 12 (1–2): 151–71. doi:10.1080/08913819808443491. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2022-10-09.
  93. ^ Blaug, Mark (1992). The Methodology of Economics: Or, How Economists Explain. Cambridge University Press. pp. 45–46. ISBN 0-521-43678-8.
  94. ^ Morgan, Mary S. (2008). "Models". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. from the original on 19 January 2012. Retrieved 22 November 2011.
  95. ^ Hoover, Kevin D. (2008). "Causality in economics and econometrics". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. from the original on 19 January 2012. Retrieved 22 November 2011.
  96. ^ Yeager, Leland B (1997). "Austrian Economics, Neoclassicism, and the Market Test". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 11 (4): 153–65. doi:10.1257/jep.11.4.153. JSTOR 2138469.
  97. ^ Samuelson, Paul (1964). Economics (6th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. p. 736. ISBN 978-0-07-074741-8.
  98. ^ a b Gordon Tullock (1988). "Why the Austrians are wrong about depressions" (PDF). The Review of Austrian Economics. 2 (1): 73–78. doi:10.1007/BF01539299. S2CID 143583608. (PDF) from the original on 2009-03-25. Retrieved 2009-06-24.
  99. ^ a b Friedman, Milton (January 2005). "The Monetary Studies of the National Bureau, 44th Annual Report". The Optimal Quantity of Money and Other Essays. Chicago: Aldine. pp. 261–84. ISBN 9781412838092 – via Google Books.
  100. ^ a b Friedman, Milton (1993). "The 'Plucking Model' of Business Fluctuations Revisited". Economic Inquiry. 31 (2): 171–77. doi:10.1111/j.1465-7295.1993.tb00874.x.
  101. ^ Krugman, Paul (1998-12-04). "The Hangover Theory". Slate. from the original on 2010-10-29. Retrieved 2008-06-20.
  102. ^ Ludwig M. Lachmann, in The Market as an Economic Process (Oxford, 1986), p. ix
  103. ^ "Problems with Austrian Business Cycle Theory" (PDF). reasonpapers.com. (PDF) from the original on 24 April 2018. Retrieved 1 May 2018.
  104. ^ "Interview in Barron's Magazine". from the original on 2013-12-31. Retrieved 2015-09-28.
  105. ^ Roger W. Garrison (1982-10-25). "Plucking Model". Auburn.edu. from the original on 2012-07-26. Retrieved 2012-08-13.
  106. ^ Ron Paul (2009). End the Fed. Grand Central Publishing.

Further reading

  • Agafonow, Alejandro (2012). "The Austrian Dehomogenization Debate, or the Possibility of a Hayekian Planner". Review of Political Economy. 24 (2): 273–287. doi:10.1080/09538259.2012.664337. S2CID 154692301.
  • Campagnolo, Gilles; Vivel, Christel (2014). "The foundations of the theory of entrepreneurship in austrian economics – Menger and Böhm-Bawerk on the entrepreneur". Revue de philosophie économique. 15 (1): 49–97. doi:10.3917/rpec.151.0049. ISBN 9782711652105. PDF (in English).
  • Hagemann, Harald; Nishizawa, Tamotsu; Ikeda, Yukihiro, eds. (2010). Austrian Economics in Transition: From Carl Menger to Friedrich Hayek. Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Holcombe, Randall (1999). The Great Austrian Economists. ISBN 0945466048.
  • Littlechild, Stephen, ed. (1990). Austrian economics. Edward Elgar. ISBN 978-1-85278-120-0.
  • Papaioannou, Theo (2012). Reading Hayek in the 21st Century: a critical inquiry into his political thought. Springer.
  • Schulak, Eugen-Maria; Unterköfler, Herbert (2011). The Austrian School of Economics: A History of Its Ideas, Ambassadors, and Institutions. Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 9781610161343.
  • Wasserman, Janek (2019). The Marginal Revolutionaries: How Austrian Economists Fought the War of Ideas. (Excerpt via Amazon).

External links

austrian, school, confused, with, education, austria, economy, austria, heterodox, school, economic, thought, that, advocates, strict, adherence, methodological, individualism, concept, that, social, phenomena, result, exclusively, from, motivations, actions, . Not to be confused with Education in Austria or Economy of Austria The Austrian School is a heterodox 1 2 3 school of economic thought that advocates strict adherence to methodological individualism the concept that social phenomena result exclusively from the motivations and actions of individuals Austrian school theorists hold that economic theory should be exclusively derived from basic principles of human action 4 5 6 The Austrian School originated in late 19th and early 20th century Vienna with the work of Carl Menger Eugen von Bohm Bawerk Friedrich von Wieser and others 7 It was methodologically opposed to the Historical School based in Germany in a dispute known as Methodenstreit or methodology struggle Current day economists working in this tradition are located in many different countries but their work is still referred to as Austrian economics Among the theoretical contributions of the early years of the Austrian School are the subjective theory of value marginalism in price theory and the formulation of the economic calculation problem each of which has become an accepted part of mainstream economics 8 Since the mid 20th century mainstream economists have been critical of the modern day Austrian School and consider its rejection of mathematical modeling econometrics and macroeconomic analysis to be outside mainstream economics or heterodox In the 1970s the Austrian School attracted some renewed interest after Friedrich Hayek shared the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences with Gunnar Myrdal 9 Contents 1 History 1 1 Etymology 1 2 First wave 1 3 Early 20th century 1 4 Later 20th century 1 5 Split among contemporary Austrians 1 6 Influence 2 Methodology 2 1 Fundamental tenets 3 Contributions to economic thought 3 1 Opportunity cost 3 2 Capital and interest 3 3 Inflation 3 4 Economic calculation problem 3 5 Business cycles 3 5 1 Central banks 4 Criticism 4 1 General 4 2 Methodology 4 3 Business cycle theory 4 3 1 Theoretical objections 4 3 2 Empirical objections 5 See also 6 Notes and references 7 Further reading 8 External linksHistory Edit Jean Baptiste Say The French Liberal School of Political Economy is an intellectual ancestor of Austrian School of Economics Etymology EditThe Austrian School owes its name to members of the German historical school of economics who argued against the Austrians during the late 19th century Methodenstreit methodology struggle in which the Austrians defended the role of theory in economics as distinct from the study or compilation of historical circumstance In 1883 Menger published Investigations into the Method of the Social Sciences with Special Reference to Economics which attacked the methods of the historical school Gustav von Schmoller a leader of the historical school responded with an unfavorable review coining the term Austrian School in an attempt to characterize the school as outcast and provincial 10 The label endured and was adopted by the adherents themselves 11 First wave Edit Carl Menger The school originated in Vienna in the Austrian Empire Carl Menger s 1871 book Principles of Economics is generally considered the founding of the Austrian School The book was one of the first modern treatises to advance the theory of marginal utility The Austrian School was one of three founding currents of the marginalist revolution of the 1870s with its major contribution being the introduction of the subjectivist approach in economics 12 page needed Despite such claim John Stuart Mill had used value in use in this sense in 1848 in Principles of Political Economy 13 where he wrote Value in use or as Mr De Quincey calls it teleologic value is the extreme limit of value in exchange The exchange value of a thing may fall short to any amount of its value in use but that it can ever exceed the value in use implies a contradiction it supposes that persons will give to possess a thing more than the utmost value which they themselves put upon it as a means of gratifying their inclinations 14 While marginalism was generally influential there was also a more specific school that began to coalesce around Menger s work which came to be known as the Psychological School Vienna School or Austrian School 15 Menger s contributions to economic theory were closely followed by those of Eugen Bohm von Bawerk and Friedrich von Wieser These three economists became what is known as the first wave of the Austrian School Bohm Bawerk wrote extensive critiques of Karl Marx in the 1880s and 1890s and was part of the Austrians participation in the late 19th century Methodenstreit during which they attacked the Hegelian doctrines of the historical school Early 20th century Edit Frank Albert Fetter 1863 1949 was a leader in the United States of Austrian thought He obtained his PhD in 1894 from the University of Halle and then was made Professor of Political Economy and Finance at Cornell in 1901 Several important Austrian economists trained at the University of Vienna in the 1920s and later participated in private seminars held by Ludwig von Mises These included Gottfried Haberler 16 Friedrich Hayek Fritz Machlup 17 Karl Menger son of Carl Menger 18 Oskar Morgenstern 19 Paul Rosenstein Rodan 20 Abraham Wald 21 and Michael A Heilperin 22 among others as well as the sociologist Alfred Schutz 23 Later 20th century Edit Campus of Mises Institute in Auburn Alabama By the mid 1930s most economists had embraced what they considered the important contributions of the early Austrians 1 Fritz Machlup quoted Hayek s statement that the greatest success of a school is that it stops existing because its fundamental teachings have become parts of the general body of commonly accepted thought 24 Sometime during the middle of the 20th century Austrian economics became disregarded or derided by mainstream economists because it rejected model building and mathematical and statistical methods in the study of economics 25 Mises student Israel Kirzner recalled that in 1954 when Kirzner was pursuing his PhD there was no separate Austrian School as such When Kirzner was deciding which graduate school to attend Mises had advised him to accept an offer of admission at Johns Hopkins because it was a prestigious university and Fritz Machlup taught there 26 After the 1940s Austrian economics can be divided into two schools of economic thought and the school split to some degree in the late 20th century One camp of Austrians exemplified by Mises regards neoclassical methodology to be irredeemably flawed the other camp exemplified by Friedrich Hayek accepts a large part of neoclassical methodology and is more accepting of government intervention in the economy 27 Henry Hazlitt wrote economics columns and editorials for a number of publications and wrote many books on the topic of Austrian economics from the 1930s to the 1980s Hazlitt s thinking was influenced by Mises 28 His book Economics in One Lesson 1946 sold over a million copies and he is also known for The Failure of the New Economics 1959 a line by line critique of John Maynard Keynes s General Theory 29 The reputation of the Austrian School rose in the late 20th century due in part to the work of Israel Kirzner and Ludwig Lachmann at New York University and to renewed public awareness of the work of Hayek after he won the 1974 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences 30 Hayek s work was influential in the revival of laissez faire thought in the 20th century 31 32 Split among contemporary Austrians Edit Economist Leland Yeager discussed the late 20th century rift and referred to a discussion written by Murray Rothbard Hans Hermann Hoppe Joseph Salerno and others in which they attack and disparage Hayek Yeager stated To try to drive a wedge between Mises and Hayek on the role of knowledge in economic calculation especially to the disparagement of Hayek is unfair to these two great men unfaithful to the history of economic thought He went on to call the rift subversive to economic analysis and the historical understanding of the fall of Eastern European communism 33 In a 1999 book published by the Ludwig von Mises Institute 34 Hoppe asserted that Rothbard was the leader of the mainstream within Austrian Economics and contrasted Rothbard with Nobel Laureate Friedrich Hayek whom he identified as a British empiricist and an opponent of the thought of Mises and Rothbard Hoppe acknowledged that Hayek was the most prominent Austrian economist within academia but stated that Hayek was an opponent of the Austrian tradition which led from Carl Menger and Bohm Bawerk through Mises to Rothbard Austrian economist Walter Block says that the Austrian School can be distinguished from other schools of economic thought through two categories economic theory and political theory According to Block while Hayek can be considered an Austrian economist his views on political theory clash with the libertarian political theory which Block sees as an integral part of the Austrian School 35 Both criticism from Hoppe and Block to Hayek apply to Carl Menger the founder of the Austrian School Hoppe emphasizes that Hayek which for him is from the English empirical tradition is an opponent of the supposed rationalist tradition of the Austrian School Menger made strong critiques to rationalism in his works in similar vein as Hayek s 36 He emphasized the idea that there are several institutions which were not deliberately created have a kind of superior wisdom and serve important functions to society 37 36 38 He also talked about Burke and the English tradition to sustain these positions 36 When saying that the libertarian political theory is an integral part of the Austrian School and supposing Hayek is not a libertarian Block excludes Menger from the Austrian School too since Menger seems to defend broader state activity than Hayek for example progressive taxation and extensive labour legislation 39 Economists of the Hayekian view are affiliated with the Cato Institute George Mason University GMU and New York University among other institutions They include Peter Boettke Roger Garrison Steven Horwitz Peter Leeson and George Reisman Economists of the Mises Rothbard view include Walter Block Hans Hermann Hoppe Jesus Huerta de Soto and Robert P Murphy each of whom is associated with the Mises Institute 40 and some of them also with academic institutions 40 According to Murphy a truce between for lack of better terms the GMU Austro libertarians and the Auburn Austro libertarians was signed around 2011 41 42 Influence Edit Many theories developed by first wave Austrian economists have long been absorbed into mainstream economics 43 These include Carl Menger s theories on marginal utility Friedrich von Wieser s theories on opportunity cost and Eugen Bohm von Bawerk s theories on time preference as well as Menger and Bohm Bawerk s criticisms of Marxian economics 44 Former American Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan said that the founders of the Austrian School reached far into the future from when most of them practiced and have had a profound and in my judgment probably an irreversible effect on how most mainstream economists think in this country 45 In 1987 Nobel Laureate James M Buchanan told an interviewer I have no objections to being called an Austrian Hayek and Mises might consider me an Austrian but surely some of the others would not 46 Currently universities with a significant Austrian presence are George Mason University 47 New York University Grove City College Loyola University New Orleans and Auburn University in the United States King Juan Carlos University in Spain 48 and Universidad Francisco Marroquin in Guatemala 49 50 Austrian economic ideas are also promoted by privately funded organizations such as the Mises Institute 51 and the Cato Institute 52 Methodology EditMain articles Action axiom Catallactics and Praxeology The Austrian School theorizes that the subjective choices of individuals including individual knowledge time expectation and other subjective factors cause all economic phenomena Austrians seek to understand the economy by examining the social ramifications of individual choice an approach called methodological individualism It differs from other schools of economic thought which have focused on aggregate variables equilibrium analysis and societal groups rather than individuals 53 Ludwig von Mises In the 20th and 21st centuries economists with a methodological lineage to the early Austrian School developed many diverse approaches and theoretical orientations Ludwig von Mises organized his version of the subjectivist approach which he called praxeology in a book published in English as Human Action in 1949 54 3 In it Mises stated that praxeology could be used to deduce a priori theoretical economic truths and that deductive economic thought experiments could yield conclusions which follow irrefutably from the underlying assumptions He wrote that conclusions could not be inferred from empirical observation or statistical analysis and argued against the use of probabilities in economic models 55 Since Mises time some Austrian thinkers have accepted his praxeological approach while others have adopted alternative methodologies 56 For example Fritz Machlup Friedrich Hayek and others did not take Mises strong a priori approach to economics 57 Ludwig Lachmann a radical subjectivist also largely rejected Mises formulation of Praxeology in favor of the verstehende Methode interpretive method articulated by Max Weber 53 58 In the 20th century various Austrians incorporated models and mathematics into their analysis Austrian economist Steven Horwitz argued in 2000 that Austrian methodology is consistent with macroeconomics and that Austrian macroeconomics can be expressed in terms of microeconomic foundations 59 Austrian economist Roger Garrison writes that Austrian macroeconomic theory can be correctly expressed in terms of diagrammatic models 60 In 1944 Austrian economist Oskar Morgenstern presented a rigorous schematization of an ordinal utility function the Von Neumann Morgenstern utility theorem in Theory of Games and Economic Behavior 61 Fundamental tenets Edit In 1981 Fritz Machlup listed the typical views of Austrian economic thinking as such 62 Methodological individualism in the explanation of economic phenomena we have to go back to the actions or inaction of individuals groups or collectives cannot act except through the actions of individual members Groups don t think people think Methodological subjectivism in the explanation of economic phenomena we have to go back to judgments and choices made by individuals on the basis of whatever knowledge they have or believe to have and whatever expectations they entertain regarding external developments and especially the perceived consequences of their own intended actions Tastes and preferences subjective valuations of goods and services determine the demand for them so that their prices are influenced by actual and potential consumers Opportunity costs the costs with which producers and other economic actors calculate reflect the alternative opportunities that must be foregone as productive services are employed for one purpose all alternative uses have to be sacrificed Marginalism in all economic designs the values costs revenues productivity and so on are determined by the significance of the last unit added to or subtracted from the total Time structure of production and consumption decisions to save reflect time preferences regarding consumption in the immediate distant or indefinite future and investments are made in view of larger outputs expected to be obtained if more time taking production processes are undertaken He included two additional tenets held by the Mises branch of Austrian economics Consumer sovereignty the influence consumers have on the effective demand for goods and services and through the prices which result in free competitive markets on the production plans of producers and investors is not merely a hard fact but also an important objective attainable only by complete avoidance of governmental interference with the markets and of restrictions on the freedom of sellers and buyers to follow their own judgment regarding quantities qualities and prices of products and services Political individualism only when individuals are given full economic freedom will it be possible to secure political and moral freedom Restrictions on economic freedom lead sooner or later to an extension of the coercive activities of the state into the political domain undermining and eventually destroying the essential individual liberties which the capitalistic societies were able to attain in the 19th century Contributions to economic thought EditOpportunity cost Edit Main article Opportunity cost Friedrich von Wieser The opportunity cost doctrine was first explicitly formulated by the Austrian economist Friedrich von Wieser in the late 19th century 63 Opportunity cost is the cost of any activity measured in terms of the value of the next best alternative foregone that is not chosen It is the sacrifice related to the second best choice available to someone or group who has picked among several mutually exclusive choices 64 Although a more ephemeral scarcity expectations of the future must also be considered Quantified as time preference opportunity cost must also be valued with respect to one s preference for present versus future investments 65 Opportunity cost is a key concept in mainstream economics and has been described as expressing the basic relationship between scarcity and choice 66 The notion of opportunity cost plays a crucial part in ensuring that resources are used efficiently 67 Capital and interest Edit See also Capital and Interest Marginalism Neutrality of money and Time preference Eugen Bohm von Bawerk The Austrian theory of capital and interest was first developed by Eugen Bohm von Bawerk He stated that interest rates and profits are determined by two factors namely supply and demand in the market for final goods and time preference 68 Bohm Bawerk s theory equates capital intensity with the degree of roundaboutness of production processes Bohm Bawerk also argued that the law of marginal utility necessarily implies the classical law of costs 68 Some Austrian economists therefore entirely reject the notion that interest rates are affected by liquidity preference 69 Inflation Edit See also Monetary inflationIn Mises s definition inflation is an increase in the supply of money 70 In theoretical investigation there is only one meaning that can rationally be attached to the expression Inflation an increase in the quantity of money in the broader sense of the term so as to include fiduciary media as well that is not offset by a corresponding increase in the need for money again in the broader sense of the term so that a fall in the objective exchange value of money must occur 71 Hayek pointed out that inflationary stimulation exploits the lag between an increase in money supply and the consequent increase in the prices of goods and services And since any inflation however modest at first can help employment only so long as it accelerates adopted as a means of reducing unemployment it will do so for any length of time only while it accelerates Mild steady inflation cannot help it can lead only to outright inflation That inflation at a constant rate soon ceases to have any stimulating effect and in the end merely leaves us with a backlog of delayed adaptations is the conclusive argument against the mild inflation represented as beneficial even in standard economics textbooks 72 Economic calculation problem Edit Main article Economic calculation problem Friedrich Hayek Israel Kirzner The economic calculation problem refers to a criticism of planned economies which was first stated by Max Weber in 1920 Mises subsequently discussed Weber s idea with his student Friedrich Hayek who developed it in various works including The Road to Serfdom 73 74 What the calculation problem essentially states is that without price signals the factors of production cannot be allocated in the most efficient way possible rendering planned economies inefficacious Austrian theory emphasizes the organizing power of markets Hayek stated that market prices reflect information the totality of which is not known to any single individual which determines the allocation of resources in an economy Because socialist systems lack the individual incentives and price discovery processes by which individuals act on their personal information Hayek argued that socialist economic planners lack all of the knowledge required to make optimal decisions Those who agree with this criticism view it as a refutation of socialism showing that socialism is not a viable or sustainable form of economic organization The debate rose to prominence in the 1920s and 1930s and that specific period of the debate has come to be known by historians of economic thought as the socialist calculation debate 75 Mises argued in a 1920 essay Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth that the pricing systems in socialist economies were necessarily deficient because if the government owned the means of production then no prices could be obtained for capital goods as they were merely internal transfers of goods in a socialist system and not objects of exchange unlike final goods Therefore they were unpriced and hence the system would be necessarily inefficient since the central planners would not know how to allocate the available resources efficiently 75 This led him to write that rational economic activity is impossible in a socialist commonwealth 76 Business cycles Edit Main article Austrian business cycle theory The Austrian theory of the business cycle ABCT focuses on banks issuance of credit as the cause of economic fluctuations 77 Although later elaborated by Hayek and others the theory was first set forth by Mises who posited that fractional reserve banks extend credit at artificially low interest rates causing businesses to invest in relatively roundabout production processes which leads to an artificial boom Mises stated that this artificial boom then led to a misallocation of resources which he called malinvestment which eventually must end in a bust 77 Mises surmised how government manipulation of money and credit in the banking system throws savings and investment out of balance resulting in misdirected investment projects that are eventually found to be unsustainable at which point the economy has to rebalance itself through a period of corrective recession 78 Austrian economist Fritz Machlup summarized the Austrian view by stating monetary factors cause the cycle but real phenomena constitute it 79 For Austrians the only prudent strategy for government is to leave money and the financial system to the free market s competitive forces to eradicate the business cycle s inflationary booms and recessionary busts allowing markets to keep people s saving and investment decisions in place for well coordinated economic stability and growth 78 A Keynesian would suggest government intervention during a recession to inject spending into the economy when people are not However the heart of Austrian macroeconomic theory states the government fine tuning through expansions and contractions in the money supply orchestrated by the government are actually the cause of business cycles because of the differing impact of the resulting interest rate changes on different stages in the structure of production 79 Austrian economist Thomas Woods further supports this view by arguing it is not consumption but rather production that should be emphasized A country cannot become rich by consuming and therefore by using up all their resources Instead production is what enables consumption as a possibility in the first place since a producer would be working for nothing if not for the desire to consume 80 Central banks Edit According to Ludwig von Mises central banks enable the commercial banks to fund loans at artificially low interest rates thereby inducing an unsustainable expansion of bank credit and impeding any subsequent contraction and argued for a gold standard to constrain growth in fiduciary media 77 Friedrich Hayek took a different perspective not focusing on gold but focusing on regulation of the banking sector via strong central banking 81 Criticism EditGeneral Edit Mainstream economists generally reject modern day Austrian economics and argue that modern day Austrian economists are excessively averse to the use of mathematics and statistics in economics 82 Austrian opposition to mathematization extends to economic theorizing only as they argue that human behavior is too variable for overarching mathematical models to hold true across time and context Austrians do however support analyzing revealed preference via mathematization to aid business and finance 83 Economist Paul Krugman has stated that Austrians are unaware of holes in their own thinking because they do not use explicit models 84 Economist Benjamin Klein has criticized the economic methodological work of Austrian economist Israel M Kirzner While praising Kirzner for highlighting shortcomings in traditional methodology Klein argued that Kirzner did not provide a viable alternative for economic methodology 85 Economist Tyler Cowen has written that Kirzner s theory of entrepreneurship can ultimately be reduced to a neoclassical search model and is thus not in the radical subjectivist tradition of Austrian praxeology Cowen states that Kirzner s entrepreneurs can be modeled in mainstream terms of search 86 Economist Jeffrey Sachs argues that among developed countries those with high rates of taxation and high social welfare spending perform better on most measures of economic performance compared to countries with low rates of taxation and low social outlays He concludes that Friedrich Hayek was wrong to argue that high levels of government spending harms an economy and a generous social welfare state is not a road to serfdom but rather to fairness economic equality and international competitiveness 87 Economist Bryan Caplan has noted that Mises has been criticized for overstating the strength of his case in describing socialism as impossible rather than as something that would need to establish non market institutions to deal with the inefficiency 88 Methodology Edit Critics generally argue that Austrian economics lacks scientific rigor and rejects scientific methods and the use of empirical data in modelling economic behavior 89 90 Some economists describe Austrian methodology as being a priori or non empirical 82 91 92 Economist Mark Blaug has criticized over reliance on methodological individualism arguing it would rule out all macroeconomic propositions that cannot be reduced to microeconomic ones and hence reject almost the whole of received macroeconomics 93 Economist Thomas Mayer has stated that Austrians advocate a rejection of the scientific method which involves the development of empirically falsifiable theories 90 92 Furthermore economists have developed numerous experiments that elicit useful information about individual preferences 94 95 Although economist Leland Yeager is sympathetic to Austrian economics he rejects many favorite views of the Misesian group of Austrians in particular the specifics of their business cycle theory ultra subjectivism in value theory and particularly in interest rate theory their insistence on unidirectional causality rather than general interdependence and their fondness for methodological brooding pointless profundities and verbal gymnastics 96 Economist Paul A Samuelson wrote in 1964 that most economists believe that economic conclusions reached by pure logical deduction are limited and weak 97 According to Samuelson and Caplan Mises deductive methodology also embraced by Murray Rothbard and to a lesser extent by Mises student Israel Kirzner was not sufficient in and of itself 91 Business cycle theory EditMainstream economic research regarding Austrian business cycle theory finds that it is inconsistent with empirical evidence Noted economists such as Gordon Tullock 98 Milton Friedman 99 100 and Paul Krugman 101 have said that they regard the theory as incorrect Austrian economist Ludwig Lachmann noted that the Austrian theory was rejected during the 1930s The promise of an Austrian theory of the trade cycle which might also serve to explain the severity of the Great Depression a feature of the early 1930s that provided the background for Hayek s successful appearance on the London scene soon proved deceptive Three giants Keynes Knight and Sraffa turned against the hapless Austrians who in the middle of that black decade thus had to do battle on three fronts Naturally it proved a task beyond their strength 102 Theoretical objections EditSome economists have argued that Austrian business cycle theory requires bankers and investors to exhibit a kind of irrationality because the Austrian theory posits that investors will be fooled repeatedly by temporarily low interest rates into making unprofitable investment decisions 98 103 Milton Friedman objected to the policy implications of the theory stating the following in a 1998 interview I think the Austrian business cycle theory has done the world a great deal of harm If you go back to the 1930s which is a key point here you had the Austrians sitting in London Hayek and Lionel Robbins and saying you just have to let the bottom drop out of the world You ve just got to let it cure itself You can t do anything about it You will only make it worse You have Rothbard saying it was a great mistake not to let the whole banking system collapse I think by encouraging that kind of do nothing policy both in Britain and in the United States they did harm 104 Empirical objections Edit In 1969 Milton Friedman examined the history of business cycles in the United States and wrote that there appears to be no systematic connection between the size of an expansion and of the succeeding contraction contradicting business cycle theories such as the Austrian business cycle theory which rely on that premise 99 He analyzed the issue using newer data in 1993 and again reached the same conclusion 100 Referring to Friedman s discussion of the business cycle Austrian economist Roger Garrison argued that Friedman s empirical findings are broadly consistent with both Monetarist and Austrian views and goes on to argue that although Friedman s model describes the economy s performance at the highest level of aggregation Austrian theory offers an insightful account of the market process that might underlie those aggregates 105 See also EditCarl Menger Chicago school of economics Criticism of the Federal Reserve 106 Eugen von Bohm Bawerk Friedrich Hayek Dorian Electra Hans Hermann Hoppe Henry Hazlitt Israel Kirzner List of Austrian intellectual traditions List of Austrian School economists Ludwig von Mises New institutional economics Perspectives on capitalism by school of thought School of Salamanca Gold standardNotes and references Edit a b Boettke Peter J Peter T Leeson 2003 28A The Austrian School of Economics 1950 2000 In Warren Samuels Jeff E Biddle John B Davis eds A Companion to the History of Economic Thought Blackwell Publishing pp 446 52 ISBN 978 0 631 22573 7 Heterodox economics Marginal revolutionaries The Economist December 31 2011 Archived from the original on February 22 2012 Retrieved February 22 2012 Denis Andy 2008 Dialectics and the Austrian School A Surprising Commonality in the Methodology of Heterodox Economics The Journal of Philosophical Economics 1 2 151 173 Retrieved 19 May 2022 Carl Menger Principles of Economics online at Principles of Economics 18 August 2014 Retrieved 2020 04 01 Heath Joseph 1 May 2018 Zalta Edward N ed The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy Metaphysics Research Lab Stanford University Retrieved 1 May 2018 via Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy Ludwig von Mises Human Action p 11 Purposeful Action and Animal Reaction Referenced 2011 11 23 Joseph A Schumpeter History of economic analysis Oxford University Press 1996 ISBN 978 0195105599 Birner Jack van Zijp Rudy 1994 Hayek Co ordination and Evolution His Legacy in Philosophy Politics Economics and the History of Ideas London New York Routledge p 94 ISBN 978 0 415 09397 2 Meijer G 1995 New Perspectives on Austrian Economics New York Routledge ISBN 978 0 415 12283 2 Menger s approach haughtily dismissed by the leader of the German Historical School Gustav Schmoller as merely Austrian the origin of that label led to a renaissance of theoretical economics in Europe and later in the United States Peter G Klein 2007 in the Foreword to Principles of Economics Carl Menger trns James Dingwall and Bert F Hoselitz 1976 Ludwig von Mises Institute Alabama 2007 ISBN 978 1 933550 12 1 von Mises Ludwig 1984 1969 The Historical Setting of the Austrian School of Economics PDF Ludwig von Mises Institute Archived PDF from the original on 2014 06 24 Keizer Willem 1997 Austrian Economics in Debate New York Routledge ISBN 978 0 415 14054 6 Ahiakpor J C W 2003 Classical Macroeconomics Some Modern Variations and Distortions Routledge p 21 Mill J S 1848 Principles of Political Economy Kirzner Israel M 1987 Austrian School of Economics The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics 1 145 51 Salerno Joseph T 1 August 2007 Biography of Gottfried Haberler 1901 1995 Mises Institute Archived from the original on 2014 09 14 Biography of Fritz Machlup Archived from the original on 5 July 2013 Retrieved 16 June 2013 About Karl Menger Department of Applied Mathematics IIT College of Science Illinois Institute of Technology www iit edu Archived from the original on 29 October 2013 Retrieved 1 May 2018 Guide to the Oskar Morgenstern Papers 1866 1992 and undated Rubenstein Library Duke University Archived from the original on 2012 10 17 Rodan Paul Rosenstein 1902 1985 political economist Archive at London School of Economics Oskar Morgenstern Oct 1951 Abraham Wald 1902 1950 Econometrica The Econometric Society 19 4 361 67 doi 10 2307 1907462 JSTOR 1907462 Studies in Economic Nationalism 18 August 2014 Kurrild Klitgaard Peter Summer 2003 The Viennese Connection Alfred Schutz and the Austrian School PDF Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 6 2 35 67 doi 10 1007 s12113 003 1018 y S2CID 154202208 Archived PDF from the original on 2022 10 09 Retrieved 2022 08 19 Kurrild Klitgaard Peter 2001 On Rationality Ideal Types and Economics Alfred Schutz and the Austrian School The Review of Austrian Economics 14 2 3 119 143 doi 10 1023 A 1011199831428 S2CID 33060092 Ludwig von Mises A Scholar Who Would Not Compromise 15 December 2004 Archived from the original on 2014 09 14 Retrieved 2014 09 13 Homage to Mises by Fritz Machlup 1981 Backhouse Roger E January 2000 Austrian economics and the mainstream View from the boundary The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 3 2 31 43 doi 10 1007 s12113 000 1002 8 S2CID 154604886 Archived from the original on 2017 02 10 Retrieved 2017 01 24 Hayek did not fall out of favor because he was not Keynesian neither are Friedman or Lucas but because he was perceived to be doing neither rigorous theory nor empirical work Kirzner Israel Interview of Israel Kirzner Ludwig von Mises Institute Archived from the original on 9 September 2013 Retrieved 17 June 2013 kanopiadmin 30 July 2014 The Hayek and Mises Controversy Bridging Differences Odd J Stalebrink PDF mises org Archived PDF from the original on 14 November 2012 Retrieved 1 May 2018 Remembering Henry Hazlitt The Freeman Archived from the original on 2013 01 13 Retrieved 2013 03 11 Biography of Henry Hazlitt Ludwig von Mises Institute Archived from the original on 2012 01 28 Retrieved 2013 03 11 Meijer Gerrit ed 1995 New Perspectives on Austrian Economics New York Routledge ISBN 978 0 415 12283 2 OCLC 70769328 Raico Ralph 2011 Austrian Economics and Classical Liberalism mises org Ludwig von Mises Institute Archived from the original on 19 May 2011 Retrieved 27 July 2011 despite the particular policy views of its founders Austrianism was perceived as the economics of the free market Kasper Sherryl Davis 2002 The Revival of Laissez faire in American Macroeconomic Theory Edward Elgar Publishing p 66 ISBN 978 1 84064 606 1 Yaeger Leland 2011 Is the Market a Test of Truth and Beauty Essays in Political Economy Ludwig von Mises Institute pp 93 ff Hoppe Hans Hermann 1999 15 Great Austrian Economists Murray Rothbard PDF Alabama Ludwig von Mises Institute pp 223 ff Archived PDF from the original on 2014 10 07 Dr Walter Block Austrian vs Chicago Schools Mises Canada Rothbard School 2014 Archived from the original on 18 May 2015 Retrieved 3 December 2014 a b c Menger Carl Investigations into the Methods of the Social Sciences PDF pp 173 175 Archived PDF from the original on 2017 02 11 Menger Carl Investigations into the Methods of the Social Sciences PDF pp 146 147 Archived PDF from the original on 2017 02 11 Menger Carl Investigations into the Methods of the Social Sciences PDF p 91 Archived PDF from the original on 2017 02 11 Ikeda Yukihiro Carl Menger s Liberalism Revisited PDF Archived PDF from the original on 2017 02 16 a b Senior Fellows Faculty Members and Staff Mises org Archived from the original on July 28 2013 Retrieved July 21 2013 In Defense of the Mises Institute consultingbyrpm com Archived from the original on 26 August 2017 Retrieved 1 May 2018 Yeager Leland 2011 Is the Market a Test of Truth and Beauty Ludwig von Mises Institute p 103 ISBN 9781610164214 It has also influenced related disciplines such as Law and Economics see K Grechenig M Litschka Law by Human Intent or Evolution Some Remarks on the Austrian School of Economics Role in the Development of Law and Economics European Journal of Law and Economics EJLE 2010 vol 29 1 pp 57 79 kanopiadmin 2011 03 14 The Austrian School s Critique of Marxism Mises Institute Retrieved 2019 02 02 Greenspan Alan Hearings before the U S House of Representatives Committee on Financial Services U S House of Representatives Committee on Financial Services Washington D C 25 July 2000 An Interview with Laureate James Buchanan Austrian Economics Newsletter 9 1 Fall 1987 Archived from the original on 2014 09 14 Retrieved 2022 08 19 Boettke Peter J Coyne Christopher J 2015 The Oxford handbook of Austrian economics Oxford p 500 ISBN 9780199811762 OCLC 905518129 Mataran Lopez Cristobal 2021 01 26 The Austrian school of Madrid The Review of Austrian Economics doi 10 1007 s11138 021 00541 0 S2CID 234027221 Generations of the Austrian School European Center of Austrian Economics Foundation Deist Jeff 2017 11 24 Gabriel Calzada on Free Market Education in Latin America Mises Institute About the Mises Institute Mises org Archived from the original on July 28 2013 Retrieved July 21 2013 Austrian Economics Cato Institute a b White Lawrence H 2003 The Methodology of the Austrian School Economists revised ed Ludwig von Mises Institute Archived from the original on 2014 02 23 Ludwig von Mises Nationalokonomie Geneva Union 1940 Human Action Auburn Ala Ludwig von Mises Institute 1949 1998 The Ultimate Foundation of Economic Science by Ludwig von Mises Mises org Archived from the original on 2012 10 29 Retrieved 2012 08 13 Caldwell Bruce J 1984 Praxeology and its Critics an Appraisal PDF History of Political Economy 16 3 363 79 doi 10 1215 00182702 16 3 363 Langlois Richard N 1985 From the Knowledge of Economics to the Economics of Knowledge Fritz Machlup on Methodology and on the Knowledge Society PDF Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 3 225 235 Archived from the original PDF on 2013 10 05 Retrieved 2012 12 06 Lachmann Ludwig 1973 Macroeconomic Thinking and the Market Economy PDF Institute of Economic Affairs Archived from the original PDF on 2014 12 16 Retrieved 2014 12 16 Horwitz Steven Microfoundations and Macroeconomics An Austrian Perspective 2000 Routledge Garrison Roger 1978 Austrian Macroeconomics A Diagrammatical Exposition PDF Institute for Humane Studies Archived from the original PDF on 16 December 2014 Retrieved 5 October 2015 Von Neumann John and Morgenstern Oskar Theory of Games and Economic Behavior Princeton New Jersey Princeton University Press 1944 Machlup Fritz 1981 Homage to Mises Hillsdale College pp 19 27 Archived from the original on 30 October 2013 Retrieved 8 August 2013 Kirzner Israel M Lachman Ludwig M 1986 Subjectivism intelligibility and economic understanding essays in honor of Ludwig M Lachmann on his eightieth birthday Illustrated ed Macmillan ISBN 978 0 333 41788 1 Opportunity Cost Investopedia Archived from the original on 14 September 2010 Retrieved 2010 09 18 Ammous Saifedean 2021 The Fiat Standard The Debt Slavery Alternative to Human Civilization Printed ed Saif House ISBN 978 1544526478 James M Buchanan 2008 Opportunity cost The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online Second ed Archived from the original on 2012 01 18 Retrieved 2010 09 18 Opportunity Cost Economics A Z The Economist Archived from the original on 9 October 2010 Retrieved 2010 09 18 a b Bohm Bawerk Eugen Ritter von Kapital Und Kapitalizns Zweite Abteilung Positive Theorie des Kapitales 1889 Translated as Capital and Interest II Positive Theory of Capital with appendices rendered as Further Essays on Capital and Interest Oppers Stefan Erik The Austrian Theory of Business Cycless Old Lessons for Modern Economic Policy PDF International Monetary Fund International Monetary Fund Retrieved 28 October 2022 von Mises Ludwig 1980 Economic Freedom and Interventionism In Greaves Bettina B ed Economics of Mobilization Sulphur Springs West Virginia The Commercial and Financial Chronicle Archived from the original on 2014 09 14 Inflation as this term was always used everywhere and especially in this country means increasing the quantity of money and bank notes in circulation and the quantity of bank deposits subject to check But people today use the term inflation to refer to the phenomenon that is an inevitable consequence of inflation that is the tendency of all prices and wage rates to rise The result of this deplorable confusion is that there is no term left to signify the cause of this rise in prices and wages There is no longer any word available to signify the phenomenon that has been up to now called inflation As you cannot talk about something that has no name you cannot fight it Those who pretend to fight inflation are in fact only fighting what is the inevitable consequence of inflation rising prices Their ventures are doomed to failure because they do not attack the root of the evil They try to keep prices low while firmly committed to a policy of increasing the quantity of money that must necessarily make them soar As long as this terminological confusion is not entirely wiped out there cannot be any question of stopping inflation The Theory of Money and Credit Mises 1912 1981 p 272 Hayek Friedrich August 1984 1980s Unemployment and the Unions Essays on the Impotent Price Structure of Britain and Monopoly in the Labour Market Institute of Economic Affairs ISBN 9780255361736 Von Mises Ludwig 1990 Economic calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth PDF Ludwig von Mises Institute ISBN 0 945466 07 2 Archived PDF from the original on 23 September 2008 Retrieved 2008 09 08 F A Hayek 1935 The Nature and History of the Problem and The Present State of the Debate om in F A Hayek ed Collectivist Economic Planning pp 1 40 201 43 a b The socialist calculation debate Archived from the original on February 18 2009 Retrieved May 20 2020 Ludwig von Mises The Principle of Methodological Individualism Human Action Ludwig von Mises Institute Archived from the original on 22 April 2009 Retrieved 2009 04 24 a b c America s Great Depression Murray Rothbard a b Ebeling Richard 2016 Austrian Economics and Public Policy Restoring Freedom and Prosperity Fairfax VA The Future of Freedom Foundation p 217 a b Hughes Arthur Middleton March 1997 The recession of 1990 An Austrian explanation The Review of Austrian Economics 10 1 107 123 doi 10 1007 BF02538145 ISSN 0889 3047 S2CID 154412906 Woods Thomas 2018 Meltdown The Classic Free Market Analysis of the 2008 Financial Crisis Washington D C Regnery Publishing Inc White Lawrence H 1999 Why Didn t Hayek Favor Laissez Faire in Banking PDF History of Political Economy 31 4 753 769 doi 10 1215 00182702 31 4 753 Archived PDF from the original on 12 April 2013 Retrieved 11 April 2013 a b White Lawrence H 2008 The research program of Austrian economics Advances in Austrian Economics Emerald Group Publishing Limited 20 Chad 2016 12 23 How Do We Calculate Value Mises Institute Retrieved 2021 02 04 Krugman Paul 7 April 2010 The Conscience of a Liberal Martin And The Austrians The New York Times Archived from the original on 23 September 2011 Retrieved 2011 09 21 Klein Benjamin Book review Competition and Entrepreneurship by Israel M Kirzner University of Chicago Press 1973 Journal of Political Economy Vol 83 No 6 1305 06 December 1975 Cowen Tyler May 2003 Entrepreneurship Austrian Economics and the Quarrel Between Philosophy and Poetry Review of Austrian Economics 16 1 5 23 doi 10 1023 A 1022958406273 S2CID 7971011 Sachs Jeffrey October 2006 The Social Welfare State Beyond Ideology Scientific American 295 5 42 doi 10 1038 scientificamerican1106 42 PMID 17076081 Archived from the original on 2008 10 14 Retrieved 2008 06 20 Caplan Bryan 2004 Is socialism really impossible Critical Review 16 33 52 doi 10 1080 08913810408443598 S2CID 143580702 White Lawrence H 2008 The research program of Austrian economics Advances in Austrian Economics Emerald Group Publishing Limited 20 a b Rules for the study of natural philosophy from Book 3 The System of the World a b Samuelson Paul A September 1964 Theory and Realism A Reply The American Economic Review American Economic Association 736 39 Well in connection with the exaggerated claims that used to be made in economics for the power of deduction and a priori reasoning I tremble for the reputation of my subject Fortunately we have left that behind us a b Mayer Thomas Winter 1998 Boettke s Austrian critique of mainstream economics An empiricist s response PDF Critical Review Routledge 12 1 2 151 71 doi 10 1080 08913819808443491 Archived PDF from the original on 2022 10 09 Blaug Mark 1992 The Methodology of Economics Or How Economists Explain Cambridge University Press pp 45 46 ISBN 0 521 43678 8 Morgan Mary S 2008 Models The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Archived from the original on 19 January 2012 Retrieved 22 November 2011 Hoover Kevin D 2008 Causality in economics and econometrics The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Archived from the original on 19 January 2012 Retrieved 22 November 2011 Yeager Leland B 1997 Austrian Economics Neoclassicism and the Market Test Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 4 153 65 doi 10 1257 jep 11 4 153 JSTOR 2138469 Samuelson Paul 1964 Economics 6th ed New York McGraw Hill p 736 ISBN 978 0 07 074741 8 a b Gordon Tullock 1988 Why the Austrians are wrong about depressions PDF The Review of Austrian Economics 2 1 73 78 doi 10 1007 BF01539299 S2CID 143583608 Archived PDF from the original on 2009 03 25 Retrieved 2009 06 24 a b Friedman Milton January 2005 The Monetary Studies of the National Bureau 44th Annual Report The Optimal Quantity of Money and Other Essays Chicago Aldine pp 261 84 ISBN 9781412838092 via Google Books a b Friedman Milton 1993 The Plucking Model of Business Fluctuations Revisited Economic Inquiry 31 2 171 77 doi 10 1111 j 1465 7295 1993 tb00874 x Krugman Paul 1998 12 04 The Hangover Theory Slate Archived from the original on 2010 10 29 Retrieved 2008 06 20 Ludwig M Lachmann in The Market as an Economic Process Oxford 1986 p ix Problems with Austrian Business Cycle Theory PDF reasonpapers com Archived PDF from the original on 24 April 2018 Retrieved 1 May 2018 Interview in Barron s Magazine Archived from the original on 2013 12 31 Retrieved 2015 09 28 Roger W Garrison 1982 10 25 Plucking Model Auburn edu Archived from the original on 2012 07 26 Retrieved 2012 08 13 Ron Paul 2009 End the Fed Grand Central Publishing Further reading EditAgafonow Alejandro 2012 The Austrian Dehomogenization Debate or the Possibility of a Hayekian Planner Review of Political Economy 24 2 273 287 doi 10 1080 09538259 2012 664337 S2CID 154692301 Campagnolo Gilles Vivel Christel 2014 The foundations of the theory of entrepreneurship in austrian economics Menger and Bohm Bawerk on the entrepreneur Revue de philosophie economique 15 1 49 97 doi 10 3917 rpec 151 0049 ISBN 9782711652105 PDF in English Hagemann Harald Nishizawa Tamotsu Ikeda Yukihiro eds 2010 Austrian Economics in Transition From Carl Menger to Friedrich Hayek Palgrave Macmillan Holcombe Randall 1999 The Great Austrian Economists ISBN 0945466048 Littlechild Stephen ed 1990 Austrian economics Edward Elgar ISBN 978 1 85278 120 0 Papaioannou Theo 2012 Reading Hayek in the 21st Century a critical inquiry into his political thought Springer Schulak Eugen Maria Unterkofler Herbert 2011 The Austrian School of Economics A History of Its Ideas Ambassadors and Institutions Ludwig von Mises Institute ISBN 9781610161343 Wasserman Janek 2019 The Marginal Revolutionaries How Austrian Economists Fought the War of Ideas Excerpt via Amazon External links Edit Wikimedia Commons has media related to Austrian School Understanding Austrian Economics by Henry Hazlitt Austrian School at Curlie Portals Business and economics Austria Libertarianism Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Austrian School amp oldid 1127797846, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.