fbpx
Wikipedia

Tenant farmer

A tenant farmer is a person (farmer or farmworker) who resides on land owned by a landlord. Tenant farming is an agricultural production system in which landowners contribute their land and often a measure of operating capital and management, while tenant farmers contribute their labor along with at times varying amounts of capital and management. Depending on the contract, tenants can make payments to the owner either of a fixed portion of the product, in cash or in a combination. The rights the tenant has over the land, the form, and measures of payment vary across systems (geographically and chronologically). In some systems, the tenant could be evicted at whim (tenancy at will); in others, the landowner and tenant sign a contract for a fixed number of years (tenancy for years or indenture). In most developed countries today, at least some restrictions are placed on the rights of landlords to evict tenants under normal circumstances.

Tenant farmer on his front porch, south of Muskogee, Oklahoma (1939)

England and Wales edit

Historically, rural society utilised a three tier structure of landowners (nobility, gentry, yeomanry), tenant farmers, and farmworkers. Originally, tenant farmers were known as peasants. Under Anglo-Norman law almost all tenants were bonded to the land, and were therefore also villeins, but after the labour shortage occasioned by the Black Death in the mid-14th century, the number of free tenants substantially increased.[1] Many tenant farmers became affluent and socially well connected, and employed a substantial number of labourers and managed more than one farm. Tenancy could be either in perpetuity[2] or rotated by the owners.[3] Cottiers (cottagers) held much less land.[4]

The 17th century to the early 19th century witnessed the growth of large estates, and the opportunity for a farmer to hold land other than by tenancy was significantly reduced,[5][6] with the result that by the 19th century about 90% of agricultural land area and holdings were tenanted, although these figures declined markedly after World War II, to around 60% in 1950, and only 35% of agricultural land area in 1994.[7] High rates of inheritance taxes in the postwar period led to the breakup or reduction of many large estates,[8] allowing many tenants to buy their holdings at favourable prices.

The landmark 1948 Act was enacted at a time when war-time food rationing was still in force and sought to encourage long-term investment by tenants by granting them lifetime security of tenure. Under the Agriculture (Miscellaneous Provisions) Act 1976 security was extended to spouses and relatives of tenants for two successions, providing that they had been earning the majority of their income from the holding for five years. Succession rights were however withdrawn for new tenancies in 1984[9] and this was consolidated in the Agricultural Holdings Act 1986. These two statutes also laid down rules for the determination of rents by the arbitration process.[7][10] The 1986 statute covered tenancies over agricultural land where the land was used for a trade or business and the definition of "agriculture" in section 96(1) was wide enough to include various uses that in themselves were not agricultural but were deemed so if ancillary to agriculture (e.g. woodlands). The essence of the code was to establish complex constraints on the landlord's ability to give the notice to quit, whilst also converting fixed-term tenancies into yearly tenancies at the conclusion of the fixed term. In addition, there was a uniform rent ascertainment scheme contained in section 12.

It became difficult to obtain new tenancies as a result of landlords' reluctance to have a tenant protected by the 1986 Act and in 1995 the government of the day, with the support of industry organizations, enacted a new market-oriented code in the form of the Agricultural Tenancies Act 1995. The protection of the 1986 Act remains in respect of tenancies created prior to the existence of the 1995 Act, and for those tenancies falling within section 4 of the 1995 Act. For all other tenancies granted on or after 1 September 1995 their regulation is within the 1995 Act framework.

That Act was altered with effect from 18 October 2006 by the Regulatory Reform (Agricultural Tenancies)(England and Wales) Order 2006 SI 2006/2805, which also contains changes to the 1986 Act. Tenancies granted after 18 October 2006 over agricultural land used for a trade or business will fall within the limited protection of the 1995 Act so as to enjoy (provided the term is more than two years in length or there is a yearly tenancy) a mandatory minimum twelve months written notice to quit, including in respect of fixed terms. There is for all tenancies within the scope of the Act a mandatory tenants' right to remove fixtures and buildings (section 8) together with compensation for improvements (Part III). The rent review provisions in Part II may be the subject of choice to a much greater extent than previously. Disputes under the Act are usually, by the terms of Part IV, the subject of statutory arbitration controlled by the framework of the Arbitration Act 1996.

The current regime under the 1995 Act for regulating tenancies, commonly known as Farm Business Tenancies, permits the creation of a clearly and easily terminable interest, whether by a periodic tenancy or a fixed term. In the cycle of animal husbandry and land use and improvement, the long-term effect of the Farm Business Tenancy on the landscape of Britain is not yet proven. It was predicted by landowners and other industry spokesmen that the 1995 Act would create opportunities for new tenants by allowing large areas of new lettings but this has not happened in practice as most landowners have continued to favour share farming or management agreements over formal tenancies and the majority of new lettings under the Act have been to existing farmers, often owner-occupiers taking on extra land at significantly higher rents than could be afforded by a traditional tenant.[7]

Canada edit

From the nineteenth century on, tenant farming immigrants came to Canada not just from the British Isles but also the United States of America.[11]

Ireland edit

Until about 1900, the majority of Ireland was held by landlords, as much as 97% in 1870, and rented out to tenant farmers who had to pay rent to landlords and taxes to the Church of Ireland and State. The majority of the people had no access to land. 1.5% of the population owned 33.7% of the island, and 50% of the country was in the hands of only 750 families. Absenteeism was common and detrimental to the country's progress. Tenants often sub-rented small plots on a yearly basis from local farmers paying for them by labour service by a system, known as conacre, most without any lease or land rights. Irish smallholders were indistinguishable from the cottiers of England.[12][13]

The abuse of tenant farmers led to widespread emigration to the United States and the colonies and was a key factor within the Home Rule Movement.[14] They also underlined a deterioration in Protestant-Catholic relationships,[15] although there were notable elements of cooperation in reform attempts such as the Tenant Right League of the 1850s.[16] Following the Great Famine tenant farmers were the largest class of people.[17] Discontent led to the Land War of the 1870s onwards, the Landlord and Tenant (Ireland) Act 1870, the founding of the Land League 1879 to establish fair rents and the fixity of tenures. The movement played a key element in the unification of country and urban classes and the creation of a national identity[18][19] not existing before.[16]

The Landlord and Tenant (Ireland) Act 1870 stands out as the first attempt to resolve problems of tenants rights in Ireland[14] and the Land Law (Ireland) Act 1881 went even further to inspire campaigners even in Wales. The Purchase of Land (Ireland) Act 1885 followed, finally the great breakthrough after the successful 1902 Land Conference, the enactment of the Land Purchase (Ireland) Act 1903 whereby the state-financed tenants to completely buy out their landlords. Under the Act of 1903 and the consequential Act of 1909, the national situation was completely transformed. When in March 1920, the Irish Estate Commission reviewed the development since 1903 under these Acts, they estimated that 83 million sterling had been advanced for 9 million acres (36,000 km2) transferred, whilst a further 2 million acres (8,100 km2) were pending costing 24 million sterling.[20] By 1914, 75% of occupiers were buying out their landlords, mostly under the two Acts. In all, under the pre-UK Land Acts over 316,000 tenants purchased their holdings amounting to 11,500,000 acres (47,000 km2) out of a total of 20 million in the country.[21]

On the formation of the Irish Free State in 1922, the Irish Land Commission was reconstituted by the Land Law (Commission) Act, 1923.[22] The commission had acquired and supervised the transfer of up to 13 million acres (53,000 km2) of farmland between 1885 and 1920 where the freehold was assigned under mortgage to tenant farmers and farm workers. The focus had been on the compulsory purchase of untenanted estates so that they could be divided into smaller units for local families. In 1983, the Commission ceased acquiring land; this signified the start of the end of the commission's reform of Irish land ownership, though freehold transfers of farmland still had to be signed off by the Commission into the 1990s. The commission was dissolved in March 1999.

Japan edit

In Japan, landowners turned over their land to families of tenant farmers to manage.[23] During the Meiji period, Japanese tenant farmers were traditionally cultivators rather than capitalistic or entrepreneurial venture by nature, paid in kind for their labors. Approximately 30% of land was held by tenants. Many aspects of Tokugawa feudalism continued.[24] After WWII, the Farm Land Reform Law of 1946 banned absentee landlordism, re-distributing land and permitted tenants to buy. By the 1950s, it virtually eliminated the landlord-tenant relationship.[25]

Scandinavia edit

Historically, despite Norway being practically a Danish province for almost 300 years before 1814, the countries of Denmark, Norway, and Sweden (with Finland) had differing approaches to land tenure.[26][27]

Norway edit

 
A typical Husmann residence from Hof

A tenant farmer in Norway was known as a husmann (plural: husmenn) and were most common in the mid-19th century when they constituted around one-quarter of the country's population. Heavy demands were placed on these tenants by their landlords, the bønder or land-owning farmers. The majority of the husmann's working hours were usually taken up by work for the landlord, leaving him little time to work on his own land or better his own situation. As a result, though the husmenn were technically free to leave the land at any time, their poor economic state made them in essence "economic serfs". Failing to own their own land also made tenant farmers ineligible to vote according to the Norwegian Constitution at the time. The number of tenant farmers in the country grew during the 19th century, rising from 48,571 in 1825 to 65,060 in 1855, the latter figure representing the height of the husmann population in Norway, most of whom lived in the eastern part of the country. Given their difficult economic and social position in Norway, many Norwegian husmenn immigrated to Canada and the United States throughout the 19th century. Following the revolutions of 1848 the husmenn's cause was taken up by Marcus Thrane. Thrane fought for the husmenn's rights at home and also encouraged them to emigrate and seek better fortunes abroad. The number of husmenn began to decline in the second half of the 19th century, and by 1910 they made up less than 5% of Norwegian society.[28]

Sweden and Finland edit

The term torpare/torppari (Swedish/Finnish for crofter) refers to a slightly different type of tenant farmers, less secure than the inheritable usufruct right as åbo but sometimes with contracts as long as 50 years. The lease was, depending on the landowner's good will, in practice often transferred to a son or a widow.

Their situation was usually poor but, contrary to in Denmark, they were in theory always free to leave. The croft's lease was typically paid in the form of corvée. They would work their own land as well as that of a landowning farmer (bonde), noble or other. In some aspects their situation made them easy victims of impressment. Population growth and landreforms (enskiftet) contributed to a 19th century increase of crofts but, particularly in Sweden, also to a shift from tenant farmers to farm laborers (statare) hired on yearlong contracts, paid in-kind.

The lives of torpare and statare were described by prominent Swedish and Finnish novelists and writers such as Ivar Lo-Johansson, Jan Fridegård, Väinö Linna (Under the North Star trilogy) and Moa Martinson. The Statare system was abolished in 1918[29] (Finland) and 1945[30] (Sweden), the Torpare system more gradually.

Scotland edit

Scotland has its own independent legal system and the legislation there differs from that of England and Wales. Neither the AHA 1986 nor the ATA 1995 applies in Scotland. The relevant legislation for Scotland is rather the Agricultural Holdings (Scotland) Act 2003 with the following amendments in The Public Services Reform (Agricultural Holdings) (Scotland) Order 2011, The Agricultural Holdings (Amendment) (Scotland) Act 2012 and The Agricultural Holdings (Scotland) 2003 Remedial Order 2014. These supersede the previous legislation in the Agricultural Holdings (Scotland) Act 1991 and the Agriculture (Scotland) Act 1948.[10]

For Scotland see Crofting, a traditional and long-established means of tenant and subsistence farming.

United States edit

Tenant farming has been important in the US from the 1870s to the present. Tenants typically bring their own tools and animals. To that extent it is distinguished from being a sharecropper, which is a tenant farmer who usually provides no capital and pays fees with crops.

A hired hand is an agricultural employee even though he or she may live on the premises and exercise a considerable amount of control over the agricultural work, such as a foreman. A sharecropper is a farm tenant who pays rent with a portion (often half) of the crop he raises and who brings little to the operation besides his family labor; the landlord usually furnishing working stock, tools, fertilizer, housing, fuel, and seed, and often providing regular advice and oversight.

Tenant farming in the North was historically a step on the "agricultural ladder" from hired hand or sharecropper taken by young farmers as they accumulated enough experience and capital to buy land (or buy out their siblings when a farm was inherited).[31]

About two-thirds of sharecroppers were white, the rest black. Sharecroppers, the poorest of the poor, organized for better conditions. The racially integrated Southern Tenant Farmers Union made gains for sharecroppers in the 1930s. Sharecropping had diminished in the 1940s due to the Great Depression, farm mechanization, and other factors.[32]

Black Belt conditions edit

In the Black Belt in the American South until the mid 20th century, the predominant agricultural system involved white land owners and African-American tenant farmers. Very little cash changed hands. The few local banks were small and cash was scarce and had to be hoarded for taxes. Landowners needed a great deal of labor at harvest time to pick the cash crop, cotton.[33] The typical plan was to divide old plantations into small farms that were assigned to the tenants. Throughout the year the tenants lived rent-free. They tended their own gardens. Every week, they bought food and supplies on credit through the local country store. At harvest time, the tenants picked the cotton, and turned it all over to the landowners. They sold the cotton on the national market and used part of the funds to pay the debts owed to the country store. The cycle then started all over again. Landowners also worked some of the land directly, using black labor paid in cash. The landowners held all the political power, and fought vigorously against government welfare programs that would provide cash that would undermine the cashless system. Economic historians Lee Alston and Joseph Ferrie (1999) describe the system as essentially an informal contract that:

bound employer and worker through the provision of housing, medical care, and other in-kind services along with cash wages. At its heart, it guaranteed a stable and adequate labor supply to the planter. Though restricted by the directives of the planter, workers in return received some measure of economic stability, including a social safety net, access to financial capital, and physical protection in an often-violent society.[34]

Tenant farmers often had agricultural managers who supervised their activities. In 1907, for instance, J. H. Netterville began employment for the Panola Company, an agricultural business founded by William Mackenzie Davidson in the rich farming area of St. Joseph in Tensas Parish in northeastern Louisiana in the Mississippi River delta country. In its heyday, Panola controlled some eleven thousand acres, two-thirds planted in cotton and the other third in grains. Netterville became general manager of three highly profitable Panola properties, the Balmoral, Blackwater, and Wyoming plantations near Newellton, in which capacity he supervised 125 African-American tenant farming families, with little strife and great ease, according to reports from that period.[35]

Latin America edit

For tenant farmers and other landholding arrangements in Latin America, see Peasant#Latin American farmers.

See also edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ Dowell, Stephen (1876). A sketch of the history of taxes in England, Volume 1: To the civil war, 1642. London: Longmans. p. 191. OCLC 228439554.
  2. ^ Tenure was based upon customary law, which was eroded by the enclosure acts and others in the 16th, 17th, 18th, and 19th centuries. Clay Christopher (1985). "Types of Tenancy". In Thirsk, Joan (ed.). The Agrarian History of England and Wales, Volume 5, 1640–1750, Part 1, Regional farming systems. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press. pp. 198–229, pages 198–199. ISBN 978-0-521-20076-9.
  3. ^ Baker, Alan R. H.; Butlin, Robin Alan (1973). Studies of Field Systems in the British Isles. London: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-20121-6.
  4. ^ Lang, James; Zandstra, Hubert G. (2001). Notes of a Potato Watcher. Texas A&M University Agriculture Series. College Station: Texas A&M University Press. ISBN 1585441384.
  5. ^ Clay, Christopher (1968). "Marriage, Inheritance, and the Rise of Large Estates in England, 1660–1815". The Economic History Review. New Series. 21 (3): 503––518. doi:10.2307/2592747. JSTOR 2592747.
  6. ^ Clay Christopher (1985). "The Land Market". In Thirsk, Joan (ed.). The Agrarian History of England and Wales, Volume 5, 1640–1750, Part 1, Regional farming systems. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press. pp. 170–197, page 177. ISBN 978-0-521-20076-9.
  7. ^ a b c Gibbard, Ravenscroft and Reeves (1997). "Agricultural Tenancy Reform: The End of Law; or a New Popular Culture?" (PDF). Reading University. Retrieved 24 June 2010.
  8. ^ Gallent, Nick; Juntti, Meri; Kidd, Sue & Shaw, Dave (2008). "Part 3: The Needs of Rural Communities: Chapter 6, Community Change". Introduction to Rural Planning. London: Routledge. pp. 141–163, page 148. ISBN 978-0-415-42996-2. citing Woods, Michael (2005). Contesting Rurality: Politics in the British Countryside. Aldershot, Hants, England: Ashgate. pp. 31–32. ISBN 978-0-7546-3025-8.
  9. ^ Marsden, Terry (1986). "Property—state relations in the 1980s: an examination of landlord-tenant legislation in British agriculture". In Cox, Graham; Lowe, Philip; Winter, Michael (eds.). Agriculture: People and Policies. London: Allen & Unwin. pp. 126–145. ISBN 978-0-04-307001-7.
  10. ^ a b "Agricultural tenancies: Overview of the legislation 1948 to 1995". HM Revenue and Customs. Retrieved 24 June 2010.
  11. ^ Bicha, K. D. (1965). "The Plains Farmer and the Prairie Province Frontier, 1897-1914". Journal of Economic History. 25 (2): 263–270. doi:10.1017/S0022050700056655. S2CID 154294637.
  12. ^ Winstanley, M. J. (1984). Ireland and the Land Question 1800-1922. London: Methuen. ISBN 0416374204.
  13. ^ Clark, Samuel (1978). "The Importance of Agrarian Classes: Agrarian Class Structure and Collective Action in Nineteenth-Century Ireland". British Journal of Sociology. 29 (1): 22–40. doi:10.2307/589217. JSTOR 589217.
  14. ^ a b Kearney, Hugh F. (1989). The British Isles: A History of Four Nations. New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 0521334209.
  15. ^ Miller, Kerby A. (1985). Emigrants and Exiles: Ireland and the Irish Exodus to North America. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0195035941.
  16. ^ a b Connolly, S. J. (1997). "Culture, Identity and Tradition". In Search of Ireland: A Cultural Geography. New York: Routledge. ISBN 0415150078.
  17. ^ Drudy, P. J. (1982). Ireland: Land, Politics, and People. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 052124577X.
  18. ^ Brockliss, L. W. B.; Eastwood, David (1997). A Union of Multiple Identities: The British Isles, c1750-c1850. New York: Manchester University Press. ISBN 0719050464.
  19. ^ Biagini, Eugenio F. (2007). British Democracy and Irish Nationalism, 1876-1906. New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521841764.
  20. ^ Lyons, F. S. L.: pp.234-5
  21. ^ Ferriter, Diarmaid: pp. 62–63
  22. ^ Land Law (Commission) Act, 1923
  23. ^ Smith, Thomas Carlyle (1990) [1954]. The Agrarian Origins of Modern Japan (Reprint ed.). Stanford: Stanford University Press. ISBN 0804705305.
  24. ^ Norman, E. Herbert; Woods, Lawrence T. (2000). Japan's Emergence As a Modern State: Political and Economic Problems of the Meiji Period (60th anniversary ed.). Vancouver: UBC Press. ISBN 0774808225.
  25. ^ Hane, Mikiso (1982). Peasants, Rebels, Women, and Outcastes: The Underside of Modern Japan. New York: Pantheon. ISBN 0394519639.
  26. ^ Tønnesson, Kåre (1981). "Tenancy, Freehold and Enclosure in Scandinavia from the Seventeenth to the Nineteenth Century". Scandinavian Journal of History. 6 (1–4): 191–206. doi:10.1080/03468758108578990.
  27. ^ Høgsæt, R. (1992). "'Their Ancestral Lands' – Succession Rights of Norwegian Tenants in the 16th and 17th Centuries". Scandinavian Journal of History. 17 (2–3): 167–173. doi:10.1080/03468759208579235.
  28. ^ Blegen, Theodore C. (1931). Norwegian Migration to America 1825-1860. Northfield, Minnesota: The Norwegian-American Historical Association.
  29. ^ Rasila V. 1970, Torpparikysymyksen ratkaisuvaihe (in Finnish)
  30. ^ Bra Böckers Lexikon, 1980 (in Swedish)
  31. ^ Donald L. Winters, "Tenant farming in Iowa, 1860-1900: a study of the terms of rental leases." Agricultural History 48.1 (1974): 130–150. Online
  32. ^ "Sharecropping". Slavery by Another Name. PBS. Retrieved 7 December 2021.
  33. ^ Arthur F. Raper, Preface to peasantry: A tale of two black belt counties (1936) Online free to borrow.
  34. ^ Lee Alston and Joseph Ferrie, Southern Paternalism and the American Welfare State (1999) p 28 quoted in Gibbs, "Reconsidering the Southern Black Belt" (2003) p 258.
  35. ^ Henry E. Chambers, (Chicago: A History of Louisiana, 1925), p. 373

Further reading edit

British Isles edit

  • Solow, Barbara (1972). The Land Question and the Irish Economy, 1870–1903. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674508750.
  • Taylor, Henry C. (1955). "Food and Farm Land in Britain". Land Economics. 31 (1): 24–34. doi:10.2307/3159797. JSTOR 3159797.
  • Winstanley, Michael J. (1984). Ireland and the Land Question 1800–1922. London: Methuen. ISBN 0416374204.
  • Buttress, F. A. (1950). Agricultural Periodicals of the British Isles, 1681–1900, and Their Location. Cambridge: University of Cambridge, School of Agriculture.
  • Nicholls, Mark (1999). A History of the Modern British Isles, 1529–1603: The Two Kingdoms. Oxford: Blackwell. ISBN 0631193332.

U.S. edit

  • Atack, Jeremy (1989). "The Agricultural Ladder Revisited: A New Look at an Old Question with Some Data for 1860". Agricultural History. 63 (1): 1–25. JSTOR 3743972.
  • Atack, Jeremy (1988). "Tenants and Yeomen in the Nineteenth Century". Agricultural History. 62 (3): 6–32. JSTOR 3743206.
  • Grubbs, Donald H. (1971). Cry from the Cotton: The Southern Tenant Farmer's Union and the New Deal. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. ISBN 0807811564.
  • Hurt, R. Douglas (2003). African American Life in the Rural South, 1900–1950. Columbia: University of Missouri Press. ISBN 0826214711.
  • Sothworth, Caleb (2002). "Aid to Sharecroppers: How Agrarian Class Structure and Tenant-Farmer Politics Influenced Federal Relief in the South, 1933–1935". Social Science History. 26 (1): 33–70. doi:10.1215/01455532-26-1-33. S2CID 246274833.
  • Turner, Howard A. (1937). "Farm Tenancy Distribution and Trends in the United States". Law and Contemporary Problems. 4 (4): 424–433. doi:10.2307/1189524. JSTOR 1189524.
  • Virts, Nancy (1991). "The Efficiency of Southern Tenant Plantations, 1900–1945". Journal of Economic History. 51 (2): 385–395. doi:10.1017/s0022050700039012. JSTOR 2122582. S2CID 154991172.

World edit

  • Allen, D. W.; Lueck, D. (1992). "Contract Choice in Modern Agriculture: Cash Rent versus Cropshare". Journal of Law and Economics. 35 (2): 397–426. doi:10.1086/467260. JSTOR 725546. S2CID 153707520.
  • Liebowitz, Jonathan J. (1989). "Tenants, Sharecroppers, and the French Agricultural Depression of the Late Nineteenth Century". Journal of Interdisciplinary History. 19 (3): 429–445. doi:10.2307/204363. JSTOR 204363.
  • Matsuoka, K. (1930). "The Peasant Worker in Japan". Pacific Affairs. 3 (12): 1109–1117. doi:10.2307/2750255. JSTOR 2750255.
  • Udo, R. K. (1964). "The Migrant Tenant Farmer of Eastern Nigeria". Africa: Journal of the International African Institute. 34 (4): 326–339. doi:10.2307/1157473. JSTOR 1157473. S2CID 145198131.

External links edit

  • King Cotton's Slaves, 1936 newsreel by The March of Time about landless farmers in the southern United States

tenant, farmer, tenant, farmer, person, farmer, farmworker, resides, land, owned, landlord, tenant, farming, agricultural, production, system, which, landowners, contribute, their, land, often, measure, operating, capital, management, while, tenant, farmers, c. A tenant farmer is a person farmer or farmworker who resides on land owned by a landlord Tenant farming is an agricultural production system in which landowners contribute their land and often a measure of operating capital and management while tenant farmers contribute their labor along with at times varying amounts of capital and management Depending on the contract tenants can make payments to the owner either of a fixed portion of the product in cash or in a combination The rights the tenant has over the land the form and measures of payment vary across systems geographically and chronologically In some systems the tenant could be evicted at whim tenancy at will in others the landowner and tenant sign a contract for a fixed number of years tenancy for years or indenture In most developed countries today at least some restrictions are placed on the rights of landlords to evict tenants under normal circumstances Tenant farmer on his front porch south of Muskogee Oklahoma 1939 Contents 1 England and Wales 2 Canada 3 Ireland 4 Japan 5 Scandinavia 5 1 Norway 5 2 Sweden and Finland 6 Scotland 7 United States 7 1 Black Belt conditions 8 Latin America 9 See also 10 Notes 11 Further reading 11 1 British Isles 11 2 U S 11 3 World 12 External linksEngland and Wales editHistorically rural society utilised a three tier structure of landowners nobility gentry yeomanry tenant farmers and farmworkers Originally tenant farmers were known as peasants Under Anglo Norman law almost all tenants were bonded to the land and were therefore also villeins but after the labour shortage occasioned by the Black Death in the mid 14th century the number of free tenants substantially increased 1 Many tenant farmers became affluent and socially well connected and employed a substantial number of labourers and managed more than one farm Tenancy could be either in perpetuity 2 or rotated by the owners 3 Cottiers cottagers held much less land 4 The 17th century to the early 19th century witnessed the growth of large estates and the opportunity for a farmer to hold land other than by tenancy was significantly reduced 5 6 with the result that by the 19th century about 90 of agricultural land area and holdings were tenanted although these figures declined markedly after World War II to around 60 in 1950 and only 35 of agricultural land area in 1994 7 High rates of inheritance taxes in the postwar period led to the breakup or reduction of many large estates 8 allowing many tenants to buy their holdings at favourable prices The landmark 1948 Act was enacted at a time when war time food rationing was still in force and sought to encourage long term investment by tenants by granting them lifetime security of tenure Under the Agriculture Miscellaneous Provisions Act 1976 security was extended to spouses and relatives of tenants for two successions providing that they had been earning the majority of their income from the holding for five years Succession rights were however withdrawn for new tenancies in 1984 9 and this was consolidated in the Agricultural Holdings Act 1986 These two statutes also laid down rules for the determination of rents by the arbitration process 7 10 The 1986 statute covered tenancies over agricultural land where the land was used for a trade or business and the definition of agriculture in section 96 1 was wide enough to include various uses that in themselves were not agricultural but were deemed so if ancillary to agriculture e g woodlands The essence of the code was to establish complex constraints on the landlord s ability to give the notice to quit whilst also converting fixed term tenancies into yearly tenancies at the conclusion of the fixed term In addition there was a uniform rent ascertainment scheme contained in section 12 It became difficult to obtain new tenancies as a result of landlords reluctance to have a tenant protected by the 1986 Act and in 1995 the government of the day with the support of industry organizations enacted a new market oriented code in the form of the Agricultural Tenancies Act 1995 The protection of the 1986 Act remains in respect of tenancies created prior to the existence of the 1995 Act and for those tenancies falling within section 4 of the 1995 Act For all other tenancies granted on or after 1 September 1995 their regulation is within the 1995 Act framework That Act was altered with effect from 18 October 2006 by the Regulatory Reform Agricultural Tenancies England and Wales Order 2006 SI 2006 2805 which also contains changes to the 1986 Act Tenancies granted after 18 October 2006 over agricultural land used for a trade or business will fall within the limited protection of the 1995 Act so as to enjoy provided the term is more than two years in length or there is a yearly tenancy a mandatory minimum twelve months written notice to quit including in respect of fixed terms There is for all tenancies within the scope of the Act a mandatory tenants right to remove fixtures and buildings section 8 together with compensation for improvements Part III The rent review provisions in Part II may be the subject of choice to a much greater extent than previously Disputes under the Act are usually by the terms of Part IV the subject of statutory arbitration controlled by the framework of the Arbitration Act 1996 The current regime under the 1995 Act for regulating tenancies commonly known as Farm Business Tenancies permits the creation of a clearly and easily terminable interest whether by a periodic tenancy or a fixed term In the cycle of animal husbandry and land use and improvement the long term effect of the Farm Business Tenancy on the landscape of Britain is not yet proven It was predicted by landowners and other industry spokesmen that the 1995 Act would create opportunities for new tenants by allowing large areas of new lettings but this has not happened in practice as most landowners have continued to favour share farming or management agreements over formal tenancies and the majority of new lettings under the Act have been to existing farmers often owner occupiers taking on extra land at significantly higher rents than could be afforded by a traditional tenant 7 Canada editFrom the nineteenth century on tenant farming immigrants came to Canada not just from the British Isles but also the United States of America 11 Ireland editUntil about 1900 the majority of Ireland was held by landlords as much as 97 in 1870 and rented out to tenant farmers who had to pay rent to landlords and taxes to the Church of Ireland and State The majority of the people had no access to land 1 5 of the population owned 33 7 of the island and 50 of the country was in the hands of only 750 families Absenteeism was common and detrimental to the country s progress Tenants often sub rented small plots on a yearly basis from local farmers paying for them by labour service by a system known as conacre most without any lease or land rights Irish smallholders were indistinguishable from the cottiers of England 12 13 The abuse of tenant farmers led to widespread emigration to the United States and the colonies and was a key factor within the Home Rule Movement 14 They also underlined a deterioration in Protestant Catholic relationships 15 although there were notable elements of cooperation in reform attempts such as the Tenant Right League of the 1850s 16 Following the Great Famine tenant farmers were the largest class of people 17 Discontent led to the Land War of the 1870s onwards the Landlord and Tenant Ireland Act 1870 the founding of the Land League 1879 to establish fair rents and the fixity of tenures The movement played a key element in the unification of country and urban classes and the creation of a national identity 18 19 not existing before 16 The Landlord and Tenant Ireland Act 1870 stands out as the first attempt to resolve problems of tenants rights in Ireland 14 and the Land Law Ireland Act 1881 went even further to inspire campaigners even in Wales The Purchase of Land Ireland Act 1885 followed finally the great breakthrough after the successful 1902 Land Conference the enactment of the Land Purchase Ireland Act 1903 whereby the state financed tenants to completely buy out their landlords Under the Act of 1903 and the consequential Act of 1909 the national situation was completely transformed When in March 1920 the Irish Estate Commission reviewed the development since 1903 under these Acts they estimated that 83 million sterling had been advanced for 9 million acres 36 000 km2 transferred whilst a further 2 million acres 8 100 km2 were pending costing 24 million sterling 20 By 1914 75 of occupiers were buying out their landlords mostly under the two Acts In all under the pre UK Land Acts over 316 000 tenants purchased their holdings amounting to 11 500 000 acres 47 000 km2 out of a total of 20 million in the country 21 On the formation of the Irish Free State in 1922 the Irish Land Commission was reconstituted by the Land Law Commission Act 1923 22 The commission had acquired and supervised the transfer of up to 13 million acres 53 000 km2 of farmland between 1885 and 1920 where the freehold was assigned under mortgage to tenant farmers and farm workers The focus had been on the compulsory purchase of untenanted estates so that they could be divided into smaller units for local families In 1983 the Commission ceased acquiring land this signified the start of the end of the commission s reform of Irish land ownership though freehold transfers of farmland still had to be signed off by the Commission into the 1990s The commission was dissolved in March 1999 Japan editIn Japan landowners turned over their land to families of tenant farmers to manage 23 During the Meiji period Japanese tenant farmers were traditionally cultivators rather than capitalistic or entrepreneurial venture by nature paid in kind for their labors Approximately 30 of land was held by tenants Many aspects of Tokugawa feudalism continued 24 After WWII the Farm Land Reform Law of 1946 banned absentee landlordism re distributing land and permitted tenants to buy By the 1950s it virtually eliminated the landlord tenant relationship 25 Scandinavia editHistorically despite Norway being practically a Danish province for almost 300 years before 1814 the countries of Denmark Norway and Sweden with Finland had differing approaches to land tenure 26 27 Norway edit nbsp A typical Husmann residence from HofA tenant farmer in Norway was known as a husmann plural husmenn and were most common in the mid 19th century when they constituted around one quarter of the country s population Heavy demands were placed on these tenants by their landlords the bonder or land owning farmers The majority of the husmann s working hours were usually taken up by work for the landlord leaving him little time to work on his own land or better his own situation As a result though the husmenn were technically free to leave the land at any time their poor economic state made them in essence economic serfs Failing to own their own land also made tenant farmers ineligible to vote according to the Norwegian Constitution at the time The number of tenant farmers in the country grew during the 19th century rising from 48 571 in 1825 to 65 060 in 1855 the latter figure representing the height of the husmann population in Norway most of whom lived in the eastern part of the country Given their difficult economic and social position in Norway many Norwegian husmenn immigrated to Canada and the United States throughout the 19th century Following the revolutions of 1848 the husmenn s cause was taken up by Marcus Thrane Thrane fought for the husmenn s rights at home and also encouraged them to emigrate and seek better fortunes abroad The number of husmenn began to decline in the second half of the 19th century and by 1910 they made up less than 5 of Norwegian society 28 Sweden and Finland edit The term torpare torppari Swedish Finnish for crofter refers to a slightly different type of tenant farmers less secure than the inheritable usufruct right as abo but sometimes with contracts as long as 50 years The lease was depending on the landowner s good will in practice often transferred to a son or a widow Their situation was usually poor but contrary to in Denmark they were in theory always free to leave The croft s lease was typically paid in the form of corvee They would work their own land as well as that of a landowning farmer bonde noble or other In some aspects their situation made them easy victims of impressment Population growth and landreforms enskiftet contributed to a 19th century increase of crofts but particularly in Sweden also to a shift from tenant farmers to farm laborers statare hired on yearlong contracts paid in kind The lives of torpare and statare were described by prominent Swedish and Finnish novelists and writers such as Ivar Lo Johansson Jan Fridegard Vaino Linna Under the North Star trilogy and Moa Martinson The Statare system was abolished in 1918 29 Finland and 1945 30 Sweden the Torpare system more gradually Scotland editThis section needs expansion You can help by adding to it July 2010 Scotland has its own independent legal system and the legislation there differs from that of England and Wales Neither the AHA 1986 nor the ATA 1995 applies in Scotland The relevant legislation for Scotland is rather the Agricultural Holdings Scotland Act 2003 with the following amendments in The Public Services Reform Agricultural Holdings Scotland Order 2011 The Agricultural Holdings Amendment Scotland Act 2012 and The Agricultural Holdings Scotland 2003 Remedial Order 2014 These supersede the previous legislation in the Agricultural Holdings Scotland Act 1991 and the Agriculture Scotland Act 1948 10 For Scotland see Crofting a traditional and long established means of tenant and subsistence farming United States editTenant farming has been important in the US from the 1870s to the present Tenants typically bring their own tools and animals To that extent it is distinguished from being a sharecropper which is a tenant farmer who usually provides no capital and pays fees with crops A hired hand is an agricultural employee even though he or she may live on the premises and exercise a considerable amount of control over the agricultural work such as a foreman A sharecropper is a farm tenant who pays rent with a portion often half of the crop he raises and who brings little to the operation besides his family labor the landlord usually furnishing working stock tools fertilizer housing fuel and seed and often providing regular advice and oversight Tenant farming in the North was historically a step on the agricultural ladder from hired hand or sharecropper taken by young farmers as they accumulated enough experience and capital to buy land or buy out their siblings when a farm was inherited 31 About two thirds of sharecroppers were white the rest black Sharecroppers the poorest of the poor organized for better conditions The racially integrated Southern Tenant Farmers Union made gains for sharecroppers in the 1930s Sharecropping had diminished in the 1940s due to the Great Depression farm mechanization and other factors 32 Black Belt conditions edit Further information Black land loss in the United States African American history of agriculture in the United States and Jim Crow economy In the Black Belt in the American South until the mid 20th century the predominant agricultural system involved white land owners and African American tenant farmers Very little cash changed hands The few local banks were small and cash was scarce and had to be hoarded for taxes Landowners needed a great deal of labor at harvest time to pick the cash crop cotton 33 The typical plan was to divide old plantations into small farms that were assigned to the tenants Throughout the year the tenants lived rent free They tended their own gardens Every week they bought food and supplies on credit through the local country store At harvest time the tenants picked the cotton and turned it all over to the landowners They sold the cotton on the national market and used part of the funds to pay the debts owed to the country store The cycle then started all over again Landowners also worked some of the land directly using black labor paid in cash The landowners held all the political power and fought vigorously against government welfare programs that would provide cash that would undermine the cashless system Economic historians Lee Alston and Joseph Ferrie 1999 describe the system as essentially an informal contract that bound employer and worker through the provision of housing medical care and other in kind services along with cash wages At its heart it guaranteed a stable and adequate labor supply to the planter Though restricted by the directives of the planter workers in return received some measure of economic stability including a social safety net access to financial capital and physical protection in an often violent society 34 Tenant farmers often had agricultural managers who supervised their activities In 1907 for instance J H Netterville began employment for the Panola Company an agricultural business founded by William Mackenzie Davidson in the rich farming area of St Joseph in Tensas Parish in northeastern Louisiana in the Mississippi River delta country In its heyday Panola controlled some eleven thousand acres two thirds planted in cotton and the other third in grains Netterville became general manager of three highly profitable Panola properties the Balmoral Blackwater and Wyoming plantations near Newellton in which capacity he supervised 125 African American tenant farming families with little strife and great ease according to reports from that period 35 Latin America editFor tenant farmers and other landholding arrangements in Latin America see Peasant Latin American farmers See also editLand reform by country Peasant Serfdom Metayage system of sharecropping Plain Folk of the Old South 1949 book about U S before 1860 Rural tenancy Sharecropping Verdingkinder Colonus person Kamajiro HottaNotes edit Dowell Stephen 1876 A sketch of the history of taxes in England Volume 1 To the civil war 1642 London Longmans p 191 OCLC 228439554 Tenure was based upon customary law which was eroded by the enclosure acts and others in the 16th 17th 18th and 19th centuries Clay Christopher 1985 Types of Tenancy In Thirsk Joan ed The Agrarian History of England and Wales Volume 5 1640 1750 Part 1 Regional farming systems Cambridge England Cambridge University Press pp 198 229 pages 198 199 ISBN 978 0 521 20076 9 Baker Alan R H Butlin Robin Alan 1973 Studies of Field Systems in the British Isles London Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 20121 6 Lang James Zandstra Hubert G 2001 Notes of a Potato Watcher Texas A amp M University Agriculture Series College Station Texas A amp M University Press ISBN 1585441384 Clay Christopher 1968 Marriage Inheritance and the Rise of Large Estates in England 1660 1815 The Economic History Review New Series 21 3 503 518 doi 10 2307 2592747 JSTOR 2592747 Clay Christopher 1985 The Land Market In Thirsk Joan ed The Agrarian History of England and Wales Volume 5 1640 1750 Part 1 Regional farming systems Cambridge England Cambridge University Press pp 170 197 page 177 ISBN 978 0 521 20076 9 a b c Gibbard Ravenscroft and Reeves 1997 Agricultural Tenancy Reform The End of Law or a New Popular Culture PDF Reading University Retrieved 24 June 2010 Gallent Nick Juntti Meri Kidd Sue amp Shaw Dave 2008 Part 3 The Needs of Rural Communities Chapter 6 Community Change Introduction to Rural Planning London Routledge pp 141 163 page 148 ISBN 978 0 415 42996 2 citing Woods Michael 2005 Contesting Rurality Politics in the British Countryside Aldershot Hants England Ashgate pp 31 32 ISBN 978 0 7546 3025 8 Marsden Terry 1986 Property state relations in the 1980s an examination of landlord tenant legislation in British agriculture In Cox Graham Lowe Philip Winter Michael eds Agriculture People and Policies London Allen amp Unwin pp 126 145 ISBN 978 0 04 307001 7 a b Agricultural tenancies Overview of the legislation 1948 to 1995 HM Revenue and Customs Retrieved 24 June 2010 Bicha K D 1965 The Plains Farmer and the Prairie Province Frontier 1897 1914 Journal of Economic History 25 2 263 270 doi 10 1017 S0022050700056655 S2CID 154294637 Winstanley M J 1984 Ireland and the Land Question 1800 1922 London Methuen ISBN 0416374204 Clark Samuel 1978 The Importance of Agrarian Classes Agrarian Class Structure and Collective Action in Nineteenth Century Ireland British Journal of Sociology 29 1 22 40 doi 10 2307 589217 JSTOR 589217 a b Kearney Hugh F 1989 The British Isles A History of Four Nations New York Cambridge University Press ISBN 0521334209 Miller Kerby A 1985 Emigrants and Exiles Ireland and the Irish Exodus to North America New York Oxford University Press ISBN 0195035941 a b Connolly S J 1997 Culture Identity and Tradition In Search of Ireland A Cultural Geography New York Routledge ISBN 0415150078 Drudy P J 1982 Ireland Land Politics and People Cambridge Cambridge University Press ISBN 052124577X Brockliss L W B Eastwood David 1997 A Union of Multiple Identities The British Isles c1750 c1850 New York Manchester University Press ISBN 0719050464 Biagini Eugenio F 2007 British Democracy and Irish Nationalism 1876 1906 New York Cambridge University Press ISBN 9780521841764 Lyons F S L pp 234 5 Ferriter Diarmaid pp 62 63 Land Law Commission Act 1923 Smith Thomas Carlyle 1990 1954 The Agrarian Origins of Modern Japan Reprint ed Stanford Stanford University Press ISBN 0804705305 Norman E Herbert Woods Lawrence T 2000 Japan s Emergence As a Modern State Political and Economic Problems of the Meiji Period 60th anniversary ed Vancouver UBC Press ISBN 0774808225 Hane Mikiso 1982 Peasants Rebels Women and Outcastes The Underside of Modern Japan New York Pantheon ISBN 0394519639 Tonnesson Kare 1981 Tenancy Freehold and Enclosure in Scandinavia from the Seventeenth to the Nineteenth Century Scandinavian Journal of History 6 1 4 191 206 doi 10 1080 03468758108578990 Hogsaet R 1992 Their Ancestral Lands Succession Rights of Norwegian Tenants in the 16th and 17th Centuries Scandinavian Journal of History 17 2 3 167 173 doi 10 1080 03468759208579235 Blegen Theodore C 1931 Norwegian Migration to America 1825 1860 Northfield Minnesota The Norwegian American Historical Association Rasila V 1970 Torpparikysymyksen ratkaisuvaihe in Finnish Bra Bockers Lexikon 1980 in Swedish Donald L Winters Tenant farming in Iowa 1860 1900 a study of the terms of rental leases Agricultural History 48 1 1974 130 150 Online Sharecropping Slavery by Another Name PBS Retrieved 7 December 2021 Arthur F Raper Preface to peasantry A tale of two black belt counties 1936 Online free to borrow Lee Alston and Joseph Ferrie Southern Paternalism and the American Welfare State 1999 p 28 quoted in Gibbs Reconsidering the Southern Black Belt 2003 p 258 Henry E Chambers Chicago A History of Louisiana 1925 p 373Further reading editBritish Isles edit Solow Barbara 1972 The Land Question and the Irish Economy 1870 1903 Cambridge Harvard University Press ISBN 0674508750 Taylor Henry C 1955 Food and Farm Land in Britain Land Economics 31 1 24 34 doi 10 2307 3159797 JSTOR 3159797 Winstanley Michael J 1984 Ireland and the Land Question 1800 1922 London Methuen ISBN 0416374204 Buttress F A 1950 Agricultural Periodicals of the British Isles 1681 1900 and Their Location Cambridge University of Cambridge School of Agriculture Nicholls Mark 1999 A History of the Modern British Isles 1529 1603 The Two Kingdoms Oxford Blackwell ISBN 0631193332 U S edit Atack Jeremy 1989 The Agricultural Ladder Revisited A New Look at an Old Question with Some Data for 1860 Agricultural History 63 1 1 25 JSTOR 3743972 Atack Jeremy 1988 Tenants and Yeomen in the Nineteenth Century Agricultural History 62 3 6 32 JSTOR 3743206 Grubbs Donald H 1971 Cry from the Cotton The Southern Tenant Farmer s Union and the New Deal Chapel Hill University of North Carolina Press ISBN 0807811564 Hurt R Douglas 2003 African American Life in the Rural South 1900 1950 Columbia University of Missouri Press ISBN 0826214711 Sothworth Caleb 2002 Aid to Sharecroppers How Agrarian Class Structure and Tenant Farmer Politics Influenced Federal Relief in the South 1933 1935 Social Science History 26 1 33 70 doi 10 1215 01455532 26 1 33 S2CID 246274833 Turner Howard A 1937 Farm Tenancy Distribution and Trends in the United States Law and Contemporary Problems 4 4 424 433 doi 10 2307 1189524 JSTOR 1189524 Virts Nancy 1991 The Efficiency of Southern Tenant Plantations 1900 1945 Journal of Economic History 51 2 385 395 doi 10 1017 s0022050700039012 JSTOR 2122582 S2CID 154991172 World edit Allen D W Lueck D 1992 Contract Choice in Modern Agriculture Cash Rent versus Cropshare Journal of Law and Economics 35 2 397 426 doi 10 1086 467260 JSTOR 725546 S2CID 153707520 Liebowitz Jonathan J 1989 Tenants Sharecroppers and the French Agricultural Depression of the Late Nineteenth Century Journal of Interdisciplinary History 19 3 429 445 doi 10 2307 204363 JSTOR 204363 Matsuoka K 1930 The Peasant Worker in Japan Pacific Affairs 3 12 1109 1117 doi 10 2307 2750255 JSTOR 2750255 Udo R K 1964 The Migrant Tenant Farmer of Eastern Nigeria Africa Journal of the International African Institute 34 4 326 339 doi 10 2307 1157473 JSTOR 1157473 S2CID 145198131 External links editKing Cotton s Slaves 1936 newsreel by The March of Time about landless farmers in the southern United States Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Tenant farmer amp oldid 1192952018, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.