fbpx
Wikipedia

Piero Sraffa

Piero Sraffa FBA (5 August 1898 – 3 September 1983) was an influential Italian economist who served as lecturer of economics at the University of Cambridge. His book Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities is taken as founding the neo-Ricardian school of economics.

Piero Sraffa
Born(1898-08-05)5 August 1898
Turin, Italy
Died3 September 1983(1983-09-03) (aged 85)
Cambridge, England, United Kingdom
Academic career
InstitutionsTrinity College, Cambridge
FieldPolitical economy
School or
tradition
Neo-Ricardian school
Alma materLondon School of Economics
Influences

Early life edit

Sraffa was born in Turin, Kingdom of Italy, to Angelo Sraffa (1865–1937) and Irma Sraffa (née Tivoli) (1873–1949), a wealthy Italian Jewish couple.[1] His father was a professor in commercial law and later dean at the Bocconi University in Milan. Despite being raised as a practising Jew, Sraffa later became an agnostic.[2] Due to his father's activity, the young Piero followed him during his academic wanderings (University of Parma, University of Milan and University of Turin), where he met Antonio Gramsci (leader of Communist Party of Italy). They became close friends, partly due to their shared political views. Sraffa was also in contact with Filippo Turati, perhaps the most important leader of the Italian Socialist Party, whom he allegedly met and frequently visited in Rapallo, where his family had a holiday villa. At the age of 18, in the spring of 1917, he began military service as an officer of the Military Engineer Corps, under the command of the First Army as rear-guard. From the end of World War I (November 1918) until March 1920 he was a member of the Royal Commission of Inquiry into the violations of the right of the people committed by the enemy. The military period corresponded to the "university" one; some anecdotes tell of exams done effortlessly wearing the officer uniform. He graduated in November 1920 with a thesis on inflation in Italy during the period of the Great War. His tutor was Luigi Einaudi, one of the most important Italian economists and later a president of the Italian Republic.

From 1921 to 1922, he studied at the London School of Economics. During this period, at Cambridge, he met twice John Maynard Keynes, who invited him to a collaboration. This request led Sraffa to write two articles about the Italian banking system published in 1922, the first (The Bank Crisis in Italy) in The Economic Journal (edited by Keynes) and the second (The current situation of Italian banks) in the supplement of the newspaper Manchester Guardian (now The Guardian). Keynes also entrusted Sraffa with the Italian edition of his A Tract on Monetary Reform. The meeting with Keynes was undoubtedly a fundamental turning point in Sraffa's biography.

In 1922 Sraffa was appointed director of the provincial labour department in Milan, where he frequented socialist circles. In this period he made friends with Carlo Rosselli and Raffaele Mattioli, both assistants of Luigi Einaudi at the time.

The march on Rome, with the consequent seizure of power by Mussolini, was an event destined to affect deeply his future. His father Angelo was the target of aggression by a fascist squad and received two very threatening telegrams by Mussolini himself who required a public retraction by Piero on the content of the second article published in the Manchester Guardian. Piero did not write a retraction. In May 1924 his friend Antonio Gramsci, who found himself stuck firstly in Moscow and then in Vienna due to the advent to power of fascism, returned to Rome on his election to Parliament. From now on the relations between the two intellectuals intensified. On 26 November 1926 Italian Parliament approved the law "defence of the state", thus giving rise to the totalitarian state. On 8 November 1926, Antonio Gramsci was arrested. During Gramsci's incarceration, Sraffa supplied books and the material, literally pens and paper, with which Gramsci would write his Prison Notebooks.

The laws of productivity under competitive conditions edit

In 1925, Sraffa wrote about returns to scale and perfect competition. In the 1926 article, The Laws of Returns under Competitive Conditions, published in The Economic Journal, Sraffa resumes and develops his work of 1925 to show the inconsistency of the Marshallian theory of partial equilibrium, according to which, in competition for each good:

  1. The equilibrium price is determined by the intersection of the demand curve and that of the supply. The supply curve is symmetrical to that of the demand.
  2. As the quantity produced by the firm increases, there are initially increasing returns and, beyond a certain point, decreasing returns.[3]

Sraffa notes that the law of decreasing returns and that of increasing returns have different origins and areas of application (and therefore cannot explain the shape of the same supply curve): the law of diminishing returns was originally applied to the entire economy and resulted from the scarcity of the agricultural land as a mean of production (the rent theory of David Ricardo); while the law of increasing returns applied to the individual firm and resulted from the benefits of division of labour. The first one allowed for the study of the laws of distribution, and the second those of production.

"Nobody, until comparatively recently - Sraffa writes - had thought of unifying these two tendencies in one single law of non-proportional productivity, and considering this as one of the bases of the theory of price"[4] Sraffa observes that the idea of considering the law of non-proportional returns as a basis for the price theory arose, for analogy, only after the study of decreasing utility had drawn attention to the relationship between the price and the quantity consumed. In fact, "if the cost of production of every unit of the commodity under consideration did not vary with variations in quantity produced the symmetry would be broken, the price would be determined exclusively by the expenses of production and demand would be unable to have any influence on it at all".[5]

The difficulties of the system that could, in short, be defined as the cross of the supply and demand curves firstly depend on the heterogeneity of the assumptions on which these two different tendencies are based. Decreasing returns and increasing costs are caused by the limited availability of some input which prevents all inputs from varying in optimal proportion. In other words, if an input is limited in quantity, a rise in production levels brings about a less efficient proportion among inputs with a fall in productivity. By contrast, the tendency toward decreasing costs stems from variations in the quantity of all inputs, and therefore they may occur only when there are no constant factors.[6]

A second difficulty stems from the fact that, as Sraffa notes, in the neoclassical theory of prices the equilibrium of the individual firm is determined on the basis of cost variations deriving from small increases in its production (marginalist theory) and taking the situation unchanged in other companies of the same industry and the entire economy, following the hypothesis of ceteris paribus, i.e. other conditions being equal.[7]

Sraffa highlights that the possibility of applying the hypothesis of increasing costs to the supply curve is limited to the rare cases in which a considerable part of the supply of input is employed for the production of only one commodity. However, in general, each input is employed by a certain number of industries that produce different goods.[8]

As for increasing returns and decreasing costs, Marshall himself notes that external economies can hardly be attributed clearly to a specific industry, but they are of considerable interest to groups, often of a large size, in related industries; consequently, it is not possible to hypothesize an increase in returns in just one company.[9]

If in the partial equilibrium system of competitive prices, it is not possible to consider decreasing or increasing costs without contradicting the nature of the system, it follows, from this point of view, that production costs of goods produced in competition must be regarded as constant in respect of small variations in the quantity produced"[10] and that the long-run supply curve of an industry is horizontal. As a consequence, the price and the quantity of a good do not derive from the simultaneous action of the supply and demand curves: the price is determined by production costs, while the quantity produced is determined by the demand. The neoclassical symmetry between demand and supply is broken. The old theory that, in competition, "makes the value of commodities dependent on the cost of production alone appears to hold its ground as the best available" (1926b:540-1).[11]

Finally, Sraffa remarks that "everyday experience shows that the majority of which produce manufactured consumers' goods operate in conditions of individual diminishing costs. If the limit to the firm's expansion does not arise from increasing costs, then it may arise from the difficulty in expanding the market share without changing any of these three aspects: improving the quality of the output, reducing its price, or increasing marketing expenses. These considerations were developed, in the 1930s, by the theory of imperfect competition.

The Cambridge years edit

In 1927, Sraffa's yet undiscussed theory of value, but also his friendship with Antonio Gramsci—a risky and compromising endeavour in the context of the Italian fascist regime—brought John Maynard Keynes to prudently invite Sraffa to the University of Cambridge, where the Italian economist was initially assigned a lectureship.

Sraffa arrived in July of 1927 and remained there for life. In the shelter of the English city, he held courses about advanced value theory in his first three years. Then, again with the help of Keynes, he held a librarian position and could devote himself to study, intertwining relationships with a series of intellectuals destined to leave remarkable and lasting tracks.

Together with Frank P. Ramsey and Ludwig Wittgenstein, Sraffa joined the so-called cafeteria group, an informal club that discussed Keynes's theory of probability and Friedrich Hayek's theory of business cycles (see Sraffa–Hayek debate).

The economists that should at least be remembered are Michał Kalecki (1899–1970), Maurice Dobb (1900–1976), Joan Robinson (1903–1983) and Nicholas Kaldor (1908–1986). Among the philosophers, Frank Plumpton Ramsey (1903–1930) was helpful during the initial elaboration of the equations, datable in 1928, of the book Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, which was published in 1960.

In the early thirties there was a controversy between Sraffa and Friedrich von Hayek, who published a criticism of Keynes's conclusions contained in Treatise on Money (1930).[12] After a first reply, Keynes asked Sraffa about writing a more detailed answer to Hayek's theses. Sraffa thoroughly analyzed the inconsistencies in the logic of Hayek's theory on the effect of forced capital savings caused by inflation and above all on the definition of natural interest rate. The debate continued with a reply by Hayek and a rejoinder by Sraffa.[13]

In 1939, Sraffa was elected to a fellowship at Trinity College. Luigi Pasinetti identifies five stages of his work in Cambridge.

  1. 1928–1931: research on the history of economic theories, aimed at recovering the "reasonable" economics of the classics. Sraffa intends to "go straight to the unknown, from Marshall to Marx, from disutility to material cost ".
  2. 1931–1940: edition of Ricardo's works; almost ready for printing, they don't get published, both because the "Introduction" (written by Sraffa later) is missing, and because of the discovery of new documents, including all Ricardo's letters to James Mill.
  3. 1941–1945: criticism of neoclassical economics, in particular of the theory of production and distribution of the theory of value (of prices), of the theory of marginal utility and of the theory of interest as a reward for abstinence; processing of his equations with surplus.
  4. 1946–1955: publication of the first ten volumes of Ricardo's works (the eleventh, containing the General Index, will be published in 1973). John Eatwell wrote of Sraffa's work on David Ricardo:

    [Sraffa's] reconstruction of Ricardo's surplus theory, presented in but a few pages of the introduction to his edition of Ricardo's Principles, penetrated a hundred years of misunderstanding and distortion to create a vivid rationale for the structure and content of the surplus theory, for the analytical role of the labour theory of value, and hence for the foundations of Marx's critical analysis of capitalist production.[14]

  5. 1955–1960: preparation of Production of Goods by Means of Goods as mere "premise to a critique of political economy". The original project proved however too vast: of the historical part remains only an appendix of a few pages entitled "Note on the sources". In the Preface, Sraffa expresses his hope that the real criticism will be attempted "later, or by the author or someone younger and better equipped for the company".

Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities edit

The critique of neo-classical price theory based on the relations between cost and quantity produced leads Sraffa to abandon the analysis of partial equilibrium. Since the late 1920s, he began to work on a price theory that takes up the classical concepts of reproducibility, surplus, circularity of production, and freedom of entry.[15] In his book, Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, published only in 1960, Sraffa focuses on the analysis of relative prices and income distribution, assuming "no changes in output and ... no changes in the proportions in which different means of production are used ..., so that no question arises as to the variation or constancy of returns".[16] As in classics, in Sraffa's 1960 book, relative prices are determined by the conditions of production and not on the basis of the functional connection between returns and quantity produced.[15]

Sraffa's Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities is proposed to perfect classical economics' theory of value as originally developed by Ricardo and others. He aimed to demonstrate flaws in the mainstream neoclassical theory of value and develop an alternative analysis.

In this important work, Sraffa analyzes a linear production model in which it is possible to determine the relative price structure and one of the two distributive variables (rate of profit or wage), exogenously given the other and the technology.[17] The value of the capital employed can be known only together with the prices of the goods from which it is made. In essence, Sraffa shows that:

  1. It is not possible to identify a law that simultaneously determines the wage and the rate of profit because: i) the rate of profit can only be determined by setting the wage (or vice versa); ii) it is impossible to measure capital without also determining prices (including the profit), so it is not possible to calculate the profit based on the value of capital (as its remuneration).
  2. It cannot be assumed that, as wages increase, labour is replaced by capital, as the value of the capital depends on the duration of the initial investment; considering capitals of different duration, it may well happen that we prefer to replace capital with labour even if wages increase (so-called "return of techniques"); consequently, unemployment cannot be attributed to the increase in wages.

Sraffa's technique of aggregating capital as "dated inputs of labour" led to a debate known as the Cambridge capital controversy.

Sraffa's analytical apparatus was used by some followers for the solution to the Marxian problem of transforming values into prices of production and for the criticism of the Marxian theory of value. Moreover, as highlighted by Pasinetti, Sraffa's analysis overcomes the limits of the input-output system of Wassily Leontief, in particular with regard to the effects of technical change.[18] Pasinetti's approach, based on Sraffa's theory, has recently been developed by Kurz and Salvadori.[19]

Economists disagree on whether Sraffa's work refutes neoclassical economics. Many post-Keynesian economists use Sraffa's critique as justification for abandoning neoclassical analysis and exploring other models of economic behaviour. Others see his work as compatible with neoclassical economics as developed in modern general equilibrium models, or as unable to determine a long-period position, just like the Walrasian approach.[20] Others still argue that the importance of Sraffa's economics is that it provides a new framing for how we understand capitalist economies that do not fall back on the arguably unrealistic assumptions of neoclassical economics.[21]

Nonetheless, Sraffa's work, particularly his interpretation of Ricardo and his Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities (1960), is seen as the starting point of the neo-Ricardian school in the 1960s.[22][23]

Personal connections edit

Sraffa was instrumental in securing Gramsci's prison notebooks from the Fascist authorities after the latter's death in 1937. In 1924, Gramsci published a letter from Sraffa "Problems of Today and of Tomorrow",[24] Gramsci published 1924 a letter from Sraffa (without signing, signed S.). In the letter, Sraffa emphasizes the function of bourgeois opposition in the struggle against fascism and the importance of democratic institutions for the social and political development of the proletariat. Seeing the Italian Communist Party as weak, Sraffa recommended collaboration with the bourgeois opposition to fascism. In his answer, Gramsci rejected this suggestion, but he followed Sraffa's advice several years later.[25]

Norman Malcolm famously credits Sraffa with providing Ludwig Wittgenstein with the conceptual break that founded the Philosophical Investigations, by means of a rude gesture on Sraffa's part:[26]

Wittgenstein was insisting that a proposition and what it describes must have the same 'logical form', the same 'logical multiplicity'. Sraffa made a gesture, familiar to Neapolitans as meaning something like disgust or contempt, of brushing the underneath of his chin with an outward sweep of the fingertips of one hand. And he asked: 'What is the logical form of that?'

In the introduction to Philosophical Investigations, Wittgenstein mentions discussions with Sraffa over many years and says: "I am indebted to this stimulus for the most consequential ideas in this book". However, Sraffa broke off his weekly conversations with Wittgenstein in 1946 despite the latter's protests; and when the philosopher said he would talk about anything Sraffa wanted, "'Yes', Sraffa replied, 'but in your way'".[27]

Sraffa and Wittgenstein influenced each other deeply.[28] While Wittgenstein made his famous turn from the Tractatus Logico-Philosophicus to the Philosophical Investigations wherein he jettisoned the previous idea that the world comprised an atomistic set of propositional facts for the notion that meaning derives from its use within a holistic self-enclosed system. Analogously, Sraffa was rebutting the neoclassical paradigm which was similarly atomistic and individualistic. While there are disputes about how to interpret Sraffa none dispute Sraffa's influence.[29][30]

After the publication of Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, Sraffa's thought became the subject of a great debate. Sraffa was described as a shy and very reserved man who was devoted to study and books. His library contained more than 8,000 volumes, many of which are now in the Trinity College Library. A popular anecdote claims that Sraffa made successful long-term investments in Japanese government bonds that he bought the day after the nuclear bombing on Hiroshima and Nagasaki.[31] Another version of this is that Sraffa bought the bonds during the war when they were trading at distressed prices as he was convinced that Japan would honour its obligations (Nicholas Kaldor, pp. 66–67).[1] Records of Sraffa's investments in his Trinity College papers show that he had in fact begun his purchasing in 1946, during post-war debates over whether Japan would repay its foreigner-held pre-war debts to return to normality (which was possible, as most of the debt having been held by Japanese citizens and so never needed to be repaid, while Imperial Japan had continued to put aside assets for the accumulating interest); his returns were large and the publication Irwin Union calculates that Sraffa realized an annual return of 15% 1946-1983, dying with 120kg of Swiss gold bullion.[32]

In 1961, before the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel had been created, he was awarded the Söderströmska Gold Medal by the Royal Swedish Academy of Science. In 1972, he was awarded an honorary doctorate by Sorbonne and in 1976 received another one from Madrid's Complutense university.

Sraffa was involved in Cambridge capital controversy, sometimes called "the capital controversy"[33] or "the two Cambridges debate". It was a debate between prominent economists such as Joan Robinson and Piero Sraffa at the University of Cambridge in England and economists such as Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, in Cambridge, Massachusetts, United States.

In 1966, Paul Samuelson organized a symposium in the QJE, in which it was accepted by all parties, including Samuelson himself, that David Levhari had made a mistake and that Sraffa’s proposition is, of course, robust. The proposition in question refuted the Clarkian-type neoclassical explanation of the rate of interest on capital on the basis of the “marginal productivity of capital,” which requires measurement of the “intensity” of capital independently of the rate of interest. Sraffa’s “re-switching” proposition showed that, in general, there is no logical way by which the “intensity of capital” can be measured independently of the rate of interest — and hence the widely held neoclassical explanation of the distribution of income was logically untenable. This victory was well-known as the pinnacle of Sraffa’s book.[34]

Principal works edit

  • Sraffa, Piero, "Monetary inflation in Italy during and after the war", Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 17, No. 1 (March 1993), pp. 7–26; Engl. translation by W.J. Harcourt and C. Sardoni of "L'inflazione monetaria in Italia durante e dopo la Guerra, Milan, Premiata Scuola Tip. Salesiana, 1920; reprint in Economia Politica, XI, n.2, August 1994, pp. 163-196.
  • Sraffa, Piero, "The Bank Crisis in Italy", The Economic Journal, 1922, 36 (126) (June), pp. 178-197.
  • Sraffa, Piero, "The current situation of Italian banks", Manchester Guardian Commercial, 1922, 7 December.
  • Sraffa, Piero, "Sulle relazioni tra costo e quantità prodotta", Annali di economia, II, 1925, pp. 277-328; English translation by A. Roncaglia and J. Eatwel, "On the relations between cost and quantity produced", in L.L. Pasinetti (ed.), Italian Economic Papers, vol. III, Il Mulino – Oxford University Press, 1998, pp. 323-363.
  • Sraffa, Piero, 1926, "The Laws of Returns under Competitive Conditions", Economic Journal, 36(144), pp. 535–550. JSTOR 2959866
  • DH Robertson, Piero Sraffa and GF Shove, "Increasing Returns and the Representative Firm ", The Economic Journal, Vol. 40, No. 157 (March, 1930), pp. 79-116.
  • Piero Sraffa and L. Einaudi, "An Alleged Correction of Ricardo", The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 44, No. 3 (May, 1930), pp. 539-545
  • Sraffa, Piero, "Dr. Hayek on Money and Capital", The Economic Journal, 1932, 42: 42–53.
  • Sraffa, Piero, "A Rejoinder", The Economic Journal, 1932, 42 (June): 249–51.
  • Sraffa, Piero, "Malthus on Public Works", The Economic Journal, 1955, 259 (Sept.): 543-544.
  • Sraffa, Piero, "Introduction to David Ricardo", Works and Correspondence, in P. Sraffa and M. H. Dobb, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1951–1955 (vols. IX) and 1973 (vol. XI, indexes), vol. I: pp. XIII-LXII.
  • Sraffa, Piero, 1960, Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities: Prelude to a Critique of Economic Theory. Cambridge University Press. Preview.
  • Sraffa, Piero and M.H. Dobb, editors (1951–1973). The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo. Cambridge University Press, 11 vols. Online at the Online Library of Liberty.

Further reading edit

  • D'Orlando, Fabio (2005). "Will the Classical-type Approach Survive Sraffian Theory?", in Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 27(4), pp. 633–654
  • Eatwell, John (1984). "Piero Sraffa: Seminal Economic Theorist." Science and Society, 48(2), pp. 211–216. JSTOR 40402578. Reprinted in Piero Sraffa: Critical Assessments, J. Wood J. C. Wood, 1995, v. 1, pp. 74–79.
  • Eatwell, John and Panico, C. (1987 [2008]). "Sraffa, Piero", The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 3, pp. 445–452.
  • Enciclopedia Treccani, "Sraffa, Piero in "Il Contributo italiano alla storia del Pensiero: Economia"". www.treccani.it.
  • Harcourt, Geoffrey C., "Sraffa, Piero (1898–1983)", Oxford Dictionary of National Biography, Oxford University Press, 2004.
  • Hayek, F. A. (1931a), "Reflection on the pure theory of money of Mr. JM Keynes," Economic 11, S. 270–95 (1931).
  • Hayek, F. A. (1931b) Prices and Production, (London: Routledge, 1931).
  • Hicks, John (1939), The Foundations of Welfare Economics, pp. 696–712 in Economic Journal, IL, December 1939
  • Kurz, Heinz D. (2000) "Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa's Legacy in Economics" (2000)
  • Kurz Heinz D. and Salvadori Neri (1907), Theory of production. A long-period analysis, Cambridge University Press.
  • Monk, R. (1991), Ludwig Wittgenstein
  • Morroni, Mario (1998a), Decreasing returns, in Kurz H. D. and Salvadori N. (eds), The Elgar Companion to Classical Economics. A–K, vol. I, Elgar, Cheltenham.
  • Morroni, Mario (1999b), Increasing returns, in Kurz H. D. and Salvadori N. (eds), The Elgar Companion to Classical Economics. A–K, vol. I, Elgar, Cheltenham.
  • Norman, Malcolm, "Ludwig Wittgenstein: A Memoir", pp. 58–59.
  • L'Ordine Nuovo (PDF). www.centrogramsci.it. Retrieved 2019-06-11.
  • Panico, Carlo, Salvadori, Neri (1994), "Sraffa, Marshall and the problem of returns", European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 1, n. 2, pp. 323–343
  • Pasinetti, Luigi L. (1977), Lectures on the theory of production, MacMillan, London.
  • Pasinetti, Luigi L. (1998), "Piero Sraffa: An Italian economist at Cambridge", in L. L. Pasinetti (ed.), Italian Economic Papers, vol. III, Il Mulino – Oxford University Press, 1998, pp. 365–382.
  • Potier, Jean-Pierre (1991). Piero Sraffa, Unorthodox Economist (1898–1983): A Biographical Essay. ISBN 978-0-415-05959-6.
  • Pilkington, Philip (2014) "The Sraffian Versus the Marginalist Worldview: A Strong Case for Academic Pluralism", Fixing the Economists, April 29 http://fixingtheeconomists.wordpress.com/2014/04/29/the-sraffian-versus-the-marginalist-worldview-a-strong-case-for-academic-pluralism/
  • Samuelson, Paul A. ([1987] 2008). "Sraffian economics." The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition. Abstract.
  • Steve Keen, Debunking Economics: The Naked Emperor of the Social Sciences (2001, Pluto Press Australia) ISBN 1-86403-070-4.
  • Heinz D. Kurz, Ed. "Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa's Contribution to Economics" (2000, Cambridge University Press) ISBN 0-521-58089-7.
  • Ranchetti F., "On the Relationship between Sraffa and Keynes", in T. Cozzi e R. Marchionatti (eds.), Piero Sraffa's Political Economy: A Centenary Estimate, Routledge, London, 2001.
  • Ranchetti F., "Communication and intellectual integrity. The correspondence between Keynes and Sraffa", in M.C. Marcuzzo e A. Rosselli (eds.), Economists in Cambridge, Routledge, London, 2005, pp. 119–148.
  • Sinha A., "Sraffa's Contributions to the Methodology of Economics." Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics January 2015 vol. 27 no. 1 33–48.
  • Sinha A., "Sraffa and the Later Wittgenstein." Contributions to Political Economy, 2009 Vol. 28, Issue 1, pp. 47–69.
  • Vianello, F. [1988], "A critique of Professor Goodwin's Critique of Sraffa", in: Ricci, G. and Velupillai, K. (eds.), Growth, Cycles and Multisectoral Economics: the Goodwin Tradition, Berlin, Sringer-Verlag, ISBN 978-3-540-19467-5.
  • Vianello, F. [1989], "Effective Demand and the Rate of Profits: Some Thoughts on Marx, Kalecki and Sraffa", in: Sebastiani, M. (ed.), Kalecki's Relevance Today, London, Macmillan, ISBN 978-0-312-02411-6.
  • Anderaos de Araujo Fabio., "Sraffa and the Labour Theory of Value - a note", Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, Oct-Dec 2019, vol 39, p. 614-637.
  • Santucci, A. A., 2010. Antonio Gramsci. NYU Press. Chapter "The Prison Notebooks" (pp. 135–161) documents Sraffa's relationship with Antonio Gramsci, while the latter was imprisoned under the Fascist Regime.

References edit

  1. ^ a b Jean-Pierre Potier (1991). Piero Sraffa, Unorthodox Economist (1898–1983): A Biographical Essay (1898–1983: a Biographical Essay). ISBN 978-0-415-05959-6.
  2. ^ Roncaglia, Alessandro. "Piero Sraffa" (PDF). pp. 22–23. Retrieved 24 July 2012. Sraffa liked walks and bike rides. In Cambridge, he always moved around by bike. He used to get up late in the morning and work late into the night. In Trinity as well as when associated with King's, he regularly dined in the college. As I noticed when he invited me to dinner at Trinity, he took care to arrive after supper was served, so as to skip the benedicite prayer (he was agnostic, with a leaning for atheism).
  3. ^ The marginal cost curve has a "U" shape: first, it decreases, then it grows until it first meets the average cost curve, then the straight line (which is given, in conditions of competition); the different points of intersection between the growing part of the marginal cost curve (beyond the intersection with the average cost curve) and the various possible price lines constitute the supply curve for the individual firm.
  4. ^ Caloca Osorio, Oscar Rogelio; Cárdenas Almagro, Antonio; Octavio Ortiz Mendoza, Enrique, La frontera Sraffa-Ricardo entre salario y cuota de ganancia, un modelo de asimetría/The Sraffa-Ricardo Boundary Between Salary and Profit Rate, an Asymmetric Model, Análisis Económico. 2014, Vol. 28 Issue 70, p73-93. 21p.
  5. ^ Sraffa (1925 in 1998, p. 324).
  6. ^ Sraffa (1926, p. 539); cf. Morroni (1998a, p. 209; 1998b, p. 402).
  7. ^ Sraffa (1925 in 1998, pp. 358-359; 1926, pp. 538-539); Morroni (1998a, p. 210).
  8. ^ Sraffa (1926, p. 540); Morroni (1998a, p. 221).
  9. ^ Sraffa (1925 in 1998, pp. 361-362; 1926, p. 540); cf. Morroni (1985, p. 109; 1998b, pp. 402-403).
  10. ^ Sraffa (1926, p. 541).
  11. ^ Sraffa (1925 in 1998, p. 363).
  12. ^ Hayek (1931a; 1931b).
  13. ^ Sraffa (1932)
  14. ^ Eatwell (1984). "Piero Sraffa: Seminal Economic Theorist." Science and Society, 48(2), pp. 211–216. JSTOR 40402578 Reprinted in Piero Sraffa: Critical Assessments, J. Wood J. C. Wood, 1995, v. 1, pp. 74–79.
  15. ^ a b Morroni (1998a, p. 212)
  16. ^ Sraffa, 1960, pp. v-vi; cf. Panico and Salvadori (1994, pp. 324 ff.)
  17. ^ Sraffa (1925 in 1986, p. 17).
  18. ^ Pasinetti (1977)
  19. ^ Kurz and Salvadoti (1997)
  20. ^ Fabio D'Orlando (2005). "Will the Classical-type Approach Survive Sraffian Theory?", in Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 27(4), pp. 633–654
  21. ^ Philip Pilkington. "The Sraffian Versus the Marginalist Worldview: A Strong Case for Academic Pluralism", Fixing the Economists, April 29th 2014, http://fixingtheeconomists.wordpress.com/2014/04/29/the-sraffian-versus-the-marginalist-worldview-a-strong-case-for-academic-pluralism/
  22. ^ Paul A. Samuelson ([1987] 2008). "Sraffian economics." The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition. Abstract.
  23. ^ *John Eatwell and Carlo Panico (1987 [2008]). "Sraffa, Piero." The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 3, pp. 445–52.
  24. ^ "L'Ordine Nuovo" (PDF). www.centrogramsci.it. Retrieved 11 June 2019.
  25. ^ "Sraffa, Piero in "Il Contributo italiano alla storia del Pensiero: Economia"". www.treccani.it.
  26. ^ Norman Malcolm. Ludwig Wittgenstein: A Memoir. pp. 58–59.
  27. ^ R. Monk, Ludwig Wittgenstein (1991) p. 487
  28. ^ A. Sinha, "Sraffa and the Later Wittgenstein" (2009)
  29. ^ A. Sinha, "Sraffa's Contribution to the Methodology of Economics (2015)
  30. ^ H. D. Kurz, "Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa's Legacy in Economics" (2000)
  31. ^ . 2 September 2000. Archived from the original on 2 September 2000.
  32. ^ "Off the Run: Piero Sraffa and Imperial Japanese Government Bonds"
  33. ^ Brems (1975) pp. 369-384
  34. ^ "Sraffa's Revolution in Economic Theory".

External links edit

  • Piero Sraffa Archives homepage at Trinity College, Cambridge. Contains an online catalogue of Sraffa's personal and professional papers.
  • Piero Sraffa (1960). Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities — Prelude to a Critique of Economic Theory (PDF). Bombay: Vora & Co., Publishers Bvt. Ltd.
  • Roncaglia, Alessandro (2009). Piero Sraffa (PDF). Great Thinkers in Economics. palgrave macmillan. ISBN 9780521099691. OCLC 956749156.
  • Works by or about Piero Sraffa at Internet Archive

piero, sraffa, august, 1898, september, 1983, influential, italian, economist, served, lecturer, economics, university, cambridge, book, production, commodities, means, commodities, taken, founding, ricardian, school, economics, born, 1898, august, 1898turin, . Piero Sraffa FBA 5 August 1898 3 September 1983 was an influential Italian economist who served as lecturer of economics at the University of Cambridge His book Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities is taken as founding the neo Ricardian school of economics Piero SraffaBorn 1898 08 05 5 August 1898Turin ItalyDied3 September 1983 1983 09 03 aged 85 Cambridge England United KingdomAcademic careerInstitutionsTrinity College CambridgeFieldPolitical economySchool ortraditionNeo Ricardian schoolAlma materLondon School of EconomicsInfluencesDavid RicardoLuigi Einaudi Contents 1 Early life 1 1 The laws of productivity under competitive conditions 1 2 The Cambridge years 1 3 Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities 2 Personal connections 3 Principal works 4 Further reading 5 References 6 External linksEarly life editSraffa was born in Turin Kingdom of Italy to Angelo Sraffa 1865 1937 and Irma Sraffa nee Tivoli 1873 1949 a wealthy Italian Jewish couple 1 His father was a professor in commercial law and later dean at the Bocconi University in Milan Despite being raised as a practising Jew Sraffa later became an agnostic 2 Due to his father s activity the young Piero followed him during his academic wanderings University of Parma University of Milan and University of Turin where he met Antonio Gramsci leader of Communist Party of Italy They became close friends partly due to their shared political views Sraffa was also in contact with Filippo Turati perhaps the most important leader of the Italian Socialist Party whom he allegedly met and frequently visited in Rapallo where his family had a holiday villa At the age of 18 in the spring of 1917 he began military service as an officer of the Military Engineer Corps under the command of the First Army as rear guard From the end of World War I November 1918 until March 1920 he was a member of the Royal Commission of Inquiry into the violations of the right of the people committed by the enemy The military period corresponded to the university one some anecdotes tell of exams done effortlessly wearing the officer uniform He graduated in November 1920 with a thesis on inflation in Italy during the period of the Great War His tutor was Luigi Einaudi one of the most important Italian economists and later a president of the Italian Republic From 1921 to 1922 he studied at the London School of Economics During this period at Cambridge he met twice John Maynard Keynes who invited him to a collaboration This request led Sraffa to write two articles about the Italian banking system published in 1922 the first The Bank Crisis in Italy in The Economic Journal edited by Keynes and the second The current situation of Italian banks in the supplement of the newspaper Manchester Guardian now The Guardian Keynes also entrusted Sraffa with the Italian edition of his A Tract on Monetary Reform The meeting with Keynes was undoubtedly a fundamental turning point in Sraffa s biography In 1922 Sraffa was appointed director of the provincial labour department in Milan where he frequented socialist circles In this period he made friends with Carlo Rosselli and Raffaele Mattioli both assistants of Luigi Einaudi at the time The march on Rome with the consequent seizure of power by Mussolini was an event destined to affect deeply his future His father Angelo was the target of aggression by a fascist squad and received two very threatening telegrams by Mussolini himself who required a public retraction by Piero on the content of the second article published in the Manchester Guardian Piero did not write a retraction In May 1924 his friend Antonio Gramsci who found himself stuck firstly in Moscow and then in Vienna due to the advent to power of fascism returned to Rome on his election to Parliament From now on the relations between the two intellectuals intensified On 26 November 1926 Italian Parliament approved the law defence of the state thus giving rise to the totalitarian state On 8 November 1926 Antonio Gramsci was arrested During Gramsci s incarceration Sraffa supplied books and the material literally pens and paper with which Gramsci would write his Prison Notebooks The laws of productivity under competitive conditions edit In 1925 Sraffa wrote about returns to scale and perfect competition In the 1926 article The Laws of Returns under Competitive Conditions published in The Economic Journal Sraffa resumes and develops his work of 1925 to show the inconsistency of the Marshallian theory of partial equilibrium according to which in competition for each good The equilibrium price is determined by the intersection of the demand curve and that of the supply The supply curve is symmetrical to that of the demand As the quantity produced by the firm increases there are initially increasing returns and beyond a certain point decreasing returns 3 Sraffa notes that the law of decreasing returns and that of increasing returns have different origins and areas of application and therefore cannot explain the shape of the same supply curve the law of diminishing returns was originally applied to the entire economy and resulted from the scarcity of the agricultural land as a mean of production the rent theory of David Ricardo while the law of increasing returns applied to the individual firm and resulted from the benefits of division of labour The first one allowed for the study of the laws of distribution and the second those of production Nobody until comparatively recently Sraffa writes had thought of unifying these two tendencies in one single law of non proportional productivity and considering this as one of the bases of the theory of price 4 Sraffa observes that the idea of considering the law of non proportional returns as a basis for the price theory arose for analogy only after the study of decreasing utility had drawn attention to the relationship between the price and the quantity consumed In fact if the cost of production of every unit of the commodity under consideration did not vary with variations in quantity produced the symmetry would be broken the price would be determined exclusively by the expenses of production and demand would be unable to have any influence on it at all 5 The difficulties of the system that could in short be defined as the cross of the supply and demand curves firstly depend on the heterogeneity of the assumptions on which these two different tendencies are based Decreasing returns and increasing costs are caused by the limited availability of some input which prevents all inputs from varying in optimal proportion In other words if an input is limited in quantity a rise in production levels brings about a less efficient proportion among inputs with a fall in productivity By contrast the tendency toward decreasing costs stems from variations in the quantity of all inputs and therefore they may occur only when there are no constant factors 6 A second difficulty stems from the fact that as Sraffa notes in the neoclassical theory of prices the equilibrium of the individual firm is determined on the basis of cost variations deriving from small increases in its production marginalist theory and taking the situation unchanged in other companies of the same industry and the entire economy following the hypothesis of ceteris paribus i e other conditions being equal 7 Sraffa highlights that the possibility of applying the hypothesis of increasing costs to the supply curve is limited to the rare cases in which a considerable part of the supply of input is employed for the production of only one commodity However in general each input is employed by a certain number of industries that produce different goods 8 As for increasing returns and decreasing costs Marshall himself notes that external economies can hardly be attributed clearly to a specific industry but they are of considerable interest to groups often of a large size in related industries consequently it is not possible to hypothesize an increase in returns in just one company 9 If in the partial equilibrium system of competitive prices it is not possible to consider decreasing or increasing costs without contradicting the nature of the system it follows from this point of view that production costs of goods produced in competition must be regarded as constant in respect of small variations in the quantity produced 10 and that the long run supply curve of an industry is horizontal As a consequence the price and the quantity of a good do not derive from the simultaneous action of the supply and demand curves the price is determined by production costs while the quantity produced is determined by the demand The neoclassical symmetry between demand and supply is broken The old theory that in competition makes the value of commodities dependent on the cost of production alone appears to hold its ground as the best available 1926b 540 1 11 Finally Sraffa remarks that everyday experience shows that the majority of which produce manufactured consumers goods operate in conditions of individual diminishing costs If the limit to the firm s expansion does not arise from increasing costs then it may arise from the difficulty in expanding the market share without changing any of these three aspects improving the quality of the output reducing its price or increasing marketing expenses These considerations were developed in the 1930s by the theory of imperfect competition The Cambridge years edit In 1927 Sraffa s yet undiscussed theory of value but also his friendship with Antonio Gramsci a risky and compromising endeavour in the context of the Italian fascist regime brought John Maynard Keynes to prudently invite Sraffa to the University of Cambridge where the Italian economist was initially assigned a lectureship Sraffa arrived in July of 1927 and remained there for life In the shelter of the English city he held courses about advanced value theory in his first three years Then again with the help of Keynes he held a librarian position and could devote himself to study intertwining relationships with a series of intellectuals destined to leave remarkable and lasting tracks Together with Frank P Ramsey and Ludwig Wittgenstein Sraffa joined the so called cafeteria group an informal club that discussed Keynes s theory of probability and Friedrich Hayek s theory of business cycles see Sraffa Hayek debate The economists that should at least be remembered are Michal Kalecki 1899 1970 Maurice Dobb 1900 1976 Joan Robinson 1903 1983 and Nicholas Kaldor 1908 1986 Among the philosophers Frank Plumpton Ramsey 1903 1930 was helpful during the initial elaboration of the equations datable in 1928 of the book Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities which was published in 1960 In the early thirties there was a controversy between Sraffa and Friedrich von Hayek who published a criticism of Keynes s conclusions contained in Treatise on Money 1930 12 After a first reply Keynes asked Sraffa about writing a more detailed answer to Hayek s theses Sraffa thoroughly analyzed the inconsistencies in the logic of Hayek s theory on the effect of forced capital savings caused by inflation and above all on the definition of natural interest rate The debate continued with a reply by Hayek and a rejoinder by Sraffa 13 In 1939 Sraffa was elected to a fellowship at Trinity College Luigi Pasinetti identifies five stages of his work in Cambridge 1928 1931 research on the history of economic theories aimed at recovering the reasonable economics of the classics Sraffa intends to go straight to the unknown from Marshall to Marx from disutility to material cost 1931 1940 edition of Ricardo s works almost ready for printing they don t get published both because the Introduction written by Sraffa later is missing and because of the discovery of new documents including all Ricardo s letters to James Mill 1941 1945 criticism of neoclassical economics in particular of the theory of production and distribution of the theory of value of prices of the theory of marginal utility and of the theory of interest as a reward for abstinence processing of his equations with surplus 1946 1955 publication of the first ten volumes of Ricardo s works the eleventh containing the General Index will be published in 1973 John Eatwell wrote of Sraffa s work on David Ricardo Sraffa s reconstruction of Ricardo s surplus theory presented in but a few pages of the introduction to his edition of Ricardo s Principles penetrated a hundred years of misunderstanding and distortion to create a vivid rationale for the structure and content of the surplus theory for the analytical role of the labour theory of value and hence for the foundations of Marx s critical analysis of capitalist production 14 1955 1960 preparation of Production of Goods by Means of Goods as mere premise to a critique of political economy The original project proved however too vast of the historical part remains only an appendix of a few pages entitled Note on the sources In the Preface Sraffa expresses his hope that the real criticism will be attempted later or by the author or someone younger and better equipped for the company Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities edit The critique of neo classical price theory based on the relations between cost and quantity produced leads Sraffa to abandon the analysis of partial equilibrium Since the late 1920s he began to work on a price theory that takes up the classical concepts of reproducibility surplus circularity of production and freedom of entry 15 In his book Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities published only in 1960 Sraffa focuses on the analysis of relative prices and income distribution assuming no changes in output and no changes in the proportions in which different means of production are used so that no question arises as to the variation or constancy of returns 16 As in classics in Sraffa s 1960 book relative prices are determined by the conditions of production and not on the basis of the functional connection between returns and quantity produced 15 Sraffa s Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities is proposed to perfect classical economics theory of value as originally developed by Ricardo and others He aimed to demonstrate flaws in the mainstream neoclassical theory of value and develop an alternative analysis In this important work Sraffa analyzes a linear production model in which it is possible to determine the relative price structure and one of the two distributive variables rate of profit or wage exogenously given the other and the technology 17 The value of the capital employed can be known only together with the prices of the goods from which it is made In essence Sraffa shows that It is not possible to identify a law that simultaneously determines the wage and the rate of profit because i the rate of profit can only be determined by setting the wage or vice versa ii it is impossible to measure capital without also determining prices including the profit so it is not possible to calculate the profit based on the value of capital as its remuneration It cannot be assumed that as wages increase labour is replaced by capital as the value of the capital depends on the duration of the initial investment considering capitals of different duration it may well happen that we prefer to replace capital with labour even if wages increase so called return of techniques consequently unemployment cannot be attributed to the increase in wages Sraffa s technique of aggregating capital as dated inputs of labour led to a debate known as the Cambridge capital controversy Sraffa s analytical apparatus was used by some followers for the solution to the Marxian problem of transforming values into prices of production and for the criticism of the Marxian theory of value Moreover as highlighted by Pasinetti Sraffa s analysis overcomes the limits of the input output system of Wassily Leontief in particular with regard to the effects of technical change 18 Pasinetti s approach based on Sraffa s theory has recently been developed by Kurz and Salvadori 19 Economists disagree on whether Sraffa s work refutes neoclassical economics Many post Keynesian economists use Sraffa s critique as justification for abandoning neoclassical analysis and exploring other models of economic behaviour Others see his work as compatible with neoclassical economics as developed in modern general equilibrium models or as unable to determine a long period position just like the Walrasian approach 20 Others still argue that the importance of Sraffa s economics is that it provides a new framing for how we understand capitalist economies that do not fall back on the arguably unrealistic assumptions of neoclassical economics 21 Nonetheless Sraffa s work particularly his interpretation of Ricardo and his Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities 1960 is seen as the starting point of the neo Ricardian school in the 1960s 22 23 Personal connections editSraffa was instrumental in securing Gramsci s prison notebooks from the Fascist authorities after the latter s death in 1937 In 1924 Gramsci published a letter from Sraffa Problems of Today and of Tomorrow 24 Gramsci published 1924 a letter from Sraffa without signing signed S In the letter Sraffa emphasizes the function of bourgeois opposition in the struggle against fascism and the importance of democratic institutions for the social and political development of the proletariat Seeing the Italian Communist Party as weak Sraffa recommended collaboration with the bourgeois opposition to fascism In his answer Gramsci rejected this suggestion but he followed Sraffa s advice several years later 25 Norman Malcolm famously credits Sraffa with providing Ludwig Wittgenstein with the conceptual break that founded the Philosophical Investigations by means of a rude gesture on Sraffa s part 26 Wittgenstein was insisting that a proposition and what it describes must have the same logical form the same logical multiplicity Sraffa made a gesture familiar to Neapolitans as meaning something like disgust or contempt of brushing the underneath of his chin with an outward sweep of the fingertips of one hand And he asked What is the logical form of that In the introduction to Philosophical Investigations Wittgenstein mentions discussions with Sraffa over many years and says I am indebted to this stimulus for the most consequential ideas in this book However Sraffa broke off his weekly conversations with Wittgenstein in 1946 despite the latter s protests and when the philosopher said he would talk about anything Sraffa wanted Yes Sraffa replied but in your way 27 Sraffa and Wittgenstein influenced each other deeply 28 While Wittgenstein made his famous turn from the Tractatus Logico Philosophicus to the Philosophical Investigations wherein he jettisoned the previous idea that the world comprised an atomistic set of propositional facts for the notion that meaning derives from its use within a holistic self enclosed system Analogously Sraffa was rebutting the neoclassical paradigm which was similarly atomistic and individualistic While there are disputes about how to interpret Sraffa none dispute Sraffa s influence 29 30 After the publication of Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities Sraffa s thought became the subject of a great debate Sraffa was described as a shy and very reserved man who was devoted to study and books His library contained more than 8 000 volumes many of which are now in the Trinity College Library A popular anecdote claims that Sraffa made successful long term investments in Japanese government bonds that he bought the day after the nuclear bombing on Hiroshima and Nagasaki 31 Another version of this is that Sraffa bought the bonds during the war when they were trading at distressed prices as he was convinced that Japan would honour its obligations Nicholas Kaldor pp 66 67 1 Records of Sraffa s investments in his Trinity College papers show that he had in fact begun his purchasing in 1946 during post war debates over whether Japan would repay its foreigner held pre war debts to return to normality which was possible as most of the debt having been held by Japanese citizens and so never needed to be repaid while Imperial Japan had continued to put aside assets for the accumulating interest his returns were large and the publication Irwin Union calculates that Sraffa realized an annual return of 15 1946 1983 dying with 120kg of Swiss gold bullion 32 In 1961 before the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel had been created he was awarded the Soderstromska Gold Medal by the Royal Swedish Academy of Science In 1972 he was awarded an honorary doctorate by Sorbonne and in 1976 received another one from Madrid s Complutense university Sraffa was involved in Cambridge capital controversy sometimes called the capital controversy 33 or the two Cambridges debate It was a debate between prominent economists such as Joan Robinson and Piero Sraffa at the University of Cambridge in England and economists such as Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology in Cambridge Massachusetts United States In 1966 Paul Samuelson organized a symposium in the QJE in which it was accepted by all parties including Samuelson himself that David Levhari had made a mistake and that Sraffa s proposition is of course robust The proposition in question refuted the Clarkian type neoclassical explanation of the rate of interest on capital on the basis of the marginal productivity of capital which requires measurement of the intensity of capital independently of the rate of interest Sraffa s re switching proposition showed that in general there is no logical way by which the intensity of capital can be measured independently of the rate of interest and hence the widely held neoclassical explanation of the distribution of income was logically untenable This victory was well known as the pinnacle of Sraffa s book 34 Principal works editSraffa Piero Monetary inflation in Italy during and after the war Cambridge Journal of Economics Vol 17 No 1 March 1993 pp 7 26 Engl translation by W J Harcourt and C Sardoni of L inflazione monetaria in Italia durante e dopo la Guerra Milan Premiata Scuola Tip Salesiana 1920 reprint in Economia Politica XI n 2 August 1994 pp 163 196 Sraffa Piero The Bank Crisis in Italy The Economic Journal 1922 36 126 June pp 178 197 Sraffa Piero The current situation of Italian banks Manchester Guardian Commercial 1922 7 December Sraffa Piero Sulle relazioni tra costo e quantita prodotta Annali di economia II 1925 pp 277 328 English translation by A Roncaglia and J Eatwel On the relations between cost and quantity produced in L L Pasinetti ed Italian Economic Papers vol III Il Mulino Oxford University Press 1998 pp 323 363 Sraffa Piero 1926 The Laws of Returns under Competitive Conditions Economic Journal 36 144 pp 535 550 JSTOR 2959866 DH Robertson Piero Sraffa and GF Shove Increasing Returns and the Representative Firm The Economic Journal Vol 40 No 157 March 1930 pp 79 116 Piero Sraffa and L Einaudi An Alleged Correction of Ricardo The Quarterly Journal of Economics Vol 44 No 3 May 1930 pp 539 545 Sraffa Piero Dr Hayek on Money and Capital The Economic Journal 1932 42 42 53 Sraffa Piero A Rejoinder The Economic Journal 1932 42 June 249 51 Sraffa Piero Malthus on Public Works The Economic Journal 1955 259 Sept 543 544 Sraffa Piero Introduction to David Ricardo Works and Correspondence in P Sraffa and M H Dobb Cambridge University Press Cambridge 1951 1955 vols IX and 1973 vol XI indexes vol I pp XIII LXII Sraffa Piero 1960 Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities Prelude to a Critique of Economic Theory Cambridge University Press Preview Sraffa Piero and M H Dobb editors 1951 1973 The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo Cambridge University Press 11 vols Online at the Online Library of Liberty Further reading editD Orlando Fabio 2005 Will the Classical type Approach Survive Sraffian Theory in Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 27 4 pp 633 654 Eatwell John 1984 Piero Sraffa Seminal Economic Theorist Science and Society 48 2 pp 211 216 JSTOR 40402578 Reprinted in Piero Sraffa Critical Assessments J Wood J C Wood 1995 v 1 pp 74 79 Eatwell John and Panico C 1987 2008 Sraffa Piero The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics v 3 pp 445 452 Enciclopedia Treccani Sraffa Piero in Il Contributo italiano alla storia del Pensiero Economia www treccani it Harcourt Geoffrey C Sraffa Piero 1898 1983 Oxford Dictionary of National Biography Oxford University Press 2004 Hayek F A 1931a Reflection on the pure theory of money of Mr JM Keynes Economic 11 S 270 95 1931 Hayek F A 1931b Prices and Production London Routledge 1931 Hicks John 1939 The Foundations of Welfare Economics pp 696 712 in Economic Journal IL December 1939 Kurz Heinz D 2000 Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa s Legacy in Economics 2000 Kurz Heinz D and Salvadori Neri 1907 Theory of production A long period analysis Cambridge University Press Monk R 1991 Ludwig Wittgenstein Morroni Mario 1998a Decreasing returns in Kurz H D and Salvadori N eds The Elgar Companion to Classical Economics A K vol I Elgar Cheltenham Morroni Mario 1999b Increasing returns in Kurz H D and Salvadori N eds The Elgar Companion to Classical Economics A K vol I Elgar Cheltenham Norman Malcolm Ludwig Wittgenstein A Memoir pp 58 59 L Ordine Nuovo PDF www centrogramsci it Retrieved 2019 06 11 Panico Carlo Salvadori Neri 1994 Sraffa Marshall and the problem of returns European Journal of the History of Economic Thought vol 1 n 2 pp 323 343 Pasinetti Luigi L 1977 Lectures on the theory of production MacMillan London Pasinetti Luigi L 1998 Piero Sraffa An Italian economist at Cambridge in L L Pasinetti ed Italian Economic Papers vol III Il Mulino Oxford University Press 1998 pp 365 382 Potier Jean Pierre 1991 Piero Sraffa Unorthodox Economist 1898 1983 A Biographical Essay ISBN 978 0 415 05959 6 Pilkington Philip 2014 The Sraffian Versus the Marginalist Worldview A Strong Case for Academic Pluralism Fixing the Economists April 29 http fixingtheeconomists wordpress com 2014 04 29 the sraffian versus the marginalist worldview a strong case for academic pluralism Samuelson Paul A 1987 2008 Sraffian economics The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Steve Keen Debunking Economics The Naked Emperor of the Social Sciences 2001 Pluto Press Australia ISBN 1 86403 070 4 Heinz D Kurz Ed Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa s Contribution to Economics 2000 Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 58089 7 Ranchetti F On the Relationship between Sraffa and Keynes in T Cozzi e R Marchionatti eds Piero Sraffa s Political Economy A Centenary Estimate Routledge London 2001 Ranchetti F Communication and intellectual integrity The correspondence between Keynes and Sraffa in M C Marcuzzo e A Rosselli eds Economists in Cambridge Routledge London 2005 pp 119 148 Sinha A Sraffa s Contributions to the Methodology of Economics Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics January 2015 vol 27 no 1 33 48 Sinha A Sraffa and the Later Wittgenstein Contributions to Political Economy 2009 Vol 28 Issue 1 pp 47 69 Vianello F 1988 A critique of Professor Goodwin s Critique of Sraffa in Ricci G and Velupillai K eds Growth Cycles and Multisectoral Economics the Goodwin Tradition Berlin Sringer Verlag ISBN 978 3 540 19467 5 Vianello F 1989 Effective Demand and the Rate of Profits Some Thoughts on Marx Kalecki and Sraffa in Sebastiani M ed Kalecki s Relevance Today London Macmillan ISBN 978 0 312 02411 6 Anderaos de Araujo Fabio Sraffa and the Labour Theory of Value a note Brazilian Journal of Political Economy Oct Dec 2019 vol 39 p 614 637 Santucci A A 2010 Antonio Gramsci NYU Press Chapter The Prison Notebooks pp 135 161 documents Sraffa s relationship with Antonio Gramsci while the latter was imprisoned under the Fascist Regime References edit a b Jean Pierre Potier 1991 Piero Sraffa Unorthodox Economist 1898 1983 A Biographical Essay 1898 1983 a Biographical Essay ISBN 978 0 415 05959 6 Roncaglia Alessandro Piero Sraffa PDF pp 22 23 Retrieved 24 July 2012 Sraffa liked walks and bike rides In Cambridge he always moved around by bike He used to get up late in the morning and work late into the night In Trinity as well as when associated with King s he regularly dined in the college As I noticed when he invited me to dinner at Trinity he took care to arrive after supper was served so as to skip the benedicite prayer he was agnostic with a leaning for atheism The marginal cost curve has a U shape first it decreases then it grows until it first meets the average cost curve then the straight line which is given in conditions of competition the different points of intersection between the growing part of the marginal cost curve beyond the intersection with the average cost curve and the various possible price lines constitute the supply curve for the individual firm Caloca Osorio Oscar Rogelio Cardenas Almagro Antonio Octavio Ortiz Mendoza Enrique La frontera Sraffa Ricardo entre salario y cuota de ganancia un modelo de asimetria The Sraffa Ricardo Boundary Between Salary and Profit Rate an Asymmetric Model Analisis Economico 2014 Vol 28 Issue 70 p73 93 21p Sraffa 1925 in 1998 p 324 Sraffa 1926 p 539 cf Morroni 1998a p 209 1998b p 402 Sraffa 1925 in 1998 pp 358 359 1926 pp 538 539 Morroni 1998a p 210 Sraffa 1926 p 540 Morroni 1998a p 221 Sraffa 1925 in 1998 pp 361 362 1926 p 540 cf Morroni 1985 p 109 1998b pp 402 403 Sraffa 1926 p 541 Sraffa 1925 in 1998 p 363 Hayek 1931a 1931b Sraffa 1932 Eatwell 1984 Piero Sraffa Seminal Economic Theorist Science and Society 48 2 pp 211 216 JSTOR 40402578 Reprinted in Piero Sraffa Critical Assessments J Wood J C Wood 1995 v 1 pp 74 79 a b Morroni 1998a p 212 Sraffa 1960 pp v vi cf Panico and Salvadori 1994 pp 324 ff Sraffa 1925 in 1986 p 17 Pasinetti 1977 Kurz and Salvadoti 1997 Fabio D Orlando 2005 Will the Classical type Approach Survive Sraffian Theory in Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 27 4 pp 633 654 Philip Pilkington The Sraffian Versus the Marginalist Worldview A Strong Case for Academic Pluralism Fixing the Economists April 29th 2014 http fixingtheeconomists wordpress com 2014 04 29 the sraffian versus the marginalist worldview a strong case for academic pluralism Paul A Samuelson 1987 2008 Sraffian economics The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract John Eatwell and Carlo Panico 1987 2008 Sraffa Piero The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics v 3 pp 445 52 L Ordine Nuovo PDF www centrogramsci it Retrieved 11 June 2019 Sraffa Piero in Il Contributo italiano alla storia del Pensiero Economia www treccani it Norman Malcolm Ludwig Wittgenstein A Memoir pp 58 59 R Monk Ludwig Wittgenstein 1991 p 487 A Sinha Sraffa and the Later Wittgenstein 2009 A Sinha Sraffa s Contribution to the Methodology of Economics 2015 H D Kurz Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa s Legacy in Economics 2000 Piero SRAFFA 2 September 2000 Archived from the original on 2 September 2000 Off the Run Piero Sraffa and Imperial Japanese Government Bonds Brems 1975 pp 369 384 Sraffa s Revolution in Economic Theory External links edit nbsp Wikiquote has quotations related to Piero Sraffa Piero Sraffa Archives homepage at Trinity College Cambridge Contains an online catalogue of Sraffa s personal and professional papers Piero Sraffa 1960 Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities Prelude to a Critique of Economic Theory PDF Bombay Vora amp Co Publishers Bvt Ltd Roncaglia Alessandro 2009 Piero Sraffa PDF Great Thinkers in Economics palgrave macmillan ISBN 9780521099691 OCLC 956749156 Works by or about Piero Sraffa at Internet Archive Portals nbsp Business and economics nbsp Italy nbsp Biography Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Piero Sraffa amp oldid 1219314613, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.