fbpx
Wikipedia

Emancipation reform of 1861

The emancipation reform of 1861 in Russia, also known as the Edict of Emancipation of Russia, (Russian: Крестьянская реформа 1861 года, romanizedKrestyanskaya reforma 1861 goda – "peasants' reform of 1861") was the first and most important of the liberal reforms enacted during the reign (1855–1881) of Emperor Alexander II of Russia. The reform effectively abolished serfdom throughout the Russian Empire.

A 1907 painting by Boris Kustodiev depicting Russian serfs listening to the proclamation of the Emancipation Manifesto in 1861

The 1861 Emancipation Manifesto proclaimed the emancipation of the serfs on private estates and of the domestic (household) serfs. By this edict more than 23 million people received their liberty.[1] Serfs gained the full rights of free citizens, including rights to marry without having to gain consent, to own property and to own a business. The Manifesto prescribed that peasants would be able to buy the land from the landlords. Household serfs were the least affected: they gained only their freedom and no land.[citation needed]

The serfs were emancipated in 1861, following a speech given by Tsar Alexander II on 30 March 1856.[2] In Georgia, the emancipation took place later, in 1864, and on much better terms for the nobles than in Russia.[3] State-owned serfs (those living on and working Imperial lands) were emancipated in 1866.[1]

Background Edit

Prior to 1861 Russia had two main categories of peasants:[citation needed]

Only those who were owned privately were considered serfs. They comprised an estimated 38% of the population.[4] As well as having obligations to the state, they also were obliged to the landowner, who had great power over their lives.

The rural population lived in households (dvory, singular dvor), gathered as villages (derevni; a derevnya with a church became a selo), run by a mir ('commune', or obshchina)—isolated, conservative, largely self-sufficient and self-governing units scattered across the land every 10 km (6.2 mi) or so. Imperial Russia had around 20 million dvory, forty percent of them containing six to ten people.[citation needed]

Intensely insular, the mir assembly, the skhod (sel'skii skhod), appointed an elder (starosta) and a 'clerk' (pisar) to deal with any external issues. Peasants within a mir shared land and resources. The fields were divided among the families as nadel ("allotment")—a complex of strip plots, distributed according to the quality of the soil. The strips were periodically redistributed within the villages to produce level economic conditions. The land however, was not owned by the mir; the land was the legal property of the 100,000 or so landowners (pomeshchiks, an equivalent of "landed gentry") and the inhabitants, as serfs, were not allowed to leave the property where they were born. The peasants were duty-bound to make regular payments in labor and goods. It has been estimated[by whom?] that landowners took at least one third of income and production by the first half of the nineteenth century.[5]

Earlier reform moves Edit

The need for urgent reform was well understood in 19th-century Russia. Much support for it emanated from universities, authors and other intellectual circles. Various projects of emancipation reforms were prepared by Mikhail Speransky, Nikolay Mordvinov, and Pavel Kiselyov. However, conservative or reactionary nobility thwarted their efforts. In Western guberniyas serfdom was abolished early in the century. In Congress Poland, serfdom had been abolished before it became Russian (by Napoleon in 1807), but it was largely restored once Russia took over in 1815. Serfdom was abolished in governorates of Estonia in 1816, in Courland in 1817, and in Livonia in 1819.[6]

In 1797, Paul I of Russia decreed that corvee labor was limited to 3 days a week, and never on Sunday, but this law was not enforced. Beginning in 1801, Alexander I of Russia appointed a committee to study possible emancipation, but its only effect was to prohibit the sale of serfs without their families. Beginning in 1825, Nicholas I of Russia expressed his desire for emancipation on many occasions, and even improved the lives of serfs on state properties, but did not change the condition of serfs on private estates.[7]

Shaping of the manifesto Edit

My intention is to abolish serfdom ... you can yourself understand that the present order of owning souls cannot remain unchanged. It is better to abolish serfdom from above, than to wait for that time when it starts to abolish itself from below. I ask you to think about the best way to carry this out

— Alexander II's speech to the Marshalls of the Nobility, 30 March 1856.[2]

The liberal politicians who stood behind the 1861 manifesto—Nikolay Milyutin, Alexei Strol'man and Yakov Rostovtsev—also recognized that their country was one of a few remaining feudal states in Europe. The pitiful display by Russian forces in the Crimean War left the government acutely aware of the empire's weaknesses. Eager to grow and develop industrial and therefore military and political strength, they introduced a number of economic reforms. It was optimistically hoped that after the abolition the mir would dissolve into individual peasant land owners and the beginnings of a market economy.[citation needed]

Alexander II, unlike his father, was willing to deal with this problem. Moving on from a petition from the Lithuanian provinces, a committee "for ameliorating the condition of the peasants" was founded and the principles of the abolition considered.[citation needed]

The main point at issue was whether the serfs should remain dependent on the landlords, or whether they should be transformed into a class of independent communal proprietors.[citation needed]

The land-owners initially pushed for granting the peasants freedom but not any land. The tsar and his advisers, mindful of 1848 events in Western Europe, were opposed to creating a proletariat and the instability this could bring. But giving the peasants freedom and land seemed to leave the existing land-owners without the large and cheap labour-force they needed to maintain their estates and lifestyles. By 1859 however, a third of their estates and two-thirds of their serfs were mortgaged to the state or noble banks. This was why they had to accept the emancipation.[8]

To 'balance' this, the legislation contained three measures to reduce the potential economic self-sufficiency of the peasants. Firstly a transition period of two years was introduced, during which the peasant was obligated as before to the old land-owner. Secondly large parts of common land were passed to the major land-owners as otrezki ("cut off lands"), making many forests, roads and rivers accessible only for a fee. The third measure was that the serfs must pay the land-owner for their allocation of land in a series of redemption payments, which in turn, were used to compensate the landowners with bonds. The government would advance 75% of the total sum to the land-owner, and then the peasants would repay the government, plus interest, over forty-nine years. The government finally cancelled these redemption payments in 1907.[citation needed]

Emancipation Manifesto Edit

 
Peasants Reading the Emancipation Manifesto, an 1873 painting by Grigory Myasoyedov

The legal basis of the reform was the Tsar's Emancipation Manifesto of 3 March [O.S. 19 February] 1861,[9][10][11] accompanied by the set of legislative acts under the general name Regulations Concerning Peasants Leaving Serf Dependence (Russian: Положения о крестьянах, выходящих из крепостной зависимости Polozheniya o krestyanakh, vykhodyashchikh iz krepostnoi zavisimosti).[citation needed]

This Manifesto proclaimed the emancipation of the serfs on private estates and of the domestic (household) serfs.[1] Serfs were granted the full rights of free citizens, gaining the rights to marry without having to gain consent, to own property and to own a business. The Manifesto also permitted peasants to buy the land from the landlords.[citation needed]

Implementation Edit

Mir communities had the power to distribute the land given to newly freed serfs by the Russian government amongst individuals within the community. Due to the community's ownership of the land, as opposed to the individual's, an individual peasant could not sell his portion of the land to go work in a factory in the city. A peasant was required to pay off long term loans received by the government. The money from these loans was given to the primary landowner. The land allotted to the recently freed serfs did not include the best land in the country, which remained in the hands of the nobility.[citation needed]

The implementation of land settlement varied over the vast and diverse territory of the Russian Empire, but typically a peasant had rights to buy out about half of the land he cultivated for himself. If he could not afford to pay it off, he would receive a half of the half, i.e., a quarter of the land, free. It was called pauper's allotment (bednyatskiy nadel).[12]

Though well planned in the legislation, the reform did not work smoothly. Many reform-minded peasants believed the manifesto's conditions were unacceptable: "In many localities the peasants refused to believe that the manifesto was genuine. There were troubles, and troops had to be called in to disperse the angry crowds."[13] The land-owners and nobility were paid in government bonds, with their debts deducted. The bonds soon fell in value. The management skills of the land-owners were generally poor.[citation needed]

Some Mir's did not enter the land redemption process at all, remaining as temporarily obligated peasants under their former owners until an 1881 decree made redemption compulsory. In 1883, concerned by rising levels of tax arrears, the government made a 13% cut (varying by commune, as a national average) to payment rates to combat the problem.[14]

Outcomes Edit

 
The Abolition of Serfdom in Russia: Work in Freedom is the Foundation of a State (1914), by Alphonse Mucha, The Slav Epic
 
Central Bank of Russia coin commemorating the 150th anniversary of the emancipation reform

Despite newly acquired freedom, the life of a serf remained grim in many aspects. Household serfs benefited the least, gaining their freedom, but no land. Many bureaucrats believed that these reforms would bring about drastic changes that would only affect the "lower stories" of society, strengthening the autocracy. In reality, the reforms forced the monarch to coexist with an independent court, free press, and local governments—all operating differently and more freely than they had in the past.[15]: p. 110  This new form of local government involved in each area an assembly called a zemstvo. In regards to new localized government, the reforms put in place a system where the landowners were now able to have more of a say within their newly formed "provinces".[15]: p. 112  While this was not the direct intent of the reforms, it was evident that this significantly weakened the idea of the autocracy. Now, the "well-to-do" serfs, along with previously free peoples, were able to purchase land as private property. While early in the reforms the creation of local government had not changed many things about Russian society, the rise in capitalism drastically affected not only the social structure of Russia, but the behaviors and activities of the self-government institutions.[15]: p. 113  With new, capitalistic ideals, local government was not responsible for the rules and regulations dictating how the new market would operate. If there was a positive of this movement towards localized government, from the autocracy's point of view; it was (as Petr Valuev put it): the zemstvo would "provide activity for the considerable portion of the press as well as those malcontents who currently stir up trouble because they have nothing to do".[15]: p. 111 

Effects on the serfs Edit

The serfs of private estates received less land than they needed to survive, which led to civil unrest. The redemption tax was so high that the serfs had to sell all the grain they produced to pay the tax, which left nothing for their survival. Landowners also suffered because many of them were deeply in debt, and the forced selling of their land left them struggling to maintain their lavish lifestyle. In many cases, the newly freed serfs were forced to "rent" their land from wealthy landowners. Furthermore, when the peasants had to work for the same landowners to pay their "labor payments", they often neglected their own fields.[15]: p. 126  Over the next few years, the yields from the peasants' crops remained low, and soon famine struck a large portion of Russia.[15]: p. 127  With little food, and finding themselves in a similar condition as when they were serfs, many peasants started to voice their disdain for the new social system. On one occasion, on 12 April 1861, a local leader murdered a large number of uprising peasants in the village of Bezdna.[16] When the incident was over, the official report counted 70 peasants dead and another 100 wounded. After further investigation, and trial of some members of the uprising, five peasants were found guilty of "agitation" and not uprising.[16] That said, several different instances did take the form of an uprising.[16]

Aftermath Edit

In Congress Poland and in northern Russia peasants became both free and landless (batraks), with only their labour to sell, while in other areas peasants became the majority land-owners in their province(s). The 1861 Emancipation Manifesto affected only the privately owned serfs. The state-owned serfs were emancipated in 1866[1] and were given better and larger plots of land.

Lastly, the reforms transformed the Russian economy. The individuals who led the reform favored an economic system similar to that in other European countries, which promoted the ideas of capitalism and free trade. The reformers aimed to promote development and to encourage the ownership of private property, free competition, entrepreneurship, and hired labor.[citation needed] This they hoped would bring about an economic system with minimal regulations and tariffs, thus a more "laissez-faire" economy. Soon after the reforms there was a substantial rise in the amount of production of grain for sale. Because of this there was also a rise in the number of hired laborers and in farm machinery.[15]: p. 125  Furthermore, a significant measuring stick in the growth of the Russian economy post-reform was the huge growth in non-gentry private landownership. Although the gentry land-holdings fell from 80% to 50%, the peasant holdings grew from 5% all the way to 20%.[15]: p. 126 

See also Edit

References Edit

  1. ^ a b c d Mee, Arthur; Hammerton, J.A.; Innes, Arthur D.; Harmsworth History of the World: Volume 7, 1907, Carmelite House, London; p. 5193.
  2. ^ a b Corrin, Chris; Feihn, Terry (31 July 2015). AQA A-level History Tsarist and Communist Russia: 1855–1964. Hachette UK: Hodder Education; Dynamic Learning. p. 11. ISBN 978-1471837807. Retrieved 8 September 2015. On 30 March 1856 Alexander II made a speech to the Marshalls of the Nobility in which he signalled the start of a process that led to the abolition of serfdom in 1861.
  3. ^ Suny, Ronald Grigor (January 1979). ""The Peasants Have Always Fed Us": The Georgian Nobility and the Peasant Emancipation, 1856–1871". The Russian Review. 38 (1): 27–51. doi:10.2307/129075. JSTOR 129075 – via JSTOR.
  4. ^ Richard Pipes, Russia Under the Old Regime.
  5. ^ Waldron, P. (2007) The Governing of Tsarist Russia Palgrave Macmillan p. 61 ISBN 978-0-333-71718-9
  6. ^ Charles Wetherell, Andrejs Plakans, "Borders, ethnicity, and demographic patterns in the Russian Baltic provinces in the late nineteenth century", Continuity and Change (1999), 14: 33–56
  7. ^ Powelson, John (1987). The Story of Land [A World History of Land Tenure and Agrarian Reform]. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. p. 115. ISBN 0899462189.
  8. ^ Figes, Orlando (1996). A People's Tragedy: The Russian Revolution: 1891–1924. Jonathan Cape. ISBN 0-224-04162-2.
  9. ^ Stakhiv, Eugene Z. (27 November 2015). "Taras Shevchenko: Aral Sea expeditionary". The Ukrainian Weekly.
  10. ^ "Dmitry Medvedev took part in the conference The Great Reforms and Modernisation of Russia". Kremlin.ru. 3 March 2011.
  11. ^ Worthington, Daryl (2 March 2015). "Alexander II Emancipates the Serfs". NewHistorian.
  12. ^ Paxton, John (2004) [1999]. Leaders of Russia and the Soviet Union Since 1613. London: Fitzroy Dearborn Publishers. ISBN 978-0203505328. OCLC 437056484, 60161944. Retrieved 2014-03-04.
  13. ^ Peasant Wars of the 20th Century, Eric Wolf, 1969
  14. ^ Nafziger, Steven. "Russian Serfdom and Emancipation: New Empirical Evidence" (PDF). Yale Department of Economics. Retrieved 9 September 2023.
  15. ^ a b c d e f g h Polunov, Alexander (2005). Owen, Thomas C.; Zakharova, L.G. (eds.). Russia in the Nineteenth Century: Autocracy, Reform, And Social Change, 1814–1914. New Russian history. Marshall S. Shatz, translator. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. ISBN 978-0765606716. OCLC 191935709. Archived from the original on 2014-03-04.
  16. ^ a b c Pushkarev, Sergei G (April 1968). "The Russian Peasants' Reaction to the Emancipation of 1861". Russian Review. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley-Blackwell. 27 (2): 199–214. doi:10.2307/127028. ISSN 1467-9434. JSTOR 127028. LCCN 43016148. OCLC 4892437069.

Further reading Edit

  • Gorshkov, Boris B (Fall 2000). "Serfs on the Move: Peasant Seasonal Migration in Pre-Reform Russia, 1800–61". Kritika: Explorations in Russian and Eurasian History. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University. 1 (4): 627–56. doi:10.1353/kri.2008.0061. ISSN 1531-023X. OCLC 741613421. S2CID 161338060.
  • Gorshkov, Boris B (2001). "Serfdom: Eastern Europe". In Sterns, Peter N. (ed.). Encyclopedia of European social history : from 1350 to 2000. Vol. 2. New York: Scribner. pp. 379–88. ISBN 978-0684805788. OCLC 84386264, 833759358.
  • Hunt, Lynn; Martin, Thomas R.; Rosenwein, Barbara H.; Hsia, R. Po-chia; Smith, Bonnie G. (2008) [2001]. The Making of the West: Peoples and Cultures. Vol. C: Since 1740 (3rd ed.). Boston, MA: Bedford-St. Martin's. ISBN 978-0312465100. OCLC 277156654.
  • Purlevskii, Savva Dmitrievich (2005). A Life Under Russian Serfdom: Memoirs of Savva Dmitrievich Purlevskii, 1800–68. Gorshkov, Boris B, ed. & trans. Budapest; New York: Central European University Press. ISBN 978-6155053955. JSTOR 10.7829/j.ctt2jbnnh. OCLC 57698677.

External links Edit

    emancipation, reform, 1861, emancipation, reform, 1861, russia, also, known, edict, emancipation, russia, russian, Крестьянская, реформа, 1861, года, romanized, krestyanskaya, reforma, 1861, goda, peasants, reform, 1861, first, most, important, liberal, reform. The emancipation reform of 1861 in Russia also known as the Edict of Emancipation of Russia Russian Krestyanskaya reforma 1861 goda romanized Krestyanskaya reforma 1861 goda peasants reform of 1861 was the first and most important of the liberal reforms enacted during the reign 1855 1881 of Emperor Alexander II of Russia The reform effectively abolished serfdom throughout the Russian Empire A 1907 painting by Boris Kustodiev depicting Russian serfs listening to the proclamation of the Emancipation Manifesto in 1861The 1861 Emancipation Manifesto proclaimed the emancipation of the serfs on private estates and of the domestic household serfs By this edict more than 23 million people received their liberty 1 Serfs gained the full rights of free citizens including rights to marry without having to gain consent to own property and to own a business The Manifesto prescribed that peasants would be able to buy the land from the landlords Household serfs were the least affected they gained only their freedom and no land citation needed The serfs were emancipated in 1861 following a speech given by Tsar Alexander II on 30 March 1856 2 In Georgia the emancipation took place later in 1864 and on much better terms for the nobles than in Russia 3 State owned serfs those living on and working Imperial lands were emancipated in 1866 1 Contents 1 Background 2 Earlier reform moves 3 Shaping of the manifesto 4 Emancipation Manifesto 5 Implementation 6 Outcomes 6 1 Effects on the serfs 6 2 Aftermath 7 See also 8 References 9 Further reading 10 External linksBackground EditPrior to 1861 Russia had two main categories of peasants citation needed Those who lived on state lands under control of the Ministry of State Property Those who lived on private landOnly those who were owned privately were considered serfs They comprised an estimated 38 of the population 4 As well as having obligations to the state they also were obliged to the landowner who had great power over their lives The rural population lived in households dvory singular dvor gathered as villages derevni a derevnya with a church became a selo run by a mir commune or obshchina isolated conservative largely self sufficient and self governing units scattered across the land every 10 km 6 2 mi or so Imperial Russia had around 20 million dvory forty percent of them containing six to ten people citation needed Intensely insular the mir assembly the skhod sel skii skhod appointed an elder starosta and a clerk pisar to deal with any external issues Peasants within a mir shared land and resources The fields were divided among the families as nadel allotment a complex of strip plots distributed according to the quality of the soil The strips were periodically redistributed within the villages to produce level economic conditions The land however was not owned by the mir the land was the legal property of the 100 000 or so landowners pomeshchiks an equivalent of landed gentry and the inhabitants as serfs were not allowed to leave the property where they were born The peasants were duty bound to make regular payments in labor and goods It has been estimated by whom that landowners took at least one third of income and production by the first half of the nineteenth century 5 Earlier reform moves EditThe need for urgent reform was well understood in 19th century Russia Much support for it emanated from universities authors and other intellectual circles Various projects of emancipation reforms were prepared by Mikhail Speransky Nikolay Mordvinov and Pavel Kiselyov However conservative or reactionary nobility thwarted their efforts In Western guberniyas serfdom was abolished early in the century In Congress Poland serfdom had been abolished before it became Russian by Napoleon in 1807 but it was largely restored once Russia took over in 1815 Serfdom was abolished in governorates of Estonia in 1816 in Courland in 1817 and in Livonia in 1819 6 In 1797 Paul I of Russia decreed that corvee labor was limited to 3 days a week and never on Sunday but this law was not enforced Beginning in 1801 Alexander I of Russia appointed a committee to study possible emancipation but its only effect was to prohibit the sale of serfs without their families Beginning in 1825 Nicholas I of Russia expressed his desire for emancipation on many occasions and even improved the lives of serfs on state properties but did not change the condition of serfs on private estates 7 Shaping of the manifesto EditMy intention is to abolish serfdom you can yourself understand that the present order of owning souls cannot remain unchanged It is better to abolish serfdom from above than to wait for that time when it starts to abolish itself from below I ask you to think about the best way to carry this out Alexander II s speech to the Marshalls of the Nobility 30 March 1856 2 The liberal politicians who stood behind the 1861 manifesto Nikolay Milyutin Alexei Strol man and Yakov Rostovtsev also recognized that their country was one of a few remaining feudal states in Europe The pitiful display by Russian forces in the Crimean War left the government acutely aware of the empire s weaknesses Eager to grow and develop industrial and therefore military and political strength they introduced a number of economic reforms It was optimistically hoped that after the abolition the mir would dissolve into individual peasant land owners and the beginnings of a market economy citation needed Alexander II unlike his father was willing to deal with this problem Moving on from a petition from the Lithuanian provinces a committee for ameliorating the condition of the peasants was founded and the principles of the abolition considered citation needed The main point at issue was whether the serfs should remain dependent on the landlords or whether they should be transformed into a class of independent communal proprietors citation needed The land owners initially pushed for granting the peasants freedom but not any land The tsar and his advisers mindful of 1848 events in Western Europe were opposed to creating a proletariat and the instability this could bring But giving the peasants freedom and land seemed to leave the existing land owners without the large and cheap labour force they needed to maintain their estates and lifestyles By 1859 however a third of their estates and two thirds of their serfs were mortgaged to the state or noble banks This was why they had to accept the emancipation 8 To balance this the legislation contained three measures to reduce the potential economic self sufficiency of the peasants Firstly a transition period of two years was introduced during which the peasant was obligated as before to the old land owner Secondly large parts of common land were passed to the major land owners as otrezki cut off lands making many forests roads and rivers accessible only for a fee The third measure was that the serfs must pay the land owner for their allocation of land in a series of redemption payments which in turn were used to compensate the landowners with bonds The government would advance 75 of the total sum to the land owner and then the peasants would repay the government plus interest over forty nine years The government finally cancelled these redemption payments in 1907 citation needed Emancipation Manifesto Edit nbsp Peasants Reading the Emancipation Manifesto an 1873 painting by Grigory MyasoyedovThe legal basis of the reform was the Tsar s Emancipation Manifesto of 3 March O S 19 February 1861 9 10 11 accompanied by the set of legislative acts under the general name Regulations Concerning Peasants Leaving Serf Dependence Russian Polozheniya o krestyanah vyhodyashih iz krepostnoj zavisimosti Polozheniya o krestyanakh vykhodyashchikh iz krepostnoi zavisimosti citation needed This Manifesto proclaimed the emancipation of the serfs on private estates and of the domestic household serfs 1 Serfs were granted the full rights of free citizens gaining the rights to marry without having to gain consent to own property and to own a business The Manifesto also permitted peasants to buy the land from the landlords citation needed Implementation EditMir communities had the power to distribute the land given to newly freed serfs by the Russian government amongst individuals within the community Due to the community s ownership of the land as opposed to the individual s an individual peasant could not sell his portion of the land to go work in a factory in the city A peasant was required to pay off long term loans received by the government The money from these loans was given to the primary landowner The land allotted to the recently freed serfs did not include the best land in the country which remained in the hands of the nobility citation needed The implementation of land settlement varied over the vast and diverse territory of the Russian Empire but typically a peasant had rights to buy out about half of the land he cultivated for himself If he could not afford to pay it off he would receive a half of the half i e a quarter of the land free It was called pauper s allotment bednyatskiy nadel 12 Though well planned in the legislation the reform did not work smoothly Many reform minded peasants believed the manifesto s conditions were unacceptable In many localities the peasants refused to believe that the manifesto was genuine There were troubles and troops had to be called in to disperse the angry crowds 13 The land owners and nobility were paid in government bonds with their debts deducted The bonds soon fell in value The management skills of the land owners were generally poor citation needed Some Mir s did not enter the land redemption process at all remaining as temporarily obligated peasants under their former owners until an 1881 decree made redemption compulsory In 1883 concerned by rising levels of tax arrears the government made a 13 cut varying by commune as a national average to payment rates to combat the problem 14 Outcomes Edit nbsp The Abolition of Serfdom in Russia Work in Freedom is the Foundation of a State 1914 by Alphonse Mucha The Slav Epic nbsp Central Bank of Russia coin commemorating the 150th anniversary of the emancipation reformDespite newly acquired freedom the life of a serf remained grim in many aspects Household serfs benefited the least gaining their freedom but no land Many bureaucrats believed that these reforms would bring about drastic changes that would only affect the lower stories of society strengthening the autocracy In reality the reforms forced the monarch to coexist with an independent court free press and local governments all operating differently and more freely than they had in the past 15 p 110 This new form of local government involved in each area an assembly called a zemstvo In regards to new localized government the reforms put in place a system where the landowners were now able to have more of a say within their newly formed provinces 15 p 112 While this was not the direct intent of the reforms it was evident that this significantly weakened the idea of the autocracy Now the well to do serfs along with previously free peoples were able to purchase land as private property While early in the reforms the creation of local government had not changed many things about Russian society the rise in capitalism drastically affected not only the social structure of Russia but the behaviors and activities of the self government institutions 15 p 113 With new capitalistic ideals local government was not responsible for the rules and regulations dictating how the new market would operate If there was a positive of this movement towards localized government from the autocracy s point of view it was as Petr Valuev put it the zemstvo would provide activity for the considerable portion of the press as well as those malcontents who currently stir up trouble because they have nothing to do 15 p 111 Effects on the serfs Edit The serfs of private estates received less land than they needed to survive which led to civil unrest The redemption tax was so high that the serfs had to sell all the grain they produced to pay the tax which left nothing for their survival Landowners also suffered because many of them were deeply in debt and the forced selling of their land left them struggling to maintain their lavish lifestyle In many cases the newly freed serfs were forced to rent their land from wealthy landowners Furthermore when the peasants had to work for the same landowners to pay their labor payments they often neglected their own fields 15 p 126 Over the next few years the yields from the peasants crops remained low and soon famine struck a large portion of Russia 15 p 127 With little food and finding themselves in a similar condition as when they were serfs many peasants started to voice their disdain for the new social system On one occasion on 12 April 1861 a local leader murdered a large number of uprising peasants in the village of Bezdna 16 When the incident was over the official report counted 70 peasants dead and another 100 wounded After further investigation and trial of some members of the uprising five peasants were found guilty of agitation and not uprising 16 That said several different instances did take the form of an uprising 16 Aftermath Edit In Congress Poland and in northern Russia peasants became both free and landless batraks with only their labour to sell while in other areas peasants became the majority land owners in their province s The 1861 Emancipation Manifesto affected only the privately owned serfs The state owned serfs were emancipated in 1866 1 and were given better and larger plots of land Lastly the reforms transformed the Russian economy The individuals who led the reform favored an economic system similar to that in other European countries which promoted the ideas of capitalism and free trade The reformers aimed to promote development and to encourage the ownership of private property free competition entrepreneurship and hired labor citation needed This they hoped would bring about an economic system with minimal regulations and tariffs thus a more laissez faire economy Soon after the reforms there was a substantial rise in the amount of production of grain for sale Because of this there was also a rise in the number of hired laborers and in farm machinery 15 p 125 Furthermore a significant measuring stick in the growth of the Russian economy post reform was the huge growth in non gentry private landownership Although the gentry land holdings fell from 80 to 50 the peasant holdings grew from 5 all the way to 20 15 p 126 See also EditSerfdom in Russia Government reforms of Alexander II of Russia Reform movement Russia 1860s Stolypin reform Judicial reform of Alexander II Bezdna Unrest Slave Trade Acts Thirteenth Amendment to the United States Constitution The economy of the Russian Empire after the abolition of serfdom Lord and Peasant in Russia from the Ninth to the Nineteenth CenturyReferences Edit a b c d Mee Arthur Hammerton J A Innes Arthur D Harmsworth History of the World Volume 7 1907 Carmelite House London p 5193 a b Corrin Chris Feihn Terry 31 July 2015 AQA A level History Tsarist and Communist Russia 1855 1964 Hachette UK Hodder Education Dynamic Learning p 11 ISBN 978 1471837807 Retrieved 8 September 2015 On 30 March 1856 Alexander II made a speech to the Marshalls of the Nobility in which he signalled the start of a process that led to the abolition of serfdom in 1861 Suny Ronald Grigor January 1979 The Peasants Have Always Fed Us The Georgian Nobility and the Peasant Emancipation 1856 1871 The Russian Review 38 1 27 51 doi 10 2307 129075 JSTOR 129075 via JSTOR Richard Pipes Russia Under the Old Regime Waldron P 2007 The Governing of Tsarist Russia Palgrave Macmillan p 61 ISBN 978 0 333 71718 9 Charles Wetherell Andrejs Plakans Borders ethnicity and demographic patterns in the Russian Baltic provinces in the late nineteenth century Continuity and Change 1999 14 33 56 Powelson John 1987 The Story of Land A World History of Land Tenure and Agrarian Reform Cambridge MA Lincoln Institute of Land Policy p 115 ISBN 0899462189 Figes Orlando 1996 A People s Tragedy The Russian Revolution 1891 1924 Jonathan Cape ISBN 0 224 04162 2 Stakhiv Eugene Z 27 November 2015 Taras Shevchenko Aral Sea expeditionary The Ukrainian Weekly Dmitry Medvedev took part in the conference The Great Reforms and Modernisation of Russia Kremlin ru 3 March 2011 Worthington Daryl 2 March 2015 Alexander II Emancipates the Serfs NewHistorian Paxton John 2004 1999 Leaders of Russia and the Soviet Union Since 1613 London Fitzroy Dearborn Publishers ISBN 978 0203505328 OCLC 437056484 60161944 Retrieved 2014 03 04 Peasant Wars of the 20th Century Eric Wolf 1969 Nafziger Steven Russian Serfdom and Emancipation New Empirical Evidence PDF Yale Department of Economics Retrieved 9 September 2023 a b c d e f g h Polunov Alexander 2005 Owen Thomas C Zakharova L G eds Russia in the Nineteenth Century Autocracy Reform And Social Change 1814 1914 New Russian history Marshall S Shatz translator Armonk NY M E Sharpe ISBN 978 0765606716 OCLC 191935709 Archived from the original on 2014 03 04 a b c Pushkarev Sergei G April 1968 The Russian Peasants Reaction to the Emancipation of 1861 Russian Review Hoboken NJ Wiley Blackwell 27 2 199 214 doi 10 2307 127028 ISSN 1467 9434 JSTOR 127028 LCCN 43016148 OCLC 4892437069 Further reading EditSee also Bibliography of Russian history 1613 1917 Gorshkov Boris B Fall 2000 Serfs on the Move Peasant Seasonal Migration in Pre Reform Russia 1800 61 Kritika Explorations in Russian and Eurasian History Baltimore MD Johns Hopkins University 1 4 627 56 doi 10 1353 kri 2008 0061 ISSN 1531 023X OCLC 741613421 S2CID 161338060 Gorshkov Boris B 2001 Serfdom Eastern Europe In Sterns Peter N ed Encyclopedia of European social history from 1350 to 2000 Vol 2 New York Scribner pp 379 88 ISBN 978 0684805788 OCLC 84386264 833759358 Hunt Lynn Martin Thomas R Rosenwein Barbara H Hsia R Po chia Smith Bonnie G 2008 2001 The Making of the West Peoples and Cultures Vol C Since 1740 3rd ed Boston MA Bedford St Martin s ISBN 978 0312465100 OCLC 277156654 Purlevskii Savva Dmitrievich 2005 A Life Under Russian Serfdom Memoirs of Savva Dmitrievich Purlevskii 1800 68 Gorshkov Boris B ed amp trans Budapest New York Central European University Press ISBN 978 6155053955 JSTOR 10 7829 j ctt2jbnnh OCLC 57698677 External links EditEmancipation Manifesto in Russian Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Emancipation reform of 1861 amp oldid 1175333619, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

    article

    , read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.