fbpx
Wikipedia

Economic stagnation

Economic stagnation is a prolonged period of slow economic growth (traditionally measured in terms of the GDP growth), usually accompanied by high unemployment. Under some definitions, slow means significantly slower than potential growth as estimated by macroeconomists, even though the growth rate may be nominally higher than in other countries not experiencing economic stagnation.

Secular stagnation theory edit

The term "secular stagnation" was originally coined by Alvin Hansen in 1938 to "describe what he feared was the fate of the American economy following the Great Depression of the early 1930s: a check to economic progress as investment opportunities were stunted by the closing of the frontier and the collapse of immigration".[1][2] Warnings similar to secular stagnation theory have been issued after all deep recessions, but they usually turned out to be wrong because they underestimated the potential of existing technologies.[3]

Secular stagnation refers to "a condition of negligible or no economic growth in a market-based economy".[4] In this context, the term secular is used in contrast to cyclical or short-term, and suggests a change of fundamental dynamics which would play out only in its own time. Alan Sweezy described the difference: "But, whereas business-cycle theory treats depression as a temporary, though recurring, phenomenon, the theory of secular stagnation brings out the possibility that depression may become the normal condition of the economy."[5]

According to Sweezy, "the idea of secular stagnation runs through much of Keynes General Theory".[5]

Stagnation in the United States edit

Historical periods of stagnation in the United States edit

  • The years following the Panic of 1873, known as the Long Depression, were followed by periods of stagnation intermixed with surges of growth until steadier growth resumed around 1896. The period was characterized by business bankruptcies, low interest rates and deflation. According to David Ames Wells (1891) the economic problems were the result of rapid changes in technology, such as railroads, steam-powered ocean ships, steel displacing iron and the telegraph system.[6] Because there was so much economic growth overall, how much of this period was stagnation remains controversial. See: Long Depression
  • The Great Depression of the 1930s and the rest of the period lasting until World War II. Post War Economic Problems, Harris (1943) was written with the expectation that the stagnation would continue after the war ended. See: Causes of the Great Depression.

19th century edit

The U.S. economy of the early 19th century was primarily agricultural and suffered from labor shortages.[7] Capital was so scarce before the Civil War that private investors supplied only a fraction of the money to build railroads, despite the large economic advantage railroads offered. As new territories were opened and federal land sales conducted, land had to be cleared and new homesteads established. Hundreds of thousands of immigrants came to the United States every year and found jobs digging canals and building railroads. Because there was little mechanization, almost all work was done by hand or with horses, mules and oxen until the last two decades of the 19th century.[8]

The decade of the 1880s saw great growth in railroads and the steel and machinery industries. Purchase of structures and equipment increased 500% from the previous decade. Labor productivity rose 26.5% and GDP nearly doubled.[9] The workweek during most of the 19th century was over 60 hours, being higher in the first half of the century, with twelve-hour work days common. There were numerous strikes and other labor movements for a ten-hour day. The tight labor market was a factor in productivity gains allowing workers to maintain or increase their nominal wages during the secular deflation that caused real wages to rise in the late 19th century. Labor did suffer temporary setbacks, such as when railroads cut wages during the Long Depression of the mid-1870s; however, this resulted in strikes throughout the nation.

End of stagnation in the U.S. after the Great Depression edit

Construction of structures, residential, commercial and industrial, fell off dramatically during the depression, but housing was well on its way to recovering by the late 1930s.[10] The depression years were the period of the highest total factor productivity growth in the United States, primarily to the building of roads and bridges, abandonment of unneeded railroad track and reduction in railroad employment, expansion of electric utilities and improvements wholesale and retail distribution.[10] This helped the United States, which escaped the devastation of World War II, to quickly convert back to peacetime production.

The war created pent up demand for many items, as factories had stopped producing automobiles and other civilian goods to convert to production of tanks, guns, military vehicles and supplies. Tires had been rationed due to shortages of natural rubber; however, the U.S. government built synthetic rubber plants. The U.S. government also built ammonia plants, aluminum smelters, aviation fuel refineries and aircraft engine factories during the war.[10] After the war, commercial aviation, plastics and synthetic rubber would become major industries and synthetic ammonia was used for fertilizer. The end of armaments production freed up hundreds of thousands of machine tools, which were made available for other industries. They were needed in the rapidly growing aircraft manufacturing industry.[11]

The memory of war created a need for preparedness in the United States. This resulted in constant spending for defense programs, creating what President Eisenhower called the military-industrial complex. U.S. birth rates began to recover by the time of World War II, and turned into the baby boom of the postwar decades. A building boom commenced in the years following the war. Suburbs began a rapid expansion and automobile ownership increased.[10] High-yielding crops and chemical fertilizers dramatically increased crop yields and greatly lowered the cost of food, giving consumers more discretionary income. Railroad locomotives switched from steam to diesel power, with a large increase in fuel efficiency. Most importantly, cheap food essentially eliminated malnutrition in countries like the United States and much of Europe. Many trends that began before the war continued:

  • The use of electricity grew steadily as prices continued to fall, although at a slower rate than in the early decades. More people purchased washing machines, dryers, refrigerators and other appliances. Air conditioning became increasingly prevalent in households and businesses. See: Diffusion of innovations#Diffusion data
  • Infrastructures: The highway system continued to expand.[10] Construction of the interstate highway system started in the late 1950s. The pipeline network continued to expand.[12] Railroad track mileage continued its decline.
  • Better roads and increased investment in the distribution system of trucks, warehouses and material-handling equipment, such as forklift trucks, continued to reduce the cost of goods.
  • Mechanization of agriculture increased dramatically, especially the use of combine harvesters. Tractor sales peaked in the mid-1950s.[13]

The workweek never returned to the 48 hours or more that was typical before the Great Depression.[14][15]

Stagflation edit

The period following the 1973 oil crisis was characterized by stagflation, the combination of low economic and productivity growth and high inflation. The period was also characterized by high interest rates, which is not entirely consistent with secular stagnation. Stronger economic growth resumed and inflation declined during the 1980s. Although productivity never returned to peak levels, it did enjoy a revival with the growth of the computer and communications industries in the 1980s and 1990s.[16] This enabled a recovery in GDP growth rates; however, debt in the period following 1982 grew at a much faster rate than GDP.[17][18] The U.S. economy experienced structural changes following the stagflation. Steel consumption peaked in 1973, both on an absolute and per-capita basis, and never returned to previous levels.[19] The energy intensity of the United States and many other developed economies also began to decline after 1973. Health care expenditures rose to over 17% of the economy.

Productivity slowdown edit

Productivity growth began to slow down sharply in developed countries after 1973, but there was a revival in the 1990s which still left productivity growth below the peak decades earlier in the 20th century.[16][20][21] Productivity growth in the U.S. slowed again since the mid-2000s.[22] A recent book titled The Great Stagnation: How America Ate All the Low-Hanging Fruit of Modern History, Got Sick and Will (Eventually) Feel better by Tyler Cowen is one of the latest of several stagnation books written in recent decades. Turning Point by Robert Ayres and The Evolution of Progress by C. Owen Paepke were earlier books that predicted the stagnation.

Stagnation and the financial explosion: the 1980s edit

A prescient analysis of stagnation and what is now called financialization was provided in the 1980s by Harry Magdoff and Paul Sweezy, coeditors of the independent socialist journal Monthly Review. Magdoff was a former economic advisor to Vice President Henry A. Wallace in Roosevelt’s New Deal administration, while Sweezy was a former Harvard economics professor. In their 1987 book, Stagnation and the Financial Explosion, they argued, based on Keynes, Hansen, Michał Kalecki, and Marx, and marshaling extensive empirical data, that, contrary to the usual way of thinking, stagnation or slow growth was the norm for mature, monopolistic (or oligopolistic) economies, while rapid growth was the exception.[23]

Private accumulation had a strong tendency to weak growth and high levels of excess capacity and unemployment/underemployment, which could, however, be countered in part by such exogenous factors as state spending (military and civilian), epoch-making technological innovations (for example, the automobile in its expansionary period), and the growth of finance. In the 1980s and 1990s Magdoff and Sweezy argued that a financial explosion of long duration was lifting the economy, but this would eventually compound the contradictions of the system, producing ever bigger speculative bubbles, and leading eventually to a resumption of overt stagnation.

Post-2008 period edit

 
This chart compares U.S. potential GDP under two CBO forecasts (one from 2007 and one from 2016) versus the actual real GDP. It is based on a similar diagram from economist Larry Summers from 2014.[24]

Secular stagnation was dusted off by Hans-Werner Sinn in a 2009 article [25] dismissing the threat of inflation, and became popular again when Larry Summers invoked the term and concept during a 2013 speech at the IMF.[26]The Economist criticizes secular stagnation as "a baggy concept, arguably too capacious for its own good".[1] Warnings similar to secular stagnation theory have been issued after all deep recessions, but they all turned out to be wrong because they underestimated the potential of existing technologies.[3]

Paul Krugman, writing in 2014, clarified that it refers to "the claim that underlying changes in the economy, such as slowing growth in the working-age population, have made episodes like the past five years in Europe and the United States, and the last 20 years in Japan, likely to happen often. That is, we will often find ourselves facing persistent shortfalls of demand, which can’t be overcome even with near-zero interest rates."[27] At its root is "the problem of building consumer demand at a time when people are less motivated to spend".[28]

One theory is that the boost in growth by the internet and technological advancement in computers of the new economy does not measure up to the boost caused by the great inventions of the past. An example of such a great invention is the assembly line production method of Fordism. The general form of the argument has been the subject of papers by Robert J. Gordon.[29] It has also been written about by Owen. C. Paepke and Tyler Cowen.[30]

Secular stagnation been linked to the rise of the digital economy. Carl Benedikt Frey, for example, has suggested that digital technologies are much less capital-absorbing, creating only little new investment demand relative to other revolutionary technologies.[31] Another is that the damage done by the Great Recession was so long-lasting and permanent, so many workers will never get jobs again, that we really cannot recover.[28] A third is that there is a "persistent and disturbing reluctance of businesses to invest and consumers to spend", perhaps in part because so much of the recent gains have gone to the people at the top, and they tend to save more of their money than people—ordinary working people who can't afford to do that.[28] A fourth is that advanced economies are just simply paying the price for years of inadequate investment in infrastructure and education, the basic ingredients of growth.[28]

Episodes edit

Japan: 1991–present edit

Japan has been suffering economic or secular stagnation for most of the period since the early 1990s.[32][33] Economists, such as Paul Krugman, attribute the stagnation to a liquidity trap (a situation in which monetary policy is unable to lower nominal interest rates because these are close to zero) exacerbated by demographics factors.[34]

World since 2008 edit

Economists have asked whether the low economic growth rate in the developed world leading up to and following the subprime mortgage crisis of 2007–2008 was due to secular stagnation. Paul Krugman wrote in September 2013: "[T]here is a case for believing that the problem of maintaining adequate aggregate demand is going to be very persistent – that we may face something like the 'secular stagnation' many economists feared after World War II." Krugman wrote that fiscal policy stimulus and higher inflation (to achieve a negative real rate of interest necessary to achieve full employment) may be potential solutions.[35]

Larry Summers presented his view during November 2013 that secular (long-term) stagnation may be a reason that U.S. growth is insufficient to reach full employment: "Suppose then that the short term real interest rate that was consistent with full employment [i.e., the "natural rate"] had fallen to negative two or negative three percent. Even with artificial stimulus to demand you wouldn't see any excess demand. Even with a resumption in normal credit conditions you would have a lot of difficulty getting back to full employment."[36][37]

Robert J. Gordon wrote in August 2012: "Even if innovation were to continue into the future at the rate of the two decades before 2007, the U.S. faces six headwinds that are in the process of dragging long-term growth to half or less of the 1.9 percent annual rate experienced between 1860 and 2007. These include demography, education, inequality, globalization, energy/environment, and the overhang of consumer and government debt. A provocative 'exercise in subtraction' suggests that future growth in consumption per capita for the bottom 99 percent of the income distribution could fall below 0.5 percent per year for an extended period of decades".[38]

The German Institute for Economic Research sees a connection between secular stagnation and the regime of low interest rates (zero interest-rate policy, negative interest rates).[39]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ a b W., P. (16 August 2014). "Secular stagnation: Fad or fact?". The Economist.
  2. ^ "U.S. Secular Stagnation?". 23 December 2015.
  3. ^ a b Pagano and Sbracia (2014) "The secular stagnation hypothesis: a review of the debate and some insights." Bank of Italy Questioni di Economia e Finanza occasional paper series number QEF-231.
  4. ^ . Financial Times. Archived from the original on 16 March 2019. Retrieved 9 October 2014.
  5. ^ a b Sweezy, Alan (1943). "Chapter IV Secular Stagnation". In Harris, Seymour E. (ed.). Postwar Economic Problems. New York, London: McGraw Hill Book Co. pp. 67–82.
  6. ^ Wells, David A. (1891). Recent Economic Changes and Their Effect on Production and Distribution of Wealth and Well-Being of Society. New York: D. Appleton and Co. ISBN 978-0-543-72474-8.
  7. ^ Habakkuk, H. J. (1962). American and British Technology in the Nineteenth Century. London; New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521094474.
  8. ^ Hunter, Louis C.; Bryant, Lynwood (1991). A History of Industrial Power in the United States, 1730–1930. Vol. 3: The Transmission of Power. Cambridge, Mass.; London: MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-08198-6.
  9. ^ Rothbard, Murray (2002). History of Money and Banking in the United States (PDF). Ludwig Von Mises Inst. p. 165. ISBN 978-0-945466-33-8.
  10. ^ a b c d e Field, Alexander J. (2011). A Great Leap Forward: 1930s Depression and U.S. Economic Growth. New Haven; London: Yale University Press. ISBN 978-0-300-15109-1.
  11. ^ Hounshell, David A. (1984), From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States, Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press, ISBN 978-0-8018-2975-8, LCCN 83016269, OCLC 1104810110
  12. ^ . Archived from the original on 18 April 2008. Retrieved 7 January 2014.
  13. ^ White, William J. . Archived from the original on 24 October 2013.
  14. ^ . 2010. Archived from the original on 26 October 2011.
  15. ^ Whaples, Robert (June 1991). "The Shortening of the American Work Week: An Economic and Historical Analysis of Its Context, Causes, and Consequences, The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 51, No. 2; pp. 454–457". {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  16. ^ a b Field, Alexander (2004). (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 10 March 2012.
  17. ^ [1] There are numerous graphs of total debt/GDP available on the Internet.
  18. ^ Roche, Cullen (2010). "Total Debt to GDP Trumps Everything Else".
  19. ^ Smil, Vaclav (2006). Transforming the Twentieth Century: Technical Innovations and Their Consequences. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press. p. 112. In the U.S., steel consumption peaked at just under 700 kg per capita and declined to just over 400 kg by 2000.
  20. ^ Kendrick, John (1 October 1991). "U.S. Productivity Performance in Perspective, Business Economics". {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  21. ^ Field, Alezander J. (2007). "U.S. Economic Growth in the Gilded Age, Journal of Macroeconomics 31": 173–190. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  22. ^ The Recent Rise and Fall of Rapid Productivity Growth
  23. ^ Magdoff, Harry; Sweezy, Paul (1987). Stagnation and the Financial Explosion. New York: Monthly Review Press.
  24. ^ Larry Summers – U.S. Economic Prospects – Keynote Address at the NABE Conference 2014
  25. ^ Hans-Werner Sin, Forget Inflation, February 26, 2009
  26. ^ "IMF Fourteenth Annual Research Conference in Honor of Stanley Fischer". 8 November 2013.
  27. ^ Krugman, Paul (15 August 2014). "Secular Stagnation: The Book". New York Times.
  28. ^ a b c d Inskeep, Steve (9 September 2014). "Is The Economy Suffering From Secular Stagnation?". NPR.
  29. ^ Gordon, Robert J. (2000). "Does the New Economy Measure Up to the Great Inventions of the Past?" (PDF). Journal of Economic Perspectives. 14 (4): 49–74. doi:10.1257/jep.14.4.49.
  30. ^ Paepke, C. Owen (1993). The Evolution of Progress: The End of Economic Growth and the Beginning of Human Transformation. New York; Toronto: Random House. ISBN 978-0-679-41582-4.
  31. ^ Frey, Carl Benedikt (2015). "The End of Economic Growth? How the Digital Economy Could Lead to Secular Stagnation". Scientific American. 312 (1).
  32. ^ Lessons from Japan's Secular Stagnation The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry
  33. ^ Hoshi, Takeo; Kashyap, Anil K. (2004). "Japan's Financial Crisis and Economic Stagnation". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 18 (1 (Winter)): 3–26. doi:10.1257/089533004773563412.
  34. ^ Krugman, Paul (2009). The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008. W.W. Norton Company Limited. ISBN 978-0-393-07101-6.
  35. ^ Paul Krugman – Bubbles, Regulation and Secular Stagnation – September 25, 2013
  36. ^ . Archived from the original on 30 September 2017. Retrieved 1 December 2013.
  37. ^ Paul Krugman – Conscience of a Liberal Blog – Secular Stagnation, Coalmines, Bubbles, and Larry Summers – November 16, 2013
  38. ^ Robert J. Gordon – Is U.S. Economic Growth Over? Faltering Innovation Confronts the Six Headwinds – August 2012 September 18, 2013, at the Wayback Machine
  39. ^ German Institute for Economic Research, January 30, 2017: "The Natural Rate of Interest and Secular Stagnation"

Further reading edit

economic, stagnation, economic, immobility, redirects, here, concept, financial, economics, economic, immobilisation, prolonged, period, slow, economic, growth, traditionally, measured, terms, growth, usually, accompanied, high, unemployment, under, some, defi. Economic immobility redirects here For the concept in financial economics see Economic immobilisation Economic stagnation is a prolonged period of slow economic growth traditionally measured in terms of the GDP growth usually accompanied by high unemployment Under some definitions slow means significantly slower than potential growth as estimated by macroeconomists even though the growth rate may be nominally higher than in other countries not experiencing economic stagnation Contents 1 Secular stagnation theory 2 Stagnation in the United States 2 1 Historical periods of stagnation in the United States 2 1 1 19th century 2 1 2 End of stagnation in the U S after the Great Depression 2 2 Stagflation 2 3 Productivity slowdown 2 4 Stagnation and the financial explosion the 1980s 2 5 Post 2008 period 3 Episodes 3 1 Japan 1991 present 3 2 World since 2008 4 See also 5 References 6 Further readingSecular stagnation theory editMain article Secular stagnation theory Further information Alvin Hansen Stagnation The term secular stagnation was originally coined by Alvin Hansen in 1938 to describe what he feared was the fate of the American economy following the Great Depression of the early 1930s a check to economic progress as investment opportunities were stunted by the closing of the frontier and the collapse of immigration 1 2 Warnings similar to secular stagnation theory have been issued after all deep recessions but they usually turned out to be wrong because they underestimated the potential of existing technologies 3 Secular stagnation refers to a condition of negligible or no economic growth in a market based economy 4 In this context the term secular is used in contrast to cyclical or short term and suggests a change of fundamental dynamics which would play out only in its own time Alan Sweezy described the difference But whereas business cycle theory treats depression as a temporary though recurring phenomenon the theory of secular stagnation brings out the possibility that depression may become the normal condition of the economy 5 According to Sweezy the idea of secular stagnation runs through much of Keynes General Theory 5 Stagnation in the United States editFurther information Economic history of the United States Historical periods of stagnation in the United States edit The years following the Panic of 1873 known as the Long Depression were followed by periods of stagnation intermixed with surges of growth until steadier growth resumed around 1896 The period was characterized by business bankruptcies low interest rates and deflation According to David Ames Wells 1891 the economic problems were the result of rapid changes in technology such as railroads steam powered ocean ships steel displacing iron and the telegraph system 6 Because there was so much economic growth overall how much of this period was stagnation remains controversial See Long Depression The Great Depression of the 1930s and the rest of the period lasting until World War II Post War Economic Problems Harris 1943 was written with the expectation that the stagnation would continue after the war ended See Causes of the Great Depression 19th century edit The U S economy of the early 19th century was primarily agricultural and suffered from labor shortages 7 Capital was so scarce before the Civil War that private investors supplied only a fraction of the money to build railroads despite the large economic advantage railroads offered As new territories were opened and federal land sales conducted land had to be cleared and new homesteads established Hundreds of thousands of immigrants came to the United States every year and found jobs digging canals and building railroads Because there was little mechanization almost all work was done by hand or with horses mules and oxen until the last two decades of the 19th century 8 The decade of the 1880s saw great growth in railroads and the steel and machinery industries Purchase of structures and equipment increased 500 from the previous decade Labor productivity rose 26 5 and GDP nearly doubled 9 The workweek during most of the 19th century was over 60 hours being higher in the first half of the century with twelve hour work days common There were numerous strikes and other labor movements for a ten hour day The tight labor market was a factor in productivity gains allowing workers to maintain or increase their nominal wages during the secular deflation that caused real wages to rise in the late 19th century Labor did suffer temporary setbacks such as when railroads cut wages during the Long Depression of the mid 1870s however this resulted in strikes throughout the nation End of stagnation in the U S after the Great Depression edit Further information Post World War II economic expansion Construction of structures residential commercial and industrial fell off dramatically during the depression but housing was well on its way to recovering by the late 1930s 10 The depression years were the period of the highest total factor productivity growth in the United States primarily to the building of roads and bridges abandonment of unneeded railroad track and reduction in railroad employment expansion of electric utilities and improvements wholesale and retail distribution 10 This helped the United States which escaped the devastation of World War II to quickly convert back to peacetime production The war created pent up demand for many items as factories had stopped producing automobiles and other civilian goods to convert to production of tanks guns military vehicles and supplies Tires had been rationed due to shortages of natural rubber however the U S government built synthetic rubber plants The U S government also built ammonia plants aluminum smelters aviation fuel refineries and aircraft engine factories during the war 10 After the war commercial aviation plastics and synthetic rubber would become major industries and synthetic ammonia was used for fertilizer The end of armaments production freed up hundreds of thousands of machine tools which were made available for other industries They were needed in the rapidly growing aircraft manufacturing industry 11 The memory of war created a need for preparedness in the United States This resulted in constant spending for defense programs creating what President Eisenhower called the military industrial complex U S birth rates began to recover by the time of World War II and turned into the baby boom of the postwar decades A building boom commenced in the years following the war Suburbs began a rapid expansion and automobile ownership increased 10 High yielding crops and chemical fertilizers dramatically increased crop yields and greatly lowered the cost of food giving consumers more discretionary income Railroad locomotives switched from steam to diesel power with a large increase in fuel efficiency Most importantly cheap food essentially eliminated malnutrition in countries like the United States and much of Europe Many trends that began before the war continued The use of electricity grew steadily as prices continued to fall although at a slower rate than in the early decades More people purchased washing machines dryers refrigerators and other appliances Air conditioning became increasingly prevalent in households and businesses See Diffusion of innovations Diffusion data Infrastructures The highway system continued to expand 10 Construction of the interstate highway system started in the late 1950s The pipeline network continued to expand 12 Railroad track mileage continued its decline Better roads and increased investment in the distribution system of trucks warehouses and material handling equipment such as forklift trucks continued to reduce the cost of goods Mechanization of agriculture increased dramatically especially the use of combine harvesters Tractor sales peaked in the mid 1950s 13 The workweek never returned to the 48 hours or more that was typical before the Great Depression 14 15 Stagflation edit The period following the 1973 oil crisis was characterized by stagflation the combination of low economic and productivity growth and high inflation The period was also characterized by high interest rates which is not entirely consistent with secular stagnation Stronger economic growth resumed and inflation declined during the 1980s Although productivity never returned to peak levels it did enjoy a revival with the growth of the computer and communications industries in the 1980s and 1990s 16 This enabled a recovery in GDP growth rates however debt in the period following 1982 grew at a much faster rate than GDP 17 18 The U S economy experienced structural changes following the stagflation Steel consumption peaked in 1973 both on an absolute and per capita basis and never returned to previous levels 19 The energy intensity of the United States and many other developed economies also began to decline after 1973 Health care expenditures rose to over 17 of the economy Productivity slowdown edit Productivity growth began to slow down sharply in developed countries after 1973 but there was a revival in the 1990s which still left productivity growth below the peak decades earlier in the 20th century 16 20 21 Productivity growth in the U S slowed again since the mid 2000s 22 A recent book titled The Great Stagnation How America Ate All the Low Hanging Fruit of Modern History Got Sick and Will Eventually Feel better by Tyler Cowen is one of the latest of several stagnation books written in recent decades Turning Point by Robert Ayres and The Evolution of Progress by C Owen Paepke were earlier books that predicted the stagnation Stagnation and the financial explosion the 1980s edit A prescient analysis of stagnation and what is now called financialization was provided in the 1980s by Harry Magdoff and Paul Sweezy coeditors of the independent socialist journal Monthly Review Magdoff was a former economic advisor to Vice President Henry A Wallace in Roosevelt s New Deal administration while Sweezy was a former Harvard economics professor In their 1987 book Stagnation and the Financial Explosion they argued based on Keynes Hansen Michal Kalecki and Marx and marshaling extensive empirical data that contrary to the usual way of thinking stagnation or slow growth was the norm for mature monopolistic or oligopolistic economies while rapid growth was the exception 23 Private accumulation had a strong tendency to weak growth and high levels of excess capacity and unemployment underemployment which could however be countered in part by such exogenous factors as state spending military and civilian epoch making technological innovations for example the automobile in its expansionary period and the growth of finance In the 1980s and 1990s Magdoff and Sweezy argued that a financial explosion of long duration was lifting the economy but this would eventually compound the contradictions of the system producing ever bigger speculative bubbles and leading eventually to a resumption of overt stagnation Post 2008 period edit nbsp This chart compares U S potential GDP under two CBO forecasts one from 2007 and one from 2016 versus the actual real GDP It is based on a similar diagram from economist Larry Summers from 2014 24 Secular stagnation was dusted off by Hans Werner Sinn in a 2009 article 25 dismissing the threat of inflation and became popular again when Larry Summers invoked the term and concept during a 2013 speech at the IMF 26 The Economist criticizes secular stagnation as a baggy concept arguably too capacious for its own good 1 Warnings similar to secular stagnation theory have been issued after all deep recessions but they all turned out to be wrong because they underestimated the potential of existing technologies 3 Paul Krugman writing in 2014 clarified that it refers to the claim that underlying changes in the economy such as slowing growth in the working age population have made episodes like the past five years in Europe and the United States and the last 20 years in Japan likely to happen often That is we will often find ourselves facing persistent shortfalls of demand which can t be overcome even with near zero interest rates 27 At its root is the problem of building consumer demand at a time when people are less motivated to spend 28 One theory is that the boost in growth by the internet and technological advancement in computers of the new economy does not measure up to the boost caused by the great inventions of the past An example of such a great invention is the assembly line production method of Fordism The general form of the argument has been the subject of papers by Robert J Gordon 29 It has also been written about by Owen C Paepke and Tyler Cowen 30 Secular stagnation been linked to the rise of the digital economy Carl Benedikt Frey for example has suggested that digital technologies are much less capital absorbing creating only little new investment demand relative to other revolutionary technologies 31 Another is that the damage done by the Great Recession was so long lasting and permanent so many workers will never get jobs again that we really cannot recover 28 A third is that there is a persistent and disturbing reluctance of businesses to invest and consumers to spend perhaps in part because so much of the recent gains have gone to the people at the top and they tend to save more of their money than people ordinary working people who can t afford to do that 28 A fourth is that advanced economies are just simply paying the price for years of inadequate investment in infrastructure and education the basic ingredients of growth 28 Episodes editJapan 1991 present edit Main article Lost Decade Japan Japan has been suffering economic or secular stagnation for most of the period since the early 1990s 32 33 Economists such as Paul Krugman attribute the stagnation to a liquidity trap a situation in which monetary policy is unable to lower nominal interest rates because these are close to zero exacerbated by demographics factors 34 World since 2008 edit Economists have asked whether the low economic growth rate in the developed world leading up to and following the subprime mortgage crisis of 2007 2008 was due to secular stagnation Paul Krugman wrote in September 2013 T here is a case for believing that the problem of maintaining adequate aggregate demand is going to be very persistent that we may face something like the secular stagnation many economists feared after World War II Krugman wrote that fiscal policy stimulus and higher inflation to achieve a negative real rate of interest necessary to achieve full employment may be potential solutions 35 Larry Summers presented his view during November 2013 that secular long term stagnation may be a reason that U S growth is insufficient to reach full employment Suppose then that the short term real interest rate that was consistent with full employment i e the natural rate had fallen to negative two or negative three percent Even with artificial stimulus to demand you wouldn t see any excess demand Even with a resumption in normal credit conditions you would have a lot of difficulty getting back to full employment 36 37 Robert J Gordon wrote in August 2012 Even if innovation were to continue into the future at the rate of the two decades before 2007 the U S faces six headwinds that are in the process of dragging long term growth to half or less of the 1 9 percent annual rate experienced between 1860 and 2007 These include demography education inequality globalization energy environment and the overhang of consumer and government debt A provocative exercise in subtraction suggests that future growth in consumption per capita for the bottom 99 percent of the income distribution could fall below 0 5 percent per year for an extended period of decades 38 The German Institute for Economic Research sees a connection between secular stagnation and the regime of low interest rates zero interest rate policy negative interest rates 39 See also editBrezhnev stagnation Lost Decade Japan The End of Work Business cycle Degrowth RecessionReferences edit a b W P 16 August 2014 Secular stagnation Fad or fact The Economist U S Secular Stagnation 23 December 2015 a b Pagano and Sbracia 2014 The secular stagnation hypothesis a review of the debate and some insights Bank of Italy Questioni di Economia e Finanza occasional paper series number QEF 231 Definition of secular stagnation Financial Times Archived from the original on 16 March 2019 Retrieved 9 October 2014 a b Sweezy Alan 1943 Chapter IV Secular Stagnation In Harris Seymour E ed Postwar Economic Problems New York London McGraw Hill Book Co pp 67 82 Wells David A 1891 Recent Economic Changes and Their Effect on Production and Distribution of Wealth and Well Being of Society New York D Appleton and Co ISBN 978 0 543 72474 8 Habakkuk H J 1962 American and British Technology in the Nineteenth Century London New York Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0521094474 Hunter Louis C Bryant Lynwood 1991 A History of Industrial Power in the United States 1730 1930 Vol 3 The Transmission of Power Cambridge Mass London MIT Press ISBN 978 0 262 08198 6 Rothbard Murray 2002 History of Money and Banking in the United States PDF Ludwig Von Mises Inst p 165 ISBN 978 0 945466 33 8 a b c d e Field Alexander J 2011 A Great Leap Forward 1930s Depression and U S Economic Growth New Haven London Yale University Press ISBN 978 0 300 15109 1 Hounshell David A 1984 From the American System to Mass Production 1800 1932 The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States Baltimore Maryland Johns Hopkins University Press ISBN 978 0 8018 2975 8 LCCN 83016269 OCLC 1104810110 BTS Table 1 1 System Mileage within the United States Statute miles Archived from the original on 18 April 2008 Retrieved 7 January 2014 White William J Economic History of Tractors in the United States Archived from the original on 24 October 2013 Hours of Work in U S History 2010 Archived from the original on 26 October 2011 Whaples Robert June 1991 The Shortening of the American Work Week An Economic and Historical Analysis of Its Context Causes and Consequences The Journal of Economic History Vol 51 No 2 pp 454 457 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help a b Field Alexander 2004 Technological Change and Economic Growth the Interwar Years and the 1990s PDF Archived from the original PDF on 10 March 2012 1 There are numerous graphs of total debt GDP available on the Internet Roche Cullen 2010 Total Debt to GDP Trumps Everything Else Smil Vaclav 2006 Transforming the Twentieth Century Technical Innovations and Their Consequences Oxford New York Oxford University Press p 112 In the U S steel consumption peaked at just under 700 kg per capita and declined to just over 400 kg by 2000 Kendrick John 1 October 1991 U S Productivity Performance in Perspective Business Economics a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Field Alezander J 2007 U S Economic Growth in the Gilded Age Journal of Macroeconomics 31 173 190 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help The Recent Rise and Fall of Rapid Productivity Growth Magdoff Harry Sweezy Paul 1987 Stagnation and the Financial Explosion New York Monthly Review Press Larry Summers U S Economic Prospects Keynote Address at the NABE Conference 2014 Hans Werner Sin Forget Inflation February 26 2009 IMF Fourteenth Annual Research Conference in Honor of Stanley Fischer 8 November 2013 Krugman Paul 15 August 2014 Secular Stagnation The Book New York Times a b c d Inskeep Steve 9 September 2014 Is The Economy Suffering From Secular Stagnation NPR Gordon Robert J 2000 Does the New Economy Measure Up to the Great Inventions of the Past PDF Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 4 49 74 doi 10 1257 jep 14 4 49 Paepke C Owen 1993 The Evolution of Progress The End of Economic Growth and the Beginning of Human Transformation New York Toronto Random House ISBN 978 0 679 41582 4 Frey Carl Benedikt 2015 The End of Economic Growth How the Digital Economy Could Lead to Secular Stagnation Scientific American 312 1 Lessons from Japan s Secular Stagnation The Research Institute of Economy Trade and Industry Hoshi Takeo Kashyap Anil K 2004 Japan s Financial Crisis and Economic Stagnation Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 1 Winter 3 26 doi 10 1257 089533004773563412 Krugman Paul 2009 The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008 W W Norton Company Limited ISBN 978 0 393 07101 6 Paul Krugman Bubbles Regulation and Secular Stagnation September 25 2013 Marco Nappollini Pieria com Secular Stagnation and Post Scarcity November 19 2013 Archived from the original on 30 September 2017 Retrieved 1 December 2013 Paul Krugman Conscience of a Liberal Blog Secular Stagnation Coalmines Bubbles and Larry Summers November 16 2013 Robert J Gordon Is U S Economic Growth Over Faltering Innovation Confronts the Six Headwinds August 2012 Archived September 18 2013 at the Wayback Machine German Institute for Economic Research January 30 2017 The Natural Rate of Interest and Secular Stagnation Further reading editAyres Robert U 1998 Turning Point An End to the Growth Paradigm London Earthscan Publications ISBN 978 1 85383 439 4 Rifkin Jeremy 1995 The End of Work The Decline of the Global Labor Force and the Dawn of the Post Market Era Putnam Publishing Group ISBN 978 0 87477 779 6 Ayres Robert 1989 Technological Transformations and Long Waves PDF a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Constable George Somerville Bob 2003 A Century of Innovation Twenty Engineering Achievements That Transformed Our Lives Washington DC Joseph Henry Press ISBN 978 0 309 08908 1 Paepke C Owen 1993 The Evolution of Progress The End of Economic Growth and the Beginning of Human Transformation New York Toronto Random House ISBN 978 0 679 41582 4 Bloomberg Secular Stagnation Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Economic stagnation amp oldid 1184768099, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.