fbpx
Wikipedia

Land reforms by country

Agrarian reform and land reform have been a recurring theme of enormous consequence in world history. They are often highly political and have been achieved (or attempted) in many countries.

Latin America edit

 
Children singing the "Internationale" at the 20th Anniversary of Brazil's Landless Workers Movement

Brazil edit

Getúlio Vargas, who rose to presidency in Brazil following the Brazilian Revolution of 1930, promised a land reform but reneged on his promise.

A first attempt to make a nationwide reform was set up in the government of José Sarney (1985–1990) as a result of the strong popular movement that had contributed to the fall of the military government. According to the 1988 Constitution of Brazil, the government is required to "expropriate for the purpose of agrarian reform, rural property that is not performing its social function" (Article 184). However, the "social function" mentioned there is not well defined, and hence the so-called First Land Reform National Plan never was put into action.

Bolivia edit

Land in Bolivia was unequally distributed – 92% of the cultivable land was held by large estates – until the Bolivian national revolution in 1952. Then, the Revolutionary Nationalist Movement government abolished forced peasantry labor and established a program of expropriation and distribution of the rural property of the traditional landlords to the indigenous peasants. A unique feature of the reform in Bolivia was the organization of peasants into syndicates. Peasants were not only granted land but their militias also were given large supplies of arms. The peasants remained a powerful political force in Bolivia during all subsequent governments. By 1970, 45% of peasant families had received title to land. Land reform projects continued in the 1970s and 1980s. A 1996 agrarian reform law increased protection for smallholdings and indigenous territories, but also protected absentee landholders who pay taxes from expropriation. Reforms were continued at 2006, with the Bolivian senate passing a bill authorizing the government redistribution of land among the nation's mostly indigenous poor.

Chile edit

Attempts at land reform began under the government of Jorge Alessandri in 1960, were accelerated during the government of Eduardo Frei Montalva (1964–1970), and reached its climax during the 1970-1973 presidency of Salvador Allende. Farms of more than 198 acres (80 ha) were expropriated. After the 1973 coup the process was halted by the military junta and – up to a point – reversed by the market forces.

Colombia edit

Alfonso López Pumarejo (1934–1938) passed Law 200 of 1936,[1] which allowed for the expropriation of private properties, in order to promote "social interest".

Later attempts declined, until the National Front presidencies of Alberto Lleras Camargo (1958–1962) and Carlos Lleras Restrepo (1966–1970), which respectively created the Colombian Institute for Agrarian Reform (INCORA) and further developed land entitlement. In 1968 and 1969 alone, the INCORA issued more than 60,000 land titles to farmers and workers.

Despite this, the process was then halted and the situation began to reverse itself, as the subsequent violent actions of drug lords, paramilitaries, guerrillas and opportunistic large landowners severely contributed to a renewed concentration of land and to the displacement of small landowners.[2]

In the early 21st century, tentative government plans to use the land legally expropriated from drug lords and/or the properties given back by demobilized paramilitary groups have not caused much practical improvement yet.

Cuba edit

Land reform was among the chief planks of the revolutionary platform of 1959. Almost all large holdings were seized by the National Institute for Agrarian Reform (INRA), which dealt with all areas of agricultural policy. A ceiling of 166 acres (67 hectares) was established, and tenants were given ownership rights, though these rights are constrained by government production quotas and a prohibition of real estate transactions.

Guatemala edit

Land reform occurred during the "Ten Years of Spring" (1944–1954) under the governments of Juan José Arévalo and Jacobo Árbenz, after a popular revolution forced out dictator Jorge Ubico. The largest part of the reform was the law officially called Decree 900, which redistributed all uncultivated land from landholdings that were larger than 673 acres (272 ha). If the estates were between 672 acres (272 ha) and 224 acres (91 ha) in size, uncultivated land was expropriated only if less than two-thirds of it was in use.[3] The law benefited 500,000 people, or one-sixth of the Guatemalan Population. Historians have called this reform as one of the most successful land reforms in history. However, the United Fruit Company felt threatened by the law and lobbied the United States government, which was a factor in the US-backed coup that deposed Árbenz in 1954. The majority of the reform was rolled back by the US supported military dictatorship that followed.[3]

Mexico edit

In 1856, the first land reform was driven by the ley Lerdo (the Lerdo law), enacted by the Liberal Party government of the Second Federal Republic of Mexico. One of the aims of the reform government was to develop the economy by returning to productive cultivation the underutilized lands of the Roman Catholic Church and the municipal communities (Indian commons), which required the division of these lands for sale, with the expectation that Mexico would develop a class of small owners. This was to be accomplished through the provisions of Ley Lerdo that prohibited ownership of land by the Church and the municipalities. The reform government also financed its war effort by seizing and selling church property and other large estates. Little land was acquired by individual small holders. After the war, the role of the state in land policy expanded during the presidency of Porfirio Diaz. The aim was to extinguish traditional subsistence farming and make agriculture in Mexico a dynamic commercial sector as part of Mexico's modernization. Land was concentrated in the hands of large-scale owners, a great many of them foreigners, leaving peasantry, the largest sector of the Mexican population, landless. Peasant unrest was a major cause of the Mexican Revolution of 1910–20. A certain degree of land reform was introduced, albeit unevenly, as part of the Mexican Revolution.[4]

In 1934, president Lázaro Cárdenas passed the 1934 Agrarian Code and accelerated the pace of land reform. He helped redistribute 45,000,000 acres (180,000 km2) of land, 4,000,000 acres (16,000 km2) of which were expropriated from American owned agricultural property. This caused conflict between Mexico and the United States. Agrarian reform had come close to extinction in the early 1930s. The first few years of the Cárdenas's reform were marked by high food prices, falling wages, high inflation, and low agricultural yields. In 1935 land reform began sweeping across the country in the periphery and core of commercial agriculture. The Cárdenas alliance with peasant groups was awarded by the destruction of the hacienda system. Cárdenas distributed more land than all his revolutionary predecessors put together, a 400% increase. The land reform justified itself in terms of productivity; average agricultural production during the three-year period from 1939 to 1941 was higher than it had been at any time since the beginning of the revolution.

Starting with the government of Miguel Alemán (1946–52), land reform steps made in previous governments were rolled back. Alemán's government allowed capitalist entrepreneurs to rent peasant land. This created phenomenon known as neolatifundismo, where land owners build up large-scale private farms on the basis of controlling land which remains ejidal but is not sown by the peasants to whom it is assigned.

In 1970, President Luis Echeverría began his term by declaring land reform dead. In the face of peasant revolt, he was forced to backtrack, and embarked on the biggest land reform program since Cárdenas. Echeverría legalized take-overs of huge foreign-owned private farms, which were turned into new collective ejidos.

In 1988, President Carlos Salinas de Gortari was elected. In December 1991, he amended Article 27 of the Constitution, making it legal to sell ejido land and allow peasants to put up their land as collateral for a loan.

Francisco Madero and Emiliano Zapata were strongly identified with land reform, as are the present-day (as of 2006) Zapatista Army of National Liberation.

Today, most Mexican peasants are landowners. However, their holdings are usually too small, and farmers must supplement their incomes by working for the remaining landlords, and/or traveling to the United States.

See also: México Indígena (2005-2008 project)

Nicaragua edit

During and after the Nicaraguan Revolution (1979), the Sandinista government officially announced their political platform which included land reform.

The last months of Sandinista rule were criticized for the Piñata Plan, which distributed large tracts of land to prominent Sandinistas. After their loss in the 1990 elections, most of the Sandinista leaders held most of the private property and businesses that had been confiscated and nationalized by the FSLN government. This process became known as the piñata and was tolerated by the new government of Violeta Chamorro.

Peru edit

Land reform in the 1950s largely eliminated a centuries-old system of debt peonage.

Further land reform occurred after the 1968 coup by left-wing colonel Juan Velasco Alvarado. The military dictatorship under General Velasco (1968–75) launched a large-scale agrarian reform movement that attempted to redistribute land, hoping to break Peru's traditionally inequitable pattern of land holding and the hold of traditional oligarchy.[5] The model used by Velasco to bring about change was the associative enterprise, in which former salaried rural workers and independent peasant families would become members of different kinds of cooperatives.[6] About 22 million acres were redistributed, more land than in any reform program outside of Cuba. Unfortunately, productivity suffered as peasants with no management experience took control. The military government continued to spend huge amounts of money to transform Peru's agriculture to socialized ownership and management. These state expenditures are to blame for the enormous increase in Peru's external debt at the beginning of the 1970s.[6] State bankruptcy was partly caused by the cheap credit the government extended to promote agrarian development, state subsidies, and administrative expenditures to carry out the agrarian reform during this period.[6] The more radical effects of this reform were reversed by president Fernando Belaúnde Terry in the 1980s.

A third land reform occurred as part of a counterterrorism effort against the Shining Path during the Internal conflict in Peru roughly 1988–1995, led by Hernando de Soto and the Institute for Liberty and Democracy during the early years of the government of Alberto Fujimori, before the latter's auto-coup.[citation needed]

Venezuela edit

In 2001, Hugo Chávez's government enacted Plan Zamora to redistribute government and unused private land to campesinos in need.

The plan met with heavy opposition which led to a coup attempt in 2002. When Pedro Carmona took over the presidency during that event, he reversed the land reform. However, the reversal was declared null when the coup failed and Chávez returned to power. By the end of 2003, 60,000 families had received temporary title to a total of 55,000 km² of land under this plan.

Despite the land reforms carried out by the government, which, according to some sources, have reduced the so-called latifundios (which means "big landownership"), most receivers of the land didn't have any knowledge about how to cultivate the land and grow crops. In many cases, peasants didn't even water, since water infrastructures were still missing in most of the regions.[7]

Moreover, in some cases, campesinos didn't gain direct ownership of the land, but only the right to farm it without having to pay the rent and without sanctions from the government, and in some cases the land wasn't given to single peasant family, but managed in communes. According to some sources, the expropriated land amounts to 4-5 million hectares.[8][9]

Paraguay edit

Paraguay has been known to have experienced some obstacles in its political history that have been known mostly as dictatorship and corruption. Paraguay's history is what has shaped the Paraguay we see today and as well as what has brought along the unequal land distributions. From the War of the Triple Alliance (1864-1870) Paraguay came out losing land to Argentina, Brazil, and Uruguay as well as suffered from a great decline in population and was left with political instability. Land in Paraguay has been known to be unequally distributed therefore prolonging rural poverty in Paraguay. Following the Triple Alliance War the nation underwent a 35-year dictatorship of President Alfredo Stroessner in the years of 1954 to 1989. Stroessner was known to take away many campesino's land in order to give it to military officials, foreign corporations and civilian supporters, "over eight million hectares of state-owned land (20 percent of total land) were given away or sold at negligible prices to friends of the regime, who accumulated huge tracts of land."[10] Stroessner also faked an alliance with the Colorado Party in order to distribute public land. Campesinos' cries for help for land reform were ignored and the prosecution against them continued, causing them to suffer from high poverty rates. June S. Beittel said that as a result of the unequal distribution of land it left, “ rural areas the most poverty-stricken.”[11] In the year of 1954, the Truth and Justice Committee focused on getting justice for the abuses many Campesinos were facing from their own government.

After decades of controversy over government land policy, two agrarian laws were created in 1963. These laws were known as the Agrarian Statute, "limiting the maximum size of landholding to 10,000 hectares in Eastern Paraguay and 20,000 hectares in the Chaco."[12] However, these laws were rarely enforced. Under the Agrarian Statute, there was also the creation of IBR (Instituto de Bienestar Rural) which "mandated to plan colonization programs, issue land titles to farmers, and provide new colonies with support services."[12] Although IBR focused on serving the land needs of farmers their task was so big and its resources so little that their goals for helping farmers were out of reach.

Paraguayan democracy came a long way after its 35-year dictatorship, but the unequal distribution of land is still a problem for the nation since their economy is one that is dependent on its agriculture. A census in 2008 revealed that “80 percent of agriculture land is held by just 1.6 percent of landowners, with the 600 largest properties occupying 40 percent of the total productive land. More than 300,000 family farmers have no land at all.”[10] Paraguayans have formed unions such as National Federation of Campesinos (FNC) who has fought for justice on the unequal land distributions in Latin America they have helped many campesinos reclaim acres of land since 1989. The ongoing inequality of land distribution has led to a demand for land regulation. Citizens remain cautious about the nation's democracy and fearful of the return of dictatorship and corruption.

The problem regarding land distribution has worsened recently due to the expansion of monoculture in specific, soy. Paraguay has become the fourth world's largest distributors of soy. Due to this distribution, soy companies are the largest landowners, taking over 80 percent of the land. This production has negatively impacted the lives of rural peasants by leaving them without their own land. Thus, in March 2017, the streets of Paraguay's capital were filled with more than 1000 campesinos demanding for agrarian reform.

Thousands of rural peasants demand access to land, fair agricultural prices for what they produce and technical assistance. Due to the increase in soy production, campesinos has been forced out of their lands leading them to demand land regulations. This demand of the stabilization and fairness of agricultural prices is a result of Paraguay's government failing to sustain secure prices for their produce which are leaving them to live in extreme poverty. In the effect of no secure economy for their produce, campesinos mandate technical help.

A great majority of Paraguayans continue to practice subsistence agriculture in the depths of the Paraguayan campo (countryside). Despite their struggle with poverty, inequality and land rights, Paraguayans are proud of their campesino structure and the traditional culture that arises from it, with this culture being the most prominent in Paraguay than anywhere else in Latin America.

In December 2017, “over one-third of the population was impoverished and 19% were living in ‘extreme poverty’”, so “the further centralization of land and power has only functioned to exacerbate socio-economic issues.”[13] Thus, the campesino movement is still ongoing due to the desire to continue their campesino traditions and to be able to make a living wage doing so.

Middle East and North Africa edit

 
The shah distributing land deeds during Iran's White Revolution

Ottoman Empire edit

The Ottoman Land Code of 1858 (1274 in the Islamic calendar) was the beginning of a systematic land reform programme started during the Tanzimat period by Sultan Abdülmecid I of the Ottoman Empire during the latter half of the 19th century, with the overall aims of increasing state revenue generated from land and for the state to be able to have greater control over individual plots of land. This was followed by the 1873 land emancipation act.

Egypt edit

Initially, Egyptian land reform essentially abolished the political influence of major land owners. However, land reform only resulted in the redistribution of about 15% of Egypt's land under cultivation, and by the early 1980s, the effects of land reform in Egypt drew to a halt as the population of Egypt moved away from agriculture. The Egyptian land reform laws were greatly curtailed under Anwar Sadat and eventually abolished.

Iran edit

Significant land reform in Iran took place under the shah as part of the socio-economic reforms of the White Revolution, begun in 1962, and agreed upon through a public referendum. At this time the Iranian economy was not performing well and there was political unrest. Essentially, the land reforms amounted to a huge redistribution of land to rural peasants who previously had no possibility of owning land as they were poorly paid labourers. The land reforms continued from 1962 until 1971 with three distinct phases of land distribution: private, government-owned and endowed land. These reforms resulted in the newly created peasant landowners owning six to seven million hectares, around 52-63% of Iran's agricultural land. According to Country-Data, even though there had been a considerable redistribution of land, the amount received by individual peasants was not enough to meet most families' basic needs, "About 75 percent of the peasant owners [however] had less than 7 hectares, an amount generally insufficient for anything but subsistence agriculture.".[14] By 1979 a quarter of prime land was in disputed ownership and half of the productive land was in the hands of 200,000 absentee landlords[14] The large land owners were able to retain the best land with the best access to fresh water and irrigation facilities. In contrast, not only were the new peasant land holdings too small to produce an income but the peasants also lacked both quality irrigation system and sustained government support to enable them to develop their land to make a reasonable living. Set against the economic boom from oil revenue it became apparent that the Land Reforms did not make life better for the rural population: according to Amid, "..only a small group of rural people experienced increasing improvements in their welfare and poverty remained the lot of the majority".[15] Moghadam argues[citation needed] that the structural changes to Iran, including the land reforms, initiated by the White Revolution, contributed to the revolution in 1979 which overthrew the Shah and turned Iran into an Islamic republic.

Iraq edit

Under British Mandate, Iraq's land was moved from communal land owned by the tribe to tribal sheikhs that agreed to work with the British Empire. Known as compradors, these families controlled much of Iraq's arable land until the end of British rule in 1958. Throughout the 1920s and 30s, more and more land began to be centered in the hands of just a couple families. By 1958 eight individual families owned almost 1 million acres (400 thousand hectares). However, the British did attempt to instill some reforms to increase the productivity of the land in Iraq. In 1926 the Pump Law was introduced, essentially legislating that all newly irrigated land would be tax free for 4 years. This led to some short term gains in land productivity. If land was cultivated for 15 years, it then became the property of the person who cultivated that land. From 1914 to 1943 there was an increase from 1 million to 4.25 million acres of land developed. Unfortunately, irrigation of the land was irresponsible, and many farmers didn't allow for drainage, which led to a buildup of salt and minerals in the land, killing its productivity.[16]

In 1958 the rise of the Iraqi Communist Party led to the seizing of much of the land by the Iraqi Republic. Landholdings were capped at 600 acres (240 hectares) in arable areas and 1,200 acres (490 hectares) in areas that had rainfall. The concentrated landholdings by the state were then redistributed among the populace, in amounts of 20 acres (8.1 hectares) in irrigated land, with 40 acres (16 hectares) in land with rainfall.

In 1970, the Ba'th Party, led by Saddam Hussein began instituting a wide series of sweeping land reforms. The intent of the reforms was to remove control of land owned by the traditional rural elites and redistribute it to peasant families. Modeled after the 1958 land reforms, much of the state land was rented out, though often to people who originally owned the large swathes of land. The key to this new reform was the Agrarian Reform Law of 1970.Between 1970 and 1982, 264,400 farmers received grants of land. However, these reforms did not contribute to an improvement in the production of agricultural goods, leading the regime to increase its imports of food products.[17]

Maghreb edit

As elsewhere in North Africa, lands formerly held by European farmers have been taken over. The nationalisation of agricultural land in Algeria, Morocco and Tunisia led to the departure of the majority of Europeans.[18]

Syria edit

Land reforms were first implemented in Syria during 1958. The Agricultural Relations Law laid down a redistribution of rights in landownership, tenancy and management.

The reforms were halted in 1961 due to a culmination of factors, including opposition from large landowners and severe crop failure during a drought between 1958 and 1961, whilst Syria was a member of the doomed United Arab Republic (UAR).

After the Ba'ath Party gained power in 1963 the reforms were resumed. The reforms were portrayed by the governing Ba'ath as politically motivated to benefit the rural property-less communities. According to Zaki al-Arsuzi, a co-founder of the Ba'ath Party, the reforms would "liberate 75 percent of the Syrian population and prepare them to be citizens qualified to participate in the building of the state".[19]

It has been argued that the land reform represented work by the 'socialist government', however, by 1984 the private sector controlled 74 percent of Syria's arable land.[20] This questions both Ba'ath claims of commitment to the redistribution of land to the majority of peasants as well as the state government being socialist (if it allowed the majority of land to be owned in the private sector how could it truly be socialist?). Hinnebusch argued that the reforms were a way of galvanising support from the large rural population: "they [Ba'ath Party members] used the implementation of agrarian reform to win over and organise peasants and curb traditional power in the countryside".[21] To this extent the reforms succeeded and resulted with an increase in Ba'ath party membership. They also prevented political threat emerging from rural areas by bringing the rural population into the system as supporters.

South Asia edit

Afghanistan edit

Afghanistan has had a couple of attempts at land reform.

In 1975, the Republic of Afghanistan under President Mohammad Daoud Khan responded to the inequities of the existing land tenure conditions by issuing a Land Reform Law. It limited individual holdings to a maximum of 20 hectares of irrigated, double-cropped land. Larger holdings were allowed for less productive land. The government was to expropriate all surplus land and pay compensation. To prevent the proliferation of small, uneconomic holdings, priority for redistributed lands was to be given to neighboring farmers with two hectares or less. Landless sharecroppers, laborers, tenants, and nomads had next priority. Despite the government's rhetorical commitment to land reform, the program was quickly postponed. Because the government's landholding limits applied to families, not individuals, wealthy families avoided expropriation by dividing their lands nominally between family members. The high ceilings for landholdings restricted the amount of land actually subject to redistribution. Finally, the government lacked the technical data and organizational bodies to pursue the program after it was announced.

After the 1978 Saur Revolution, the communist Peoples Democratic Party of Afghanistan (PDPA) issued Decree No. 6, which canceled gerau and other mortgage debts of agricultural laborers, tenants, and small landowners with less than two hectares of land. The cancellation applied only to debts contracted before 1973. The Decree No. 8 of November 1978 made new landholdings from the 20 hectares of prime irrigated land in the 1975 law to just six hectares. It divided all land into seven classes and again allowed for larger holdings of less productive land. There was no compensation for government-expropriated surplus land and it established categories of farmers who had priority for redistributed land; sharecroppers already working on the land had highest priority.[22][23]

India edit

Under the British occupation, the land system in India has been feudalist, with few absentee landlords holding most of the lands and claiming high rents from poor peasants. The demand for a land reform was a major theme in the demand for independence. After independence, the different states in India gradually started a land reform process in four main categories: abolition of intermediaries (rent collectors under the pre-Independence land revenue system); tenancy regulation (to improve the contractual terms including security of tenure); a ceiling on landholdings (to redistribute surplus land to the landless); and attempts to consolidate disparate landholdings. The extent and success of these reforms varied greatly between the different states of India.

Sri Lanka edit

In 1972, the Government of Sirimavo Bandaranaike, through the Land Reform Act of No. 01 of 1972, imposed a ceiling of twenty hectares on privately owned land and sought to distribute lands in excess of the ceiling for the benefit of landless peasants. Private lands that were in excess were vested in under the Land Reform Commission with its former owners paid a compensation which came to a nominal value based on government valuations that were below market rates. Both land owned by public companies and paddy lands under ten hectares in extent were exempted from this ceiling. Between 1972 and 1974, the Land Reform Commission took over nearly 228,000 hectares. In 1975 the Land Reform (Amendment) Law brought over 169,000 hectares of plantations owned by companies (including British-owned companies) under state control.[24] Following the second wave of land reclamations, the government gained control of vast amounts of plantation estates that produced the main exports of the country, mainly the tea industry. Most of the estates vested to the state were allocated to the Sri Lanka State Plantations Corporation, the Janatha Estate Development Board (People's Estate Development Board) and the USAWASAMA (Upcountry Cooperative Estate Development Board). In the years following these land reforms, the production of the key export crops which Sri Lanka depended on for the in follow of foreign currency dropped.[25] The productivity and production of these estates declined due to mismanagement and lack of investments, becoming a burden on the General Treasury, which itself had heavily taxed its profits reducing investments and welfare of the workers. In the 1980's and 1990's these estates had been privatized.[26]

Europe edit

Albania edit

Albania has gone through three waves of land reform since the end of World War II: in 1946, the land in estates and large farms was expropriated by the communist People's Republic of Albania and redistributed among small peasants; in the 1950s, the land was reorganized into large-scale collective farms; and after 1991, the land was again redistributed among private smallholders.[citation needed]

Czechoslovakia edit

In 1918, all land owned by Habsburgs was confiscated. In 1919, the Land Reform Act forced large landholders - mostly nobility and church - to sell their land to the state which in turn sold it to the peasants. This concerned arable land only, forests, vineyards, and pastures were excluded. During the Holocaust in Slovakia, the Land Reform Act of February 1940 confiscated and nationalized 101,423 hectares (250,620 acres) of land owned by 4,943 Jews.[27]

Estonia edit

Estonia has witnessed two periods of land reform in 1919 and 1991 which occurred very shortly after the declaration of Estonian independence and the restoration of independence respectively. The act of 1919 was primarily concerned with the transferral of land ownership from Baltic Germans to ethnic Estonians. The 1991 act was instead aimed at the transfer of land ownership from the state (having been nationalised under Soviet occupation) to private individuals based on historic land ownership in 1940 as well as the protection of the legal rights of the present users of land.

Finland edit

In the general reparcelling out of land, begun in 1757 when Finland was a part of the Swedish Empire, the medieval model of all fields consisting of numerous strips, each belonging to a farm, was replaced by a model of fields and forest areas each belonging to a single farm.[28] In the further reparcellings, which started in 1848 when Finland was part of the Russian Empire, the idea of concentrating all the land in a farm to a single piece of real estate was reinforced. In these reparcelling processes, the land is redistributed in direct proportion to earlier prescription.[29] Both the general reparcelling and the further reparcelling processes are still active in some parts of the country, and a new reparcelling can be initiated when the local need for such reparcelling arises.[30] After the Finnish Civil War, when Finland had become independent, a series of land reforms followed. These included the compensated transfer of lease-holdings (torppa) to the leasers and prohibition of forestry companies to acquire land. The reforms led to greater economic equality.[31]

After the Second World War, Karelians evacuated from areas ceded to the Soviet Union were given land in remaining Finnish areas, taken from public and private holdings with less than full compensation to the previous owners. Also the war veterans, and their widows benefited from these allotments. In addition, land could be provided to farms considered too small. The land could be acquired either via a voluntary purchase by the state or via expropriation. As a result of post-WWII land reform, 30,000 new farms were established, 33,000 small farms received more land and 67,000 families received either a plot for a single-family home or a homestead with some arable land.[32]

Germany edit

 
Population and urban population of Germany (1700 to 1950)

Land reform in Germany can be seen as three separate but connected movements that build on each other chronologically. Peasants were first liberated from serfdom in the Prussian reforms from 1763 until 1859. Following rapid urbanization in Europe, several influential social economists such as Karl Marx, Friedrich Engels, Karl Kautsky and Eduard Bernstein began to discuss land reforms in the 1830s. Their theories inspired private settlements and official government programms for the so called Binnenkolonisierung (interior colonization), whereby wasteland could be transformed into homesteads for the poor. Finally, land was collectivized under the East German Bodenreform between 1956 and 1975 but West German agriculture remained largely unchanged.

Ireland edit

At the 19th century, most of the land in Ireland belonged to large landowners, most of them of English origin. Most of the Irish population were tenants, having few rights and forced to pay high rents. This situation was a contributory factor to the Great Irish Famine of 1845-1852 and the main cause of the Land Wars of 1870s-1890s.[33]

The governments of the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Ireland responded to the agitations in Ireland with a series of land acts, beginning with the Landlord and Tenant (Ireland) Act 1870 (initiated by prime minister William Ewart Gladstone), followed by further five land acts overseen by a Land Commission, prior to independence in 1922, by which time over 90% of lands had transferred from landlords to their former tenant farmers on negotiated terms with funding provided by the UK government.[34]

Italy edit

Land reform has been a long-standing and widespread problem before the 20th century, especially in Southern Italy. Despite the vain attempts of the governments to redistribute the land in Southern Italy (the so-called Mezzogiorno), from the pragmatic decree De administratione Universitatum (1792) of Ferdinand I of the Two Sicilies to the law Leggi eversive delle feudalità (which literally means "laws abolishing feudalism") in 1806–1808, enacted by Joseph Bonaparte, the issue remained largely unsolved, mainly because of the strenuous opposition of the great landowners, unwilling to lose their privileges and to allow the emancipation of the peasant class. Even with the Unification of Italy, despite the promises of the abolition of the so-called latifondi ("large estates"), the problem remained unsolved. Southern Italy's big landowners, which had been loyal to the Bourbons until the 1860, actively contributed to the unification of Italy in order to not lose its prestige, and expropriating estates from them would have implied, for the Kingdom of Italy (1861-1946), to have a powerful enemy.[35] Southern Italy's peasants, disappointed and irritated, rebelled and provoked a bloody civil war, known as Post-Unification Brigandage.

The first effective land reform was carried out in 1950, right after the birth of the Italian Republic. Italian Parliament passed the decree legge stralcio n. 841 del 21 ottobre 1950, which provided the legal basis for land expropriation and redistribution. The redistribution occurred over a longer period of time, about 10–20 years.

The decree, financed in part with the funds of Marshall Plan, launched by the United States in 1947, but also opposed by conservative members of the American administration[36] probably was, according to some scholars, the most important reform of the aftermath of World War II.[37] The decree provided that the land had to be distributed to peasants through compulsory purchase, thus turning them into small entrepreneurs no longer subjected to large landowners. On one side, the reform had a positive outcome to the population, but, on the other side, it also considerably reduced Italian farms size, reducing the chances for bigger companies to grow. However, this drawback was attenuated and, in some cases, eliminated by implementing forms of cooperation. Agricultural cooperatives started to spread, and, since then, agriculture turned into an entrepreneurial business which could expand, plan its production and centralize the sale of products.

After the land reform of 1950, large estates (latifondi) in some regions of Italy by law cannot be bigger than 300 ha (740 acres).[38] Before the 1950, large estates were widespread, especially in Southern Italy. Nowadays large estate aren't present anymore on Italy's territory.[citation needed] For example, in Sicily before the 1950, estates larger than 500 ha (1,200 acres) later averaged at about 230 ha (570 acres).[39] Moreover, 20.6 percent of the island's land was owned by only 282 big landowners.[40] In the region Abruzzo, large estates were also widespread. The most notable case is perhaps the estate of the Torlonia family, which owned large estates near Piana del Fucino; its size was more than 14,000 ha (35,000 acres), and it was redistributed to 5,000 Italian families of landless farmers.[41]

A 2022 study found that the post-WWII land reform "fueled comparative underdevelopment and precarity locally over the long term. Several related mechanisms delayed development in land reform zones: a slower transition out of agriculture, lower labor mobility, and an aging demographic."[42]

Russia and the Soviet Union edit

The Emancipation reform of 1861, effected during the reign of Alexander II of Russia, abolished serfdom throughout the Russian Empire. More than 23 million people received their liberty. Serfs were granted the full rights of free citizens, gaining the rights to marry without having to gain consent, to own property and to own a business. The Manifesto prescribed that peasants would be able to buy the land from the landlords.

Until the beginning of the 20th century, the vast majority of Russian peasants held their land in communal ownership within peasant communities called mirs, which acted as village governments and cooperatives. Arable land was divided in sections based on soil quality and distance from the village. Each household had the right to claim one or more strips from each section depending on the number of adults in the household. This communal system was abolished in 1906 by the capitalist-oriented Stolypin reforms. The reforms introduced the unconditional right of individual landownership. They encouraged peasants to buy their share of the community lands, leave the communities and settle in privately owned settlements called Khutors. By 1910 the share of private settlements among all rural households in the European Russia was estimated at 10.5%.

The Stolypin reforms and the majority of their benefits were reversed after the October Revolution of 1917. The Decree on Land, issued by Vladimir Lenin's new Bolshevik government, and the "Fundamental Law of Land Socialization" of 1918, decreed that private ownership of land is totally abolished - land may not be sold, purchased, leased, mortgaged, or otherwise alienated. All land, whether state, crown, monastery, church, factory, entailed, private, public, peasant, etc., shall be confiscated without compensation and become the property of the whole people, and pass into the use of all those who cultivate it. These decrees were superseded by the 1922 Land Code of the Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic. After the universal agricultural collectivization, land codes of the Soviet republics lost their significance. See Agriculture in the Soviet Union.

After winning World War II and occupying much of Central and Eastern Europe, the Soviet Union implemented similar collectivization policies in its new satellite states in the Eastern Bloc.[43]

After the dissolution of the Soviet Union, a new land code was enacted, allowing private land ownership.

Latvia edit

The Latvian Land Reform of 1920 was a land reform act expropriating land under the first Republic of Latvia in 1920 (during the Latvian War of Independence shortly after independence). The agrarian reform law of 1920 sought to transfer most of the land from Baltic German nobles to Latvian farmers. On September 16, 1920 Constitutional Assembly of Latvia passed the law of the Land reform, which would break up large landholdings and redistribute land to those peasants who worked it and to the newly created Latvian State Land Fund.[44]

Sweden edit

In 1757, the general reparcelling out of land began. In this process, the medieval principle of dividing all the fields in a village into strips, each belonging to a farm, was changed into a principle of each farm consisting of a few relatively large areas of land. The land was redistributed in proportion to earlier possession of land, while uninhabited forests far from villages were socialized.

In the 20th century, Sweden, almost non-violently, arrived at regulating the length minimum of tenant farming contracts at 25 years.

Ukraine edit

In Ukraine a debate around the land reform has lasted for more than 20 years and it is still not over.

— Olena Bogdan, 2011[45]

Ukraine has nearly as much farmland as France and Germany combined.[46] Before the dissolution of the Soviet Union in December 1991, Ukrainian farmers worked on collective farms and a free market had only existed for around a year.[47][48] In the aftermath of the dissolution, more than 6 million Ukrainians received plots of arable land, getting between two and three hectares each. In 2001, a ban was imposed on sales of farmland, in order to deter speculation. The law also prevented the farmers from using farmland as collateral for bank loans. The 2001 law has also prevented the government from selling millions of additional hectares. Only five other countries in the world, among them China and North Korea,[49][50] have maintained similar restrictions on the sale of private agricultural land.[51][52]

The European Court for Human Rights ruled in the May 2018 judgement of Zelenchuk and Tsytsyura v. Ukraine that the ban violates the Ukrainian Constitution by preventing owners from fully exercising their property rights.[52] The Groysman Government pledged in July 2017 to lift the ban on sales of farmland.[53] According to a 2020 estimate of the World Bank a land-reform programme could bring an increase up to 1.5% in GDP.[54] The party Batkivshchyna pledged in 2018 to initiate a nationwide referendum to stop the lifting of the ban on sales of farmland.[55]

In July 2019, President Volodymyr Zelenskyy wanted the reforms of the land laws to pass before 2020.[56][need quotation to verify][57][need quotation to verify] A brawl broke out in the Verkhovna Rada (Ukraine's parliament) on 6 February 2020 over the bill.[58] The Verkhovna Rada terminated the Honcharuk Government on 5 March 2020 and pledged the passage of legislation sought by the International Monetary Fund to lift the ban on sales of agricultural land.[59] The Honcharuk Government had appeared to be too weak to pass the necessary reforms through the Verkhovna Rada during several weeks of protest by agriculturalists, even in spite of Zelenskyy's personal appearances.[51]

In March 2020, the IMF was still concerned about the pace of land reforms.[60] Ukraine in 2020 needed to repay $17 billion of foreign loans and the International Monetary Fund pressured the government to enact laws which would hasten land reform in exchange for a $5.5 billion loan-package.[61] On 31 March 2020, the Verkhovna Rada adopted a law introducing amendments on the sale of agricultural land.[62] Per the law, the moratorium on the sale of agricultural land was lifted on 1 July 2021.[62] From July 2021 until 1 January 2024, however, no more than 100 hectares can be purchased per person and only individuals living in Ukraine will be able to buy land.[62][63]

United Kingdom edit

Advocates of land reform in Britain have included the 17th-century Diggers, John Stuart Mill, Alfred Russel Wallace, and Jesse Collings. Currently[when?] the Labour Land Campaign[64] promotes the case for a land value tax, one of the results of which would be some land reform. The Green Party of England and Wales[65][66] and the Scottish Green Party support land value tax. Currently aristocrats still own a third of England and Wales.[67]

Scotland edit

In the 21st century, land reform in Scotland has focused on the abolition and modernisation of Scotland's antiquated feudal land tenure system, security of tenure for crofters and decentralisation of Scotland's highly concentrated private land ownership.[68] Scotland's land reform is distinct from other contemporary land reforms in its focus on community land ownership[69] ,[70] with the Land Reform (Scotland) Acts of 2003 and 2016 establishing the Community Right to Buy, allowing rural and urban communities first right of refusal to purchase local land when it comes up for sale. Crofting communities are granted a similar Right to Buy though they do not require a willing seller to buy out local crofting land.[71] Under the Community Empowerment (Scotland) Act 2015 and Land Reform (Scotland) Act 2016, Scottish ministers can grant a compulsory sale order for vacant or derelict private land or land which, if owned by the local community, could further sustainable development.[72][73]

Africa edit

Ethiopia edit

Historically, Ethiopia was divided into the northern highlands, which constituted the core of the old Christian kingdom, and the southern highlands, most of which were brought under imperial rule by conquest. In the northern regions, the major form of ownership was a type of communal system known as rist. According to this system, all descendants of an individual founder were entitled to a share, and individuals had the right to use a plot of family land. Rist was hereditary, inalienable, and inviolable. No user of any piece of land could sell his or her share outside the family or mortgage or bequeath his or her share as a gift, as the land belonged not to the individual but to the descent group. Most peasants in the northern highlands held at least some rist land. Absentee landlordism was rare, and landless tenants were estimated at only about 20% of holdings. On the contrary, in the southern provinces, few farmers owned the land on which they worked. After the conquest, officials divided southern land equally among the state, the church, and the indigenous population. Tenancy in the southern provinces ranged between 65% and 80% of the holdings, and tenant payments to landowners averaged as high as 50% of the produce. In the Eastern Lowland periphery and the Great Rift Valley, most land were used for grazing. The pastoral social structure is based on a kinship system with strong interclan connections; grazing and water rights are regulated by custom.

Beginning in the 1950s, the government tried to modernize the agriculture by granting large tracts of traditional grazing lands to large corporations and converting them into large-scale commercial farms. In the north and south, peasant farmers lacked the means to improve production because of the fragmentation of holdings, a lack of credit, and the absence of modern facilities. Particularly in the south, the insecurity of tenure and high rents killed the peasants' incentive to improve production. Further, those attempts by the Imperial government to improve the peasant's title to their land were often met with suspicion. By the mid-1960s, many sectors of Ethiopian society favored land reform. University students led the land reform movement and campaigned against the government's reluctance to introduce land reform programs and the lack of commitment to integrated rural development.

In 1974, the socialist Derg government rose to power, and on March 4, 1975, the Derg announced its land reform program. The government nationalized rural land without compensation, abolished tenancy, forbade the hiring of wage labor on private farms, ordered all commercial farms to remain under state control, and granted each peasant family so-called "possessing rights" to a plot of land not to exceed ten hectares. The Ethiopian Orthodox Church lost all its land. Although the Derg gained little respect during its rule, this reform resulted in a rare show of support for the junta.

Tenant farmers in southern Ethiopia welcomed the land reform, but in the northern highlands many people resisted land reform and perceived it as an attack on their rights to rist land. The lowland peripheries were only slightly affected by the reforms.

The land reform destroyed the feudal order. It changed landowning patterns – particularly in the south – in favor of peasants and small landowners. It also provided the opportunity for peasants to participate in local matters by permitting them to form associations.

Kenya edit

The colonial administration in Kenya implemented a land documentation system in the early 1900s. In the 1970s, politicians engaged in extensive sales and exploitation of fraudulent land documents. By the late 1990s, the land documentation system had fallen into disrepute due to extensive fraud.[74]

Two land reforms occurred amid the Mau Mau uprising. The first, in the mid-1950s, allowed Africans to consolidate and gain individual legal titles to their land. The second enabled Africans to buy land from Europeans, many of whom sought to liquidate their holdings in Kenya prior to Kenyan independence.[75]

In the 1960s, president Jomo Kenyatta launched a peaceful land reform program based on "willing buyer-willing seller". It was funded by the United Kingdom, the former colonial power.

In 2006, president Mwai Kibaki said it will repossess all land owned by "absentee landlords" in the coastal strip and redistribute it to squatters.[76]

A 2023 study found that over the course of independent Kenyan history, democratic governments engaged in greater formalization of land rights than autocratic regimes and that democratic governments tended to formalize land rights to gain the support of pivotal swing voters.[77]

Namibia edit

Namibia's colonial past had resulted in substantial land inequality[78] where about 20% of the population (mostly white settlers) owned about 75 percent of all the land.[79]

In 1990, shortly after Namibia achieved independence from South Africa, its first president Sam Nujoma initiated a plan for land reform, in which land would be redistributed from whites to blacks. Legislation passed in September 1994, with a compulsory, compensated approach.[80] The land reform has been slow, mainly because Namibia's constitution only allows land to be bought from farmers willing to sell. Also, the price of land is very high in Namibia, which further complicates the matter.

By 2007, some 12% of the total commercial farmland in the country was taken away from white Namibian farmers and given to black citizens.

South Africa edit

The Natives' Land Act of 1913 "prohibited the establishment of new farming operations, sharecropping or cash rentals by blacks outside of the reserves"[81] where they were forced to live.

In 1991, after a long anti-apartheid struggle led by the African National Congress, State President F. W. de Klerk declared the repeal of several apartheid rules, particularly: the Population Registration Act, the Group Areas Act, and the Natives' Land Act. A catch-all Abolition of Racially Based Land Measures Act was passed.[82] These measures ensured no one could claim, or be deprived of, any land rights on the basis of race.

In 1994, shortly after the African National Congress came to power in South Africa in the first general election, it initiated a land reform process focused on three areas: restitution, land tenure reform and land redistribution.[81][83] Restitution, where the government compensates (monetary) individuals who had been forcefully removed, has been very unsuccessful and the policy has now shifted to redistribution.

Initially, land was bought from its owners (willing seller) by the government (willing buyer) and redistributed, in order to maintain public confidence in the land market.[81] This system has proved to be very difficult to implement, because many owners do not actually see the land they are purchasing and are not involved in the important decisions made at the beginning of the purchase and negotiation.

In 2000 the South African Government decided to review and change the redistribution and tenure process to a more decentralized and area based planning process. The idea is to have local integrated development plans in 47 districts.[84]

Zimbabwe edit

The 1930 Land Apportionment Act restricted the areas of Zimbabwe, then known as Southern Rhodesia, where black people could legally purchase land. Large segments of the country were set aside for the exclusive ownership of the white minority.[85]

By 1979, when Zimbabwe gained independence, 46.5% of the country's arable land was owned by around 6,000 commercial farmers,[86] and white farmers, who made up less than 1% of the population, owned 70% of the best farming land.[87]

As part of the Lancaster House Agreement of 1979, president Robert Mugabe initiated a "willing buyer, willing seller" plan, in which white land-owners were encouraged to sell their lands to the government, with partial funding from Britain.[88] Around 71,000 families (perhaps 500,000 people) settled on 3.5 million hectares of former white-owned land under this programme, which was described by "The Economist" in 1989 as "perhaps the most successful aid programme in Africa".[89]

The 1992 Land Acquisition Act was enacted to speed up the land reform process by removing the "willing seller, willing buyer" clause, limiting the size of farms and introducing a land tax (although the tax was never implemented.)[90] The Act empowered the government to buy land compulsorily for redistribution, and a fair compensation was to be paid for land acquired. Landowners could challenge in court the price set by the acquiring authority. Opposition by landowners increased throughout the period of 1992 to 1997. In the 1990s, less than 1 million hectares (2.47 million acres) were acquired, and fewer than 20,000 families were resettled. Much of the land acquired during what has become known as "phase one" of land reform was of poor quality, according to Human Rights Watch. Only 19 percent of the almost 3.5 million hectares (8.65 million acres) of resettled land was considered prime, or farmable.

In 1997, the new British government, led by Tony Blair, unilaterally stopped funding the "willing buyer, willing seller" land reform programme. Britain's ruling Labour Party felt no obligation to continue paying white farmers compensation.

In 2000, a referendum on constitutional amendments was held. The proposed amendments called for a "fast track" land reform and allowed the government to confiscate white-owned land for redistribution to black farmers without compensation. The motion failed with 55% of participants against the referendum.[91] However, self-styled "war veterans", led by Chenjerai Hunzvi, began invading white-owned farms. Those who did not leave voluntarily were often tortured and sometimes killed.[92] On 6 April 2000, Parliament pushed through an amendment, taken word for word from the draft constitution that was rejected by voters, allowing the seizure of white-owned farmlands without due reimbursement or payment.[93] In this first wave of farm invasions, a total of 110,000 square kilometres of land had been seized.

Parliament, dominated by Zanu-PF, passed a constitutional amendment, signed into law on 12 September 2005, that nationalised farmland acquired through the "Fast Track" process and deprived original landowners of the right to challenge in court the government's decision to expropriate their land.[94] The Supreme Court of Zimbabwe ruled against legal challenges to this amendment.[95]

During the "fast track", many parcels of land came under the control of people close to the government. The several forms of forcible change in management caused a severe drop in production and other economic disruptions.

North America edit

Canada edit

A land reform was carried out as part of Prince Edward Island's agreement to join the Canadian Confederation in 1873. Most of the land was owned by absentee landlords in England, and as part of the deal Canada was to buy all the land and give it to the farmers.

United States edit

Following the American Civil War, many African Americans and Union Army officials considered land reform vital. The downfall of the Confederacy and the abolition of slavery with the Thirteenth Amendment emancipated millions, but few former slaves had the means to exercise real autonomy. Land, even at depressed post-war prices, was difficult for African Americans to procure.[96] At the same time, with southern wealth the result of centuries of forced labor, blacks nationwide called for property on the basis of just reparations.[97] Politically, redistribution carried the support of Radical Republicans.[98] But opposing any grants to blacks were southern Democrats, along with President Andrew Johnson's administration committed to 'restoration'.[99][100] Given national divisions, reform efforts were varied but short-lived.

Many African Americans believed property was critical to erasing slave-oriented social order.[101] In addition to speaking out, some demanded plots and moved into their master's plantation homes by force.[102] Others bought land collectively, or squatted on what was undeveloped.[103] Throughout war and Reconstruction, the presence of Federal troops provided a platform for agricultural policy. In 1865, William Tecumseh Sherman issued Field Order 15, taking coastal land in South Carolina, Georgia and Florida, and dividing it into 40-acre plots for black settlement, hence the term "40 acres and a mule".[104]

In March, Congress established the Freedmen’s Bureau, whose commissioner had authority to redistribute confiscated or abandoned southern land.[105] The Bureau held 850,000 acres (3,400 km2), and key directors pushed for its settling with former slaves. When President Johnson began to pardon Confederates and restore their property, Commissioner Oliver O. Howard issued Circular 13. The order instructed agents to establish 40-acre parcels with haste. Johnson rescinded the order, and an overwhelming majority of Bureau land returned to its previous owners.[106]

The final reform attempts of Reconstruction occurred within state governments. In South Carolina, a land commission was established, which purchased property and sold it on long-term credit.[107] Other state Republicans utilized new tax systems, penalizing large estates, to seize and divide land and stimulate black ownership. This indirect method achieved little, as taxes were repaid and lands were reclaimed. Of property not redeemed, much was exploited by investors.[108]

Radicals began to fall even earlier, with the failure of Johnson's impeachment. Liberal Republicans, eroding the era's political landscape, called for an immediate end to “black barbarism”.[109][110] White supremacist violence and the Long Depression[111] weakened Reconstruction to the breaking point. With the Compromise of 1877, it was finished.[112]

In the 19th century, Native American tribes owned about 138 million acres (560,000 km2) of land in the USA. Land was considered the property of the whole tribe, which used it to cater to the needs of the individual tribe members. This approach to land ownership was different than the white European approach, which regarded land as private property of individuals.[citation needed]

Many US politicians[who?] believed it was important to assimilate Native Americans into white American culture, and thus have their lands open for commerce and development. The Dawes Act (also known as the General Allotment Act or the Dawes Severalty Act), adopted by Congress in 1887, authorized the President of the United States to survey Native American tribal land and divide it into allotments for individual Indians. Those who accepted allotments and lived separately from the tribe would be granted United States citizenship. The Dawes Act was amended in 1891, and again in 1906 by the Burke Act.

Through the Dawes Act, many Indians received private title to a land-plot, but most of the Indian lands were considered "surplus", and put to sale to white European settlers. Thus, the total amount of land owned by Indians decreased to only 48 million acres (190,000 km2) in 1934.[citation needed]

Most tribal land still owned by ethnic Indians was recollectivized in 1934.

East Asia edit

Mainland China edit

Since the fall of the Qing dynasty in the 1911 Revolution, China has been through a series of land reform programs. The founder of the Nationalist Party, Sun Yat-sen, advocated a "land to the tiller" program of equal distribution of land. which was partly implemented by the Nationalist government under Chiang Kai-shek. In the 1940s, the Sino-American Joint Commission on Rural Reconstruction, funded with American money, with the support of the national government, carried out land reform and community action programs in several provinces.

In October 1947, two years before the foundation of the People's Republic of China (PRC), the Chinese Communist Party launched land reform campaigns that established control in North China villages.

In the mid-1950s, a second land reform during the Great Leap Forward compelled individual farmers to join collectives, which, in turn, were grouped into People's communes with centrally controlled property rights and an egalitarian principle of distribution. This policy was generally a failure in terms of production.[113] The PRC reversed this policy in 1962 through the proclamation of the Sixty Articles. As a result, the ownership of the basic means of production was divided into three levels with collective land ownership vested in the production team (see also Ho [2001]).

A third land reform beginning in the late 1970s re-introduced the family-based contract system known as the Household Responsibility System, was followed by a period of stagnation. Chen, Wang, and Davis [1998] suggest that the stagnation was due, in part, to a system of periodic redistributions that encouraged over-exploitation rather than private capital investment in future productivity.[113] However, although land use rights were returned to individual farmers, collective land ownership was left undefined after the disbandment of the People's Communes.

Since 1983, China has launched a series of land policy reforms to improve land-use efficiency, to rationalize land allocation, to enhance land management, and to coordinate urban and rural development. These land policy reforms have yielded positive impacts on urban land use as well as negative socioeconomic consequences. On the positive side, they have contributed to emerging land markets, increased government revenue for the financing of massive infrastructure projects and provision of public goods, and improved the rationalization of land use. On the negative side, problems such as loss of social equity, socioeconomic conflicts, and government corruption have emerged.[114]

Since 1998 China is in the midst of drafting the new Property Law which is the first piece of national legislation that will define the land ownership structure in China for years to come. The Property Law forms the basis for China's future land policy of establishing a system of freehold, rather than of private ownership (see also Ho, [2005]).

Taiwan edit

In the 1950s, after the Kuomintang retreat to Taiwan, land reform and community development was carried out by the Sino-American Joint Commission on Rural Reconstruction. This course of action was made attractive, in part, by the fact that many of the large landowners were Japanese who had fled, and the other large landowners were compensated with Japanese commercial and industrial properties seized after Taiwan reverted from Japanese rule in 1945. The land program succeeded also because the Kuomintang were mostly from the mainland and had few ties to the remaining indigenous landowners.

Japan edit

The first land reform in recent history, called the Land Tax Reform or chisokaisei (地租改正), passed in 1873, six years after the Meiji Restoration. It established the right of private land ownership in Japan for the first time and was a major restructuring of the previous land taxation system.

The government initially ordered individual farmers to measure the plots of their land themselves, calculate their taxes, and submit the results to local tax officials. However, difficulties arose with the honesty of the measuring system and the government responded by forcefully changing land values to meet the set amount if self-reported values did not meet projected values. This caused widespread resentment among farmers and several large-scale riots, causing the government to lower the tax rate from 3% to 2.5%. The department continued its aggressive taxation until 1878, but the strictness of rules gradually decreased as it became clear that required amounts would be met. By 1880, seven years after the start of the land reforms, the new system had been completely implemented.

Private land ownership was recognized for the first time in Japan with the issuing of land titles. Previously, individual farmers were merely borrowing the land from feudal lords, who in turn were borrowing the land from the emperor. The reform abolished this archaic system of land ownership, and began to allow landowners to use their property as a financial asset in collateral or other investment. This law was one of the first steps towards the development of capitalism in Japan, paralleling the English (and later United Kingdom) statute Quia Emptores enacted several centuries earlier.

Another major land reform was carried out in 1947, during the occupied era after World War II, under instructions of the Supreme Commander of the Allied Powers based on a proposal from the Japanese government which had been prepared before the defeat of the Greater Japanese Empire. This last reform is also called Nōchi-kaihō (農地解放, emancipation of farming land).

Between 1947 and 1949, approximately 5,800,000 acres (23,000 km2) of land (approximately 38% of Japan's cultivated land) was purchased from the landlords under the reform program and re-sold at extremely low prices (after inflation) to the farmers who worked them. By 1950, three million peasants had acquired land, dismantling a power structure that the landlords had long dominated.[115]

South Korea edit

From 1945 to 1950, United States Army Military Government in Korea and First Republic of Korea authorities carried out a land reform that retained the institution of private property. They confiscated and redistributed all land held by the Japanese colonial government, Japanese companies, and individual Japanese colonists. The Korean government carried out a reform whereby Koreans with large landholdings were obliged to divest most of their land. A new class of independent, family proprietors was created.

North Korea edit

By the end of the Second World War, 58% of arable land in North Korea was privately owned by Japanese colonists and Korean feudal landlords comprising 4% of the population. On March 5, 1946, the North Korean Provisional People’s Committee enacted the 1946 Land Reform Law whereby both Japanese colonists would have their entire estate expropriated and Korean landlords in possession of more than 50,000 square meters of land would have their estates expropriated and distributed to existing tenant farmers for free, abolishing the existing tenant farming system. In just one month, the Provisional People's Committee of North Korea and the Workers' Party of North Korea led land reform by organizing 90,697 members into 11,500 farming committees. They organized 210,000 farmers into self-defense forces who supported the work of the farming committees. During three weeks of land reform, 98 percent of confiscated land was distributed to farmers who in turn became the possessors of up to 13,200 square meters of land and over one million hectares of land were expropriated. The early land reform may have been partially intended to prepare for the Korean War by improving the South Korean public's perception of the Communist government in the north as well as by providing large stockpiles of food.[116]

During the 1954-58 transition period, farm holdings went through three progressively collective phases: permanent mutual aid teams; semisocialist cooperatives; and complete socialist cooperatives. In the final stage, all land and farm implements were owned collectively by the members of each cooperative. The pace of collectivization quickened during 1956, and by the end of that year, about 80% of all farmland was cooperatively owned. By August 1958, more than 13,300 cooperatives with an average of eighty households and 130 hectares of land dotted the countryside. In October 1958, the Workers' Party of Korea government increased the size of the average cooperative to 300 households managing 500 hectares of land through consolidation of all farms in each village.[117][118]

Southeast Asia edit

Cambodia edit

Hun Sen implemented land reform, the "leopard skin land reform", in Cambodia.[119] Hun Sen's government has been responsible for leasing 45% of the total landmass in Cambodia—primarily to foreign investors—in the years 2007–08, threatening more than 150,000 Cambodians with eviction. Parts of the concessions are protected wildlife areas or national parks and have driven deforestation across the country.[120][121][122][123] As of 2015, Cambodia had one of the highest rates of forest loss in the world.[124] The land sales have been perceived by observers as government corruption and have resulted in thousands of citizens being forcibly evicted.[125][126] According to Alice Beban, the land reform strengthened patronage politics in Cambodia and did not enable land tenure security.[119]

Philippines edit

During the Macapagal administration in the early 1960s, a limited land reform program was initiated in Central Luzon covering rice fields.

During the martial law era of the Ferdinand Marcos Administration, Presidential Decree 27, signed in 1972, instituted a land reform program covering less than 14% of cultivated lands.[127] Rice and corn production under this land reform program was supported by the Marcos Administration with land distribution and financing program known as the Masagana 99 and other production loans that briefly increased in rice and corn production. Costly subsidies and a faulty credit scheme led to the program benefiting only 3.7% of the country's small rice farmers by 1980.[128][129] General Order 47 and Presidential Decree 472 were signed in 1974 to launch corporate farming programs that undermined the land reform program.[127]

The Corazon Aquino Administration in the mid-1980s instituted a very controversial land reform known as the Comprehensive Agrarian Reform Program (CARP), which covered all agricultural lands. The program led to rice shortages in the succeeding years and lasted for 20 years without accomplishing the goal of land distribution. The program caused entrepreneurs to stay away from agriculture and a number of productive farmers left the farming sector. The CARP was a monumental failure in terms of cost to the government and the landowners whose lands were subjective to legal landgrabbing by the government. CARP expired at the end of December 2008.[130]

Thailand edit

Thailand first spoke of land reform after the Siamese revolution of 1932 by Pridi Banomyong,[131] but was seen as a communist idea. And it was mentioned again after the 1973 Thai popular uprising, resulting in the drafting and promulgation the Agricultural Land Reform Act of 1975[132] and the Agricultural Land Reform Office was established on March 6, 1975. under the Ministry of Agriculture and Cooperatives.

Vietnam edit

In the years after World War II, land redistribution to poor and landless peasants was initiated by the communist Viet Minh insurgents in areas which they controlled. After the partition of the country into two parts (North Vietnam and South Vietnam) under the Geneva Accords, the communist land reform (1953–1956) redistributed land to more than 2 million poor peasants, but at a cost of thousands, possibly tens of thousands of lives[133] and contributed to the exodus of up to 1 million people from the North to the South in 1954 and 1955.[citation needed]. The land reform campaign was accompanied by large-scale repression and excesses.[134] some of which were subsequently criticized within the ruling Workers' Party of North Vietnam itself.[134][135][136]

South Vietnam made several further attempts in the post-Diem years, the most ambitious being the Land to the Tiller program instituted in 1970 by President Nguyen Van Thieu. This limited individuals to 15 hectares, compensated the owners of expropriated tracts, and extended legal title to peasants who in areas under control of the South Vietnamese government to whom had land had previously been distributed by the Viet Cong.

Summary table edit

The following table summarizes many land reforms that are not mentioned in this page. The color in the "Year" column is darker for earlier periods and brighter for later periods.

Region/place Reformer Year Ideology / motivations Actions Outcomes
Middle East: Egypt Joseph −1500 Monarchism
  • Nationalization
  • Joseph bought all lands for Pharaoh
Egyptian peasants became serfs of Pharaoh
Middle East: Egypt Bakenranef −720 Social Justice
  • Help the peasants
  • Freedom to peasants
  • Land alienability
  • Debt annulment
Bakenranef murdered, reforms undone
Europe: Greece / Athens Solon −575 Stabilization
  • Help the poor
  • Prevent an uprising
  • Freedom to peasants
  • Debt annulment
  • Forbid slavery of Athenians
poverty somewhat alleviated
Europe: Greece / Athens Peisistratos −560 Centralization
  • Help the poor
  • strengthening the tyrant
  • Land redistribution from rich to poor
Athenian aristocracy weakened, poverty somewhat reduced
Europe: Greece / Sparta Agis IV,

Cleomenes III

−244– −227 Centralization
  • Help the poor
  • strengthening the army
  • Land redistribution
  • Debt annulment
Reformer kings murdered by opponents, reforms undone
Europe: Italy / Rome Gracchi brothers −133– −121 Social Justice
  • Help the landless soldiers
  • Land redistribution
  • Enforcement of land ceiling law
Reformer tribunes murdered by Senate, reforms undone
Europe: Austria / Habsburg monarchy Maria Theresa and Joseph II 1680–1790 Enlightenment
  • Liberate peasants
  • increase tax revenues
Freedom to peasants
  • Abolish serfdom duties
nobles did not cooperate and laws were not enforced
Europe: France / Savoy Victor Amadeus II 1720–1793 Economics
  • Increase royal income
  • Weaken the nobility
Freedom to peasants
  • Abolish serfdom duties
  • Confiscate lands from lords
All estates were at least partially emancipated
Europe: Prussia various 1763–1850 Economics
  • Modernize the state by improving the peasants' conditions
Freedom to peasants from serfdom duties
  • Enable serfs to become free landlords
nobles bought much more land than peasants
Europe: Italy / Sicily various 1773–1865 Enlightenment
  • Liberate the peasants and strengthen the king
Nationalize noble lands
  • Reduce duties of peasants to landlords
  • Abolish private landlord armies
  • Distribute common lands to poor peasants.
The rich bought most lands and became richer; the Sicilian Mafia was born.
Europe: Austria / Austrian empire Constituent Assembly 1849 Enlightenment
  • Liberate peasants
Freedom to peasants; subsidized purchase of their lands feudal law abolished, but most land remained concentrated with the nobles
Latin America: Mexico Miguel Lerdo, Porfirio Díaz 1856–1910 Liberalism and economics Forced sale of corporately held property, specifically lands held by the Catholic Church and indigenous communities. Changed the nature of land tenure in Mexico. Most native-owned land was acquired by large estates. 95% of villages lost their lands.
Europe: Russia / Russian empire Alexander II 1861 Enlightenment
  • Liberate peasants
Freedom to peasants; subsidized purchase of their lands More than 23 million people received their liberty, but many of them received land insufficient for survival and became proletariat
Europe: Britain / Ireland William Ewart Gladstone, UK government 1870–1922 Social justice
  • Historic justice to Irish natives
Land transfer from large English landlords to their Irish tenants, funded by UK government By 1922, over 90% of lands had been transferred
Europe: Russia / Russian empire Stolypin 1906–1916 Economics
  • Encourage private property and capitalism
  • Liquidize communal villages
  • Divide lands to individual peasants.
Private land holdings increased, but reforms were reversed after Soviet revolution
Latin America: Mexico (after revolution) Álvaro Obregón, Lázaro Cárdenas 1910–1940 Social justice
  • Decentralization
  • Lessening inequality
  • Allocate land to peasants in need of it
Reversed the process of land concentration, reduced the power and legitimacy of the landlord class. Much land was allocated to peasants. Production increased.
Europe: Russia / Soviet union Lenin 1917 Communism
  • Abolish private property
  • Private ownership of land was prohibited
Private land holdings increased, but reforms were reversed after Soviet revolution
Europe: Albania / Albania Post-WW2 government 1946 Social justice
  • Lessening inequality
Constitutional Reforms
  • Land to the tiller
  • Disallowed large estates
By 1954, more than 90% of land was held in small and mid-sized farms.
Southeast Asia: Philippines various 1946–2014 Social justice
  • Lessening inequality
  • Land redistribution laws
Some lands were distributed to landless peasants, but agricultural production suffered.
East Asia: Taiwan Chiang Monlin, Y.C. James Yen 1950s Modernization
  • Community development
Established the JCRR
  • Agricultural development programs
  • Co-operative formation
  • Rural credit programs
The JCRR is credited with laying the agricultural basis for Taiwan's outstanding economic growth in the following decades
Middle East: Egypt Nasser 1952–1961 Social justice
  • Lessening inequality
  • Land redistribution
15% of arable land redistributed; reforms undone after change of government
Southeast Asia: Vietnam / North Hồ Chí Minh 1953–1956 Communism
  • Break the power of the traditional village elite
  • Landlords were murdered by government
  • Land redistributed to peasants
Thousands were killed, and 1 million people fled to the South
Latin America: Guatemala Juan José Arévalo, Jacobo Árbenz 1953–1954 Social justice
  • Lessening inequality
  • Expropriation of land
  • Redistribution to peasants
The reform itself was successful, but a later US-backed coup reversed it entirely.
Latin America: Bolivia Víctor Paz EstenssoroEvo Morales 1953–2006 Social justice
  • Expanding indigenous rights
  • Abolished forced peasantry labor
  • Distribute rural property of traditional landlords to indigenous peasants
  • Organized peasants into armed militias.
By 1970, 45% of peasant families had received title to land. The reform goes on.
Europe: Albania / Albania Enver Hoxha 1958–1962 Communism
  • Collectivization drive
  • Most agricultural lands were shifted to Soviet-style collective and state farms.
By 1971, independent family farms had virtually disappeared
Latin America: Cuba Che Guevara 1959–1963 Communism
  • Nationalization of large estates
  • Redistribution to peasants
  • Land ceiling
Peasants were given land rights, but these rights are constrained by government production quotas and a prohibition of real estate transactions
South Asia: India Hare Krishna Konar, E. M. S. Namboodiripad and others 1961– Economics
  • Modernize the agriculture
  • End the exploitation of the poor
  • Abolition of rent-collectors
  • Secure land-tenure
  • Land ceiling
  • Consolidate disparate holdings.
In parts of India redistribution of land became more equitable; in other parts, people found loopholes in ceiling laws.
Latin America: Chile Jorge Alessandri[citation needed] 1962–1973 Social justice
  • Lessening Inequality
  • Nationalization of large estates
  • Redistribution to peasants
After the 1973 coup the process was halted and somewhat reversed by market forces
Southeast Asia: Vietnam / South Nguyen Van Thieu 1970 Social welfare
  • Gain support from rural population during the Vietnam war.
  • Land ceiling
  • Land redistribution with compensation to previous landlords
Land was redistributed, but law became meaningless 5 years later at the fall of Saigon.
Africa: Ethiopia DERG 1975 Social justice
  • Lessening inequality
  • Nationalization of large estates
  • Redistribution to peasants
  • abolished tenancy
End of feudal law, strengthening of peasants
Oceania: Australia various 1976–2004 Social justice
  • Several laws giving land rights to Aboriginals
Large lands have been returned to Aboriginals
Europe: Albania / Albania Post-communist government 1991 Privatization
  • Allow private property
  • Arable land held in cooperatives
  • State-owned farms were equally distributed among rural households.
Land was privatized.
Europe: Russia / Russian Federation GorbachevYeltsinPutin 1989–2001 Privatization
  • Allow private property
  • Private ownership of land was re-allowed in several stages
Private ownership gradually increased, but became centralized into the hands of Russian oligarchs
Latin America: Venezuela Hugo Chávez 2001–2003 Social justice
  • Lessening inequality
  • Redistribute government & unused private land to campesinos in need
60K families received land title
Europe: Britain / Scotland Scottish Parliament 2003 Social justice
  • Freedom to farmer communities
  • Farmer communities can buy their lands without landlord consent
End of feudal law

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ "The Land Law Bill: forward and back". Colombia Support Network.
  2. ^ Matsetela (2000)
  3. ^ a b Gleijeses, Piero (1989). "The Agrarian Reform of Jacobo Arbenz". Journal of Latin American Studies. 21 (3): 453–480. doi:10.1017/S0022216X00018514. S2CID 145201357.
  4. ^ Markiewicz, Dana. The Mexican Revolution and the Limits of Land Reform, 1915-1946. Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publisher 1993.
  5. ^ Hunefeldt, C. A Brief History of Peru. New York, NY.
  6. ^ a b c Hunefeldt, C. A Brief History of Peru. New York, NY
  7. ^ Forero, Juan (2009-06-20). "In Venezuela, Land 'Rescue' Hopes Unmet".
  8. ^ "This Land Was Your Land". 13 November 2015.
  9. ^ "In Venezuela, Land Redistribution Program Backfires". NPR.
  10. ^ a b https://www.oxfamamerica.org/static/media/files/Paraguay_background.pdf[bare URL PDF]
  11. ^ https://fas.org/sgp/crs/row/R44936.pdf[bare URL PDF]
  12. ^ a b "Paraguay - Land Reform and Land Policy".
  13. ^ "Monoculture Soy and the Future of the Paraguayan Campesino". HuffPost. 25 November 2013.
  14. ^ a b "Iran - Rural Society". Country-data.com. Retrieved 2010-06-27.
  15. ^ Amid, M. (1990) 'Agriculture, Poverty and Reform in Iran' London, Routledge
  16. ^ A History of Iraq by Charles Tripp
  17. ^ A History of the Modern Middle East, William > Cleveland and Martin Bunton
  18. ^ Raimondo Cagiano De Azevedo (1994). "Migration and development co-operation.". Council of Europe. p.25. ISBN 92-871-2611-9
  19. ^ as quoted in Heydemann 1999 p.193 'Authoritarianism in Syria: Institutions and Social Conflict' 1946-1970 Cornell University Press Ithaca
  20. ^ "Syria - Agriculture". Countrystudies.us. Retrieved 2010-06-27.
  21. ^ Hinnebusch, R. 2001 p.55 'Syria Revolution From Above' Routledge New York
  22. ^ Afghanistan Country Study and Government Publication
  23. ^ . Archived from the original on 2012-03-22. Retrieved 2012-12-07.
  24. ^ "Sri Lanka land reform legislation". Country-data.com. Retrieved 2010-06-27.
  25. ^ Peiris, G. H. (1978). "Land Reform and Agrarian Change in Sri Lanka". Modern Asian Studies. 12 (4): 611–628. doi:10.1017/S0026749X0000634X. JSTOR 312371. S2CID 144022457. Retrieved 23 August 2022.
  26. ^ "Sri Lanka 'land reform' disaster made the state the biggest land owner". Economynext.com. Retrieved 23 August 2022.
  27. ^ Dreyfus, Jean-Marc; Nižňanský, Eduard (2011). "Jews and non-Jews in the Aryanization Process: Comparison of France and the Slovak State, 1939–45". In Kosmala, Beate; Verbeeck, Georgi (eds.). Facing the Catastrophe: Jews and non-Jews in Europe during World War II. Oxford: Berg. p. 24. ISBN 978-1-84520-471-6.
  28. ^ Isojako. Etälukio. Finnish Board of Education. Retrieved 2016-03-15. (in Finnish)
  29. ^ Uusjako hajotti ryhmäkylät. University of Helsinki. Retrieved 2016-03-15. (in Finnish)
  30. ^ Vitikainen, A. (2003) Uusjakojen kysynnästä ja toimitusmenettelyn uudistamistarpeesta. Maanmittaus 78:1-2. 5-20. Retrieved 2016-03-15. (in Finnish)
  31. ^ Meriläinen, Jaakko; Mitrunen, Matti; Virkola, Tuomo (2022). "Famine, Inequality, and Conflict". Journal of the European Economic Association. 21 (4): 1478–1509. doi:10.1093/jeea/jvac069. ISSN 1542-4766.
  32. ^ Virtanen, P. V. (2003) MAAREFORMIT itsenäisessä Suomessa. Maankäyttö 3/2003, p. 9-14. Retrieved 2016-03-15. (in Finnish)
  33. ^ "The Land War in Ireland - A History for the Times". Retrieved 25 June 2016.
  34. ^ Land Purchase Acts 1903+1909 encyclopedic definitions
  35. ^ Tommaso Pedio. "Latifondo e usi civici, prammatica 1792, eversione della feudalità, usurpazioni delle terre demaniali, adesione dei galantuomini al nuovo regime". Retrieved 24 June 2014.
  36. ^ Sulla complessa vicenda dell'apporto americano, Emanuele Bernardi, "La riforma agraria in Italia e gli Stati Uniti", Bologna, il Mulino, 2006
  37. ^ Corrado Barberis Teoria e storia della riforma agraria Firenze, Vallecchi, 1957
  38. ^ Fonte: Pag 108 del libro Studi sul Mezzogiorno repubblicano: storia politica ed analisi, Di Luca Bussotti, Rubbettino Editore srl, 2003
  39. ^ "The Edinburgh Journal of Gadda Studies". www.arts.ed.ac.uk. Archived from the original on 18 July 2012. Retrieved 22 May 2022.
  40. ^ "L'Indipendenza della Catalogna e i compiti della sinistra spagnola".
  41. ^ Fonte: Pag 195 di "La Geografia. Per la scuola Media, Volume n°1; G. Bacchi, A. Londrrillo; Editore Bulgarini; Firenze 1983"
  42. ^ Albertus, Michael (2022). "The Persistence of Rural Underdevelopment: Evidence from Land Reform in Italy". Comparative Political Studies. 56: 65–100. doi:10.1177/00104140221089653. S2CID 244675475.
  43. ^ Naimark, Norman M. (1995). The Russians in Germany: A History of the Soviet Zone of Occupation, 1945–1949. Cambridge: Belknap Press. p. 142.
  44. ^ Agrarian Reform in Latvia University Centre for International Studies
  45. ^ Bogdan, Olena. "Land Reform and Rural Employment in Ukraine" (PDF). Kyiv School of Economics. Retrieved 7 March 2020.
  46. ^ Bershidsky, Leonid (20 September 2019). "Europe's Last Land Frontier Is Opening Up". Bloomberg.
  47. ^ Synovitz, Roy (4 April 2000). "Ukraine: Collective Farm System Proves Entrenched". Radio Free Europe/Radio Liberty. Retrieved 1 June 2022.
  48. ^ Dobbs, Michael (4 December 1990). "PRIVATE LAND OWNERSHIP LEGALIZED IN RUSSIA". The Washington Post. Retrieved 1 June 2022.
  49. ^ Johnson, Ian (26 September 2019). "Barred From Owning Land, Rural Chinese Miss Spoils of Country's Success". The New York Times. Retrieved 1 June 2022.
  50. ^ "Land Law of the Democratic People's Republic of Korea (1999)". Law and North Korea. 16 June 1999. Retrieved 1 June 2022.
  51. ^ a b Olearchyk, Roman (19 January 2020). "Ukraine sows seeds of suspicion with land sale plans". The Financial Times. THE FINANCIAL TIMES LTD.
  52. ^ a b Sologoub, Ilona (26 November 2019). "Ukraine is finally ready to embrace land reform". Atlantic Council. The sale of private agricultural land has been banned since 2001. Ukraine is one of six countries in the world to maintain this restriction.
  53. ^ Langley, Andrew (4 July 2017). "Ukrainian Premier Signals IMF Delay as Key Reform Not Ready". Bloomberg.
  54. ^ "EU supports land reform in Ukraine, but it should be implemented properly". Kyiv Post. Interfax Ukraine. 6 February 2020.
  55. ^ "Поле для маніпуляцій: Топ-5 міфів про земельний мораторій від українських політиків". Vox Ukraine. 13 March 2018.
  56. ^ Winfrey, Michael (30 July 2019). "Ukraine Turns to Blueprint That Transformed Ex-Communist Europe". Bloomberg.
  57. ^ Gomez, James M (2 January 2018). "Ukraine's Ban on Selling Farmland Is Choking the Economy". Bloomberg.
  58. ^ . Channel News Asia. AFP. 6 February 2020. Archived from the original on 7 February 2020.
  59. ^ Krasnolutska, Daryna (7 March 2020). "Ukrainian Leader Backs Calamitous Reshuffle to Deliver Results". Bloomberg.
  60. ^ "Ukraine Receives IMF Support But Must Accelerate Reforms". International Monetary Fund. 4 April 2017. Retrieved 1 June 2022.
  61. ^ Talant, Bermet (6 March 2020). "Hasty government reshuffle sows disquiet at home, abroad". Kyiv Post.
  62. ^ a b c Land reform will promote more active lending to agricultural enterprises - NBU, Ukrinform (16 September 2020)
  63. ^ Raczkiewycz, Mark (22 August 2021). "In Fertile Ukraine, A 20-Year Freeze On The Sale Of Farmland Is Lifted -- With Uncertain Consequences". Radio Free Europe/Radio Liberty. Retrieved 1 June 2022.
  64. ^ "Labour Land Campaign". August 2014. Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  65. ^ "Policies for a Sustainable Society: Land". 2000. Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  66. ^ "Policies for a Sustainable Society: Economy". 2015. Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  67. ^ "Country Life research 2010". Independent.co.uk. 23 October 2011. Retrieved 23 July 2020., The Independent
  68. ^ Elliot, Alison; Watt, John; Ian, Cooke; Taylor, Pip (2014). "The Land of Scotland and the Common Good: Report of the Land Reform Review Group" (PDF). The Scottish Government. Retrieved 4 March 2017.
  69. ^ Bryden, John; Geisler, Charles (2007). "Community-based land reform: Lessons from Scotland". Land Use Policy. 24: 24–34. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2005.09.004.
  70. ^ Hoffman, Matthew (2013). "Why community ownership? Understanding land reform in Scotland". Land Use Policy. 31: 289–297. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2012.07.013.
  71. ^ "Land Reform (Scotland) Act 2003". Retrieved 5 March 2017.
  72. ^ "Community Empowerment (Scotland) Act 2015". Retrieved 5 March 2017.
  73. ^ "Land Reform (Scotland) Act 2016". Retrieved 5 March 2017.
  74. ^ Onoma, Ato Kwamena (2009), Mahoney, James; Thelen, Kathleen (eds.), "The Contradictory Potential of Institutions: The Rise and Decline of Land Documentation in Kenya", Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power, Cambridge University Press, pp. 63–93, ISBN 978-0-521-11883-5
  75. ^ Harbeson, John W. (1971). "Land Reforms and Politics in Kenya, 1954-70". The Journal of Modern African Studies. 9 (2): 231–251. doi:10.1017/S0022278X00024915. ISSN 0022-278X. JSTOR 159442. S2CID 154641256.
  76. ^ Joseph, Odhiambo (2006-08-22). "Pledge to redistribute Kenya land". BBC News. Retrieved 2010-06-27.
  77. ^ Hassan, Mai; Klaus, Kathleen (2023-03-28). "Closing The Gap: The Politics of Property Rights in Kenya". World Politics. 75 (2): 233–279. doi:10.1353/wp.2023.0008. ISSN 1086-3338. S2CID 235702685.
  78. ^ Tjirera, Ellison (2023). "Namibia's Intractable Land Question". Current History. 122 (844): 167–171. doi:10.1525/curh.2023.122.844.167. ISSN 0011-3530.
  79. ^ William, Vincent. "Namibia: Situation Report" (PDF). United Nations High Commission on Refugees.
  80. ^ Namibia: Land Reform to Cost Billions
  81. ^ a b c Deininger, Klaus. "Making Negotiated Land Reform Work: Initial Experience from Colombia, Brazil and South Africa." World Development Vol. 27(1999): 651-672
  82. ^ Ross, Robert (1999). A concise history of South Africa. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521575782.
  83. ^ Moseley, W.G. and B. McCusker. 2008. "Fighting Fire with a Broken Tea Cup: A Comparative Analysis of South Africa's Land Redistribution Program." Geographical Review. 98(3): 322-338.
  84. ^ Hall, Ruth. "Decentralisation in South Africa's Land Redistribution." Presentation to the PLAAS regional workshop on Land Reform from Below? Decentralisation of Land Reform in Southern Africa. Program for land anad agrarian studies. Kopanong Conference Centre, Kempton Park, Johannesburg. 23-04-2008. Address
  85. ^ Machingaidze, Victor E.M. (1991). "Agrarian Change from above: The Southern Rhodesia Native Land Husbandry Act and African Response". The International Journal of African Historical Studies. 24 (3): 557–588. doi:10.2307/219092. JSTOR 219092.
  86. ^ Chigara, Ben (2002). Land Reform Policy. Ashgate Publishing. p. 52. ISBN 978-0-7546-2293-2.
  87. ^ "Britain's troubles with Mugabe". BBC News. 3 April 2000.
  88. ^ Page 302 Big Men, Little People: The Leaders Who Defined Africa
  89. ^ All Party Parliamentary Group Report Dec 2009
  90. ^ "Online NewsHour – Land Redistribution in Southern Africa: Zimbabwe Program". Pbs.org. Retrieved 2012-11-20.
  91. ^ Page 372 Africa Review 2003/2004
  92. ^ "In the Pit of Africa" A Review by Joshua Hammer. 2014-05-06 at the Wayback Machine New York Review of Books, 7 January 2008
  93. ^ (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2013-11-01.
  94. ^ "voanews.com". Archived from the original on 2005-11-12. Retrieved 2018-01-22.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  95. ^ Mike Campbell (Private) Limited v. The Minister of National Security Responsible for Land, Land Reform and Resettlement, Supreme Court of Zimbabwe, 22 January 2008
  96. ^ Eric Foner, Reconstruction: America's Unfinished Revolution, 1863-1877, Harper & Row, 1988, p. 374
  97. ^ Foner, 1988, p. 104
  98. ^ Alan Brinkley, The Unfinished Nation: A Concise History of the American People, 6th ed, McGraw-Hill, 2010, p.372-374
  99. ^ Brinkley, 2010, p. 375
  100. ^ Clayborne Carson, Emma J. Lapsansky-Werner, and Gary B. Nash, The Struggle for Freedom: A History of African Americans, Combined vol., 2nd ed., Prentice Hall, 2011, p. 265-266,276-277
  101. ^ Brinkley, 2010, p. 371
  102. ^ Foner, 1988, p.104-105
  103. ^ Foner, 1988, p. 105-106, 403
  104. ^ "Order by the Commander of the Military Division of the Mississippi". Freedmen and Southern Society Project. Retrieved 2012-12-31.
  105. ^ Proceedings of 13th Congress, 13 Stat. 507 (enacted March 3, 1865) from the Library of Congress.
  106. ^ Foner, 1988, p. 159
  107. ^ Foner, 1988, p. 375
  108. ^ Foner, 1988, pp. 375-377
  109. ^ James S. Pike, reporting on the south, indicating the growing appeal of racist rhetoric in anti-Reconstruction politics. Foner, 1988, p. 525
  110. ^ Foner, 1988, pp. 524-531
  111. ^ Brinkley, 2010, p. 387
  112. ^ Foner, 1988, pp. 602-612
  113. ^ a b . Fao.org. Archived from the original on 2010-12-23. Retrieved 2010-06-27.
  114. ^ Ding, C. (2003). "Land policy reform in China: Assessment and prospects". Land Use Policy. 20 (2): 109–120. doi:10.1016/s0264-8377(02)00073-x.
  115. ^ Flores 1970, p. 901.
  116. ^ Cha, Victor D. (2013). The Impossible State: North Korea, Past and Future. Internet Archive. New York: Ecco. pp. 46–47. ISBN 978-0-06-199850-8.
  117. ^ Yoo Gwan Hee (March 5, 2010). "Collective or Farmer: Land Ownership in North Korea". Retrieved December 15, 2021.
  118. ^ Andrea Matles Savad (1993). "North Korea: A Country Study". Retrieved December 15, 2021.
  119. ^ a b Beban, Alice (2021). Unwritten Rule: State-Making through Land Reform in Cambodia. Cornell University Press. ISBN 978-1-5017-5362-6. JSTOR 10.7591/j.ctv12sdwbz.
  120. ^ "'They never intended to conserve it': Outcry as loggers gut Cambodian reserve". Mongabay Environmental News. 2020-05-13. Retrieved 2020-12-08.
  121. ^ "Interactive: Plundering Cambodia's forests". interactive.aljazeera.com. Retrieved 2020-12-08.
  122. ^ Campbell, Charlie (2013-05-14). "In Cambodia, China Fuels Deadly Illegal Logging Trade". Time. ISSN 0040-781X. Retrieved 2020-12-08.
  123. ^ "Illegal logging poised to wipe Cambodian wildlife sanctuary off the map". Mongabay Environmental News. 2019-05-02. Retrieved 2020-12-08.
  124. ^ "Cambodia's Forests Are Disappearing". earthobservatory.nasa.gov. 2017-01-10. Retrieved 2020-12-08.
  125. ^ Adrian Levy; Cathy Scott-Clark (26 April 2008). "Country for sale". The Guardian. Retrieved 13 February 2014.
  126. ^ "Country For Sale". Global Witness. Retrieved 2020-12-08.
  127. ^ a b "The Marcos Agrarian Reform Program: Promises and Contradictions". Martial Law Museum. Retrieved 2021-11-02.
  128. ^ Esguerra, E. F. (1980). "Some notes on the Masagana 99 [rice] program and small farmer access to credit [Philippines]". Philippine Sociological Review (Philippines). ISSN 0031-7810.
  129. ^ Reyes, Miguel Paolo P.; Ariate Jr., Joel F.; Del Mundo, Larah Vinda (2021-05-24). "'Success' of Masagana 99 all in Imee's head - UP researchers". Vera Files. Retrieved 2021-11-02.
  130. ^ CARP not renewed 2012-09-25 at the Wayback Machine, Inquirer.net, 3 January 2009.
  131. ^ "Father of Thai democracy, forever misunderstood". Bangkok Post. Retrieved 2022-04-06.
  132. ^ "Land Legislation | Gender and Land Rights Database | Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations". www.fao.org. Retrieved 2022-04-06.
  133. ^ The Viet Minh Regime, Government and Administration in the Democratic Republic of Vietnam, Bernard Fall, Greenwood Press, Connecticut, 1975.
  134. ^ a b Nhan, Vo Tri (1990). Vietnam's Economic Policy Since 1975 (1 ed.). Institute for Southeast Asian Studies. pp. 2–7. ISBN 978-981-3035-54-6. Retrieved 8 July 2015.
  135. ^ Moise, Edwin E. (1976). "Land Reform and Land Reform Errors in North Vietnam". Pacific Affairs. 49 (1, Spring 1976): 84–85. doi:10.2307/2756362. JSTOR 2756362.
  136. ^ Communist Party of Vietnam, Kinh nghiệm giải quyết vấn đề ruộng đất trong cách mạng Việt Nam (Experience in land reform in the Vietnamese Revolution), available online:

land, reforms, country, agrarian, reform, land, reform, have, been, recurring, theme, enormous, consequence, world, history, they, often, highly, political, have, been, achieved, attempted, many, countries, contents, latin, america, brazil, bolivia, chile, col. Agrarian reform and land reform have been a recurring theme of enormous consequence in world history They are often highly political and have been achieved or attempted in many countries Contents 1 Latin America 1 1 Brazil 1 2 Bolivia 1 3 Chile 1 4 Colombia 1 5 Cuba 1 6 Guatemala 1 7 Mexico 1 8 Nicaragua 1 9 Peru 1 10 Venezuela 1 11 Paraguay 2 Middle East and North Africa 2 1 Ottoman Empire 2 2 Egypt 2 3 Iran 2 4 Iraq 2 5 Maghreb 2 6 Syria 3 South Asia 3 1 Afghanistan 3 2 India 3 3 Sri Lanka 4 Europe 4 1 Albania 4 2 Czechoslovakia 4 3 Estonia 4 4 Finland 4 5 Germany 4 6 Ireland 4 7 Italy 4 8 Russia and the Soviet Union 4 9 Latvia 4 10 Sweden 4 11 Ukraine 4 12 United Kingdom 4 12 1 Scotland 5 Africa 5 1 Ethiopia 5 2 Kenya 5 3 Namibia 5 4 South Africa 5 5 Zimbabwe 6 North America 6 1 Canada 6 2 United States 7 East Asia 7 1 Mainland China 7 2 Taiwan 7 3 Japan 7 4 South Korea 7 5 North Korea 8 Southeast Asia 8 1 Cambodia 8 2 Philippines 8 3 Thailand 8 4 Vietnam 9 Summary table 10 See also 11 ReferencesLatin America edit nbsp Children singing the Internationale at the 20th Anniversary of Brazil s Landless Workers MovementBrazil edit Getulio Vargas who rose to presidency in Brazil following the Brazilian Revolution of 1930 promised a land reform but reneged on his promise A first attempt to make a nationwide reform was set up in the government of Jose Sarney 1985 1990 as a result of the strong popular movement that had contributed to the fall of the military government According to the 1988 Constitution of Brazil the government is required to expropriate for the purpose of agrarian reform rural property that is not performing its social function Article 184 However the social function mentioned there is not well defined and hence the so called First Land Reform National Plan never was put into action Bolivia edit Main article Land reform in Bolivia Land in Bolivia was unequally distributed 92 of the cultivable land was held by large estates until the Bolivian national revolution in 1952 Then the Revolutionary Nationalist Movement government abolished forced peasantry labor and established a program of expropriation and distribution of the rural property of the traditional landlords to the indigenous peasants A unique feature of the reform in Bolivia was the organization of peasants into syndicates Peasants were not only granted land but their militias also were given large supplies of arms The peasants remained a powerful political force in Bolivia during all subsequent governments By 1970 45 of peasant families had received title to land Land reform projects continued in the 1970s and 1980s A 1996 agrarian reform law increased protection for smallholdings and indigenous territories but also protected absentee landholders who pay taxes from expropriation Reforms were continued at 2006 with the Bolivian senate passing a bill authorizing the government redistribution of land among the nation s mostly indigenous poor Chile edit Main article Chilean land reform Attempts at land reform began under the government of Jorge Alessandri in 1960 were accelerated during the government of Eduardo Frei Montalva 1964 1970 and reached its climax during the 1970 1973 presidency of Salvador Allende Farms of more than 198 acres 80 ha were expropriated After the 1973 coup the process was halted by the military junta and up to a point reversed by the market forces Colombia edit Alfonso Lopez Pumarejo 1934 1938 passed Law 200 of 1936 1 which allowed for the expropriation of private properties in order to promote social interest Later attempts declined until the National Front presidencies of Alberto Lleras Camargo 1958 1962 and Carlos Lleras Restrepo 1966 1970 which respectively created the Colombian Institute for Agrarian Reform INCORA and further developed land entitlement In 1968 and 1969 alone the INCORA issued more than 60 000 land titles to farmers and workers Despite this the process was then halted and the situation began to reverse itself as the subsequent violent actions of drug lords paramilitaries guerrillas and opportunistic large landowners severely contributed to a renewed concentration of land and to the displacement of small landowners 2 In the early 21st century tentative government plans to use the land legally expropriated from drug lords and or the properties given back by demobilized paramilitary groups have not caused much practical improvement yet Cuba edit Main article Land reform in Cuba Land reform was among the chief planks of the revolutionary platform of 1959 Almost all large holdings were seized by the National Institute for Agrarian Reform INRA which dealt with all areas of agricultural policy A ceiling of 166 acres 67 hectares was established and tenants were given ownership rights though these rights are constrained by government production quotas and a prohibition of real estate transactions Guatemala edit Main article Decree 900 Land reform occurred during the Ten Years of Spring 1944 1954 under the governments of Juan Jose Arevalo and Jacobo Arbenz after a popular revolution forced out dictator Jorge Ubico The largest part of the reform was the law officially called Decree 900 which redistributed all uncultivated land from landholdings that were larger than 673 acres 272 ha If the estates were between 672 acres 272 ha and 224 acres 91 ha in size uncultivated land was expropriated only if less than two thirds of it was in use 3 The law benefited 500 000 people or one sixth of the Guatemalan Population Historians have called this reform as one of the most successful land reforms in history However the United Fruit Company felt threatened by the law and lobbied the United States government which was a factor in the US backed coup that deposed Arbenz in 1954 The majority of the reform was rolled back by the US supported military dictatorship that followed 3 Mexico edit Main article Land reform in Mexico In 1856 the first land reform was driven by the ley Lerdo the Lerdo law enacted by the Liberal Party government of the Second Federal Republic of Mexico One of the aims of the reform government was to develop the economy by returning to productive cultivation the underutilized lands of the Roman Catholic Church and the municipal communities Indian commons which required the division of these lands for sale with the expectation that Mexico would develop a class of small owners This was to be accomplished through the provisions of Ley Lerdo that prohibited ownership of land by the Church and the municipalities The reform government also financed its war effort by seizing and selling church property and other large estates Little land was acquired by individual small holders After the war the role of the state in land policy expanded during the presidency of Porfirio Diaz The aim was to extinguish traditional subsistence farming and make agriculture in Mexico a dynamic commercial sector as part of Mexico s modernization Land was concentrated in the hands of large scale owners a great many of them foreigners leaving peasantry the largest sector of the Mexican population landless Peasant unrest was a major cause of the Mexican Revolution of 1910 20 A certain degree of land reform was introduced albeit unevenly as part of the Mexican Revolution 4 In 1934 president Lazaro Cardenas passed the 1934 Agrarian Code and accelerated the pace of land reform He helped redistribute 45 000 000 acres 180 000 km2 of land 4 000 000 acres 16 000 km2 of which were expropriated from American owned agricultural property This caused conflict between Mexico and the United States Agrarian reform had come close to extinction in the early 1930s The first few years of the Cardenas s reform were marked by high food prices falling wages high inflation and low agricultural yields In 1935 land reform began sweeping across the country in the periphery and core of commercial agriculture The Cardenas alliance with peasant groups was awarded by the destruction of the hacienda system Cardenas distributed more land than all his revolutionary predecessors put together a 400 increase The land reform justified itself in terms of productivity average agricultural production during the three year period from 1939 to 1941 was higher than it had been at any time since the beginning of the revolution Starting with the government of Miguel Aleman 1946 52 land reform steps made in previous governments were rolled back Aleman s government allowed capitalist entrepreneurs to rent peasant land This created phenomenon known as neolatifundismo where land owners build up large scale private farms on the basis of controlling land which remains ejidal but is not sown by the peasants to whom it is assigned In 1970 President Luis Echeverria began his term by declaring land reform dead In the face of peasant revolt he was forced to backtrack and embarked on the biggest land reform program since Cardenas Echeverria legalized take overs of huge foreign owned private farms which were turned into new collective ejidos In 1988 President Carlos Salinas de Gortari was elected In December 1991 he amended Article 27 of the Constitution making it legal to sell ejido land and allow peasants to put up their land as collateral for a loan Francisco Madero and Emiliano Zapata were strongly identified with land reform as are the present day as of 2006 Zapatista Army of National Liberation Today most Mexican peasants are landowners However their holdings are usually too small and farmers must supplement their incomes by working for the remaining landlords and or traveling to the United States See also Mexico Indigena 2005 2008 project Nicaragua edit During and after the Nicaraguan Revolution 1979 the Sandinista government officially announced their political platform which included land reform The last months of Sandinista rule were criticized for the Pinata Plan which distributed large tracts of land to prominent Sandinistas After their loss in the 1990 elections most of the Sandinista leaders held most of the private property and businesses that had been confiscated and nationalized by the FSLN government This process became known as the pinata and was tolerated by the new government of Violeta Chamorro Peru edit Land reform in the 1950s largely eliminated a centuries old system of debt peonage Further land reform occurred after the 1968 coup by left wing colonel Juan Velasco Alvarado The military dictatorship under General Velasco 1968 75 launched a large scale agrarian reform movement that attempted to redistribute land hoping to break Peru s traditionally inequitable pattern of land holding and the hold of traditional oligarchy 5 The model used by Velasco to bring about change was the associative enterprise in which former salaried rural workers and independent peasant families would become members of different kinds of cooperatives 6 About 22 million acres were redistributed more land than in any reform program outside of Cuba Unfortunately productivity suffered as peasants with no management experience took control The military government continued to spend huge amounts of money to transform Peru s agriculture to socialized ownership and management These state expenditures are to blame for the enormous increase in Peru s external debt at the beginning of the 1970s 6 State bankruptcy was partly caused by the cheap credit the government extended to promote agrarian development state subsidies and administrative expenditures to carry out the agrarian reform during this period 6 The more radical effects of this reform were reversed by president Fernando Belaunde Terry in the 1980s A third land reform occurred as part of a counterterrorism effort against the Shining Path during the Internal conflict in Peru roughly 1988 1995 led by Hernando de Soto and the Institute for Liberty and Democracy during the early years of the government of Alberto Fujimori before the latter s auto coup citation needed Venezuela edit In 2001 Hugo Chavez s government enacted Plan Zamora to redistribute government and unused private land to campesinos in need The plan met with heavy opposition which led to a coup attempt in 2002 When Pedro Carmona took over the presidency during that event he reversed the land reform However the reversal was declared null when the coup failed and Chavez returned to power By the end of 2003 60 000 families had received temporary title to a total of 55 000 km of land under this plan Despite the land reforms carried out by the government which according to some sources have reduced the so called latifundios which means big landownership most receivers of the land didn t have any knowledge about how to cultivate the land and grow crops In many cases peasants didn t even water since water infrastructures were still missing in most of the regions 7 Moreover in some cases campesinos didn t gain direct ownership of the land but only the right to farm it without having to pay the rent and without sanctions from the government and in some cases the land wasn t given to single peasant family but managed in communes According to some sources the expropriated land amounts to 4 5 million hectares 8 9 Paraguay edit Paraguay has been known to have experienced some obstacles in its political history that have been known mostly as dictatorship and corruption Paraguay s history is what has shaped the Paraguay we see today and as well as what has brought along the unequal land distributions From the War of the Triple Alliance 1864 1870 Paraguay came out losing land to Argentina Brazil and Uruguay as well as suffered from a great decline in population and was left with political instability Land in Paraguay has been known to be unequally distributed therefore prolonging rural poverty in Paraguay Following the Triple Alliance War the nation underwent a 35 year dictatorship of President Alfredo Stroessner in the years of 1954 to 1989 Stroessner was known to take away many campesino s land in order to give it to military officials foreign corporations and civilian supporters over eight million hectares of state owned land 20 percent of total land were given away or sold at negligible prices to friends of the regime who accumulated huge tracts of land 10 Stroessner also faked an alliance with the Colorado Party in order to distribute public land Campesinos cries for help for land reform were ignored and the prosecution against them continued causing them to suffer from high poverty rates June S Beittel said that as a result of the unequal distribution of land it left rural areas the most poverty stricken 11 In the year of 1954 the Truth and Justice Committee focused on getting justice for the abuses many Campesinos were facing from their own government After decades of controversy over government land policy two agrarian laws were created in 1963 These laws were known as the Agrarian Statute limiting the maximum size of landholding to 10 000 hectares in Eastern Paraguay and 20 000 hectares in the Chaco 12 However these laws were rarely enforced Under the Agrarian Statute there was also the creation of IBR Instituto de Bienestar Rural which mandated to plan colonization programs issue land titles to farmers and provide new colonies with support services 12 Although IBR focused on serving the land needs of farmers their task was so big and its resources so little that their goals for helping farmers were out of reach Paraguayan democracy came a long way after its 35 year dictatorship but the unequal distribution of land is still a problem for the nation since their economy is one that is dependent on its agriculture A census in 2008 revealed that 80 percent of agriculture land is held by just 1 6 percent of landowners with the 600 largest properties occupying 40 percent of the total productive land More than 300 000 family farmers have no land at all 10 Paraguayans have formed unions such as National Federation of Campesinos FNC who has fought for justice on the unequal land distributions in Latin America they have helped many campesinos reclaim acres of land since 1989 The ongoing inequality of land distribution has led to a demand for land regulation Citizens remain cautious about the nation s democracy and fearful of the return of dictatorship and corruption The problem regarding land distribution has worsened recently due to the expansion of monoculture in specific soy Paraguay has become the fourth world s largest distributors of soy Due to this distribution soy companies are the largest landowners taking over 80 percent of the land This production has negatively impacted the lives of rural peasants by leaving them without their own land Thus in March 2017 the streets of Paraguay s capital were filled with more than 1000 campesinos demanding for agrarian reform Thousands of rural peasants demand access to land fair agricultural prices for what they produce and technical assistance Due to the increase in soy production campesinos has been forced out of their lands leading them to demand land regulations This demand of the stabilization and fairness of agricultural prices is a result of Paraguay s government failing to sustain secure prices for their produce which are leaving them to live in extreme poverty In the effect of no secure economy for their produce campesinos mandate technical help A great majority of Paraguayans continue to practice subsistence agriculture in the depths of the Paraguayan campo countryside Despite their struggle with poverty inequality and land rights Paraguayans are proud of their campesino structure and the traditional culture that arises from it with this culture being the most prominent in Paraguay than anywhere else in Latin America In December 2017 over one third of the population was impoverished and 19 were living in extreme poverty so the further centralization of land and power has only functioned to exacerbate socio economic issues 13 Thus the campesino movement is still ongoing due to the desire to continue their campesino traditions and to be able to make a living wage doing so Middle East and North Africa editSee also Arab Socialism nbsp The shah distributing land deeds during Iran s White RevolutionOttoman Empire edit The Ottoman Land Code of 1858 1274 in the Islamic calendar was the beginning of a systematic land reform programme started during the Tanzimat period by Sultan Abdulmecid I of the Ottoman Empire during the latter half of the 19th century with the overall aims of increasing state revenue generated from land and for the state to be able to have greater control over individual plots of land This was followed by the 1873 land emancipation act Egypt edit Main articles Land reform in ancient Egypt and Land reform in Egypt Initially Egyptian land reform essentially abolished the political influence of major land owners However land reform only resulted in the redistribution of about 15 of Egypt s land under cultivation and by the early 1980s the effects of land reform in Egypt drew to a halt as the population of Egypt moved away from agriculture The Egyptian land reform laws were greatly curtailed under Anwar Sadat and eventually abolished Iran edit Main articles White Revolution and Iranian Land Reform Significant land reform in Iran took place under the shah as part of the socio economic reforms of the White Revolution begun in 1962 and agreed upon through a public referendum At this time the Iranian economy was not performing well and there was political unrest Essentially the land reforms amounted to a huge redistribution of land to rural peasants who previously had no possibility of owning land as they were poorly paid labourers The land reforms continued from 1962 until 1971 with three distinct phases of land distribution private government owned and endowed land These reforms resulted in the newly created peasant landowners owning six to seven million hectares around 52 63 of Iran s agricultural land According to Country Data even though there had been a considerable redistribution of land the amount received by individual peasants was not enough to meet most families basic needs About 75 percent of the peasant owners however had less than 7 hectares an amount generally insufficient for anything but subsistence agriculture 14 By 1979 a quarter of prime land was in disputed ownership and half of the productive land was in the hands of 200 000 absentee landlords 14 The large land owners were able to retain the best land with the best access to fresh water and irrigation facilities In contrast not only were the new peasant land holdings too small to produce an income but the peasants also lacked both quality irrigation system and sustained government support to enable them to develop their land to make a reasonable living Set against the economic boom from oil revenue it became apparent that the Land Reforms did not make life better for the rural population according to Amid only a small group of rural people experienced increasing improvements in their welfare and poverty remained the lot of the majority 15 Moghadam argues citation needed that the structural changes to Iran including the land reforms initiated by the White Revolution contributed to the revolution in 1979 which overthrew the Shah and turned Iran into an Islamic republic Iraq edit Under British Mandate Iraq s land was moved from communal land owned by the tribe to tribal sheikhs that agreed to work with the British Empire Known as compradors these families controlled much of Iraq s arable land until the end of British rule in 1958 Throughout the 1920s and 30s more and more land began to be centered in the hands of just a couple families By 1958 eight individual families owned almost 1 million acres 400 thousand hectares However the British did attempt to instill some reforms to increase the productivity of the land in Iraq In 1926 the Pump Law was introduced essentially legislating that all newly irrigated land would be tax free for 4 years This led to some short term gains in land productivity If land was cultivated for 15 years it then became the property of the person who cultivated that land From 1914 to 1943 there was an increase from 1 million to 4 25 million acres of land developed Unfortunately irrigation of the land was irresponsible and many farmers didn t allow for drainage which led to a buildup of salt and minerals in the land killing its productivity 16 In 1958 the rise of the Iraqi Communist Party led to the seizing of much of the land by the Iraqi Republic Landholdings were capped at 600 acres 240 hectares in arable areas and 1 200 acres 490 hectares in areas that had rainfall The concentrated landholdings by the state were then redistributed among the populace in amounts of 20 acres 8 1 hectares in irrigated land with 40 acres 16 hectares in land with rainfall In 1970 the Ba th Party led by Saddam Hussein began instituting a wide series of sweeping land reforms The intent of the reforms was to remove control of land owned by the traditional rural elites and redistribute it to peasant families Modeled after the 1958 land reforms much of the state land was rented out though often to people who originally owned the large swathes of land The key to this new reform was the Agrarian Reform Law of 1970 Between 1970 and 1982 264 400 farmers received grants of land However these reforms did not contribute to an improvement in the production of agricultural goods leading the regime to increase its imports of food products 17 Maghreb edit As elsewhere in North Africa lands formerly held by European farmers have been taken over The nationalisation of agricultural land in Algeria Morocco and Tunisia led to the departure of the majority of Europeans 18 Syria edit Land reforms were first implemented in Syria during 1958 The Agricultural Relations Law laid down a redistribution of rights in landownership tenancy and management The reforms were halted in 1961 due to a culmination of factors including opposition from large landowners and severe crop failure during a drought between 1958 and 1961 whilst Syria was a member of the doomed United Arab Republic UAR After the Ba ath Party gained power in 1963 the reforms were resumed The reforms were portrayed by the governing Ba ath as politically motivated to benefit the rural property less communities According to Zaki al Arsuzi a co founder of the Ba ath Party the reforms would liberate 75 percent of the Syrian population and prepare them to be citizens qualified to participate in the building of the state 19 It has been argued that the land reform represented work by the socialist government however by 1984 the private sector controlled 74 percent of Syria s arable land 20 This questions both Ba ath claims of commitment to the redistribution of land to the majority of peasants as well as the state government being socialist if it allowed the majority of land to be owned in the private sector how could it truly be socialist Hinnebusch argued that the reforms were a way of galvanising support from the large rural population they Ba ath Party members used the implementation of agrarian reform to win over and organise peasants and curb traditional power in the countryside 21 To this extent the reforms succeeded and resulted with an increase in Ba ath party membership They also prevented political threat emerging from rural areas by bringing the rural population into the system as supporters South Asia editAfghanistan edit Afghanistan has had a couple of attempts at land reform In 1975 the Republic of Afghanistan under President Mohammad Daoud Khan responded to the inequities of the existing land tenure conditions by issuing a Land Reform Law It limited individual holdings to a maximum of 20 hectares of irrigated double cropped land Larger holdings were allowed for less productive land The government was to expropriate all surplus land and pay compensation To prevent the proliferation of small uneconomic holdings priority for redistributed lands was to be given to neighboring farmers with two hectares or less Landless sharecroppers laborers tenants and nomads had next priority Despite the government s rhetorical commitment to land reform the program was quickly postponed Because the government s landholding limits applied to families not individuals wealthy families avoided expropriation by dividing their lands nominally between family members The high ceilings for landholdings restricted the amount of land actually subject to redistribution Finally the government lacked the technical data and organizational bodies to pursue the program after it was announced After the 1978 Saur Revolution the communist Peoples Democratic Party of Afghanistan PDPA issued Decree No 6 which canceled gerau and other mortgage debts of agricultural laborers tenants and small landowners with less than two hectares of land The cancellation applied only to debts contracted before 1973 The Decree No 8 of November 1978 made new landholdings from the 20 hectares of prime irrigated land in the 1975 law to just six hectares It divided all land into seven classes and again allowed for larger holdings of less productive land There was no compensation for government expropriated surplus land and it established categories of farmers who had priority for redistributed land sharecroppers already working on the land had highest priority 22 23 India edit Main articles Land reform in India and Land reform in Kerala Under the British occupation the land system in India has been feudalist with few absentee landlords holding most of the lands and claiming high rents from poor peasants The demand for a land reform was a major theme in the demand for independence After independence the different states in India gradually started a land reform process in four main categories abolition of intermediaries rent collectors under the pre Independence land revenue system tenancy regulation to improve the contractual terms including security of tenure a ceiling on landholdings to redistribute surplus land to the landless and attempts to consolidate disparate landholdings The extent and success of these reforms varied greatly between the different states of India Sri Lanka edit In 1972 the Government of Sirimavo Bandaranaike through the Land Reform Act of No 01 of 1972 imposed a ceiling of twenty hectares on privately owned land and sought to distribute lands in excess of the ceiling for the benefit of landless peasants Private lands that were in excess were vested in under the Land Reform Commission with its former owners paid a compensation which came to a nominal value based on government valuations that were below market rates Both land owned by public companies and paddy lands under ten hectares in extent were exempted from this ceiling Between 1972 and 1974 the Land Reform Commission took over nearly 228 000 hectares In 1975 the Land Reform Amendment Law brought over 169 000 hectares of plantations owned by companies including British owned companies under state control 24 Following the second wave of land reclamations the government gained control of vast amounts of plantation estates that produced the main exports of the country mainly the tea industry Most of the estates vested to the state were allocated to the Sri Lanka State Plantations Corporation the Janatha Estate Development Board People s Estate Development Board and the USAWASAMA Upcountry Cooperative Estate Development Board In the years following these land reforms the production of the key export crops which Sri Lanka depended on for the in follow of foreign currency dropped 25 The productivity and production of these estates declined due to mismanagement and lack of investments becoming a burden on the General Treasury which itself had heavily taxed its profits reducing investments and welfare of the workers In the 1980 s and 1990 s these estates had been privatized 26 Europe editAlbania edit Main article Land reform in Albania Albania has gone through three waves of land reform since the end of World War II in 1946 the land in estates and large farms was expropriated by the communist People s Republic of Albania and redistributed among small peasants in the 1950s the land was reorganized into large scale collective farms and after 1991 the land was again redistributed among private smallholders citation needed Czechoslovakia edit In 1918 all land owned by Habsburgs was confiscated In 1919 the Land Reform Act forced large landholders mostly nobility and church to sell their land to the state which in turn sold it to the peasants This concerned arable land only forests vineyards and pastures were excluded During the Holocaust in Slovakia the Land Reform Act of February 1940 confiscated and nationalized 101 423 hectares 250 620 acres of land owned by 4 943 Jews 27 Estonia edit Main articles Estonian Land Reform Act 1919 and Estonian Land Reform Act 1991 Estonia has witnessed two periods of land reform in 1919 and 1991 which occurred very shortly after the declaration of Estonian independence and the restoration of independence respectively The act of 1919 was primarily concerned with the transferral of land ownership from Baltic Germans to ethnic Estonians The 1991 act was instead aimed at the transfer of land ownership from the state having been nationalised under Soviet occupation to private individuals based on historic land ownership in 1940 as well as the protection of the legal rights of the present users of land Finland edit In the general reparcelling out of land begun in 1757 when Finland was a part of the Swedish Empire the medieval model of all fields consisting of numerous strips each belonging to a farm was replaced by a model of fields and forest areas each belonging to a single farm 28 In the further reparcellings which started in 1848 when Finland was part of the Russian Empire the idea of concentrating all the land in a farm to a single piece of real estate was reinforced In these reparcelling processes the land is redistributed in direct proportion to earlier prescription 29 Both the general reparcelling and the further reparcelling processes are still active in some parts of the country and a new reparcelling can be initiated when the local need for such reparcelling arises 30 After the Finnish Civil War when Finland had become independent a series of land reforms followed These included the compensated transfer of lease holdings torppa to the leasers and prohibition of forestry companies to acquire land The reforms led to greater economic equality 31 After the Second World War Karelians evacuated from areas ceded to the Soviet Union were given land in remaining Finnish areas taken from public and private holdings with less than full compensation to the previous owners Also the war veterans and their widows benefited from these allotments In addition land could be provided to farms considered too small The land could be acquired either via a voluntary purchase by the state or via expropriation As a result of post WWII land reform 30 000 new farms were established 33 000 small farms received more land and 67 000 families received either a plot for a single family home or a homestead with some arable land 32 Germany edit Main article Land reform in Germany nbsp Population and urban population of Germany 1700 to 1950 Land reform in Germany can be seen as three separate but connected movements that build on each other chronologically Peasants were first liberated from serfdom in the Prussian reforms from 1763 until 1859 Following rapid urbanization in Europe several influential social economists such as Karl Marx Friedrich Engels Karl Kautsky and Eduard Bernstein began to discuss land reforms in the 1830s Their theories inspired private settlements and official government programms for the so called Binnenkolonisierung interior colonization whereby wasteland could be transformed into homesteads for the poor Finally land was collectivized under the East German Bodenreform between 1956 and 1975 but West German agriculture remained largely unchanged Ireland edit Main article Irish Land Acts At the 19th century most of the land in Ireland belonged to large landowners most of them of English origin Most of the Irish population were tenants having few rights and forced to pay high rents This situation was a contributory factor to the Great Irish Famine of 1845 1852 and the main cause of the Land Wars of 1870s 1890s 33 The governments of the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Ireland responded to the agitations in Ireland with a series of land acts beginning with the Landlord and Tenant Ireland Act 1870 initiated by prime minister William Ewart Gladstone followed by further five land acts overseen by a Land Commission prior to independence in 1922 by which time over 90 of lands had transferred from landlords to their former tenant farmers on negotiated terms with funding provided by the UK government 34 Italy edit See also Land reform in the Roman republic and Land reform in Sicily Land reform has been a long standing and widespread problem before the 20th century especially in Southern Italy Despite the vain attempts of the governments to redistribute the land in Southern Italy the so called Mezzogiorno from the pragmatic decree De administratione Universitatum 1792 of Ferdinand I of the Two Sicilies to the law Leggi eversive delle feudalita which literally means laws abolishing feudalism in 1806 1808 enacted by Joseph Bonaparte the issue remained largely unsolved mainly because of the strenuous opposition of the great landowners unwilling to lose their privileges and to allow the emancipation of the peasant class Even with the Unification of Italy despite the promises of the abolition of the so called latifondi large estates the problem remained unsolved Southern Italy s big landowners which had been loyal to the Bourbons until the 1860 actively contributed to the unification of Italy in order to not lose its prestige and expropriating estates from them would have implied for the Kingdom of Italy 1861 1946 to have a powerful enemy 35 Southern Italy s peasants disappointed and irritated rebelled and provoked a bloody civil war known as Post Unification Brigandage The first effective land reform was carried out in 1950 right after the birth of the Italian Republic Italian Parliament passed the decree legge stralcio n 841 del 21 ottobre 1950 which provided the legal basis for land expropriation and redistribution The redistribution occurred over a longer period of time about 10 20 years The decree financed in part with the funds of Marshall Plan launched by the United States in 1947 but also opposed by conservative members of the American administration 36 probably was according to some scholars the most important reform of the aftermath of World War II 37 The decree provided that the land had to be distributed to peasants through compulsory purchase thus turning them into small entrepreneurs no longer subjected to large landowners On one side the reform had a positive outcome to the population but on the other side it also considerably reduced Italian farms size reducing the chances for bigger companies to grow However this drawback was attenuated and in some cases eliminated by implementing forms of cooperation Agricultural cooperatives started to spread and since then agriculture turned into an entrepreneurial business which could expand plan its production and centralize the sale of products After the land reform of 1950 large estates latifondi in some regions of Italy by law cannot be bigger than 300 ha 740 acres 38 Before the 1950 large estates were widespread especially in Southern Italy Nowadays large estate aren t present anymore on Italy s territory citation needed For example in Sicily before the 1950 estates larger than 500 ha 1 200 acres later averaged at about 230 ha 570 acres 39 Moreover 20 6 percent of the island s land was owned by only 282 big landowners 40 In the region Abruzzo large estates were also widespread The most notable case is perhaps the estate of the Torlonia family which owned large estates near Piana del Fucino its size was more than 14 000 ha 35 000 acres and it was redistributed to 5 000 Italian families of landless farmers 41 A 2022 study found that the post WWII land reform fueled comparative underdevelopment and precarity locally over the long term Several related mechanisms delayed development in land reform zones a slower transition out of agriculture lower labor mobility and an aging demographic 42 Russia and the Soviet Union edit See also Agriculture in Russia The Emancipation reform of 1861 effected during the reign of Alexander II of Russia abolished serfdom throughout the Russian Empire More than 23 million people received their liberty Serfs were granted the full rights of free citizens gaining the rights to marry without having to gain consent to own property and to own a business The Manifesto prescribed that peasants would be able to buy the land from the landlords Until the beginning of the 20th century the vast majority of Russian peasants held their land in communal ownership within peasant communities called mirs which acted as village governments and cooperatives Arable land was divided in sections based on soil quality and distance from the village Each household had the right to claim one or more strips from each section depending on the number of adults in the household This communal system was abolished in 1906 by the capitalist oriented Stolypin reforms The reforms introduced the unconditional right of individual landownership They encouraged peasants to buy their share of the community lands leave the communities and settle in privately owned settlements called Khutors By 1910 the share of private settlements among all rural households in the European Russia was estimated at 10 5 The Stolypin reforms and the majority of their benefits were reversed after the October Revolution of 1917 The Decree on Land issued by Vladimir Lenin s new Bolshevik government and the Fundamental Law of Land Socialization of 1918 decreed that private ownership of land is totally abolished land may not be sold purchased leased mortgaged or otherwise alienated All land whether state crown monastery church factory entailed private public peasant etc shall be confiscated without compensation and become the property of the whole people and pass into the use of all those who cultivate it These decrees were superseded by the 1922 Land Code of the Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic After the universal agricultural collectivization land codes of the Soviet republics lost their significance See Agriculture in the Soviet Union After winning World War II and occupying much of Central and Eastern Europe the Soviet Union implemented similar collectivization policies in its new satellite states in the Eastern Bloc 43 After the dissolution of the Soviet Union a new land code was enacted allowing private land ownership Latvia edit See also Latvian Land Reform of 1920 The Latvian Land Reform of 1920 was a land reform act expropriating land under the first Republic of Latvia in 1920 during the Latvian War of Independence shortly after independence The agrarian reform law of 1920 sought to transfer most of the land from Baltic German nobles to Latvian farmers On September 16 1920 Constitutional Assembly of Latvia passed the law of the Land reform which would break up large landholdings and redistribute land to those peasants who worked it and to the newly created Latvian State Land Fund 44 Sweden edit See also Great Partition Sweden and Agriculture in Sweden History In 1757 the general reparcelling out of land began In this process the medieval principle of dividing all the fields in a village into strips each belonging to a farm was changed into a principle of each farm consisting of a few relatively large areas of land The land was redistributed in proportion to earlier possession of land while uninhabited forests far from villages were socialized In the 20th century Sweden almost non violently arrived at regulating the length minimum of tenant farming contracts at 25 years Ukraine edit In Ukraine a debate around the land reform has lasted for more than 20 years and it is still not over Olena Bogdan 2011 45 Ukraine has nearly as much farmland as France and Germany combined 46 Before the dissolution of the Soviet Union in December 1991 Ukrainian farmers worked on collective farms and a free market had only existed for around a year 47 48 In the aftermath of the dissolution more than 6 million Ukrainians received plots of arable land getting between two and three hectares each In 2001 a ban was imposed on sales of farmland in order to deter speculation The law also prevented the farmers from using farmland as collateral for bank loans The 2001 law has also prevented the government from selling millions of additional hectares Only five other countries in the world among them China and North Korea 49 50 have maintained similar restrictions on the sale of private agricultural land 51 52 The European Court for Human Rights ruled in the May 2018 judgement of Zelenchuk and Tsytsyura v Ukraine that the ban violates the Ukrainian Constitution by preventing owners from fully exercising their property rights 52 The Groysman Government pledged in July 2017 to lift the ban on sales of farmland 53 According to a 2020 estimate of the World Bank a land reform programme could bring an increase up to 1 5 in GDP 54 The party Batkivshchyna pledged in 2018 to initiate a nationwide referendum to stop the lifting of the ban on sales of farmland 55 In July 2019 President Volodymyr Zelenskyy wanted the reforms of the land laws to pass before 2020 56 need quotation to verify 57 need quotation to verify A brawl broke out in the Verkhovna Rada Ukraine s parliament on 6 February 2020 over the bill 58 The Verkhovna Rada terminated the Honcharuk Government on 5 March 2020 and pledged the passage of legislation sought by the International Monetary Fund to lift the ban on sales of agricultural land 59 The Honcharuk Government had appeared to be too weak to pass the necessary reforms through the Verkhovna Rada during several weeks of protest by agriculturalists even in spite of Zelenskyy s personal appearances 51 In March 2020 the IMF was still concerned about the pace of land reforms 60 Ukraine in 2020 needed to repay 17 billion of foreign loans and the International Monetary Fund pressured the government to enact laws which would hasten land reform in exchange for a 5 5 billion loan package 61 On 31 March 2020 the Verkhovna Rada adopted a law introducing amendments on the sale of agricultural land 62 Per the law the moratorium on the sale of agricultural land was lifted on 1 July 2021 62 From July 2021 until 1 January 2024 however no more than 100 hectares can be purchased per person and only individuals living in Ukraine will be able to buy land 62 63 United Kingdom edit Advocates of land reform in Britain have included the 17th century Diggers John Stuart Mill Alfred Russel Wallace and Jesse Collings Currently when the Labour Land Campaign 64 promotes the case for a land value tax one of the results of which would be some land reform The Green Party of England and Wales 65 66 and the Scottish Green Party support land value tax Currently aristocrats still own a third of England and Wales 67 Scotland edit Main article Land Reform in Scotland In the 21st century land reform in Scotland has focused on the abolition and modernisation of Scotland s antiquated feudal land tenure system security of tenure for crofters and decentralisation of Scotland s highly concentrated private land ownership 68 Scotland s land reform is distinct from other contemporary land reforms in its focus on community land ownership 69 70 with the Land Reform Scotland Acts of 2003 and 2016 establishing the Community Right to Buy allowing rural and urban communities first right of refusal to purchase local land when it comes up for sale Crofting communities are granted a similar Right to Buy though they do not require a willing seller to buy out local crofting land 71 Under the Community Empowerment Scotland Act 2015 and Land Reform Scotland Act 2016 Scottish ministers can grant a compulsory sale order for vacant or derelict private land or land which if owned by the local community could further sustainable development 72 73 Africa editEthiopia edit Main article Land reform in Ethiopia Historically Ethiopia was divided into the northern highlands which constituted the core of the old Christian kingdom and the southern highlands most of which were brought under imperial rule by conquest In the northern regions the major form of ownership was a type of communal system known as rist According to this system all descendants of an individual founder were entitled to a share and individuals had the right to use a plot of family land Rist was hereditary inalienable and inviolable No user of any piece of land could sell his or her share outside the family or mortgage or bequeath his or her share as a gift as the land belonged not to the individual but to the descent group Most peasants in the northern highlands held at least some rist land Absentee landlordism was rare and landless tenants were estimated at only about 20 of holdings On the contrary in the southern provinces few farmers owned the land on which they worked After the conquest officials divided southern land equally among the state the church and the indigenous population Tenancy in the southern provinces ranged between 65 and 80 of the holdings and tenant payments to landowners averaged as high as 50 of the produce In the Eastern Lowland periphery and the Great Rift Valley most land were used for grazing The pastoral social structure is based on a kinship system with strong interclan connections grazing and water rights are regulated by custom Beginning in the 1950s the government tried to modernize the agriculture by granting large tracts of traditional grazing lands to large corporations and converting them into large scale commercial farms In the north and south peasant farmers lacked the means to improve production because of the fragmentation of holdings a lack of credit and the absence of modern facilities Particularly in the south the insecurity of tenure and high rents killed the peasants incentive to improve production Further those attempts by the Imperial government to improve the peasant s title to their land were often met with suspicion By the mid 1960s many sectors of Ethiopian society favored land reform University students led the land reform movement and campaigned against the government s reluctance to introduce land reform programs and the lack of commitment to integrated rural development In 1974 the socialist Derg government rose to power and on March 4 1975 the Derg announced its land reform program The government nationalized rural land without compensation abolished tenancy forbade the hiring of wage labor on private farms ordered all commercial farms to remain under state control and granted each peasant family so called possessing rights to a plot of land not to exceed ten hectares The Ethiopian Orthodox Church lost all its land Although the Derg gained little respect during its rule this reform resulted in a rare show of support for the junta Tenant farmers in southern Ethiopia welcomed the land reform but in the northern highlands many people resisted land reform and perceived it as an attack on their rights to rist land The lowland peripheries were only slightly affected by the reforms The land reform destroyed the feudal order It changed landowning patterns particularly in the south in favor of peasants and small landowners It also provided the opportunity for peasants to participate in local matters by permitting them to form associations Kenya edit The colonial administration in Kenya implemented a land documentation system in the early 1900s In the 1970s politicians engaged in extensive sales and exploitation of fraudulent land documents By the late 1990s the land documentation system had fallen into disrepute due to extensive fraud 74 Two land reforms occurred amid the Mau Mau uprising The first in the mid 1950s allowed Africans to consolidate and gain individual legal titles to their land The second enabled Africans to buy land from Europeans many of whom sought to liquidate their holdings in Kenya prior to Kenyan independence 75 In the 1960s president Jomo Kenyatta launched a peaceful land reform program based on willing buyer willing seller It was funded by the United Kingdom the former colonial power In 2006 president Mwai Kibaki said it will repossess all land owned by absentee landlords in the coastal strip and redistribute it to squatters 76 A 2023 study found that over the course of independent Kenyan history democratic governments engaged in greater formalization of land rights than autocratic regimes and that democratic governments tended to formalize land rights to gain the support of pivotal swing voters 77 Namibia edit Main article Land reform in Namibia Namibia s colonial past had resulted in substantial land inequality 78 where about 20 of the population mostly white settlers owned about 75 percent of all the land 79 In 1990 shortly after Namibia achieved independence from South Africa its first president Sam Nujoma initiated a plan for land reform in which land would be redistributed from whites to blacks Legislation passed in September 1994 with a compulsory compensated approach 80 The land reform has been slow mainly because Namibia s constitution only allows land to be bought from farmers willing to sell Also the price of land is very high in Namibia which further complicates the matter By 2007 some 12 of the total commercial farmland in the country was taken away from white Namibian farmers and given to black citizens South Africa edit Main article Land Reform in South Africa The Natives Land Act of 1913 prohibited the establishment of new farming operations sharecropping or cash rentals by blacks outside of the reserves 81 where they were forced to live In 1991 after a long anti apartheid struggle led by the African National Congress State President F W de Klerk declared the repeal of several apartheid rules particularly the Population Registration Act the Group Areas Act and the Natives Land Act A catch all Abolition of Racially Based Land Measures Act was passed 82 These measures ensured no one could claim or be deprived of any land rights on the basis of race In 1994 shortly after the African National Congress came to power in South Africa in the first general election it initiated a land reform process focused on three areas restitution land tenure reform and land redistribution 81 83 Restitution where the government compensates monetary individuals who had been forcefully removed has been very unsuccessful and the policy has now shifted to redistribution Initially land was bought from its owners willing seller by the government willing buyer and redistributed in order to maintain public confidence in the land market 81 This system has proved to be very difficult to implement because many owners do not actually see the land they are purchasing and are not involved in the important decisions made at the beginning of the purchase and negotiation In 2000 the South African Government decided to review and change the redistribution and tenure process to a more decentralized and area based planning process The idea is to have local integrated development plans in 47 districts 84 Zimbabwe edit Main article Land reform in Zimbabwe The 1930 Land Apportionment Act restricted the areas of Zimbabwe then known as Southern Rhodesia where black people could legally purchase land Large segments of the country were set aside for the exclusive ownership of the white minority 85 By 1979 when Zimbabwe gained independence 46 5 of the country s arable land was owned by around 6 000 commercial farmers 86 and white farmers who made up less than 1 of the population owned 70 of the best farming land 87 As part of the Lancaster House Agreement of 1979 president Robert Mugabe initiated a willing buyer willing seller plan in which white land owners were encouraged to sell their lands to the government with partial funding from Britain 88 Around 71 000 families perhaps 500 000 people settled on 3 5 million hectares of former white owned land under this programme which was described by The Economist in 1989 as perhaps the most successful aid programme in Africa 89 The 1992 Land Acquisition Act was enacted to speed up the land reform process by removing the willing seller willing buyer clause limiting the size of farms and introducing a land tax although the tax was never implemented 90 The Act empowered the government to buy land compulsorily for redistribution and a fair compensation was to be paid for land acquired Landowners could challenge in court the price set by the acquiring authority Opposition by landowners increased throughout the period of 1992 to 1997 In the 1990s less than 1 million hectares 2 47 million acres were acquired and fewer than 20 000 families were resettled Much of the land acquired during what has become known as phase one of land reform was of poor quality according to Human Rights Watch Only 19 percent of the almost 3 5 million hectares 8 65 million acres of resettled land was considered prime or farmable In 1997 the new British government led by Tony Blair unilaterally stopped funding the willing buyer willing seller land reform programme Britain s ruling Labour Party felt no obligation to continue paying white farmers compensation In 2000 a referendum on constitutional amendments was held The proposed amendments called for a fast track land reform and allowed the government to confiscate white owned land for redistribution to black farmers without compensation The motion failed with 55 of participants against the referendum 91 However self styled war veterans led by Chenjerai Hunzvi began invading white owned farms Those who did not leave voluntarily were often tortured and sometimes killed 92 On 6 April 2000 Parliament pushed through an amendment taken word for word from the draft constitution that was rejected by voters allowing the seizure of white owned farmlands without due reimbursement or payment 93 In this first wave of farm invasions a total of 110 000 square kilometres of land had been seized Parliament dominated by Zanu PF passed a constitutional amendment signed into law on 12 September 2005 that nationalised farmland acquired through the Fast Track process and deprived original landowners of the right to challenge in court the government s decision to expropriate their land 94 The Supreme Court of Zimbabwe ruled against legal challenges to this amendment 95 During the fast track many parcels of land came under the control of people close to the government The several forms of forcible change in management caused a severe drop in production and other economic disruptions North America editCanada edit Main articles Land Purchase Act 1875 and Land Question Prince Edward Island A land reform was carried out as part of Prince Edward Island s agreement to join the Canadian Confederation in 1873 Most of the land was owned by absentee landlords in England and as part of the deal Canada was to buy all the land and give it to the farmers United States edit Main articles Forty acres and a mule and Dawes Act Following the American Civil War many African Americans and Union Army officials considered land reform vital The downfall of the Confederacy and the abolition of slavery with the Thirteenth Amendment emancipated millions but few former slaves had the means to exercise real autonomy Land even at depressed post war prices was difficult for African Americans to procure 96 At the same time with southern wealth the result of centuries of forced labor blacks nationwide called for property on the basis of just reparations 97 Politically redistribution carried the support of Radical Republicans 98 But opposing any grants to blacks were southern Democrats along with President Andrew Johnson s administration committed to restoration 99 100 Given national divisions reform efforts were varied but short lived Many African Americans believed property was critical to erasing slave oriented social order 101 In addition to speaking out some demanded plots and moved into their master s plantation homes by force 102 Others bought land collectively or squatted on what was undeveloped 103 Throughout war and Reconstruction the presence of Federal troops provided a platform for agricultural policy In 1865 William Tecumseh Sherman issued Field Order 15 taking coastal land in South Carolina Georgia and Florida and dividing it into 40 acre plots for black settlement hence the term 40 acres and a mule 104 In March Congress established the Freedmen s Bureau whose commissioner had authority to redistribute confiscated or abandoned southern land 105 The Bureau held 850 000 acres 3 400 km2 and key directors pushed for its settling with former slaves When President Johnson began to pardon Confederates and restore their property Commissioner Oliver O Howard issued Circular 13 The order instructed agents to establish 40 acre parcels with haste Johnson rescinded the order and an overwhelming majority of Bureau land returned to its previous owners 106 The final reform attempts of Reconstruction occurred within state governments In South Carolina a land commission was established which purchased property and sold it on long term credit 107 Other state Republicans utilized new tax systems penalizing large estates to seize and divide land and stimulate black ownership This indirect method achieved little as taxes were repaid and lands were reclaimed Of property not redeemed much was exploited by investors 108 Radicals began to fall even earlier with the failure of Johnson s impeachment Liberal Republicans eroding the era s political landscape called for an immediate end to black barbarism 109 110 White supremacist violence and the Long Depression 111 weakened Reconstruction to the breaking point With the Compromise of 1877 it was finished 112 In the 19th century Native American tribes owned about 138 million acres 560 000 km2 of land in the USA Land was considered the property of the whole tribe which used it to cater to the needs of the individual tribe members This approach to land ownership was different than the white European approach which regarded land as private property of individuals citation needed Many US politicians who believed it was important to assimilate Native Americans into white American culture and thus have their lands open for commerce and development The Dawes Act also known as the General Allotment Act or the Dawes Severalty Act adopted by Congress in 1887 authorized the President of the United States to survey Native American tribal land and divide it into allotments for individual Indians Those who accepted allotments and lived separately from the tribe would be granted United States citizenship The Dawes Act was amended in 1891 and again in 1906 by the Burke Act Through the Dawes Act many Indians received private title to a land plot but most of the Indian lands were considered surplus and put to sale to white European settlers Thus the total amount of land owned by Indians decreased to only 48 million acres 190 000 km2 in 1934 citation needed Most tribal land still owned by ethnic Indians was recollectivized in 1934 East Asia editMainland China edit Main article Chinese Land Reform Since the fall of the Qing dynasty in the 1911 Revolution China has been through a series of land reform programs The founder of the Nationalist Party Sun Yat sen advocated a land to the tiller program of equal distribution of land which was partly implemented by the Nationalist government under Chiang Kai shek In the 1940s the Sino American Joint Commission on Rural Reconstruction funded with American money with the support of the national government carried out land reform and community action programs in several provinces In October 1947 two years before the foundation of the People s Republic of China PRC the Chinese Communist Party launched land reform campaigns that established control in North China villages In the mid 1950s a second land reform during the Great Leap Forward compelled individual farmers to join collectives which in turn were grouped into People s communes with centrally controlled property rights and an egalitarian principle of distribution This policy was generally a failure in terms of production 113 The PRC reversed this policy in 1962 through the proclamation of the Sixty Articles As a result the ownership of the basic means of production was divided into three levels with collective land ownership vested in the production team see also Ho 2001 A third land reform beginning in the late 1970s re introduced the family based contract system known as the Household Responsibility System was followed by a period of stagnation Chen Wang and Davis 1998 suggest that the stagnation was due in part to a system of periodic redistributions that encouraged over exploitation rather than private capital investment in future productivity 113 However although land use rights were returned to individual farmers collective land ownership was left undefined after the disbandment of the People s Communes Since 1983 China has launched a series of land policy reforms to improve land use efficiency to rationalize land allocation to enhance land management and to coordinate urban and rural development These land policy reforms have yielded positive impacts on urban land use as well as negative socioeconomic consequences On the positive side they have contributed to emerging land markets increased government revenue for the financing of massive infrastructure projects and provision of public goods and improved the rationalization of land use On the negative side problems such as loss of social equity socioeconomic conflicts and government corruption have emerged 114 Since 1998 China is in the midst of drafting the new Property Law which is the first piece of national legislation that will define the land ownership structure in China for years to come The Property Law forms the basis for China s future land policy of establishing a system of freehold rather than of private ownership see also Ho 2005 Taiwan edit Main article Land reform in TaiwanSee also Taiwan Land Reform Museum In the 1950s after the Kuomintang retreat to Taiwan land reform and community development was carried out by the Sino American Joint Commission on Rural Reconstruction This course of action was made attractive in part by the fact that many of the large landowners were Japanese who had fled and the other large landowners were compensated with Japanese commercial and industrial properties seized after Taiwan reverted from Japanese rule in 1945 The land program succeeded also because the Kuomintang were mostly from the mainland and had few ties to the remaining indigenous landowners Japan edit The first land reform in recent history called the Land Tax Reform or chisokaisei 地租改正 passed in 1873 six years after the Meiji Restoration It established the right of private land ownership in Japan for the first time and was a major restructuring of the previous land taxation system The government initially ordered individual farmers to measure the plots of their land themselves calculate their taxes and submit the results to local tax officials However difficulties arose with the honesty of the measuring system and the government responded by forcefully changing land values to meet the set amount if self reported values did not meet projected values This caused widespread resentment among farmers and several large scale riots causing the government to lower the tax rate from 3 to 2 5 The department continued its aggressive taxation until 1878 but the strictness of rules gradually decreased as it became clear that required amounts would be met By 1880 seven years after the start of the land reforms the new system had been completely implemented Private land ownership was recognized for the first time in Japan with the issuing of land titles Previously individual farmers were merely borrowing the land from feudal lords who in turn were borrowing the land from the emperor The reform abolished this archaic system of land ownership and began to allow landowners to use their property as a financial asset in collateral or other investment This law was one of the first steps towards the development of capitalism in Japan paralleling the English and later United Kingdom statute Quia Emptores enacted several centuries earlier Another major land reform was carried out in 1947 during the occupied era after World War II under instructions of the Supreme Commander of the Allied Powers based on a proposal from the Japanese government which had been prepared before the defeat of the Greater Japanese Empire This last reform is also called Nōchi kaihō 農地解放 emancipation of farming land Between 1947 and 1949 approximately 5 800 000 acres 23 000 km2 of land approximately 38 of Japan s cultivated land was purchased from the landlords under the reform program and re sold at extremely low prices after inflation to the farmers who worked them By 1950 three million peasants had acquired land dismantling a power structure that the landlords had long dominated 115 South Korea edit From 1945 to 1950 United States Army Military Government in Korea and First Republic of Korea authorities carried out a land reform that retained the institution of private property They confiscated and redistributed all land held by the Japanese colonial government Japanese companies and individual Japanese colonists The Korean government carried out a reform whereby Koreans with large landholdings were obliged to divest most of their land A new class of independent family proprietors was created North Korea edit By the end of the Second World War 58 of arable land in North Korea was privately owned by Japanese colonists and Korean feudal landlords comprising 4 of the population On March 5 1946 the North Korean Provisional People s Committee enacted the 1946 Land Reform Law whereby both Japanese colonists would have their entire estate expropriated and Korean landlords in possession of more than 50 000 square meters of land would have their estates expropriated and distributed to existing tenant farmers for free abolishing the existing tenant farming system In just one month the Provisional People s Committee of North Korea and the Workers Party of North Korea led land reform by organizing 90 697 members into 11 500 farming committees They organized 210 000 farmers into self defense forces who supported the work of the farming committees During three weeks of land reform 98 percent of confiscated land was distributed to farmers who in turn became the possessors of up to 13 200 square meters of land and over one million hectares of land were expropriated The early land reform may have been partially intended to prepare for the Korean War by improving the South Korean public s perception of the Communist government in the north as well as by providing large stockpiles of food 116 During the 1954 58 transition period farm holdings went through three progressively collective phases permanent mutual aid teams semisocialist cooperatives and complete socialist cooperatives In the final stage all land and farm implements were owned collectively by the members of each cooperative The pace of collectivization quickened during 1956 and by the end of that year about 80 of all farmland was cooperatively owned By August 1958 more than 13 300 cooperatives with an average of eighty households and 130 hectares of land dotted the countryside In October 1958 the Workers Party of Korea government increased the size of the average cooperative to 300 households managing 500 hectares of land through consolidation of all farms in each village 117 118 Southeast Asia editCambodia edit Hun Sen implemented land reform the leopard skin land reform in Cambodia 119 Hun Sen s government has been responsible for leasing 45 of the total landmass in Cambodia primarily to foreign investors in the years 2007 08 threatening more than 150 000 Cambodians with eviction Parts of the concessions are protected wildlife areas or national parks and have driven deforestation across the country 120 121 122 123 As of 2015 Cambodia had one of the highest rates of forest loss in the world 124 The land sales have been perceived by observers as government corruption and have resulted in thousands of citizens being forcibly evicted 125 126 According to Alice Beban the land reform strengthened patronage politics in Cambodia and did not enable land tenure security 119 Philippines edit Main article Land reform in the Philippines During the Macapagal administration in the early 1960s a limited land reform program was initiated in Central Luzon covering rice fields During the martial law era of the Ferdinand Marcos Administration Presidential Decree 27 signed in 1972 instituted a land reform program covering less than 14 of cultivated lands 127 Rice and corn production under this land reform program was supported by the Marcos Administration with land distribution and financing program known as the Masagana 99 and other production loans that briefly increased in rice and corn production Costly subsidies and a faulty credit scheme led to the program benefiting only 3 7 of the country s small rice farmers by 1980 128 129 General Order 47 and Presidential Decree 472 were signed in 1974 to launch corporate farming programs that undermined the land reform program 127 The Corazon Aquino Administration in the mid 1980s instituted a very controversial land reform known as the Comprehensive Agrarian Reform Program CARP which covered all agricultural lands The program led to rice shortages in the succeeding years and lasted for 20 years without accomplishing the goal of land distribution The program caused entrepreneurs to stay away from agriculture and a number of productive farmers left the farming sector The CARP was a monumental failure in terms of cost to the government and the landowners whose lands were subjective to legal landgrabbing by the government CARP expired at the end of December 2008 130 Thailand edit Thailand first spoke of land reform after the Siamese revolution of 1932 by Pridi Banomyong 131 but was seen as a communist idea And it was mentioned again after the 1973 Thai popular uprising resulting in the drafting and promulgation the Agricultural Land Reform Act of 1975 132 and the Agricultural Land Reform Office was established on March 6 1975 under the Ministry of Agriculture and Cooperatives Vietnam edit Main articles Land reform in Vietnam Land reform in South Vietnam and Land reform in North Vietnam In the years after World War II land redistribution to poor and landless peasants was initiated by the communist Viet Minh insurgents in areas which they controlled After the partition of the country into two parts North Vietnam and South Vietnam under the Geneva Accords the communist land reform 1953 1956 redistributed land to more than 2 million poor peasants but at a cost of thousands possibly tens of thousands of lives 133 and contributed to the exodus of up to 1 million people from the North to the South in 1954 and 1955 citation needed The land reform campaign was accompanied by large scale repression and excesses 134 some of which were subsequently criticized within the ruling Workers Party of North Vietnam itself 134 135 136 South Vietnam made several further attempts in the post Diem years the most ambitious being the Land to the Tiller program instituted in 1970 by President Nguyen Van Thieu This limited individuals to 15 hectares compensated the owners of expropriated tracts and extended legal title to peasants who in areas under control of the South Vietnamese government to whom had land had previously been distributed by the Viet Cong Summary table editThe following table summarizes many land reforms that are not mentioned in this page The color in the Year column is darker for earlier periods and brighter for later periods Region place Reformer Year Ideology motivations Actions OutcomesMiddle East Egypt Joseph 1500 Monarchism Strengthen the Pharaoh Nationalization Joseph bought all lands for Pharaoh Egyptian peasants became serfs of PharaohMiddle East Egypt Bakenranef 720 Social Justice Help the peasants Freedom to peasants Land alienability Debt annulment Bakenranef murdered reforms undoneEurope Greece Athens Solon 575 Stabilization Help the poor Prevent an uprising Freedom to peasants Debt annulment Forbid slavery of Athenians poverty somewhat alleviatedEurope Greece Athens Peisistratos 560 Centralization Help the poor strengthening the tyrant Land redistribution from rich to poor Athenian aristocracy weakened poverty somewhat reducedEurope Greece Sparta Agis IV Cleomenes III 244 227 Centralization Help the poor strengthening the army Land redistribution Debt annulment Reformer kings murdered by opponents reforms undoneEurope Italy Rome Gracchi brothers 133 121 Social Justice Help the landless soldiers Land redistribution Enforcement of land ceiling law Reformer tribunes murdered by Senate reforms undoneEurope Austria Habsburg monarchy Maria Theresa and Joseph II 1680 1790 Enlightenment Liberate peasants increase tax revenues Freedom to peasants Abolish serfdom duties nobles did not cooperate and laws were not enforcedEurope France Savoy Victor Amadeus II 1720 1793 Economics Increase royal income Weaken the nobility Freedom to peasants Abolish serfdom duties Confiscate lands from lords All estates were at least partially emancipatedEurope Prussia various 1763 1850 Economics Modernize the state by improving the peasants conditions Freedom to peasants from serfdom duties Enable serfs to become free landlords nobles bought much more land than peasantsEurope Italy Sicily various 1773 1865 Enlightenment Liberate the peasants and strengthen the king Nationalize noble lands Reduce duties of peasants to landlords Abolish private landlord armies Distribute common lands to poor peasants The rich bought most lands and became richer the Sicilian Mafia was born Europe Austria Austrian empire Constituent Assembly 1849 Enlightenment Liberate peasants Freedom to peasants subsidized purchase of their lands feudal law abolished but most land remained concentrated with the noblesLatin America Mexico Miguel Lerdo Porfirio Diaz 1856 1910 Liberalism and economics Forced sale of corporately held property specifically lands held by the Catholic Church and indigenous communities Changed the nature of land tenure in Mexico Most native owned land was acquired by large estates 95 of villages lost their lands Europe Russia Russian empire Alexander II 1861 Enlightenment Liberate peasants Freedom to peasants subsidized purchase of their lands More than 23 million people received their liberty but many of them received land insufficient for survival and became proletariatEurope Britain Ireland William Ewart Gladstone UK government 1870 1922 Social justice Historic justice to Irish natives Land transfer from large English landlords to their Irish tenants funded by UK government By 1922 over 90 of lands had been transferredEurope Russia Russian empire Stolypin 1906 1916 Economics Encourage private property and capitalism Liquidize communal villages Divide lands to individual peasants Private land holdings increased but reforms were reversed after Soviet revolutionLatin America Mexico after revolution Alvaro Obregon Lazaro Cardenas 1910 1940 Social justice Decentralization Lessening inequality Allocate land to peasants in need of it Reversed the process of land concentration reduced the power and legitimacy of the landlord class Much land was allocated to peasants Production increased Europe Russia Soviet union Lenin 1917 Communism Abolish private property Private ownership of land was prohibited Private land holdings increased but reforms were reversed after Soviet revolutionEurope Albania Albania Post WW2 government 1946 Social justice Lessening inequality Constitutional Reforms Land to the tiller Disallowed large estates By 1954 more than 90 of land was held in small and mid sized farms Southeast Asia Philippines various 1946 2014 Social justice Lessening inequality Land redistribution laws Some lands were distributed to landless peasants but agricultural production suffered East Asia Taiwan Chiang Monlin Y C James Yen 1950s Modernization Community development Established the JCRR Agricultural development programs Co operative formation Rural credit programs The JCRR is credited with laying the agricultural basis for Taiwan s outstanding economic growth in the following decadesMiddle East Egypt Nasser 1952 1961 Social justice Lessening inequality Land redistribution 15 of arable land redistributed reforms undone after change of governmentSoutheast Asia Vietnam North Hồ Chi Minh 1953 1956 Communism Break the power of the traditional village elite Landlords were murdered by government Land redistributed to peasants Thousands were killed and 1 million people fled to the SouthLatin America Guatemala Juan Jose Arevalo Jacobo Arbenz 1953 1954 Social justice Lessening inequality Expropriation of land Redistribution to peasants The reform itself was successful but a later US backed coup reversed it entirely Latin America Bolivia Victor Paz EstenssoroEvo Morales 1953 2006 Social justice Expanding indigenous rights Abolished forced peasantry labor Distribute rural property of traditional landlords to indigenous peasants Organized peasants into armed militias By 1970 45 of peasant families had received title to land The reform goes on Europe Albania Albania Enver Hoxha 1958 1962 Communism Collectivization drive Most agricultural lands were shifted to Soviet style collective and state farms By 1971 independent family farms had virtually disappearedLatin America Cuba Che Guevara 1959 1963 Communism Nationalization of large estates Redistribution to peasants Land ceiling Peasants were given land rights but these rights are constrained by government production quotas and a prohibition of real estate transactionsSouth Asia India Hare Krishna Konar E M S Namboodiripad and others 1961 Economics Modernize the agriculture End the exploitation of the poor Abolition of rent collectors Secure land tenure Land ceiling Consolidate disparate holdings In parts of India redistribution of land became more equitable in other parts people found loopholes in ceiling laws Latin America Chile Jorge Alessandri citation needed 1962 1973 Social justice Lessening Inequality Nationalization of large estates Redistribution to peasants After the 1973 coup the process was halted and somewhat reversed by market forcesSoutheast Asia Vietnam South Nguyen Van Thieu 1970 Social welfare Gain support from rural population during the Vietnam war Land ceiling Land redistribution with compensation to previous landlords Land was redistributed but law became meaningless 5 years later at the fall of Saigon Africa Ethiopia DERG 1975 Social justice Lessening inequality Nationalization of large estates Redistribution to peasants abolished tenancy End of feudal law strengthening of peasantsOceania Australia various 1976 2004 Social justice Historic justice to Indigenous Australians Several laws giving land rights to Aboriginals Large lands have been returned to AboriginalsEurope Albania Albania Post communist government 1991 Privatization Allow private property Arable land held in cooperatives State owned farms were equally distributed among rural households Land was privatized Europe Russia Russian Federation GorbachevYeltsinPutin 1989 2001 Privatization Allow private property Private ownership of land was re allowed in several stages Private ownership gradually increased but became centralized into the hands of Russian oligarchsLatin America Venezuela Hugo Chavez 2001 2003 Social justice Lessening inequality Redistribute government amp unused private land to campesinos in need 60K families received land titleEurope Britain Scotland Scottish Parliament 2003 Social justice Freedom to farmer communities Farmer communities can buy their lands without landlord consent End of feudal lawSee also editAnti globalization movement Communism Eminent domain Georgism Homestead principle Inclosure Land Banking Land claim Land reform Land Reform in Developing Countries Land rights Land value tax Landless Workers Movement Open field system Restitution SquatterReferences edit The Land Law Bill forward and back Colombia Support Network Matsetela 2000 a b Gleijeses Piero 1989 The Agrarian Reform of Jacobo Arbenz Journal of Latin American Studies 21 3 453 480 doi 10 1017 S0022216X00018514 S2CID 145201357 Markiewicz Dana The Mexican Revolution and the Limits of Land Reform 1915 1946 Boulder Lynne Rienner Publisher 1993 Hunefeldt C A Brief History of Peru New York NY a b c Hunefeldt C A Brief History of Peru New York NY Forero Juan 2009 06 20 In Venezuela Land Rescue Hopes Unmet This Land Was Your Land 13 November 2015 In Venezuela Land Redistribution Program Backfires NPR a b https www oxfamamerica org static media files Paraguay background pdf bare URL PDF https fas org sgp crs row R44936 pdf bare URL PDF a b Paraguay Land Reform and Land Policy Monoculture Soy and the Future of the Paraguayan Campesino HuffPost 25 November 2013 a b Iran Rural Society Country data com Retrieved 2010 06 27 Amid M 1990 Agriculture Poverty and Reform in Iran London Routledge A History of Iraq by Charles Tripp A History of the Modern Middle East William gt Cleveland and Martin Bunton Raimondo Cagiano De Azevedo 1994 Migration and development co operation Council of Europe p 25 ISBN 92 871 2611 9 as quoted in Heydemann 1999 p 193 Authoritarianism in Syria Institutions and Social Conflict 1946 1970 Cornell University Press Ithaca Syria Agriculture Countrystudies us Retrieved 2010 06 27 Hinnebusch R 2001 p 55 Syria Revolution From Above Routledge New York Afghanistan Country Study and Government Publication Afghanistan Country Study Archived from the original on 2012 03 22 Retrieved 2012 12 07 Sri Lanka land reform legislation Country data com Retrieved 2010 06 27 Peiris G H 1978 Land Reform and Agrarian Change in Sri Lanka Modern Asian Studies 12 4 611 628 doi 10 1017 S0026749X0000634X JSTOR 312371 S2CID 144022457 Retrieved 23 August 2022 Sri Lanka land reform disaster made the state the biggest land owner Economynext com Retrieved 23 August 2022 Dreyfus Jean Marc Niznansky Eduard 2011 Jews and non Jews in the Aryanization Process Comparison of France and the Slovak State 1939 45 In Kosmala Beate Verbeeck Georgi eds Facing the Catastrophe Jews and non Jews in Europe during World War II Oxford Berg p 24 ISBN 978 1 84520 471 6 Isojako Etalukio Finnish Board of Education Retrieved 2016 03 15 in Finnish Uusjako hajotti ryhmakylat University of Helsinki Retrieved 2016 03 15 in Finnish Vitikainen A 2003 Uusjakojen kysynnasta ja toimitusmenettelyn uudistamistarpeesta Maanmittaus 78 1 2 5 20 Retrieved 2016 03 15 in Finnish Merilainen Jaakko Mitrunen Matti Virkola Tuomo 2022 Famine Inequality and Conflict Journal of the European Economic Association 21 4 1478 1509 doi 10 1093 jeea jvac069 ISSN 1542 4766 Virtanen P V 2003 MAAREFORMIT itsenaisessa Suomessa Maankaytto 3 2003 p 9 14 Retrieved 2016 03 15 in Finnish The Land War in Ireland A History for the Times Retrieved 25 June 2016 Land Purchase Acts 1903 1909 encyclopedic definitions Tommaso Pedio Latifondo e usi civici prammatica 1792 eversione della feudalita usurpazioni delle terre demaniali adesione dei galantuomini al nuovo regime Retrieved 24 June 2014 Sulla complessa vicenda dell apporto americano Emanuele Bernardi La riforma agraria in Italia e gli Stati Uniti Bologna il Mulino 2006 Corrado Barberis Teoria e storia della riforma agraria Firenze Vallecchi 1957 Fonte Pag 108 del libro Studi sul Mezzogiorno repubblicano storia politica ed analisi Di Luca Bussotti Rubbettino Editore srl 2003 The Edinburgh Journal of Gadda Studies www arts ed ac uk Archived from the original on 18 July 2012 Retrieved 22 May 2022 L Indipendenza della Catalogna e i compiti della sinistra spagnola Fonte Pag 195 di La Geografia Per la scuola Media Volume n 1 G Bacchi A Londrrillo Editore Bulgarini Firenze 1983 Albertus Michael 2022 The Persistence of Rural Underdevelopment Evidence from Land Reform in Italy Comparative Political Studies 56 65 100 doi 10 1177 00104140221089653 S2CID 244675475 Naimark Norman M 1995 The Russians in Germany A History of the Soviet Zone of Occupation 1945 1949 Cambridge Belknap Press p 142 Agrarian Reform in Latvia University Centre for International Studies Bogdan Olena Land Reform and Rural Employment in Ukraine PDF Kyiv School of Economics Retrieved 7 March 2020 Bershidsky Leonid 20 September 2019 Europe s Last Land Frontier Is Opening Up Bloomberg Synovitz Roy 4 April 2000 Ukraine Collective Farm System Proves Entrenched Radio Free Europe Radio Liberty Retrieved 1 June 2022 Dobbs Michael 4 December 1990 PRIVATE LAND OWNERSHIP LEGALIZED IN RUSSIA The Washington Post Retrieved 1 June 2022 Johnson Ian 26 September 2019 Barred From Owning Land Rural Chinese Miss Spoils of Country s Success The New York Times Retrieved 1 June 2022 Land Law of the Democratic People s Republic of Korea 1999 Law and North Korea 16 June 1999 Retrieved 1 June 2022 a b Olearchyk Roman 19 January 2020 Ukraine sows seeds of suspicion with land sale plans The Financial Times THE FINANCIAL TIMES LTD a b Sologoub Ilona 26 November 2019 Ukraine is finally ready to embrace land reform Atlantic Council The sale of private agricultural land has been banned since 2001 Ukraine is one of six countries in the world to maintain this restriction Langley Andrew 4 July 2017 Ukrainian Premier Signals IMF Delay as Key Reform Not Ready Bloomberg EU supports land reform in Ukraine but it should be implemented properly Kyiv Post Interfax Ukraine 6 February 2020 Pole dlya manipulyacij Top 5 mifiv pro zemelnij moratorij vid ukrayinskih politikiv Vox Ukraine 13 March 2018 Winfrey Michael 30 July 2019 Ukraine Turns to Blueprint That Transformed Ex Communist Europe Bloomberg Gomez James M 2 January 2018 Ukraine s Ban on Selling Farmland Is Choking the Economy Bloomberg Brawl erupts in Ukraine parliament over controversial land reform Channel News Asia AFP 6 February 2020 Archived from the original on 7 February 2020 Krasnolutska Daryna 7 March 2020 Ukrainian Leader Backs Calamitous Reshuffle to Deliver Results Bloomberg Ukraine Receives IMF Support But Must Accelerate Reforms International Monetary Fund 4 April 2017 Retrieved 1 June 2022 Talant Bermet 6 March 2020 Hasty government reshuffle sows disquiet at home abroad Kyiv Post a b c Land reform will promote more active lending to agricultural enterprises NBU Ukrinform 16 September 2020 Raczkiewycz Mark 22 August 2021 In Fertile Ukraine A 20 Year Freeze On The Sale Of Farmland Is Lifted With Uncertain Consequences Radio Free Europe Radio Liberty Retrieved 1 June 2022 Labour Land Campaign August 2014 Retrieved 22 May 2015 Policies for a Sustainable Society Land 2000 Retrieved 22 May 2015 Policies for a Sustainable Society Economy 2015 Retrieved 22 May 2015 Country Life research 2010 Independent co uk 23 October 2011 Retrieved 23 July 2020 The Independent Elliot Alison Watt John Ian Cooke Taylor Pip 2014 The Land of Scotland and the Common Good Report of the Land Reform Review Group PDF The Scottish Government Retrieved 4 March 2017 Bryden John Geisler Charles 2007 Community based land reform Lessons from Scotland Land Use Policy 24 24 34 doi 10 1016 j landusepol 2005 09 004 Hoffman Matthew 2013 Why community ownership Understanding land reform in Scotland Land Use Policy 31 289 297 doi 10 1016 j landusepol 2012 07 013 Land Reform Scotland Act 2003 Retrieved 5 March 2017 Community Empowerment Scotland Act 2015 Retrieved 5 March 2017 Land Reform Scotland Act 2016 Retrieved 5 March 2017 Onoma Ato Kwamena 2009 Mahoney James Thelen Kathleen eds The Contradictory Potential of Institutions The Rise and Decline of Land Documentation in Kenya Explaining Institutional Change Ambiguity Agency and Power Cambridge University Press pp 63 93 ISBN 978 0 521 11883 5 Harbeson John W 1971 Land Reforms and Politics in Kenya 1954 70 The Journal of Modern African Studies 9 2 231 251 doi 10 1017 S0022278X00024915 ISSN 0022 278X JSTOR 159442 S2CID 154641256 Joseph Odhiambo 2006 08 22 Pledge to redistribute Kenya land BBC News Retrieved 2010 06 27 Hassan Mai Klaus Kathleen 2023 03 28 Closing The Gap The Politics of Property Rights in Kenya World Politics 75 2 233 279 doi 10 1353 wp 2023 0008 ISSN 1086 3338 S2CID 235702685 Tjirera Ellison 2023 Namibia s Intractable Land Question Current History 122 844 167 171 doi 10 1525 curh 2023 122 844 167 ISSN 0011 3530 William Vincent Namibia Situation Report PDF United Nations High Commission on Refugees Namibia Land Reform to Cost Billions a b c Deininger Klaus Making Negotiated Land Reform Work Initial Experience from Colombia Brazil and South Africa World Development Vol 27 1999 651 672 Ross Robert 1999 A concise history of South Africa Cambridge University Press ISBN 9780521575782 Moseley W G and B McCusker 2008 Fighting Fire with a Broken Tea Cup A Comparative Analysis of South Africa s Land Redistribution Program Geographical Review 98 3 322 338 Hall Ruth Decentralisation in South Africa s Land Redistribution Presentation to the PLAAS regional workshop on Land Reform from Below Decentralisation of Land Reform in Southern Africa Program for land anad agrarian studies Kopanong Conference Centre Kempton Park Johannesburg 23 04 2008 Address Machingaidze Victor E M 1991 Agrarian Change from above The Southern Rhodesia Native Land Husbandry Act and African Response The International Journal of African Historical Studies 24 3 557 588 doi 10 2307 219092 JSTOR 219092 Chigara Ben 2002 Land Reform Policy Ashgate Publishing p 52 ISBN 978 0 7546 2293 2 Britain s troubles with Mugabe BBC News 3 April 2000 Page 302 Big Men Little People The Leaders Who Defined Africa All Party Parliamentary Group Report Dec 2009 Online NewsHour Land Redistribution in Southern Africa Zimbabwe Program Pbs org Retrieved 2012 11 20 Page 372 Africa Review 2003 2004 In the Pit of Africa A Review by Joshua Hammer Archived 2014 05 06 at the Wayback Machine New York Review of Books 7 January 2008 Constitution of Zimbabwe Chapter III Section 16 p 10 PDF Archived from the original PDF on 2013 11 01 voanews com Archived from the original on 2005 11 12 Retrieved 2018 01 22 a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a CS1 maint bot original URL status unknown link Mike Campbell Private Limited v The Minister of National Security Responsible for Land Land Reform and Resettlement Supreme Court of Zimbabwe 22 January 2008 Eric Foner Reconstruction America s Unfinished Revolution 1863 1877 Harper amp Row 1988 p 374 Foner 1988 p 104 Alan Brinkley The Unfinished Nation A Concise History of the American People 6th ed McGraw Hill 2010 p 372 374 Brinkley 2010 p 375 Clayborne Carson Emma J Lapsansky Werner and Gary B Nash The Struggle for Freedom A History of African Americans Combined vol 2nd ed Prentice Hall 2011 p 265 266 276 277 Brinkley 2010 p 371 Foner 1988 p 104 105 Foner 1988 p 105 106 403 Order by the Commander of the Military Division of the Mississippi Freedmen and Southern Society Project Retrieved 2012 12 31 Proceedings of 13th Congress 13 Stat 507 enacted March 3 1865 from the Library of Congress Foner 1988 p 159 Foner 1988 p 375 Foner 1988 pp 375 377 James S Pike reporting on the south indicating the growing appeal of racist rhetoric in anti Reconstruction politics Foner 1988 p 525 Foner 1988 pp 524 531 Brinkley 2010 p 387 Foner 1988 pp 602 612 a b SD Institutions Land reform in rural China since the mid 1980s Part 1 Fao org Archived from the original on 2010 12 23 Retrieved 2010 06 27 Ding C 2003 Land policy reform in China Assessment and prospects Land Use Policy 20 2 109 120 doi 10 1016 s0264 8377 02 00073 x Flores 1970 p 901 Cha Victor D 2013 The Impossible State North Korea Past and Future Internet Archive New York Ecco pp 46 47 ISBN 978 0 06 199850 8 Yoo Gwan Hee March 5 2010 Collective or Farmer Land Ownership in North Korea Retrieved December 15 2021 Andrea Matles Savad 1993 North Korea A Country Study Retrieved December 15 2021 a b Beban Alice 2021 Unwritten Rule State Making through Land Reform in Cambodia Cornell University Press ISBN 978 1 5017 5362 6 JSTOR 10 7591 j ctv12sdwbz They never intended to conserve it Outcry as loggers gut Cambodian reserve Mongabay Environmental News 2020 05 13 Retrieved 2020 12 08 Interactive Plundering Cambodia s forests interactive aljazeera com Retrieved 2020 12 08 Campbell Charlie 2013 05 14 In Cambodia China Fuels Deadly Illegal Logging Trade Time ISSN 0040 781X Retrieved 2020 12 08 Illegal logging poised to wipe Cambodian wildlife sanctuary off the map Mongabay Environmental News 2019 05 02 Retrieved 2020 12 08 Cambodia s Forests Are Disappearing earthobservatory nasa gov 2017 01 10 Retrieved 2020 12 08 Adrian Levy Cathy Scott Clark 26 April 2008 Country for sale The Guardian Retrieved 13 February 2014 Country For Sale Global Witness Retrieved 2020 12 08 a b The Marcos Agrarian Reform Program Promises and Contradictions Martial Law Museum Retrieved 2021 11 02 Esguerra E F 1980 Some notes on the Masagana 99 rice program and small farmer access to credit Philippines Philippine Sociological Review Philippines ISSN 0031 7810 Reyes Miguel Paolo P Ariate Jr Joel F Del Mundo Larah Vinda 2021 05 24 Success of Masagana 99 all in Imee s head UP researchers Vera Files Retrieved 2021 11 02 CARP not renewed Archived 2012 09 25 at the Wayback Machine Inquirer net 3 January 2009 Father of Thai democracy forever misunderstood Bangkok Post Retrieved 2022 04 06 Land Legislation Gender and Land Rights Database Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations www fao org Retrieved 2022 04 06 The Viet Minh Regime Government and Administration in the Democratic Republic of Vietnam Bernard Fall Greenwood Press Connecticut 1975 a b Nhan Vo Tri 1990 Vietnam s Economic Policy Since 1975 1 ed Institute for Southeast Asian Studies pp 2 7 ISBN 978 981 3035 54 6 Retrieved 8 July 2015 Moise Edwin E 1976 Land Reform and Land Reform Errors in North Vietnam Pacific Affairs 49 1 Spring 1976 84 85 doi 10 2307 2756362 JSTOR 2756362 Communist Party of Vietnam Kinh nghiệm giải quyết vấn đề ruộng đất trong cach mạng Việt Nam Experience in land reform in the Vietnamese Revolution available online Bao Dien tu Dang Cong san Viet Nam nbsp Wikimedia Commons has media related to Land reform Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Land reforms by country amp oldid 1182588058 India, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.