fbpx
Wikipedia

Chinese economic reform

The Chinese economic reform or Chinese economic miracle,[1][2] also known domestically as reform and opening-up (Chinese: 改革开放; pinyin: Gǎigé kāifàng), refers to a variety of economic reforms termed "socialism with Chinese characteristics" and "socialist market economy" in the People's Republic of China (PRC) that began in the late 20th century. Guided by Deng Xiaoping, who is often credited as the "General Architect", the reforms were launched by reformists within the ruling Chinese Communist Party (CCP) on December 18, 1978, during the "Boluan Fanzheng" period.[3][4][5][6]

Chinese economic reform
Simplified Chinese改革开放
Traditional Chinese改革開放
Literal meaning"Reform and Opening-Up"

Overview edit

The reforms briefly went into stagnation after the 1989 Tiananmen Square protests and massacre, but were revived after Deng Xiaoping's southern tour in 1992. The reforms led to significant economic growth for China within the successive decades; in 2010, China overtook Japan as the world's second-largest economy by nominal GDP[7][8] before overtaking the United States in 2016 as the world's largest economy by GDP (PPP).[9]

The CCP carried out the market reforms in two stages. The first stage, in the late 1970s and early 1980s, involved the de-collectivization of agriculture, the opening up of the country to foreign investment, and permission for entrepreneurs to start businesses. However, a large percentage of industries remained state-owned. The second stage of reform, in the late 1980s and 1990s, involved the privatization and contracting out of much state-owned industry. The 1985 lifting of price controls[10] was a major reform, and the lifting of protectionist policies and regulations soon followed, although state monopolies in the commanding heights of the economy such as banking and petroleum remained.

In 2001, China joined the World Trade Organization (WTO). Not long after, the private sector grew remarkably, accounting for as much as 70 percent of China's gross domestic product (GDP) by 2005.[11] From 1978 until 2013, unprecedented growth occurred, with the economy increasing by 9.5% a year. Hu Jintao and Wen Jiabao's administration took a more conservative approach towards reforms, regulated and controlled the economy more heavily after 2005, reversing some reforms.[12] On the other hand, a parallel set of political reforms were launched by Deng in 1980, which also inspired the then Soviet Union's Glasnost and Perestroika, but eventually ended in 1989 due to the crackdown on Tiananmen Square protests, halting further political liberalization.

Causes of the reforms edit

Origin edit

Before Deng Xiaoping's reforms, China's economy suffered due to centrally planned policies, such as the Great Leap Forward and the Cultural Revolution, resulting in stagnation, inefficiency, and poverty.[13] Prior to the reforms, the Chinese economy was dominated by state ownership and central planning. From 1950 to 1973, Chinese real GDP per capita grew at a rate of 2.9% per year on average, albeit with major fluctuations.[14] This placed it near the middle of the Asian nations during the same period,[15] with neighboring countries such as Japan, South Korea, Singapore and then rival Chiang Kai-shek's Republic of China (ROC) outstripping mainland China's rate of growth.[16] Starting in 1970, the economy entered into a period of stagnation,[17] and after the death of Mao Zedong, the CCP leadership decided to abandon Maoism and turn to market-oriented reforms to salvage the stagnant economy.[18] In September 1976, Mao Zedong died, and in October, Hua Guofeng together with Ye Jianying and Wang Dongxing arrested the Gang of Four, putting an end to the Cultural Revolution. Hua's break with Cultural Revolution era economic policies were consistent with the 1975 reform agenda of Deng Xiaoping.[19] Hua made national economic development a matter of the highest priority and emphasized the need to achieve "liberation of productive forces."[19] He "combined Soviet-style big push industrialization with an opening up to the capitalist world" and under his leadership, China opened its first Special Economic Zone and launched major efforts to attract foreign direct investment.[19]

Economic reforms began in earnest during the "Boluan Fanzheng" period, especially after Deng and his reformist allies rose to power with Deng replacing Hua Guofeng as the paramount leader in December 1978. By the time Deng took power, there was widespread support among the elite for economic reforms.[20] From 1978 to 1992, Deng described reform and opening up as a "large scale experiment" requiring thorough "experimentation in practice" instead of textbook knowledge.[21]: 65  As the de facto leader, Deng's policies faced opposition from party conservatives but were extremely successful in increasing the country's wealth.

Major reforms (including rural decollectivization, SOE reform, and rural health care reform) almost always began first as decentralized local experiments subject to intervention from high level Communist Party officials before they were more widely adopted.[22]: 6 

1979–1984 edit

 
The image of Deng Xiaoping in Shenzhen, Guangdong, one of the first special economic zones approved by Deng in 1979.

In 1979, Deng Xiaoping emphasized the goal of "Four Modernizations" and further proposed the idea of "xiaokang", or "moderately prosperous society".[23][24][25] The achievements of Lee Kuan Yew to create an economic success in Singapore had a profound effect on the CCP leadership in China. Leaders in China made a major effort, especially under Deng Xiaoping, to emulate his policies of economic growth, entrepreneurship, and subtle suppression of dissent. Over the years, more than 22,000 Chinese officials were sent to Singapore to study its methods.[26]

Generally, reforms in this period started with local experiments that were adopted and expanded elsewhere once their success had been demonstrated.[27]: 127  Officials generally faced few penalties for experimenting and failing and those who developed successful programs received nation-wide praise and recognition.[27]: 127  The bottom-up approach of the reforms promoted by Deng, in contrast to the top-down approach of the Perestroika in the Soviet Union, is considered an important factor contributing to the success of China's economic transition.[28]

The first reforms began in agriculture. By the late 1970s, food supplies and production had become so deficient that government officials were warning that China was about to repeat the "disaster of 1959", the famines which killed tens of millions during the Great Leap Forward.[29] Deng responded by decollectivizing agriculture and emphasizing the household-responsibility system, which divided the land of the People's communes into private plots. Under the new policy, peasants were able to exercise formal control of their land as long as they sold a contracted portion of their crops to the government.[30] This move increased agricultural production by 25 percent between 1975 and 1985, setting a precedent for privatizing other parts of the economy.[30]

Reforms were also implemented in urban industry to increase productivity. A dual-price system was introduced, in which (State-owned enterprise reform 1979) state-owned industries were allowed to sell any production above the plan quota, and commodities were sold at both plan and market prices, allowing citizens to avoid the shortages of the Maoist era. Moreover, the adoption of Industrial Responsibility System 1980s further promote the development of state-owned enterprise by allowing individuals or groups to manage the enterprise by contract. Private businesses were allowed to operate for the first time since the CCP takeover, and they gradually began to make up a greater percentage of industrial output.[31] Price flexibility was also increased, expanding the service sector.[32]

At the same time, in December 1978, Deng announced a new policy, the Open Door Policy, to open the door to foreign businesses that wanted to set up in China.[33][34] For the first time since the Kuomintang era, the country was opened to foreign investment. Deng created a series of Special Economic Zones, including Shenzhen, Zhuhai and Xiamen, for foreign investment that were relatively free of the bureaucratic regulations and interventions that hampered economic growth. These regions became engines of growth for the national economy.[32] On January 31, 1979, the Shekou Industrial Zone of Shenzhen was founded, becoming the first experimental area in China to "open up".[35][36]

In July 1979, China adopted its first Law on Joint Venture Using Chinese and Foreign Investment.[37] This law was effective in helping to attract and absorb foreign technology and capital from advanced countries like the United States, facilitated China's exports to such countries, and thereby contributed to China's subsequent rapid economic growth.[37]

Under the leadership of Yuan Geng, the "Shekou model" of development was gradually formed, embodied in its famous slogan Time is Money, Efficiency is Life, which then widely spread to other parts of China.[35][38] In January 1984, Deng Xiaoping made his first inspection tour to Shenzhen and Zhuhai, praising the "Shenzhen speed" of development as well as the success of the special economics zones.[39][40]

 
Hu Yaobang, then General Secretary of CCP, played an important role in implementing the reforms together with Zhao Ziyang, then Premier of China.

Besides Deng Xiaoping himself, important high-ranking reformists who helped carry out the reforms include Hu Yaobang, then General Secretary of Chinese Communist Party, and Zhao Ziyang, then Premier of the People's Republic of China.[41][42] Other leaders who favored Deng's reforms include Xi Zhongxun (the father of Xi Jinping), Wan Li, Hu Qili and others.[43][44][45] Another influential leader was Chen Yun, regarded by some as the second most powerful person in China after Deng with more conservative ideology of the reforms.[46][47][48] Though Deng Xiaoping is credited as the architect of modern China's economic reforms, Chen was more directly involved in the details of its planning and construction, and led a force that opposed many of the reforms from Deng's side.[47][49] The two sides struggled over the general direction of the reforms until Chen died in 1995.[47][48][49] A key feature of Chen's ideas was to use the market to allocate resources, within the scope of an overall plan. Some reforms of the early 1980s were, in effect, the implementation of a program that Chen had outlined in the mid-1950s. Chen called this the "birdcage economy (鸟笼经济/鳥籠經濟)".[50][51] According to Chen, "the cage is the plan, and it may be large or small. But within the cage the bird [the economy] is free to fly as he wishes."[47][51] Chen and some other conservative leaders including Li Xiannian never visited Shenzhen, the leading special economic zone championed by Deng.[51]

1984–1993 edit

 
Shenzhen, one of the first special economic zones of China and the "Silicon Valley of China".[52][53][54][55] Notable high-tech companies such as Huawei, ZTE and Konka were all founded in Shenzhen in the 1980s.

In October 1984, the Party adopted its Decision on the Reform of the Economic System, marking a major shift in the thinking of Chinese policymakers with regard to market mechanisms.[56]: 39–40  The Decision acknowledged that a planned economy was not the only way to develop socialism and that prior policies restricting the commodity economy had hindered socialist development.[56]: 40  After the Decision, reform focused on building a socialist planned commodity economy with Chinese characteristics.[56]: 40 

Controls on private businesses and government intervention continued to decrease, notably in the agrifood sector which saw relaxation of price controls in 1985[10] and the establishment of the household responsibility system, and there was small-scale privatization of state enterprises which had become unviable. A notable development was the decentralization of state control, leaving local provincial leaders to experiment with ways to increase economic growth and privatize the state sector.[57] Township and village enterprises, firms nominally owned by local governments but effectively private, began to gain market share at the expense of the state sector.[58] With the help of Yuan Geng, the first joint-stock commercial bank in China, the China Merchants Bank, and the first joint-stock insurance company in China, the Ping An Insurance, were both established in Shekou. In May 1984, fourteen coastal cities in China including Shanghai, Guangzhou and Tianjin were named "Open Coastal Cities (沿海开放城市)".[59][60]

A significant economic debate during this period concerned the approach to price liberalization and whether China should adopt an approach consistent with shock therapy -- sudden price liberalization – or a more gradual approach.[61] But in 1986, the latter approach won out.[61] "Confronted with the diverse, authoritative warnings about the unforeseeable risks of imposing the shock of price reform and the uncertainty about its benefits," Premier Zhao Ziyang and the leadership ultimately rejected shock price reform.[61] Zhao had accepted the argument that the basic concern in economic reform was energizing enterprises.[61] By late summer, what started under the rubric of "coordinated comprehensive package reform" had been diluted to an adjustment in the price of steel (although its price was both important had carried symbolic weight) as well as partial tax and financial reform.[61] Radical price reform again became a focus in 1988, and this time led to spiraling inflation (the first time it had done so since the 1940s) as well as a backlash that included local protests, bank runs, and panic buying.[62] The Chinese leadership halted these price liberalization plans in fall 1988 and instead focused on austerity, price reform, and retrenchment.[62]

 
The slogan "Time is Money, Efficiency is Life" from Shekou, Shenzhen, representing the "Shenzhen speed".

Corruption and increased inflation increased discontent, contributing to the 1989 Tiananmen Square protests and massacre and a conservative backlash after that event which ousted several key reformers and threatened to reverse many of Deng's reforms.[63] The events of 1988 and 1989 led to the imprisonment or exile of many reformist officials.[62] However, Deng stood by his reforms and in 1992, he affirmed the need to continue reforms in his southern tour.[64] Thanks to his encouragement, in November 1990 the Shanghai Stock Exchange was reopened after being closed by Mao 40 years earlier, while the Shenzhen Stock Exchange was also founded in December 1990.[65][66]

In contrast to the approach of Deng, conservative elders led by Chen Yun called to strike a balance between too much laissez-faire market economy and retaining state control over key areas of the economy. Chen Yun helped preserve the economy by preventing policies that would have damaged the interests of special interest groups in the government bureaucracy.[64]

Although the economy grew quickly during this period, economic troubles in the inefficient state sector increased. Heavy losses had to be made up by state revenues and acted as a drain upon the economy.[67] Inflation became problematic in 1985, 1988 and 1992.[63] Privatizations began to accelerate after 1992, and the private sector grew as a percentage of GDP. China's government slowly expanded recognition of the private economy, first as a "complement" to the state sector (1988) and then as an "important component" (1999) of the socialist market economy.[68]

1993–2005 edit

 
The Lujiazui financial district of Pudong, Shanghai, the financial and commercial hub of modern China
 
A market in Kashgar in 1992 with slogans of "Insist reform and opening-up", an alternative rendering of insisting Chinese economic reform which was well underway at the time.

In the 1990s, Deng allowed many radical reforms to be carried out. In 1993, the National People's Congress adopted the landmark Corporation Law.[69] It provides that in state owned enterprises, the state is no more than an investor and controller of stock and assets.[69] Pursuant to the Corporation Law, private and foreign investment in such enterprises must be below 49%.[69] The law also permitted state firms to declare bankruptcy in the event of business failure.[69]

In the beginning, Chen supported Deng, carried out and implemented many of the influential reforms that made a generation of Chinese richer. But later, Chen realized that the state still needed an active iron hand involvement in the market to prevent the private sector from becoming untamable. Chen's criticism of Deng's later economic reforms was widely influential within the CCP and was reflected in the policies of China's leaders after Deng. Chen's theories supported the efforts of Jiang Zemin and Hu Jintao to use state power to provide boundaries for the operation of the market, and to mediate the damage that capitalism can do to those who find it difficult to benefit from the free market. Chen's notion of the CPC as a "ruling party" was central to the redefinition of the role of the Party in Jiang Zemin's Three Represents. In 2005, on the occasion of the hundredth anniversary of Chen's birth, the Party press published, over the course of several weeks, the proceedings of a symposium discussing Chen's contributions to CCP history, theory and practice.[64]

Although Deng died in 1997, reforms continued under his handpicked successors, Jiang Zemin and Zhu Rongji, who were ardent reformers who also abided by Chen Yun advice to keep the reforms steady and keep the state still in charge of key areas. In 1997 and 1998, large-scale privatization occurred, in which all state enterprises, except a few large monopolies, were liquidated and their assets sold to private investors. Between 2001 and 2004, the number of state-owned enterprises decreased by 48 percent.[58] During the same period, Jiang and Zhu also reduced tariffs, trade barriers, and regulations; reformed the banking system; dismantled much of the Mao-era social welfare system; forced the Chinese army (PLA) to divest itself of military-run businesses;[70] reduced inflation; and joined the World Trade Organization. These moves invoked discontent among some groups, especially laid-off workers of state enterprises that had been privatized.[71]

The domestic private sector first exceeded 50% of GDP in 2005 and has further expanded since. Also in 1999, China was able to surpass Japan as the largest economy in Asia by purchasing power parity (PPP) values.[72] However, some state monopolies still remained, such as in petroleum and banking.[73]

2005–2012 edit

CCP general secretary Hu Jintao and premier Wen Jiabao took a more conservative approach towards reforms, and began to reverse some of Deng Xiaoping's reforms in 2005. Observers note that the government adopted more egalitarian and populist policies.[74] It increased subsidies and control over the health care sector,[75] increased funding for education, halted privatization,[12] and adopted a loose monetary policy, which led to the formation of a U.S.-style property bubble in which property prices tripled.[76] The privileged state sector was the primary recipient of government investment, which, under the new administration, promoted the rise of large "national champions" which could compete with large foreign corporations.[12] Nevertheless, the share of SOEs in the total number of companies have continued to fall, dropping to 5%, though their share of total output remained at 26%. Exchange rates for the yuan were also liberalized and the peg to the U.S. dollar was broken, leading the yuan to rise by 31% against the dollar from 2005 to 2012.[77] China's economic growth has averaged around 10% under Hu, while the economy surpassed the United Kingdom, France, Germany and Japan.[78][77]

2012–2020 edit

Under CCP general secretary Xi Jinping and his administration, the CCP has sought numerous reforms, with the Third Plenum of the 18th Central Committee announcing that "market forces" would begin to play a "decisive" role in allocating resources.[79] Xi launched the Shanghai Free-Trade Zone in August 2013, seen as part of the reforms.[80] He has additionally voiced support for SOEs,[81][82] and under him, at least 288 firms have revised their corporate charters by 2017 to allow the CCP greater influence in corporate management, and to reflect the party line.[83] This trend also includes Hong Kong listed firms, who have traditionally downplayed their party links, but are now "redrafting bylaws to formally establish party committees that previously existed only at the group level."[84] In other dimensions, according to Ray Dalio, the Xi era has also been marked by economic opening, greater market-oriented decision-making and discontinuation of support for poorly managed state-owned enterprises.[85]

Xi has increased the power of CCP bodies in economic decision-making, decreasing the influence of the State Council and the premier.[86] His administration made it easier for banks to issue mortgages, increased foreign participation in the bond market, and increased the national currency renminbi's global role, helping it to join IMF's basket of special drawing right.[87] His administration has also pursued a debt-deleveraging campaign, seeking to slow and cut the unsustainable amount of debt China has accrued during its economic growth.[88]

Xi's administration has also reoriented the economy to increase self-reliance, and accordingly launched two campaigns; Made in China 2025 and China Standards 2035, which have sought to scale up and displace US dominance in various high-tech sectors,[85] though publicly China de-emphasized these plans due to the outbreak of a trade war with the U.S in 2018.[89] This is alongside more aggressive pursuit of trade policies, in line with an outlook that sees China move towards taking a more active role in writing the rules of trade.

Some analysts have also added that the reform era has been scaled down significantly during the leadership of Xi when the reformists lost power,[90][91][92] citing that Xi has reasserted state control over different aspects of Chinese society,[93] including the economy.[14][94][95]

2020–present edit

Xi has circulated a policy called "dual circulation", meaning reorienting the economy towards domestic consumption while remaining open to foreign trade and investment.[96] Since 2021, his administration has formulated the "three red lines" policy that aimed to deleverage the heavily indebted property sector.[97]

In September 2020, the CCP announced that it would strengthen United Front work in the private sector by establishing more party committees in the regional federations of industry and commerce (FIC), and by arranging a special liaison between FIC and the CCP.[98]

Since 2021, Xi has promoted the term "common prosperity", a term which he defined as an "essential requirement of socialism", described as affluence for all and said entailed reasonable adjustments to excess incomes.[99][100] Common prosperity has been used as the justification for large-scale crackdowns and regulations towards the perceived "excesses" of several sectors, most prominently tech and tutoring industries.[101]

Effects of the reforms edit

Economic performance edit

 
China's nominal GDP trend from 1952 to 2015. Note the rapid increase since reform in the late 1970s.

The success of China's economic policies and the manner of their implementation resulted in immense changes in Chinese society in the last 40 years, including greatly decreased poverty while both average incomes and income inequality have increased, leading to a backlash led by the more ideologically pure New Left. Scholars have debated the reason for the success of the Chinese "dual-track" economy, and have compared it to attempts to reform socialism in the Eastern Bloc and the Soviet Union; as well as to the growth of other developing economies. Additionally, these series of reforms have led to China's rise as a great power and a shift of international geopolitical interests towards China, especially in matters relating to the ambiguous political status of Taiwan. Some analysts have also added that the reform era has been scaled down significantly during the leadership of current CCP General Secretary Xi Jinping when the reformists lost power,[90][91][92] citing that Xi has reasserted state control over different aspects of Chinese society,[93] including the economy.[14][94][95]

After three decades of reform, China's economy experienced one of the world's biggest booms. Agriculture and light industry have largely been privatized, while the state still retains control over some heavy industries. Despite the dominance of state ownership in finance, telecommunications, petroleum and other important sectors of the economy, private entrepreneurs continue to expand into sectors formerly reserved for public enterprise. Prices have also been liberalized.[102]

China's economic growth since the reform has been very rapid, exceeding the East Asian Tigers. Since the beginning of Deng Xiaoping's reforms, China's GDP has risen tenfold.[103] The increase in total factor productivity (TFP) was the most important factor, with productivity accounting for 40.1% of the GDP increase, compared with a decline of 13.2% for the period 1957 to 1978—the height of Maoist policies. For the period 1978–2005, Chinese GDP per capita increased from 2.7% to 15.7% of U.S. GDP per capita, and from 53.7% to 188.5% of Indian GDP per capita. Per capita incomes grew at 6.6% a year.[104] Average wages rose sixfold between 1978 and 2005,[105] while absolute poverty declined from 41% of the population to 5% from 1978 to 2001.[106] Some scholars believed that China's economic growth has been understated, due to large sectors of the economy not being counted.[107]

Impact on world growth edit

China is widely seen as an engine of world and regional growth.[108] Surges in Chinese demand account for 50, 44 and 66 percent of export growth of the Hong Kong SAR of China, Japan and Taiwan respectively, and China's trade deficit with the rest of East Asia helped to revive the economies of Japan and Southeast Asia.[108] Asian leaders view China's economic growth as an "engine of growth for all Asia".[109]

Effect on inequality edit

 
Gini-coefficient of national income distribution around the world (dark green: <0.25, red: >0.60)

Although the economic reforms has caused significant economic growth in China, it has also caused increased inequality, resulting in backlash and an attempt at pushing back the reforms by the Chinese New Left faction. Despite rapid economic growth which has virtually eliminated poverty in urban China and reduced it greatly in rural regions and the fact that living standards for everyone in China have drastically increased in comparison to the pre-reform era, the Gini coefficient of China is estimated to be above 0.45, comparable to some Latin American countries such as Argentina and Mexico as well as the United States.[110]

Increased inequality is attributed to the gradual withdrawal of the welfare state system in China and differences between coastal and interior provinces, the latter being burdened by a larger state sector.[111] Some Western scholars have suggested that reviving the welfare state and instituting a re-distributive income tax system is needed to relieve inequality,[112] while some Chinese economists have suggested that privatizing state monopolies and distributing the proceeds to the population can reduce inequality.[113]

Reforms in specific sectors edit

Agriculture edit

 
Production of wheat from 1961 to 2004. Data from FAO, year 2005. Y-axis: Production in metric ton.

During the pre-reform period, Chinese agricultural performance was extremely poor and food shortages were common.[114] After Deng Xiaoping implemented the household responsibility system, agricultural output increased by 8.2% a year, compared with 2.7% in the pre-reform period, despite a decrease in the area of land used.[114] Food prices fell nearly 50%, while agricultural incomes rose.[115]

Zhao Ziyang wrote in his memoirs that in the years following the household contracting system, "the energy that was unleashed … was magical, beyond what anyone could have imagined. A problem thought to be unsolvable had worked itself out in just a few years time … [B]y 1984, farmers actually had more grain than they could sell. The state grain storehouses were stacked full from the annual procurement program."[116]

A fundamental transformation was the economy's growing adoption of cash crops instead of just growing rice and grain.[115] Vegetable and meat production increased to the point that Chinese agricultural production was adding the equivalent of California's vegetable industry every two years. Growth in the sector slowed after 1984, with agriculture falling from 40% of GDP to 16%; however, increases in agricultural productivity allowed workers to be released for work in industry and services, while simultaneously increasing agricultural production.[117] Trade in agriculture was also liberalized and China became an exporter of food, a great contrast to its previous famines and shortages.[118]

Industry edit

In the pre-reform period, industry was largely stagnant and the socialist system presented few incentives for improvements in quality and productivity. With the introduction of the dual-price system and greater autonomy for enterprise managers, productivity increased greatly in the early 1980s.[119] Foreign enterprises and newly formed Township and Village Enterprises, owned by local government and often de facto private firms, competed successfully with state-owned enterprises. By the 1990s, large-scale privatizations reduced the market share of both the Township and Village Enterprises and state-owned enterprises and increased the private sector's market share. The state sector's share of industrial output dropped from 81% in 1980 to 15% in 2005.[120] Foreign capital controls much of Chinese industry and plays an important role.[58]

From virtually an industrial backwater in 1978, China is now the world's biggest producer of concrete, steel, ships and textiles, and has the world's largest automobile market. Chinese steel output quadrupled between 1980 and 2000, and from 2000 to 2006 rose from 128.5 million tons to 418.8 million tons, one-third of global production.[121] Labor productivity at some Chinese steel firms exceeds Western productivity.[121] From 1975 to 1992, China's automobile production rose from 139,800 to 1.1 million, rising to 9.35 million in 2008.[122] Light industries such as textiles saw an even greater increase, due to reduced government interference. Chinese textile exports increased from 4.6% of world exports in 1980 to 24.1% in 2005. Textile output increased 18-fold over the same period.[123]

This increase in production is largely the result of the removal of barriers to entry and increased competition; the number of industrial firms rose from 377,300 in 1980 to nearly 8 million in 1990 and 1996; the 2004 economic census, which excluded enterprises with annual sales below RMB 5 million, counted 1.33 million manufacturing firms, with Jiangsu and Zhejiang reporting more firms than the nationwide total for 1980.[124] Compared to other East Asian industrial growth spurts, China's industrial performance exceeded Japan's but remained behind South Korea and Taiwan's economies.[125]

Trade and foreign investment edit

 
Global distribution of Chinese exports in 2006 as a percentage of the top market

Some scholars assert that China has maintained a high degree of openness that is unusual among the other large and populous nations,[dubious ] with competition from foreign goods in almost every sector of the economy. Foreign investment helped to greatly increase quality, knowledge and standards, especially in heavy industry. China's experience supports the assertion that globalization greatly increases wealth for poor countries.[124] Throughout the reform period, the government reduced tariffs and other trade barriers, with the overall tariff rate falling from 56% to 15%. By 2001, less than 40% of imports were subject to tariffs and only 9 percent of import were subject to licensing and import quotas. Even during the early reform era, protectionist policies were often circumvented by smuggling.[126] When China joined the WTO, it agreed to considerably harsher conditions than other developing countries.[127] Trade has increased from under 10% of GDP to 64% of GDP over the same period.[128] China is considered the most open large country; by 2005, China's average statutory tariff on industrial products was 8.9%. The average was 30.9% for Argentina, 27.0% for Brazil, 32.4% for India, and 36.9% for Indonesia.[129]

China's trade surplus is considered by some in the United States as threatening American jobs. In the 2000s, the Bush administration pursued protectionist policies such as tariffs and quotas to limit the import of Chinese goods. Some scholars argue that China's growing trade surplus is the result of industries in more developed Asian countries moving to China, and not a new phenomenon.[109] China's trade policy, which allows producers to avoid paying the Value Added Tax (VAT) for exports and undervaluation of the currency since 2002, has resulted in an overdeveloped export sector and distortion of the economy overall, a result that could hamper future growth.[130]

Foreign investment was also liberalized upon Deng's ascension. Special Economic Zones (SEZs) were created in the early 1980s to attract foreign capital by exempting them from taxes and regulations. This experiment was successful and SEZs were expanded to cover the whole Chinese coast. Although FDI fell briefly after the 1989 student protests, it increased again to 160 billion by 2004.[131]

Services edit

 
Shanghai Stock Exchange
 
Shenzhen Stock Exchange

In the 1990s, the financial sector was liberalized.[132] After China joined the World Trade Organization (WTO), the service sector was considerably liberalized and foreign investment was allowed; restrictions on retail, wholesale and distribution ended.[133] Banking, financial services, insurance and telecommunications were also opened up to foreign investment.[134]

China's banking sector is dominated by four large state-owned banks, which are largely inefficient and monopolistic.[135] China's largest bank, ICBC, is the largest bank in the world. The financial sector is widely seen as a drag on the economy due to the inefficient state management.[136] Non-performing loans, mostly made to local governments and unprofitable state-owned enterprises for political purposes,[137] especially the political goal of keeping unemployment low, are a big drain on the financial system and economy, reaching over 22% of GDP by 2000, with a drop to 6.3% by 2006 due to government recapitalization of these banks. In 2006, the total amount of non-performing loans was estimated at $160 billion.[138] Observers recommend privatization of the banking system to solve this problem, a move that was partially carried out when the four banks were floated on the stock market.[139] China's financial markets, the Shanghai Stock Exchange and Shenzhen Stock Exchange, are relatively ineffective at raising capital, as they comprise only 11% of GDP.[140]

Due to the weakness of the banks, firms raise most of their capital through an informal, nonstandard financial sector developed during the 1980s and 1990s, consisting largely of underground businesses and private banks.[141] Internal finance is the most important method successful firms use to fund their activities.[141]

By the 1980s much emphasis was placed on the role of advertising in meeting the modernization goals being promoted by Deng. Lip service was still paid to old Maoist ideals of egalitarianism, but it did not inhibit the growth of consumerism.[142]

Government finances edit

In the pre-reform era, government was funded by profits from state-owned enterprises, much like the Soviet Union.[143] As the state sector fell in importance and profitability, government revenues, especially that of the central government in Beijing, fell substantially and the government relied on a confused system of inventory taxes. Government revenues fell from 35% of GDP to 11% of GDP in the mid-1990s, excluding revenue from state-owned enterprises, with the central government's budget at just 3% of GDP.[144] The tax system was reformed in 1994 when inventory taxes were unified into a single VAT of 17% on all manufacturing, repair, and assembly activities and an excise tax on 11 items, with the VAT becoming the main income source, accounting for half of government revenue. The 1994 reform also increased the central government's share of revenues, increasing it to 9% of GDP.[145]

Academic studies edit

Reasons for success edit

 
Discussion of "China's Next Global Agenda" during the World Economic Forum (2013).

Scholars have proposed a number of theories to explain China's successful transition from a planned to a socialist market economy. This occurred despite unfavorable factors such as the troublesome legacies of socialism, considerable erosion of the work ethic, decades of anti-market propaganda, and the "lost generation" whose education disintegrated amid the disruption of the Cultural Revolution.[146]

One notable theory is that decentralization of state authority allowed local leaders to experiment with various ways to privatize the state sector and energize the economy.[57] Although Deng was not the originator of many of the reforms, he approved them. Another theory focuses on internal incentives within the Chinese government, in which officials presiding over areas of high economic growth were more likely to be promoted. This made local and provincial governments "hungry for investment," who competed to reduce regulations and barriers to investment to boost both economic growth and their careers. Such reforms were possible because Deng cultivated pro-market followers in the government.[147] Herman Kahn argued that Confucian ethic was playing a "similar but more spectacular role in the modernization of East Asia than the Protestant ethic played in Europe".[148]

Taken together, Yuen Yuen Ang argues in Foreign Affairs that political reforms took place with economic reforms under Deng, except the former did not take Western forms. She writes, "To be sure, Deng's reforms emphasized brute capital accumulation rather than holistic development, which led to environmental degradation, inequality, and other social problems. Still they undoubtedly kicked China's growth machine into gear by making the bureaucracy results oriented, fiercely competitive, and responsive to business needs, qualities that are normally associated with democracies." But this only applies to the Deng era. Ang notes that since 2012, when Xi Jinping took over, the new leader has reversed Deng's political reforms and limits to power, "just as political freedoms have become imperative for continued economic growth."[149]

 
Roberto Azevêdo, Director-General of WTO, met with China's Minister of Commerce Gao Hucheng in Qingdao (2014).

China's success is also due to the export-led growth strategy used successfully by the Four Asian Tigers beginning with Japan in the 1960s–1970s and other newly industrialized countries.[150] In 2001, China joined the World Trade Organization (WTO).[151] As of 2006, over 400 of the Fortune 500 companies had entered the Chinese market, while at the same time a considerable number of Chinese companies had opened their markets outside of China.[152] Foreign aids to China, including those from Hong Kong, Macau and Taiwan, also played an important role.[153][154][155] Since the beginning of opening, China has received a significant amount of aid from major developed countries such as the United States, Japan, Germany, France and the United Kingdom.[153][154] For instance, through its Official Development Assistance (ODA), Japan had offered China various forms of assistance worth 3.65 trillion Yen as of 2018.[153][156] On the other hand, the assistance from the U.S. reached a total of US$556 million as of 2012, and has "helped Tibetan communities improve livelihoods, promote sustainable development and environmental conservation, and preserve cultural traditions...also supports targeted programs that strengthen cooperation on combatting the spread of HIV/AIDS and other pandemic and emerging diseases as well as rule of law programs."[153][155]

In contrast to the neoliberal view which emphasizes benefits from decentralization, increased privatization, and globalization, Professor Lin Chun concludes that studies have demonstrated pre-reform period factors that are at least as compelling factors in China's success.[157] Those factors include strong "human capital" accumulated through decades of state investments in basic needs including health care and public education, state and rural collective ownership of land, the public sector's retaining of strategic industries, government sponsorship of trade and technology transfers, and public spending.[157]

The collapse of the Soviet Bloc and centrally planned economies in 1989 provided renewed impetus for China to further reform its economy through different policies to avoid a similar fate.[158] China also wanted to avoid the Russian ad-hoc experiments with market capitalism under Boris Yeltsin resulting in the rise of powerful oligarchs, corruption, and the loss of state revenue which exacerbated economic disparity.[159]

The Cultural Revolution contributed to China's economic growth in long run. According to Mancur Olson, the Cultural Revolution attacked the very administrators and managers on which Chinese economy depended, and the immediate result was instability and administrative chaos in short run. A longer-run result was that there were not nearly as many well-entrenched interest groups as in the Soviet Union and the Eastern Bloc, so when Deng Xiaoping and the other pragmatists take power, there were few interest groups whose lobbying could undermine Deng's market-oriented reforms, because the Cultural Revolution had destroyed the narrowly entrenched interests with a stake in the status quo.[160]

Comparison to other developing economies edit

 
Development trends of Chinese and Indian GDP (1950–2010)

China's transition from a planned economy to a socialist market economy has often been compared with economies in Eastern Europe that are undergoing a similar transition. China's performance has been praised for avoiding the major shocks and inflation that plagued the Eastern Bloc.[161] The Eastern bloc economies saw declines varying from 13% to 65% in GDP at the beginning of reforms, while Chinese growth has been very strong since the beginning of reform.[162] China also managed to avoid the hyperinflation of 200 to 1,000% that Eastern Europe experienced.[163] This success is attributed to the gradualist and decentralized approach of the Chinese government, which allowed market institutions to develop to the point where they could replace state planning. This contrasts with the "big bang" approach of Eastern Europe, where the state-owned sector was rapidly privatized with employee buyouts, but retained much of the earlier, inefficient management.[164] Other factors thought to account for the differences are the greater urbanization of the CIS economies and differences in social welfare and other institutions.[165] Another argument is that, in the Eastern European economies, political change is sometimes seen to have made gradualist reforms impossible, so the shocks and inflation were unavoidable.[166]

China's economic growth has been compared with other developing countries, such as Brazil, Mexico, and India. GDP growth in China outstrips all other developing countries, with only India after 1990 coming close to China's experience.[167] Scholars believe that high rates of investments, especially increases in capital invested per worker, have contributed to China's superior economic performance.[167] China's relatively free economy, with less government intervention and regulation, is cited by scholars as an important factor in China's superior performance compared to other developing countries.[168]

Criticism and development issues edit

 
Air pollution has become a major environmental issue in China resulting from the economic development. (The picture shows thick haze in Lujiazui of Shanghai in 2011)
 
Global CO2 gas emissions by country (2015).

The government retains monopolies in several sectors, such as petroleum and banking. The recent reversal of some reforms have left some observers dubbing 2008 the "third anniversary of the end of reforms".[12] Nevertheless, observers[who?] believe that China's economy can continue growing at rates of 6–8 percent until 2025,[169] though a reduction in state intervention is considered by some to be necessary for sustained growth.[170]

It has been reported, including by the National Bureau of Statistics, that over the years that the GDP figures and other economic data from local Chinese governments may be inflated or manipulated otherwise.[171][172][173][174][175] Officials from central government have said that local government officials sometimes falsify economic data to meet the economic growth targets or for personal promotions.[171][176]

Despite reducing poverty and increasing China's wealth, Deng's reforms have been criticized by the Chinese New Left for increasing inequality and allowing private entrepreneurs to purchase state assets at reduced prices. These accusations were especially intense during the Lang–Gu dispute, in which New Left academic Larry Hsien Ping Lang accused entrepreneur Gu Sujung of usurping state assets, after which Gu was imprisoned.[177] The Hu–Wen Administration adopted some New Left policies, such as halting privatizations and increasing the state sector's importance in the economy, and Keynesian policies that have been criticized by some Chinese economists such as Zhang Weiying, who advocate a policy of deregulation, tax cuts and privatization.[113]

Other criticisms focus on the effects of rapid industrialization on public health and the environment. For instance, China is the largest CO2 emitter in the world.[178] However, scholars believe that public health issues are unlikely to become major obstacles to the growth of China's economy during the coming decades, and studies have shown that air quality and other environmental measures in China are better than those in developed countries, such as the United States and Japan, at the same level of development.[179] Air pollution reached its peak in the early 2010s, and has declined significantly since then.[180][181]

Some scholars have also contested the claims that the reform has led to as dramatic reduction in poverty as reported. The dramatic reduction reported relies on the use of the World Bank poverty line of $1.90 per day, which some have argued is an inaccurate means of measuring poverty in pre-reform China, as during the Mao era and the decade after its end, an effective and far-reaching system of public provision existed in China which kept prices low, and a food rationing system which (except during the Great Chinese Famine years) effectively guaranteed the vast majority of China's population with access to food.[182] Using China's "Basic Needs Poverty Line", calculated based on OECD datasets, the proportion of Chinese people unable to afford a "subsistence basket" (basic needs) has increased since the increasing pace of reforms in the late 1980s and 1990s.[183][184]

The economic reforms were initially accompanied with a series of political reforms in the 1980s, supported by Deng Xiaoping. However, many of the planned political reforms ended after the 1989 Tiananmen Square protests and massacre.[185] Lack of political reform contributed to the serious corruption issue in China.[186] Additionally, China's economic growth has led to the rise of a real state bubble.[187]

Since the late 1970s, Deng and other senior leaders including Chen Yun and Li Xiannian supported the "one-child policy" to cope with the overpopulation crisis.[188] However, the 2010 census data showed that the population growth rate dropped to low levels.[189] Due to the financial pressure and other factors, many young couples increasingly choose to delay or even abandon the plan of raising a second child even after the Chinese government largely relaxed the one-child policy in late 2015.[190][191][192] This has led to the aging of the Chinese population, which economists have said could potentially harm the economy in the future.[191][193][194]

See also edit

References edit

Citations edit

  1. ^ Ray, Alok (2002). "The Chinese Economic Miracle: Lessons to Be Learnt". Economic and Political Weekly. 37 (37): 3835–3848. ISSN 0012-9976. JSTOR 4412606.
  2. ^ Harrison, Virginia; Palumbo, Daniele (30 September 2019). "China anniversary: How the country became the world's 'economic miracle'". BBC News. Retrieved 26 December 2022.
  3. ^ Faison, Seth (1997-02-20). "DENG XIAOPING IS DEAD AT 92; ARCHITECT OF MODERN CHINA (Published 1997)". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 2021-01-12.
  4. ^ Eisenman, Joshua. "Analysis | What we really know about China's Reform and Opening Up". The Washington Post. ISSN 0190-8286. Retrieved 2021-01-12.
  5. ^ Ezra F. Vogel, Deng Xiaoping and the Transformation of China (2011).
  6. ^ "关于"总设计师"称谓提法的来龙去脉--邓小平纪念网". Renmin Wang (in Chinese). 2016-06-30. from the original on 2020-07-12. Retrieved 2021-01-12.
  7. ^ Barboza, David (2010-08-15). "China Passes Japan as Second-Largest Economy". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 2020-05-03.
  8. ^ "China overtakes Japan as world's second-largest economy". The Guardian. Associated Press. 2010-08-16. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved 2020-05-03.
  9. ^ Bergsten, C. Fred (2022). The United States vs. China : the quest for global economic leadership. Cambridge. p. 86. ISBN 978-1-5095-4735-7. OCLC 1255691875.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  10. ^ a b Longworth, John William; Brown, Colin G.; Waldron, Scott A. (2001). Beef in China: Agribusiness Opportunities and Challenges. University of Queensland Press. p. 248. ISBN 9780702232312.
  11. ^ Engardio, Peter (21 August 2005). . Bloomberg Businessweek. Archived from the original on 29 January 2014. Retrieved 30 September 2014.
  12. ^ a b c d Scissors, Derek (May–June 2009). "Deng Undone: The Costs of Halting Market Reform in China". Foreign Affairs. 88 (3). from the original on 2015-04-21. Retrieved 2014-09-30.
  13. ^ "Политика реформ и открытости в Китае". Свои в Китае (in Russian). 12 July 2023. Retrieved 2023-07-12.
  14. ^ a b c Naughton, Barry (2007). The Chinese economy : transitions and growth. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. pp. 3–5. ISBN 978-0262640640. OCLC 70839809.
  15. ^ Walder 2015, pp. 321.
  16. ^ Brandt 2008, p. 8.
  17. ^ Walder 2015, pp. 322.
  18. ^ Brandt 2008, pp. 7–8.
  19. ^ a b c Weber, Isabella (2021). How China escaped shock therapy : the market reform debate. Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge. p. 106. ISBN 978-0-429-49012-5. OCLC 1228187814.
  20. ^ Marquis, Christopher; Qiao, Kunyuan (2022-11-15). Mao and Markets: The Communist Roots of Chinese Enterprise. Yale University Press. doi:10.2307/j.ctv3006z6k. ISBN 978-0-300-26883-6. JSTOR j.ctv3006z6k. S2CID 253067190.
  21. ^ Heilmann, Sebastian (2018). Red Swan: How Unorthodox Policy-Making Facilitated China's Rise. The Chinese University of Hong Kong Press. ISBN 978-962-996-827-4.
  22. ^ Heilmann, Sebastian (2018). Red Swan: How Unorthodox Policy-Making Facilitated China's Rise. The Chinese University of Hong Kong Press. ISBN 978-962-996-827-4.
  23. ^ "Meet "moderately prosperous" China". Economist. 21 November 2019. from the original on 2020-06-04. Retrieved 2020-05-26.
  24. ^ . Xinhuanet. 2019-03-04. Archived from the original on 2019-03-04. Retrieved 2020-05-26.
  25. ^ Wong, John (1998-03-01). "Xiao-kang: Deng Xiaoping's socio-economic development target for China". Journal of Contemporary China. 7 (17): 141–152. doi:10.1080/10670569808724309. ISSN 1067-0564.
  26. ^ Buckley, C. (March 23, 2015). . The New York Times. Archived from the original on March 24, 2015.
  27. ^ a b Jin, Keyu (2023). The New China Playbook: Beyond Socialism and Capitalism. New York: Viking. ISBN 978-1-9848-7828-1.
  28. ^ Cited by Susan L. Shirk in The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China, University of California, Berkeley and Los Angeles, 1993. ISBN 0-520-07706-7
  29. ^ Brandt 2008, p. 8
  30. ^ a b Hunt, Michael H. (2004). The World Transformed: 1945 to the Present. Boston: Bedford/St. Martin's. p. 355. ISBN 9780312245832. LCCN 2003101700. OCLC 1151774819. OL 3695802M.
  31. ^ Brandt 2008, p. 10
  32. ^ a b Brandt 2008, p. 11
  33. ^ "Open Door Policy". BBC. from the original on 2017-07-25. Retrieved 2019-05-17.
  34. ^ Yun-Wing Sung (16 January 1992). The China-Hong Kong Connection: The Key to China's Open Door Policy. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521382458.
  35. ^ a b "Unsung hero of China's opening up is star of Shenzhen museum". South China Morning Post. 2018-12-27. Retrieved 2020-09-05.
  36. ^ "Shekou Industrial Zone — firsts in reform and opening-up". China Daily. Retrieved 2020-09-05.
  37. ^ a b Zhao, Suisheng (2023). The dragon roars back : transformational leaders and dynamics of Chinese foreign policy. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press. pp. 54–55. ISBN 978-1-5036-3415-2. OCLC 1332788951.
  38. ^ Cheong, Danson (2018-12-07). "Shenzhen – from village to city of opportunities". The Straits Times. Retrieved 2020-09-05.
  39. ^ "Jan 24–29,1984: Deng Xiaoping visits Shenzhen and Zhuhai – China – Chinadaily.com.cn". China Daily. Retrieved 2020-06-17.
  40. ^ Yuan, Yiming (2017-03-15). Studies on China's Special Economic Zones. Springer. ISBN 978-981-10-3704-7.
  41. ^ "Hu Yaobang: an icon of China's reform – and of how little has changed". South China Morning Post. 2019-04-14. Retrieved 2021-01-12.
  42. ^ "Zhao Ziyang: The forgotten architect of China's economic reforms | DW | 14.01.2015". Deutsche Welle. 2015-01-14. from the original on 2015-08-20. Retrieved 2021-01-12.
  43. ^ Hornby, Lucy (2018-11-15). "Xi versus Deng, the family feud over China's reforms". Financial Times. from the original on 2018-11-18. Retrieved 2021-01-12.
  44. ^ "Chinese reform politician Wan Li dies at 98". AP NEWS. 16 July 2015. Retrieved 2021-01-12.
  45. ^ "Hu Qili Urged People Throughout Country to Help Change China With AM-China, Bjt". AP NEWS. Retrieved 2021-01-12.
  46. ^ Bachman, David (1986). "Differing Visions of China's Post-Mao Economy: The Ideas of Chen Yun, Deng Xiaoping, and Zhao Ziyang". Asian Survey. 26 (3): 292–321. doi:10.2307/2644194. ISSN 0004-4687. JSTOR 2644194.
  47. ^ a b c d Wudunn, Sheryl (1995-04-11). "Chen Yun, a Chinese Communist Patriarch Who Helped Slow Reforms, Is Dead at 89 (Published 1995)". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 2021-01-12.
  48. ^ a b "CHEN YUN DIES". The Washington Post. ISSN 0190-8286. Retrieved 2021-01-12.
  49. ^ a b Sullivan, Lawrence R. (1988). "Assault on the Reforms: Conservative Criticism of Political and Economic Liberalization in China, 1985–86". The China Quarterly. 114 (114): 198–222. doi:10.1017/S030574100002676X. ISSN 0305-7410. JSTOR 654442. S2CID 154870609.
  50. ^ Exupoli. "Bird Cage Economics" 2022-12-08 at the Wayback Machine. Exupoli.net.
  51. ^ a b c Coase, Ronald; Wang, Ning (2012), Coase, Ronald; Wang, Ning (eds.), "A Bird in the Cage: Market Reform under Socialism", How China Became Capitalist, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 68–103, doi:10.1057/9781137019370_4, ISBN 978-1-137-01937-0, retrieved 2021-01-12
  52. ^ Rivers, Matt (2018-11-23). "Inside China's Silicon Valley: From copycats to innovation | CNN Business". CNN. Retrieved 2022-09-19.
  53. ^ The rise of China's 'Silicon Valley' – CNN Video, 19 November 2018, retrieved 2020-05-25
  54. ^ "A $30 Billion Fortune Is Hiding in China's Silicon Valley". Bloomberg L.P. October 18, 2021.
  55. ^ . Xinhua News Agency. Archived from the original on December 19, 2019. Retrieved 2020-05-25.
  56. ^ a b c Liu, Zongyuan Zoe (2023). Sovereign Funds: How the Communist Party of China Finances its Global Ambitions. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674271913.
  57. ^ a b Brandt 2008, pp. 17–18
  58. ^ a b c Rawski 2008, p. 573
  59. ^ Lee, Dinah (1984-11-25). "China's Coastal Cities Seek Foreign Investors". The Washington Post. ISSN 0190-8286. Retrieved 2022-09-19.
  60. ^ Yang, Dali L. (1991). "China Adjusts to the World Economy: The Political Economy of China's Coastal Development Strategy". Pacific Affairs. 64 (1): 42–64. doi:10.2307/2760362. ISSN 0030-851X. JSTOR 2760362.
  61. ^ a b c d e Weber, Isabella (2021). How China escaped shock therapy : the market reform debate. Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge. p. 220. ISBN 978-0-429-49012-5. OCLC 1228187814.
  62. ^ a b c Weber, Isabella (2021). How China escaped shock therapy : the market reform debate. Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge. p. 240. ISBN 978-0-429-49012-5. OCLC 1228187814.
  63. ^ a b Naughton 2008, p. 105
  64. ^ a b c Naughton 2008, p. 114
  65. ^ Walter, Carl E. (September 2014). "Was Deng Xiaoping Right? An Overview of China's Equity Markets". Journal of Applied Corporate Finance. 26 (3): 8–19. doi:10.1111/jacf.12075. ISSN 1078-1196. S2CID 153763863.
  66. ^ . Embassy of the People's Republic of China in the Republic of Kenya. Archived from the original on 2020-06-04. Retrieved 2020-05-02.
  67. ^ Brandt 2008, p. 22
  68. ^ Brandt 2008, p. 19
  69. ^ a b c d Lin, Chun (2006). The transformation of Chinese socialism. Durham [N.C.]: Duke University Press. p. 259. ISBN 978-0-8223-3785-0. OCLC 63178961.
  70. ^ Naughton 2008, p. 116
  71. ^ Brandt 2008, p. 128
  72. ^ Schoenleber, H. (23 September 2006). "China's Private Economy Grows Up". 8km.de. from the original on 31 August 2010. Retrieved 28 August 2010.
  73. ^ Zhao, Huanxin (19 December 2006). "China names key industries for state control". China Daily. from the original on 11 October 2017.
  74. ^ Naughton 2008, p. 129
  75. ^ "China's New Healthcare could cover millions more" 2013-08-26 at the Wayback Machine, Time magazine.
  76. ^ Chovanec, Patrick (2009-06-08). "China's Real Estate Riddle" 2009-06-14 at the Wayback Machine. Far East Economic Review. Retrieved 13 March 2010.
  77. ^ a b Orlik, Tom (16 November 2012). "Charting China's Economy: 10 Years Under Hu". The Wall Street Journal. Retrieved 7 June 2023.
  78. ^ "China overtakes Japan as world's second-biggest economy". BBC News. February 14, 2011.
  79. ^ Kroeber, Arthur R. (17 November 2013). "Xi Jinping's Ambitious Agenda for Economic Reform in China". Brookings Institution. from the original on 27 July 2014. Retrieved 21 July 2014.
  80. ^ Denyer, Simon (25 August 2013). "Creeping reforms as China gives Shanghai Free Trade Zone go-ahead". The Washington Post. Retrieved 4 January 2023.
  81. ^ Wang, Orange; Leng, Sidney (28 September 2018). "Chinese President Xi Jinping's show of support for state-owned firms 'no surprise', analysts say". South China Morning Post. Retrieved 31 January 2020.
  82. ^ Whyte, Martin K. (15 March 2021). "China's economic development history and Xi Jinping's "China dream:" an overview with personal reflections". Chinese Sociological Review. 53 (2): 115–134. doi:10.1080/21620555.2020.1833321. ISSN 2162-0555. S2CID 228867589.
  83. ^ . asia.nikkei.com. Archived from the original on 2017-08-18. Retrieved 2017-08-18.
  84. ^ "Commentary: Why Chinese state companies are getting the Communist party's attention". Channel NewsAsia. from the original on 2017-08-18. Retrieved 2017-08-18.
  85. ^ a b Dalio, Ray. . principles.com. Archived from the original on 2021-01-06. Retrieved 2021-01-03.
  86. ^ Mitchell, Tom (25 July 2016). "Xi's China: The rise of party politics". Financial Times. Archived from the original on 11 December 2022. Retrieved 31 January 2020.
  87. ^ Bradsher, Keith (4 March 2017). "China and Economic Reform: Xi Jinping's Track Record". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. from the original on 5 March 2017. Retrieved 31 January 2020.
  88. ^ Tran, Hung (14 March 2023). "China's debt-reduction campaign is making progress, but at a cost". Atlantic Council.
  89. ^ Fifield, Anna (2 November 2018). "As China settles in for trade war, leader Xi emphasizes 'self reliance'". The Washington Post. Retrieved 31 January 2020.
  90. ^ a b Youwei (2019-06-04). "The End of Reform in China". Foreign Affairs: America and the World. ISSN 0015-7120. from the original on 2019-08-19. Retrieved 2019-08-19.
  91. ^ a b Tiezzi, Shannon (2018-04-04). "Carl Minzner on China's Post-Reform Era". The Diplomat. from the original on 2019-08-19. Retrieved 2019-08-19.
  92. ^ a b "China: Deng Xiaoping era ends with start of Xi era". EJ Insight. 2018-09-06. from the original on 2019-08-19. Retrieved 2019-08-19.
  93. ^ a b "Chinese state tightens grip 40 years after Deng's reforms". Nikkei Asian Review. from the original on 2019-08-24. Retrieved 2019-08-23.
  94. ^ a b Westcott, Ben; Lee, Lily (December 17, 2018). "China sparked an economic miracle — now there's a fight over its legacy". CNN International Edition. from the original on January 2, 2019. Retrieved January 2, 2019.
  95. ^ a b "Xi Jinping's turn away from the market puts Chinese growth at risk". Financial Times. 15 January 2019. from the original on 2019-08-23. Retrieved 2019-08-23.
  96. ^ Wei, Lingling (12 August 2020). "China's Xi Speeds Up Inward Economic Shift". The Wall Street Journal. ISSN 0099-9660. Retrieved 13 August 2022.
  97. ^ Lin, Andy; Hale, Thomas; Hudson, Hudson (8 October 2021). "Half of China's top developers crossed Beijing's 'red lines'". Financial Times. Archived from the original on 11 December 2022. Retrieved 11 August 2022.
  98. ^ General Office of the CCP Central Committee. . Xinhua net (in Chinese). Archived from the original on 19 October 2020. Retrieved 15 September 2020.
  99. ^ "Full Text: Xi Jinping's Speech on Boosting Common Prosperity – Caixin Global". Caixin Global. 19 October 2021. Retrieved 11 August 2022.
  100. ^ Hass, Ryan (9 September 2021). "Assessing China's "common prosperity" campaign". Brookings Institution. Retrieved 11 August 2022.
  101. ^ Shen, Samuel; Ranganathan, Vidya (3 November 2021). "China stock pickers reshape portfolios on Xi's 'common prosperity'". Reuters. Retrieved 11 August 2022.
  102. ^ Brandt 2008, p. 3
  103. ^ China has socialist market economy in place (People's Daily Online, 2005).
  104. ^ Heston 2008, p. 28
  105. ^ Cai 2008, p. 184
  106. ^ Brandt 2008, p. 2
  107. ^ Perkins 2008, p. 834
  108. ^ a b Branstetter 2008, p. 668
  109. ^ a b Branstetter 2008, p. 669
  110. ^ Benjamin 2008, p. 730
  111. ^ Benjamin 2008, pp. 730–731
  112. ^ Benjamin 2008, p. 774
  113. ^ a b Weiyin, Zhang, "Completely bury Keynesianism" 2011-05-11 at the Wayback Machine, (February 17, 2009)
  114. ^ a b Huang 2008, p. 478
  115. ^ a b Huang 2008, p. 480
  116. ^ Weber, Isabella (2021). How China escaped shock therapy : the market reform debate. Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge. p. 164. ISBN 978-0-429-49012-5. OCLC 1228187814.
  117. ^ Huang 2008, pp. 481–482
  118. ^ Huang 2008, p. 483
  119. ^ Rawski 2008, p. 572
  120. ^ Perkins 2008, p. 862
  121. ^ a b Rawski 2008, p. 593
  122. ^ "China poised to be world’s largest auto market" 2016-12-31 at the Wayback Machine. NBC News. 2009-02-04.
  123. ^ Rawski 2008, p. 588
  124. ^ a b Brandt 2008, p. 13
  125. ^ Rawski 2008, p. 570
  126. ^ Branstetter 2008, pp. 635–638
  127. ^ Branstetter 2008, p. 655
  128. ^ Brandt 2008, pp. 1–3
  129. ^ Branstetter 2008, p. 656
  130. ^ Branstetter 2008, p. 676
  131. ^ Branstetter 2008, pp. 640–642
  132. ^ Haggard, Stevens et al (2008), 339
  133. ^ Branstetter 2008, p. 657
  134. ^ Branstetter 2008, pp. 658–659
  135. ^ Allen 2008, p. 522
  136. ^ Perkins 2008, p. 866
  137. ^ Allen 2008, p. 523
  138. ^ Allen 2008, p. 528
  139. ^ Allen 2008, p. 530
  140. ^ Allen 2008, p. 514
  141. ^ a b Allen 2008, p. 556
  142. ^ Xin Zhao and Russell W. Belk, "Politicizing Consumer Culture: Advertising's Appropriation of Political Ideology in China's Social Transition," Journal of Consumer Research (2008) 35#2 pp 231–244
  143. ^ Wong 2008, p. 431
  144. ^ Wong 2008, p. 440
  145. ^ Wong 2008, p. 434
  146. ^ Calhoun, Craig; Wasserstrom, Jeffrey N. (2003), "The Cultural Revolution and the Democracy Movement of 1989: Complexity in Historical Connections", in Law, Kam-yee (ed.), The Chinese cultural revolution reconsidered: beyond purge and holocaust, Palgrave Macmillan, p. 247, ISBN 978-0-333-73835-1, retrieved 2011-10-20
  147. ^ Brandt 2008, pp. 18–19
  148. ^ Kahn 1979, pp. 455
  149. ^ Ang, Yuen Yuen (May–June 2018). "Autocracy With Chinese Characteristics". Foreign Affairs.
  150. ^ Sharma, Shalendra D. (Winter–Spring 2007). . Global Dialogue. 9 (1–2). Archived from the original on 2013-05-13. Retrieved 2014-09-30.
  151. ^ "WTO | China – Member information". www.wto.org. Retrieved 2020-06-20.
  152. ^ Zhang, Jianping; Liu, Huan (2019-03-09). "改革开放40年:"引进来"与"走出去"". Qiushi (in Chinese). from the original on 2021-01-03. Retrieved 2020-06-19.
  153. ^ a b c d Yuan, Xiaobin. "发达国家对华援助"不手软"". NetEase (in Chinese). from the original on 2021-01-03. Retrieved 2020-06-18.
  154. ^ a b "中国还需要发达国家的政府援助吗?" (in Chinese). Phoenix Television. 2009-11-17. from the original on 2021-01-08. Retrieved 2020-06-18.
  155. ^ a b . www.foreignassistance.gov. Archived from the original on 2020-06-20. Retrieved 2020-06-18.
  156. ^ "Japan to discontinue development assistance projects for China: Taro Kono". The Japan Times. 2018-10-23. Retrieved 2020-06-18.
  157. ^ a b Lin, Chun (2006). The transformation of Chinese socialism. Durham [N.C.]: Duke University Press. p. 2. ISBN 978-0-8223-3785-0. OCLC 63178961.
  158. ^ Dorn, James A. (Fall 2002). "Economic Development and Freedom: The Legacy of Peter Bauer" (PDF). Cato Journal. Cato Institute. 22 (2). (PDF) from the original on 2014-10-06. Retrieved 2014-09-30.
  159. ^ Remnick, David (January–February 1997). "Can Russia Change?". Foreign Affairs. 76 (1): 35–49. doi:10.2307/20047908. JSTOR 20047908. from the original on 2014-04-14. Retrieved 2014-09-30.
  160. ^ Olson, Mancur (2000). Power and prosperity : outgrowing communist and capitalist dictatorships. New York: Basic Books. ISBN 978-0465051960.
  161. ^ Svejnar 2008, p. 68
  162. ^ Svejnar 2008, p. 74
  163. ^ Svejnar 2008, p. 76
  164. ^ Svejnar 2008, pp. 69–70
  165. ^ Svejnar 2008, p. 72
  166. ^ Naughton 2008, p. 96
  167. ^ a b Heston 2008, p. 37
  168. ^ Heston 2008, p. 46
  169. ^ Perkins 2008, p. 879
  170. ^ Perkins 2008, p. 865
  171. ^ a b "China's economic census uncovers more fake data". South China Morning Post. 2019-06-20. Retrieved 2021-05-20.
  172. ^ "Study Suggests That Local Chinese Officials Manipulate GDP". Yale University. 11 February 2020. from the original on 2020-04-03. Retrieved 2021-05-20.
  173. ^ Watts, Gordon (2019-10-18). "Fake figures cloud China's economic data". Asia Times. Retrieved 2021-05-20.
  174. ^ "China's GDP Growth Pace Was Inflated for Nine Years, Study Finds". Bloomberg.com. 8 March 2019. from the original on 2019-03-08. Retrieved 2021-05-20.
  175. ^ "Why China's dramatic economic recovery might not add up". The Guardian. 2020-10-25. Retrieved 2021-05-20.
  176. ^ Pham, Sherisse (2017-01-18). "Chinese province admits falsifying economic data for years". CNNMoney. Retrieved 2021-05-20.
  177. ^ Wàn, Jìng (30 October 2008). [The Lang-Gu debate: a debate that has not yet ended]. Hexun (in Chinese). Archived from the original on 23 July 2011.
  178. ^ "Each Country's Share of CO2 [sic] Emissions | Union of Concerned Scientists". www.ucsusa.org. Retrieved 2021-05-05.
  179. ^ Perkins 2008, pp. 870–871
  180. ^ Jayaram, Kripa; Kay, Chris; Murtaugh, Dan (14 June 2022). "China Reduced Air Pollution in 7 Years as Much as US Did in Three Decades". Bloomberg News. Retrieved 7 June 2023.
  181. ^ "China has Quickly and Sharply Reduced Pollution Since Enacting Strict Policies". EPIC. Retrieved 2023-06-07.
  182. ^ Drèze, J., and Sen, A., 1989. Hunger and Public Action, p. 209. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
  183. ^ Sullivan, Dylan; Moatsos, Michail; Hickel, Jason (2023). "Capitalist reforms and extreme poverty in China: Unprecedented progress or income deflation?". New Political Economy. 29: 1–21. doi:10.1080/13563467.2023.2217087. S2CID 259664228.
  184. ^ Moatsos, M., 2021. Global extreme poverty: present and past since 1820. In: OECD, ed. How was life? Vol. II: new perspectives on well-being and global inequality since 1820. Paris: OECD Publishing, 186–212.
  185. ^ Wang, Yuhua. . The Washington Post. ISSN 0190-8286. Archived from the original on 4 June 2019. Retrieved 2021-05-05.
  186. ^ He, Zengke (1 June 2000). "Corruption and anti-corruption in reform China". Communist and Post-Communist Studies. 33 (2): 243–270. doi:10.1016/S0967-067X(00)00006-4. ISSN 0967-067X.
  187. ^ Bird, Stella Yifan Xie and Mike (2020-07-17). "The $52 Trillion Bubble: China Grapples With Epic Property Boom". The Wall Street Journal. ISSN 0099-9660. Retrieved 2021-05-05.
  188. ^ Greenhalgh, Susan (2005). "Missile Science, Population Science: The Origins of China's One-Child Policy". The China Quarterly. 182 (182): 253–276. doi:10.1017/S0305741005000184. ISSN 0305-7410. JSTOR 20192474. S2CID 144640139.
  189. ^ Cai, Yong (2013-09-01). "China's New Demographic Reality: Learning from the 2010 Census". Population and Development Review. 39 (3): 371–396. doi:10.1111/j.1728-4457.2013.00608.x. ISSN 0098-7921. PMC 4302763. PMID 25620818.
  190. ^ Zhou, C. (3 Feb 2018). "A look inside the struggles and benefits of China's 'little emperor' generation". Australian Broadcasting Corporation. Retrieved 5 May 2021.
  191. ^ a b "How China's Demographic Time Bomb Threatens its Economy". Wharton Business. from the original on 2018-08-21. Retrieved 2021-05-05.
  192. ^ Pak, Jennifer (2020-10-09). "Cost of child rearing in China hinders baby boom". Marketplace. Retrieved 2021-05-05.
  193. ^ Myers, Steven Lee; Wu, Jin; Fu, Claire (2019-01-17). "China's Looming Crisis: A Shrinking Population". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 2021-05-05.
  194. ^ "Could China's population crisis be reaching a point of no return?". South China Morning Post. 2021-03-25. Retrieved 2021-05-05.

General and cited sources edit

  • Allen, Franklin; et al. (2008), "China's Financial system: Past, present and future", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press
  • Cardenal, Juan Pablo; Araújo, Heriberto (2011), La silenciosa conquista china (in Spanish), Barcelona: Crítica, ISBN 9788498922578
  • Benjamin, Dwayne; et al. (2008), "Income inequality during China's Economic Transition", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge university press
  • Brandt, Loren; et al. (2008), Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge university press
  • Branstetter, Lee; et al. (2008), "China's embrace of globalization", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
  • Cai, Fang; et al. (2008), "The Chinese labor market in the reform era", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge university press
  • Dillon, Michael. Deng Xiaoping: The Man Who Made Modern China (Bloomsbury Publishing, 2014).
  • Haggard, Stevens; et al. (2008), "The political economy of private-sector development in China", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge university press
  • Heston, Alan; et al. (2008), "China and Development economics", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge university press
  • Huang, Jikun; et al. (2008), "Agriculture in China's Development: Past Disappointments, Recent Successes, and Future Challenges", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge university press
  • Kahn, Herman (24 May 1979). World Economic Development: 1979 And Beyond. Avalon Publishing. ISBN 978-0-89158-392-9.
  • Kau, Michael Y. M. China in the Era of Deng Xiaoping: A Decade of Reform (Routledge, 2016).
  • Naughton, Barry; et al. (2008), "A Political Economy of China's Economic Transitionin China's Great Transformation", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge university press
  • Perkins, Dwight; et al. (2008), "Forecasting China's growth to 2025", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge university press
  • Rawski, G. Thomas; et al. (2008), "China's Industrial Development", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge university press
  • Svejnar, Jan; et al. (2008), "China in light of other transition economies", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge university press
  • Vogel, Ezra F. Deng Xiaoping and the Transformation of China (Harvard UP, 2011).
  • Walder, Andrew G. (2015). China Under Mao. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-05815-6.
  • Wong, P.W. Christine; et al. (2008), "China's Fiscal system: a work in progress", in Brandt, Loren; Rawski, G. Thomas (eds.), China's Great Transformation, Cambridge: Cambridge university press
  • Zhao, Xin; Russell W. Belk (August 2008). "Politicizing Consumer Culture: Advertising's Appropriation of Political Ideology in China's Social Transition". Journal of Consumer Research. 35 (2): 231–244. doi:10.1086/588747. ISSN 0093-5301.

Further reading edit

  • Gewirtz, Julian. 2022. Never Turn Back: China and the Forbidden History of the 1980s. Belknap Press.

External links edit

  •   Quotations related to Chinese economic reform at Wikiquote

chinese, economic, reform, chinese, economic, miracle, also, known, domestically, reform, opening, chinese, 改革开放, pinyin, gǎigé, kāifàng, refers, variety, economic, reforms, termed, socialism, with, chinese, characteristics, socialist, market, economy, people,. The Chinese economic reform or Chinese economic miracle 1 2 also known domestically as reform and opening up Chinese 改革开放 pinyin Gǎige kaifang refers to a variety of economic reforms termed socialism with Chinese characteristics and socialist market economy in the People s Republic of China PRC that began in the late 20th century Guided by Deng Xiaoping who is often credited as the General Architect the reforms were launched by reformists within the ruling Chinese Communist Party CCP on December 18 1978 during the Boluan Fanzheng period 3 4 5 6 Chinese economic reformSimplified Chinese改革开放Traditional Chinese改革開放Literal meaning Reform and Opening Up TranscriptionsStandard MandarinHanyu PinyinGǎige kaifangWade GilesKai3 ko2 k ai1 fang4IPA ka ɪkɤ kʰa ɪfa ŋ Yue CantoneseYale RomanizationGoigaak hōifongJyutpingGoi2 gaak3 hoi1 fong3IPA kɔːi kaːk hɔːi fɔːŋ Contents 1 Overview 2 Causes of the reforms 2 1 Origin 2 2 1979 1984 2 3 1984 1993 2 4 1993 2005 2 5 2005 2012 2 6 2012 2020 2 7 2020 present 3 Effects of the reforms 3 1 Economic performance 3 2 Impact on world growth 3 3 Effect on inequality 4 Reforms in specific sectors 4 1 Agriculture 4 2 Industry 4 3 Trade and foreign investment 4 4 Services 4 5 Government finances 5 Academic studies 5 1 Reasons for success 5 2 Comparison to other developing economies 5 3 Criticism and development issues 6 See also 7 References 7 1 Citations 7 2 General and cited sources 8 Further reading 9 External linksOverview editThe reforms briefly went into stagnation after the 1989 Tiananmen Square protests and massacre but were revived after Deng Xiaoping s southern tour in 1992 The reforms led to significant economic growth for China within the successive decades in 2010 China overtook Japan as the world s second largest economy by nominal GDP 7 8 before overtaking the United States in 2016 as the world s largest economy by GDP PPP 9 The CCP carried out the market reforms in two stages The first stage in the late 1970s and early 1980s involved the de collectivization of agriculture the opening up of the country to foreign investment and permission for entrepreneurs to start businesses However a large percentage of industries remained state owned The second stage of reform in the late 1980s and 1990s involved the privatization and contracting out of much state owned industry The 1985 lifting of price controls 10 was a major reform and the lifting of protectionist policies and regulations soon followed although state monopolies in the commanding heights of the economy such as banking and petroleum remained In 2001 China joined the World Trade Organization WTO Not long after the private sector grew remarkably accounting for as much as 70 percent of China s gross domestic product GDP by 2005 11 From 1978 until 2013 unprecedented growth occurred with the economy increasing by 9 5 a year Hu Jintao and Wen Jiabao s administration took a more conservative approach towards reforms regulated and controlled the economy more heavily after 2005 reversing some reforms 12 On the other hand a parallel set of political reforms were launched by Deng in 1980 which also inspired the then Soviet Union s Glasnost and Perestroika but eventually ended in 1989 due to the crackdown on Tiananmen Square protests halting further political liberalization Causes of the reforms editOrigin edit Before Deng Xiaoping s reforms China s economy suffered due to centrally planned policies such as the Great Leap Forward and the Cultural Revolution resulting in stagnation inefficiency and poverty 13 Prior to the reforms the Chinese economy was dominated by state ownership and central planning From 1950 to 1973 Chinese real GDP per capita grew at a rate of 2 9 per year on average albeit with major fluctuations 14 This placed it near the middle of the Asian nations during the same period 15 with neighboring countries such as Japan South Korea Singapore and then rival Chiang Kai shek s Republic of China ROC outstripping mainland China s rate of growth 16 Starting in 1970 the economy entered into a period of stagnation 17 and after the death of Mao Zedong the CCP leadership decided to abandon Maoism and turn to market oriented reforms to salvage the stagnant economy 18 In September 1976 Mao Zedong died and in October Hua Guofeng together with Ye Jianying and Wang Dongxing arrested the Gang of Four putting an end to the Cultural Revolution Hua s break with Cultural Revolution era economic policies were consistent with the 1975 reform agenda of Deng Xiaoping 19 Hua made national economic development a matter of the highest priority and emphasized the need to achieve liberation of productive forces 19 He combined Soviet style big push industrialization with an opening up to the capitalist world and under his leadership China opened its first Special Economic Zone and launched major efforts to attract foreign direct investment 19 Economic reforms began in earnest during the Boluan Fanzheng period especially after Deng and his reformist allies rose to power with Deng replacing Hua Guofeng as the paramount leader in December 1978 By the time Deng took power there was widespread support among the elite for economic reforms 20 From 1978 to 1992 Deng described reform and opening up as a large scale experiment requiring thorough experimentation in practice instead of textbook knowledge 21 65 As the de facto leader Deng s policies faced opposition from party conservatives but were extremely successful in increasing the country s wealth Major reforms including rural decollectivization SOE reform and rural health care reform almost always began first as decentralized local experiments subject to intervention from high level Communist Party officials before they were more widely adopted 22 6 1979 1984 edit See also History of the People s Republic of China Political reforms nbsp The image of Deng Xiaoping in Shenzhen Guangdong one of the first special economic zones approved by Deng in 1979 In 1979 Deng Xiaoping emphasized the goal of Four Modernizations and further proposed the idea of xiaokang or moderately prosperous society 23 24 25 The achievements of Lee Kuan Yew to create an economic success in Singapore had a profound effect on the CCP leadership in China Leaders in China made a major effort especially under Deng Xiaoping to emulate his policies of economic growth entrepreneurship and subtle suppression of dissent Over the years more than 22 000 Chinese officials were sent to Singapore to study its methods 26 Generally reforms in this period started with local experiments that were adopted and expanded elsewhere once their success had been demonstrated 27 127 Officials generally faced few penalties for experimenting and failing and those who developed successful programs received nation wide praise and recognition 27 127 The bottom up approach of the reforms promoted by Deng in contrast to the top down approach of the Perestroika in the Soviet Union is considered an important factor contributing to the success of China s economic transition 28 The first reforms began in agriculture By the late 1970s food supplies and production had become so deficient that government officials were warning that China was about to repeat the disaster of 1959 the famines which killed tens of millions during the Great Leap Forward 29 Deng responded by decollectivizing agriculture and emphasizing the household responsibility system which divided the land of the People s communes into private plots Under the new policy peasants were able to exercise formal control of their land as long as they sold a contracted portion of their crops to the government 30 This move increased agricultural production by 25 percent between 1975 and 1985 setting a precedent for privatizing other parts of the economy 30 Reforms were also implemented in urban industry to increase productivity A dual price system was introduced in which State owned enterprise reform 1979 state owned industries were allowed to sell any production above the plan quota and commodities were sold at both plan and market prices allowing citizens to avoid the shortages of the Maoist era Moreover the adoption of Industrial Responsibility System 1980s further promote the development of state owned enterprise by allowing individuals or groups to manage the enterprise by contract Private businesses were allowed to operate for the first time since the CCP takeover and they gradually began to make up a greater percentage of industrial output 31 Price flexibility was also increased expanding the service sector 32 At the same time in December 1978 Deng announced a new policy the Open Door Policy to open the door to foreign businesses that wanted to set up in China 33 34 For the first time since the Kuomintang era the country was opened to foreign investment Deng created a series of Special Economic Zones including Shenzhen Zhuhai and Xiamen for foreign investment that were relatively free of the bureaucratic regulations and interventions that hampered economic growth These regions became engines of growth for the national economy 32 On January 31 1979 the Shekou Industrial Zone of Shenzhen was founded becoming the first experimental area in China to open up 35 36 In July 1979 China adopted its first Law on Joint Venture Using Chinese and Foreign Investment 37 This law was effective in helping to attract and absorb foreign technology and capital from advanced countries like the United States facilitated China s exports to such countries and thereby contributed to China s subsequent rapid economic growth 37 Under the leadership of Yuan Geng the Shekou model of development was gradually formed embodied in its famous slogan Time is Money Efficiency is Life which then widely spread to other parts of China 35 38 In January 1984 Deng Xiaoping made his first inspection tour to Shenzhen and Zhuhai praising the Shenzhen speed of development as well as the success of the special economics zones 39 40 nbsp Hu Yaobang then General Secretary of CCP played an important role in implementing the reforms together with Zhao Ziyang then Premier of China Besides Deng Xiaoping himself important high ranking reformists who helped carry out the reforms include Hu Yaobang then General Secretary of Chinese Communist Party and Zhao Ziyang then Premier of the People s Republic of China 41 42 Other leaders who favored Deng s reforms include Xi Zhongxun the father of Xi Jinping Wan Li Hu Qili and others 43 44 45 Another influential leader was Chen Yun regarded by some as the second most powerful person in China after Deng with more conservative ideology of the reforms 46 47 48 Though Deng Xiaoping is credited as the architect of modern China s economic reforms Chen was more directly involved in the details of its planning and construction and led a force that opposed many of the reforms from Deng s side 47 49 The two sides struggled over the general direction of the reforms until Chen died in 1995 47 48 49 A key feature of Chen s ideas was to use the market to allocate resources within the scope of an overall plan Some reforms of the early 1980s were in effect the implementation of a program that Chen had outlined in the mid 1950s Chen called this the birdcage economy 鸟笼经济 鳥籠經濟 50 51 According to Chen the cage is the plan and it may be large or small But within the cage the bird the economy is free to fly as he wishes 47 51 Chen and some other conservative leaders including Li Xiannian never visited Shenzhen the leading special economic zone championed by Deng 51 1984 1993 edit See also 1986 Chinese student demonstrations 1989 Tiananmen Square protests and massacre and Deng Xiaoping s southern tour nbsp Shenzhen one of the first special economic zones of China and the Silicon Valley of China 52 53 54 55 Notable high tech companies such as Huawei ZTE and Konka were all founded in Shenzhen in the 1980s In October 1984 the Party adopted its Decision on the Reform of the Economic System marking a major shift in the thinking of Chinese policymakers with regard to market mechanisms 56 39 40 The Decision acknowledged that a planned economy was not the only way to develop socialism and that prior policies restricting the commodity economy had hindered socialist development 56 40 After the Decision reform focused on building a socialist planned commodity economy with Chinese characteristics 56 40 Controls on private businesses and government intervention continued to decrease notably in the agrifood sector which saw relaxation of price controls in 1985 10 and the establishment of the household responsibility system and there was small scale privatization of state enterprises which had become unviable A notable development was the decentralization of state control leaving local provincial leaders to experiment with ways to increase economic growth and privatize the state sector 57 Township and village enterprises firms nominally owned by local governments but effectively private began to gain market share at the expense of the state sector 58 With the help of Yuan Geng the first joint stock commercial bank in China the China Merchants Bank and the first joint stock insurance company in China the Ping An Insurance were both established in Shekou In May 1984 fourteen coastal cities in China including Shanghai Guangzhou and Tianjin were named Open Coastal Cities 沿海开放城市 59 60 A significant economic debate during this period concerned the approach to price liberalization and whether China should adopt an approach consistent with shock therapy sudden price liberalization or a more gradual approach 61 But in 1986 the latter approach won out 61 Confronted with the diverse authoritative warnings about the unforeseeable risks of imposing the shock of price reform and the uncertainty about its benefits Premier Zhao Ziyang and the leadership ultimately rejected shock price reform 61 Zhao had accepted the argument that the basic concern in economic reform was energizing enterprises 61 By late summer what started under the rubric of coordinated comprehensive package reform had been diluted to an adjustment in the price of steel although its price was both important had carried symbolic weight as well as partial tax and financial reform 61 Radical price reform again became a focus in 1988 and this time led to spiraling inflation the first time it had done so since the 1940s as well as a backlash that included local protests bank runs and panic buying 62 The Chinese leadership halted these price liberalization plans in fall 1988 and instead focused on austerity price reform and retrenchment 62 nbsp The slogan Time is Money Efficiency is Life from Shekou Shenzhen representing the Shenzhen speed Corruption and increased inflation increased discontent contributing to the 1989 Tiananmen Square protests and massacre and a conservative backlash after that event which ousted several key reformers and threatened to reverse many of Deng s reforms 63 The events of 1988 and 1989 led to the imprisonment or exile of many reformist officials 62 However Deng stood by his reforms and in 1992 he affirmed the need to continue reforms in his southern tour 64 Thanks to his encouragement in November 1990 the Shanghai Stock Exchange was reopened after being closed by Mao 40 years earlier while the Shenzhen Stock Exchange was also founded in December 1990 65 66 In contrast to the approach of Deng conservative elders led by Chen Yun called to strike a balance between too much laissez faire market economy and retaining state control over key areas of the economy Chen Yun helped preserve the economy by preventing policies that would have damaged the interests of special interest groups in the government bureaucracy 64 Although the economy grew quickly during this period economic troubles in the inefficient state sector increased Heavy losses had to be made up by state revenues and acted as a drain upon the economy 67 Inflation became problematic in 1985 1988 and 1992 63 Privatizations began to accelerate after 1992 and the private sector grew as a percentage of GDP China s government slowly expanded recognition of the private economy first as a complement to the state sector 1988 and then as an important component 1999 of the socialist market economy 68 1993 2005 edit nbsp The Lujiazui financial district of Pudong Shanghai the financial and commercial hub of modern China nbsp A market in Kashgar in 1992 with slogans of Insist reform and opening up an alternative rendering of insisting Chinese economic reform which was well underway at the time In the 1990s Deng allowed many radical reforms to be carried out In 1993 the National People s Congress adopted the landmark Corporation Law 69 It provides that in state owned enterprises the state is no more than an investor and controller of stock and assets 69 Pursuant to the Corporation Law private and foreign investment in such enterprises must be below 49 69 The law also permitted state firms to declare bankruptcy in the event of business failure 69 In the beginning Chen supported Deng carried out and implemented many of the influential reforms that made a generation of Chinese richer But later Chen realized that the state still needed an active iron hand involvement in the market to prevent the private sector from becoming untamable Chen s criticism of Deng s later economic reforms was widely influential within the CCP and was reflected in the policies of China s leaders after Deng Chen s theories supported the efforts of Jiang Zemin and Hu Jintao to use state power to provide boundaries for the operation of the market and to mediate the damage that capitalism can do to those who find it difficult to benefit from the free market Chen s notion of the CPC as a ruling party was central to the redefinition of the role of the Party in Jiang Zemin s Three Represents In 2005 on the occasion of the hundredth anniversary of Chen s birth the Party press published over the course of several weeks the proceedings of a symposium discussing Chen s contributions to CCP history theory and practice 64 Although Deng died in 1997 reforms continued under his handpicked successors Jiang Zemin and Zhu Rongji who were ardent reformers who also abided by Chen Yun advice to keep the reforms steady and keep the state still in charge of key areas In 1997 and 1998 large scale privatization occurred in which all state enterprises except a few large monopolies were liquidated and their assets sold to private investors Between 2001 and 2004 the number of state owned enterprises decreased by 48 percent 58 During the same period Jiang and Zhu also reduced tariffs trade barriers and regulations reformed the banking system dismantled much of the Mao era social welfare system forced the Chinese army PLA to divest itself of military run businesses 70 reduced inflation and joined the World Trade Organization These moves invoked discontent among some groups especially laid off workers of state enterprises that had been privatized 71 The domestic private sector first exceeded 50 of GDP in 2005 and has further expanded since Also in 1999 China was able to surpass Japan as the largest economy in Asia by purchasing power parity PPP values 72 However some state monopolies still remained such as in petroleum and banking 73 2005 2012 edit CCP general secretary Hu Jintao and premier Wen Jiabao took a more conservative approach towards reforms and began to reverse some of Deng Xiaoping s reforms in 2005 Observers note that the government adopted more egalitarian and populist policies 74 It increased subsidies and control over the health care sector 75 increased funding for education halted privatization 12 and adopted a loose monetary policy which led to the formation of a U S style property bubble in which property prices tripled 76 The privileged state sector was the primary recipient of government investment which under the new administration promoted the rise of large national champions which could compete with large foreign corporations 12 Nevertheless the share of SOEs in the total number of companies have continued to fall dropping to 5 though their share of total output remained at 26 Exchange rates for the yuan were also liberalized and the peg to the U S dollar was broken leading the yuan to rise by 31 against the dollar from 2005 to 2012 77 China s economic growth has averaged around 10 under Hu while the economy surpassed the United Kingdom France Germany and Japan 78 77 2012 2020 edit Under CCP general secretary Xi Jinping and his administration the CCP has sought numerous reforms with the Third Plenum of the 18th Central Committee announcing that market forces would begin to play a decisive role in allocating resources 79 Xi launched the Shanghai Free Trade Zone in August 2013 seen as part of the reforms 80 He has additionally voiced support for SOEs 81 82 and under him at least 288 firms have revised their corporate charters by 2017 to allow the CCP greater influence in corporate management and to reflect the party line 83 This trend also includes Hong Kong listed firms who have traditionally downplayed their party links but are now redrafting bylaws to formally establish party committees that previously existed only at the group level 84 In other dimensions according to Ray Dalio the Xi era has also been marked by economic opening greater market oriented decision making and discontinuation of support for poorly managed state owned enterprises 85 Xi has increased the power of CCP bodies in economic decision making decreasing the influence of the State Council and the premier 86 His administration made it easier for banks to issue mortgages increased foreign participation in the bond market and increased the national currency renminbi s global role helping it to join IMF s basket of special drawing right 87 His administration has also pursued a debt deleveraging campaign seeking to slow and cut the unsustainable amount of debt China has accrued during its economic growth 88 Xi s administration has also reoriented the economy to increase self reliance and accordingly launched two campaigns Made in China 2025 and China Standards 2035 which have sought to scale up and displace US dominance in various high tech sectors 85 though publicly China de emphasized these plans due to the outbreak of a trade war with the U S in 2018 89 This is alongside more aggressive pursuit of trade policies in line with an outlook that sees China move towards taking a more active role in writing the rules of trade Some analysts have also added that the reform era has been scaled down significantly during the leadership of Xi when the reformists lost power 90 91 92 citing that Xi has reasserted state control over different aspects of Chinese society 93 including the economy 14 94 95 2020 present edit Main article 2020 2021 Xi Jinping Administration reform spree Xi has circulated a policy called dual circulation meaning reorienting the economy towards domestic consumption while remaining open to foreign trade and investment 96 Since 2021 his administration has formulated the three red lines policy that aimed to deleverage the heavily indebted property sector 97 In September 2020 the CCP announced that it would strengthen United Front work in the private sector by establishing more party committees in the regional federations of industry and commerce FIC and by arranging a special liaison between FIC and the CCP 98 Since 2021 Xi has promoted the term common prosperity a term which he defined as an essential requirement of socialism described as affluence for all and said entailed reasonable adjustments to excess incomes 99 100 Common prosperity has been used as the justification for large scale crackdowns and regulations towards the perceived excesses of several sectors most prominently tech and tutoring industries 101 Effects of the reforms editEconomic performance edit nbsp China s nominal GDP trend from 1952 to 2015 Note the rapid increase since reform in the late 1970s The success of China s economic policies and the manner of their implementation resulted in immense changes in Chinese society in the last 40 years including greatly decreased poverty while both average incomes and income inequality have increased leading to a backlash led by the more ideologically pure New Left Scholars have debated the reason for the success of the Chinese dual track economy and have compared it to attempts to reform socialism in the Eastern Bloc and the Soviet Union as well as to the growth of other developing economies Additionally these series of reforms have led to China s rise as a great power and a shift of international geopolitical interests towards China especially in matters relating to the ambiguous political status of Taiwan Some analysts have also added that the reform era has been scaled down significantly during the leadership of current CCP General Secretary Xi Jinping when the reformists lost power 90 91 92 citing that Xi has reasserted state control over different aspects of Chinese society 93 including the economy 14 94 95 After three decades of reform China s economy experienced one of the world s biggest booms Agriculture and light industry have largely been privatized while the state still retains control over some heavy industries Despite the dominance of state ownership in finance telecommunications petroleum and other important sectors of the economy private entrepreneurs continue to expand into sectors formerly reserved for public enterprise Prices have also been liberalized 102 China s economic growth since the reform has been very rapid exceeding the East Asian Tigers Since the beginning of Deng Xiaoping s reforms China s GDP has risen tenfold 103 The increase in total factor productivity TFP was the most important factor with productivity accounting for 40 1 of the GDP increase compared with a decline of 13 2 for the period 1957 to 1978 the height of Maoist policies For the period 1978 2005 Chinese GDP per capita increased from 2 7 to 15 7 of U S GDP per capita and from 53 7 to 188 5 of Indian GDP per capita Per capita incomes grew at 6 6 a year 104 Average wages rose sixfold between 1978 and 2005 105 while absolute poverty declined from 41 of the population to 5 from 1978 to 2001 106 Some scholars believed that China s economic growth has been understated due to large sectors of the economy not being counted 107 Impact on world growth edit China is widely seen as an engine of world and regional growth 108 Surges in Chinese demand account for 50 44 and 66 percent of export growth of the Hong Kong SAR of China Japan and Taiwan respectively and China s trade deficit with the rest of East Asia helped to revive the economies of Japan and Southeast Asia 108 Asian leaders view China s economic growth as an engine of growth for all Asia 109 Effect on inequality edit See also Social welfare in China nbsp Gini coefficient of national income distribution around the world dark green lt 0 25 red gt 0 60 Although the economic reforms has caused significant economic growth in China it has also caused increased inequality resulting in backlash and an attempt at pushing back the reforms by the Chinese New Left faction Despite rapid economic growth which has virtually eliminated poverty in urban China and reduced it greatly in rural regions and the fact that living standards for everyone in China have drastically increased in comparison to the pre reform era the Gini coefficient of China is estimated to be above 0 45 comparable to some Latin American countries such as Argentina and Mexico as well as the United States 110 Increased inequality is attributed to the gradual withdrawal of the welfare state system in China and differences between coastal and interior provinces the latter being burdened by a larger state sector 111 Some Western scholars have suggested that reviving the welfare state and instituting a re distributive income tax system is needed to relieve inequality 112 while some Chinese economists have suggested that privatizing state monopolies and distributing the proceeds to the population can reduce inequality 113 Reforms in specific sectors editAgriculture edit nbsp Production of wheat from 1961 to 2004 Data from FAO year 2005 Y axis Production in metric ton During the pre reform period Chinese agricultural performance was extremely poor and food shortages were common 114 After Deng Xiaoping implemented the household responsibility system agricultural output increased by 8 2 a year compared with 2 7 in the pre reform period despite a decrease in the area of land used 114 Food prices fell nearly 50 while agricultural incomes rose 115 Zhao Ziyang wrote in his memoirs that in the years following the household contracting system the energy that was unleashed was magical beyond what anyone could have imagined A problem thought to be unsolvable had worked itself out in just a few years time B y 1984 farmers actually had more grain than they could sell The state grain storehouses were stacked full from the annual procurement program 116 A fundamental transformation was the economy s growing adoption of cash crops instead of just growing rice and grain 115 Vegetable and meat production increased to the point that Chinese agricultural production was adding the equivalent of California s vegetable industry every two years Growth in the sector slowed after 1984 with agriculture falling from 40 of GDP to 16 however increases in agricultural productivity allowed workers to be released for work in industry and services while simultaneously increasing agricultural production 117 Trade in agriculture was also liberalized and China became an exporter of food a great contrast to its previous famines and shortages 118 Industry edit In the pre reform period industry was largely stagnant and the socialist system presented few incentives for improvements in quality and productivity With the introduction of the dual price system and greater autonomy for enterprise managers productivity increased greatly in the early 1980s 119 Foreign enterprises and newly formed Township and Village Enterprises owned by local government and often de facto private firms competed successfully with state owned enterprises By the 1990s large scale privatizations reduced the market share of both the Township and Village Enterprises and state owned enterprises and increased the private sector s market share The state sector s share of industrial output dropped from 81 in 1980 to 15 in 2005 120 Foreign capital controls much of Chinese industry and plays an important role 58 From virtually an industrial backwater in 1978 China is now the world s biggest producer of concrete steel ships and textiles and has the world s largest automobile market Chinese steel output quadrupled between 1980 and 2000 and from 2000 to 2006 rose from 128 5 million tons to 418 8 million tons one third of global production 121 Labor productivity at some Chinese steel firms exceeds Western productivity 121 From 1975 to 1992 China s automobile production rose from 139 800 to 1 1 million rising to 9 35 million in 2008 122 Light industries such as textiles saw an even greater increase due to reduced government interference Chinese textile exports increased from 4 6 of world exports in 1980 to 24 1 in 2005 Textile output increased 18 fold over the same period 123 This increase in production is largely the result of the removal of barriers to entry and increased competition the number of industrial firms rose from 377 300 in 1980 to nearly 8 million in 1990 and 1996 the 2004 economic census which excluded enterprises with annual sales below RMB 5 million counted 1 33 million manufacturing firms with Jiangsu and Zhejiang reporting more firms than the nationwide total for 1980 124 Compared to other East Asian industrial growth spurts China s industrial performance exceeded Japan s but remained behind South Korea and Taiwan s economies 125 Trade and foreign investment edit This section needs to be updated The reason given is China United States trade war Please help update this article to reflect recent events or newly available information October 2020 nbsp Global distribution of Chinese exports in 2006 as a percentage of the top marketSome scholars assert that China has maintained a high degree of openness that is unusual among the other large and populous nations dubious discuss with competition from foreign goods in almost every sector of the economy Foreign investment helped to greatly increase quality knowledge and standards especially in heavy industry China s experience supports the assertion that globalization greatly increases wealth for poor countries 124 Throughout the reform period the government reduced tariffs and other trade barriers with the overall tariff rate falling from 56 to 15 By 2001 less than 40 of imports were subject to tariffs and only 9 percent of import were subject to licensing and import quotas Even during the early reform era protectionist policies were often circumvented by smuggling 126 When China joined the WTO it agreed to considerably harsher conditions than other developing countries 127 Trade has increased from under 10 of GDP to 64 of GDP over the same period 128 China is considered the most open large country by 2005 China s average statutory tariff on industrial products was 8 9 The average was 30 9 for Argentina 27 0 for Brazil 32 4 for India and 36 9 for Indonesia 129 China s trade surplus is considered by some in the United States as threatening American jobs In the 2000s the Bush administration pursued protectionist policies such as tariffs and quotas to limit the import of Chinese goods Some scholars argue that China s growing trade surplus is the result of industries in more developed Asian countries moving to China and not a new phenomenon 109 China s trade policy which allows producers to avoid paying the Value Added Tax VAT for exports and undervaluation of the currency since 2002 has resulted in an overdeveloped export sector and distortion of the economy overall a result that could hamper future growth 130 Foreign investment was also liberalized upon Deng s ascension Special Economic Zones SEZs were created in the early 1980s to attract foreign capital by exempting them from taxes and regulations This experiment was successful and SEZs were expanded to cover the whole Chinese coast Although FDI fell briefly after the 1989 student protests it increased again to 160 billion by 2004 131 Services edit nbsp Shanghai Stock Exchange nbsp Shenzhen Stock ExchangeIn the 1990s the financial sector was liberalized 132 After China joined the World Trade Organization WTO the service sector was considerably liberalized and foreign investment was allowed restrictions on retail wholesale and distribution ended 133 Banking financial services insurance and telecommunications were also opened up to foreign investment 134 China s banking sector is dominated by four large state owned banks which are largely inefficient and monopolistic 135 China s largest bank ICBC is the largest bank in the world The financial sector is widely seen as a drag on the economy due to the inefficient state management 136 Non performing loans mostly made to local governments and unprofitable state owned enterprises for political purposes 137 especially the political goal of keeping unemployment low are a big drain on the financial system and economy reaching over 22 of GDP by 2000 with a drop to 6 3 by 2006 due to government recapitalization of these banks In 2006 the total amount of non performing loans was estimated at 160 billion 138 Observers recommend privatization of the banking system to solve this problem a move that was partially carried out when the four banks were floated on the stock market 139 China s financial markets the Shanghai Stock Exchange and Shenzhen Stock Exchange are relatively ineffective at raising capital as they comprise only 11 of GDP 140 Due to the weakness of the banks firms raise most of their capital through an informal nonstandard financial sector developed during the 1980s and 1990s consisting largely of underground businesses and private banks 141 Internal finance is the most important method successful firms use to fund their activities 141 By the 1980s much emphasis was placed on the role of advertising in meeting the modernization goals being promoted by Deng Lip service was still paid to old Maoist ideals of egalitarianism but it did not inhibit the growth of consumerism 142 Government finances edit In the pre reform era government was funded by profits from state owned enterprises much like the Soviet Union 143 As the state sector fell in importance and profitability government revenues especially that of the central government in Beijing fell substantially and the government relied on a confused system of inventory taxes Government revenues fell from 35 of GDP to 11 of GDP in the mid 1990s excluding revenue from state owned enterprises with the central government s budget at just 3 of GDP 144 The tax system was reformed in 1994 when inventory taxes were unified into a single VAT of 17 on all manufacturing repair and assembly activities and an excise tax on 11 items with the VAT becoming the main income source accounting for half of government revenue The 1994 reform also increased the central government s share of revenues increasing it to 9 of GDP 145 Academic studies editReasons for success edit See also Foreign aid to China and China model nbsp Discussion of China s Next Global Agenda during the World Economic Forum 2013 Scholars have proposed a number of theories to explain China s successful transition from a planned to a socialist market economy This occurred despite unfavorable factors such as the troublesome legacies of socialism considerable erosion of the work ethic decades of anti market propaganda and the lost generation whose education disintegrated amid the disruption of the Cultural Revolution 146 One notable theory is that decentralization of state authority allowed local leaders to experiment with various ways to privatize the state sector and energize the economy 57 Although Deng was not the originator of many of the reforms he approved them Another theory focuses on internal incentives within the Chinese government in which officials presiding over areas of high economic growth were more likely to be promoted This made local and provincial governments hungry for investment who competed to reduce regulations and barriers to investment to boost both economic growth and their careers Such reforms were possible because Deng cultivated pro market followers in the government 147 Herman Kahn argued that Confucian ethic was playing a similar but more spectacular role in the modernization of East Asia than the Protestant ethic played in Europe 148 Taken together Yuen Yuen Ang argues in Foreign Affairs that political reforms took place with economic reforms under Deng except the former did not take Western forms She writes To be sure Deng s reforms emphasized brute capital accumulation rather than holistic development which led to environmental degradation inequality and other social problems Still they undoubtedly kicked China s growth machine into gear by making the bureaucracy results oriented fiercely competitive and responsive to business needs qualities that are normally associated with democracies But this only applies to the Deng era Ang notes that since 2012 when Xi Jinping took over the new leader has reversed Deng s political reforms and limits to power just as political freedoms have become imperative for continued economic growth 149 nbsp Roberto Azevedo Director General of WTO met with China s Minister of Commerce Gao Hucheng in Qingdao 2014 China s success is also due to the export led growth strategy used successfully by the Four Asian Tigers beginning with Japan in the 1960s 1970s and other newly industrialized countries 150 In 2001 China joined the World Trade Organization WTO 151 As of 2006 over 400 of the Fortune 500 companies had entered the Chinese market while at the same time a considerable number of Chinese companies had opened their markets outside of China 152 Foreign aids to China including those from Hong Kong Macau and Taiwan also played an important role 153 154 155 Since the beginning of opening China has received a significant amount of aid from major developed countries such as the United States Japan Germany France and the United Kingdom 153 154 For instance through its Official Development Assistance ODA Japan had offered China various forms of assistance worth 3 65 trillion Yen as of 2018 153 156 On the other hand the assistance from the U S reached a total of US 556 million as of 2012 and has helped Tibetan communities improve livelihoods promote sustainable development and environmental conservation and preserve cultural traditions also supports targeted programs that strengthen cooperation on combatting the spread of HIV AIDS and other pandemic and emerging diseases as well as rule of law programs 153 155 In contrast to the neoliberal view which emphasizes benefits from decentralization increased privatization and globalization Professor Lin Chun concludes that studies have demonstrated pre reform period factors that are at least as compelling factors in China s success 157 Those factors include strong human capital accumulated through decades of state investments in basic needs including health care and public education state and rural collective ownership of land the public sector s retaining of strategic industries government sponsorship of trade and technology transfers and public spending 157 The collapse of the Soviet Bloc and centrally planned economies in 1989 provided renewed impetus for China to further reform its economy through different policies to avoid a similar fate 158 China also wanted to avoid the Russian ad hoc experiments with market capitalism under Boris Yeltsin resulting in the rise of powerful oligarchs corruption and the loss of state revenue which exacerbated economic disparity 159 The Cultural Revolution contributed to China s economic growth in long run According to Mancur Olson the Cultural Revolution attacked the very administrators and managers on which Chinese economy depended and the immediate result was instability and administrative chaos in short run A longer run result was that there were not nearly as many well entrenched interest groups as in the Soviet Union and the Eastern Bloc so when Deng Xiaoping and the other pragmatists take power there were few interest groups whose lobbying could undermine Deng s market oriented reforms because the Cultural Revolution had destroyed the narrowly entrenched interests with a stake in the status quo 160 Comparison to other developing economies edit nbsp Development trends of Chinese and Indian GDP 1950 2010 China s transition from a planned economy to a socialist market economy has often been compared with economies in Eastern Europe that are undergoing a similar transition China s performance has been praised for avoiding the major shocks and inflation that plagued the Eastern Bloc 161 The Eastern bloc economies saw declines varying from 13 to 65 in GDP at the beginning of reforms while Chinese growth has been very strong since the beginning of reform 162 China also managed to avoid the hyperinflation of 200 to 1 000 that Eastern Europe experienced 163 This success is attributed to the gradualist and decentralized approach of the Chinese government which allowed market institutions to develop to the point where they could replace state planning This contrasts with the big bang approach of Eastern Europe where the state owned sector was rapidly privatized with employee buyouts but retained much of the earlier inefficient management 164 Other factors thought to account for the differences are the greater urbanization of the CIS economies and differences in social welfare and other institutions 165 Another argument is that in the Eastern European economies political change is sometimes seen to have made gradualist reforms impossible so the shocks and inflation were unavoidable 166 China s economic growth has been compared with other developing countries such as Brazil Mexico and India GDP growth in China outstrips all other developing countries with only India after 1990 coming close to China s experience 167 Scholars believe that high rates of investments especially increases in capital invested per worker have contributed to China s superior economic performance 167 China s relatively free economy with less government intervention and regulation is cited by scholars as an important factor in China s superior performance compared to other developing countries 168 Criticism and development issues edit nbsp Air pollution has become a major environmental issue in China resulting from the economic development The picture shows thick haze in Lujiazui of Shanghai in 2011 nbsp Global CO2 gas emissions by country 2015 The government retains monopolies in several sectors such as petroleum and banking The recent reversal of some reforms have left some observers dubbing 2008 the third anniversary of the end of reforms 12 Nevertheless observers who believe that China s economy can continue growing at rates of 6 8 percent until 2025 169 though a reduction in state intervention is considered by some to be necessary for sustained growth 170 It has been reported including by the National Bureau of Statistics that over the years that the GDP figures and other economic data from local Chinese governments may be inflated or manipulated otherwise 171 172 173 174 175 Officials from central government have said that local government officials sometimes falsify economic data to meet the economic growth targets or for personal promotions 171 176 Despite reducing poverty and increasing China s wealth Deng s reforms have been criticized by the Chinese New Left for increasing inequality and allowing private entrepreneurs to purchase state assets at reduced prices These accusations were especially intense during the Lang Gu dispute in which New Left academic Larry Hsien Ping Lang accused entrepreneur Gu Sujung of usurping state assets after which Gu was imprisoned 177 The Hu Wen Administration adopted some New Left policies such as halting privatizations and increasing the state sector s importance in the economy and Keynesian policies that have been criticized by some Chinese economists such as Zhang Weiying who advocate a policy of deregulation tax cuts and privatization 113 Other criticisms focus on the effects of rapid industrialization on public health and the environment For instance China is the largest CO2 emitter in the world 178 However scholars believe that public health issues are unlikely to become major obstacles to the growth of China s economy during the coming decades and studies have shown that air quality and other environmental measures in China are better than those in developed countries such as the United States and Japan at the same level of development 179 Air pollution reached its peak in the early 2010s and has declined significantly since then 180 181 Some scholars have also contested the claims that the reform has led to as dramatic reduction in poverty as reported The dramatic reduction reported relies on the use of the World Bank poverty line of 1 90 per day which some have argued is an inaccurate means of measuring poverty in pre reform China as during the Mao era and the decade after its end an effective and far reaching system of public provision existed in China which kept prices low and a food rationing system which except during the Great Chinese Famine years effectively guaranteed the vast majority of China s population with access to food 182 Using China s Basic Needs Poverty Line calculated based on OECD datasets the proportion of Chinese people unable to afford a subsistence basket basic needs has increased since the increasing pace of reforms in the late 1980s and 1990s 183 184 The economic reforms were initially accompanied with a series of political reforms in the 1980s supported by Deng Xiaoping However many of the planned political reforms ended after the 1989 Tiananmen Square protests and massacre 185 Lack of political reform contributed to the serious corruption issue in China 186 Additionally China s economic growth has led to the rise of a real state bubble 187 Since the late 1970s Deng and other senior leaders including Chen Yun and Li Xiannian supported the one child policy to cope with the overpopulation crisis 188 However the 2010 census data showed that the population growth rate dropped to low levels 189 Due to the financial pressure and other factors many young couples increasingly choose to delay or even abandon the plan of raising a second child even after the Chinese government largely relaxed the one child policy in late 2015 190 191 192 This has led to the aging of the Chinese population which economists have said could potentially harm the economy in the future 191 193 194 See also editChina model Beijing Consensus Deng Xiaoping Theory Go Out policy China s political reforms in 1980s Japanese economic miracle Khrushchev Thaw Tiger economy Lost decadeReferences editCitations edit Ray Alok 2002 The Chinese Economic Miracle Lessons to Be Learnt Economic and Political Weekly 37 37 3835 3848 ISSN 0012 9976 JSTOR 4412606 Harrison Virginia Palumbo Daniele 30 September 2019 China anniversary How the country became the world s economic miracle BBC News Retrieved 26 December 2022 Faison Seth 1997 02 20 DENG XIAOPING IS DEAD AT 92 ARCHITECT OF MODERN CHINA Published 1997 The New York Times ISSN 0362 4331 Retrieved 2021 01 12 Eisenman Joshua Analysis What we really know about China s Reform and Opening Up The Washington Post ISSN 0190 8286 Retrieved 2021 01 12 Ezra F Vogel Deng Xiaoping and the Transformation of China 2011 关于 总设计师 称谓提法的来龙去脉 邓小平纪念网 Renmin Wang in Chinese 2016 06 30 Archived from the original on 2020 07 12 Retrieved 2021 01 12 Barboza David 2010 08 15 China Passes Japan as Second Largest Economy The New York Times ISSN 0362 4331 Retrieved 2020 05 03 China overtakes Japan as world s second largest economy The Guardian Associated Press 2010 08 16 ISSN 0261 3077 Retrieved 2020 05 03 Bergsten C Fred 2022 The United States vs China the quest for global economic leadership Cambridge p 86 ISBN 978 1 5095 4735 7 OCLC 1255691875 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint location missing publisher link a b Longworth John William Brown Colin G Waldron Scott A 2001 Beef in China Agribusiness Opportunities and Challenges University of Queensland Press p 248 ISBN 9780702232312 Engardio Peter 21 August 2005 China Is a Private Sector Economy Bloomberg Businessweek Archived from the original on 29 January 2014 Retrieved 30 September 2014 a b c d Scissors Derek May June 2009 Deng Undone The Costs of Halting Market Reform in China Foreign Affairs 88 3 Archived from the original on 2015 04 21 Retrieved 2014 09 30 Politika reform i otkrytosti v Kitae Svoi v Kitae in Russian 12 July 2023 Retrieved 2023 07 12 a b c Naughton Barry 2007 The Chinese economy transitions and growth Cambridge Mass MIT Press pp 3 5 ISBN 978 0262640640 OCLC 70839809 Walder 2015 pp 321 Brandt 2008 p 8 Walder 2015 pp 322 Brandt 2008 pp 7 8 a b c Weber Isabella 2021 How China escaped shock therapy the market reform debate Abingdon Oxon Routledge p 106 ISBN 978 0 429 49012 5 OCLC 1228187814 Marquis Christopher Qiao Kunyuan 2022 11 15 Mao and Markets The Communist Roots of Chinese Enterprise Yale University Press doi 10 2307 j ctv3006z6k ISBN 978 0 300 26883 6 JSTOR j ctv3006z6k S2CID 253067190 Heilmann Sebastian 2018 Red Swan How Unorthodox Policy Making Facilitated China s Rise The Chinese University of Hong Kong Press ISBN 978 962 996 827 4 Heilmann Sebastian 2018 Red Swan How Unorthodox Policy Making Facilitated China s Rise The Chinese University of Hong Kong Press ISBN 978 962 996 827 4 Meet moderately prosperous China Economist 21 November 2019 Archived from the original on 2020 06 04 Retrieved 2020 05 26 Commentary Sprinting toward a moderately prosperous society Xinhuanet 2019 03 04 Archived from the original on 2019 03 04 Retrieved 2020 05 26 Wong John 1998 03 01 Xiao kang Deng Xiaoping s socio economic development target for China Journal of Contemporary China 7 17 141 152 doi 10 1080 10670569808724309 ISSN 1067 0564 Buckley C March 23 2015 In Lee Kuan Yew China Saw a Leader to Emulate The New York Times Archived from the original on March 24 2015 a b Jin Keyu 2023 The New China Playbook Beyond Socialism and Capitalism New York Viking ISBN 978 1 9848 7828 1 Cited by Susan L Shirk in The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China University of California Berkeley and Los Angeles 1993 ISBN 0 520 07706 7 Brandt 2008 p 8 a b Hunt Michael H 2004 The World Transformed 1945 to the Present Boston Bedford St Martin s p 355 ISBN 9780312245832 LCCN 2003101700 OCLC 1151774819 OL 3695802M Brandt 2008 p 10 a b Brandt 2008 p 11 Open Door Policy BBC Archived from the original on 2017 07 25 Retrieved 2019 05 17 Yun Wing Sung 16 January 1992 The China Hong Kong Connection The Key to China s Open Door Policy Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0521382458 a b Unsung hero of China s opening up is star of Shenzhen museum South China Morning Post 2018 12 27 Retrieved 2020 09 05 Shekou Industrial Zone firsts in reform and opening up China Daily Retrieved 2020 09 05 a b Zhao Suisheng 2023 The dragon roars back transformational leaders and dynamics of Chinese foreign policy Stanford California Stanford University Press pp 54 55 ISBN 978 1 5036 3415 2 OCLC 1332788951 Cheong Danson 2018 12 07 Shenzhen from village to city of opportunities The Straits Times Retrieved 2020 09 05 Jan 24 29 1984 Deng Xiaoping visits Shenzhen and Zhuhai China Chinadaily com cn China Daily Retrieved 2020 06 17 Yuan Yiming 2017 03 15 Studies on China s Special Economic Zones Springer ISBN 978 981 10 3704 7 Hu Yaobang an icon of China s reform and of how little has changed South China Morning Post 2019 04 14 Retrieved 2021 01 12 Zhao Ziyang The forgotten architect of China s economic reforms DW 14 01 2015 Deutsche Welle 2015 01 14 Archived from the original on 2015 08 20 Retrieved 2021 01 12 Hornby Lucy 2018 11 15 Xi versus Deng the family feud over China s reforms Financial Times Archived from the original on 2018 11 18 Retrieved 2021 01 12 Chinese reform politician Wan Li dies at 98 AP NEWS 16 July 2015 Retrieved 2021 01 12 Hu Qili Urged People Throughout Country to Help Change China With AM China Bjt AP NEWS Retrieved 2021 01 12 Bachman David 1986 Differing Visions of China s Post Mao Economy The Ideas of Chen Yun Deng Xiaoping and Zhao Ziyang Asian Survey 26 3 292 321 doi 10 2307 2644194 ISSN 0004 4687 JSTOR 2644194 a b c d Wudunn Sheryl 1995 04 11 Chen Yun a Chinese Communist Patriarch Who Helped Slow Reforms Is Dead at 89 Published 1995 The New York Times ISSN 0362 4331 Retrieved 2021 01 12 a b CHEN YUN DIES The Washington Post ISSN 0190 8286 Retrieved 2021 01 12 a b Sullivan Lawrence R 1988 Assault on the Reforms Conservative Criticism of Political and Economic Liberalization in China 1985 86 The China Quarterly 114 114 198 222 doi 10 1017 S030574100002676X ISSN 0305 7410 JSTOR 654442 S2CID 154870609 Exupoli Bird Cage Economics Archived 2022 12 08 at the Wayback Machine Exupoli net a b c Coase Ronald Wang Ning 2012 Coase Ronald Wang Ning eds A Bird in the Cage Market Reform under Socialism How China Became Capitalist London Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 68 103 doi 10 1057 9781137019370 4 ISBN 978 1 137 01937 0 retrieved 2021 01 12 Rivers Matt 2018 11 23 Inside China s Silicon Valley From copycats to innovation CNN Business CNN Retrieved 2022 09 19 The rise of China s Silicon Valley CNN Video 19 November 2018 retrieved 2020 05 25 A 30 Billion Fortune Is Hiding in China s Silicon Valley Bloomberg L P October 18 2021 Xinhua Headlines The rise of China s Silicon Valley Xinhua News Agency Archived from the original on December 19 2019 Retrieved 2020 05 25 a b c Liu Zongyuan Zoe 2023 Sovereign Funds How the Communist Party of China Finances its Global Ambitions The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press ISBN 9780674271913 a b Brandt 2008 pp 17 18 a b c Rawski 2008 p 573 Lee Dinah 1984 11 25 China s Coastal Cities Seek Foreign Investors The Washington Post ISSN 0190 8286 Retrieved 2022 09 19 Yang Dali L 1991 China Adjusts to the World Economy The Political Economy of China s Coastal Development Strategy Pacific Affairs 64 1 42 64 doi 10 2307 2760362 ISSN 0030 851X JSTOR 2760362 a b c d e Weber Isabella 2021 How China escaped shock therapy the market reform debate Abingdon Oxon Routledge p 220 ISBN 978 0 429 49012 5 OCLC 1228187814 a b c Weber Isabella 2021 How China escaped shock therapy the market reform debate Abingdon Oxon Routledge p 240 ISBN 978 0 429 49012 5 OCLC 1228187814 a b Naughton 2008 p 105 a b c Naughton 2008 p 114 Walter Carl E September 2014 Was Deng Xiaoping Right An Overview of China s Equity Markets Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 26 3 8 19 doi 10 1111 jacf 12075 ISSN 1078 1196 S2CID 153763863 An old man s ups and downs in China s stock market Embassy of the People s Republic of China in the Republic of Kenya Archived from the original on 2020 06 04 Retrieved 2020 05 02 Brandt 2008 p 22 Brandt 2008 p 19 a b c d Lin Chun 2006 The transformation of Chinese socialism Durham N C Duke University Press p 259 ISBN 978 0 8223 3785 0 OCLC 63178961 Naughton 2008 p 116 Brandt 2008 p 128 Schoenleber H 23 September 2006 China s Private Economy Grows Up 8km de Archived from the original on 31 August 2010 Retrieved 28 August 2010 Zhao Huanxin 19 December 2006 China names key industries for state control China Daily Archived from the original on 11 October 2017 Naughton 2008 p 129 China s New Healthcare could cover millions more Archived 2013 08 26 at the Wayback Machine Time magazine Chovanec Patrick 2009 06 08 China s Real Estate Riddle Archived 2009 06 14 at the Wayback Machine Far East Economic Review Retrieved 13 March 2010 a b Orlik Tom 16 November 2012 Charting China s Economy 10 Years Under Hu The Wall Street Journal Retrieved 7 June 2023 China overtakes Japan as world s second biggest economy BBC News February 14 2011 Kroeber Arthur R 17 November 2013 Xi Jinping s Ambitious Agenda for Economic Reform in China Brookings Institution Archived from the original on 27 July 2014 Retrieved 21 July 2014 Denyer Simon 25 August 2013 Creeping reforms as China gives Shanghai Free Trade Zone go ahead The Washington Post Retrieved 4 January 2023 Wang Orange Leng Sidney 28 September 2018 Chinese President Xi Jinping s show of support for state owned firms no surprise analysts say South China Morning Post Retrieved 31 January 2020 Whyte Martin K 15 March 2021 China s economic development history and Xi Jinping s China dream an overview with personal reflections Chinese Sociological Review 53 2 115 134 doi 10 1080 21620555 2020 1833321 ISSN 2162 0555 S2CID 228867589 Chinese enterprises write Communist Party s role into charters Nikkei Asian Review asia nikkei com Archived from the original on 2017 08 18 Retrieved 2017 08 18 Commentary Why Chinese state companies are getting the Communist party s attention Channel NewsAsia Archived from the original on 2017 08 18 Retrieved 2017 08 18 a b Dalio Ray Principles by Ray Dalio principles com Archived from the original on 2021 01 06 Retrieved 2021 01 03 Mitchell Tom 25 July 2016 Xi s China The rise of party politics Financial Times Archived from the original on 11 December 2022 Retrieved 31 January 2020 Bradsher Keith 4 March 2017 China and Economic Reform Xi Jinping s Track Record The New York Times ISSN 0362 4331 Archived from the original on 5 March 2017 Retrieved 31 January 2020 Tran Hung 14 March 2023 China s debt reduction campaign is making progress but at a cost Atlantic Council Fifield Anna 2 November 2018 As China settles in for trade war leader Xi emphasizes self reliance The Washington Post Retrieved 31 January 2020 a b Youwei 2019 06 04 The End of Reform in China Foreign Affairs America and the World ISSN 0015 7120 Archived from the original on 2019 08 19 Retrieved 2019 08 19 a b Tiezzi Shannon 2018 04 04 Carl Minzner on China s Post Reform Era The Diplomat Archived from the original on 2019 08 19 Retrieved 2019 08 19 a b China Deng Xiaoping era ends with start of Xi era EJ Insight 2018 09 06 Archived from the original on 2019 08 19 Retrieved 2019 08 19 a b Chinese state tightens grip 40 years after Deng s reforms Nikkei Asian Review Archived from the original on 2019 08 24 Retrieved 2019 08 23 a b Westcott Ben Lee Lily December 17 2018 China sparked an economic miracle now there s a fight over its legacy CNN International Edition Archived from the original on January 2 2019 Retrieved January 2 2019 a b Xi Jinping s turn away from the market puts Chinese growth at risk Financial Times 15 January 2019 Archived from the original on 2019 08 23 Retrieved 2019 08 23 Wei Lingling 12 August 2020 China s Xi Speeds Up Inward Economic Shift The Wall Street Journal ISSN 0099 9660 Retrieved 13 August 2022 Lin Andy Hale Thomas Hudson Hudson 8 October 2021 Half of China s top developers crossed Beijing s red lines Financial Times Archived from the original on 11 December 2022 Retrieved 11 August 2022 General Office of the CCP Central Committee Opinions on Strengthening the United Front Work of Private Economy in the New Era Xinhua net in Chinese Archived from the original on 19 October 2020 Retrieved 15 September 2020 Full Text Xi Jinping s Speech on Boosting Common Prosperity Caixin Global Caixin Global 19 October 2021 Retrieved 11 August 2022 Hass Ryan 9 September 2021 Assessing China s common prosperity campaign Brookings Institution Retrieved 11 August 2022 Shen Samuel Ranganathan Vidya 3 November 2021 China stock pickers reshape portfolios on Xi s common prosperity Reuters Retrieved 11 August 2022 Brandt 2008 p 3 China has socialist market economy in place People s Daily Online 2005 Heston 2008 p 28 Cai 2008 p 184 Brandt 2008 p 2 Perkins 2008 p 834 a b Branstetter 2008 p 668 a b Branstetter 2008 p 669 Benjamin 2008 p 730 Benjamin 2008 pp 730 731 Benjamin 2008 p 774 a b Weiyin Zhang Completely bury Keynesianism Archived 2011 05 11 at the Wayback Machine February 17 2009 a b Huang 2008 p 478 a b Huang 2008 p 480 Weber Isabella 2021 How China escaped shock therapy the market reform debate Abingdon Oxon Routledge p 164 ISBN 978 0 429 49012 5 OCLC 1228187814 Huang 2008 pp 481 482 Huang 2008 p 483 Rawski 2008 p 572 Perkins 2008 p 862 a b Rawski 2008 p 593 China poised to be world s largest auto market Archived 2016 12 31 at the Wayback Machine NBC News 2009 02 04 Rawski 2008 p 588 a b Brandt 2008 p 13 Rawski 2008 p 570 Branstetter 2008 pp 635 638 Branstetter 2008 p 655 Brandt 2008 pp 1 3 Branstetter 2008 p 656 Branstetter 2008 p 676 Branstetter 2008 pp 640 642 Haggard Stevens et al 2008 339 Branstetter 2008 p 657 Branstetter 2008 pp 658 659 Allen 2008 p 522 Perkins 2008 p 866 Allen 2008 p 523 Allen 2008 p 528 Allen 2008 p 530 Allen 2008 p 514 a b Allen 2008 p 556 Xin Zhao and Russell W Belk Politicizing Consumer Culture Advertising s Appropriation of Political Ideology in China s Social Transition Journal of Consumer Research 2008 35 2 pp 231 244 Wong 2008 p 431 Wong 2008 p 440 Wong 2008 p 434 Calhoun Craig Wasserstrom Jeffrey N 2003 The Cultural Revolution and the Democracy Movement of 1989 Complexity in Historical Connections in Law Kam yee ed The Chinese cultural revolution reconsidered beyond purge and holocaust Palgrave Macmillan p 247 ISBN 978 0 333 73835 1 retrieved 2011 10 20 Brandt 2008 pp 18 19 Kahn 1979 pp 455 Ang Yuen Yuen May June 2018 Autocracy With Chinese Characteristics Foreign Affairs Sharma Shalendra D Winter Spring 2007 China s Economic Transformation Global Dialogue 9 1 2 Archived from the original on 2013 05 13 Retrieved 2014 09 30 WTO China Member information www wto org Retrieved 2020 06 20 Zhang Jianping Liu Huan 2019 03 09 改革开放40年 引进来 与 走出去 Qiushi in Chinese Archived from the original on 2021 01 03 Retrieved 2020 06 19 a b c d Yuan Xiaobin 发达国家对华援助 不手软 NetEase in Chinese Archived from the original on 2021 01 03 Retrieved 2020 06 18 a b 中国还需要发达国家的政府援助吗 in Chinese Phoenix Television 2009 11 17 Archived from the original on 2021 01 08 Retrieved 2020 06 18 a b China ForeignAssistance gov www foreignassistance gov Archived from the original on 2020 06 20 Retrieved 2020 06 18 Japan to discontinue development assistance projects for China Taro Kono The Japan Times 2018 10 23 Retrieved 2020 06 18 a b Lin Chun 2006 The transformation of Chinese socialism Durham N C Duke University Press p 2 ISBN 978 0 8223 3785 0 OCLC 63178961 Dorn James A Fall 2002 Economic Development and Freedom The Legacy of Peter Bauer PDF Cato Journal Cato Institute 22 2 Archived PDF from the original on 2014 10 06 Retrieved 2014 09 30 Remnick David January February 1997 Can Russia Change Foreign Affairs 76 1 35 49 doi 10 2307 20047908 JSTOR 20047908 Archived from the original on 2014 04 14 Retrieved 2014 09 30 Olson Mancur 2000 Power and prosperity outgrowing communist and capitalist dictatorships New York Basic Books ISBN 978 0465051960 Svejnar 2008 p 68 Svejnar 2008 p 74 Svejnar 2008 p 76 Svejnar 2008 pp 69 70 Svejnar 2008 p 72 Naughton 2008 p 96 a b Heston 2008 p 37 Heston 2008 p 46 Perkins 2008 p 879 Perkins 2008 p 865 a b China s economic census uncovers more fake data South China Morning Post 2019 06 20 Retrieved 2021 05 20 Study Suggests That Local Chinese Officials Manipulate GDP Yale University 11 February 2020 Archived from the original on 2020 04 03 Retrieved 2021 05 20 Watts Gordon 2019 10 18 Fake figures cloud China s economic data Asia Times Retrieved 2021 05 20 China s GDP Growth Pace Was Inflated for Nine Years Study Finds Bloomberg com 8 March 2019 Archived from the original on 2019 03 08 Retrieved 2021 05 20 Why China s dramatic economic recovery might not add up The Guardian 2020 10 25 Retrieved 2021 05 20 Pham Sherisse 2017 01 18 Chinese province admits falsifying economic data for years CNNMoney Retrieved 2021 05 20 Wan Jing 30 October 2008 郎顾之争 一场远没有结束的论战 The Lang Gu debate a debate that has not yet ended Hexun in Chinese Archived from the original on 23 July 2011 Each Country s Share of CO2 sic Emissions Union of Concerned Scientists www ucsusa org Retrieved 2021 05 05 Perkins 2008 pp 870 871 Jayaram Kripa Kay Chris Murtaugh Dan 14 June 2022 China Reduced Air Pollution in 7 Years as Much as US Did in Three Decades Bloomberg News Retrieved 7 June 2023 China has Quickly and Sharply Reduced Pollution Since Enacting Strict Policies EPIC Retrieved 2023 06 07 Dreze J and Sen A 1989 Hunger and Public Action p 209 Oxford Clarendon Press Sullivan Dylan Moatsos Michail Hickel Jason 2023 Capitalist reforms and extreme poverty in China Unprecedented progress or income deflation New Political Economy 29 1 21 doi 10 1080 13563467 2023 2217087 S2CID 259664228 Moatsos M 2021 Global extreme poverty present and past since 1820 In OECD ed How was life Vol II new perspectives on well being and global inequality since 1820 Paris OECD Publishing 186 212 Wang Yuhua Analysis How has Tiananmen changed China The Washington Post ISSN 0190 8286 Archived from the original on 4 June 2019 Retrieved 2021 05 05 He Zengke 1 June 2000 Corruption and anti corruption in reform China Communist and Post Communist Studies 33 2 243 270 doi 10 1016 S0967 067X 00 00006 4 ISSN 0967 067X Bird Stella Yifan Xie and Mike 2020 07 17 The 52 Trillion Bubble China Grapples With Epic Property Boom The Wall Street Journal ISSN 0099 9660 Retrieved 2021 05 05 Greenhalgh Susan 2005 Missile Science Population Science The Origins of China s One Child Policy The China Quarterly 182 182 253 276 doi 10 1017 S0305741005000184 ISSN 0305 7410 JSTOR 20192474 S2CID 144640139 Cai Yong 2013 09 01 China s New Demographic Reality Learning from the 2010 Census Population and Development Review 39 3 371 396 doi 10 1111 j 1728 4457 2013 00608 x ISSN 0098 7921 PMC 4302763 PMID 25620818 Zhou C 3 Feb 2018 A look inside the struggles and benefits of China s little emperor generation Australian Broadcasting Corporation Retrieved 5 May 2021 a b How China s Demographic Time Bomb Threatens its Economy Wharton Business Archived from the original on 2018 08 21 Retrieved 2021 05 05 Pak Jennifer 2020 10 09 Cost of child rearing in China hinders baby boom Marketplace Retrieved 2021 05 05 Myers Steven Lee Wu Jin Fu Claire 2019 01 17 China s Looming Crisis A Shrinking Population The New York Times ISSN 0362 4331 Retrieved 2021 05 05 Could China s population crisis be reaching a point of no return South China Morning Post 2021 03 25 Retrieved 2021 05 05 General and cited sources edit Allen Franklin et al 2008 China s Financial system Past present and future in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge England Cambridge University Press Cardenal Juan Pablo Araujo Heriberto 2011 La silenciosa conquista china in Spanish Barcelona Critica ISBN 9788498922578 Benjamin Dwayne et al 2008 Income inequality during China s Economic Transition in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge university press Brandt Loren et al 2008 Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge university press Branstetter Lee et al 2008 China s embrace of globalization in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge University Press Cai Fang et al 2008 The Chinese labor market in the reform era in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge university press Dillon Michael Deng Xiaoping The Man Who Made Modern China Bloomsbury Publishing 2014 Haggard Stevens et al 2008 The political economy of private sector development in China in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge university press Heston Alan et al 2008 China and Development economics in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge university press Huang Jikun et al 2008 Agriculture in China s Development Past Disappointments Recent Successes and Future Challenges in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge university press Kahn Herman 24 May 1979 World Economic Development 1979 And Beyond Avalon Publishing ISBN 978 0 89158 392 9 Kau Michael Y M China in the Era of Deng Xiaoping A Decade of Reform Routledge 2016 Naughton Barry et al 2008 A Political Economy of China s Economic TransitioninChina s Great Transformation in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge university press Perkins Dwight et al 2008 Forecasting China s growth to 2025 in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge university press Rawski G Thomas et al 2008 China s Industrial Development in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge university press Svejnar Jan et al 2008 China in light of other transition economies in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge university press Vogel Ezra F Deng Xiaoping and the Transformation of China Harvard UP 2011 Walder Andrew G 2015 China Under Mao Cambridge MA Harvard University Press ISBN 978 0 674 05815 6 Wong P W Christine et al 2008 China s Fiscal system a work in progress in Brandt Loren Rawski G Thomas eds China s Great Transformation Cambridge Cambridge university press Zhao Xin Russell W Belk August 2008 Politicizing Consumer Culture Advertising s Appropriation of Political Ideology in China s Social Transition Journal of Consumer Research 35 2 231 244 doi 10 1086 588747 ISSN 0093 5301 Further reading editGewirtz Julian 2022 Never Turn Back China and the Forbidden History of the 1980s Belknap Press External links edit nbsp Quotations related to Chinese economic reform at WikiquotePortals nbsp China nbsp Capitalism nbsp Communism nbsp Economics nbsp Politics Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Chinese economic reform amp oldid 1204830371, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.