fbpx
Wikipedia

Comecon

The Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (Russian: Сове́т Экономи́ческой Взаимопо́мощи, tr. Sovét Ekonomícheskoy Vzaimopómoshchi, СЭВ; English abbreviation COMECON, CMEA, CEMA, or CAME) was an economic organization from 1949 to 1991 under the leadership of the Soviet Union that comprised the countries of the Eastern Bloc along with a number of socialist states elsewhere in the world.[1]

Council for Mutual Economic Assistance
Совет Экономической Взаимопомощи
Sovét Ekonomícheskoy Vzaimopómoshchi (BGN/PCGN Russian)
Sovet Ekonomičeskoj Vzaimopomošči (GOST Russian)
1949–1991
Logo
Map of Comecon member states as of November 1986
Comecon as of November 1986:
  Members   Members that left the Warsaw Pact (Albania)
  Associate members   Observers
HeadquartersMoscow, Soviet Union
Official languages
TypeEconomic union
Member states
Historical eraCold War
• Organization established
5–8 January 1949
• Dissolution of Comecon
28 June 1991
26 December 1991
Area
196023,422,281 km2 (9,043,393 sq mi)
198925,400,231 km2 (9,807,084 sq mi)
Population
• 1989
504 million
Currency
Driving sideright

The descriptive term was often applied to all multilateral activities involving members of the organization, rather than being restricted to the direct functions of Comecon and its organs.[2] This usage was sometimes extended as well to bilateral relations among members because in the system of communist international economic relations, multilateral accords – typically of a general nature – tended to be implemented through a set of more detailed, bilateral agreements.[3]

Comecon was the Eastern Bloc's response to the formation in Western Europe of the Marshall Plan and the OEEC, which later became the OECD.[3]

Name in official languages of the members Edit

Country name Official language Name Abbreviation
  Bulgaria Bulgarian Съвет за икономическа взаимопомощ
(Sǎvet za ikonomičeska vzaimopomošt)
СИВ
(SIV)
  Cuba Spanish Consejo de Ayuda Mutua Económica CAME
  Czechoslovakia Czech Rada vzájemné hospodářské pomoci RVHP
Slovak Rada vzájomnej hospodárskej pomoci RVHP
  East Germany German Rat für gegenseitige Wirtschaftshilfe RGW
  Hungary Hungarian Kölcsönös Gazdasági Segítség Tanácsa KGST
  Mongolia Mongolian Эдийн засгийн харилцан туслалцах зөвлөл
(Ediin zasgiin khariltsan tuslaltsakh zövlöl)
ЭЗХТЗ
(EZKhTZ)
  Poland Polish Rada Wzajemnej Pomocy Gospodarczej RWPG
  Romania Romanian Consiliul de Ajutor Economic Reciproc CAER
  Soviet Union Russian Сове́т Экономи́ческой Взаимопо́мощи
(Sovet ekonomicheskoy vzaimopomoshchi)
СЭВ
(SEV)
Ukrainian Рада Економічної Взаємодопомоги
(Rada Ekonomičnoji Vzajemodopomohy)
РЕВ
(REV)
Belarusian Савет Эканамічнай Узаемадапамогі
(Saviet Ekanamičnaj Uzajemadapamohi)
СЭУ
(SEU)
Uzbek Ўзаро Иқтисодий Ёрдам Кенгаши
(O'zaro iqtisodiy yordam kengashi)
ЎИЁК
(O'IYoK)
Kazakh Экономикалық өзара көмек кеңесі
(Ekonomıkalyq özara kömek keñesi)
ЭӨКК
(EÖKK)
Georgian ორმხრივი ეკონომიკური დახმარების საბჭო
(Ormkhrivi Ekonomikuri Dakhmarebis Sabcho)
ოედს
(OEDS)
Azerbaijani Гаршылыглы Игтисади Јарадым Шурасы
(Qarşılıqlı İqtisadi Yardım Şurası)
ГИЈШ
(QİYŞ)
Lithuanian Ekonominės Savitarpio Pagalbos Taryba ESPT
Moldavian Консилюл де Ажутор Економик Речипрок
(Consiliul de Ajutor Economic Reciproc)
КАЕР
(CAER)
Latvian Savstarpējās ekonomiskās palīdzības padome SEPP
Kirghiz Өз ара Экономикалык Жардам үчүн кеңеш
(Öz ara ekonomikalık jardam üçün keŋeş)
ӨАЭЖҮК
(ÖAEJÜK)
Tajik Шӯрои Барои Кумак Иқтисодии Муштарак
(Shūroi baroi kumak iqtisodii mushtarak)
ШБKИМ
(ShBKIM)
Armenian Խորհուրդը փոխադարձ տնտեսական աջակցության
(Khorhurdy p'vokhadardz tntesakan ajakts'ut'yan)
Խփտա
(KhPTA)
Turkmen Ыкдысады Өзара Көмек Гүррңи
(Ykdysady özara kömek gürrüňi)
ЫӨКГ
(YÖKG)
Estonian Vastastikkuse Majandusabi Nõukogu VMN
  Vietnam Vietnamese Hội đồng Tương trợ Kinh tế HĐTTKT

History Edit

Foundation Edit

 
Former USSR Comecon headquarters in Moscow.[4]

The Comecon was founded in 1949 by the Soviet Union, Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, Poland, and Romania. The primary factors in Comecon's formation appear to have been Joseph Stalin's desire to cooperate and strengthen the international relationships at an economic level with the smaller states of Central Europe,[3] and which were now, increasingly, cut off from their traditional markets and suppliers in the rest of Europe.[5] Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland had remained interested in Marshall aid despite the requirements for a convertible currency and market economies. These requirements, which would inevitably have resulted in stronger economic ties to free European markets than to the Soviet Union, were not acceptable to Stalin, who in July 1947, ordered these communist governments to pull out of the Paris Conference on the European Recovery Programme. This has been described as "the moment of truth" in the post-World War II division of Europe.[6] According to the Soviet view the "Anglo-American bloc" and "American monopolists ... whose interests had nothing in common with those of the European people" had spurned East-West collaboration within the framework agreed within the United Nations, that is, through the Economic Commission for Europe.[7]

Some say that Stalin's precise motives in establishing Comecon were "inscrutable"[8] They may well have been "more negative than positive", with Stalin "more anxious to keep other powers out of neighbouring buffer states… than to integrate them."[9] Furthermore, GATT's notion of ostensibly nondiscriminatory treatment of trade partners was thought to be incompatible with notions of socialist solidarity.[5] In any event, proposals for a customs union and economic integration of Central and Eastern Europe date back at least to the Revolutions of 1848 (although many earlier proposals had been intended to stave off the Russian and/or communist "menace")[5] and the state-to-state trading inherent in centrally planned economies required some sort of coordination: otherwise, a monopolist seller would face a monopsonist buyer, with no structure to set prices.[10]

Comecon was established at a Moscow economic conference January 5–8, 1949, at which the six founding member countries were represented; its foundation was publicly announced on January 25; Albania joined a month later and East Germany in 1950.[8]

Recent research by the Romanian researcher Elena Dragomir suggests that Romania played a rather important role in the Comecon's creation in 1949. Dragomir argues that Romania was interested in the creation of a "system of cooperation" to improve its trade relations with the other people's democracies, especially with those able to export industrial equipment and machinery to Romania.[11] According to Dragomir, in December 1948, the Romanian leader Gheorghe Gheorghiu-Dej sent a letter to Stalin, proposing the creation of the Comecon.[12]

At first, planning seemed to be moving along rapidly. After pushing aside Nikolai Voznesensky's technocratic, price-based approach (see further discussion below), the direction appeared to be toward a coordination of national economic plans, but with no coercive authority from Comecon itself. All decisions would require unanimous ratification, and even then governments would separately translate these into policy.[clarification needed][13] Then in summer 1950, probably unhappy with the favorable implications for the effective individual and collective sovereignty of the smaller states, Stalin "seems to have taken [Comecon's] personnel by surprise,"[clarification needed] bringing operations to a nearly complete halt, as the Soviet Union moved domestically toward autarky and internationally toward an "embassy system of meddling in other countries' affairs directly" rather than by "constitutional means"[clarification needed]. Comecon's scope was officially limited in November 1950 to "practical questions of facilitating trade."[clarification needed][14]

One important legacy of this brief period of activity was the "Sofia Principle", adopted at the August 1949 Comecon council session in Bulgaria. This radically weakened intellectual property rights, making each country's technologies available to the others for a nominal charge that did little more than cover the cost of documentation. This, naturally, benefited the less industrialized Comecon countries, and especially the technologically lagging Soviet Union, at the expense of East Germany and Czechoslovakia and, to a lesser extent, Hungary and Poland. (This principle would weaken after 1968, as it became clear that it discouraged new research – and as the Soviet Union itself began to have more marketable technologies.)[15]

In a recent paper by Faudot, Nenovsky and Marinova (2022) the functioning and the collapse of the Comecon has been studied. It focuses on the evolution of the monetary mechanisms and some technical problems of multilateral payments and the peculiarities of the transfer ruble. Comecon as an organization proved unable to develop multilateralism mainly because of issues related to domestic planning that encouraged autarky and, at best, bilateral exchanges.[16]

Nikita Khrushchev era Edit

After Stalin's death in 1953, Comecon again began to find its footing. In the early 1950s, all Comecon countries had adopted relatively autarkic policies; now they began again to discuss developing complementary specialties, and in 1956, ten permanent standing committees arose, intended to facilitate coordination in these matters. The Soviet Union began to trade oil for Comecon manufactured goods. There was much discussion of coordinating five-year plans.[15]

However, once again, trouble arose. The Polish protests and Hungarian uprising led to major social and economic changes, including the 1957 abandonment of the 1956–60 Soviet five-year plan, as the Comecon governments struggled to reestablish their legitimacy and popular support.[17] The next few years saw a series of small steps toward increased trade and economic integration, including the introduction of the "convertible rouble [ru]", revised efforts at national specialization, and a 1959 charter modeled after the 1957 Treaty of Rome.[18]

Once again, efforts at transnational central planning failed. In December 1961, a council session approved the Basic Principles of the International Socialist Division of Labour, which talked of closer coordination of plans and of "concentrating production of similar products in one or several socialist countries." In November 1962, Soviet Premier Nikita Khrushchev followed this up with a call for "a common single planning organ."[19] This was resisted by Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland, but most emphatically by increasingly nationalistic Romania, which strongly rejected the notion that they should specialize in agriculture.[20] In Central and Eastern Europe, only Bulgaria happily took on an assigned role (also agricultural, but in Bulgaria's case this had been the country's chosen direction even as an independent country in the 1930s).[21] Essentially, by the time the Soviet Union was calling for tight economic integration, they no longer had the power to impose it. Despite some slow headway – integration increased in petroleum, electricity, and other technical/scientific sectors – and the 1963 founding of an International Bank for Economic Co-operation, Comecon countries all increased trade with the West relatively more than with one another.[22]

Leonid Brezhnev era Edit

From its founding until 1967, Comecon had operated only on the basis of unanimous agreements. It had become increasingly obvious that the result was usually failure. In 1967, Comecon adopted the "interested party principle", under which any country could opt out of any project they chose, still allowing the other member states to use Comecon mechanisms to coordinate their activities. In principle, a country could still veto, but the hope was that they would typically choose just to step aside rather than either veto or be a reluctant participant.[23] This aimed, at least in part, at allowing Romania to chart its own economic course without leaving Comecon entirely or bringing it to an impasse (see de-satellization of Communist Romania).[24]

Also until the late 1960s, the official term for Comecon activities was cooperation. The term integration was always avoided because of its connotations of monopolistic capitalist collusion. After the "special" council session of April 1969 and the development and adoption (in 1971) of the Comprehensive Program for the Further Extension and Improvement of Cooperation and the Further Development of Socialist Economic Integration by Comecon Member Countries, Comecon activities were officially termed integration (equalization of "differences in relative scarcities of goods and services between states through the deliberate elimination of barriers to trade and other forms of interaction"). Although such equalization had not been a pivotal point in the formation and implementation of Comecon's economic policies, improved economic integration had always been Comecon's goal.[3][25]

While such integration was to remain a goal, and while Bulgaria became yet more tightly integrated with the Soviet Union, progress in this direction was otherwise continually frustrated by the national central planning prevalent in all Comecon countries, by the increasing diversity of its members (which by this time included Mongolia and would soon include Cuba) and by the "overwhelming asymmetry" and resulting distrust between the many small member states and the Soviet "superstate" which, in 1983, "accounted for 88 percent of Comecon's territory and 60 percent of its population."[26]

In this period, there were some efforts to move away from central planning, by establishing intermediate industrial associations and combines in various countries (which were often empowered to negotiate their own international deals). However, these groupings typically proved "unwieldy, conservative, risk-averse, and bureaucratic," reproducing the problems they had been intended to solve.[27]

One economic success of the 1970s was the development of Soviet oil fields. While doubtless "(Central and) East Europeans resented having to defray some of the costs of developing the economy of their hated overlord and oppressor,"[28] they benefited from low prices for fuel and other mineral products. As a result, Comecon economies generally showed strong growth in the mid-1970s. They were largely unaffected by the 1973 oil crisis.[27] Another short-term economic gain in this period was that détente brought opportunities for investment and technology transfers from the West. This also led to an importation of Western cultural attitudes, especially in Central Europe. However, many undertakings based on Western technology were less than successful (for example, Poland's Ursus tractor factory did not do well with technology licensed from Massey Ferguson); other investment was wasted on luxuries for the party elite, and most Comecon countries ended up indebted to the West when capital flows died out as détente faded in the late 1970s, and from 1979 to 1983, all of Comecon experienced a recession from which (with the possible exceptions of East Germany and Bulgaria) they never recovered in the Communist era. Romania and Poland experienced major declines in the standard of living.[29]

Perestroika Edit

The 1985 Comprehensive Program for Scientific and Technical Progress and the rise to power of Soviet general secretary Mikhail Gorbachev increased Soviet influence in Comecon operations and led to attempts to give Comecon some degree of supranational authority. The Comprehensive Program for Scientific and Technical Progress was designed to improve economic cooperation through the development of a more efficient and interconnected scientific and technical base.[3] This was the era of perestroika ("restructuring"), the last attempt to put the Comecon economies on a sound economic footing.[30] Gorbachev and his economic mentor Abel Aganbegyan hoped to make "revolutionary changes" in the economy, foreseeing that "science will increasingly become a 'direct productive force', as Marx foresaw… By the year 2000… the renewal of plant and machinery… will be running at 6 percent or more per year."[31]

The program was not a success. "The Gorbachev regime made too many commitments on too many fronts, thereby overstretching and overheating the Soviet economy. Bottlenecks and shortages were not relieved but exacerbated, while the (Central and) East European members of Comecon resented being asked to contribute scarce capital to projects that were chiefly of interest to the Soviet Union…"[32] Furthermore, the liberalization that by June 25, 1988 allowed Comecon countries to negotiate trade treaties directly with the European Community (the renamed EEC), and the "Sinatra doctrine" under which the Soviet Union allowed that change would be the exclusive affair of each individual country marked the beginning of the end for Comecon. Although the Revolutions of 1989 did not formally end Comecon, and the Soviet government itself lasted until 1991, the March 1990 meeting in Prague was little more than a formality, discussing the coordination of non-existent five-year plans. From January 1, 1991, the countries shifted their dealings with one another to a hard currency market basis. The result was a radical decrease in trade with one another, as "(Central and) Eastern Europe… exchanged asymmetrical trade dependence on the Soviet Union for an equally asymmetrical commercial dependence on the European Community."[33]

The final Comecon council session took place on June 28, 1991, in Budapest, and led to an agreement to dissolve in 90 days.[34] The Soviet Union was dissolved on December 26, 1991.

Post-Cold War activity after Comecon Edit

After the fall of the Soviet Union and communist rule in Eastern Europe, East Germany (now unified with West Germany) automatically joined the European Union (then the European Community) in 1990. The Baltic States (Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania), Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia, and Slovenia joined the EU in 2004, followed by Bulgaria and Romania in 2007 and Croatia in 2013. To date, Czech Republic, Estonia, Germany (former GDR), Hungary, Latvia, Poland, Slovakia, and Slovenia are now members of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. All four Central European states are now members of the Visegrád Group.

Russia, the successor to the Soviet Union along with Ukraine and Belarus founded the Commonwealth of Independent States which consists of most of the ex-Soviet republics. The country also leads the Shanghai Cooperation Organisation with Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan and Uzbekistan and the Eurasian Economic Union with Armenia, Belarus, Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan. Along with Ukraine, Georgia, Azerbaijan and Moldova are also part of the GUAM.

Vietnam and Laos joined the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) in 1995 and 1997 respectively.

Membership Edit

Full members Edit

Albania had stopped participating in Comecon activities in 1961 following the Soviet–Albanian split, but formally withdrew in 1987. East Germany reunified with the West in 1990.

Name
Official name
Accession
date
Continent
Capital
Area
(km²)
Population
(1989)
Density
(per km²)
Currency
Official
languages
  Albania People's Socialist Republic of Albania
(Republika Popullore Socialiste e Shqipërisë)
Feb. 1949 Europe Tirana 28,748 3,512,317 122.2 Lek Albanian
  Bulgaria People's Republic of Bulgaria
(Народна република България)
Jan. 1949 Europe Sofia 110,994 9,009,018 81.2 Lev Bulgarian
  Cuba Republic of Cuba
(República de Cuba)
July 1972 North America Havana 109,884 10,486,110 95.4 Peso Spanish
  Czechoslovakia Czechoslovak Socialist Republic
(Československá socialistická republika)
Jan. 1949 Europe Prague 127,900 15,658,079 122.4 Koruna Czech
Slovak
  East Germany German Democratic Republic
(Deutsche Demokratische Republik)
1950 Europe East Berlin 108,333 16,586,490 153.1 Mark German
  Hungary Hungarian People's Republic
(Magyar Népköztársaság)
Jan. 1949 Europe Budapest 93,030 10,375,323 111.5 Forint Hungarian
  Mongolia Mongolian People's Republic
(Бүгд Найрамдах Монгол Ард Улс)
1962 Asia Ulaanbaatar 1,564,116 2,125,463 1.4 Tögrög Mongolian
  Poland Polish People's Republic
(Polska Rzeczpospolita Ludowa)
Jan. 1949 Europe Warsaw 312,685 38,094,812 121.8 Zloty Polish
  Romania Socialist Republic of Romania
(Republica Socialistă România)
Jan. 1949 Europe Bucharest 238,391 23,472,562 98.5 Leu Romanian
  Soviet Union Union of Soviet Socialist Republics
(Союз Советских Социалистических Республик)
Jan. 1949 Europe / Asia Moscow 22,402,200 286,730,819 12.8 Rouble None[c]
  Vietnam[3] Socialist Republic of Vietnam
(Cộng hòa xã hội chủ nghĩa Việt Nam)
1978 Asia Hanoi 332,698 66,757,401 200.7 Đồng Vietnamese

Associate status Edit

Observer status Edit

In the late 1950s, a number of communist-ruled non-member countries – the People's Republic of China, North Korea, Mongolia, Vietnam, and Yugoslavia – were invited to participate as observers in Comecon sessions. Although Mongolia and Vietnam later gained full membership, China stopped attending Comecon sessions after 1961. Yugoslavia negotiated a form of associate status in the organization, specified in its 1964 agreement with Comecon.[3] Collectively, the members of the Comecon did not display the necessary prerequisites for economic integration: their level of industrialization was low and uneven, with a single dominant member (the Soviet Union) producing 70% of the community national product.[36]

In the late 1980s, there were ten full members: the Soviet Union, six East European countries, and three extra-regional members. Geography, therefore, no longer united Comecon members. Wide variations in economic size and level of economic development also tended to generate divergent interests among the member countries. All these factors combined to give rise to significant differences in the member states' expectations about the benefits to be derived from membership in Comecon. Unity was provided instead by political and ideological factors. All Comecon members were "united by a commonality of fundamental class interests and the ideology of Marxism-Leninism" and had common approaches to economic ownership (state versus private) and management (plan versus market). In 1949 the ruling communist parties of the founding states were also linked internationally through the Cominform, from which Yugoslavia had been expelled the previous year. Although the Cominform was disbanded in 1956, interparty links continued to be strong among Comecon members, and all participated in periodic international conferences of communist parties. Comecon provided a mechanism through which its leading member, the Soviet Union, sought to foster economic links with and among its closest political and military allies. The East European members of Comecon were also militarily allied with the Soviet Union in the Warsaw Pact.[3]

There were three kinds of relationships – besides the 10 full memberships – with the Comecon:

  • Yugoslavia was the only country considered to have associate member status. On the basis of the 1964 agreement, Yugoslavia participated in twenty-one of the thirty-two key Comecon institutions as if it were a full member.[3]
  • Finland, Iraq, Mexico, and Nicaragua had a cooperant status with Comecon. Because the governments of these countries were not empowered to conclude agreements in the name of private companies, the governments did not take part in Comecon operations. They were represented in Comecon by commissions made up of members of the government and the business community. The commissions were empowered to sign various "framework" agreements with Comecon's Joint Commission on Cooperation.[3]
  • After 1956, Comecon allowed certain countries with communist or pro-Soviet governments to attend sessions as observers. In November 1986, delegations from Afghanistan, Ethiopia, Laos, and South Yemen attended the 42nd Council Session as observers.[3]

Exchange Edit

Working with neither meaningful exchange rates nor a market economy, Comecon countries had to look to world markets as a reference point for prices, but unlike agents acting in a market, prices tended to be stable over a period of years, rather than constantly fluctuating, which assisted central planning. Also, there was a tendency to underprice raw materials relative to the manufactured goods produced in many of the Comecon countries.[37]

International barter helped preserve the Comecon countries' scarce hard currency reserves. In strict economic terms, barter inevitably harmed countries whose goods would have brought higher prices in the free market or whose imports could have been obtained more cheaply and benefitted those for whom it was the other way around. Still, all of the Comecon countries gained some stability, and the governments gained some legitimacy,[37] and in many ways this stability and protection from the world market was viewed, at least in the early years of Comecon, as an advantage of the system, as was the formation of stronger ties with other socialist countries.[38]

Within Comecon, there were occasional struggles over how this system should work. Early on, Nikolai Voznesensky pushed for a more "law-governed" and technocratic price-based approach. However, with the August 1948 death of Andrei Zhdanov, Voznesensky lost his patron and was soon accused of treason as part of the Leningrad Affair; within two years he was dead in prison. Instead, what won out was a "physical planning" approach that strengthened the role of central governments over technocrats.[39] At the same time, the effort to create a single regime of planning "common economic organization" with the ability to set plans throughout the Comecon region also came to nought. A protocol to create such a system was signed January 18, 1949, but never ratified.[40] While historians are not unanimous on why this was stymied, it clearly threatened the sovereignty not only of the smaller states but even of the Soviet Union itself, since an international body would have had real power; Stalin clearly preferred informal means of intervention in the other Comecon states.[41] This lack of either rationality or international central planning tended to promote autarky in each Comecon country because none fully trusted the others to deliver goods and services.[39]

With few exceptions, foreign trade in the Comecon countries was a state monopoly, and the state agencies and captive trading companies were often corrupt. Even at best, this tended to put several removes between a producer and any foreign customer, limiting the ability to learn to adjust to foreign customers' needs. Furthermore, there was often strong political pressure to keep the best products for domestic use in each country. From the early 1950s to Comecon's demise in the early 1990s, intra-Comecon trade, except for Soviet petroleum, was in steady decline.[42]

Oil transfers Edit

Beginning no later than the early 1970s,[43] Soviet petroleum and natural gas were routinely transferred within Comecon at below-market rates. Most Western commentators have viewed this as implicit, politically motivated subsidization of shaky economies to defuse discontent and reward compliance with Soviet wishes.[44] Other commentators say that this may not have been deliberate policy, noting that whenever prices differ from world market prices, there will be winners and losers. They argue that this may have been simply an unforeseen consequence of two factors: the slow adjustment of Comecon prices during a time of rising oil and gas prices, and the fact that mineral resources were abundant in the Comecon sphere, relative to manufactured goods. A possible point of comparison is that there were also winners and losers under EEC agricultural policy in the same period.[45] Russian and Kazakh oil kept the Comecon countries' oil prices low when the 1973 oil crisis quadrupled Western oil prices.

Ineffective production Edit

The organization of Comecon was officially focused on common expansion of states, more effective production and building relationships between countries within. And as in every planned economy, operations did not reflect state of market, innovations, availability of items or the specific needs of a country. One example came from former Czechoslovakia. In the 1970s, the Communist party of Czechoslovakia finally realized that there was a need for underground trains. Czechoslovak designers projected a cheap but technologically innovative underground train. The train was a state-of-the-art project, capable of moving underground or on the surface using standard rails, had a high number of passenger seats, and was lightweight. According to the designers, the train was technologically more advanced than the trains used in New York's Subway, London's Tube or the Paris Metro. However, due to the plan of Comecon, older Soviet trains were used, which guaranteed profit for the Soviet Union and work for workers in Soviet factories. That economical change lead to the cancellation of the R1 trains by A. Honzík. The Comecon plan, though more profitable for the Soviets, if less resourceful for the Czechs and Slovaks, forced the Czechoslovak government to buy trains "Ečs (81-709)" and "81-71", both of which were designed in early 1950s and were heavy, unreliable and expensive. (Materials available only in Czech Republic and Slovakia, video included)[46]

On the other hand, Czechoslovak trams (Tatra T3) and jet trainers (L-29) were the standard for all Comecon countries, including the USSR, and other countries could develop their own designs but only for their own needs, like Poland (respectively, Konstal trams and TS-11 jets). Poland was a manufacturer of light helicopters for Comecon countries (Mi-2 of the Soviet design). The USSR developed their own model Kamov Ka-26 and Romania produced French helicopters under license for their own market. In a formal or informal way, often the countries were discouraged from developing their own designs that competed with the main Comecon design.

Structure Edit

Although not formally part of the organization's hierarchy, the Conference of First Secretaries of Communist and Workers' Parties and of the Heads of Government of the Comecon Member Countries was Comecon's most important organ. These party and government leaders gathered for conference meetings regularly to discuss topics of mutual interest. Because of the rank of conference participants, their decisions had considerable influence on the actions taken by Comecon and its organs.[3]

The official hierarchy of Comecon consisted of the Session of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance, the Executive Committee of the Council, the Secretariat of the Council, four council committees, twenty-four standing commissions, six interstate conferences, two scientific institutes, and several associated organizations.[3]

The Session Edit

The Session of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance, officially the highest Comecon organ, examined fundamental problems of economic integration and directed the activities of the Secretariat and other subordinate organizations. Delegations from each Comecon member country attended these meetings. Prime ministers usually headed the delegations, which met during the second quarter of each year in a member country's capital (the location of the meeting was determined by a system of rotation based on Cyrillic script). All interested parties had to consider recommendations handed down by the Session. A treaty or other kind of legal agreement implemented adopted recommendations. Comecon itself might adopt decisions only on organizational and procedural matters pertaining to itself and its organs.[3]

Each country appointed one permanent representative to maintain relations between members and Comecon between annual meetings. An extraordinary Session, such as the one in December 1985, might be held with the consent of at least one-third of the members. Such meetings usually took place in Moscow.[3]

Executive committee Edit

The highest executive organ in Comecon, the Executive Committee, was entrusted with elaborating policy recommendations and supervising their implementation between sessions. In addition, it supervised work on plan coordination and scientific-technical cooperation. Composed of one representative from each member country, usually a deputy prime minister, the Executive Committee met quarterly, usually in Moscow. In 1971 and 1974, the Executive Committee acquired economic departments that ranked above the standing commissions. These economic departments considerably strengthened the authority and importance of the Executive Committee.[3]

Other entities Edit

There were four council committees: Council Committee for Cooperation in Planning, Council Committee for Scientific and Technical Cooperation, Council Committee for Cooperation in Material and Technical Supply, and Council Committee for Cooperation in Machine Building. Their mission was "to ensure the comprehensive examination and a multilateral settlement of the major problems of cooperation among member countries in the economy, science, and technology." All committees were headquartered in Moscow and usually met there. These committees advised the standing commissions, the Secretariat, the interstate conferences, and the scientific institutes in their areas of specialization. Their jurisdiction was generally wider than that of the standing commissions because they had the right to make policy recommendations to other Comecon organizations.[3]

The Council Committee for Cooperation in Planning was the most important of the four. It coordinated the national economic plans of Comecon members. As such, it ranked in importance only after the Session and the Executive Committee. Made up of the chairmen of Comecon members' national central planning offices, the Council Committee for Cooperation in Planning drew up draft agreements for joint projects, adopted a resolution approving these projects, and recommended approval to the concerned parties. If its decisions were not subject to approval by national governments and parties, this committee would be considered Comecon's supranational planning body.[3]

The international Secretariat, Comecon's only permanent body, was Comecon's primary economic research and administrative organ. The secretary, who has been a Soviet official since Comecon creation, was the official Comecon representative to Comecon member states and to other states and international organizations. Subordinate to the secretary were his deputy and the various departments of the Secretariat, which generally corresponded to the standing commissions. The Secretariat's responsibilities included preparation and organization of Comecon sessions and other meetings conducted under the auspices of Comecon; compilation of digests on Comecon activities; conduct of economic and other research for Comecon members; and preparation of recommendations on various issues concerning Comecon operations.[3]

In 1956, eight standing commissions were set up to help Comecon make recommendations pertaining to specific economic sectors. The commissions have been rearranged and renamed a number of times since the establishment of the first eight. In 1986 there were twenty-four standing commissions, each headquartered in the capital of a member country and headed by one of that country's leading authorities in the field addressed by the commission. The Secretariat supervised the actual operations of the commissions. The standing commissions had authority only to make recommendations, which had then to be approved by the Executive Committee, presented to the Session, and ratified by the interested member countries. Commissions usually met twice a year in Moscow.[3]

The six interstate conferences (on water management, internal trade, legal matters, inventions and patents, pricing, and labor affairs) served as forums for discussing shared issues and experiences. They were purely consultative and generally acted in an advisory capacity to the Executive Committee or its specialized committees.[3]

The scientific institutes on standardization and on economic problems of the world economic system concerned themselves with theoretical problems of international cooperation. Both were headquartered in Moscow and were staffed by experts from various member countries.[3]

Affiliated agencies Edit

 
1974 Medallion 10th Anniversary of Intermetall, that was founded in 1964 in Budapest

Several affiliated agencies, having a variety of relationships with Comecon, existed outside the official Comecon hierarchy. They served to develop "direct links between appropriate bodies and organizations of Comecon member countries."[3]

These affiliated agencies were divided into two categories: intergovernmental economic organizations (which worked on a higher level in the member countries and generally dealt with a wider range of managerial and coordinative activities) and international economic organizations (which worked closer to the operational level of research, production, or trade). A few examples of the former are the International Bank for Economic Cooperation (managed the transferable rouble system), the International Investment Bank (in charge of financing joint projects), and Intermetall (encouraged cooperation in ferrous metallurgy).[3]

International economic organizations generally took the form of either joint enterprises, international economic associations or unions, or international economic partnerships. The latter included Interatominstrument (nuclear machinery producers), Intertekstilmash (textile machinery producers), and Haldex (a Hungarian-Polish joint enterprise for reprocessing coal slag).[3]

Nature of operation Edit

Comecon was an interstate organization through which members attempted to coordinate economic activities of mutual interest and to develop multilateral economic, scientific, and technical cooperation:[3]

  • The Charter (1959) stated that "the sovereign equality of all members" was fundamental to the organization and procedures of Comecon.[3][18]
  • The Comprehensive Program further emphasized that the processes of integration of members' economies were "completely voluntary and do not involve the creation of supranational bodies." Hence under the provisions of the Charter, each country had the right to equal representation and one vote in all organs of Comecon, regardless of the country's economic size or the size of its contribution to Comecon's budget.[3]
  • From 1967, the "interestedness" provisions of the Charter reinforced the principle of "sovereign equality." Comecon's recommendations and decisions could be adopted only upon agreement among the interested members, and each had the right to declare its "interest" in any matter under consideration.[3][23]
  • Furthermore, in the words of the Charter (as revised in 1967), "recommendations and decisions shall not apply to countries that have declared that they have no interest in a particular matter."[3][23]
  • Although Comecon recognized the principle of unanimity, from 1967 disinterested parties did not have a veto but rather the right to abstain from participation. A declaration of disinterest could not block a project unless the disinterested party's participation was vital. Otherwise, the Charter implied that the interested parties could proceed without the abstaining member, affirming that a country that had declared a lack of interest "may subsequently adhere to the recommendations and decisions adopted by the remaining members of the Council."[3] However, a member country could also declare an "interest" and exercise a veto.[23]

Over the years of its functioning, Comecon acted more as an instrument of mutual economic assistance than a means of economic integration, with multilateralism as an unachievable goal.[47] J.F. Brown, a British historian of Eastern Europe, cited Vladimir Sobell, a Czech-born economist, for the view that Comecon was an "international protection system" rather than an "international trade system", in contrast with the EEC, which was essentially the latter.[48] Whereas the latter was interested in production efficiency and in allocation via market prices, the former was interested in bilateral aid to fulfill central planning goals.[48] Writing in 1988, Brown stated that many people in both the West and the East had assumed that a trade and efficiency approach was what Comecon was meant to pursue, which might make it an international trade system more like the EEC, and that some economists in Hungary and Poland had advocated such an approach in the 1970s and 1980s, but that "it would need a transformation of every [Eastern Bloc] economy along Hungarian lines [i.e., only partly centrally planned] to enable a market-guided Comecon to work. And any change along those lines has been ideologically unacceptable up to now."[48]

Comecon versus the European Economic Community Edit

 
European trade blocs as of the late 1980s. EEC member states are marked in blue, EFTA – green, and Comecon – red.

Although Comecon was loosely referred to as the "European Economic Community (EEC) of (Central and) Eastern Europe," important contrasts existed between the two organizations. Both organizations administered economic integration; however, their economic structure, size, balance, and influence differed:[3]

In the 1980s, the EEC incorporated the 270 million people in Europe into economic association through intergovernmental agreements aimed at maximizing profits and economic efficiency on a national and international scale. The EEC was a supranational body that could adopt decisions (such as removing tariffs) and enforce them. Activity by members was based on initiative and enterprise from below (on the individual or enterprise level) and was strongly influenced by market forces.[3]

Comecon joined together 450 million people in 10 countries and on 3 continents. The level of industrialization from country to country differed greatly: the organization linked two underdeveloped countries – Mongolia, and Vietnam – with some highly industrialized states. Likewise, a large national income difference existed between European and non-European members. The physical size, military power, and political and economic resource base of the Soviet Union made it the dominant member. In trade among Comecon members, the Soviet Union usually provided raw materials, and Central and East European countries provided finished equipment and machinery. The three underdeveloped Comecon members had a special relationship with the other seven. Comecon realized disproportionately more political than economic gains from its heavy contributions to these three countries' underdeveloped economies. Economic integration or "plan coordination" formed the basis of Comecon's activities. In this system, which mirrored the member countries' planned economies, the decisions handed down from above ignored the influences of market forces or private initiative. Comecon had no supranational authority to make decisions or to implement them. Its recommendations could only be adopted with the full concurrence of interested parties and (from 1967[23]) did not affect those members who declared themselves disinterested parties.[3]

As remarked above, most Comecon foreign trade was a state monopoly, placing several barriers between a producer and a foreign customer.[42] Unlike the EEC, where treaties mostly limited government activity and allowed the market to integrate economies across national lines, Comecon needed to develop agreements that called for positive government action. Furthermore, while private trade slowly limited or erased national rivalries in the EEC, state-to-state trade in Comecon reinforced national rivalries and resentments.[49]

Prices, exchange rates, coordination of national plans Edit

See: Comprehensive Program for Socialist Economic Integration

International relations within the Comecon Edit

See: International relations within the Comecon

Soviet domination of Comecon was a function of its economic, political, and military power. The Soviet Union possessed 90 percent of Comecon members' land and energy resources, 70 percent of their population, 65 percent of their national income, and industrial and military capacities second in the world only to those of the United States[citation needed]. The location of many Comecon committee headquarters in Moscow and the large number of Soviet nationals in positions of authority also testified to the power of the Soviet Union within the organization.[3]

Soviet efforts to exercise political power over its Comecon partners, however, were met with determined opposition. The "sovereign equality" of members, as described in the Comecon Charter, assured members that if they did not wish to participate in a Comecon project, they might abstain. Central and East European members frequently invoked this principle in fear that economic interdependence would further reduce political sovereignty. Thus, neither Comecon nor the Soviet Union as a major force within Comecon had supranational authority. Although this fact ensured some degree of freedom from Soviet economic domination of the other members, it also deprived Comecon of necessary power to achieve maximum economic efficiency.[3]

See also Edit

Notes Edit

  1. ^ Stopped participating in Comecon activities in 1961, withdrew in 1987.
  2. ^ Withdrew in 1990
  3. ^ Russian was de facto national language of the Union.
  1. ^ Michael C. Kaser, Comecon: Integration problems of the planned economies (Oxford University Press, 1967).
  2. ^ For example, this is the usage in the Library of Congress Country Study that is heavily cited in the present article.
  3. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r s t u v w x y z aa ab ac ad ae af ag ah ai aj . Library of Congress Country Study. Archived from the original on 1 May 2009.
  4. ^ "СОГЛАШЕНИЕ между Правительством Союза Советских Социалистических Республик и Советом Экономической Взаимопомощи об урегулировании вопросов, связанных с месторасположением в СССР учреждений СЭВ". from the original on 2021-06-12.
  5. ^ a b c Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 536.
  6. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 534–35.
  7. ^ Kaser, 1967, pp. 9–10.
  8. ^ a b Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 535.
  9. ^ W. Wallace and R. Clarke, Comecon, Trade, and the West, London: Pinter (1986), p. 1, quoted by Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 536.
  10. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 536–37.
  11. ^ Elena Dragomir, ‘The formation of the Soviet bloc’s Council for Mutual Economic Assistance: Romania’s involvement’, Journal Cold War Studies, xiv (2012), 34–47.http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/abs/10.1162/JCWS_a_00190#.VQKof9KsX65.
  12. ^ Dragomir, Elena (2015). "The creation of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance as seen from the Romanian archives: The creation of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance". Historical Research. 88 (240): 355–379. doi:10.1111/1468-2281.12083.
  13. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 539–41.
  14. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 541–42.
  15. ^ a b Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 542–43.
  16. ^ Faudot, Adrien; Marinova, Tsvetelina; Nenovsky, Nikolay (2022-07-20). "Comecon Monetary Mechanisms. A history of socialist monetary integration (1949–1991)". mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de. Retrieved 2023-04-20.
  17. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 543–34.
  18. ^ a b Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 544.
  19. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 559.
  20. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 560.
  21. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 553.
  22. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 560–61.
  23. ^ a b c d e Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 561.
  24. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 566.
  25. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 564, 566.
  26. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 564.
  27. ^ a b Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 568–69.
  28. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 568.
  29. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 571–72.
  30. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 579.
  31. ^ Abel Aganbegyan, quoted in Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 580.
  32. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 580.
  33. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 580–82; the quotation is on p. 582.
  34. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 582.
  35. ^ Smolansky, Oleg; Smolansky, Bettie (1991). The USSR and Iraq: The Soviet Quest for Influence. Duke University Press. p. 25. ISBN 978-0-8223-1116-4.
  36. ^ Zwass, 1989, p. 4
  37. ^ a b Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 537.
  38. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 538.
  39. ^ a b Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 539.
  40. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 540.
  41. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 540–41.
  42. ^ a b Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 565.
  43. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 569.
  44. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 570 makes the assertion about this being the dominant view, and cites several examples.
  45. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, pp. 570–71.
  46. ^ "Zašlapané projekty: Pražské metro – Česká televize". Česká televize. from the original on 19 June 2010. Retrieved 8 May 2018.
  47. ^ Zwass, 1989, pp. 14–21
  48. ^ a b c Brown, J.F. (1988), Eastern Europe and Communist Rule, Duke University Press, ISBN 978-0882308418, pp. 145–56.
  49. ^ Bideleux and Jeffries, 1998, p. 567.

References Edit

  •   This article incorporates text from this source, which is in the public domain. Country Studies. Federal Research Division.
  • Robert Bideleux and Ian Jeffries, A History of Eastern Europe: Crisis and Change, Routledge, 1998. ISBN 0-415-16111-8.
  • Brine, Jenny J., ed. Comecon: the rise and fall of an international socialist organization. Vol. 3. Transaction Publishers, 1992.
  • Crump, Laurien, and Simon Godard. "Reassessing Communist International Organisations: A Comparative Analysis of COMECON and the Warsaw Pact in relation to their Cold War Competitors." Contemporary European History 27.1 (2018): 85-109.
  • Falk, Flade. Review of Economic Entanglements in East-Central Europe and the Comecon´s Position in the Global Economy (1949-1991) online at (H-Soz-u-Kult, H-Net Reviews. Jam. 2013)
  • Godard, Simon. "Only One Way to Be a Communist? How Biographical Trajectories Shaped Internationalism among COMECON Experts." Critique internationale 1 (2015): 69-83.
  • Michael Kaser, Comecon: Integration Problems of the Planned Economies, Royal Institute of International Affairs/ Oxford University Press, 1967. ISBN 0-192-14956-3
  • Lányi, Kamilla. "The collapse of the COMECON market." Russian & East European Finance and Trade 29.1 (1993): 68-86. online
  • Libbey, James. "CoCom, Comecon, and the Economic Cold War." Russian History 37.2 (2010): 133-152.
  • Radisch, Erik. "The Struggle of the Soviet Conception of Comecon, 1953–1975." Comparativ 27.5-6 (2017): 26-47.
  • Zwass, Adam. "The Council for Mutual Economic Assistance: The Thorny Path from Political to Economic Integration", M.E. Sharpe, Armonk, NY 1989.
  • Faudot, Adrien, Tsvetelina Marinova and Nikolay Nenovsky. " Comecon Monetary Mechanisms. A history of socialist monetary integration (1949–1991)", MPRA 2022. Comecon Monetary Mechanisms. A history of socialist monetary integration (1949–1991)

External links Edit

  • Germany (East) Country Study (TOC), Data as of July 1987, Appendix B: The Council for Mutual Economic Assistance, Library of Congress Call Number DD280.6 .E22 1988.

comecon, confused, with, comic, book, convention, council, mutual, economic, assistance, russian, Сове, Экономи, ческой, Взаимопо, мощи, sovét, ekonomícheskoy, vzaimopómoshchi, СЭВ, english, abbreviation, comecon, cmea, cema, came, economic, organization, from. Not to be confused with Comic book convention The Council for Mutual Economic Assistance Russian Sove t Ekonomi cheskoj Vzaimopo moshi tr Sovet Ekonomicheskoy Vzaimopomoshchi SEV English abbreviation COMECON CMEA CEMA or CAME was an economic organization from 1949 to 1991 under the leadership of the Soviet Union that comprised the countries of the Eastern Bloc along with a number of socialist states elsewhere in the world 1 Council for Mutual Economic AssistanceSovet Ekonomicheskoj Vzaimopomoshi Sovet Ekonomicheskoy Vzaimopomoshchi BGN PCGN Russian Sovet Ekonomiceskoj Vzaimopomosci GOST Russian 1949 1991LogoMap of Comecon member states as of November 1986 Comecon as of November 1986 Members Members that left the Warsaw Pact Albania Associate members ObserversHeadquartersMoscow Soviet UnionOfficial languages11 languages AlbanianRussianBulgarianCzechGermanHungarianMongolianPolishRomanianSpanishVietnameseTypeEconomic unionMember statesSee list Albania a BulgariaCzechoslovakia Cuba East Germany b HungaryMongoliaPolandRomania Soviet Union VietnamHistorical eraCold War Organization established5 8 January 1949 Dissolution of Comecon28 June 1991 Dissolution of the Soviet Union26 December 1991Area196023 422 281 km2 9 043 393 sq mi 198925 400 231 km2 9 807 084 sq mi Population 1989504 millionCurrency10 currencies Soviet rubleEast German markPolish zlotyCzechoslovak korunaRomanian leuBulgarian levHungarian forintCuban pesoMongolian togrogVietnamese đồngDriving siderightSucceeded byCommonwealth of Independent StatesEurasian Economic CommunityGUAMOECDBolivarian Alliance for the Peoples of Our AmericaASEANVisegrad GroupCraiova GroupAlbaniaMongoliaTurkmenistanThe descriptive term was often applied to all multilateral activities involving members of the organization rather than being restricted to the direct functions of Comecon and its organs 2 This usage was sometimes extended as well to bilateral relations among members because in the system of communist international economic relations multilateral accords typically of a general nature tended to be implemented through a set of more detailed bilateral agreements 3 Comecon was the Eastern Bloc s response to the formation in Western Europe of the Marshall Plan and the OEEC which later became the OECD 3 Contents 1 Name in official languages of the members 2 History 2 1 Foundation 2 2 Nikita Khrushchev era 2 3 Leonid Brezhnev era 2 4 Perestroika 2 5 Post Cold War activity after Comecon 3 Membership 3 1 Full members 3 2 Associate status 3 3 Observer status 4 Exchange 4 1 Oil transfers 4 2 Ineffective production 5 Structure 5 1 The Session 5 2 Executive committee 5 3 Other entities 5 4 Affiliated agencies 6 Nature of operation 7 Comecon versus the European Economic Community 8 Prices exchange rates coordination of national plans 9 International relations within the Comecon 10 See also 11 Notes 12 References 13 External linksName in official languages of the members EditCountry name Official language Name Abbreviation nbsp Bulgaria Bulgarian Svet za ikonomicheska vzaimopomosh Sǎvet za ikonomiceska vzaimopomost SIV SIV nbsp Cuba Spanish Consejo de Ayuda Mutua Economica CAME nbsp Czechoslovakia Czech Rada vzajemne hospodarske pomoci RVHPSlovak Rada vzajomnej hospodarskej pomoci RVHP nbsp East Germany German Rat fur gegenseitige Wirtschaftshilfe RGW nbsp Hungary Hungarian Kolcsonos Gazdasagi Segitseg Tanacsa KGST nbsp Mongolia Mongolian Edijn zasgijn harilcan tuslalcah zovlol Ediin zasgiin khariltsan tuslaltsakh zovlol EZHTZ EZKhTZ nbsp Poland Polish Rada Wzajemnej Pomocy Gospodarczej RWPG nbsp Romania Romanian Consiliul de Ajutor Economic Reciproc CAER nbsp Soviet Union Russian Sove t Ekonomi cheskoj Vzaimopo moshi Sovet ekonomicheskoy vzaimopomoshchi SEV SEV Ukrainian Rada Ekonomichnoyi Vzayemodopomogi Rada Ekonomicnoji Vzajemodopomohy REV REV Belarusian Savet Ekanamichnaj Uzaemadapamogi Saviet Ekanamicnaj Uzajemadapamohi SEU SEU Uzbek Ўzaro Iktisodij Yordam Kengashi O zaro iqtisodiy yordam kengashi ЎIYoK O IYoK Kazakh Ekonomikalyk ozara komek kenesi Ekonomikalyq ozara komek kenesi EӨKK EOKK Georgian ორმხრივი ეკონომიკური დახმარების საბჭო Ormkhrivi Ekonomikuri Dakhmarebis Sabcho ოედს OEDS Azerbaijani Garshylygly Igtisadi Јaradym Shurasy Qarsiliqli Iqtisadi Yardim Surasi GIЈSh QIYS Lithuanian Ekonomines Savitarpio Pagalbos Taryba ESPTMoldavian Konsilyul de Azhutor Ekonomik Rechiprok Consiliul de Ajutor Economic Reciproc KAER CAER Latvian Savstarpejas ekonomiskas palidzibas padome SEPPKirghiz Өz ara Ekonomikalyk Zhardam үchүn kenesh Oz ara ekonomikalik jardam ucun keŋes ӨAEZhҮK OAEJUK Tajik Shӯroi Baroi Kumak Iktisodii Mushtarak Shuroi baroi kumak iqtisodii mushtarak ShBKIM ShBKIM Armenian Խորհուրդը փոխադարձ տնտեսական աջակցության Khorhurdy p vokhadardz tntesakan ajakts ut yan Խփտա KhPTA Turkmen Ykdysady Өzara Komek Gүrrni Ykdysady ozara komek gurruni YӨKG YOKG Estonian Vastastikkuse Majandusabi Noukogu VMN nbsp Vietnam Vietnamese Hội đồng Tương trợ Kinh tế HĐTTKTHistory EditFoundation Edit nbsp Former USSR Comecon headquarters in Moscow 4 The Comecon was founded in 1949 by the Soviet Union Bulgaria Czechoslovakia Hungary Poland and Romania The primary factors in Comecon s formation appear to have been Joseph Stalin s desire to cooperate and strengthen the international relationships at an economic level with the smaller states of Central Europe 3 and which were now increasingly cut off from their traditional markets and suppliers in the rest of Europe 5 Czechoslovakia Hungary and Poland had remained interested in Marshall aid despite the requirements for a convertible currency and market economies These requirements which would inevitably have resulted in stronger economic ties to free European markets than to the Soviet Union were not acceptable to Stalin who in July 1947 ordered these communist governments to pull out of the Paris Conference on the European Recovery Programme This has been described as the moment of truth in the post World War II division of Europe 6 According to the Soviet view the Anglo American bloc and American monopolists whose interests had nothing in common with those of the European people had spurned East West collaboration within the framework agreed within the United Nations that is through the Economic Commission for Europe 7 Some say that Stalin s precise motives in establishing Comecon were inscrutable 8 They may well have been more negative than positive with Stalin more anxious to keep other powers out of neighbouring buffer states than to integrate them 9 Furthermore GATT s notion of ostensibly nondiscriminatory treatment of trade partners was thought to be incompatible with notions of socialist solidarity 5 In any event proposals for a customs union and economic integration of Central and Eastern Europe date back at least to the Revolutions of 1848 although many earlier proposals had been intended to stave off the Russian and or communist menace 5 and the state to state trading inherent in centrally planned economies required some sort of coordination otherwise a monopolist seller would face a monopsonist buyer with no structure to set prices 10 Comecon was established at a Moscow economic conference January 5 8 1949 at which the six founding member countries were represented its foundation was publicly announced on January 25 Albania joined a month later and East Germany in 1950 8 Recent research by the Romanian researcher Elena Dragomir suggests that Romania played a rather important role in the Comecon s creation in 1949 Dragomir argues that Romania was interested in the creation of a system of cooperation to improve its trade relations with the other people s democracies especially with those able to export industrial equipment and machinery to Romania 11 According to Dragomir in December 1948 the Romanian leader Gheorghe Gheorghiu Dej sent a letter to Stalin proposing the creation of the Comecon 12 This article may be confusing or unclear to readers Please help clarify the article There might be a discussion about this on the talk page December 2016 Learn how and when to remove this template message At first planning seemed to be moving along rapidly After pushing aside Nikolai Voznesensky s technocratic price based approach see further discussion below the direction appeared to be toward a coordination of national economic plans but with no coercive authority from Comecon itself All decisions would require unanimous ratification and even then governments would separately translate these into policy clarification needed 13 Then in summer 1950 probably unhappy with the favorable implications for the effective individual and collective sovereignty of the smaller states Stalin seems to have taken Comecon s personnel by surprise clarification needed bringing operations to a nearly complete halt as the Soviet Union moved domestically toward autarky and internationally toward an embassy system of meddling in other countries affairs directly rather than by constitutional means clarification needed Comecon s scope was officially limited in November 1950 to practical questions of facilitating trade clarification needed 14 One important legacy of this brief period of activity was the Sofia Principle adopted at the August 1949 Comecon council session in Bulgaria This radically weakened intellectual property rights making each country s technologies available to the others for a nominal charge that did little more than cover the cost of documentation This naturally benefited the less industrialized Comecon countries and especially the technologically lagging Soviet Union at the expense of East Germany and Czechoslovakia and to a lesser extent Hungary and Poland This principle would weaken after 1968 as it became clear that it discouraged new research and as the Soviet Union itself began to have more marketable technologies 15 In a recent paper by Faudot Nenovsky and Marinova 2022 the functioning and the collapse of the Comecon has been studied It focuses on the evolution of the monetary mechanisms and some technical problems of multilateral payments and the peculiarities of the transfer ruble Comecon as an organization proved unable to develop multilateralism mainly because of issues related to domestic planning that encouraged autarky and at best bilateral exchanges 16 Nikita Khrushchev era Edit After Stalin s death in 1953 Comecon again began to find its footing In the early 1950s all Comecon countries had adopted relatively autarkic policies now they began again to discuss developing complementary specialties and in 1956 ten permanent standing committees arose intended to facilitate coordination in these matters The Soviet Union began to trade oil for Comecon manufactured goods There was much discussion of coordinating five year plans 15 However once again trouble arose The Polish protests and Hungarian uprising led to major social and economic changes including the 1957 abandonment of the 1956 60 Soviet five year plan as the Comecon governments struggled to reestablish their legitimacy and popular support 17 The next few years saw a series of small steps toward increased trade and economic integration including the introduction of the convertible rouble ru revised efforts at national specialization and a 1959 charter modeled after the 1957 Treaty of Rome 18 Once again efforts at transnational central planning failed In December 1961 a council session approved the Basic Principles of the International Socialist Division of Labour which talked of closer coordination of plans and of concentrating production of similar products in one or several socialist countries In November 1962 Soviet Premier Nikita Khrushchev followed this up with a call for a common single planning organ 19 This was resisted by Czechoslovakia Hungary and Poland but most emphatically by increasingly nationalistic Romania which strongly rejected the notion that they should specialize in agriculture 20 In Central and Eastern Europe only Bulgaria happily took on an assigned role also agricultural but in Bulgaria s case this had been the country s chosen direction even as an independent country in the 1930s 21 Essentially by the time the Soviet Union was calling for tight economic integration they no longer had the power to impose it Despite some slow headway integration increased in petroleum electricity and other technical scientific sectors and the 1963 founding of an International Bank for Economic Co operation Comecon countries all increased trade with the West relatively more than with one another 22 Leonid Brezhnev era Edit From its founding until 1967 Comecon had operated only on the basis of unanimous agreements It had become increasingly obvious that the result was usually failure In 1967 Comecon adopted the interested party principle under which any country could opt out of any project they chose still allowing the other member states to use Comecon mechanisms to coordinate their activities In principle a country could still veto but the hope was that they would typically choose just to step aside rather than either veto or be a reluctant participant 23 This aimed at least in part at allowing Romania to chart its own economic course without leaving Comecon entirely or bringing it to an impasse see de satellization of Communist Romania 24 Also until the late 1960s the official term for Comecon activities was cooperation The term integration was always avoided because of its connotations of monopolistic capitalist collusion After the special council session of April 1969 and the development and adoption in 1971 of the Comprehensive Program for the Further Extension and Improvement of Cooperation and the Further Development of Socialist Economic Integration by Comecon Member Countries Comecon activities were officially termed integration equalization of differences in relative scarcities of goods and services between states through the deliberate elimination of barriers to trade and other forms of interaction Although such equalization had not been a pivotal point in the formation and implementation of Comecon s economic policies improved economic integration had always been Comecon s goal 3 25 While such integration was to remain a goal and while Bulgaria became yet more tightly integrated with the Soviet Union progress in this direction was otherwise continually frustrated by the national central planning prevalent in all Comecon countries by the increasing diversity of its members which by this time included Mongolia and would soon include Cuba and by the overwhelming asymmetry and resulting distrust between the many small member states and the Soviet superstate which in 1983 accounted for 88 percent of Comecon s territory and 60 percent of its population 26 In this period there were some efforts to move away from central planning by establishing intermediate industrial associations and combines in various countries which were often empowered to negotiate their own international deals However these groupings typically proved unwieldy conservative risk averse and bureaucratic reproducing the problems they had been intended to solve 27 One economic success of the 1970s was the development of Soviet oil fields While doubtless Central and East Europeans resented having to defray some of the costs of developing the economy of their hated overlord and oppressor 28 they benefited from low prices for fuel and other mineral products As a result Comecon economies generally showed strong growth in the mid 1970s They were largely unaffected by the 1973 oil crisis 27 Another short term economic gain in this period was that detente brought opportunities for investment and technology transfers from the West This also led to an importation of Western cultural attitudes especially in Central Europe However many undertakings based on Western technology were less than successful for example Poland s Ursus tractor factory did not do well with technology licensed from Massey Ferguson other investment was wasted on luxuries for the party elite and most Comecon countries ended up indebted to the West when capital flows died out as detente faded in the late 1970s and from 1979 to 1983 all of Comecon experienced a recession from which with the possible exceptions of East Germany and Bulgaria they never recovered in the Communist era Romania and Poland experienced major declines in the standard of living 29 Perestroika Edit The 1985 Comprehensive Program for Scientific and Technical Progress and the rise to power of Soviet general secretary Mikhail Gorbachev increased Soviet influence in Comecon operations and led to attempts to give Comecon some degree of supranational authority The Comprehensive Program for Scientific and Technical Progress was designed to improve economic cooperation through the development of a more efficient and interconnected scientific and technical base 3 This was the era of perestroika restructuring the last attempt to put the Comecon economies on a sound economic footing 30 Gorbachev and his economic mentor Abel Aganbegyan hoped to make revolutionary changes in the economy foreseeing that science will increasingly become a direct productive force as Marx foresaw By the year 2000 the renewal of plant and machinery will be running at 6 percent or more per year 31 The program was not a success The Gorbachev regime made too many commitments on too many fronts thereby overstretching and overheating the Soviet economy Bottlenecks and shortages were not relieved but exacerbated while the Central and East European members of Comecon resented being asked to contribute scarce capital to projects that were chiefly of interest to the Soviet Union 32 Furthermore the liberalization that by June 25 1988 allowed Comecon countries to negotiate trade treaties directly with the European Community the renamed EEC and the Sinatra doctrine under which the Soviet Union allowed that change would be the exclusive affair of each individual country marked the beginning of the end for Comecon Although the Revolutions of 1989 did not formally end Comecon and the Soviet government itself lasted until 1991 the March 1990 meeting in Prague was little more than a formality discussing the coordination of non existent five year plans From January 1 1991 the countries shifted their dealings with one another to a hard currency market basis The result was a radical decrease in trade with one another as Central and Eastern Europe exchanged asymmetrical trade dependence on the Soviet Union for an equally asymmetrical commercial dependence on the European Community 33 The final Comecon council session took place on June 28 1991 in Budapest and led to an agreement to dissolve in 90 days 34 The Soviet Union was dissolved on December 26 1991 Post Cold War activity after Comecon Edit After the fall of the Soviet Union and communist rule in Eastern Europe East Germany now unified with West Germany automatically joined the European Union then the European Community in 1990 The Baltic States Estonia Latvia and Lithuania Czech Republic Hungary Poland Slovakia and Slovenia joined the EU in 2004 followed by Bulgaria and Romania in 2007 and Croatia in 2013 To date Czech Republic Estonia Germany former GDR Hungary Latvia Poland Slovakia and Slovenia are now members of the Organisation for Economic Co operation and Development All four Central European states are now members of the Visegrad Group Russia the successor to the Soviet Union along with Ukraine and Belarus founded the Commonwealth of Independent States which consists of most of the ex Soviet republics The country also leads the Shanghai Cooperation Organisation with Kazakhstan Kyrgyzstan and Uzbekistan and the Eurasian Economic Union with Armenia Belarus Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan Along with Ukraine Georgia Azerbaijan and Moldova are also part of the GUAM Vietnam and Laos joined the Association of Southeast Asian Nations ASEAN in 1995 and 1997 respectively Membership EditFull members Edit Albania had stopped participating in Comecon activities in 1961 following the Soviet Albanian split but formally withdrew in 1987 East Germany reunified with the West in 1990 Name Official name Accessiondate Continent Capital Area km Population 1989 Density per km Currency Officiallanguages nbsp Albania People s Socialist Republic of Albania Republika Popullore Socialiste e Shqiperise Feb 1949 Europe Tirana 28 748 3 512 317 122 2 Lek Albanian nbsp Bulgaria People s Republic of Bulgaria Narodna republika Blgariya Jan 1949 Europe Sofia 110 994 9 009 018 81 2 Lev Bulgarian nbsp Cuba Republic of Cuba Republica de Cuba July 1972 North America Havana 109 884 10 486 110 95 4 Peso Spanish nbsp Czechoslovakia Czechoslovak Socialist Republic Ceskoslovenska socialisticka republika Jan 1949 Europe Prague 127 900 15 658 079 122 4 Koruna CzechSlovak nbsp East Germany German Democratic Republic Deutsche Demokratische Republik 1950 Europe East Berlin 108 333 16 586 490 153 1 Mark German nbsp Hungary Hungarian People s Republic Magyar Nepkoztarsasag Jan 1949 Europe Budapest 93 030 10 375 323 111 5 Forint Hungarian nbsp Mongolia Mongolian People s Republic Bүgd Najramdah Mongol Ard Uls 1962 Asia Ulaanbaatar 1 564 116 2 125 463 1 4 Togrog Mongolian nbsp Poland Polish People s Republic Polska Rzeczpospolita Ludowa Jan 1949 Europe Warsaw 312 685 38 094 812 121 8 Zloty Polish nbsp Romania Socialist Republic of Romania Republica Socialistă Romania Jan 1949 Europe Bucharest 238 391 23 472 562 98 5 Leu Romanian nbsp Soviet Union Union of Soviet Socialist Republics Soyuz Sovetskih Socialisticheskih Respublik Jan 1949 Europe Asia Moscow 22 402 200 286 730 819 12 8 Rouble None c nbsp Vietnam 3 Socialist Republic of Vietnam Cộng hoa xa hội chủ nghĩa Việt Nam 1978 Asia Hanoi 332 698 66 757 401 200 7 Đồng VietnameseAssociate status Edit nbsp Yugoslavia 1964 Observer status Edit nbsp People s Republic of China 1949 stopped participating in Comecon activities in 1961 following the Sino Soviet split nbsp North Korea 1949 nbsp North Vietnam 1949 nbsp Finland 1973 nbsp Iraq 1975 35 nbsp Mexico 1975 nbsp Angola 1976 nbsp Nicaragua 1984 nbsp Mozambique 1985 nbsp Afghanistan 1986 nbsp Ethiopia 1986 nbsp Laos 1986 nbsp South Yemen 1986 In the late 1950s a number of communist ruled non member countries the People s Republic of China North Korea Mongolia Vietnam and Yugoslavia were invited to participate as observers in Comecon sessions Although Mongolia and Vietnam later gained full membership China stopped attending Comecon sessions after 1961 Yugoslavia negotiated a form of associate status in the organization specified in its 1964 agreement with Comecon 3 Collectively the members of the Comecon did not display the necessary prerequisites for economic integration their level of industrialization was low and uneven with a single dominant member the Soviet Union producing 70 of the community national product 36 In the late 1980s there were ten full members the Soviet Union six East European countries and three extra regional members Geography therefore no longer united Comecon members Wide variations in economic size and level of economic development also tended to generate divergent interests among the member countries All these factors combined to give rise to significant differences in the member states expectations about the benefits to be derived from membership in Comecon Unity was provided instead by political and ideological factors All Comecon members were united by a commonality of fundamental class interests and the ideology of Marxism Leninism and had common approaches to economic ownership state versus private and management plan versus market In 1949 the ruling communist parties of the founding states were also linked internationally through the Cominform from which Yugoslavia had been expelled the previous year Although the Cominform was disbanded in 1956 interparty links continued to be strong among Comecon members and all participated in periodic international conferences of communist parties Comecon provided a mechanism through which its leading member the Soviet Union sought to foster economic links with and among its closest political and military allies The East European members of Comecon were also militarily allied with the Soviet Union in the Warsaw Pact 3 There were three kinds of relationships besides the 10 full memberships with the Comecon Yugoslavia was the only country considered to have associate member status On the basis of the 1964 agreement Yugoslavia participated in twenty one of the thirty two key Comecon institutions as if it were a full member 3 Finland Iraq Mexico and Nicaragua had a cooperant status with Comecon Because the governments of these countries were not empowered to conclude agreements in the name of private companies the governments did not take part in Comecon operations They were represented in Comecon by commissions made up of members of the government and the business community The commissions were empowered to sign various framework agreements with Comecon s Joint Commission on Cooperation 3 After 1956 Comecon allowed certain countries with communist or pro Soviet governments to attend sessions as observers In November 1986 delegations from Afghanistan Ethiopia Laos and South Yemen attended the 42nd Council Session as observers 3 Exchange EditWorking with neither meaningful exchange rates nor a market economy Comecon countries had to look to world markets as a reference point for prices but unlike agents acting in a market prices tended to be stable over a period of years rather than constantly fluctuating which assisted central planning Also there was a tendency to underprice raw materials relative to the manufactured goods produced in many of the Comecon countries 37 International barter helped preserve the Comecon countries scarce hard currency reserves In strict economic terms barter inevitably harmed countries whose goods would have brought higher prices in the free market or whose imports could have been obtained more cheaply and benefitted those for whom it was the other way around Still all of the Comecon countries gained some stability and the governments gained some legitimacy 37 and in many ways this stability and protection from the world market was viewed at least in the early years of Comecon as an advantage of the system as was the formation of stronger ties with other socialist countries 38 Within Comecon there were occasional struggles over how this system should work Early on Nikolai Voznesensky pushed for a more law governed and technocratic price based approach However with the August 1948 death of Andrei Zhdanov Voznesensky lost his patron and was soon accused of treason as part of the Leningrad Affair within two years he was dead in prison Instead what won out was a physical planning approach that strengthened the role of central governments over technocrats 39 At the same time the effort to create a single regime of planning common economic organization with the ability to set plans throughout the Comecon region also came to nought A protocol to create such a system was signed January 18 1949 but never ratified 40 While historians are not unanimous on why this was stymied it clearly threatened the sovereignty not only of the smaller states but even of the Soviet Union itself since an international body would have had real power Stalin clearly preferred informal means of intervention in the other Comecon states 41 This lack of either rationality or international central planning tended to promote autarky in each Comecon country because none fully trusted the others to deliver goods and services 39 With few exceptions foreign trade in the Comecon countries was a state monopoly and the state agencies and captive trading companies were often corrupt Even at best this tended to put several removes between a producer and any foreign customer limiting the ability to learn to adjust to foreign customers needs Furthermore there was often strong political pressure to keep the best products for domestic use in each country From the early 1950s to Comecon s demise in the early 1990s intra Comecon trade except for Soviet petroleum was in steady decline 42 Oil transfers Edit Beginning no later than the early 1970s 43 Soviet petroleum and natural gas were routinely transferred within Comecon at below market rates Most Western commentators have viewed this as implicit politically motivated subsidization of shaky economies to defuse discontent and reward compliance with Soviet wishes 44 Other commentators say that this may not have been deliberate policy noting that whenever prices differ from world market prices there will be winners and losers They argue that this may have been simply an unforeseen consequence of two factors the slow adjustment of Comecon prices during a time of rising oil and gas prices and the fact that mineral resources were abundant in the Comecon sphere relative to manufactured goods A possible point of comparison is that there were also winners and losers under EEC agricultural policy in the same period 45 Russian and Kazakh oil kept the Comecon countries oil prices low when the 1973 oil crisis quadrupled Western oil prices Ineffective production Edit The organization of Comecon was officially focused on common expansion of states more effective production and building relationships between countries within And as in every planned economy operations did not reflect state of market innovations availability of items or the specific needs of a country One example came from former Czechoslovakia In the 1970s the Communist party of Czechoslovakia finally realized that there was a need for underground trains Czechoslovak designers projected a cheap but technologically innovative underground train The train was a state of the art project capable of moving underground or on the surface using standard rails had a high number of passenger seats and was lightweight According to the designers the train was technologically more advanced than the trains used in New York s Subway London s Tube or the Paris Metro However due to the plan of Comecon older Soviet trains were used which guaranteed profit for the Soviet Union and work for workers in Soviet factories That economical change lead to the cancellation of the R1 trains by A Honzik The Comecon plan though more profitable for the Soviets if less resourceful for the Czechs and Slovaks forced the Czechoslovak government to buy trains Ecs 81 709 and 81 71 both of which were designed in early 1950s and were heavy unreliable and expensive Materials available only in Czech Republic and Slovakia video included 46 On the other hand Czechoslovak trams Tatra T3 and jet trainers L 29 were the standard for all Comecon countries including the USSR and other countries could develop their own designs but only for their own needs like Poland respectively Konstal trams and TS 11 jets Poland was a manufacturer of light helicopters for Comecon countries Mi 2 of the Soviet design The USSR developed their own model Kamov Ka 26 and Romania produced French helicopters under license for their own market In a formal or informal way often the countries were discouraged from developing their own designs that competed with the main Comecon design Structure EditAlthough not formally part of the organization s hierarchy the Conference of First Secretaries of Communist and Workers Parties and of the Heads of Government of the Comecon Member Countries was Comecon s most important organ These party and government leaders gathered for conference meetings regularly to discuss topics of mutual interest Because of the rank of conference participants their decisions had considerable influence on the actions taken by Comecon and its organs 3 The official hierarchy of Comecon consisted of the Session of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance the Executive Committee of the Council the Secretariat of the Council four council committees twenty four standing commissions six interstate conferences two scientific institutes and several associated organizations 3 The Session Edit The Session of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance officially the highest Comecon organ examined fundamental problems of economic integration and directed the activities of the Secretariat and other subordinate organizations Delegations from each Comecon member country attended these meetings Prime ministers usually headed the delegations which met during the second quarter of each year in a member country s capital the location of the meeting was determined by a system of rotation based on Cyrillic script All interested parties had to consider recommendations handed down by the Session A treaty or other kind of legal agreement implemented adopted recommendations Comecon itself might adopt decisions only on organizational and procedural matters pertaining to itself and its organs 3 Each country appointed one permanent representative to maintain relations between members and Comecon between annual meetings An extraordinary Session such as the one in December 1985 might be held with the consent of at least one third of the members Such meetings usually took place in Moscow 3 Executive committee Edit The highest executive organ in Comecon the Executive Committee was entrusted with elaborating policy recommendations and supervising their implementation between sessions In addition it supervised work on plan coordination and scientific technical cooperation Composed of one representative from each member country usually a deputy prime minister the Executive Committee met quarterly usually in Moscow In 1971 and 1974 the Executive Committee acquired economic departments that ranked above the standing commissions These economic departments considerably strengthened the authority and importance of the Executive Committee 3 Other entities Edit There were four council committees Council Committee for Cooperation in Planning Council Committee for Scientific and Technical Cooperation Council Committee for Cooperation in Material and Technical Supply and Council Committee for Cooperation in Machine Building Their mission was to ensure the comprehensive examination and a multilateral settlement of the major problems of cooperation among member countries in the economy science and technology All committees were headquartered in Moscow and usually met there These committees advised the standing commissions the Secretariat the interstate conferences and the scientific institutes in their areas of specialization Their jurisdiction was generally wider than that of the standing commissions because they had the right to make policy recommendations to other Comecon organizations 3 The Council Committee for Cooperation in Planning was the most important of the four It coordinated the national economic plans of Comecon members As such it ranked in importance only after the Session and the Executive Committee Made up of the chairmen of Comecon members national central planning offices the Council Committee for Cooperation in Planning drew up draft agreements for joint projects adopted a resolution approving these projects and recommended approval to the concerned parties If its decisions were not subject to approval by national governments and parties this committee would be considered Comecon s supranational planning body 3 The international Secretariat Comecon s only permanent body was Comecon s primary economic research and administrative organ The secretary who has been a Soviet official since Comecon creation was the official Comecon representative to Comecon member states and to other states and international organizations Subordinate to the secretary were his deputy and the various departments of the Secretariat which generally corresponded to the standing commissions The Secretariat s responsibilities included preparation and organization of Comecon sessions and other meetings conducted under the auspices of Comecon compilation of digests on Comecon activities conduct of economic and other research for Comecon members and preparation of recommendations on various issues concerning Comecon operations 3 In 1956 eight standing commissions were set up to help Comecon make recommendations pertaining to specific economic sectors The commissions have been rearranged and renamed a number of times since the establishment of the first eight In 1986 there were twenty four standing commissions each headquartered in the capital of a member country and headed by one of that country s leading authorities in the field addressed by the commission The Secretariat supervised the actual operations of the commissions The standing commissions had authority only to make recommendations which had then to be approved by the Executive Committee presented to the Session and ratified by the interested member countries Commissions usually met twice a year in Moscow 3 The six interstate conferences on water management internal trade legal matters inventions and patents pricing and labor affairs served as forums for discussing shared issues and experiences They were purely consultative and generally acted in an advisory capacity to the Executive Committee or its specialized committees 3 The scientific institutes on standardization and on economic problems of the world economic system concerned themselves with theoretical problems of international cooperation Both were headquartered in Moscow and were staffed by experts from various member countries 3 Affiliated agencies Edit nbsp 1974 Medallion 10th Anniversary of Intermetall that was founded in 1964 in BudapestSeveral affiliated agencies having a variety of relationships with Comecon existed outside the official Comecon hierarchy They served to develop direct links between appropriate bodies and organizations of Comecon member countries 3 These affiliated agencies were divided into two categories intergovernmental economic organizations which worked on a higher level in the member countries and generally dealt with a wider range of managerial and coordinative activities and international economic organizations which worked closer to the operational level of research production or trade A few examples of the former are the International Bank for Economic Cooperation managed the transferable rouble system the International Investment Bank in charge of financing joint projects and Intermetall encouraged cooperation in ferrous metallurgy 3 International economic organizations generally took the form of either joint enterprises international economic associations or unions or international economic partnerships The latter included Interatominstrument nuclear machinery producers Intertekstilmash textile machinery producers and Haldex a Hungarian Polish joint enterprise for reprocessing coal slag 3 Nature of operation EditComecon was an interstate organization through which members attempted to coordinate economic activities of mutual interest and to develop multilateral economic scientific and technical cooperation 3 The Charter 1959 stated that the sovereign equality of all members was fundamental to the organization and procedures of Comecon 3 18 The Comprehensive Program further emphasized that the processes of integration of members economies were completely voluntary and do not involve the creation of supranational bodies Hence under the provisions of the Charter each country had the right to equal representation and one vote in all organs of Comecon regardless of the country s economic size or the size of its contribution to Comecon s budget 3 From 1967 the interestedness provisions of the Charter reinforced the principle of sovereign equality Comecon s recommendations and decisions could be adopted only upon agreement among the interested members and each had the right to declare its interest in any matter under consideration 3 23 Furthermore in the words of the Charter as revised in 1967 recommendations and decisions shall not apply to countries that have declared that they have no interest in a particular matter 3 23 Although Comecon recognized the principle of unanimity from 1967 disinterested parties did not have a veto but rather the right to abstain from participation A declaration of disinterest could not block a project unless the disinterested party s participation was vital Otherwise the Charter implied that the interested parties could proceed without the abstaining member affirming that a country that had declared a lack of interest may subsequently adhere to the recommendations and decisions adopted by the remaining members of the Council 3 However a member country could also declare an interest and exercise a veto 23 Over the years of its functioning Comecon acted more as an instrument of mutual economic assistance than a means of economic integration with multilateralism as an unachievable goal 47 J F Brown a British historian of Eastern Europe cited Vladimir Sobell a Czech born economist for the view that Comecon was an international protection system rather than an international trade system in contrast with the EEC which was essentially the latter 48 Whereas the latter was interested in production efficiency and in allocation via market prices the former was interested in bilateral aid to fulfill central planning goals 48 Writing in 1988 Brown stated that many people in both the West and the East had assumed that a trade and efficiency approach was what Comecon was meant to pursue which might make it an international trade system more like the EEC and that some economists in Hungary and Poland had advocated such an approach in the 1970s and 1980s but that it would need a transformation of every Eastern Bloc economy along Hungarian lines i e only partly centrally planned to enable a market guided Comecon to work And any change along those lines has been ideologically unacceptable up to now 48 Comecon versus the European Economic Community Edit nbsp European trade blocs as of the late 1980s EEC member states are marked in blue EFTA green and Comecon red Although Comecon was loosely referred to as the European Economic Community EEC of Central and Eastern Europe important contrasts existed between the two organizations Both organizations administered economic integration however their economic structure size balance and influence differed 3 In the 1980s the EEC incorporated the 270 million people in Europe into economic association through intergovernmental agreements aimed at maximizing profits and economic efficiency on a national and international scale The EEC was a supranational body that could adopt decisions such as removing tariffs and enforce them Activity by members was based on initiative and enterprise from below on the individual or enterprise level and was strongly influenced by market forces 3 Comecon joined together 450 million people in 10 countries and on 3 continents The level of industrialization from country to country differed greatly the organization linked two underdeveloped countries Mongolia and Vietnam with some highly industrialized states Likewise a large national income difference existed between European and non European members The physical size military power and political and economic resource base of the Soviet Union made it the dominant member In trade among Comecon members the Soviet Union usually provided raw materials and Central and East European countries provided finished equipment and machinery The three underdeveloped Comecon members had a special relationship with the other seven Comecon realized disproportionately more political than economic gains from its heavy contributions to these three countries underdeveloped economies Economic integration or plan coordination formed the basis of Comecon s activities In this system which mirrored the member countries planned economies the decisions handed down from above ignored the influences of market forces or private initiative Comecon had no supranational authority to make decisions or to implement them Its recommendations could only be adopted with the full concurrence of interested parties and from 1967 23 did not affect those members who declared themselves disinterested parties 3 As remarked above most Comecon foreign trade was a state monopoly placing several barriers between a producer and a foreign customer 42 Unlike the EEC where treaties mostly limited government activity and allowed the market to integrate economies across national lines Comecon needed to develop agreements that called for positive government action Furthermore while private trade slowly limited or erased national rivalries in the EEC state to state trade in Comecon reinforced national rivalries and resentments 49 Prices exchange rates coordination of national plans EditSee Comprehensive Program for Socialist Economic IntegrationInternational relations within the Comecon EditSee International relations within the ComeconSoviet domination of Comecon was a function of its economic political and military power The Soviet Union possessed 90 percent of Comecon members land and energy resources 70 percent of their population 65 percent of their national income and industrial and military capacities second in the world only to those of the United States citation needed The location of many Comecon committee headquarters in Moscow and the large number of Soviet nationals in positions of authority also testified to the power of the Soviet Union within the organization 3 Soviet efforts to exercise political power over its Comecon partners however were met with determined opposition The sovereign equality of members as described in the Comecon Charter assured members that if they did not wish to participate in a Comecon project they might abstain Central and East European members frequently invoked this principle in fear that economic interdependence would further reduce political sovereignty Thus neither Comecon nor the Soviet Union as a major force within Comecon had supranational authority Although this fact ensured some degree of freedom from Soviet economic domination of the other members it also deprived Comecon of necessary power to achieve maximum economic efficiency 3 See also Edit nbsp Soviet Union portal nbsp Economy portalAssociation of Southeast Asian Nations Bilateral trade Commonwealth of Independent States Economy of the Soviet Union Eurasian Economic Union European Union Druzhba pipeline also as Friendship Pipeline also as Comecon Pipeline Five year plans of the Soviet Union History of the Soviet Union Non Aligned Movement State capitalism State socialism Planned economy Shanghai Cooperation Organisation Spartakiad Bolivarian Alliance for the Peoples of Our America Visegrad Group Craiova Group Warsaw PactNotes Edit Stopped participating in Comecon activities in 1961 withdrew in 1987 Withdrew in 1990 Russian was de facto national language of the Union Michael C Kaser Comecon Integration problems of the planned economies Oxford University Press 1967 For example this is the usage in the Library of Congress Country Study that is heavily cited in the present article a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r s t u v w x y z aa ab ac ad ae af ag ah ai aj Appendix B The Council for Mutual Economic Assistance Germany East Library of Congress Country Study Archived from the original on 1 May 2009 SOGLAShENIE mezhdu Pravitelstvom Soyuza Sovetskih Socialisticheskih Respublik i Sovetom Ekonomicheskoj Vzaimopomoshi ob uregulirovanii voprosov svyazannyh s mestoraspolozheniem v SSSR uchrezhdenij SEV Archived from the original on 2021 06 12 a b c Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 536 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 534 35 Kaser 1967 pp 9 10 a b Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 535 W Wallace and R Clarke Comecon Trade and the West London Pinter 1986 p 1 quoted by Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 536 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 536 37 Elena Dragomir The formation of the Soviet bloc s Council for Mutual Economic Assistance Romania s involvement Journal Cold War Studies xiv 2012 34 47 http www mitpressjournals org doi abs 10 1162 JCWS a 00190 VQKof9KsX65 Dragomir Elena 2015 The creation of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance as seen from the Romanian archives The creation of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance Historical Research 88 240 355 379 doi 10 1111 1468 2281 12083 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 539 41 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 541 42 a b Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 542 43 Faudot Adrien Marinova Tsvetelina Nenovsky Nikolay 2022 07 20 Comecon Monetary Mechanisms A history of socialist monetary integration 1949 1991 mpra ub uni muenchen de Retrieved 2023 04 20 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 543 34 a b Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 544 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 559 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 560 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 553 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 560 61 a b c d e Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 561 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 566 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 564 566 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 564 a b Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 568 69 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 568 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 571 72 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 579 Abel Aganbegyan quoted in Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 580 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 580 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 580 82 the quotation is on p 582 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 582 Smolansky Oleg Smolansky Bettie 1991 The USSR and Iraq The Soviet Quest for Influence Duke University Press p 25 ISBN 978 0 8223 1116 4 Zwass 1989 p 4 a b Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 537 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 538 a b Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 539 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 540 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 540 41 a b Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 565 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 569 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 570 makes the assertion about this being the dominant view and cites several examples Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 pp 570 71 Zaslapane projekty Prazske metro Ceska televize Ceska televize Archived from the original on 19 June 2010 Retrieved 8 May 2018 Zwass 1989 pp 14 21 a b c Brown J F 1988 Eastern Europe and Communist Rule Duke University Press ISBN 978 0882308418 pp 145 56 Bideleux and Jeffries 1998 p 567 References Edit nbsp This article incorporates text from this source which is in the public domain Country Studies Federal Research Division Robert Bideleux and Ian Jeffries A History of Eastern Europe Crisis and Change Routledge 1998 ISBN 0 415 16111 8 Brine Jenny J ed Comecon the rise and fall of an international socialist organization Vol 3 Transaction Publishers 1992 Crump Laurien and Simon Godard Reassessing Communist International Organisations A Comparative Analysis of COMECON and the Warsaw Pact in relation to their Cold War Competitors Contemporary European History 27 1 2018 85 109 Falk Flade Review of Economic Entanglements in East Central Europe and the Comecon s Position in the Global Economy 1949 1991 online at H Soz u Kult H Net Reviews Jam 2013 Godard Simon Only One Way to Be a Communist How Biographical Trajectories Shaped Internationalism among COMECON Experts Critique internationale 1 2015 69 83 Michael Kaser Comecon Integration Problems of the Planned Economies Royal Institute of International Affairs Oxford University Press 1967 ISBN 0 192 14956 3 Lanyi Kamilla The collapse of the COMECON market Russian amp East European Finance and Trade 29 1 1993 68 86 online Libbey James CoCom Comecon and the Economic Cold War Russian History 37 2 2010 133 152 Radisch Erik The Struggle of the Soviet Conception of Comecon 1953 1975 Comparativ 27 5 6 2017 26 47 Zwass Adam The Council for Mutual Economic Assistance The Thorny Path from Political to Economic Integration M E Sharpe Armonk NY 1989 Faudot Adrien Tsvetelina Marinova and Nikolay Nenovsky Comecon Monetary Mechanisms A history of socialist monetary integration 1949 1991 MPRA 2022 Comecon Monetary Mechanisms A history of socialist monetary integration 1949 1991 External links EditGermany East Country Study TOC Data as of July 1987 Appendix B The Council for Mutual Economic Assistance Library of Congress Call Number DD280 6 E22 1988 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Comecon amp oldid 1176854534, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.