fbpx
Wikipedia

Land Reform Movement (China)

The Land Reform Movement, also known by the Chinese abbreviation Tǔgǎi (土改), was a mass movement led by the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) leader Mao Zedong during the late phase of the Chinese Civil War and the early People's Republic of China,[1] which achieved land redistribution to the peasantry. Landlords — whose status was theoretically defined through the percentage of income derived from exploitation as opposed to labor[2] — had their land confiscated and they were subjected to mass killing by the CCP and former tenants,[3][4] with the estimated death toll ranging from hundreds of thousands to millions.[5][6][7] The campaign resulted in hundreds of millions of peasants receiving a plot of land for the first time.[3][4]

Land Reform Movement
The land reform staff publicizing the Land Reform Law to peasants in 1950
Simplified Chinese土地改革运动
Traditional Chinese土地改革運動
Literal meaningLand Reform Movement
Transcriptions
Standard Mandarin
Hanyu PinyinTǔdì gǎigé yùndòng
Bopomofoㄊㄨˇ ㄉㄧˋ ㄍㄞˇ ㄍㄜˊ ㄩㄣˋ ㄉㄨㄥˋ
Wade–GilesTu3 ti4 kai3 ko2 yun4 tong4
Yale RomanizationTu3di4 gai3ge2 yun4dung4
Yue: Cantonese
Yale Romanizationtóu deih gói gaak wahn duhng
Jyutpingtou2 dei6 goi2 gaak3 wan6 dung6

By 1953, land reform had been completed in mainland China with the exception of Xinjiang, Tibet, Qinghai, and Sichuan. From 1953 onwards, the CCP began to implement the collective ownership of expropriated land through the creation of "Agricultural Production Cooperatives", transferring property rights of the seized land to the Chinese state. Farmers were compelled to join collective farms, which were grouped into People's communes with centrally controlled property rights.[8]

Origins

China's land reform was not only an economic or administrative process of taking and redistributing deeds or legal ownership of land.[4] It was a party-led mass movement which turned peasants into active participants and which pushed for political and ideological change beyond the immediate economic question of land ownership.[4][1]

It had historical antecedents in China. In the mid-19th century, the Taiping Rebellion had a short-lived program of land confiscation and redistribution and after the Xinhai Revolution in 1911, the founder of the Chinese Nationalist Party Sun Yat-sen advocated a "land to the tiller" program of equal distribution of land which was partly implemented by the Nationalist government under Chiang Kai-shek.

As early as 1927, Mao Zedong believed that the countryside would be the basis of revolution.[9] Land reform was key for the CCP both to carry out its program of social equality and to extend its control to the countryside. Unlike in Russia before the revolution, peasants in imperial China were not in feudal bondage to large estates; they either owned their land or rented it. They marketed their crops for cash in village markets, but local elites used their connections with officialdom to dominate local society. When the central government began to lose control in the late 19th century and then disintegrated after 1911, the local gentry and clan organizations became even more powerful.[10] Mao's 1927 Report on an Investigation of the Peasant Movement in Hunan advocated a then heretical strategy of mobilizing poor peasants to carry out "struggle" (douzheng). Mao from that point on rejected the idea of peaceful land reform, arguing that peasants could not achieve true liberation unless they participated in the violent overthrow of the landlords.[11] In Mao's view, peasant uprisings were organic events, and as a "revolutionary party," the Communists should choose to lead them rather than stand in their way or to "trail behind them" and criticize.[9] He concluded that "[w]ithout using the greatest force, the peasants cannot possibly overthrow the deep-rooted authority of the landlords, which has lasted for thousands of years."[12]

In a speech at the Second National Congress in 1934, Mao addressed the significance of land reform in the context of the struggle against the civil war against the Nationalists:[13]

If we only mobilize the people to carry on the war and do nothing else, can we succeed in defeating the enemy? Of course not. If we want to win, we must do a great deal more. We must lead the peasants' struggle for land and distribute the land to them [...] If we attend to these problems, solve them and satisfy the needs of the masses, we shall really become organizers of the well-being of the masses, and they will truly rally around us and give us their warm support.

The Communist Party launched various rural campaigns as precursors to land reform.[14] These mass campaigns adjusted rent and interest to be more favorable to tenants, returned excessive deposits to renters, and overall served to weaken the traditional rural elites.[14]

Peasant land holdings prior to reform

During China's feudal period, a small number of landlords owned vast amounts of farmland, while the majority of Chinese were landless peasants.[15] Land concentration continued after the 1911 Revolution overthrew the Qing Dynasty.[15] By 1934, 4% of the population owned half of the land, while 70% of peasant households owned only 17% of the land.[15] Frequently, poor peasants who rented land were required to pay more than half of their income to landlords.[15]

Process of land reform

Land reform progressed unevenly by region[16] and in different time periods.[17] In northern China, which had been governed by Communists since 1935, the peasants were more radical.[16] Land reform was undertaken more quickly and more violently than in the south, especially beginning in 1950.[16] Land reform issues were also a matter of debate within the Communist Party, and leaders disagreed over such questions as the level of violence which was to be used; whether to woo or target middle peasants, who farmed most of the land; or to redistribute all of the land to poor peasants.[18]

Landlords were subjected to public "struggle sessions" organised by the CCP where they were accused of crimes against the peasants and sometimes sentenced to death, including killed in public by peasants at these mass meetings.[1][16] Struggle was confrontational by design, consistent with Mao's view that the masses had to actively take part in avenging past injustices.[19] "Speaking bitterness", defined as "articulating one’s history of being oppressed and exploited by class enemies and thus stimulating others’ class hatred, and in the meantime consolidating one’s own class standpoint", was employed to fan the flames of peasant resentment towards landlords.[20] While violence was not necessarily involved, Mao's position that the masses had to be given free rein in confronting their class enemies meant that peasant violence against those deemed landlords was common.[21]

In the north, Communist Party cadre often tried to restrain excessive violence from peasants.[16] Land reform proceeded more slowly and less violently in the South.[16] There, land was owned by extended clans rather than individual landlords and poor peasants were sometimes part of the same kinship networks.[16] In contrast to the north, the CCP had difficulty convincing poorer peasants that land should be expropriated at all.[16]

Rural women had a significant impact on the movement, with the Communist Party making specific efforts to mobilize them.[22] Party activists observed that because peasant women were less tied to old power structures, that they more readily opposed those identified as class enemies.[23] In 1947, Deng Yingchao emphasized at a land reform policy meeting that "women function as great mobilizers when they speak bitterness."[22] The All-China Women's Federation called for Party activists to encourage peasant women to understand their "special bitterness" from a class perspective.[23] Women activists helped peasant women prepare to speak in public, including by roleplaying as landlords to help such women practice.[23]

By 1952, land redistribution was generally completed.[16] Most landlords had been permitted to retain plots of land after admitting to historical crimes, although many had been killed.[16] The amount of cultivated land had grown, along with related infrastructure projects and availability of fertilizers and insecticides.[16] By 1952, rural agriculture had become hugely more productive in China.[24]

Chinese civil war era campaigns (1946–1948)

During the Second Sino-Japanese War and the Second United Front, the party emphasized Sun Yat-sen's moderate "land to the tiller" program, which limited rent to 37.5% of the crop, rather than land redistribution. The earliest land reform campaigns following Japan's surrender focused on mobilizing peasants to take revenge on traitors who had collaborated with the Japanese.[25]

Throughout the land reform campaigns of the Civil War era, trends towards violent struggle against landlords coincided with increased combat in the war; when Nationalist forces or homecoming regiments were present, land reform and Civil War violence overlapped.[26]

At the outbreak of the Civil War in 1946, Mao began to push for a return to radical policies to mobilize the village against the landlord class, but protected the rights of middle peasants and specified that rich peasants were not landlords.[27]

On May 4, 1946, the Party's Central Committee issued its Instructions on Land Issues.[28] The May 4th Instructions (also referred to as the May 4th Directive)[29] required local party committees to support landlords who approved of land acquisition by the peasantry.[30] As part of an effort to address some concerns of some landowners and those connected to them, the May 4th Instructions stated that landlords who “had earned merit for resisting Japan” would be left the more land and that the land holdings of wealthier peasants would be mostly unchanged.[30] The May 4th Instructions provided significant leeway for differing regional and local interpretations.[31] In villages where land reform was occurring for the first time, the East China Bureau allowed small and medium landlords to donate land; those who did were allowed to keep more than the average middle peasant.[31] The Northeast Bureau took a similar approach, even allowing most peasants who had served the Japanese Manchukuo regime to apologize and retain their land.[31] In contrast to these approaches, the Central China Bureau moved more steadily towards land equalization.[32]

The July 7 Directive of 1946 set off eighteen months of fierce conflict in which all rich peasant and landlord property of all types was to be confiscated and redistributed to poor peasants. Party work teams (gongzuodui) were the primary instrument of land reform[25] and went from village to village and divided the population into landlords, rich, middle, poor, and landless peasants. Because the work teams did not involve villagers in the process, rich and middle peasants quickly returned to power.[33]

From July to September 1947, the Communist Party held a National Land Conference to formulate the Outline of the Chinese Land Law.[30] Issued in October 1947, the Outline identified the goal of "[t]he abolition of feudal and semi-feudal exploitation of the land system and the implementation of the cultivator owning the field."[34] The Outline Land Law codified confiscation of land from rich peasants.[35] According to Historian William H. Hinton, it "played the same role as did Lincoln's Manifesto of Liberating Black Slaves during the American Civil War."[36]

Late 1947 directives from the Party called for more lenient treatment for allies among the rural elite in established base areas whom the Party viewed as sufficiently enlightened.[37] The Party instructed work teams and cadres not to dampen the enthusiasm of the peasant masses, but also to convince activists to minimize beatings and to oppose spontaneous executions.[37]

Party central sent the work teams back to the villages to put poor and landless peasants in charge, mandating the elimination of land rent, which it compared to feudal exploitation, and the elimination of landlord status. The work teams mobilized poor and landless peasants to take direct and violent action against the leading clans and families of neighboring villages to ensure that family loyalties not interfere with the campaign.[38][clarification needed] In one village in southern Hebei, foreign observers recorded that four people were stoned to death,[39] and Hinton reported that at least a dozen purported rich peasants or landlords were beaten to death in the village he called Longbow.[40]

Land reform movement violence surged in early 1948, prompting some Party leaders such as Xi Zhongxun and Ren Bishi to criticize the movement.[41] Ren announced a policy shift in January 1948, guaranteeing that targets of the movement would nonetheless be allowed to keep a share of property.[42] This policy change contributed to a shift away from economic struggle and to political struggle.[42] The Party instructed that fewer landlords should be targeted and work teams should not beat or torture their targets.[42]

Land reform was a decisive factor in the result of the Chinese Civil War.[43] At the time of the Communist victory, more than half of the population living in Communist areas had participated in land reform and over 25 million hectares of land had been redistributed, largely as a result of confiscations form landlords and rich peasants.[44] Millions of peasants who obtained land through the movement joined the People's Liberation Army or assisted in its logistical networks.[43] According to academic Brian DeMare, land redistribution was a critical factor in the Communists' military success in the civil war because land reforms linked the interests of north and northeast Chinese peasants to the Party's success.[44] The success of land reform meant that at the founding of the PRC in 1949, China could credibly claim that for the first time since the late Qing period that it had succeeded in feeding one fifth of the world's population with only 7% of the world's cultivable land.[45]

Early People's Republic of China campaigns (1949–1953)

The Land Reform Movement continued during peace time.[44] The round of land reform carried out in the winter 1949-1950 involved treatment of landlords that were considerably more lenient than in the Civil War era land reforms, with most landlords avoiding struggle.[44] In summer 1950, the Land Reform Law of the People's Republic of China made more lenient treatment of landlords the official policy.[46] Landlords would be allowed to keep commercial enterprises and personal belongings other than the "five big properties."[46] These "five big properties" --- land, draft animals, excess grain, agricultural tools, and surplus housing -- were still subject to redistribution.[46] The 1950 Land Reform law was also explicit that the land of middle peasants should not be redistributed.[46] It also stated that the rich peasant economy must be preserved[46] and that law-abiding rich peasants must not be subjected to struggle sessions.[47]

In this period, the Party's view was that fewer targets were necessary in order to unite a broad base in opposition to a limited number of landlords.[48] According to this view, a focused attack on the landlord class's core would also result in compliance from small and medium landlords.[47] The Party instructed work teams to refrain from indiscriminate struggle, which was now viewed as "illegal struggle."[47] Pursuant to these directives, the East China Bureau tested a new struggle method in which the most exploitive or criminal landlords (deemed "evil tyrants") would be sent to trial but that work teams would meet with other landlords to explain land reform policy and their comparatively lenient treatment under it.[49] The East China Bureau encountered no resistance from these latter landlords and the Party deemed this test program in non-violent struggle a total success.[49]

However, the Korean War prompted Party leadership to be concerned that landlords might use the conflict to oppose the new rural order, increasing the view that violent struggle was necessary to defeat class enemies.[50] Land reform in May 1951, according to Mao biographer Philip Short, "lurched violently to the left" with Mao Zedong laying down new guidelines for "not correcting excesses prematurely."[1] Beatings, while not officially promoted by the party, were not prohibited either. While landlords had no protection, those who were branded "rich peasants" received moderate protections from violence and those who were on the lower end were fully protected.[51] In this vein, Mao insisted that the people themselves, not the public security organs, should become involved in enacting the Land Reform Law and killing the landlords who had oppressed them, in contrast to the Soviet practice of dekulakization.[1] Mao thought that peasants who killed landlords who had oppressed them would become permanently linked to the revolutionary process in a way that passive spectators could not be.[1] Although violence came to be particularly frowned upon by the Party in the final rounds of land reform, in practice the struggle by peasants against landlords continued to be often brutal.[52]

In the early PRC era, there were millions of war widows.[53] Widows whose husbands had fought in Communist armies received land through the land reform movement, as well as assistance farming it.[53]

Mass killings of landlords

Destruction of the Chinese landlord class (1949–1953)
Part of Early Mao era of China
 
A farmer confronting a landlord, 1946
LocationChina
Date1946–1953
Attack type
Massacre, classicide
Deaths
Injured1.5[56]–6[57] up to 12.5[55] million sent to Laogai camps
VictimsLandlords, better-off peasants
PerpetratorsChinese Communist Party and radicalized peasants
MotiveMaoism, economic inequality, class struggle

Those who were killed were targeted on the basis of their social class rather than their ethnicity; the neologism classicide is used to describe the killings.[58] Class-motivated mass murder continued almost throughout the 30 years of social and economic transformation in Maoist China, and by the end of the reforms, the landlord class had largely been eliminated from Mainland China or it had fled to Taiwan.[59]

In his Report on the Peasant Movement in Hunan, Mao addressed Party members who were concerned with violence by the peasants against landlords, arguing that these concerns were a tool for continuing the oppression of the peasants.[60] In this context, Mao coined his famous comment that "revolution is not a dinner party."[60] Mao wrote in response to objections to violence:[60]

It is fine. It is not "terrible" at all. It is anything but "terrible." ... "It's terrible!" is obviously a theory for combatting the rise of the peasants in the interests of the landlords; it is obviously a theory of the landlord class for preserving the old feudal order and obstructing the establishment of the new democratic order; it is obviously a counterrevolutionary theory.

The Communist Party's tolerance of, encouragement of, or efforts to restrain, violence by peasants against landlords in the course of the land reform movement varied over time and location.[61] Its directions were not always followed, and as late as the final rounds of land reform, Hu Yaobang had to explain that the call to "annihilate" the landlord class meant taking landlord property not landlord lives.[48]

Jean-Louis Margolin argues that the killings were not a pre-condition for land reform, because in Taiwan and Japan, land reforms were launched with little violence. Rather the violence was a result of the fact that the land reform was less about redistribution (because within a few years of the reforms, most of the land had to be surrendered to collective farms) than it was about eliminating "rural class enemies" and the assumption of local power by the communists. Margolin observes that even in very poor villages (which covered half of Northern China) where nobody could qualify as a landlord, some landlords were "manufactured" so they could be persecuted. In Wugong village, 70 households (out of a total of 387 households) were converted from middle peasants into rich peasants, making them acceptable targets for class struggle.[62] There were policies in certain regions of China (not necessarily obeyed)[citation needed] which required the selection of "at least one landlord, and usually several, in virtually every village for public execution".[6] An official reported 180 to 190 thousand landlords were executed in the Kwangsi province alone, in addition a Catholic school teacher reported 2.5% of his village was executed.[55] Some condemned as landlords were buried alive, dismembered, strangled or shot.[51] In many villages, landlords' women were "redistributed" as concubines or daughters for peasants or pressured into marrying their husband's persecutors.[63][64]

Estimated number of deaths

Estimates for the number of deaths range from a lower estimate of 200,000 to 800,000,[65][5][6] and higher estimates of 2,000,000[5][66][67] to 5 million[68][66] executions for the years 1949–1953, along with 1.5 million[56] to 6 million[57] sent to "reform through labour" (Laogai) camps, where many perished.[57] Philip Short wrote that such estimates exclude the hundreds of thousands driven to suicide during "struggle sessions" of the three-anti/five-anti campaigns, which also occurred around the same time.[69] Zhou Enlai estimated 830,000 had been killed, while Mao Zedong estimated as many as 2 to 3 million were killed.[54] Deng Zihui, Vice Chairman of the Central South Military and Administrative Council, estimated that 15% of China's 50,000,000 landlords and rich peasants had been "sentenced to death", 25% had been "sent to labor reform camps for remolding through manual work" and 60% to "participation in production work under supervision".[55] Not all of those sentenced to death were actually executed and therefore there is no way of knowing the exact number of performed executions.[70]

Retaliation by landlords

During the Chinese Civil War, the Kuomintang established the "Huanxiang Tuan" (Chinese: 還鄉團; pinyin: Huán xiāng tuán), or the Homecoming Legion, which was composed of landlords who sought the return of their redistributed land and property from peasants and CCP guerrillas, and the release of forcibly conscripted peasants and communist POWs.[71] The Homecoming legion conducted its guerrilla warfare campaign against CCP forces and purported collaborators up until the end of the civil war in 1949.[71]

Many landlords used violence to oppose land reform including after the defeat of the Kuomintang.[72] Some landlords poisoned wells, destroyed agricultural tools, or cut down forests.[72] The Communist Party widely disseminated stories of landlords' crimes as an effort to build support for its view of the landlord class as a whole.[72]

Land redistribution

Land seized from Landlords was brought under collective ownership, resulting in the creation of "Agricultural production cooperatives".[73] In the mid-1950s, a second land reform during the Great Leap Forward compelled individual farmers to join collectives, which, in turn, were grouped into People's communes with centrally controlled property rights and an egalitarian principle of distribution. This policy was generally a failure in terms of production.[8] The PRC reversed this policy in 1962 through the proclamation of the Sixty Articles. As a result, the ownership of the basic means of production was divided into three levels with collective land ownership vested in the production team.

Ownership of cultivable land before reform in mainland China[74][a]
Classification Number of households
(10,000)
Proportion of households
(%)
Population
(10,000)
Population ratio
(%)
Farmland
(10,000 mu)
The proportion of cultivated land
(%)
The average cultivated land
(mu)
Per capita cultivated land
(mu)
Poor Farmer 6062 57.44 24123 52.37 21503 14.28 3.55 0.89
Middle Peasants 3081 29.20 15260 33.13 46577 30.94 15.12 3.05
Rich Farmer 325 3.08 2144 4.66 20566 13.66 63.24 9.59
Landlord 400 3.79 2188 4.75 57588 38.26 144.11 26.32
Other 686 6.49 2344 5.09 4300 2.86 6.27 1.83
Total 10554 100.00 46059 100.00 150534 100.00 14.26 3.27
Ownership of cultivable land after reform in mainland China[74][b]
Classification Number of households
(%)
Population
(%)
Cultivated land
(%)
Per capita cultivated land
(mu)
Large livestock
(Head/100 households)
Poor Farmer 54.5 52.2 47.1 12.5 46.73
Middle Peasants 39.3 39.9 44.3 19.0 90.93
Rich Farmer 3.1 5.3 6.4 25.1 114.86
Landlord 2.4 2.6 2.2 12.2 23.19
Other 0.7 -- -- -- --
Total 100.00 100.00 100.00 15.3 64.01

Economic effects

 
An example of a people's commune collective farm.

As an economic reform program, the land reform succeeded in redistributing about 43% of China's cultivated land to approximately 60% of the rural population.[75] Poor peasants increased their holdings, while middle peasants benefitted most because of their strong initial position.[75] The movement expropriated land from over ten million landlords.[76] Historian Walter Scheidel writes that the violence of the land reform campaign had a significant impact in reducing economic inequality. He gives as an example the 1940s campaigns in village of Zhangzhuangcun, made famous by William Hinton's book Fanshen. Although poor and middle peasants had already owned 70% of the land:

In Zhangzhuangcun, in the more thoroughly reformed north of the country, most "landlords" and "rich peasants" had lost all their land and often their lives or had fled. All formerly landless workers had received land, which eliminated this category altogether. As a result, "middling peasants," who now accounted for 90 percent of the village population, owned 90.8 percent of the land, as close to perfect equality as one could possibly hope for.[3]

Following conclusion of the land reform movement, harvests and incomes increased.[77]

Land reform on Taiwan

After its retreat to Taiwan, the Nationalist government carried out a program of land reform under the Joint Commission on Rural Reconstruction.[78] The land reform law removed the landlord class, and created a higher number of peasants who, with the help of the state, dramatically increased Taiwan's agricultural output.[79] Land reform also succeeded because the Kuomintang's members were mostly from mainland China and, as a result, had few ties with the remaining indigenous Taiwanese landowners.[80]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ The number of households, population, and total arable land are based on the 1950 agricultural production annual report. The figures for each class are calculated based on the proportion of each class before the land reform in each region.
  2. ^ The number of households was calculated based on the survey data of 9900 households in 21 provinces and autonomous regions. Others are calculated based on the survey data of more than 15,000 rural households in 23 provinces and autonomous regions in 1954.

References

  1. ^ a b c d e f Short (2001), pp. 436–437.
  2. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 93.
  3. ^ a b c Scheidel, Walter (2017). The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century. Princeton University Press. pp. 223, 226. ISBN 978-0-691-16502-8.
  4. ^ a b c d Ching, Pao-Yu (2021). Revolution and counterrevolution : China's continuing class struggle since liberation (2nd ed.). Paris: Foreign languages press. p. 185. ISBN 978-2-491182-89-2. OCLC 1325647379.
  5. ^ a b c Roberts, J. A. G. (2006). A History of China (Palgrave Essential Histories Series). Palgrave Macmillan. p. 257. ISBN 978-1-4039-9275-8. Estimates of the number of landlords and rural power-holders who died range from 200,000 to two million.
  6. ^ a b c Teiwes, Frederic (1987). "Establishment of the New Regime". In Twitchett, Denis; John K. Fairbank; Roderick MacFarquhar (eds.). The Cambridge history of China. Cambridge University Press. p. 87. ISBN 0-521-24336-X. from the original on 2019-02-20. Retrieved 2008-08-23. "For a careful review of the evidence and a cautious estimate of 200,000 two 800,000 executions, see Benedict Stavis, The Politics of Agricultural Mechanization in China (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1978), 25–30.
  7. ^ Rummel, Rudolph J. (2007). China's bloody century: genocide and mass murder since 1900. Transaction Publishers. p. 223. ISBN 978-1-4128-0670-1. from the original on 2016-11-09. Retrieved 2016-11-02.
  8. ^ a b ChenDavis (1998).
  9. ^ a b Bradley (2015), pp. 137–138.
  10. ^ Mühlhahn (2019), p. 402.
  11. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 10, 104–105.
  12. ^ Bradley (2015), p. 138.
  13. ^ Coderre, Laurence (2021). Newborn socialist things : materiality in Maoist China. Durham: Duke University Press. p. 65. ISBN 978-1-4780-2161-2. OCLC 1250021710.
  14. ^ a b DeMare (2019), p. 137.
  15. ^ a b c d Ching, Pao-Yu (2021). Revolution and counterrevolution : China's continuing class struggle since liberation (2nd ed.). Paris: Foreign languages press. p. 252. ISBN 978-2-491182-89-2. OCLC 1325647379.
  16. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k Karl (2010), pp. 80–81.
  17. ^ DeMare (2019), pp. 166–168.
  18. ^ DeMare (2019), pp. 6–17.
  19. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 104.
  20. ^ Wu, Guo (26 April 2014). "SPEAKING BITTERNESS: POLITICAL EDUCATION IN LAND REFORM AND MILITARY TRAINING UNDER THE CCP, 1947–1951". The Chinese Historical Review. 21 (1): 3–23. doi:10.1179/1547402X14Z.00000000026. S2CID 144044801. Retrieved 18 March 2023.
  21. ^ DeMare (2019), pp. 104–105.
  22. ^ a b DeMare (2019), pp. 62–63.
  23. ^ a b c DeMare (2019), p. 63.
  24. ^ Karl (2010), p. 82.
  25. ^ a b DeMare (2019), p. 33.
  26. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 111.
  27. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 10-11.
  28. ^ Huang (2020), pp. 249–250.
  29. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 167.
  30. ^ a b c Huang (2020), p. 250.
  31. ^ a b c DeMare (2019), p. 84.
  32. ^ DeMare (2019), pp. 84–85.
  33. ^ Tanner (2015), pp. 134–135.
  34. ^ Huang (2020), p. 532.
  35. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 86.
  36. ^ Hinton, William (1972). Fanshen : a documentary of revolution in a Chinese village. Harmondsworth: Penguin. p. 7. ISBN 0-14-021570-0. OCLC 16255144.
  37. ^ a b DeMare (2019), p. 112.
  38. ^ Tanner, Harold Miles (2015). Where Chiang Kai-Shek Lost China: The Liao-Shen Campaign, 1948. Bloomington: Indiana University Press. ISBN 978-0-253-01692-8. p.135-137
  39. ^ CrookCrook (1979), p. 151.
  40. ^ Hinton (1966), p. xi.
  41. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 113.
  42. ^ a b c DeMare (2019), p. 114.
  43. ^ a b Lin, Chun (2006). The transformation of Chinese socialism. Durham [N.C.]: Duke University Press. p. 43. ISBN 978-0-8223-3785-0. OCLC 63178961.
  44. ^ a b c d DeMare (2019), p. 18.
  45. ^ Lin, Chun (2006). The transformation of Chinese socialism. Durham [N.C.]: Duke University Press. p. 44. ISBN 978-0-8223-3785-0. OCLC 63178961.
  46. ^ a b c d e DeMare (2019), p. 19.
  47. ^ a b c DeMare (2019), p. 116.
  48. ^ a b DeMare (2019), p. 118.
  49. ^ a b DeMare (2019), p. 117.
  50. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 90.
  51. ^ a b Scheidel, Walter (2017). The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century. Princeton University Press. p. 225. ISBN 978-0-691-16502-8. from the original on 2017-09-04. Retrieved 2017-09-03.
  52. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 105.
  53. ^ a b Lary, Diana (2022). China's grandmothers : gender, family, and aging from late Qing to twenty-first century. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press. p. 92. ISBN 978-1-009-06478-1. OCLC 1292532755.
  54. ^ a b c Daniel Chirot. Modern Tyrants: The Power and Prevalence of Evil in Our Age. Princeton University Press, 1996: 187 [ 2014-03-30 ] . ISBN 0-691-02777-3 (original content. Archived in 2014-07-03).
  55. ^ a b c d Rummel, Rudolph .J. (2007). China's bloody century: genocide and mass murder since 1900. Transaction Publishers. p. 222. ISBN 978-1-4128-0670-1.
  56. ^ a b Short (2001), p. 436.
  57. ^ a b c Benjamin A. Valentino. Final Solutions: Mass Killing and Genocide in the Twentieth Century 2019-02-20 at the Wayback Machine Cornell University Press, 2004. pp. 121–122. ISBN 0-8014-3965-5
  58. ^ Wu, Harry (2013). "Classicide in Communist China". In Arrigo, Bruce and Heather Bersot (ed.). The Routledge Handbook of International Crime and Justice Studies. Routledge. ISBN 978-1-136-86850-4., xxv-xxvi
  59. ^ Liu, William Thomas (1967). Chinese Society Under Communism: A Reader. Wiley.
  60. ^ a b c Karl (2010), p. 31.
  61. ^ DeMare (2019), pp. 105–118.
  62. ^ Margolin (2008), p. 452.
  63. ^ Su, Yang. Collective killings in rural China during the cultural revolution. Cambridge University Press, 2011, p.111
  64. ^ Margolin (2008), p. 455.
  65. ^ Stavis, Benedict (1978). The Politics of Agricultural Mechanization in China. University of California: Cornell University Press. ISBN 978-0-8014-1087-1. It would appear that somewhere between 400,000 and 800,000 people were killed offi- cially after 1949.... The Chinese Communist leadership had estimated that landlords and their families constituted 4 -5 percent of the rural population-about 20 million people. This would imply that 1 to 4 percent of landlords' families met death. If a half million people were killed in land reform, this would be .1 percent of the rural population or 2.5 percent of the landlord class and would represent roughly one death in six landlord families (pp. 29-30).
  66. ^ a b Lee Feigon. Mao: A Reinterpretation. Ivan R. Dee, 2002. ISBN 1-56663-522-5 p. 96: "By 1952 they had extended land reform throughout the countryside, but in the process somewhere between two and five million landlords had been killed."
  67. ^ Maurice Meisner. Mao's China and After: A History of the People's Republic, Third Edition. Free Press, 1999. ISBN 0-684-85635-2 p. 72: "... the estimate of many relatively impartial observers that there were 2,000,000 people executed during the first three years of the People's Republic is probably as accurate a guess as one can make on the basis of scanty information."
  68. ^ Steven W. Mosher. China Misperceived: American Illusions and Chinese Reality. Basic Books, 1992. ISBN 0-465-09813-4 pg 74: "...a figure that Fairbank has cited as the upper range of "sober" estimates."
  69. ^ Short (2001), p. 437.
  70. ^ Stavis, Benedict (1978). The Politics of Agricultural Mechanization in China. Cornell University Press. p. 29. ISBN 978-0-8014-1087-1.
  71. ^ a b Zaiyu, Liu (2002). 第二次國共戰爭時期的還鄉團 (PDF). Hong Kong: Twenty First Century Bimonthly.
  72. ^ a b c DeMare (2019), p. 94.
  73. ^ "在中国共产党第七届中央委员会第六次全体会议上". Central People's Government of the People's Republic of China. from the original on 27 October 2019. Retrieved 27 October 2019.
  74. ^ a b 国家统计局编:《建国三十年全国农业统计资料(1949-1979)》,1980年3月印制。
  75. ^ a b Fairbank, John King; MacFarquhar, Roderick (1987). The Cambridge History of China: The People's Republic. Cambridge University Press. p. 87. ISBN 978-0-521-24336-0.
  76. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 141.
  77. ^ DeMare (2019), p. 146.
  78. ^ Clough, Ralph (1991). "Chapter 12: Taiwan under Nationalist Rule, 1949-1982". In MacFaquhar, Roderick; Fairbank, John K. (eds.). The People's Republic. Cambridge [Cambridgeshire]: Cambridge University Press. p. 837. ISBN 978-0-521-24337-7.
  79. ^ "The Labour Movement in Taiwan". September 21, 2004. from the original on October 21, 2019. Retrieved November 7, 2019.
  80. ^ [Land Reform Museum] (in Chinese). Archived from the original on 2011-07-25.

Bibliography and further reading

  • Bradley, James (2015). The China mirage : the hidden history of American disaster in Asia (1st ed.). New York. ISBN 978-0-316-19667-3. OCLC 870199580.
  • Chen, Fu; Davis, John (1998). "Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s". Land Reform. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.
  • Crook, Isabel; Crook, David (1979). Ten Mile Inn: Mass Movement in a Chinese Village. New York: Pantheon Books. ISBN 0-394-41178-1.
  • DeMare, Brian James (2019). Land Wars: The Story of China's Agrarian Revolution. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. ISBN 978-1-5036-0952-5.
  • Hinton, William (1966). Fanshen: A Documentary of Revolution in a Chinese Village. New York: Monthly Review Press.
  • Huang, Yibing (2020). An ideological history of the Communist Party of China. Vol. I. Qian Zheng, Guoyou Wu, Xuemei Ding, Li Sun, Shelly Bryant. Montreal, Quebec. ISBN 978-1-4878-0425-1. OCLC 1165409653.
  • Karl, Rebecca E. (2010). Mao Zedong and China in the twentieth-century world : a concise history. Durham [NC]: Duke University Press. ISBN 978-0-8223-4780-4. OCLC 503828045.
  • Li, Huaiyin (2011). Village China under Socialism and Reform : A Micro History, 1948-2008. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press. ISBN 978-0-8047-7657-8.
  • Margolin, Jean-Louis (13 February 2008). "Mao's China: The Worst Non-Genocidal Regime?". In Stone, Dan (ed.). The Historiography of Genocide. Springer. ISBN 978-0-230-29778-4.
  • Moise, Edwin E. (1983). Land Reform in China and North Vietnam : Consolidating the Revolution at the Village Level. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. ISBN 9780807874455.
  • Mühlhahn, Klaus (2019). Making China Modern: From the Great Qing to Xi Jinping. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-73735-8.
  • Short, Philip (2001). Mao: A Life. Owl Books. ISBN 0-8050-6638-1.
  • Shue, Vivienne (1980). Peasant China in Transition: The Dynamics of Development toward Socialism, 1949-1956. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. ISBN 978-0-520-03734-2.

External links

  • Land Reform and Collectivization (1950-1953) Posters from the Stephan Landsberger collection. There are other posters on the topic in other sections of the site.

land, reform, movement, china, land, reform, movement, also, known, chinese, abbreviation, tǔgǎi, 土改, mass, movement, chinese, communist, party, leader, zedong, during, late, phase, chinese, civil, early, people, republic, china, which, achieved, land, redistr. The Land Reform Movement also known by the Chinese abbreviation Tǔgǎi 土改 was a mass movement led by the Chinese Communist Party CCP leader Mao Zedong during the late phase of the Chinese Civil War and the early People s Republic of China 1 which achieved land redistribution to the peasantry Landlords whose status was theoretically defined through the percentage of income derived from exploitation as opposed to labor 2 had their land confiscated and they were subjected to mass killing by the CCP and former tenants 3 4 with the estimated death toll ranging from hundreds of thousands to millions 5 6 7 The campaign resulted in hundreds of millions of peasants receiving a plot of land for the first time 3 4 Land Reform MovementThe land reform staff publicizing the Land Reform Law to peasants in 1950Simplified Chinese土地改革运动Traditional Chinese土地改革運動Literal meaningLand Reform MovementTranscriptionsStandard MandarinHanyu PinyinTǔdi gǎige yundongBopomofoㄊㄨˇ ㄉㄧˋ ㄍㄞˇ ㄍㄜˊ ㄩㄣˋ ㄉㄨㄥˋWade GilesTu3 ti4 kai3 ko2 yun4 tong4Yale RomanizationTu3di4 gai3ge2 yun4dung4Yue CantoneseYale Romanizationtou deih goi gaak wahn duhngJyutpingtou2 dei6 goi2 gaak3 wan6 dung6By 1953 land reform had been completed in mainland China with the exception of Xinjiang Tibet Qinghai and Sichuan From 1953 onwards the CCP began to implement the collective ownership of expropriated land through the creation of Agricultural Production Cooperatives transferring property rights of the seized land to the Chinese state Farmers were compelled to join collective farms which were grouped into People s communes with centrally controlled property rights 8 Contents 1 Origins 2 Peasant land holdings prior to reform 3 Process of land reform 3 1 Chinese civil war era campaigns 1946 1948 3 2 Early People s Republic of China campaigns 1949 1953 4 Mass killings of landlords 4 1 Estimated number of deaths 4 2 Retaliation by landlords 5 Land redistribution 5 1 Economic effects 6 Land reform on Taiwan 7 See also 8 Notes 9 References 10 Bibliography and further reading 11 External linksOrigins EditChina s land reform was not only an economic or administrative process of taking and redistributing deeds or legal ownership of land 4 It was a party led mass movement which turned peasants into active participants and which pushed for political and ideological change beyond the immediate economic question of land ownership 4 1 It had historical antecedents in China In the mid 19th century the Taiping Rebellion had a short lived program of land confiscation and redistribution and after the Xinhai Revolution in 1911 the founder of the Chinese Nationalist Party Sun Yat sen advocated a land to the tiller program of equal distribution of land which was partly implemented by the Nationalist government under Chiang Kai shek As early as 1927 Mao Zedong believed that the countryside would be the basis of revolution 9 Land reform was key for the CCP both to carry out its program of social equality and to extend its control to the countryside Unlike in Russia before the revolution peasants in imperial China were not in feudal bondage to large estates they either owned their land or rented it They marketed their crops for cash in village markets but local elites used their connections with officialdom to dominate local society When the central government began to lose control in the late 19th century and then disintegrated after 1911 the local gentry and clan organizations became even more powerful 10 Mao s 1927 Report on an Investigation of the Peasant Movement in Hunan advocated a then heretical strategy of mobilizing poor peasants to carry out struggle douzheng Mao from that point on rejected the idea of peaceful land reform arguing that peasants could not achieve true liberation unless they participated in the violent overthrow of the landlords 11 In Mao s view peasant uprisings were organic events and as a revolutionary party the Communists should choose to lead them rather than stand in their way or to trail behind them and criticize 9 He concluded that w ithout using the greatest force the peasants cannot possibly overthrow the deep rooted authority of the landlords which has lasted for thousands of years 12 In a speech at the Second National Congress in 1934 Mao addressed the significance of land reform in the context of the struggle against the civil war against the Nationalists 13 If we only mobilize the people to carry on the war and do nothing else can we succeed in defeating the enemy Of course not If we want to win we must do a great deal more We must lead the peasants struggle for land and distribute the land to them If we attend to these problems solve them and satisfy the needs of the masses we shall really become organizers of the well being of the masses and they will truly rally around us and give us their warm support The Communist Party launched various rural campaigns as precursors to land reform 14 These mass campaigns adjusted rent and interest to be more favorable to tenants returned excessive deposits to renters and overall served to weaken the traditional rural elites 14 Peasant land holdings prior to reform EditDuring China s feudal period a small number of landlords owned vast amounts of farmland while the majority of Chinese were landless peasants 15 Land concentration continued after the 1911 Revolution overthrew the Qing Dynasty 15 By 1934 4 of the population owned half of the land while 70 of peasant households owned only 17 of the land 15 Frequently poor peasants who rented land were required to pay more than half of their income to landlords 15 Process of land reform EditLand reform progressed unevenly by region 16 and in different time periods 17 In northern China which had been governed by Communists since 1935 the peasants were more radical 16 Land reform was undertaken more quickly and more violently than in the south especially beginning in 1950 16 Land reform issues were also a matter of debate within the Communist Party and leaders disagreed over such questions as the level of violence which was to be used whether to woo or target middle peasants who farmed most of the land or to redistribute all of the land to poor peasants 18 Landlords were subjected to public struggle sessions organised by the CCP where they were accused of crimes against the peasants and sometimes sentenced to death including killed in public by peasants at these mass meetings 1 16 Struggle was confrontational by design consistent with Mao s view that the masses had to actively take part in avenging past injustices 19 Speaking bitterness defined as articulating one s history of being oppressed and exploited by class enemies and thus stimulating others class hatred and in the meantime consolidating one s own class standpoint was employed to fan the flames of peasant resentment towards landlords 20 While violence was not necessarily involved Mao s position that the masses had to be given free rein in confronting their class enemies meant that peasant violence against those deemed landlords was common 21 In the north Communist Party cadre often tried to restrain excessive violence from peasants 16 Land reform proceeded more slowly and less violently in the South 16 There land was owned by extended clans rather than individual landlords and poor peasants were sometimes part of the same kinship networks 16 In contrast to the north the CCP had difficulty convincing poorer peasants that land should be expropriated at all 16 Rural women had a significant impact on the movement with the Communist Party making specific efforts to mobilize them 22 Party activists observed that because peasant women were less tied to old power structures that they more readily opposed those identified as class enemies 23 In 1947 Deng Yingchao emphasized at a land reform policy meeting that women function as great mobilizers when they speak bitterness 22 The All China Women s Federation called for Party activists to encourage peasant women to understand their special bitterness from a class perspective 23 Women activists helped peasant women prepare to speak in public including by roleplaying as landlords to help such women practice 23 By 1952 land redistribution was generally completed 16 Most landlords had been permitted to retain plots of land after admitting to historical crimes although many had been killed 16 The amount of cultivated land had grown along with related infrastructure projects and availability of fertilizers and insecticides 16 By 1952 rural agriculture had become hugely more productive in China 24 Chinese civil war era campaigns 1946 1948 Edit During the Second Sino Japanese War and the Second United Front the party emphasized Sun Yat sen s moderate land to the tiller program which limited rent to 37 5 of the crop rather than land redistribution The earliest land reform campaigns following Japan s surrender focused on mobilizing peasants to take revenge on traitors who had collaborated with the Japanese 25 Throughout the land reform campaigns of the Civil War era trends towards violent struggle against landlords coincided with increased combat in the war when Nationalist forces or homecoming regiments were present land reform and Civil War violence overlapped 26 At the outbreak of the Civil War in 1946 Mao began to push for a return to radical policies to mobilize the village against the landlord class but protected the rights of middle peasants and specified that rich peasants were not landlords 27 On May 4 1946 the Party s Central Committee issued its Instructions on Land Issues 28 The May 4th Instructions also referred to as the May 4th Directive 29 required local party committees to support landlords who approved of land acquisition by the peasantry 30 As part of an effort to address some concerns of some landowners and those connected to them the May 4th Instructions stated that landlords who had earned merit for resisting Japan would be left the more land and that the land holdings of wealthier peasants would be mostly unchanged 30 The May 4th Instructions provided significant leeway for differing regional and local interpretations 31 In villages where land reform was occurring for the first time the East China Bureau allowed small and medium landlords to donate land those who did were allowed to keep more than the average middle peasant 31 The Northeast Bureau took a similar approach even allowing most peasants who had served the Japanese Manchukuo regime to apologize and retain their land 31 In contrast to these approaches the Central China Bureau moved more steadily towards land equalization 32 The July 7 Directive of 1946 set off eighteen months of fierce conflict in which all rich peasant and landlord property of all types was to be confiscated and redistributed to poor peasants Party work teams gongzuodui were the primary instrument of land reform 25 and went from village to village and divided the population into landlords rich middle poor and landless peasants Because the work teams did not involve villagers in the process rich and middle peasants quickly returned to power 33 From July to September 1947 the Communist Party held a National Land Conference to formulate the Outline of the Chinese Land Law 30 Issued in October 1947 the Outline identified the goal of t he abolition of feudal and semi feudal exploitation of the land system and the implementation of the cultivator owning the field 34 The Outline Land Law codified confiscation of land from rich peasants 35 According to Historian William H Hinton it played the same role as did Lincoln s Manifesto of Liberating Black Slaves during the American Civil War 36 Late 1947 directives from the Party called for more lenient treatment for allies among the rural elite in established base areas whom the Party viewed as sufficiently enlightened 37 The Party instructed work teams and cadres not to dampen the enthusiasm of the peasant masses but also to convince activists to minimize beatings and to oppose spontaneous executions 37 Party central sent the work teams back to the villages to put poor and landless peasants in charge mandating the elimination of land rent which it compared to feudal exploitation and the elimination of landlord status The work teams mobilized poor and landless peasants to take direct and violent action against the leading clans and families of neighboring villages to ensure that family loyalties not interfere with the campaign 38 clarification needed In one village in southern Hebei foreign observers recorded that four people were stoned to death 39 and Hinton reported that at least a dozen purported rich peasants or landlords were beaten to death in the village he called Longbow 40 Land reform movement violence surged in early 1948 prompting some Party leaders such as Xi Zhongxun and Ren Bishi to criticize the movement 41 Ren announced a policy shift in January 1948 guaranteeing that targets of the movement would nonetheless be allowed to keep a share of property 42 This policy change contributed to a shift away from economic struggle and to political struggle 42 The Party instructed that fewer landlords should be targeted and work teams should not beat or torture their targets 42 Land reform was a decisive factor in the result of the Chinese Civil War 43 At the time of the Communist victory more than half of the population living in Communist areas had participated in land reform and over 25 million hectares of land had been redistributed largely as a result of confiscations form landlords and rich peasants 44 Millions of peasants who obtained land through the movement joined the People s Liberation Army or assisted in its logistical networks 43 According to academic Brian DeMare land redistribution was a critical factor in the Communists military success in the civil war because land reforms linked the interests of north and northeast Chinese peasants to the Party s success 44 The success of land reform meant that at the founding of the PRC in 1949 China could credibly claim that for the first time since the late Qing period that it had succeeded in feeding one fifth of the world s population with only 7 of the world s cultivable land 45 Early People s Republic of China campaigns 1949 1953 Edit The Land Reform Movement continued during peace time 44 The round of land reform carried out in the winter 1949 1950 involved treatment of landlords that were considerably more lenient than in the Civil War era land reforms with most landlords avoiding struggle 44 In summer 1950 the Land Reform Law of the People s Republic of China made more lenient treatment of landlords the official policy 46 Landlords would be allowed to keep commercial enterprises and personal belongings other than the five big properties 46 These five big properties land draft animals excess grain agricultural tools and surplus housing were still subject to redistribution 46 The 1950 Land Reform law was also explicit that the land of middle peasants should not be redistributed 46 It also stated that the rich peasant economy must be preserved 46 and that law abiding rich peasants must not be subjected to struggle sessions 47 In this period the Party s view was that fewer targets were necessary in order to unite a broad base in opposition to a limited number of landlords 48 According to this view a focused attack on the landlord class s core would also result in compliance from small and medium landlords 47 The Party instructed work teams to refrain from indiscriminate struggle which was now viewed as illegal struggle 47 Pursuant to these directives the East China Bureau tested a new struggle method in which the most exploitive or criminal landlords deemed evil tyrants would be sent to trial but that work teams would meet with other landlords to explain land reform policy and their comparatively lenient treatment under it 49 The East China Bureau encountered no resistance from these latter landlords and the Party deemed this test program in non violent struggle a total success 49 However the Korean War prompted Party leadership to be concerned that landlords might use the conflict to oppose the new rural order increasing the view that violent struggle was necessary to defeat class enemies 50 Land reform in May 1951 according to Mao biographer Philip Short lurched violently to the left with Mao Zedong laying down new guidelines for not correcting excesses prematurely 1 Beatings while not officially promoted by the party were not prohibited either While landlords had no protection those who were branded rich peasants received moderate protections from violence and those who were on the lower end were fully protected 51 In this vein Mao insisted that the people themselves not the public security organs should become involved in enacting the Land Reform Law and killing the landlords who had oppressed them in contrast to the Soviet practice of dekulakization 1 Mao thought that peasants who killed landlords who had oppressed them would become permanently linked to the revolutionary process in a way that passive spectators could not be 1 Although violence came to be particularly frowned upon by the Party in the final rounds of land reform in practice the struggle by peasants against landlords continued to be often brutal 52 In the early PRC era there were millions of war widows 53 Widows whose husbands had fought in Communist armies received land through the land reform movement as well as assistance farming it 53 Mass killings of landlords EditDestruction of the Chinese landlord class 1949 1953 Part of Early Mao era of China A farmer confronting a landlord 1946LocationChinaDate1946 1953Attack typeMassacre classicideDeaths830 000 Zhou Enlai s estimate 54 800 000 or 2 3 million Mao Zedong s estimate 55 54 200 000 5 000 000 academic estimates Injured1 5 56 6 57 up to 12 5 55 million sent to Laogai campsVictimsLandlords better off peasantsPerpetratorsChinese Communist Party and radicalized peasantsMotiveMaoism economic inequality class struggleThose who were killed were targeted on the basis of their social class rather than their ethnicity the neologism classicide is used to describe the killings 58 Class motivated mass murder continued almost throughout the 30 years of social and economic transformation in Maoist China and by the end of the reforms the landlord class had largely been eliminated from Mainland China or it had fled to Taiwan 59 In his Report on the Peasant Movement in Hunan Mao addressed Party members who were concerned with violence by the peasants against landlords arguing that these concerns were a tool for continuing the oppression of the peasants 60 In this context Mao coined his famous comment that revolution is not a dinner party 60 Mao wrote in response to objections to violence 60 It is fine It is not terrible at all It is anything but terrible It s terrible is obviously a theory for combatting the rise of the peasants in the interests of the landlords it is obviously a theory of the landlord class for preserving the old feudal order and obstructing the establishment of the new democratic order it is obviously a counterrevolutionary theory The Communist Party s tolerance of encouragement of or efforts to restrain violence by peasants against landlords in the course of the land reform movement varied over time and location 61 Its directions were not always followed and as late as the final rounds of land reform Hu Yaobang had to explain that the call to annihilate the landlord class meant taking landlord property not landlord lives 48 Jean Louis Margolin argues that the killings were not a pre condition for land reform because in Taiwan and Japan land reforms were launched with little violence Rather the violence was a result of the fact that the land reform was less about redistribution because within a few years of the reforms most of the land had to be surrendered to collective farms than it was about eliminating rural class enemies and the assumption of local power by the communists Margolin observes that even in very poor villages which covered half of Northern China where nobody could qualify as a landlord some landlords were manufactured so they could be persecuted In Wugong village 70 households out of a total of 387 households were converted from middle peasants into rich peasants making them acceptable targets for class struggle 62 There were policies in certain regions of China not necessarily obeyed citation needed which required the selection of at least one landlord and usually several in virtually every village for public execution 6 An official reported 180 to 190 thousand landlords were executed in the Kwangsi province alone in addition a Catholic school teacher reported 2 5 of his village was executed 55 Some condemned as landlords were buried alive dismembered strangled or shot 51 In many villages landlords women were redistributed as concubines or daughters for peasants or pressured into marrying their husband s persecutors 63 64 Estimated number of deaths Edit Estimates for the number of deaths range from a lower estimate of 200 000 to 800 000 65 5 6 and higher estimates of 2 000 000 5 66 67 to 5 million 68 66 executions for the years 1949 1953 along with 1 5 million 56 to 6 million 57 sent to reform through labour Laogai camps where many perished 57 Philip Short wrote that such estimates exclude the hundreds of thousands driven to suicide during struggle sessions of the three anti five anti campaigns which also occurred around the same time 69 Zhou Enlai estimated 830 000 had been killed while Mao Zedong estimated as many as 2 to 3 million were killed 54 Deng Zihui Vice Chairman of the Central South Military and Administrative Council estimated that 15 of China s 50 000 000 landlords and rich peasants had been sentenced to death 25 had been sent to labor reform camps for remolding through manual work and 60 to participation in production work under supervision 55 Not all of those sentenced to death were actually executed and therefore there is no way of knowing the exact number of performed executions 70 Retaliation by landlords Edit During the Chinese Civil War the Kuomintang established the Huanxiang Tuan Chinese 還鄉團 pinyin Huan xiang tuan or the Homecoming Legion which was composed of landlords who sought the return of their redistributed land and property from peasants and CCP guerrillas and the release of forcibly conscripted peasants and communist POWs 71 The Homecoming legion conducted its guerrilla warfare campaign against CCP forces and purported collaborators up until the end of the civil war in 1949 71 Many landlords used violence to oppose land reform including after the defeat of the Kuomintang 72 Some landlords poisoned wells destroyed agricultural tools or cut down forests 72 The Communist Party widely disseminated stories of landlords crimes as an effort to build support for its view of the landlord class as a whole 72 Land redistribution EditLand seized from Landlords was brought under collective ownership resulting in the creation of Agricultural production cooperatives 73 In the mid 1950s a second land reform during the Great Leap Forward compelled individual farmers to join collectives which in turn were grouped into People s communes with centrally controlled property rights and an egalitarian principle of distribution This policy was generally a failure in terms of production 8 The PRC reversed this policy in 1962 through the proclamation of the Sixty Articles As a result the ownership of the basic means of production was divided into three levels with collective land ownership vested in the production team Ownership of cultivable land before reform in mainland China 74 a Classification Number of households 10 000 Proportion of households Population 10 000 Population ratio Farmland 10 000 mu The proportion of cultivated land The average cultivated land mu Per capita cultivated land mu Poor Farmer 6062 57 44 24123 52 37 21503 14 28 3 55 0 89Middle Peasants 3081 29 20 15260 33 13 46577 30 94 15 12 3 05Rich Farmer 325 3 08 2144 4 66 20566 13 66 63 24 9 59Landlord 400 3 79 2188 4 75 57588 38 26 144 11 26 32Other 686 6 49 2344 5 09 4300 2 86 6 27 1 83Total 10554 100 00 46059 100 00 150534 100 00 14 26 3 27Ownership of cultivable land after reform in mainland China 74 b Classification Number of households Population Cultivated land Per capita cultivated land mu Large livestock Head 100 households Poor Farmer 54 5 52 2 47 1 12 5 46 73Middle Peasants 39 3 39 9 44 3 19 0 90 93Rich Farmer 3 1 5 3 6 4 25 1 114 86Landlord 2 4 2 6 2 2 12 2 23 19Other 0 7 Total 100 00 100 00 100 00 15 3 64 01Economic effects Edit An example of a people s commune collective farm As an economic reform program the land reform succeeded in redistributing about 43 of China s cultivated land to approximately 60 of the rural population 75 Poor peasants increased their holdings while middle peasants benefitted most because of their strong initial position 75 The movement expropriated land from over ten million landlords 76 Historian Walter Scheidel writes that the violence of the land reform campaign had a significant impact in reducing economic inequality He gives as an example the 1940s campaigns in village of Zhangzhuangcun made famous by William Hinton s book Fanshen Although poor and middle peasants had already owned 70 of the land In Zhangzhuangcun in the more thoroughly reformed north of the country most landlords and rich peasants had lost all their land and often their lives or had fled All formerly landless workers had received land which eliminated this category altogether As a result middling peasants who now accounted for 90 percent of the village population owned 90 8 percent of the land as close to perfect equality as one could possibly hope for 3 Following conclusion of the land reform movement harvests and incomes increased 77 Land reform on Taiwan EditMain article Land reform in Taiwan After its retreat to Taiwan the Nationalist government carried out a program of land reform under the Joint Commission on Rural Reconstruction 78 The land reform law removed the landlord class and created a higher number of peasants who with the help of the state dramatically increased Taiwan s agricultural output 79 Land reform also succeeded because the Kuomintang s members were mostly from mainland China and as a result had few ties with the remaining indigenous Taiwanese landowners 80 See also EditCrimes against humanity under communist regimes Criticism of communist party rule Dekulakization Land reform by country List of massacres in China Mass killings under communist regimesNotes Edit The number of households population and total arable land are based on the 1950 agricultural production annual report The figures for each class are calculated based on the proportion of each class before the land reform in each region The number of households was calculated based on the survey data of 9900 households in 21 provinces and autonomous regions Others are calculated based on the survey data of more than 15 000 rural households in 23 provinces and autonomous regions in 1954 References Edit a b c d e f Short 2001 pp 436 437 DeMare 2019 p 93 a b c Scheidel Walter 2017 The Great Leveler Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty First Century Princeton University Press pp 223 226 ISBN 978 0 691 16502 8 a b c d Ching Pao Yu 2021 Revolution and counterrevolution China s continuing class struggle since liberation 2nd ed Paris Foreign languages press p 185 ISBN 978 2 491182 89 2 OCLC 1325647379 a b c Roberts J A G 2006 A History of China Palgrave Essential Histories Series Palgrave Macmillan p 257 ISBN 978 1 4039 9275 8 Estimates of the number of landlords and rural power holders who died range from 200 000 to two million a b c Teiwes Frederic 1987 Establishment of the New Regime In Twitchett Denis John K Fairbank Roderick MacFarquhar eds The Cambridge history of China Cambridge University Press p 87 ISBN 0 521 24336 X Archived from the original on 2019 02 20 Retrieved 2008 08 23 For a careful review of the evidence and a cautious estimate of 200 000 two 800 000 executions see Benedict Stavis The Politics of Agricultural Mechanization in China Ithaca NY Cornell University Press 1978 25 30 Rummel Rudolph J 2007 China s bloody century genocide and mass murder since 1900 Transaction Publishers p 223 ISBN 978 1 4128 0670 1 Archived from the original on 2016 11 09 Retrieved 2016 11 02 a b ChenDavis 1998 a b Bradley 2015 pp 137 138 Muhlhahn 2019 p 402 DeMare 2019 p 10 104 105 Bradley 2015 p 138 Coderre Laurence 2021 Newborn socialist things materiality in Maoist China Durham Duke University Press p 65 ISBN 978 1 4780 2161 2 OCLC 1250021710 a b DeMare 2019 p 137 a b c d Ching Pao Yu 2021 Revolution and counterrevolution China s continuing class struggle since liberation 2nd ed Paris Foreign languages press p 252 ISBN 978 2 491182 89 2 OCLC 1325647379 a b c d e f g h i j k Karl 2010 pp 80 81 DeMare 2019 pp 166 168 DeMare 2019 pp 6 17 DeMare 2019 p 104 Wu Guo 26 April 2014 SPEAKING BITTERNESS POLITICAL EDUCATION IN LAND REFORM AND MILITARY TRAINING UNDER THE CCP 1947 1951 The Chinese Historical Review 21 1 3 23 doi 10 1179 1547402X14Z 00000000026 S2CID 144044801 Retrieved 18 March 2023 DeMare 2019 pp 104 105 a b DeMare 2019 pp 62 63 a b c DeMare 2019 p 63 Karl 2010 p 82 a b DeMare 2019 p 33 DeMare 2019 p 111 DeMare 2019 p 10 11 Huang 2020 pp 249 250 DeMare 2019 p 167 a b c Huang 2020 p 250 a b c DeMare 2019 p 84 DeMare 2019 pp 84 85 Tanner 2015 pp 134 135 Huang 2020 p 532 DeMare 2019 p 86 Hinton William 1972 Fanshen a documentary of revolution in a Chinese village Harmondsworth Penguin p 7 ISBN 0 14 021570 0 OCLC 16255144 a b DeMare 2019 p 112 Tanner Harold Miles 2015 Where Chiang Kai Shek Lost China The Liao Shen Campaign 1948 Bloomington Indiana University Press ISBN 978 0 253 01692 8 p 135 137 CrookCrook 1979 p 151 Hinton 1966 p xi DeMare 2019 p 113 a b c DeMare 2019 p 114 a b Lin Chun 2006 The transformation of Chinese socialism Durham N C Duke University Press p 43 ISBN 978 0 8223 3785 0 OCLC 63178961 a b c d DeMare 2019 p 18 Lin Chun 2006 The transformation of Chinese socialism Durham N C Duke University Press p 44 ISBN 978 0 8223 3785 0 OCLC 63178961 a b c d e DeMare 2019 p 19 a b c DeMare 2019 p 116 a b DeMare 2019 p 118 a b DeMare 2019 p 117 DeMare 2019 p 90 a b Scheidel Walter 2017 The Great Leveler Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty First Century Princeton University Press p 225 ISBN 978 0 691 16502 8 Archived from the original on 2017 09 04 Retrieved 2017 09 03 DeMare 2019 p 105 a b Lary Diana 2022 China s grandmothers gender family and aging from late Qing to twenty first century Cambridge United Kingdom Cambridge University Press p 92 ISBN 978 1 009 06478 1 OCLC 1292532755 a b c Daniel Chirot Modern Tyrants The Power and Prevalence of Evil in Our Age Princeton University Press 1996 187 2014 03 30 ISBN 0 691 02777 3 original content Archived in 2014 07 03 a b c d Rummel Rudolph J 2007 China s bloody century genocide and mass murder since 1900 Transaction Publishers p 222 ISBN 978 1 4128 0670 1 a b Short 2001 p 436 a b c Benjamin A Valentino Final Solutions Mass Killing and Genocide in the Twentieth Century Archived 2019 02 20 at the Wayback Machine Cornell University Press 2004 pp 121 122 ISBN 0 8014 3965 5 Wu Harry 2013 Classicide in Communist China In Arrigo Bruce and Heather Bersot ed The Routledge Handbook of International Crime and Justice Studies Routledge ISBN 978 1 136 86850 4 xxv xxvi Liu William Thomas 1967 Chinese Society Under Communism A Reader Wiley a b c Karl 2010 p 31 DeMare 2019 pp 105 118 Margolin 2008 p 452 Su Yang Collective killings in rural China during the cultural revolution Cambridge University Press 2011 p 111 Margolin 2008 p 455 Stavis Benedict 1978 The Politics of Agricultural Mechanization in China University of California Cornell University Press ISBN 978 0 8014 1087 1 It would appear that somewhere between 400 000 and 800 000 people were killed offi cially after 1949 The Chinese Communist leadership had estimated that landlords and their families constituted 4 5 percent of the rural population about 20 million people This would imply that 1 to 4 percent of landlords families met death If a half million people were killed in land reform this would be 1 percent of the rural population or 2 5 percent of the landlord class and would represent roughly one death in six landlord families pp 29 30 a b Lee Feigon Mao A Reinterpretation Ivan R Dee 2002 ISBN 1 56663 522 5 p 96 By 1952 they had extended land reform throughout the countryside but in the process somewhere between two and five million landlords had been killed Maurice Meisner Mao s China and After A History of the People s Republic Third Edition Free Press 1999 ISBN 0 684 85635 2 p 72 the estimate of many relatively impartial observers that there were 2 000 000 people executed during the first three years of the People s Republic is probably as accurate a guess as one can make on the basis of scanty information Steven W Mosher China Misperceived American Illusions and Chinese Reality Basic Books 1992 ISBN 0 465 09813 4 pg 74 a figure that Fairbank has cited as the upper range of sober estimates Short 2001 p 437 Stavis Benedict 1978 The Politics of Agricultural Mechanization in China Cornell University Press p 29 ISBN 978 0 8014 1087 1 a b Zaiyu Liu 2002 第二次國共戰爭時期的還鄉團 PDF Hong Kong Twenty First Century Bimonthly a b c DeMare 2019 p 94 在中国共产党第七届中央委员会第六次全体会议上 Central People s Government of the People s Republic of China Archived from the original on 27 October 2019 Retrieved 27 October 2019 a b 国家统计局编 建国三十年全国农业统计资料 1949 1979 1980年3月印制 a b Fairbank John King MacFarquhar Roderick 1987 The Cambridge History of China The People s Republic Cambridge University Press p 87 ISBN 978 0 521 24336 0 DeMare 2019 p 141 DeMare 2019 p 146 Clough Ralph 1991 Chapter 12 Taiwan under Nationalist Rule 1949 1982 In MacFaquhar Roderick Fairbank John K eds The People s Republic Cambridge Cambridgeshire Cambridge University Press p 837 ISBN 978 0 521 24337 7 The Labour Movement in Taiwan September 21 2004 Archived from the original on October 21 2019 Retrieved November 7 2019 土地改革紀念館 Land Reform Museum in Chinese Archived from the original on 2011 07 25 Bibliography and further reading EditBradley James 2015 The China mirage the hidden history of American disaster in Asia 1st ed New York ISBN 978 0 316 19667 3 OCLC 870199580 Chen Fu Davis John 1998 Land reform in rural China since the mid 1980s Land Reform Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations Crook Isabel Crook David 1979 Ten Mile Inn Mass Movement in a Chinese Village New York Pantheon Books ISBN 0 394 41178 1 DeMare Brian James 2019 Land Wars The Story of China s Agrarian Revolution Palo Alto CA Stanford University Press ISBN 978 1 5036 0952 5 Hinton William 1966 Fanshen A Documentary of Revolution in a Chinese Village New York Monthly Review Press Huang Yibing 2020 An ideological history of the Communist Party of China Vol I Qian Zheng Guoyou Wu Xuemei Ding Li Sun Shelly Bryant Montreal Quebec ISBN 978 1 4878 0425 1 OCLC 1165409653 Karl Rebecca E 2010 Mao Zedong and China in the twentieth century world a concise history Durham NC Duke University Press ISBN 978 0 8223 4780 4 OCLC 503828045 Li Huaiyin 2011 Village China under Socialism and Reform A Micro History 1948 2008 Stanford Calif Stanford University Press ISBN 978 0 8047 7657 8 Margolin Jean Louis 13 February 2008 Mao s China The Worst Non Genocidal Regime In Stone Dan ed The Historiography of Genocide Springer ISBN 978 0 230 29778 4 Moise Edwin E 1983 Land Reform in China and North Vietnam Consolidating the Revolution at the Village Level Chapel Hill University of North Carolina Press ISBN 9780807874455 Muhlhahn Klaus 2019 Making China Modern From the Great Qing to Xi Jinping Cambridge Massachusetts Harvard University Press ISBN 978 0 674 73735 8 Short Philip 2001 Mao A Life Owl Books ISBN 0 8050 6638 1 Shue Vivienne 1980 Peasant China in Transition The Dynamics of Development toward Socialism 1949 1956 Berkeley CA University of California Press ISBN 978 0 520 03734 2 External links EditLand Reform and Collectivization 1950 1953 Posters from the Stephan Landsberger collection There are other posters on the topic in other sections of the site Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Land Reform Movement China amp oldid 1146885437, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.