fbpx
Wikipedia

Proportional representation

Proportional representation (PR) refers to a type of electoral system under which subgroups of an electorate are reflected proportionately in the elected body.[1] The concept applies mainly to political divisions (political parties) among voters. The essence of such systems is that all votes cast – or almost all votes cast – contribute to the result and are effectively used to help elect someone – not just a bare plurality, or (exclusively) the majority – and that the system produces mixed, balanced representation reflecting how votes are cast.

Activists campaigning for proportional representation in Canada in September 2013

In the context of voting systems, PR means that each representative in an assembly is elected by a roughly equal number of voters. In the common case of electoral systems that only allow a choice of parties, the seats are allocated in proportion to the vote share each party receives.

The term "Proportional representation" may also be used to mean fair representation by population as applied to states, regions etc. However, representation being proportional in terms of population size are not considered to make an electoral system proportional the way the term is usually used. For example, the US House of Representatives has 435 members, who each represent a roughly equal number of people and each state is allocated a number of members in accordance with its population size, thus producing fair representation by population. But members of the House are elected in first-past-the-post elections: first-past-the-post is not proportional by vote share as it has only one winner. Meanwhile, PR electoral systems are typically proportional to both population (seats per district) and vote share (typically party-wise). The European Parliament gives each member state a number of seats roughly based on its population size (see degressive proportionality) and further, in each member state the election must be held using a PR system (with proportional results based on vote share).

The most widely used families of PR electoral systems are party-list PR, used in 85 countries,[2] mixed-member PR (MMP), used in 7 countries,[3] and the single transferable vote (STV), used in Ireland,[4] Malta and Australian Senate.[5] All PR systems require multi-member voting districts, meaning votes are pooled to elect multiple representatives at once. Pooling may be done in various multi-member districts (in STV and most list PR systems) or in single countrywide – so called at-large – district (in other list-PR systems). A country-wide pooling of votes to elect more than a hundred members is used in Angola, for example. For large districts, party-list PR is more often used. A purely candidate-based PR system, STV, has never been used to elect more than 21 in a single contest to this point in history. Some PR systems use at-large pooling or regional pooling in conjunction with single-member districts (such as the New Zealand MMP and the Scottish additional member system), others use at-large pooling in conjunction with multi-member districts (Denmark). In these cases pooling is used to allocated the so called leveling seats (top-up) to compensate for the disproportional results produced in single-member districts using FPTP (MMP/AMS) or to polish the fairness produced in multi-member districts using list PR (Denmark's MMP). PR systems that achieve the highest levels of proportionality tend to use as general pooling as possible (typically country-wide) or districts with large numbers of seats.

Due to various factors, perfect proportionality is rarely achieved under PR systems. The use of electoral thresholds (in list-PR or MMP), small districts with few seats in each (in STV or list-PR), absence or insufficient number of leveling seats (in list-PR, MMP or AMS) may produce disproportionality. Other sources are electoral tactics that may be used in certain system, such as party splitting in some MMP systems. Nonetheless, PR systems approximate proportionality much better than other systems[6] and are more resistant to gerrymandering and other forms of manipulation.

Basics

 
An illustrated graphic regarding the basic concept of proportional representation

To achieve their intended effect, Proportional electoral systems always have to allow for multiple winners. There needs to be more than one seat in each district or some form of pooling of votes. Elections for a single president cannot be based on proportional representation, but a legislative body (assembly, parliament) may be elected proportionally.

In the European Parliament for instance, each member state has a number of seats that is (roughly) proportional to its population, enabling geographical proportional representation. For these elections all EU countries also must use a proportional electoral system (enabling political proportional representation): When n% of the electorate support a particular political party or set of candidates as their favorite, then roughly n% of seats are allotted to that party or those candidates.[7] All PR aim to provide some form of equal representation for votes, but may differ in their approaches on how they achieve this.

How party-list PR works

Party list PR is the most commonly used version of proportional representation. Voters cast votes for parties and each party is allocated seats based on its party share.

Some party-list PR systems use overall country-wide vote counts; others count vote shares in separate parts of the country and allocate seats in each part according to that specific vote count. Some use both.

List PR involves parties in the election process. Voters do not primarily vote for candidates (persons), but for electoral lists (or party lists), which are lists of candidates that parties put forward. The mechanism that allocates seats to the parties/lists is how these systems achieve proportionality. Once this is done, the candidates who take the seats are based on the order in which they appear on the list. This is the basic, closed list version of list PR.

An example election where the assembly has 200 seats to be filled is presented below. Every voter votes for the list created by their favourite party and the results of the election are as follows (popular vote). Under party-list PR, every party gets a number of seats proportional to their share of the popular vote.

Party Popular vote Party-list PR - D'Hondt (Jefferson) method
Number of seats Seats %  
Party A 43.91% 88 44%
Party B 39.94% 80 40%
Party C 9.98% 20 10%
Party D 6.03% 12 6%
TOTAL 100% 200 100%

This is done by a proportional formula/method, for example the D'Hondt method (also called the Jefferson method) - these are the same methods that may be used to allocate seats for geographic proportional representation (for example, how many seats each states gets in the US House of Representatives). Votes and seats often cannot be mathematically perfectly allocated, so some amount of rounding has to be done. The various methods deal with this in different ways, although the difference is reduced if there are many seats ― for example, if the whole country is one district. Party list PR is also more complicated in reality than in the example, as countries often use more than one district, multiple tiers (e.g. local, regional and national), open lists or an electoral threshold.

How the single transferable vote (STV) works

The single transferable vote is an older method than party-list PR, and it does not need to formally involve parties in the election process. Instead of parties putting forward ordered lists of candidates from which winners are drawn in order, candidates run by name and it is voters themselves who rank the candidates. This is done using a preferential ballot. The ranking is used to instruct election officials of how the vote should be used in case it is placed on an un-electable candidate or on an elected candidate. Each voter casts one vote and the district used elects multiple members (more than one, usually 3 to 7). Because parties play no role in the vote count, STV may be used for nonpartisan elections, such as the city council of Cambridge, Massachusetts.[8] A large proportion of the votes cast are used to actually elect someone so the result is mixed and balanced with no one voting block taking much more than its due share of the seats. Where party labels are indicated, proportionality party-wise is noticeable.

Counting votes under STV is more complicated than first-past-the-post voting, but the following example shows how the vote count is performed and how proportionality is achieved in a district with 3 seats. In reality, districts need to be larger than that to achieve strict proportionality. The risk though is that if the number of seats is larger than say 10 seats, the ballot will be so large as to be inconvenient and voters may find it difficult to rank the many candidates. (Note that in many STV systems voters are not required to mark more choices than is desired. Even if all voters marked only one preference, the resulting representation would be more balanced than under single-winner FPTP.)

Under STV, an amount that guarantees election is set. This is called the quota. Specifically the Droop quota is used. In this example, a candidate who earns more than 25% of the vote is declared elected. Note that it is only possible for 3 candidates to each get that quota.

In the first count, the first preferences (favourite candidates) of all the voters are counted. Any candidates who pass the quota are declared elected.

 
Simplified example of an STV ballot
Candidate Party Popular vote

(first preferences)

Quota Elected? If elected: surplus votes
Jane Doe Party A 40% 25%(+1 vote) Yes 15%
John Citizen Party A 11% 25%(+1 vote)
Joe Smith Party A 16% 25%(+1 vote)
Fred Rubble Party B 30% 25%(+1 vote) Yes 5%
Mary Hill Party B 3% 25%(+1 vote)
TOTAL 100%

Next, the votes the candidates received above the quota (surplus votes that they did not need to get elected) are transferred to the next preferences of the voters who voted for them. We start with Jane Doe's surplus. For the example we suppose that all voters of Jane Doe prefer John Citizen as their second choice (as he is also from Party A). Based on this we reallocate the votes and find that John Citizen has passed the quota and so is declared elected to the 3rd and last seat that we had to fill. (Even if we assume that Fred Rubble's surplus would have gone to Mary Hill, the vote transfer plus Hill's original votes would not add up to quota. Party B did not have two quotas of votes so was not due two seats, while Party A was.) (It is possible in realistic STV elections for a candidate to win without quota if they are still in the running when the field of candidates is thinned to the number of remaining open seats. But that was not necessary in this case.)

The district result is balanced party-wise. No one party took all the seats as frequently happens under FPTP or other non-proportional voting systems. The result is fair – the most popular party took two seats; the less popular party took just one. The most popular candidate(s) in each party won the party's seat(s). 81 percent of the voters saw their first choice elected. Fifteen percent of them saw both their first and second choices elected. Every voter had satisfaction of seeing someone of the party they support elected in the district.

Candidate Party Current vote total Quota Elected? Party First preference votes

for candidates of party

Number of seats Party seats % under STV
Jane Doe Party A already elected (25%+1 vote) 25%(+1 vote) Yes Party A 67% 2 67%
John Citizen Party A 11% + 15% = 26% 25%(+1 vote) Yes
Joe Smith Party A 16% 25%(+1 vote)
Fred Rubble Party B already elected (25%+1 vote) 25%(+1 vote) Yes Party B 33% 1 33%
Mary Hill Party B 3% 25%(+1 vote)
TOTAL 100% 3 100% 3 100%

How mixed-member proportional representation (MMP) works

Mixed Member Proportional Representation combines election of district members with election of additional members as compensatory top-up.

Often MMP systems use single-member districts to elect district members. (Denmark, Iceland and Sweden uses multi-member districts in their MMP systems). MMP with SMDs is described here.

The mixed-member proportional system combines single member plurality voting (SMP), also known as first-past-the-post (FPTP), with party-list PR in a way that the overall result of the election is supposed to be proportional. The voter may vote for a district candidate as well as a party. The main idea behind MMP is compensation, meaning that the list-PR seat allocation is not independent of the results of the district level voting. First-past-the-post is a single winner system and cannot be proportional (winner-takes-all), so these disproportionalities are compensated by the party-list component.

A simple, yet common version of MMP has as many list-PR seats as there are single-member districts. In the example it can be seen, as is often the case in reality, that the results of the district elections are highly disproportional: large parties typically win more seats than they should proportionally, but there is also random-ness - a party that receives more votes than another party might not win more seats than the other. Any such dis-proportionality produced by the district elections is addressed, where possible, by the allocation of the compensatory additional members.

     
 
Party Popular vote FPTP seats

(Number of districts won)

Compensatory seats under MMP

(party-list PR seats)

Total number of seats

under MMP

Seats % under MMP
Party A 43.91% 64 24 88 44%
Party B 39.94% 33 47 80 40%
Party C 9.98% 0 20 20 10%
Party D 6.03% 3 9 12 6%
TOTAL 100% 100 100 200 100%

MMP gives only as many compensatory seats to a party as they need to have the number of seats of each party be proportional. Another way to say this is that MMP focuses on making the final outcome proportional.

Differences to parallel voting

Compare the MMP example to parallel voting. Parallel voting is a mixed-member majoritarian system. Here the party-list PR seat allocation is independent of the district results, meaning that there is no compensation (no regard to how the district seats were filled). The popular vote, the number of districts won by each party, and the number of districts and party-list PR seats are all the same as in the MMP example above, yet the total number of seats is different.

     
 
Party Popular vote FPTP seats

(Number of districts won)

Party-list PR seats

under parallel voting

Total number of seats

under parallel voting

Seats %

under parallel voting

Party A 43.91% 64 44 108 54.0%
Party B 39.94% 33 40 73 36.5%
Party C 9.98% 0 10 10 5.0%
Party D 6.03% 3 6 9 4.5%
TOTAL 100% 100 100 200 100%

The overall results are not proportional, although they are more balanced and fair than most single-winner First past the post elections. Parallel voting is mostly semi-proportional. Mixed system is the most proportional if the additional members are allocated in compensatory form.

There are many versions of MMP in use. Some use only a single vote; in some, voters cast two votes, one for a local candidate and one for a party. Some allocate compensatory seats to best losers; others allocate according to party lists. Some use levelling seats to compensate for potential overhang seats; others don't. Most impose an electoral threshold in order for a party to be eligible for any additional seats; some allow parties that elect one or more district seats to be eligible for additional seats even if its party share is below the threshold. Any barrier to access to the additional seats may produce wasted votes and dis-proportionality in the final result.

As well, there is single non-transferable vote, which is also semi-proportional. It has the advantage that parties play no direct role in elections and voters do not need to mark ranked votes. Each voter casts one vote for a candidate and as many candidates win by plurality as the number of seats in the district. Due to each voter casting just one vote, as in STV, and each district electing multiple members, as in STV, mixed representation is produced in each district and overall rough proportionality more or less. Without transferable votes, more votes are wasted than under STV.

Advantages and disadvantages

The case for a Single Transferrable Vote system, a form of proportional representation, was made by John Stuart Mill in his 1861 essay Considerations on Representative Government:

In a representative body actually deliberating, the minority must of course be overruled; and in an equal democracy, the majority of the people, through their representatives, will outvote and prevail over the minority and their representatives. But does it follow that the minority should have no representatives at all? ... Is it necessary that the minority should not even be heard? Nothing but habit and old association can reconcile any reasonable being to the needless injustice. In a really equal democracy, every or any section would be represented, not disproportionately, but proportionately. A majority of the electors would always have a majority of the representatives, but a minority of the electors would always have a minority of the representatives. Man for man, they would be as fully represented as the majority. Unless they are, there is not equal government ... there is a part whose fair and equal share of influence in the representation is withheld from them, contrary to all just government, but, above all, contrary to the principle of democracy, which professes equality as its very root and foundation.[1]

Mill's essay does not support Party-based Proportional Representation and may indicate a distaste for the ills of Party-based systems in saying:

Of all modes in which a national representation can possibly be constituted, this one affords the best security for the intellectual qualifications desirable in the representatives. At present, by universal admission, it is becoming more and more difficult for any one who has only talents and character to gain admission into the House of Commons. The only persons who can get elected are those who possess local influence, or make their way by lavish expenditure, or who, on the invitation of three or four tradesmen or attorneys, are sent down by one of the two great parties from their London clubs, as men whose votes the party can depend on under all circumstances.[1]

Many political theorists agree with Mill[9] that in a representative democracy the representatives should represent all substantial segments of society but want reform rather than abolition of direct local community representation in the legislature.[10]

STV and the Additional-Member system both produce local area representation and overall PR through mixed, balanced representation at the district level.[11]

Fairness

 

PR tries to resolve the unfairness of majoritarian and plurality voting systems where the largest parties receive an "unfair" seat bonus and smaller parties are disadvantaged, always under-represented, and on occasion win no representation at all (Duverger's law).[12][13][14]: 6–7  Under FPTP, an established party in UK elections has been elected to majority government with as little as 35% of votes (2005 UK general election). In certain Canadian elections, majority governments have been formed by parties with the support of under 40% of votes cast (2011 Canadian election, 2015 Canadian election). If turnout levels in the electorate are less than 60%, such outcomes allow a party to form a majority government by convincing as few as one quarter of the electorate to vote for it. In the 2005 UK election, for example, the Labour Party under Tony Blair won a comfortable parliamentary majority with the votes of only 21.6% of the total electorate.[15]: 3  Such misrepresentation has been criticized as "no longer a question of 'fairness' but of elementary rights of citizens".[16]: 22 

However, intermediate PR systems with a high electoral threshold, or other features that reduce proportionality, are not necessarily much fairer: in the 2002 Turkish general election, using an open list system with a 10% threshold, 46% of votes were wasted.[17]: 83  The other 54 percent of the votes did receive fair level of representation, though. Under First past the post, a third or so of members are elected with less than half the votes cast in their district, the majority in such districts not getting any local representation and with no levelling seats getting no representation at all.

Plurality/majoritarian systems also benefit regional parties that win many seats in the region where they have a strong following but have little support nationally, while other parties with national support that is not concentrated in specific districts, like the Greens, win few or no seats. An example is the Bloc Québécois in Canada that won 52 seats in the 1993 federal election, all in Quebec, on 13.5% of the national vote, while the Progressive Conservatives collapsed to two seats on 16% spread nationally. The Conservative party although strong nationally had had very strong regional support in the West but in this election its supporters in the West turned to the Reform party (another regional party), which won all its seats west of Ontario, winning most of its seats west of Saskatchewan.[14][18] Similarly, in the 2015 UK General Election, the Scottish National Party gained 56 seats, all in Scotland, with a 4.7% share of the national vote while the UK Independence Party, with 12.6%, gained only a single seat.[19]

Representation of minor parties

The use of multiple-member districts enables a greater variety of candidates to be elected. It has been argued that in emerging democracies, inclusion of minorities in the legislature can be essential for social stability and to consolidate the democratic process.[17]: 58 

Critics, on the other hand, claim this can give extreme parties a foothold in parliament, sometimes cited as a cause for the collapse of the Weimar government. With very low thresholds, very small parties can act as "king-makers",[20] holding larger parties to ransom during coalition discussions. The example of Israel is often quoted,[17]: 59  but these problems can be limited, as in the modern German Bundestag, by the introduction of higher threshold limits for a party to gain parliamentary representation (which in turn increases the number of wasted votes).

Another criticism is that the dominant parties in plurality/majoritarian systems, often looked on as "coalitions" or as "broad churches",[21] can fragment under PR as the election of candidates from smaller groups becomes possible. Israel, Brazil, and Italy (until 1993) are examples.[17]: 59, 89  However, research shows, in general, there is only a small increase in the number of parties in parliament (although small parties have larger representation) under PR.[22]

Open list systems and STV, the only prominent PR system which does not require political parties,[23] enable independent candidates to be elected. In Ireland, on average, about six independent candidates have been elected each parliament.[24] This can lead to a situation where forming a Parliamentary majority requires support of one or more of these independent representatives. In some cases these independents have positions that are closely aligned with the governing party and it hardly matters. The Irish Government formed after the 2016 election even included independent representatives in the cabinet of a minority government. In others, the electoral platform is entirely local and addressing this is a price for support.


Coalitions

The election of smaller parties gives rise to one of the principal objections to PR systems, that they almost always result in coalition governments.[17]: 59 [9]

Supporters of PR see coalitions as an advantage, forcing compromise between parties to form a coalition at the centre of the political spectrum, and so leading to continuity and stability. Opponents counter that with many policies compromise is not possible. Neither can many policies be easily positioned on the left-right spectrum (for example, the environment). So policies are horse-traded during coalition formation, with the consequence that voters have no way of knowing which policies will be pursued by the government they elect; voters have less influence on governments. Also, coalitions do not necessarily form at the centre, and small parties can have excessive influence, supplying a coalition with a majority only on condition that a policy or policies favoured by few voters is/are adopted. Most importantly, the ability of voters to vote a party in disfavour out of power is curtailed.[9]

 
Countries with PR do not appear to have more elections.

All these disadvantages, the PR opponents contend, are avoided by two-party plurality systems. Coalitions are rare; the two dominant parties necessarily compete at the centre for votes, so that governments are more reliably moderate; the strong opposition necessary for proper scrutiny of government is assured; and governments remain sensitive to public sentiment because they can be, and are, regularly voted out of power.[9] However, this is not necessarily so; a two-party system can result in a "drift to extremes", hollowing out the centre,[25] or, at least, in one party drifting to an extreme.[26] The opponents of PR also contend that coalition governments created under PR are less stable, and elections are more frequent. Italy is an often-cited example with many governments composed of many different coalition partners. However, Italy is unusual in that both its houses can make a government fall, whereas other PR nations have either just one house or have one of their two houses be the core body supporting a government. Italy's current parallel voting system is not PR, so Italy is not an appropriate candidate for measuring the stability of PR.

Voter participation

Plurality systems usually result in single-party-majority government because generally fewer parties are elected in large numbers under FPTP compared to PR, and FPTP compresses politics to little more than two-party contests. Relatively few votes in a few of the most finely balanced districts, the "swing seats", are able to swing majority control in the house. Incumbents in less evenly divided districts are invulnerable to slight swings of political mood. In the UK, for example, about half the constituencies have always elected the same party since 1945;[27] in the 2012 US House elections 45 districts (10% of all districts) were uncontested by one of the two dominant parties.[28] Voters who know their preferred candidate will not win have little incentive to vote, and even if they do their votes have no effect, although they are still counted in the popular vote calculation.[17]: 10 

With PR, there are no "swing seats". Most votes contribute to the election of a candidate, so parties need to campaign in all districts, not just those where their support is strongest or where they perceive most advantage. This fact in turn encourages parties to be more responsive to voters, producing a more "balanced" ticket by nominating more women and minority candidates.[14] On average about 8% more women are elected.[22]

Since most votes count, there are fewer "wasted votes", so voters, aware that their vote can make a difference, are more likely to make the effort to vote, and less likely to vote tactically. Compared to countries with plurality electoral systems, voter turnout improves and the population is more involved in the political process.[17][14][22] However, some experts argue that transitioning from plurality to PR only increases voter turnout in geographical areas associated with safe seats under the plurality system; turnout may decrease in areas formerly associated with swing seats.[29]

Gerrymandering

First past the post elections are dependent on the drawing of boundaries of their single-member districts, a process vulnerable to political interference (gerrymandering) even if districts are drawn in such a way as to ensure approximately equal representation. To compound the problem, boundaries have to be periodically re-drawn to accommodate population changes. Even apolitically drawn boundaries can unintentionally produce the effect of gerrymandering, reflecting naturally occurring concentrations.[30]: 65 

PR systems, due to having larger and fewer multiple-member districts, are less prone to gerrymandering  – research suggests five-seat districts or larger are immune to gerrymandering.[30]: 66 

Equality of size of multiple-member districts is not important (the number of seats can vary) so districts can be aligned with historical territories of varying sizes such as cities, counties, states or provinces. Later population changes can be accommodated by simply adjusting the number of representatives elected, without having to re-draw boundary. For example, Professor Mollison in his 2010 plan for STV for the UK divided the country into 143 districts and then allocated varying number of seats to each district (to add up to the existing total of 650 MPs) depending on the number of voters in each but with wide ranges (his five-seat districts include one with 327,000 voters and another with 382,000 voters). His district boundaries follow historical county and local authority boundaries, yet he achieves more uniform representation than does the Boundary Commission, the body responsible for balancing the UK's first-past-the-post constituency sizes.[27][31]

Mixed member systems are susceptible to gerrymandering for the local seats that remain a part of such systems. Under parallel voting, a semi-proportional system, there is no compensation for the effects that such gerrymandering might have. Under MMP, the use of compensatory list seats makes gerrymandering less of an issue. However, its effectiveness in this regard depends upon the features of the system, including the size of the regional districts, the relative share of list seats in the total, and opportunities for collusion that might exist. A striking example of how the compensatory mechanism can be undermined can be seen in the 2014 Hungarian parliamentary election, where the leading party, Fidesz, combined gerrymandering and decoy lists, which resulted in a two-thirds parliamentary majority from a 45% vote.[32][33] This illustrates how certain implementations of mixed systems (if non-compensatory or insufficiently compensatory) can produce moderately proportional outcomes, similar to parallel voting.

Link between constituent and representative

It is generally accepted that a particular advantage of plurality electoral systems such as first past the post, or majoritarian electoral systems such as the alternative vote, is the geographic link between representatives and their constituents.[17]: 36 [34]: 65 [16]: 21  A notable disadvantage of PR is that, as its multiple-member districts are made larger, this link is weakened.[17]: 82  In party list PR systems without delineated districts, such as the Netherlands and Israel, the geographic link between representatives and their constituents is considered weak, but has shown to play a role for some parties. Yet with relatively small multiple-member districts, in particular with STV, there are counter-arguments: about 90% of voters can consult a representative they voted for, someone whom they might think more sympathetic to their problem. In such cases it is sometimes argued that constituents and representatives have a closer link;[27][30]: 212  constituents have a choice of representative so they can consult one with particular expertise in the topic at issue.[30]: 212 [35] With multiple-member districts, prominent candidates have more opportunity to be elected in their home constituencies, which they know and can represent authentically. There is less likely to be a strong incentive to parachute them into constituencies in which they are strangers and thus less than ideal representatives.[36]: 248–250  Mixed-member PR systems incorporate single-member districts to preserve the link between constituents and representatives.[17]: 95  However, because up to half the parliamentary seats are list rather than district seats, the districts are necessarily up to twice as large as with a plurality/majoritarian system where all representatives serve single-member districts.[16]: 32 

An interesting case occurred in the Netherlands, when "out of the blue" a party for the elderly, the General Elderly Alliance gained six seats in the 1994 election. The other parties had not paid attention, but this made them aware. With the next election, the Party of the Elderly was gone, because the established parties had started to listen to the elderly. Today, a party for older folks, 50PLUS, has established itself in the Netherlands, albeit never with the same high number of seats. This can be seen as an example how geography in itself may not be a good enough reason to establish voting results around it and overturn all other particulars of the voting population. In a sense, voting in districts restricts the voters to a specific geography. Proportional voting follows the exact outcome of all the votes.[37]

Potential lack of balance in presidential systems

In a presidential system, the president is chosen independently from the parliament. As a consequence, it is possible to have a divided government where a parliament and president have opposing views and may want to balance each other's influence. However, the proportional system favors government of coalitions of many smaller parties that require compromising and negotiating topics.[citation needed] As a consequence, these coalitions might have difficulties presenting a united front to counter presidential influence, leading to a lack of balance between these two powers. With a proportionally elected House, a President may strong-arm certain political issues[citation needed]

This issue does not happen in a parliamentary system, where the prime-minister is elected indirectly by the parliament itself. As a consequence, a divided government is impossible. Even if the political views change with time and the prime minister loses their support from parliament, they can be replaced with a motion of no confidence. Effectively, both measures make it impossible to create a divided government.

Attributes of PR systems

District magnitude

Academics agree that the most important influence on proportionality is an electoral district's magnitude, the number of representatives elected from the district. As magnitude increases, proportionality improves.[17] Some scholars recommend for STV voting districts of roughly four to eight seats,[38] which are considered small relative to PR systems in general, which frequently have district magnitudes in the hundreds.

At one extreme, the binomial electoral system used in Chile between 1989 and 2013,[39] a nominally proportional open-list system, features two-member districts. As this system can be expected to result in the election of one candidate from each of the two dominant political blocks in most districts, it is not generally considered proportional.[17]: 79 

At the other extreme, where the district encompasses the entire country (and with a low minimum threshold, highly proportionate representation of political parties can result), parties gain by broadening their appeal by nominating more minority and women candidates.[17]: 83 

After the introduction of STV in Ireland in 1921, district magnitudes slowly diminished as more and more three-member constituencies were defined, benefiting the dominant Fianna Fáil, until 1979 when an independent boundary commission was established reversing the trend.[40] In 2010, a parliamentary constitutional committee recommended a minimum magnitude of four.[41] Despite relatively low magnitudes, Ireland has generally experienced highly proportional results.[17]: 73 

In the FairVote plan for STV (which FairVote calls choice voting) for the US House of Representatives, three- to five-member super-districts are proposed.[42]

In Professor Mollison's plan for STV in the UK, four- and five-member districts are mostly used, with three and six seat districts used as necessary to fit existing boundaries, and even two and single member districts used where geography dictates.[27]

Electoral threshold

The electoral threshold is the minimum vote required to win one seat. The lower the threshold, the higher the proportion of votes contributing to the election of representatives and the lower the proportion of votes wasted.[17]

All electoral systems have electoral thresholds, either formally defined or the natural threshold, which is the mathematical consequence of the district magnitude and election parameters.[17]: 83 

A formal threshold usually requires parties to win a certain percentage of the vote in order to be awarded seats from the party lists. In Germany and New Zealand (both MMP), the threshold is 5% of the national vote but the threshold is not applied to parties that win a minimum number of constituency seats (three in Germany, one in New Zealand). Turkey defines a threshold of 7%,[43] the Netherlands 0.67%.[17] Israel has raised its threshold from 1% (before 1992) to 1.5% (up to 2004), 2% (in 2006) and 3.25% in 2014.[44] South Africa has no explicit electoral threshold, only a natural threshold ~0.2%. A list of electoral thresholds by country shows a typical electoral threshold for party-list PR is 3-5%.

In STV elections, winning the quota (ballots/(seats+1)plus 1) of votes assures election.[45] Winning the quota in the first count when first preference votes are all that are counted, assures election at that point.[46] E.g. for a district magnitude of 3, the STV electoral threshold would be 25% (of first-preference votes plus transferred later-preference votes), significantly higher than typical party-list PR. However, candidates who receive only about half the quota of first preference votes alone may attract good second (and third, etc.) preference support and win election.[27]

However success with less than quota cannot be relied on. Sometimes candidates in winning positions in the first count (but who do not have quota) are not elected, being pushed aside during the vote count in favor of other candidates who were initially less popular but have wide support and benefit from vote transfers. The need to attract second preferences tends to promote consensus and to disadvantage extremes. Those who do not have wide support may not benefit greatly from vote transfers so may not be elected if they do not receive quota on first count.[46]

The electoral threshold has different effects on STV than on Party-list PR. For STV the votes for candidates below natural threshold are not wasted, but transferred to the next-indicated choice. For party-list PR a vote for a party below electoral threshold is an unrepresented vote, unless the spare vote system is applied.

Party magnitude

Party magnitude is the number of candidates elected from one party in one district. As party magnitude increases a more balanced ticket will be more successful, encouraging parties to nominate women and minority candidates for election.[47]

But under STV, nominating too many candidates can be counter-productive, splitting the first-preference votes and allowing the candidates to be eliminated before receiving transferred votes from other parties. An example of this was identified in a ward in the 2007 Scottish local elections where Labour, putting up three candidates, won only one seat while they might have won two had one of their voters' preferred candidates not stood.[27] The same effect may have contributed to the collapse of Fianna Fáil in the 2011 Irish general election.[48] But generally in STV contests the transfers of votes allows each party to take roughly its due share of the seats based on vote tallies of the party's candidates and where all the candidates of a party preferred by a voter are eliminated, the vote may be transferred to a candidate of a different party also preferred by the voter.[49]

Others

Other aspects of PR can influence proportionality such as the size of the elected body, the choice of open or closed lists, ballot design, and vote counting methods.

Measuring disproportionality

Exact proportionality has a single unambiguous definition: the seat shares must exactly equal the vote shares, measured as seats-to-votes ratio. When this condition is violated, the allocation is disproportional, and it may be interesting to examine the degree of disproportionality – the degree to which the number of seats won by each party differs from that of a perfectly proportional outcome. This degree does not have a single unambiguous definition. Some common disproportionality indexes are:[50]

  • The Loosemore–Hanby index - calculated by subtracting each party's vote share from its seat share, adding up the absolute values (ignoring any negative signs), and dividing by two.[51]: 4–6 
    • Related to it is the Rae index. It measures the average deviation, while the Loosemore–Hanby index measures the total deviation.
    • Related to the amount of unrepresented vote, which only measures the difference between votes cast and seats obtained for parties which did not obtain any seat.
  • The Gallagher Index - involves squaring the difference between each party's vote share and seat share, and taking the square root of the sum.
  • The Sainte-Laguë Index - where the squared discrepancy from ideal seats-to-votes ratio is weighted equally for each voter.

The disproportionality changes from one election to another depending on voter behavior and size of effective electoral threshold, here shown is the unrepresented vote for New Zealand.[52] In 2005 New Zealand general election every party above 1% got seats due to the electoral threshold in New Zealand of at least one seat in first-past-the-post voting, which caused a much lower unrepresented vote compared to the other years.

Different indexes measure different concepts of disproportionality. Some disproportionality concepts have been mapped to social welfare functions.[53]

Disproportionality indexes are sometimes used to evaluate existing and proposed electoral systems. For example, the Canadian Parliament's 2016 Special Committee on Electoral Reform recommended that a system be designed to achieve "a Gallagher score of 5 or less". This indicated a much lower degree of disproportionality than observed in the 2015 Canadian election under first-past-the-post voting, where the Gallagher index was 12.[54]

There are various other measures of proportionality, some of them have software implementation.[55]

The common indexes (Loosemore–Hanby, Gallagher, Sainte-Laguë) do not support ranked voting.[56][57] An alternative that does support it is the Droop proportionality criterion (DPC). It requires that if, for some set M of candidates, there exist more than k Droop quotas of voters who rank them at the top |M| positions, then at least k candidates from M are elected. In the special case in which voters vote solely by party, DPC implies proportionality.

PR electoral systems

Party-based systems

Party list PR

Party list proportional representation is an electoral system in which seats are first allocated to parties based on vote share, and then assigned to party-affiliated candidates on the parties' electoral lists. This system is used in many countries, including Finland (open list), Latvia (open list), Sweden (open list), Israel (national closed list), Brazil (open list), Nepal (closed list) as adopted in 2008 in first CA election, the Netherlands (open list), Russia (closed list), South Africa (closed list), Democratic Republic of the Congo (open list), and Ukraine (open list). For elections to the European Parliament, most member states use open lists; but most large EU countries use closed lists, so that the majority of EP seats are distributed by those.[58] Local lists were used to elect the Italian Senate during the second half of the 20th century. Some common types of electoral lists are:

  • Closed list systems, where each party lists its candidates according to the party's candidate selection process. This sets the order of candidates on the list and thus, in effect, their probability of being elected. The first candidate on a list, for example, will get the first seat that party wins. Each voter casts a vote for a list of candidates. Voters, therefore, do not have the option to express their preferences at the ballot as to which of a party's candidates are elected into office.[59][60] A party is allocated seats in proportion to the number of votes it receives.[61]
  • Ley de Lemas - an intermediate system used in Uruguay, where each party presents several closed lists, each representing a faction. Seats are distributed between parties according to the number of votes, and then between the factions within each party.[citation needed]
  • Open list systems, where voters may vote, depending on the model, for one person, or for two, or indicate their order of preference within the list. These votes sometimes rearrange the order of names on the party's list and thus which of its candidates are elected. Nevertheless, the number of candidates elected from the list is determined by the number of votes the list receives.[citation needed]
  • Localized list systems, where parties divide their candidates in single member-like constituencies, which are ranked inside each general party list depending by their percentages. This method allows electors to judge every single candidate as in a FPTP system.
  • Two-tier party list systems - as in Denmark, Norway, and Sweden. In Denmark, for example, the country is divided into ten multiple-member voting districts arranged in three regions, electing 135 representatives. In addition, 40 compensatory seats are elected. Voters have one vote which can be cast for an individual candidate or for a party list on the district ballot. To determine district winners, candidates are apportioned their share of their party's district list vote plus their individual votes. The compensatory seats are apportioned to the regions according to the party votes aggregated nationally, and then to the districts where the compensatory representatives are determined. In the 2007 general election, the district magnitudes, including compensatory representatives, varied between 14 and 28. The basic design of the system has remained unchanged since its introduction in 1920.[62][63][64]

Mixed systems

There are mixed electoral systems combining a plurality/majority formula with a proportional formula[65] or using the proportional component to compensate for disproportionality caused by the plurality/majority component.[66][67]

The most prominent mixed compensatory system is mixed member proportional representation (MMP). It combines a single-district vote, usually first-past-the-post, with a compensatory regional or nationwide party list proportional vote. For example, suppose that a party wins 10 seats based on plurality, but requires 15 seats in total to obtain its proportional share of an elected body. A fully proportional mixed compensatory system would award this party 5 compensatory (PR) seats, raising the party's seat count from 10 to 15. MMP has the potential to produce proportional or moderately proportional election outcomes, depending on a number of factors such as the ratio of FPTP seats to PR seats, the existence or nonexistence of extra compensatory seats to make up for overhang seats, and electoral thresholds.[68][69][70] It was invented for the German Bundestag after the Second World War, and has spread to Lesotho, Bolivia, New Zealand and Thailand. The system is also used for the Welsh Parliament and Scottish Parliament where it is called the additional member system.[71][3]

Voters typically have two votes, one for their district representative and one for the party list. The list vote usually determines how many seats are allocated to each party in parliament. After the district winners have been determined, sufficient candidates from each party list are elected to "top-up" each party to the overall number of parliamentary seats due to it according to the party's overall list vote. Before apportioning list seats, all list votes for parties which failed to reach the threshold are discarded. If eliminated parties lose seats in this manner, then the seat counts for parties that achieved the threshold improve. Any direct seats won by independent candidates are subtracted from the parliamentary total used to apportion list seats.[72]

Proportionality of MMP can be compromised if the ratio of list to district seats is too low, as it may then not be possible to completely compensate district seat disproportionality. Another factor can be how overhang seats are handled, district seats that a party wins in excess of the number due to it under the list vote. To achieve proportionality, other parties require "balance seats", increasing the size of parliament by twice the number of overhang seats, but this is not always done. Until recently, Germany increased the size of parliament by the number of overhang seats but did not use the increased size for apportioning list seats. This was changed for the 2013 national election after the constitutional court rejected the previous law, not compensating for overhang seats had resulted in a negative vote weight effect.[73] Lesotho, Scotland and Wales do not increase the size of parliament at all, and, in 2012, a New Zealand parliamentary commission also proposed abandoning compensation for overhang seats, and so fixing the size of parliament. At the same time, it would abolish the single-seat threshold – any such seats would then be overhang seats and would otherwise have increased the size of parliament further – and reduce the electoral threshold from 5% to 4%. Proportionality would not suffer.[17][74]

Similarly to MMP, mixed single vote systems (MSV) use a proportional formula for allocating seats on the compensatory tier, but voters only have one vote that functions on both levels. MSV may use a positive vote transfer system, where unused votes are transferred from the lower tier to the upper, compensatory tier, where only these are used in the proportional formula. Alternatively, the MMP (seat linkage) algorithm can be used with a mixed single vote to "top-up" to a proportional result. With MSV, the similar requirements as in MMP apply to guarantee an overall proportional result.

Parallel voting (MMM) systems use proportional formulas to allocate seats on a proportional tier separately from other tiers. Certain systems, like scorporo use a proportional formula after combining results of a parallel list vote with transferred votes from lower tiers (using negative or positive vote transfer).

Another mixed system is dual-member proportional representation (DMP). It is a single-vote system that elects two representatives in every district.[75] The first seat in each district is awarded to the candidate who wins a plurality of the votes, similar to FPTP voting. The remaining seats are awarded in a compensatory manner to achieve proportionality across a larger region. DMP employs a formula similar to the "best near-winner" variant of MMP used in the German state of Baden-Württemberg.[76] In Baden-Württemberg, compensatory seats are awarded to candidates who receive high levels of support at the district level compared with other candidates of the same party. DMP differs in that at most one candidate per district is permitted to obtain a compensatory seat. If multiple candidates contesting the same district are slated to receive one of their parties' compensatory seats, the candidate with the highest vote share is elected and the others are eliminated. DMP is similar to STV in that all elected representatives, including those who receive compensatory seats, serve their local districts. Invented in 2013 in the Canadian province of Alberta, DMP received attention on Prince Edward Island where it appeared on a 2016 plebiscite as a potential replacement for FPTP,[77] but was eliminated on the third round.[78][79] It was also one of three proportional voting system options on a 2018 referendum in British Columbia.[80][81][82]

Biproportional apportionment

Biproportional apportionment aims to achieve proportionality in two dimensions, for example: proportionality by region and proportionality by party. There are several mathematical methods to attain biproportionality.

One method is called iterative proportional fitting (IPF). It was proposed for elections by the mathematician Michel Balinski in 1989, and first used by the city of Zurich for its council elections in February 2006, in a modified form called "new Zurich apportionment" (Neue Zürcher Zuteilungsverfahren). Zurich had had to modify its party list PR system after the Swiss Federal Court ruled that its smallest wards, as a result of population changes over many years, unconstitutionally disadvantaged smaller political parties. With biproportional apportionment, the use of open party lists has not changed, but the way winning candidates are determined has. The proportion of seats due to each party is calculated according to their overall citywide vote, and then the district winners are adjusted to conform to these proportions. This means that some candidates, who would otherwise have been successful, can be denied seats in favor of initially unsuccessful candidates, in order to improve the relative proportions of their respective parties overall. This peculiarity is accepted by the Zurich electorate because the resulting city council is proportional and all votes, regardless of district magnitude, now have equal weight. The system has since been adopted by other Swiss cities and cantons.[83][84]

Balinski has proposed another variant called fair majority voting (FMV) to replace single-winner plurality/majoritarian electoral systems, in particular the system used for the US House of Representatives. FMV introduces proportionality without changing the method of voting, the number of seats, or the – possibly gerrymandered – district boundaries. Seats would be apportioned to parties in a proportional manner at the state level.[84] In a related proposal for the UK parliament, whose elections are contested by many more parties, the authors note that parameters can be tuned to adopt any degree of proportionality deemed acceptable to the electorate. In order to elect smaller parties, a number of constituencies would be awarded to candidates placed fourth or even fifth in the constituency – unlikely to be acceptable to the electorate, the authors concede – but this effect could be substantially reduced by incorporating a third, regional, apportionment tier, or by specifying minimum thresholds.[85]

Candidate-based systems

Single transferable vote

The single transferable vote (STV), also called ranked choice voting,[86][8] is a ranked system: voters rank candidates in order of preference. Voting districts usually elect three to seven representatives; each voter casts just one vote. The count is cyclic, electing or eliminating candidates and transferring votes until all seats are filled. A candidate whose tally reaches a quota, the minimum vote that guarantees election, is declared elected. The candidate's surplus votes (those in excess of the quota) are transferred to other candidates at a fraction of their value proportionate to the surplus, according to the voters' preferences. If there are no surplus votes to transfer and there are still seats to fill, the least popular candidate is eliminated, those votes being transferred to their next preference at full value. The votes are transferred according to the next marked preference. Any votes that cannot be transferred are moved to a pile labelled exhausted or non-transferable.

The cont continues until all the seats are filled or until there is only one more candidate than the number of remaining open seats. At that point all of them except the least popular candidate are declared elected, even if they do not have quota.

The transfer of votes of eliminated candidates is simple -- the transfer of surplus votes is more involved. There are various methods for transferring surplus votes.

Manual methods used in early times and still today in places where STV was adopted in early 20th Century (Ireland and Malta) transfer surplus votes according to a randomly selected sample, or transfer only a segment of the surplus selected based on the next usable marked preference.

Other more recent methods transfer all votes at a fraction of their value (the fraction derived by the surplus divided by the candidate's tally) and with reference to all the marked preferences on the ballots, not just the next usable preference. They may need the use of a computer.

The different methods may not produce the same result in all respects. But the front runners in the first count before any transfers are conducted are all or mostly elected in the end, so the various methods of transfers all produce much the same result.

Some variants of STV allow transfers to already elected or eliminated candidates, and these, too, can require a computer.[87][88]

In effect, the method produces groups of voters of much the same size so the overall effect is to reflect the diversity of the electorate, each substantial group having one or more representatives the group voted for.

Statistics of effective votes vary.

In Cambridge, under STV, 90 percent of voters see their vote help to elect a candidate, more than 65 percent of voters see their first choice candidate elected, and more than 95 percent of voters see one of their top three choices win.[89]

Other reports claim that 90% of voters have a representative to whom they gave their first preference. Voters can choose candidates using any criteria they wish, the proportionality is implicit.[27]

Political parties are not necessary; all other prominent PR electoral systems presume that parties reflect voters wishes, which many believe gives power to parties.[87] STV satisfies the electoral system criterion proportionality for solid coalitions – a solid coalition for a set of candidates is the group of voters that rank all those candidates above all others – and is therefore considered a system of proportional representation.[87]

However, the small district magnitude used in STV elections (usually 5 to 9 seats, but sometimes rising to 21) has been criticized as impairing proportionality, especially when more parties compete than there are seats available,[9]: 50  and STV has, for this reason, sometimes been labelled "quasi proportional".[90]: 83 

While this may be true when considering districts in isolation, results overall are proportional.

Even though Ireland has particularly small magnitudes (3 to 5 seats), results of STV elections are "highly proportional".[17]: 73 [4] In 1997, the average magnitude was 4.0 but eight parties gained representation, four of them with less than 3% of first preference votes nationally. Six independent candidates also won election.[40]

STV has also been described as the most proportional system as it elects candidates without the need for parties. The influence of parties can distort proportionality.[90]: 83 

The system tends to handicap extreme candidates because, to gain transfers based on back-up preferences and so improve their chance of election, candidates need to canvass voters beyond their own circle of supporters, and so need to moderate their views.[91][92]

Conversely, widely respected candidates can win election even if they receive relatively few first preferences. They do this by benefiting from strong subordinate preference support. Of course, they must have enough initial support so that they are not in the bottom rung of popularity or they will be eliminated when the field of candidate is thinned.[27]

Proportional approval voting

Systems can be devised that aim at proportional representation but are based on approval votes on individual candidates (not parties). Such is the idea of proportional approval voting (PAV).[93] When there are a lot of seats to be filled, as in a legislature, counting ballots under PAV may not be feasible, so sequential variants have been used, such as sequential proportional approval voting (SPAV).

Sequential proportional approval voting

Sequential proportional approval voting (SPAV) is a multi-winner voting system similar to STV in that voters can express support for multiple candidates, but different in that candidates are graded instead of ranked.[94] That is, a voter approves or disapproves of each candidate. SPAV was used briefly in Sweden during the early 1900s.[95]

The vote counting procedure occurs in rounds. The first round of SPAV is identical to approval voting. All ballots are added with equal weight, and the candidate with the highest overall score is elected. In all subsequent rounds, ballots that support candidates who have already been elected are added with a reduced weight. Thus voters who support none of the winners in the early rounds are increasingly likely to elect one of their preferred candidates in a later round. The procedure has been shown to yield proportional outcomes especially when voters are loyal to distinct groups of candidates (e.g. political parties).[96][97]

Reweighted Range Voting

Reweighted Range Voting (RRV) uses the same method as sequential proportional approval voting but uses a score ballot.[98][99] Reweighted Range Voting was used for the nominations in the Visual Effects category for recent Academy Award Oscars from 2013 through 2017,[100][101] and is used in the city of Berkeley, California, for sorting the priorities of the city council.[102]

Asset voting

In asset voting,[94][103] the voters vote for candidates and then the candidates negotiate amongst each other and reallocate votes amongst themselves. Asset voting was proposed by Lewis Carroll in 1884[104] and has been more recently independently rediscovered and extended by Warren D. Smith and Forest Simmons.[105] As such, this method substitutes candidates' collective preferences for those of the voters.

Evaluative proportional representation (EPR)

Similar to majority judgment voting that elects single winners, evaluative proportional representation (EPR) elects all the members of a legislative body.[106] In contrast to any other voting method, EPR explains how it does not "waste" any votes, quantitatively, or qualitatively.[107] [108] Each EPR voter is invited to grade one or more of the candidate's suitability for office as one of: Excellent (ideal), Very Good, Good, Acceptable, Poor, or Reject (entirely unsuitable). Multiple candidates may be given the same grade by a voter. Each citizen is assured that their one vote will equally increase the voting power of the elected member of the legislature who received either their highest grade, remaining highest grade, or proxy vote. Each elected member has a weighted vote in the legislative body exactly equal to the number of citizens' ballots exclusively counted for them. Using EPR, each citizen elects their representative at-large for a city council. For a large and diverse state legislature, each citizen chooses to vote through any of the districts or official non-geographically defined electoral associations in the country. Each voter grades any number of candidates in the whole country. Each member's weighted vote results from receiving one of the following from each voter: their highest grade, highest remaining grade, or proxy vote. Each citizen's vote equally adds to the voting power in the legislative body of the elected candidate they see as most likely to represent their hopes and concerns accurately. Also, each self-identifying minority or majority, is proportionally represented exactly. Like majority judgment, EPR reduces by almost half both the incentives and possibilities for voters to use Tactical Voting.

History

One of the earliest proposals of proportionality in an assembly was by John Adams in his influential pamphlet Thoughts on Government, written in 1776 during the American Revolution:

It should be in miniature, an exact portrait of the people at large. It should think, feel, reason, and act like them. That it may be the interest of this Assembly to do strict justice at all times, it should be an equal representation, or in other words equal interest among the people should have equal interest in it.[109]

Mirabeau, speaking to the Assembly of Provence on January 30, 1789, was also an early proponent of a proportionally representative assembly:[110]

A representative body is to the nation what a chart is for the physical configuration of its soil: in all its parts, and as a whole, the representative body should at all times present a reduced picture of the people, their opinions, aspirations, and wishes, and that presentation should bear the relative proportion to the original precisely.

In February 1793, the Marquis de Condorcet led the drafting of the Girondist constitution which proposed a limited voting scheme with proportional aspects. Before that could be voted on, the Montagnards took over the National Convention and produced their own constitution. On June 24, Saint-Just proposed the single non-transferable vote, which can be proportional, for national elections but the constitution was passed on the same day specifying first-past-the-post voting.[110]

Already in 1787, James Wilson, like Adams a US Founding Father, understood the importance of multiple-member districts: "Bad elections proceed from the smallness of the districts which give an opportunity to bad men to intrigue themselves into office",[111] and again, in 1791, in his Lectures on Law: "It may, I believe, be assumed as a general maxim, of no small importance in democratical governments, that the more extensive the district of election is, the choice will be the more wise and enlightened".[112] The 1790 Constitution of Pennsylvania specified multiple-member districts for the state Senate and required their boundaries to follow county lines.[113]

STV or more precisely, an election method where voters have one transferable vote, was first invented in 1819 by an English schoolmaster, Thomas Wright Hill, who devised a "plan of election" for the committee of the Society for Literary and Scientific Improvement in Birmingham that used not only transfers of surplus votes from winners but also from losers, a refinement that later both Andræ and Hare initially omitted. But the procedure was unsuitable for a public election and was not publicised. In 1839, Hill's son, Rowland Hill, recommended the concept for public elections in Adelaide, and a simple process was used in which voters formed as many groups as there were representatives to be elected, each group electing one representative.[110]

The first practical PR election method, the List Plan system, was conceived by Thomas Gilpin, a retired paper-mill owner, in a paper he read to the American Philosophical Society in Philadelphia in 1844: "On the representation of minorities of electors to act with the majority in elected assemblies". It was never put into practical use, but even as late as 1914 it was put forward as a way to elect the U.S. electoral college delegates and for local elections.[110][114][115]

A practical election using the Single Transferable Vote system (a combination of preferential voting and multi-member districts) was devised in Denmark by Carl Andræ, a mathematician, and first used there in 1855, making it the oldest PR system. That system was later adopted for national elections in Malta (1921), the Republic of Ireland (1921) and Australia (1948).

STV was also invented (apparently independently) in the UK in 1857 by Thomas Hare, a London barrister, in his pamphlet The Machinery of Representation and expanded on in his 1859 Treatise on the Election of Representatives. The scheme was enthusiastically taken up by John Stuart Mill, ensuring international interest. The 1865 edition of the book included the transfer of preferences from dropped candidates and the STV method was essentially complete, although Hare pictured the entire British Isles as one single district. Mill proposed it to the House of Commons in 1867, but the British parliament rejected it. The name evolved from "Mr.Hare's scheme" to "proportional representation", then "proportional representation with the single transferable vote", and finally, by the end of the 19th century, to "the single transferable vote".

In Australia, the political activist Catherine Helen Spence became an enthusiast of STV and an author on the subject. Through her influence and the efforts of the Tasmanian politician Andrew Inglis Clark, Tasmania became an early pioneer of the system, electing the world's first legislators through STV in 1896, prior to its federation into Australia.[116]

A party-list proportional representation system was devised and described in 1878 by Victor D'Hondt in Belgium, which became the first country to adopt list PR in 1900 for its national parliament. D'Hondt's method of seat allocation, the D'Hondt method, is still widely used. Some Swiss cantons (beginning with Ticino in 1890) used the system before Belgium. Victor Considerant, a utopian socialist, devised a similar system in an 1892 book. Many European countries adopted similar systems during or after World War I. List PR was favoured on the Continent because the use of lists in elections, the scrutin de liste, was already widespread. STV was preferred in the English-speaking world because its tradition was the election of individuals.[36]

In the UK, the 1917 Speaker's Conference recommended STV for all multi-seat Westminster constituencies, but it was only applied to university constituencies, lasting from 1918 until 1950 when those constituencies were abolished.

In Ireland, STV was used in 1918 in the Dublin University constituency, and was introduced for devolved elections in 1921.

STV is currently used for two national lower houses of parliament, Ireland, since independence (as the Irish Free State) in 1922,[4] and Malta, since 1921, long before independence in 1966.[117] In Ireland, two attempts were made by Fianna Fáil governments to abolish STV and replace it with the 'First Past the Post' plurality system. Both attempts were rejected by voters in referendums held in 1959 and again in 1968. STV is also prescribed for all other elections in Ireland including that of the presidency, although it is there effectively the alternative vote, as it is an election with a single winner.

It is also used for the Northern Ireland Assembly and European and local authorities, Scottish local authorities, some New Zealand and Australian local authorities,[35] the Tasmanian (since 1907) and Australian Capital Territory assemblies, where the method is known as Hare-Clark,[118] and the city council in Cambridge, Massachusetts, (since 1941).[8][119]

PR is used by a majority of the world's 33 most robust democracies with populations of at least two million people; only six use plurality or a majoritarian system (runoff or instant runoff) for elections to the legislative assembly, four use parallel systems, and 23 use PR.[120] PR dominates Europe, including Germany and most of northern and eastern Europe; it is also used for European Parliament elections. France adopted PR at the end of World War II, but discarded it in 1958; it was used for parliament elections in 1986. Switzerland has the most widespread use of proportional representation, which is the system used to elect not only national legislatures and local councils, but also all local executives. PR is less common in the English-speaking world; Malta and Ireland use STV for election of legislators. Australia uses it for Senate elections. New Zealand adopted MMP in 1993. But UK, Canada and India use plurality (First Past the Post) systems for legislative elections. In Canada, STV was used to elect provincial legislators in Alberta from 1926 to 1955, and in Manitoba from 1920 to 1953. In both provinces the alternative vote (AV) was used in rural areas. First-past-the-post was re-adopted in Alberta by the dominant party for reasons of political advantage. In Manitoba a principal reason was the underrepresentation of Winnipeg in the provincial legislature.[110]: 223–234 [121]

STV has some history in the United States. Between 1915 and 1962, twenty-four cities used the system for at least one election. In many cities, minority parties and other groups used STV to break up single-party monopolies on elective office. One of the most famous cases is New York City, where a coalition of Republicans and others pursued the adoption of STV in 1936 as part of an effort to free the city from control by the Tammany Hall machine.[122] Another famous case is Cincinnati, Ohio, where, in 1924, Democrats and Progressive-wing Republicans secured the adoption of a council-manager charter with STV elections in order to dislodge the Republican machine of Rudolph K. Hynicka. Although Cincinnati's council-manager system survives, Republicans and other disaffected groups replaced STV with plurality-at-large voting in 1957.[123] From 1870 to 1980, Illinois used a semi-proportional cumulative voting system to elect its House of Representatives. Each district across the state elected both Republicans and Democrats year-after-year.

Cambridge, Massachusetts (STV), and Peoria, Illinois (cumulative voting), have used PR for many years now.

San Francisco (before 1977 and 1980–1999) had citywide elections in which people cast votes for as many as nine candidates, but usually five or six candidates, simultaneously (block voting), delivering some of the benefits of proportional representation through the use of a multi-member district. San Francisco used preferential voting (Bucklin Voting) in its 1917 city election.

List of countries using proportional representation

List of countries using proportional representation to elect the lower (or only) house of national legislature
 
  Party-list PR
  Single transferable vote
  Mixed-member proportional
  Mixed-member majoritarian

Eighty-five countries in the world use a proportional electoral system to fill a nationally elected legislative body.

The table below lists those countries and gives information on the specific PR system that is in use.

Detailed information on electoral systems applying to the first chamber of the legislature is maintained by the ACE Electoral Knowledge Network.[124][125] Countries using PR as part of a mixed-member majoritarian (e.g. parallel voting) system are not included.

Country Body Type of body Type of proportional system List type

(if applicable)

Variation of open lists

(if applicable)

Allocating formula Electoral threshold Constituencies Governmental system Notes
Albania Parliament (Kuvendi) Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Open list ? Highest averages method
(D'Hondt method)
4% nationally or 2.5% in a district Counties
Algeria People's National Assembly Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list ? Largest remainder method(Hare quota) 5% of votes in respective district.[126]
Angola National Assembly Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Closed list
Highest averages method
(D'Hondt method)
[citation needed] 5 member districts and nationwide Double simultaneous vote use to elect the President and the National Assembly at the same election.
Argentina Chamber of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Closed list
Highest averages method
(D'Hondt method)
3% of registered voters
Armenia National Assembly Party-list PR with majority jackpot and minority jackpot [127] Open list ? Largest remainder method (? quota) 5% (parties), 7% (blocs) Party lists run-off, but only if necessary to ensure stable majority of 54% if it is not achieved either immediately (one party) or through building a coalition.[128][129] If a party would win more than 2/3 seats, at least 1/3 seats are distributed to the other parties.
Closed list
Largest remainder method (? quota)
Aruba (Kingdom of the Netherlands) Party-list PR
Australia Senate Upper house of national legislature Single transferable vote (STV)
Austria National Council Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list More open:

14% on the district level (among votes for the candidates party)

Largest remainder method (Hare quota) 4% Single-member districts within federal states (Länder) Parliamentary republic
Open list More open:

10% on the regional (state) level (among votes for the candidates party)

Largest remainder method(Hare quota) Federal states (Länder)
Open list More open: 7% of the on the federal level (among votes for the candidates party) Highest averages method
(D'Hondt method)
Single federal (nationwide) constituency
Belgium Party-list PR 5%
Bénin Party-list PR
Bolivia Chamber of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Additional member system (AMS) - MMP (fixed number of seats - no leveling seats) Closed list 3% Ballots use the double simultaneous vote: voters cast a single vote for a presidential candidate and their party's list and local candidates at the same time (vote splitting is not possible/allowed)
Chamber of Senators Upper house of national legislature Party-list PR Closed list Highest averages method
(D'Hondt method)
Bosnia and Herzegovina Party-list PR
Brazil Chamber of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list ? States and Federal District Presidential Republic
Bulgaria Party-list PR 4%
Burkina Faso Party-list PR
Burundi Party-list PR 2%
Cambodia Party-list PR
Cape Verde Party-list PR
Chile Party-list PR
Colombia Party-list PR
Costa Rica Party-list PR
Croatia Party-list PR 5%
Cyprus Party-list PR
Czech Republic Party-list PR 5%
Denmark Folketing Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Open list Highest averages method
(D'Hondt method)
2% Parliamentary system 135 constituency seats, 40 leveling seats
Dominican Republic Party-list PR
East Timor Party-list PR
El Salvador Party-list PR
Equatorial Guinea Party-list PR
Estonia Party-list PR 5%
European Union European Parliament Lower house of supranational legislature varies by state Party-list PR in 25 member states
Single transferable vote (STV) in Ireland and Malta
Faroe Islands Party-list PR
Fiji Party-list PR 5%
Finland Party-list PR
Germany Mixed-member proportional representation (MMP) Closed list
5% regionally

(or 3 district winners)

Greece Party-list PR 3% Nationwide closed lists and open lists in multi-member districts. The winning party used to receive a majority bonus of 50 seats (out of 300), but this system will be abolished two elections after 2016.[130] In 2020 parliament voted to return to the majority bonus two elections thereafter.[131]
Greenland Party-list PR
Guatemala Party-list PR
Guinea-Bissau Party-list PR
Guyana Party-list PR
Honduras Party-list PR
Iceland Party-list PR
Indonesia Party-list PR 4%
Ireland Lower house of national legislature Single transferable vote (STV)
Israel Party-list PR 3.25%
Kosovo Party-list PR
Latvia Saeima Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Open list Most open Highest averages method
(Sainte-Laguë method)
5% 5 multi-member constituencies consisting of municipalities[132] Parliamentary republic
Lebanon Party-list PR
Lesotho Mixed-member proportional representation (MMP) variant using a mixed single vote
Liechtenstein Party-list PR 8%
Luxembourg Party-list PR
Macedonia Party-list PR
Malta Single transferable vote (STV)
Moldova Party-list PR 6%
Montenegro Party-list PR 3%
Mozambique Party-list PR
Namibia Party-list PR
Netherlands Party-list PR
New Zealand Mixed-member proportional representation (MMP) 5%

or 1 district won

Nepal Mixed list 3%
Norway Party-list PR 4%
Paraguay Party-list PR
Peru Party-list PR 5%
Poland Party-list PR 5% threshold or more for single parties, 8% or more for coalitions or 0% or more for minorities
Portugal Party-list PR
Romania Party-list PR
Rwanda Party-list PR
San Marino Party-list PR 3.5% If needed to ensure a stable majority, the two best-placed parties participate in a run-off vote to receive a majority bonus.
São Tomé and Príncipe Party-list PR
Serbia Party-list PR 3%
Sint Maarten Party-list PR
Slovakia Party-list PR 5%
Slovenia Party-list PR 4%
South Africa Party-list PR
Spain Congress of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR[133] Closed list
Highest averages method
(D'Hondt method)
3% Provinces of Spain Parliamentary system
Sri Lanka Parliament Party-list PR[134][135][136] Open list
(for 196/225 seats)
Panachage
(up to 3 preference votes)[137]
Highest averages method
(D'Hondt method)
12.5%
(per constituency)
Constituencies Semi-presidential system
Closed list
(for 29/225 seats)
? No threshold None
(single nationwide constituency)
Suriname National Assembly Party-list PR[138] Open list Most open Highest averages method
(D'Hondt method)
No threshold Districts of Suriname Assembly-independent republic
Sweden Riksdag Party-list PR[139][140] Open list More open
(5% of the party vote to override the default party-list)[141]
Highest averages method
(Sainte-Laguë method)
4% nationally or 12%
in a given constituency
Counties of Sweden
(some counties are further subdivided)
Parliamentary system Leveling seats
Switzerland National Council Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR[142] Open list Panachage Highest averages method
(Modified D'Hondt method: Hagenbach-Bischoff system)
No threshold Cantons of Switzerland Semi-direct democracy under an assembly-independent[143][144] directorial republic
Council of States
(only to elect Councillors in:
Party-list PR[146] Open list Most open ? No threshold[147] None
(single cantonwide constituency)[148]
Thailand House of Representatives Lower house of national legislature Mixed-member proportional representation[149] Closed list
Largest remainder method (? quota) No threshold None
(single nationwide constituency)
Parliamentary system
under a constitutional monarchy
Next elections are to be held under parallel voting
Togo National Assembly Party-list PR[150] Closed list
Highest averages method (?) No threshold Constituencies Presidential system
Tunisia Assembly of the Representatives of the People Party-list PR[151] Closed list
Largest remainder method (? quota) No threshold Constituencies Semi-presidential system
Turkey Grand National Assembly Party-list PR[152] Closed list
Highest averages method
(D'Hondt method)
7% Provinces of Turkey
(some provinces are further subdivided)
Presidential system
Uruguay Chamber of Representatives Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR[153][154] Closed list
Highest averages method
(D'Hondt method)
No threshold Departments of Uruguay Presidential system Ballots use the double simultaneous vote, the same ballot is used for electing the president (first round) and the two chambers
Chamber of Senators Upper house of national legislature None
(single nationwide constituency)

Incentives for choosing an electoral system

Changing the electoral system requires the agreement of a majority of the currently selected legislators, who were chosen using the incumbent electoral system. Therefore, an interesting question is what incentives make current legislators support a new electoral system, particularly a PR system.

Many political scientists argue that PR was adopted by parties on the right as a strategy to survive amid suffrage expansion, democratization and the rise of workers' parties. According to Stein Rokkan in a seminal 1970 study, parties on the right opted to adopt PR as a way to survive as competitive parties in situations when the parties on the right were not united enough to exist under majoritarian systems.[155] This argument was formalized and supported by Carles Boix in a 1999 study.[156] Amel Ahmed notes that prior to the adoption of PR, many electoral systems were based on majority or plurality rule, and that these systems risked eradicating parties on the right in areas where the working class was large in numbers. He therefore argues that parties on the right adopted PR as a way to ensure that they would survive as potent political forces amid suffrage expansion.[157] A 2021 study linked the adoption of PR to incumbent fears of revolutionary threats.[158]

In contrast, other scholars argue that the choice to adopt PR was also due to a demand by parties on the left to ensure a foothold in politics, as well as to encourage a consensual system that would help the left realize its preferred economic policies.[159]

See also

References

  1. ^ a b c Mill, John Stuart (1861). "Chapter VII, Of True and False Democracy; Representation of All, and Representation of the Majority only". Considerations on Representative Government. London: Parker, Son, & Bourn.
  2. ^ ACE Project: The Electoral Knowledge Network. "Electoral Systems Comparative Data, Table by Question". Retrieved 20 November 2014.
  3. ^ a b Amy, Douglas J. "How Proportional Representation Elections Work". FairVote. Retrieved 26 October 2017.
  4. ^ a b c Gallagher, Michael. "Ireland: The Archetypal Single Transferable Vote System" (PDF). Retrieved 26 October 2014.
  5. ^ Hirczy de Miño, Wolfgang, University of Houston; Lane, John, State University of New York at Buffalo (1999). "Malta: STV in a two-party system" (PDF). Retrieved 24 July 2014.
  6. ^ Laakso, Markku (1980). "Electoral Justice as a Criterion for Different Systems of Proportional Representation". Scandinavian Political Studies. Wiley. 3 (3): 249–264. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9477.1980.tb00248.x. ISSN 0080-6757.
  7. ^ "Proportional Representation (PR)". ACE Electoral Knowledge Network. Retrieved 9 April 2014.
  8. ^ a b c Amy, Douglas J. "A Brief History of Proportional Representation in the United States". FairVote. Retrieved 16 October 2015.
  9. ^ a b c d e Forder, James (2011). The case against voting reform. Oxford: Oneworld Publications. ISBN 978-1-85168-825-8.
  10. ^ Abbott, Lewis F. British Democracy: Its Restoration and Extension. ISR/Kindle Books, 2019. ISBN 9780906321522. Chapter 7, "Electoral System Reform: Increasing Competition and Voter Choice and Influence".
  11. ^ 2020 Irish general election]]
  12. ^ Koriyama, Y.; Macé, A.; Laslier, J.-F.; Treibich, R. (2013). "Optimal apportionment". Journal of Political Economy. 121 (3): 584–608. doi:10.1086/670380. S2CID 10158811.
  13. ^ Amy, Douglas. "Proportional Representation Voting Systems". Fairvote.org. Takoma Park. Retrieved 25 August 2017.
  14. ^ a b c d Norris, Pippa (1997). (PDF). International Political Science Review. Harvard University. 18 (3): 297–312. doi:10.1177/019251297018003005. ISSN 0192-5121. S2CID 9523715. Archived from the original on 2015-04-01. Retrieved 9 April 2014.
  15. ^ Colin Rallings; Michael Thrasher. (PDF). Electoral Commission, Research, Electoral data. London: Electoral Commission. Archived from the original (PDF) on 20 October 2017. Retrieved 29 March 2015.
  16. ^ a b c Commission On Electoral Reform, Hansard Society for Parliamentary Government (1976). "Report of the Hansard Society Commission on Electoral Reform". Hansard Society. London.
  17. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r s "Electoral System Design: the New International IDEA Handbook". International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance. 2005. Retrieved 9 April 2014.
  18. ^ "1993 Canadian Federal Election Results". University of British Columbia. Retrieved 25 January 2016.
  19. ^ "Election 2015 - BBC News". BBC. Retrieved 11 May 2015.
  20. ^ Ana Nicolaci da Costa; Charlotte Greenfield (September 23, 2017). "New Zealand's ruling party ahead after poll but kingmaker in no rush to decide". Reuters.
  21. ^ Roberts, Iain (29 June 2010). "People in broad church parties should think twice before attacking coalitions". Liberal Democrat Voice. Retrieved 29 July 2014.
  22. ^ a b c "A look at the evidence". Fair Vote Canada. Retrieved 2 January 2019.
  23. ^ Amy, Douglas J. "Single Transferable Vote Or Choice Voting". FairVote. Retrieved 9 April 2014.
  24. ^ "Electoral Reform Society's evidence to the Joint Committee on the Draft Bill for House of Lords Reform". Electoral Reform Society. 21 October 2011. Retrieved 10 May 2015.
  25. ^ Harris, Paul (20 November 2011). "'America is better than this': paralysis at the top leaves voters desperate for change". The Guardian. Retrieved 17 November 2014.
  26. ^ Krugman, Paul (19 May 2012). "Going To Extreme". The Conscience of a Liberal, Paul Krugman Blog. The New York Times Co. Retrieved 24 Nov 2014.
  27. ^ a b c d e f g h Mollison, Denis. "Fair votes in practice STV for Westminster" (PDF). Heriot Watt University. Retrieved 3 June 2014.
  28. ^ "Democrats' Edge in House Popular Vote Would Have Increased if All Seats Had Been Contested". FairVote. Retrieved 7 July 2014.
  29. ^ Cox, Gary W.; Fiva, Jon H.; Smith, Daniel M. (2016). "The Contraction Effect: How Proportional Representation Affects Mobilization and Turnout" (PDF). The Journal of Politics. 78 (4): 1249–1263. doi:10.1086/686804. hdl:11250/2429132. S2CID 55400647.
  30. ^ a b c d Amy, Douglas J (2002). Real Choices / New Voices, How Proportional Representation Elections Could Revitalize American Democracy. Columbia University Press. ISBN 9780231125499.
  31. ^ Mollison, Denis (2010). "Fair votes in practice: STV for Westminster". Heriot-Watt University. Retrieved 3 June 2014.
  32. ^ Scheppele, Kim Lane (April 13, 2014). "Legal But Not Fair (Hungary)". The Conscience of a Liberal, Paul Krugman Blog. The New York Times Co. Retrieved 12 July 2014.
  33. ^ Office for Democratic Institutions and Human Rights (11 July 2014). "Hungary, Parliamentary Elections, 6 April 2014: Final Report". OSCE.
  34. ^ "Voting Counts: Electoral Reform for Canada" (PDF). Law Commission of Canada. 2004. p. 22.
  35. ^ a b "Single Transferable Vote". London: Electoral Reform Society. Retrieved 28 July 2014.
  36. ^ a b Humphreys, John H (1911). Proportional Representation, A Study in Methods of Election. London: Methuen & Co.Ltd.
  37. ^ (Dutch) "Evenredige vertegenwoordiging". www.parlement.com (in Dutch). Retrieved 2020-01-28. {{cite web}}: Check |url= value (help)
  38. ^ Carey, John M.; Hix, Simon (2011). "The Electoral Sweet Spot: Low-Magnitude Proportional Electoral Systems" (PDF). American Journal of Political Science. 55 (2): 383–397. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2010.00495.x.
  39. ^ "Electoral reform in Chile: Tie breaker". The Economist. 14 February 2015. Retrieved 11 April 2018.
  40. ^ a b Laver, Michael (1998). "A new electoral system for Ireland?" (PDF). The Policy Institute, Trinity College Dublin.
  41. ^ "Joint Committee on the Constitution" (PDF). Dublin: Houses of the Oireachtas. July 2010.
  42. ^ "National projections" (PDF). Monopoly Politics 2014 and the Fair Voting Solution. FairVote. Retrieved 9 July 2014.
  43. ^ "Turkey reduces election threshold to 7 percent - Türkiye News". Hürriyet Daily News. Retrieved 2023-03-19.
  44. ^ Lubell, Maayan (March 11, 2014). "Israel ups threshold for Knesset seats despite opposition boycott". Thomson Reuters. Retrieved 10 July 2014.
  45. ^ Benoit, Kenneth. "Which Electoral Formula Is the Most Proportional?" (PDF). doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.pan.a029822. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2010-06-24
  46. ^ a b A Report on Alberta Elections, 1905-1982
  47. ^ "Party Magnitude and Candidate Selection". ACE Electoral Knowledge Network.
  48. ^ O'Kelly, Michael. "The fall of Fianna Fáil in the 2011 Irish general election". Significance. Royal Statistical Society, American Statistical Association. Archived from the original on 2014-08-06.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  49. ^ Hoag and Hallett, Proportional Representation, p. 74
  50. ^ Karpov, Alexander (2008). "Measurement of disproportionality in proportional representation systems". Mathematical and Computer Modelling. 48 (9–10): 1421–1438. doi:10.1016/j.mcm.2008.05.027.
  51. ^ Dunleavy, Patrick; Margetts, Helen (2004). "How proportional are the 'British AMS' systems?". Representation. 40 (4): 317–329. doi:10.1080/00344890408523280. S2CID 154404168. Retrieved 25 November 2014.
  52. ^ "2020 GENERAL ELECTION - OFFICIAL RESULTS AND STATISTICS". ElectionResults.govt.nz. Electoral Commission. 30 November 2020.
  53. ^ Wada, Junichiro (2016). "Apportionment behind the veil of uncertainty". The Japanese Economic Review. 67 (3): 348–360. doi:10.1111/jere.12093. S2CID 156608434.
  54. ^ Canadian House of Commons Special Committee on Electoral Reform (December 2016). "Strengthening Democracy in Canada: Principles, Process and Public Engagement for Electoral Reform".
  55. ^ "polrep: Calculate Political Representation Scores version 0.32.7 from R-Forge". rdrr.io. Retrieved 2021-04-18.
  56. ^ Kestelman, Philip (March 1999). "Quantifying Representativity". Voting Matters (10). Retrieved 10 August 2013.
  57. ^ Hill, I D (May 1997). "Measuring proportionality". Voting Matters (8).
  58. ^ As counted from the table in http://www.wahlrecht.de/ausland/europa.htm [in German]; "Vorzugsstimme(n)" means "open list".
  59. ^ "Party List PR". Electoral Reform Society. Retrieved 23 May 2016.
  60. ^ Gordon Gibson (2003). Fixing Canadian Democracy. The Fraser Institute. p. 76. ISBN 9780889752016.
  61. ^ Gallagher, Michael; Mitchell, Paul (2005). The Politics of Electoral Systems. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press. p. 11. ISBN 978-0-19-925756-0.
  62. ^ "The Parliamentary Electoral System in Denmark". Copenhagen: Ministry of the Interior and Health. 2011. Retrieved 1 Sep 2014.
  63. ^ "The main features of the Norwegian electoral system". Oslo: Ministry of Local Government and Modernisation. 2017-07-06. Retrieved 1 Sep 2014.
  64. ^ . Stockholm: Election Authority. 2011. Archived from the original on 18 August 2014. Retrieved 1 Sep 2014.
  65. ^ ACE Project Electoral Knowledge Network. "Mixed Systems". Retrieved 29 June 2016.
  66. ^ Massicotte, Louis (2004). In Search of Compensatory Mixed Electoral System for Québec (PDF) (Report).
  67. ^ Bochsler, Daniel (May 13, 2010). "Chapter 5, How Party Systems Develop in Mixed Electoral Systems". Territory and Electoral Rules in Post-Communist Democracies. Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 9780230281424.
  68. ^ "Electoral Systems and the Delimitation of Constituencies". International Foundation for Electoral Systems. 2 Jul 2009.
  69. ^ Moser, Robert G. (December 2004). "Mixed electoral systems and electoral system effects: controlled comparison and cross-national analysis". Electoral Studies. 23 (4): 575–599. doi:10.1016/S0261-3794(03)00056-8.
  70. ^ Massicotte, Louis (September 1999). "Mixed electoral systems: a conceptual and empirical survey". Electoral Studies. 18 (3): 341–366. doi:10.1016/S0261-3794(98)00063-8.
  71. ^ "Additional Member System". London: Electoral Reform Society. Retrieved 16 October 2015.
  72. ^ "MMP Voting System". Wellington: Electoral Commission New Zealand. 2011. Retrieved 10 Aug 2014.
  73. ^ "Deutschland hat ein neues Wahlrecht" (in German). Zeit Online. 22 February 2013.
  74. ^ . Wellington: Electoral Commission New Zealand. 2011. Archived from the original on 7 July 2014. Retrieved 10 Aug 2014.
  75. ^ Graham, Sean (2016). "Dual-Member Mixed Proportional: A New Electoral System for Canada". doi:10.7939/R3-QPPP-B676. Retrieved 2022-08-10. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  76. ^ Antony Hodgson (Jan 21, 2016). "Why a referendum on electoral reform would be undemocratic". The Tyee.
  77. ^ Kerry Campbell (April 15, 2016). "P.E.I. electoral reform committee proposes ranked ballot". CBC News.
  78. ^ Elections PEI (November 7, 2016). . Archived from the original on November 8, 2016. Retrieved October 26, 2017.
  79. ^ Susan Bradley (November 7, 2016). "P.E.I. plebiscite favours mixed member proportional representation". CBC News.
  80. ^ Eby, David (May 30, 2018). (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on August 31, 2018. Retrieved June 9, 2018.
  81. ^ McElroy, Justin (June 2, 2018). "Know your voting systems: three types of electoral reform on B.C.'s ballot". CBC News.
  82. ^ "2018 Referendum on Electoral Reform: Voting Results Available". Elections BC. 20 December 2018. Retrieved November 1, 2020.
  83. ^ Pukelsheim, Friedrich (September 2009). "Zurich's New Apportionment" (PDF). German Research. 31 (2): 10–12. doi:10.1002/germ.200990024. Retrieved 10 August 2014.
  84. ^ a b Balinski, Michel (February 2008). "Fair Majority Voting (or How to Eliminate Gerrymandering)". The American Mathematical Monthly. 115 (2): 97–113. doi:10.1080/00029890.2008.11920503. S2CID 1139441. Retrieved 10 August 2014.
  85. ^ Akartunalı, Kerem; Knight, Philip A. (June 2017). "Network models and biproportional rounding for fair seat allocations in the UK elections". Annals of Operations Research. University of Strathclyde. 253 (1): 1–19. doi:10.1007/s10479-016-2323-0. ISSN 0254-5330. S2CID 30623821. Retrieved 10 August 2014.
  86. ^ "Fair Voting/Proportional Representation". FairVote. Retrieved 9 April 2014.
  87. ^ a b c Tideman, Nicolaus (1995). "The Single Transferable Vote". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 9 (1): 27–38. doi:10.1257/jep.9.1.27.
  88. ^ O’Neill, Jeffrey C. (July 2006). "Comments on the STV Rules Proposed by British Columbia". Voting Matters (22). Retrieved 10 August 2013.
  89. ^ Model City Charter National Civic League. 9th edition. 2021
  90. ^ a b David M. Farrell; Ian McAllister (2006). The Australian Electoral System: Origins, Variations, and Consequences. Sydney: UNSW Press. ISBN 978-0868408583.
  91. ^ "Referendum 2011: A look at the STV system". The New Zealand Herald. Auckland: The New Zealand Herald. 1 Nov 2011. Retrieved 21 Nov 2014.
  92. ^ "Change the Way We Elect? Round Two of the Debate". The Tyee. Vancouver. 30 Apr 2009. Retrieved 21 Nov 2014.
  93. ^ Brill, Markus; Laslier, Jean-François; Skowron, Piotr (2016). "Multiwinner Approval Rules as Apportionment Methods". arXiv:1611.08691 [cs.GT].
  94. ^ a b Smith, Warren (18 June 2006). "Comparative survey of multiwinner election methods" (PDF).
  95. ^ Aziz, Haris; Serge Gaspers, Joachim Gudmundsson, Simon Mackenzie, Nicholas Mattei, Toby Walsh (2014). "Computational Aspects of Multi-Winner Approval Voting". Proceedings of the 2015 International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems. pp. 107–115. arXiv:1407.3247v1. ISBN 978-1-4503-3413-6.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  96. ^ Faliszewski, Piotr; Skowron, Piotr; Szufa, Stanisław; Talmon, Nimrod (2019-05-08). "Proportional Representation in Elections: STV vs PAV". Proceedings of the 18th International Conference on Autonomous Agents and MultiAgent Systems. AAMAS '19. Richland, SC: International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems: 1946–1948. ISBN 978-1-4503-6309-9.
  97. ^ Lackner, Martin; Skowron, Piotr (2023). Multi-Winner Voting with Approval Preferences. SpringerBriefs in Intelligent Systems. arXiv:2007.01795. doi:10.1007/978-3-031-09016-5. ISBN 978-3-031-09015-8. S2CID 244921148.
  98. ^ Kok, Jan; Smith, Warren. "Reweighted Range Voting – a Proportional Representation voting method that feels like range voting". Retrieved 4 April 2016.
  99. ^ Ryan, Ivan. "Reweighted Range Voting – a Proportional Representation voting method that feels like range voting". Retrieved 4 April 2016.
  100. ^ "89th Annual Academy Awards of Merit for Achievements during 2017" (PDF). Retrieved 4 April 2016.
  101. ^ . Archived from the original on 14 September 2012. Retrieved 4 April 2016.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  102. ^ Sargent, Felix (2019-06-19). "Opinion: Berkeley's City Council's switch to 're-weighted range voting' adds fairness to the system". Berkeleyside. Retrieved 2022-05-11.
  103. ^ Smith, Warren (8 March 2005). ""Asset voting" scheme for multiwinner elections" (PDF).
  104. ^ Dodgson, Charles (1884). "The Principles of Parliamentary Representation". London: Harrison and Sons. Retrieved 28 June 2019. The Elector must understand that, in giving his vote to A, he gives it to him as his absolute property, to use for himself, or to transfer to other Candidates, or to leave unused.
  105. ^ Smith, Warren. "Asset voting – an interesting and very simple multiwinner voting system". Retrieved 4 April 2016.
  106. ^ Balinski, M. & Laraki R., 2011 Majority Judgment, MIT; pp. 389 and 394.
  107. ^ Bosworth, S. et al., 2020.Electing Legislatures by Evaluative Proportional Representation (EPR): An Algorithm. https://www.jpolrisk.com/legislatures-elected-by-evaluative-proportional-representation-epr-an-algorithm-v3/. 14 February 2023.
  108. ^ M. Balinski & R. Laraki (2010). Majority Judgment. MIT. ISBN 978-0-262-01513-4.
  109. ^ Adams, John (1776). "Thoughts on Government". The Adams Papers Digital Edition. Massachusetts Historical Society. Retrieved 26 July 2014.
  110. ^ a b c d e Hoag, Clarence; Hallett, George (1926). Proportional Representation. New York: The Macmillan Company.
  111. ^ Madison, James. "Notes of Debates in the Federal Convention of 1787, Wednesday, June 6". TeachingAmericanHistory.org. Retrieved 5 August 2014.
  112. ^ Wilson, James (1804). "Vol 2, Part II, Ch.1 Of the constitutions of the United States and of Pennsylvania – Of the legislative department, I, of the election of its members". The Works of the Honourable James Wilson. Constitution Society. Retrieved 5 August 2014.
  113. ^ "Constitution of the Commonwealth of Pennsylvania – 1790, art.I,§ VII, Of districts for electing Senators". Duquesne University. Retrieved 9 December 2014.
  114. ^ Hoag, Effective Voting (1914), p. 31
  115. ^ Swain, Civics for Montana Students, 1912, p. 163
  116. ^ Newman, Hare-Clark in Tasmania, p. 7-10
  117. ^ Hirczy de Miño, Wolfgang (1997). "Malta: Single-Transferable Vote with Some Twists". ACE Electoral Knowledge Network. Retrieved 5 Dec 2014.
  118. ^ "The Hare-Clark System of Proportional Representation". Melbourne: Proportional Representation Society of Australia. Retrieved 21 Nov 2014.
  119. ^ . Welcome to the City of Cambridge. City of Cambridge, MA. Archived from the original on 13 December 2014. Retrieved 25 November 2014.
  120. ^ "Proportional Representation in Most Robust Democracies". Fair Vote: The Center for Voting And Democracy. 7 March 2016. Retrieved 9 October 2017.
  121. ^ Jansen, Harold John (1998). "The Single Transferable Vote in Alberta and Manitoba" (PDF). Library and Archives Canada. University of Alberta. Retrieved 23 March 2015.
  122. ^ Santucci, Jack (2016-11-10). "Party Splits, Not Progressives". American Politics Research. 45 (3): 494–526. doi:10.1177/1532673x16674774. ISSN 1532-673X. S2CID 157400899.
  123. ^ Barber, Kathleen (1995). Proportional Representation and Election Reform in Ohio. Columbus, OH: Ohio State University Press. ISBN 978-0814206607.
  124. ^ ACE Project: The Electoral Knowledge Network. "Electoral Systems Comparative Data, World Map". Retrieved 24 October 2017.
  125. ^ ACE Project: The Electoral Knowledge Network. "Electoral Systems Comparative Data, Table by Country". Retrieved 24 October 2017.
  126. ^ "FINAL REPORT ON ALGERIA'S LEGISLATIVE ELECTIONS" (pdf). ACE Project. National Democratic Institute. 10 May 2012. Retrieved 10 January 2015.
  127. ^ Following electoral system amendments introduced in April 2021, members of parliament are elected only through closed party lists by party list proportional representation method but with more seats added if leading party takes more than 2/3 of seats or after two-round of voting no party takes more than 54 percent of the seats
  128. ^ "Armenia, Parliamentary Elections, 2 April 2017: Needs Assessment Mission Report". www.osce.org. Retrieved 2022-05-30.
  129. ^ "DocumentView". www.arlis.am.
  130. ^ "Greek MPs approve end to bonus seats, lower voting age". Reuters. 2016-07-21. Retrieved 2019-06-22.
  131. ^ "Parliament votes to change election law | Kathimerini". www.ekathimerini.com. Retrieved 2020-01-25.
  132. ^ "Saeimas vēlēšanu likums". LIKUMI.LV (in Latvian). Section 7. Retrieved 2022-06-10.
  133. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SPAIN (Congreso de los Diputados), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  134. ^ "IFES Election Guide | Elections: Sri Lanka Parliament 2020". www.electionguide.org.
  135. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SRI LANKA (Parliament), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  136. ^ (PDF). www.ndi.org. Archived from the original (PDF) on 3 March 2016. Retrieved 12 January 2022.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  137. ^ "Sri Lanka electors can vote for one party, three preferences in 2020 general elections: polls chief". EconomyNext. August 4, 2020.
  138. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SURINAME (Nationale Assemblee), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  139. ^ "IFES Election Guide | Elections: Sweden Parliament 2018". www.electionguide.org.
  140. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SWEDEN (Riksdagen), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  141. ^ Swedish Election Authority: Elections in Sweden: The way its done 2009-02-25 at the Wayback Machine (page 16)
  142. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SWITZERLAND (Nationalrat - Conseil national - Consiglio nazionale), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  143. ^ Shugart, Matthew Søberg (December 2005). "Semi-Presidential Systems: Dual Executive And Mixed Authority Patterns". French Politics. 3 (3): 323–351. doi:10.1057/palgrave.fp.8200087. S2CID 73642272.
  144. ^ Elgie, Robert (2016). "Government Systems, Party Politics, and Institutional Engineering in the Round". Insight Turkey. 18 (4): 79–92. ISSN 1302-177X. JSTOR 26300453.
  145. ^ a b "IFES Election Guide | Elections: Switzerland Council of States 2019". www.electionguide.org.
  146. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SWITZERLAND (Ständerat - Conseil des Etats - Consiglio degli Stati), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  147. ^ Thresholds moot due to these cantons only electing 2 Councillors
  148. ^ As these cantons only send two members to the Council of States, further subdividing these cantons into constituencies while retaining proportionality would be mathematically impossible)
  149. ^ "Explainer: New rules for the House of Representatives". Bangkok Post.
  150. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: TOGO (Assemblée nationale), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  151. ^ "IFES Election Guide | Elections: Tunisia Parliament 2019". www.electionguide.org.
  152. ^ "IFES Election Guide | Elections: Turkey Grand National Assembly 2018". www.electionguide.org.
  153. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: URUGUAY (Cámara de Representantes), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  154. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: URUGUAY (Cámara de Senadores), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  155. ^ Rokkan, Stein (1970). Citizens, elections, parties: approaches to the comparative study of the processes of development. McKay.
  156. ^ Boix, Carles (1999). "Setting the Rules of the Game: The Choice of Electoral Systems in Advanced Democracies". The American Political Science Review. 93 (3): 609–624. doi:10.2307/2585577. hdl:10230/307. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 2585577. S2CID 16429584.
  157. ^ Ahmed, Amel (2012). Democracy and the Politics of Electoral System Choice: Engineering Electoral Dominance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9781139382137. ISBN 9781139382137. S2CID 153171400.
  158. ^ Gjerløw, Haakon; Rasmussen, Magnus B. (2021). "Revolution, Elite Fear, and Electoral Institutions". Comparative Politics. 54 (4): 595–620. doi:10.5129/001041522x16316387001621. S2CID 244107337.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: url-status (link)
  159. ^ Cusack, Thomas R.; Iversen, Torben; Soskice, David (2007). "Economic Interests and the Origins of Electoral Systems". The American Political Science Review. 101 (3): 373–391. doi:10.1017/S0003055407070384. hdl:10419/51231. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 27644455. S2CID 2799521.

Further reading

Books

  • Abbott, Lewis F. British Democracy: Its Restoration and Extension. ISR/Kindle Books, 2019. ISBN 9780906321522. Chapter 7, "Electoral System Reform: Increasing Competition and Voter Choice and Influence".
  • Ashworth, H.P.C.; Ashworth, T.R. (1900). Proportional Representation Applied to Party Government. Melbourne: Robertson and Co.
  • Amy, Douglas J. (1993). Real Choices/New Voices: The Case for Proportional Representation Elections in the United States. Columbia University Press.
  • Batto, Nathan F.; Huang, Chi; Tan, Alexander C.; Cox, Gary (2016). Mixed-Member Electoral Systems in Constitutional Context: Taiwan, Japan, and Beyond. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
  • Pilon, Dennis (2007). The Politics of Voting. Edmond Montgomery Publications.
  • Colomer, Josep M. (2003). Political Institutions. Oxford University Press.
  • Colomer, Josep M., ed. (2004). Handbook of Electoral System Choice. Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Pukelsheim, Friedrich (2014). Proportional Representation. Springer.
  • Linton, Martin; Southcott, Mary (1998). Making Votes Count: The Case for Electoral Reform. London: Profile Books.
  • Forder, James (2011). The case against voting reform. Oxford: Oneworld Publications. ISBN 978-1-85168-825-8.
  • Jenifer Hart, Proportional Representation: Critics of the British Electoral System,1820-1945 (Clarendon Press, 1992)
  • F.D. Parsons, Thomas Hare and Political Representation in Victorian Britain (Palgrave Macmillan, 2009)
  • Sawer, Marian & Miskin, Sarah (1999). Papers on Parliament No. 34 Representation and Institutional Change: 50 Years of Proportional Representation in the Senate (PDF). Department of the Senate. ISBN 0-642-71061-9.

Journals

  • Hickman, John; Little, Chris (November 2000). "Seat/vote proportionality in Romanian and Spanish parliamentary elections". Journal of Southern Europe and the Balkans Online. 2 (2): 197–212. doi:10.1080/713683348. S2CID 153800069.
  • Galasso, Vincenzo; Nannicini, Tommaso (December 2015). "So closed: political selection in proportional systems". European Journal of Political Economy. 40 (B): 260–273. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2015.04.008. S2CID 55902803.
  • Golder, Sona N.; Stephenson, Laura B.; Van der Straeten, Karine; Blais, André; Bol, Damien; Harfst, Philipp; Laslier, Jean-François (March 2017). "Votes for women: electoral systems and support for female candidates". Politics & Gender. 13 (1): 107–131. doi:10.1017/S1743923X16000684.

External links

  • The De Borda Institute A Northern Ireland-based organisation promoting inclusive voting procedures
  • Election Districts Voting improves PR with overlapping districts elections for first past the post, alternative vote and single transferable vote voters
  • founded in England in 1884, the longest running PR organization. Contains good information about single transferable vote – the Society's preferred form of PR
  • Electoral Reform Australia
  • Proportional Representation Society of Australia
  • Fair Vote Canada
  • FairVote, USA
  • Why Not Proportional Representation?
  • Vote Dilution means Voters have Less Voice Law is Cool site
  • Proportional Representation and British Democracy Debate on British electoral system reform
  • RangeVoting.org. page on PR
  • Australia's Upper Houses - ABC Rear Vision A podcast about the development of Australia's upper houses into STV proportional representation elected chambers.

proportional, representation, proportional, rule, redirects, here, division, rule, financial, proportional, rule, bankruptcy, refers, type, electoral, system, under, which, subgroups, electorate, reflected, proportionately, elected, body, concept, applies, mai. Proportional rule redirects here For the division rule in financial law see Proportional rule bankruptcy Proportional representation PR refers to a type of electoral system under which subgroups of an electorate are reflected proportionately in the elected body 1 The concept applies mainly to political divisions political parties among voters The essence of such systems is that all votes cast or almost all votes cast contribute to the result and are effectively used to help elect someone not just a bare plurality or exclusively the majority and that the system produces mixed balanced representation reflecting how votes are cast Activists campaigning for proportional representation in Canada in September 2013 In the context of voting systems PR means that each representative in an assembly is elected by a roughly equal number of voters In the common case of electoral systems that only allow a choice of parties the seats are allocated in proportion to the vote share each party receives The term Proportional representation may also be used to mean fair representation by population as applied to states regions etc However representation being proportional in terms of population size are not considered to make an electoral system proportional the way the term is usually used For example the US House of Representatives has 435 members who each represent a roughly equal number of people and each state is allocated a number of members in accordance with its population size thus producing fair representation by population But members of the House are elected in first past the post elections first past the post is not proportional by vote share as it has only one winner Meanwhile PR electoral systems are typically proportional to both population seats per district and vote share typically party wise The European Parliament gives each member state a number of seats roughly based on its population size see degressive proportionality and further in each member state the election must be held using a PR system with proportional results based on vote share The most widely used families of PR electoral systems are party list PR used in 85 countries 2 mixed member PR MMP used in 7 countries 3 and the single transferable vote STV used in Ireland 4 Malta and Australian Senate 5 All PR systems require multi member voting districts meaning votes are pooled to elect multiple representatives at once Pooling may be done in various multi member districts in STV and most list PR systems or in single countrywide so called at large district in other list PR systems A country wide pooling of votes to elect more than a hundred members is used in Angola for example For large districts party list PR is more often used A purely candidate based PR system STV has never been used to elect more than 21 in a single contest to this point in history Some PR systems use at large pooling or regional pooling in conjunction with single member districts such as the New Zealand MMP and the Scottish additional member system others use at large pooling in conjunction with multi member districts Denmark In these cases pooling is used to allocated the so called leveling seats top up to compensate for the disproportional results produced in single member districts using FPTP MMP AMS or to polish the fairness produced in multi member districts using list PR Denmark s MMP PR systems that achieve the highest levels of proportionality tend to use as general pooling as possible typically country wide or districts with large numbers of seats Due to various factors perfect proportionality is rarely achieved under PR systems The use of electoral thresholds in list PR or MMP small districts with few seats in each in STV or list PR absence or insufficient number of leveling seats in list PR MMP or AMS may produce disproportionality Other sources are electoral tactics that may be used in certain system such as party splitting in some MMP systems Nonetheless PR systems approximate proportionality much better than other systems 6 and are more resistant to gerrymandering and other forms of manipulation Contents 1 Basics 1 1 How party list PR works 1 2 How the single transferable vote STV works 1 3 How mixed member proportional representation MMP works 1 3 1 Differences to parallel voting 2 Advantages and disadvantages 2 1 Fairness 2 2 Representation of minor parties 2 3 Coalitions 2 4 Voter participation 2 5 Gerrymandering 2 6 Link between constituent and representative 2 7 Potential lack of balance in presidential systems 3 Attributes of PR systems 3 1 District magnitude 3 2 Electoral threshold 3 3 Party magnitude 3 4 Others 4 Measuring disproportionality 5 PR electoral systems 5 1 Party based systems 5 1 1 Party list PR 5 1 2 Mixed systems 5 1 3 Biproportional apportionment 5 2 Candidate based systems 5 2 1 Single transferable vote 5 2 2 Proportional approval voting 5 2 3 Sequential proportional approval voting 5 2 4 Reweighted Range Voting 5 2 5 Asset voting 5 2 6 Evaluative proportional representation EPR 6 History 7 List of countries using proportional representation 8 Incentives for choosing an electoral system 9 See also 10 References 11 Further reading 11 1 Books 11 2 Journals 12 External linksBasics Edit An illustrated graphic regarding the basic concept of proportional representation To achieve their intended effect Proportional electoral systems always have to allow for multiple winners There needs to be more than one seat in each district or some form of pooling of votes Elections for a single president cannot be based on proportional representation but a legislative body assembly parliament may be elected proportionally In the European Parliament for instance each member state has a number of seats that is roughly proportional to its population enabling geographical proportional representation For these elections all EU countries also must use a proportional electoral system enabling political proportional representation When n of the electorate support a particular political party or set of candidates as their favorite then roughly n of seats are allotted to that party or those candidates 7 All PR aim to provide some form of equal representation for votes but may differ in their approaches on how they achieve this How party list PR works Edit Main article Party list proportional representation Party list PR is the most commonly used version of proportional representation Voters cast votes for parties and each party is allocated seats based on its party share Some party list PR systems use overall country wide vote counts others count vote shares in separate parts of the country and allocate seats in each part according to that specific vote count Some use both List PR involves parties in the election process Voters do not primarily vote for candidates persons but for electoral lists or party lists which are lists of candidates that parties put forward The mechanism that allocates seats to the parties lists is how these systems achieve proportionality Once this is done the candidates who take the seats are based on the order in which they appear on the list This is the basic closed list version of list PR An example election where the assembly has 200 seats to be filled is presented below Every voter votes for the list created by their favourite party and the results of the election are as follows popular vote Under party list PR every party gets a number of seats proportional to their share of the popular vote Party Popular vote Party list PR D Hondt Jefferson methodNumber of seats Seats Party A 43 91 88 44 Party B 39 94 80 40 Party C 9 98 20 10 Party D 6 03 12 6 TOTAL 100 200 100 This is done by a proportional formula method for example the D Hondt method also called the Jefferson method these are the same methods that may be used to allocate seats for geographic proportional representation for example how many seats each states gets in the US House of Representatives Votes and seats often cannot be mathematically perfectly allocated so some amount of rounding has to be done The various methods deal with this in different ways although the difference is reduced if there are many seats for example if the whole country is one district Party list PR is also more complicated in reality than in the example as countries often use more than one district multiple tiers e g local regional and national open lists or an electoral threshold How the single transferable vote STV works Edit Main article Single transferable vote The single transferable vote is an older method than party list PR and it does not need to formally involve parties in the election process Instead of parties putting forward ordered lists of candidates from which winners are drawn in order candidates run by name and it is voters themselves who rank the candidates This is done using a preferential ballot The ranking is used to instruct election officials of how the vote should be used in case it is placed on an un electable candidate or on an elected candidate Each voter casts one vote and the district used elects multiple members more than one usually 3 to 7 Because parties play no role in the vote count STV may be used for nonpartisan elections such as the city council of Cambridge Massachusetts 8 A large proportion of the votes cast are used to actually elect someone so the result is mixed and balanced with no one voting block taking much more than its due share of the seats Where party labels are indicated proportionality party wise is noticeable Counting votes under STV is more complicated than first past the post voting but the following example shows how the vote count is performed and how proportionality is achieved in a district with 3 seats In reality districts need to be larger than that to achieve strict proportionality The risk though is that if the number of seats is larger than say 10 seats the ballot will be so large as to be inconvenient and voters may find it difficult to rank the many candidates Note that in many STV systems voters are not required to mark more choices than is desired Even if all voters marked only one preference the resulting representation would be more balanced than under single winner FPTP Under STV an amount that guarantees election is set This is called the quota Specifically the Droop quota is used In this example a candidate who earns more than 25 of the vote is declared elected Note that it is only possible for 3 candidates to each get that quota In the first count the first preferences favourite candidates of all the voters are counted Any candidates who pass the quota are declared elected Simplified example of an STV ballot Candidate Party Popular vote first preferences Quota Elected If elected surplus votesJane Doe Party A 40 25 1 vote Yes 15 John Citizen Party A 11 25 1 vote Joe Smith Party A 16 25 1 vote Fred Rubble Party B 30 25 1 vote Yes 5 Mary Hill Party B 3 25 1 vote TOTAL 100 Next the votes the candidates received above the quota surplus votes that they did not need to get elected are transferred to the next preferences of the voters who voted for them We start with Jane Doe s surplus For the example we suppose that all voters of Jane Doe prefer John Citizen as their second choice as he is also from Party A Based on this we reallocate the votes and find that John Citizen has passed the quota and so is declared elected to the 3rd and last seat that we had to fill Even if we assume that Fred Rubble s surplus would have gone to Mary Hill the vote transfer plus Hill s original votes would not add up to quota Party B did not have two quotas of votes so was not due two seats while Party A was It is possible in realistic STV elections for a candidate to win without quota if they are still in the running when the field of candidates is thinned to the number of remaining open seats But that was not necessary in this case The district result is balanced party wise No one party took all the seats as frequently happens under FPTP or other non proportional voting systems The result is fair the most popular party took two seats the less popular party took just one The most popular candidate s in each party won the party s seat s 81 percent of the voters saw their first choice elected Fifteen percent of them saw both their first and second choices elected Every voter had satisfaction of seeing someone of the party they support elected in the district Candidate Party Current vote total Quota Elected Party First preference votes for candidates of party Number of seats Party seats under STVJane Doe Party A already elected 25 1 vote 25 1 vote Yes Party A 67 2 67 John Citizen Party A 11 15 26 25 1 vote YesJoe Smith Party A 16 25 1 vote Fred Rubble Party B already elected 25 1 vote 25 1 vote Yes Party B 33 1 33 Mary Hill Party B 3 25 1 vote TOTAL 100 3 100 3 100 How mixed member proportional representation MMP works Edit Main article Mixed member proportional representation Mixed Member Proportional Representation combines election of district members with election of additional members as compensatory top up Often MMP systems use single member districts to elect district members Denmark Iceland and Sweden uses multi member districts in their MMP systems MMP with SMDs is described here The mixed member proportional system combines single member plurality voting SMP also known as first past the post FPTP with party list PR in a way that the overall result of the election is supposed to be proportional The voter may vote for a district candidate as well as a party The main idea behind MMP is compensation meaning that the list PR seat allocation is not independent of the results of the district level voting First past the post is a single winner system and cannot be proportional winner takes all so these disproportionalities are compensated by the party list component A simple yet common version of MMP has as many list PR seats as there are single member districts In the example it can be seen as is often the case in reality that the results of the district elections are highly disproportional large parties typically win more seats than they should proportionally but there is also random ness a party that receives more votes than another party might not win more seats than the other Any such dis proportionality produced by the district elections is addressed where possible by the allocation of the compensatory additional members Party Popular vote FPTP seats Number of districts won Compensatory seats under MMP party list PR seats Total number of seats under MMP Seats under MMPParty A 43 91 64 24 88 44 Party B 39 94 33 47 80 40 Party C 9 98 0 20 20 10 Party D 6 03 3 9 12 6 TOTAL 100 100 100 200 100 MMP gives only as many compensatory seats to a party as they need to have the number of seats of each party be proportional Another way to say this is that MMP focuses on making the final outcome proportional Differences to parallel voting Edit Compare the MMP example to parallel voting Parallel voting is a mixed member majoritarian system Here the party list PR seat allocation is independent of the district results meaning that there is no compensation no regard to how the district seats were filled The popular vote the number of districts won by each party and the number of districts and party list PR seats are all the same as in the MMP example above yet the total number of seats is different Party Popular vote FPTP seats Number of districts won Party list PR seats under parallel voting Total number of seats under parallel voting Seats under parallel votingParty A 43 91 64 44 108 54 0 Party B 39 94 33 40 73 36 5 Party C 9 98 0 10 10 5 0 Party D 6 03 3 6 9 4 5 TOTAL 100 100 100 200 100 The overall results are not proportional although they are more balanced and fair than most single winner First past the post elections Parallel voting is mostly semi proportional Mixed system is the most proportional if the additional members are allocated in compensatory form There are many versions of MMP in use Some use only a single vote in some voters cast two votes one for a local candidate and one for a party Some allocate compensatory seats to best losers others allocate according to party lists Some use levelling seats to compensate for potential overhang seats others don t Most impose an electoral threshold in order for a party to be eligible for any additional seats some allow parties that elect one or more district seats to be eligible for additional seats even if its party share is below the threshold Any barrier to access to the additional seats may produce wasted votes and dis proportionality in the final result As well there is single non transferable vote which is also semi proportional It has the advantage that parties play no direct role in elections and voters do not need to mark ranked votes Each voter casts one vote for a candidate and as many candidates win by plurality as the number of seats in the district Due to each voter casting just one vote as in STV and each district electing multiple members as in STV mixed representation is produced in each district and overall rough proportionality more or less Without transferable votes more votes are wasted than under STV Advantages and disadvantages EditThe case for a Single Transferrable Vote system a form of proportional representation was made by John Stuart Mill in his 1861 essay Considerations on Representative Government In a representative body actually deliberating the minority must of course be overruled and in an equal democracy the majority of the people through their representatives will outvote and prevail over the minority and their representatives But does it follow that the minority should have no representatives at all Is it necessary that the minority should not even be heard Nothing but habit and old association can reconcile any reasonable being to the needless injustice In a really equal democracy every or any section would be represented not disproportionately but proportionately A majority of the electors would always have a majority of the representatives but a minority of the electors would always have a minority of the representatives Man for man they would be as fully represented as the majority Unless they are there is not equal government there is a part whose fair and equal share of influence in the representation is withheld from them contrary to all just government but above all contrary to the principle of democracy which professes equality as its very root and foundation 1 Mill s essay does not support Party based Proportional Representation and may indicate a distaste for the ills of Party based systems in saying Of all modes in which a national representation can possibly be constituted this one affords the best security for the intellectual qualifications desirable in the representatives At present by universal admission it is becoming more and more difficult for any one who has only talents and character to gain admission into the House of Commons The only persons who can get elected are those who possess local influence or make their way by lavish expenditure or who on the invitation of three or four tradesmen or attorneys are sent down by one of the two great parties from their London clubs as men whose votes the party can depend on under all circumstances 1 Many political theorists agree with Mill 9 that in a representative democracy the representatives should represent all substantial segments of society but want reform rather than abolition of direct local community representation in the legislature 10 STV and the Additional Member system both produce local area representation and overall PR through mixed balanced representation at the district level 11 Fairness Edit PR tries to resolve the unfairness of majoritarian and plurality voting systems where the largest parties receive an unfair seat bonus and smaller parties are disadvantaged always under represented and on occasion win no representation at all Duverger s law 12 13 14 6 7 Under FPTP an established party in UK elections has been elected to majority government with as little as 35 of votes 2005 UK general election In certain Canadian elections majority governments have been formed by parties with the support of under 40 of votes cast 2011 Canadian election 2015 Canadian election If turnout levels in the electorate are less than 60 such outcomes allow a party to form a majority government by convincing as few as one quarter of the electorate to vote for it In the 2005 UK election for example the Labour Party under Tony Blair won a comfortable parliamentary majority with the votes of only 21 6 of the total electorate 15 3 Such misrepresentation has been criticized as no longer a question of fairness but of elementary rights of citizens 16 22 However intermediate PR systems with a high electoral threshold or other features that reduce proportionality are not necessarily much fairer in the 2002 Turkish general election using an open list system with a 10 threshold 46 of votes were wasted 17 83 The other 54 percent of the votes did receive fair level of representation though Under First past the post a third or so of members are elected with less than half the votes cast in their district the majority in such districts not getting any local representation and with no levelling seats getting no representation at all Plurality majoritarian systems also benefit regional parties that win many seats in the region where they have a strong following but have little support nationally while other parties with national support that is not concentrated in specific districts like the Greens win few or no seats An example is the Bloc Quebecois in Canada that won 52 seats in the 1993 federal election all in Quebec on 13 5 of the national vote while the Progressive Conservatives collapsed to two seats on 16 spread nationally The Conservative party although strong nationally had had very strong regional support in the West but in this election its supporters in the West turned to the Reform party another regional party which won all its seats west of Ontario winning most of its seats west of Saskatchewan 14 18 Similarly in the 2015 UK General Election the Scottish National Party gained 56 seats all in Scotland with a 4 7 share of the national vote while the UK Independence Party with 12 6 gained only a single seat 19 Representation of minor parties Edit The use of multiple member districts enables a greater variety of candidates to be elected It has been argued that in emerging democracies inclusion of minorities in the legislature can be essential for social stability and to consolidate the democratic process 17 58 Critics on the other hand claim this can give extreme parties a foothold in parliament sometimes cited as a cause for the collapse of the Weimar government With very low thresholds very small parties can act as king makers 20 holding larger parties to ransom during coalition discussions The example of Israel is often quoted 17 59 but these problems can be limited as in the modern German Bundestag by the introduction of higher threshold limits for a party to gain parliamentary representation which in turn increases the number of wasted votes Another criticism is that the dominant parties in plurality majoritarian systems often looked on as coalitions or as broad churches 21 can fragment under PR as the election of candidates from smaller groups becomes possible Israel Brazil and Italy until 1993 are examples 17 59 89 However research shows in general there is only a small increase in the number of parties in parliament although small parties have larger representation under PR 22 Open list systems and STV the only prominent PR system which does not require political parties 23 enable independent candidates to be elected In Ireland on average about six independent candidates have been elected each parliament 24 This can lead to a situation where forming a Parliamentary majority requires support of one or more of these independent representatives In some cases these independents have positions that are closely aligned with the governing party and it hardly matters The Irish Government formed after the 2016 election even included independent representatives in the cabinet of a minority government In others the electoral platform is entirely local and addressing this is a price for support Coalitions Edit The election of smaller parties gives rise to one of the principal objections to PR systems that they almost always result in coalition governments 17 59 9 Supporters of PR see coalitions as an advantage forcing compromise between parties to form a coalition at the centre of the political spectrum and so leading to continuity and stability Opponents counter that with many policies compromise is not possible Neither can many policies be easily positioned on the left right spectrum for example the environment So policies are horse traded during coalition formation with the consequence that voters have no way of knowing which policies will be pursued by the government they elect voters have less influence on governments Also coalitions do not necessarily form at the centre and small parties can have excessive influence supplying a coalition with a majority only on condition that a policy or policies favoured by few voters is are adopted Most importantly the ability of voters to vote a party in disfavour out of power is curtailed 9 Countries with PR do not appear to have more elections All these disadvantages the PR opponents contend are avoided by two party plurality systems Coalitions are rare the two dominant parties necessarily compete at the centre for votes so that governments are more reliably moderate the strong opposition necessary for proper scrutiny of government is assured and governments remain sensitive to public sentiment because they can be and are regularly voted out of power 9 However this is not necessarily so a two party system can result in a drift to extremes hollowing out the centre 25 or at least in one party drifting to an extreme 26 The opponents of PR also contend that coalition governments created under PR are less stable and elections are more frequent Italy is an often cited example with many governments composed of many different coalition partners However Italy is unusual in that both its houses can make a government fall whereas other PR nations have either just one house or have one of their two houses be the core body supporting a government Italy s current parallel voting system is not PR so Italy is not an appropriate candidate for measuring the stability of PR Voter participation Edit Plurality systems usually result in single party majority government because generally fewer parties are elected in large numbers under FPTP compared to PR and FPTP compresses politics to little more than two party contests Relatively few votes in a few of the most finely balanced districts the swing seats are able to swing majority control in the house Incumbents in less evenly divided districts are invulnerable to slight swings of political mood In the UK for example about half the constituencies have always elected the same party since 1945 27 in the 2012 US House elections 45 districts 10 of all districts were uncontested by one of the two dominant parties 28 Voters who know their preferred candidate will not win have little incentive to vote and even if they do their votes have no effect although they are still counted in the popular vote calculation 17 10 With PR there are no swing seats Most votes contribute to the election of a candidate so parties need to campaign in all districts not just those where their support is strongest or where they perceive most advantage This fact in turn encourages parties to be more responsive to voters producing a more balanced ticket by nominating more women and minority candidates 14 On average about 8 more women are elected 22 Since most votes count there are fewer wasted votes so voters aware that their vote can make a difference are more likely to make the effort to vote and less likely to vote tactically Compared to countries with plurality electoral systems voter turnout improves and the population is more involved in the political process 17 14 22 However some experts argue that transitioning from plurality to PR only increases voter turnout in geographical areas associated with safe seats under the plurality system turnout may decrease in areas formerly associated with swing seats 29 Gerrymandering Edit First past the post elections are dependent on the drawing of boundaries of their single member districts a process vulnerable to political interference gerrymandering even if districts are drawn in such a way as to ensure approximately equal representation To compound the problem boundaries have to be periodically re drawn to accommodate population changes Even apolitically drawn boundaries can unintentionally produce the effect of gerrymandering reflecting naturally occurring concentrations 30 65 PR systems due to having larger and fewer multiple member districts are less prone to gerrymandering research suggests five seat districts or larger are immune to gerrymandering 30 66 Equality of size of multiple member districts is not important the number of seats can vary so districts can be aligned with historical territories of varying sizes such as cities counties states or provinces Later population changes can be accommodated by simply adjusting the number of representatives elected without having to re draw boundary For example Professor Mollison in his 2010 plan for STV for the UK divided the country into 143 districts and then allocated varying number of seats to each district to add up to the existing total of 650 MPs depending on the number of voters in each but with wide ranges his five seat districts include one with 327 000 voters and another with 382 000 voters His district boundaries follow historical county and local authority boundaries yet he achieves more uniform representation than does the Boundary Commission the body responsible for balancing the UK s first past the post constituency sizes 27 31 Mixed member systems are susceptible to gerrymandering for the local seats that remain a part of such systems Under parallel voting a semi proportional system there is no compensation for the effects that such gerrymandering might have Under MMP the use of compensatory list seats makes gerrymandering less of an issue However its effectiveness in this regard depends upon the features of the system including the size of the regional districts the relative share of list seats in the total and opportunities for collusion that might exist A striking example of how the compensatory mechanism can be undermined can be seen in the 2014 Hungarian parliamentary election where the leading party Fidesz combined gerrymandering and decoy lists which resulted in a two thirds parliamentary majority from a 45 vote 32 33 This illustrates how certain implementations of mixed systems if non compensatory or insufficiently compensatory can produce moderately proportional outcomes similar to parallel voting Link between constituent and representative Edit It is generally accepted that a particular advantage of plurality electoral systems such as first past the post or majoritarian electoral systems such as the alternative vote is the geographic link between representatives and their constituents 17 36 34 65 16 21 A notable disadvantage of PR is that as its multiple member districts are made larger this link is weakened 17 82 In party list PR systems without delineated districts such as the Netherlands and Israel the geographic link between representatives and their constituents is considered weak but has shown to play a role for some parties Yet with relatively small multiple member districts in particular with STV there are counter arguments about 90 of voters can consult a representative they voted for someone whom they might think more sympathetic to their problem In such cases it is sometimes argued that constituents and representatives have a closer link 27 30 212 constituents have a choice of representative so they can consult one with particular expertise in the topic at issue 30 212 35 With multiple member districts prominent candidates have more opportunity to be elected in their home constituencies which they know and can represent authentically There is less likely to be a strong incentive to parachute them into constituencies in which they are strangers and thus less than ideal representatives 36 248 250 Mixed member PR systems incorporate single member districts to preserve the link between constituents and representatives 17 95 However because up to half the parliamentary seats are list rather than district seats the districts are necessarily up to twice as large as with a plurality majoritarian system where all representatives serve single member districts 16 32 An interesting case occurred in the Netherlands when out of the blue a party for the elderly the General Elderly Alliance gained six seats in the 1994 election The other parties had not paid attention but this made them aware With the next election the Party of the Elderly was gone because the established parties had started to listen to the elderly Today a party for older folks 50PLUS has established itself in the Netherlands albeit never with the same high number of seats This can be seen as an example how geography in itself may not be a good enough reason to establish voting results around it and overturn all other particulars of the voting population In a sense voting in districts restricts the voters to a specific geography Proportional voting follows the exact outcome of all the votes 37 Potential lack of balance in presidential systems Edit In a presidential system the president is chosen independently from the parliament As a consequence it is possible to have a divided government where a parliament and president have opposing views and may want to balance each other s influence However the proportional system favors government of coalitions of many smaller parties that require compromising and negotiating topics citation needed As a consequence these coalitions might have difficulties presenting a united front to counter presidential influence leading to a lack of balance between these two powers With a proportionally elected House a President may strong arm certain political issues citation needed This issue does not happen in a parliamentary system where the prime minister is elected indirectly by the parliament itself As a consequence a divided government is impossible Even if the political views change with time and the prime minister loses their support from parliament they can be replaced with a motion of no confidence Effectively both measures make it impossible to create a divided government Attributes of PR systems EditDistrict magnitude Edit Academics agree that the most important influence on proportionality is an electoral district s magnitude the number of representatives elected from the district As magnitude increases proportionality improves 17 Some scholars recommend for STV voting districts of roughly four to eight seats 38 which are considered small relative to PR systems in general which frequently have district magnitudes in the hundreds At one extreme the binomial electoral system used in Chile between 1989 and 2013 39 a nominally proportional open list system features two member districts As this system can be expected to result in the election of one candidate from each of the two dominant political blocks in most districts it is not generally considered proportional 17 79 At the other extreme where the district encompasses the entire country and with a low minimum threshold highly proportionate representation of political parties can result parties gain by broadening their appeal by nominating more minority and women candidates 17 83 After the introduction of STV in Ireland in 1921 district magnitudes slowly diminished as more and more three member constituencies were defined benefiting the dominant Fianna Fail until 1979 when an independent boundary commission was established reversing the trend 40 In 2010 a parliamentary constitutional committee recommended a minimum magnitude of four 41 Despite relatively low magnitudes Ireland has generally experienced highly proportional results 17 73 In the FairVote plan for STV which FairVote calls choice voting for the US House of Representatives three to five member super districts are proposed 42 In Professor Mollison s plan for STV in the UK four and five member districts are mostly used with three and six seat districts used as necessary to fit existing boundaries and even two and single member districts used where geography dictates 27 Electoral threshold Edit The electoral threshold is the minimum vote required to win one seat The lower the threshold the higher the proportion of votes contributing to the election of representatives and the lower the proportion of votes wasted 17 All electoral systems have electoral thresholds either formally defined or the natural threshold which is the mathematical consequence of the district magnitude and election parameters 17 83 A formal threshold usually requires parties to win a certain percentage of the vote in order to be awarded seats from the party lists In Germany and New Zealand both MMP the threshold is 5 of the national vote but the threshold is not applied to parties that win a minimum number of constituency seats three in Germany one in New Zealand Turkey defines a threshold of 7 43 the Netherlands 0 67 17 Israel has raised its threshold from 1 before 1992 to 1 5 up to 2004 2 in 2006 and 3 25 in 2014 44 South Africa has no explicit electoral threshold only a natural threshold 0 2 A list of electoral thresholds by country shows a typical electoral threshold for party list PR is 3 5 In STV elections winning the quota ballots seats 1 plus 1 of votes assures election 45 Winning the quota in the first count when first preference votes are all that are counted assures election at that point 46 E g for a district magnitude of 3 the STV electoral threshold would be 25 of first preference votes plus transferred later preference votes significantly higher than typical party list PR However candidates who receive only about half the quota of first preference votes alone may attract good second and third etc preference support and win election 27 However success with less than quota cannot be relied on Sometimes candidates in winning positions in the first count but who do not have quota are not elected being pushed aside during the vote count in favor of other candidates who were initially less popular but have wide support and benefit from vote transfers The need to attract second preferences tends to promote consensus and to disadvantage extremes Those who do not have wide support may not benefit greatly from vote transfers so may not be elected if they do not receive quota on first count 46 The electoral threshold has different effects on STV than on Party list PR For STV the votes for candidates below natural threshold are not wasted but transferred to the next indicated choice For party list PR a vote for a party below electoral threshold is an unrepresented vote unless the spare vote system is applied Party magnitude Edit Party magnitude is the number of candidates elected from one party in one district As party magnitude increases a more balanced ticket will be more successful encouraging parties to nominate women and minority candidates for election 47 But under STV nominating too many candidates can be counter productive splitting the first preference votes and allowing the candidates to be eliminated before receiving transferred votes from other parties An example of this was identified in a ward in the 2007 Scottish local elections where Labour putting up three candidates won only one seat while they might have won two had one of their voters preferred candidates not stood 27 The same effect may have contributed to the collapse of Fianna Fail in the 2011 Irish general election 48 But generally in STV contests the transfers of votes allows each party to take roughly its due share of the seats based on vote tallies of the party s candidates and where all the candidates of a party preferred by a voter are eliminated the vote may be transferred to a candidate of a different party also preferred by the voter 49 Others Edit Other aspects of PR can influence proportionality such as the size of the elected body the choice of open or closed lists ballot design and vote counting methods Measuring disproportionality EditExact proportionality has a single unambiguous definition the seat shares must exactly equal the vote shares measured as seats to votes ratio When this condition is violated the allocation is disproportional and it may be interesting to examine the degree of disproportionality the degree to which the number of seats won by each party differs from that of a perfectly proportional outcome This degree does not have a single unambiguous definition Some common disproportionality indexes are 50 The Loosemore Hanby index calculated by subtracting each party s vote share from its seat share adding up the absolute values ignoring any negative signs and dividing by two 51 4 6 Related to it is the Rae index It measures the average deviation while the Loosemore Hanby index measures the total deviation Related to the amount of unrepresented vote which only measures the difference between votes cast and seats obtained for parties which did not obtain any seat The Gallagher Index involves squaring the difference between each party s vote share and seat share and taking the square root of the sum The Sainte Lague Index where the squared discrepancy from ideal seats to votes ratio is weighted equally for each voter The disproportionality changes from one election to another depending on voter behavior and size of effective electoral threshold here shown is the unrepresented vote for New Zealand 52 In 2005 New Zealand general election every party above 1 got seats due to the electoral threshold in New Zealand of at least one seat in first past the post voting which caused a much lower unrepresented vote compared to the other years Graphs are temporarily unavailable due to technical issues Different indexes measure different concepts of disproportionality Some disproportionality concepts have been mapped to social welfare functions 53 Disproportionality indexes are sometimes used to evaluate existing and proposed electoral systems For example the Canadian Parliament s 2016 Special Committee on Electoral Reform recommended that a system be designed to achieve a Gallagher score of 5 or less This indicated a much lower degree of disproportionality than observed in the 2015 Canadian election under first past the post voting where the Gallagher index was 12 54 There are various other measures of proportionality some of them have software implementation 55 The common indexes Loosemore Hanby Gallagher Sainte Lague do not support ranked voting 56 57 An alternative that does support it is the Droop proportionality criterion DPC It requires that if for some set M of candidates there exist more than k Droop quotas of voters who rank them at the top M positions then at least k candidates from M are elected In the special case in which voters vote solely by party DPC implies proportionality PR electoral systems EditParty based systems Edit Party list PR Edit Main article Party list proportional representation Party list proportional representation is an electoral system in which seats are first allocated to parties based on vote share and then assigned to party affiliated candidates on the parties electoral lists This system is used in many countries including Finland open list Latvia open list Sweden open list Israel national closed list Brazil open list Nepal closed list as adopted in 2008 in first CA election the Netherlands open list Russia closed list South Africa closed list Democratic Republic of the Congo open list and Ukraine open list For elections to the European Parliament most member states use open lists but most large EU countries use closed lists so that the majority of EP seats are distributed by those 58 Local lists were used to elect the Italian Senate during the second half of the 20th century Some common types of electoral lists are Closed list systems where each party lists its candidates according to the party s candidate selection process This sets the order of candidates on the list and thus in effect their probability of being elected The first candidate on a list for example will get the first seat that party wins Each voter casts a vote for a list of candidates Voters therefore do not have the option to express their preferences at the ballot as to which of a party s candidates are elected into office 59 60 A party is allocated seats in proportion to the number of votes it receives 61 Ley de Lemas an intermediate system used in Uruguay where each party presents several closed lists each representing a faction Seats are distributed between parties according to the number of votes and then between the factions within each party citation needed Open list systems where voters may vote depending on the model for one person or for two or indicate their order of preference within the list These votes sometimes rearrange the order of names on the party s list and thus which of its candidates are elected Nevertheless the number of candidates elected from the list is determined by the number of votes the list receives citation needed Localized list systems where parties divide their candidates in single member like constituencies which are ranked inside each general party list depending by their percentages This method allows electors to judge every single candidate as in a FPTP system Two tier party list systems as in Denmark Norway and Sweden In Denmark for example the country is divided into ten multiple member voting districts arranged in three regions electing 135 representatives In addition 40 compensatory seats are elected Voters have one vote which can be cast for an individual candidate or for a party list on the district ballot To determine district winners candidates are apportioned their share of their party s district list vote plus their individual votes The compensatory seats are apportioned to the regions according to the party votes aggregated nationally and then to the districts where the compensatory representatives are determined In the 2007 general election the district magnitudes including compensatory representatives varied between 14 and 28 The basic design of the system has remained unchanged since its introduction in 1920 62 63 64 Mixed systems Edit There are mixed electoral systems combining a plurality majority formula with a proportional formula 65 or using the proportional component to compensate for disproportionality caused by the plurality majority component 66 67 The most prominent mixed compensatory system is mixed member proportional representation MMP It combines a single district vote usually first past the post with a compensatory regional or nationwide party list proportional vote For example suppose that a party wins 10 seats based on plurality but requires 15 seats in total to obtain its proportional share of an elected body A fully proportional mixed compensatory system would award this party 5 compensatory PR seats raising the party s seat count from 10 to 15 MMP has the potential to produce proportional or moderately proportional election outcomes depending on a number of factors such as the ratio of FPTP seats to PR seats the existence or nonexistence of extra compensatory seats to make up for overhang seats and electoral thresholds 68 69 70 It was invented for the German Bundestag after the Second World War and has spread to Lesotho Bolivia New Zealand and Thailand The system is also used for the Welsh Parliament and Scottish Parliament where it is called the additional member system 71 3 Voters typically have two votes one for their district representative and one for the party list The list vote usually determines how many seats are allocated to each party in parliament After the district winners have been determined sufficient candidates from each party list are elected to top up each party to the overall number of parliamentary seats due to it according to the party s overall list vote Before apportioning list seats all list votes for parties which failed to reach the threshold are discarded If eliminated parties lose seats in this manner then the seat counts for parties that achieved the threshold improve Any direct seats won by independent candidates are subtracted from the parliamentary total used to apportion list seats 72 Proportionality of MMP can be compromised if the ratio of list to district seats is too low as it may then not be possible to completely compensate district seat disproportionality Another factor can be how overhang seats are handled district seats that a party wins in excess of the number due to it under the list vote To achieve proportionality other parties require balance seats increasing the size of parliament by twice the number of overhang seats but this is not always done Until recently Germany increased the size of parliament by the number of overhang seats but did not use the increased size for apportioning list seats This was changed for the 2013 national election after the constitutional court rejected the previous law not compensating for overhang seats had resulted in a negative vote weight effect 73 Lesotho Scotland and Wales do not increase the size of parliament at all and in 2012 a New Zealand parliamentary commission also proposed abandoning compensation for overhang seats and so fixing the size of parliament At the same time it would abolish the single seat threshold any such seats would then be overhang seats and would otherwise have increased the size of parliament further and reduce the electoral threshold from 5 to 4 Proportionality would not suffer 17 74 Similarly to MMP mixed single vote systems MSV use a proportional formula for allocating seats on the compensatory tier but voters only have one vote that functions on both levels MSV may use a positive vote transfer system where unused votes are transferred from the lower tier to the upper compensatory tier where only these are used in the proportional formula Alternatively the MMP seat linkage algorithm can be used with a mixed single vote to top up to a proportional result With MSV the similar requirements as in MMP apply to guarantee an overall proportional result Parallel voting MMM systems use proportional formulas to allocate seats on a proportional tier separately from other tiers Certain systems like scorporo use a proportional formula after combining results of a parallel list vote with transferred votes from lower tiers using negative or positive vote transfer Another mixed system is dual member proportional representation DMP It is a single vote system that elects two representatives in every district 75 The first seat in each district is awarded to the candidate who wins a plurality of the votes similar to FPTP voting The remaining seats are awarded in a compensatory manner to achieve proportionality across a larger region DMP employs a formula similar to the best near winner variant of MMP used in the German state of Baden Wurttemberg 76 In Baden Wurttemberg compensatory seats are awarded to candidates who receive high levels of support at the district level compared with other candidates of the same party DMP differs in that at most one candidate per district is permitted to obtain a compensatory seat If multiple candidates contesting the same district are slated to receive one of their parties compensatory seats the candidate with the highest vote share is elected and the others are eliminated DMP is similar to STV in that all elected representatives including those who receive compensatory seats serve their local districts Invented in 2013 in the Canadian province of Alberta DMP received attention on Prince Edward Island where it appeared on a 2016 plebiscite as a potential replacement for FPTP 77 but was eliminated on the third round 78 79 It was also one of three proportional voting system options on a 2018 referendum in British Columbia 80 81 82 Biproportional apportionment Edit Main article Biproportional apportionment Biproportional apportionment aims to achieve proportionality in two dimensions for example proportionality by region and proportionality by party There are several mathematical methods to attain biproportionality One method is called iterative proportional fitting IPF It was proposed for elections by the mathematician Michel Balinski in 1989 and first used by the city of Zurich for its council elections in February 2006 in a modified form called new Zurich apportionment Neue Zurcher Zuteilungsverfahren Zurich had had to modify its party list PR system after the Swiss Federal Court ruled that its smallest wards as a result of population changes over many years unconstitutionally disadvantaged smaller political parties With biproportional apportionment the use of open party lists has not changed but the way winning candidates are determined has The proportion of seats due to each party is calculated according to their overall citywide vote and then the district winners are adjusted to conform to these proportions This means that some candidates who would otherwise have been successful can be denied seats in favor of initially unsuccessful candidates in order to improve the relative proportions of their respective parties overall This peculiarity is accepted by the Zurich electorate because the resulting city council is proportional and all votes regardless of district magnitude now have equal weight The system has since been adopted by other Swiss cities and cantons 83 84 Balinski has proposed another variant called fair majority voting FMV to replace single winner plurality majoritarian electoral systems in particular the system used for the US House of Representatives FMV introduces proportionality without changing the method of voting the number of seats or the possibly gerrymandered district boundaries Seats would be apportioned to parties in a proportional manner at the state level 84 In a related proposal for the UK parliament whose elections are contested by many more parties the authors note that parameters can be tuned to adopt any degree of proportionality deemed acceptable to the electorate In order to elect smaller parties a number of constituencies would be awarded to candidates placed fourth or even fifth in the constituency unlikely to be acceptable to the electorate the authors concede but this effect could be substantially reduced by incorporating a third regional apportionment tier or by specifying minimum thresholds 85 Candidate based systems Edit Single transferable vote Edit Main article Single transferable vote The single transferable vote STV also called ranked choice voting 86 8 is a ranked system voters rank candidates in order of preference Voting districts usually elect three to seven representatives each voter casts just one vote The count is cyclic electing or eliminating candidates and transferring votes until all seats are filled A candidate whose tally reaches a quota the minimum vote that guarantees election is declared elected The candidate s surplus votes those in excess of the quota are transferred to other candidates at a fraction of their value proportionate to the surplus according to the voters preferences If there are no surplus votes to transfer and there are still seats to fill the least popular candidate is eliminated those votes being transferred to their next preference at full value The votes are transferred according to the next marked preference Any votes that cannot be transferred are moved to a pile labelled exhausted or non transferable The cont continues until all the seats are filled or until there is only one more candidate than the number of remaining open seats At that point all of them except the least popular candidate are declared elected even if they do not have quota The transfer of votes of eliminated candidates is simple the transfer of surplus votes is more involved There are various methods for transferring surplus votes Manual methods used in early times and still today in places where STV was adopted in early 20th Century Ireland and Malta transfer surplus votes according to a randomly selected sample or transfer only a segment of the surplus selected based on the next usable marked preference Other more recent methods transfer all votes at a fraction of their value the fraction derived by the surplus divided by the candidate s tally and with reference to all the marked preferences on the ballots not just the next usable preference They may need the use of a computer The different methods may not produce the same result in all respects But the front runners in the first count before any transfers are conducted are all or mostly elected in the end so the various methods of transfers all produce much the same result Some variants of STV allow transfers to already elected or eliminated candidates and these too can require a computer 87 88 In effect the method produces groups of voters of much the same size so the overall effect is to reflect the diversity of the electorate each substantial group having one or more representatives the group voted for Statistics of effective votes vary In Cambridge under STV 90 percent of voters see their vote help to elect a candidate more than 65 percent of voters see their first choice candidate elected and more than 95 percent of voters see one of their top three choices win 89 Other reports claim that 90 of voters have a representative to whom they gave their first preference Voters can choose candidates using any criteria they wish the proportionality is implicit 27 Political parties are not necessary all other prominent PR electoral systems presume that parties reflect voters wishes which many believe gives power to parties 87 STV satisfies the electoral system criterion proportionality for solid coalitions a solid coalition for a set of candidates is the group of voters that rank all those candidates above all others and is therefore considered a system of proportional representation 87 However the small district magnitude used in STV elections usually 5 to 9 seats but sometimes rising to 21 has been criticized as impairing proportionality especially when more parties compete than there are seats available 9 50 and STV has for this reason sometimes been labelled quasi proportional 90 83 While this may be true when considering districts in isolation results overall are proportional Even though Ireland has particularly small magnitudes 3 to 5 seats results of STV elections are highly proportional 17 73 4 In 1997 the average magnitude was 4 0 but eight parties gained representation four of them with less than 3 of first preference votes nationally Six independent candidates also won election 40 STV has also been described as the most proportional system as it elects candidates without the need for parties The influence of parties can distort proportionality 90 83 The system tends to handicap extreme candidates because to gain transfers based on back up preferences and so improve their chance of election candidates need to canvass voters beyond their own circle of supporters and so need to moderate their views 91 92 Conversely widely respected candidates can win election even if they receive relatively few first preferences They do this by benefiting from strong subordinate preference support Of course they must have enough initial support so that they are not in the bottom rung of popularity or they will be eliminated when the field of candidate is thinned 27 Proportional approval voting Edit Main article Proportional approval voting Systems can be devised that aim at proportional representation but are based on approval votes on individual candidates not parties Such is the idea of proportional approval voting PAV 93 When there are a lot of seats to be filled as in a legislature counting ballots under PAV may not be feasible so sequential variants have been used such as sequential proportional approval voting SPAV Sequential proportional approval voting Edit Main article Sequential proportional approval voting Sequential proportional approval voting SPAV is a multi winner voting system similar to STV in that voters can express support for multiple candidates but different in that candidates are graded instead of ranked 94 That is a voter approves or disapproves of each candidate SPAV was used briefly in Sweden during the early 1900s 95 The vote counting procedure occurs in rounds The first round of SPAV is identical to approval voting All ballots are added with equal weight and the candidate with the highest overall score is elected In all subsequent rounds ballots that support candidates who have already been elected are added with a reduced weight Thus voters who support none of the winners in the early rounds are increasingly likely to elect one of their preferred candidates in a later round The procedure has been shown to yield proportional outcomes especially when voters are loyal to distinct groups of candidates e g political parties 96 97 Reweighted Range Voting Edit Reweighted Range Voting RRV uses the same method as sequential proportional approval voting but uses a score ballot 98 99 Reweighted Range Voting was used for the nominations in the Visual Effects category for recent Academy Award Oscars from 2013 through 2017 100 101 and is used in the city of Berkeley California for sorting the priorities of the city council 102 Asset voting Edit In asset voting 94 103 the voters vote for candidates and then the candidates negotiate amongst each other and reallocate votes amongst themselves Asset voting was proposed by Lewis Carroll in 1884 104 and has been more recently independently rediscovered and extended by Warren D Smith and Forest Simmons 105 As such this method substitutes candidates collective preferences for those of the voters Evaluative proportional representation EPR EditSimilar to majority judgment voting that elects single winners evaluative proportional representation EPR elects all the members of a legislative body 106 In contrast to any other voting method EPR explains how it does not waste any votes quantitatively or qualitatively 107 108 Each EPR voter is invited to grade one or more of the candidate s suitability for office as one of Excellent ideal Very Good Good Acceptable Poor or Reject entirely unsuitable Multiple candidates may be given the same grade by a voter Each citizen is assured that their one vote will equally increase the voting power of the elected member of the legislature who received either their highest grade remaining highest grade or proxy vote Each elected member has a weighted vote in the legislative body exactly equal to the number of citizens ballots exclusively counted for them Using EPR each citizen elects their representative at large for a city council For a large and diverse state legislature each citizen chooses to vote through any of the districts or official non geographically defined electoral associations in the country Each voter grades any number of candidates in the whole country Each member s weighted vote results from receiving one of the following from each voter their highest grade highest remaining grade or proxy vote Each citizen s vote equally adds to the voting power in the legislative body of the elected candidate they see as most likely to represent their hopes and concerns accurately Also each self identifying minority or majority is proportionally represented exactly Like majority judgment EPR reduces by almost half both the incentives and possibilities for voters to use Tactical Voting See also Tactical voting Majority judgmentHistory EditOne of the earliest proposals of proportionality in an assembly was by John Adams in his influential pamphlet Thoughts on Government written in 1776 during the American Revolution It should be in miniature an exact portrait of the people at large It should think feel reason and act like them That it may be the interest of this Assembly to do strict justice at all times it should be an equal representation or in other words equal interest among the people should have equal interest in it 109 Mirabeau speaking to the Assembly of Provence on January 30 1789 was also an early proponent of a proportionally representative assembly 110 A representative body is to the nation what a chart is for the physical configuration of its soil in all its parts and as a whole the representative body should at all times present a reduced picture of the people their opinions aspirations and wishes and that presentation should bear the relative proportion to the original precisely In February 1793 the Marquis de Condorcet led the drafting of the Girondist constitution which proposed a limited voting scheme with proportional aspects Before that could be voted on the Montagnards took over the National Convention and produced their own constitution On June 24 Saint Just proposed the single non transferable vote which can be proportional for national elections but the constitution was passed on the same day specifying first past the post voting 110 Already in 1787 James Wilson like Adams a US Founding Father understood the importance of multiple member districts Bad elections proceed from the smallness of the districts which give an opportunity to bad men to intrigue themselves into office 111 and again in 1791 in his Lectures on Law It may I believe be assumed as a general maxim of no small importance in democratical governments that the more extensive the district of election is the choice will be the more wise and enlightened 112 The 1790 Constitution of Pennsylvania specified multiple member districts for the state Senate and required their boundaries to follow county lines 113 STV or more precisely an election method where voters have one transferable vote was first invented in 1819 by an English schoolmaster Thomas Wright Hill who devised a plan of election for the committee of the Society for Literary and Scientific Improvement in Birmingham that used not only transfers of surplus votes from winners but also from losers a refinement that later both Andrae and Hare initially omitted But the procedure was unsuitable for a public election and was not publicised In 1839 Hill s son Rowland Hill recommended the concept for public elections in Adelaide and a simple process was used in which voters formed as many groups as there were representatives to be elected each group electing one representative 110 The first practical PR election method the List Plan system was conceived by Thomas Gilpin a retired paper mill owner in a paper he read to the American Philosophical Society in Philadelphia in 1844 On the representation of minorities of electors to act with the majority in elected assemblies It was never put into practical use but even as late as 1914 it was put forward as a way to elect the U S electoral college delegates and for local elections 110 114 115 A practical election using the Single Transferable Vote system a combination of preferential voting and multi member districts was devised in Denmark by Carl Andrae a mathematician and first used there in 1855 making it the oldest PR system That system was later adopted for national elections in Malta 1921 the Republic of Ireland 1921 and Australia 1948 STV was also invented apparently independently in the UK in 1857 by Thomas Hare a London barrister in his pamphlet The Machinery of Representation and expanded on in his 1859 Treatise on the Election of Representatives The scheme was enthusiastically taken up by John Stuart Mill ensuring international interest The 1865 edition of the book included the transfer of preferences from dropped candidates and the STV method was essentially complete although Hare pictured the entire British Isles as one single district Mill proposed it to the House of Commons in 1867 but the British parliament rejected it The name evolved from Mr Hare s scheme to proportional representation then proportional representation with the single transferable vote and finally by the end of the 19th century to the single transferable vote In Australia the political activist Catherine Helen Spence became an enthusiast of STV and an author on the subject Through her influence and the efforts of the Tasmanian politician Andrew Inglis Clark Tasmania became an early pioneer of the system electing the world s first legislators through STV in 1896 prior to its federation into Australia 116 A party list proportional representation system was devised and described in 1878 by Victor D Hondt in Belgium which became the first country to adopt list PR in 1900 for its national parliament D Hondt s method of seat allocation the D Hondt method is still widely used Some Swiss cantons beginning with Ticino in 1890 used the system before Belgium Victor Considerant a utopian socialist devised a similar system in an 1892 book Many European countries adopted similar systems during or after World War I List PR was favoured on the Continent because the use of lists in elections the scrutin de liste was already widespread STV was preferred in the English speaking world because its tradition was the election of individuals 36 In the UK the 1917 Speaker s Conference recommended STV for all multi seat Westminster constituencies but it was only applied to university constituencies lasting from 1918 until 1950 when those constituencies were abolished In Ireland STV was used in 1918 in the Dublin University constituency and was introduced for devolved elections in 1921 STV is currently used for two national lower houses of parliament Ireland since independence as the Irish Free State in 1922 4 and Malta since 1921 long before independence in 1966 117 In Ireland two attempts were made by Fianna Fail governments to abolish STV and replace it with the First Past the Post plurality system Both attempts were rejected by voters in referendums held in 1959 and again in 1968 STV is also prescribed for all other elections in Ireland including that of the presidency although it is there effectively the alternative vote as it is an election with a single winner It is also used for the Northern Ireland Assembly and European and local authorities Scottish local authorities some New Zealand and Australian local authorities 35 the Tasmanian since 1907 and Australian Capital Territory assemblies where the method is known as Hare Clark 118 and the city council in Cambridge Massachusetts since 1941 8 119 PR is used by a majority of the world s 33 most robust democracies with populations of at least two million people only six use plurality or a majoritarian system runoff or instant runoff for elections to the legislative assembly four use parallel systems and 23 use PR 120 PR dominates Europe including Germany and most of northern and eastern Europe it is also used for European Parliament elections France adopted PR at the end of World War II but discarded it in 1958 it was used for parliament elections in 1986 Switzerland has the most widespread use of proportional representation which is the system used to elect not only national legislatures and local councils but also all local executives PR is less common in the English speaking world Malta and Ireland use STV for election of legislators Australia uses it for Senate elections New Zealand adopted MMP in 1993 But UK Canada and India use plurality First Past the Post systems for legislative elections In Canada STV was used to elect provincial legislators in Alberta from 1926 to 1955 and in Manitoba from 1920 to 1953 In both provinces the alternative vote AV was used in rural areas First past the post was re adopted in Alberta by the dominant party for reasons of political advantage In Manitoba a principal reason was the underrepresentation of Winnipeg in the provincial legislature 110 223 234 121 STV has some history in the United States Between 1915 and 1962 twenty four cities used the system for at least one election In many cities minority parties and other groups used STV to break up single party monopolies on elective office One of the most famous cases is New York City where a coalition of Republicans and others pursued the adoption of STV in 1936 as part of an effort to free the city from control by the Tammany Hall machine 122 Another famous case is Cincinnati Ohio where in 1924 Democrats and Progressive wing Republicans secured the adoption of a council manager charter with STV elections in order to dislodge the Republican machine of Rudolph K Hynicka Although Cincinnati s council manager system survives Republicans and other disaffected groups replaced STV with plurality at large voting in 1957 123 From 1870 to 1980 Illinois used a semi proportional cumulative voting system to elect its House of Representatives Each district across the state elected both Republicans and Democrats year after year Cambridge Massachusetts STV and Peoria Illinois cumulative voting have used PR for many years now San Francisco before 1977 and 1980 1999 had citywide elections in which people cast votes for as many as nine candidates but usually five or six candidates simultaneously block voting delivering some of the benefits of proportional representation through the use of a multi member district San Francisco used preferential voting Bucklin Voting in its 1917 city election List of countries using proportional representation EditList of countries using proportional representation to elect the lower or only house of national legislature Party list PR Single transferable vote Mixed member proportional Mixed member majoritarianEighty five countries in the world use a proportional electoral system to fill a nationally elected legislative body The table below lists those countries and gives information on the specific PR system that is in use Detailed information on electoral systems applying to the first chamber of the legislature is maintained by the ACE Electoral Knowledge Network 124 125 Countries using PR as part of a mixed member majoritarian e g parallel voting system are not included Country Body Type of body Type of proportional system List type if applicable Variation of open lists if applicable Allocating formula Electoral threshold Constituencies Governmental system NotesAlbania Parliament Kuvendi Unicameral national legislature Party list PR Open list Highest averages method D Hondt method 4 nationally or 2 5 in a district CountiesAlgeria People s National Assembly Lower house of national legislature Party list PR Open list Largest remainder method Hare quota 5 of votes in respective district 126 Angola National Assembly Lower house of national legislature Party list PR Closed list Highest averages method D Hondt method citation needed 5 member districts and nationwide Double simultaneous vote use to elect the President and the National Assembly at the same election Argentina Chamber of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Party list PR Closed list Highest averages method D Hondt method 3 of registered votersArmenia National Assembly Party list PR with majority jackpot and minority jackpot 127 Open list Largest remainder method quota 5 parties 7 blocs Party lists run off but only if necessary to ensure stable majority of 54 if it is not achieved either immediately one party or through building a coalition 128 129 If a party would win more than 2 3 seats at least 1 3 seats are distributed to the other parties Closed list Largest remainder method quota Aruba Kingdom of the Netherlands Party list PRAustralia Senate Upper house of national legislature Single transferable vote STV Austria National Council Lower house of national legislature Party list PR Open list More open 14 on the district level among votes for the candidates party Largest remainder method Hare quota 4 Single member districts within federal states Lander Parliamentary republicOpen list More open 10 on the regional state level among votes for the candidates party Largest remainder method Hare quota Federal states Lander Open list More open 7 of the on the federal level among votes for the candidates party Highest averages method D Hondt method Single federal nationwide constituencyBelgium Party list PR 5 Benin Party list PRBolivia Chamber of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Additional member system AMS MMP fixed number of seats no leveling seats Closed list 3 Ballots use the double simultaneous vote voters cast a single vote for a presidential candidate and their party s list and local candidates at the same time vote splitting is not possible allowed Chamber of Senators Upper house of national legislature Party list PR Closed list Highest averages method D Hondt method Bosnia and Herzegovina Party list PRBrazil Chamber of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Party list PR Open list States and Federal District Presidential RepublicBulgaria Party list PR 4 Burkina Faso Party list PRBurundi Party list PR 2 Cambodia Party list PRCape Verde Party list PRChile Party list PRColombia Party list PRCosta Rica Party list PRCroatia Party list PR 5 Cyprus Party list PRCzech Republic Party list PR 5 Denmark Folketing Unicameral national legislature Party list PR Open list Highest averages method D Hondt method 2 Parliamentary system 135 constituency seats 40 leveling seatsDominican Republic Party list PREast Timor Party list PREl Salvador Party list PREquatorial Guinea Party list PREstonia Party list PR 5 European Union European Parliament Lower house of supranational legislature varies by state Party list PR in 25 member states Single transferable vote STV in Ireland and MaltaFaroe Islands Party list PRFiji Party list PR 5 Finland Party list PRGermany Mixed member proportional representation MMP Closed list 5 regionally or 3 district winners Greece Party list PR 3 Nationwide closed lists and open lists in multi member districts The winning party used to receive a majority bonus of 50 seats out of 300 but this system will be abolished two elections after 2016 130 In 2020 parliament voted to return to the majority bonus two elections thereafter 131 Greenland Party list PRGuatemala Party list PRGuinea Bissau Party list PRGuyana Party list PRHonduras Party list PRIceland Party list PRIndonesia Party list PR 4 Ireland Lower house of national legislature Single transferable vote STV Israel Party list PR 3 25 Kosovo Party list PRLatvia Saeima Unicameral national legislature Party list PR Open list Most open Highest averages method Sainte Lague method 5 5 multi member constituencies consisting of municipalities 132 Parliamentary republicLebanon Party list PRLesotho Mixed member proportional representation MMP variant using a mixed single voteLiechtenstein Party list PR 8 Luxembourg Party list PRMacedonia Party list PRMalta Single transferable vote STV Moldova Party list PR 6 Montenegro Party list PR 3 Mozambique Party list PRNamibia Party list PRNetherlands Party list PRNew Zealand Mixed member proportional representation MMP 5 or 1 district wonNepal Mixed list 3 Norway Party list PR 4 Paraguay Party list PRPeru Party list PR 5 Poland Party list PR 5 threshold or more for single parties 8 or more for coalitions or 0 or more for minoritiesPortugal Party list PRRomania Party list PRRwanda Party list PRSan Marino Party list PR 3 5 If needed to ensure a stable majority the two best placed parties participate in a run off vote to receive a majority bonus Sao Tome and Principe Party list PRSerbia Party list PR 3 Sint Maarten Party list PRSlovakia Party list PR 5 Slovenia Party list PR 4 South Africa Party list PRSpain Congress of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Party list PR 133 Closed list Highest averages method D Hondt method 3 Provinces of Spain Parliamentary systemSri Lanka Parliament Party list PR 134 135 136 Open list for 196 225 seats Panachage up to 3 preference votes 137 Highest averages method D Hondt method 12 5 per constituency Constituencies Semi presidential systemClosed list for 29 225 seats No threshold None single nationwide constituency Suriname National Assembly Party list PR 138 Open list Most open Highest averages method D Hondt method No threshold Districts of Suriname Assembly independent republicSweden Riksdag Party list PR 139 140 Open list More open 5 of the party vote to override the default party list 141 Highest averages method Sainte Lague method 4 nationally or 12 in a given constituency Counties of Sweden some counties are further subdivided Parliamentary system Leveling seatsSwitzerland National Council Lower house of national legislature Party list PR 142 Open list Panachage Highest averages method Modified D Hondt method Hagenbach Bischoff system No threshold Cantons of Switzerland Semi direct democracy under an assembly independent 143 144 directorial republicCouncil of States only to elect Councillors in Jura 145 Neuchatel 145 Party list PR 146 Open list Most open No threshold 147 None single cantonwide constituency 148 Thailand House of Representatives Lower house of national legislature Mixed member proportional representation 149 Closed list Largest remainder method quota No threshold None single nationwide constituency Parliamentary systemunder a constitutional monarchy Next elections are to be held under parallel votingTogo National Assembly Party list PR 150 Closed list Highest averages method No threshold Constituencies Presidential systemTunisia Assembly of the Representatives of the People Party list PR 151 Closed list Largest remainder method quota No threshold Constituencies Semi presidential systemTurkey Grand National Assembly Party list PR 152 Closed list Highest averages method D Hondt method 7 Provinces of Turkey some provinces are further subdivided Presidential systemUruguay Chamber of Representatives Lower house of national legislature Party list PR 153 154 Closed list Highest averages method D Hondt method No threshold Departments of Uruguay Presidential system Ballots use the double simultaneous vote the same ballot is used for electing the president first round and the two chambersChamber of Senators Upper house of national legislature None single nationwide constituency Incentives for choosing an electoral system EditChanging the electoral system requires the agreement of a majority of the currently selected legislators who were chosen using the incumbent electoral system Therefore an interesting question is what incentives make current legislators support a new electoral system particularly a PR system Many political scientists argue that PR was adopted by parties on the right as a strategy to survive amid suffrage expansion democratization and the rise of workers parties According to Stein Rokkan in a seminal 1970 study parties on the right opted to adopt PR as a way to survive as competitive parties in situations when the parties on the right were not united enough to exist under majoritarian systems 155 This argument was formalized and supported by Carles Boix in a 1999 study 156 Amel Ahmed notes that prior to the adoption of PR many electoral systems were based on majority or plurality rule and that these systems risked eradicating parties on the right in areas where the working class was large in numbers He therefore argues that parties on the right adopted PR as a way to ensure that they would survive as potent political forces amid suffrage expansion 157 A 2021 study linked the adoption of PR to incumbent fears of revolutionary threats 158 In contrast other scholars argue that the choice to adopt PR was also due to a demand by parties on the left to ensure a foothold in politics as well as to encourage a consensual system that would help the left realize its preferred economic policies 159 See also EditCondorcet paradox Direct representation Electoral threshold First past the post voting Hare quota Interactive representation Justified representation a generalization of the principle of proportionality to multiwinner approval voting One person one vote Sainte Lague method Spare vote Two round systemReferences Edit a b c Mill John Stuart 1861 Chapter VII Of True and False Democracy Representation of All and Representation of the Majority only Considerations on Representative Government London Parker Son amp Bourn ACE Project The Electoral Knowledge Network Electoral Systems Comparative Data Table by Question Retrieved 20 November 2014 a b Amy Douglas J How Proportional Representation Elections Work FairVote Retrieved 26 October 2017 a b c Gallagher Michael Ireland The Archetypal Single Transferable Vote System PDF Retrieved 26 October 2014 Hirczy de Mino Wolfgang University of Houston Lane John State University of New York at Buffalo 1999 Malta STV in a two party system PDF Retrieved 24 July 2014 Laakso Markku 1980 Electoral Justice as a Criterion for Different Systems of Proportional Representation Scandinavian Political Studies Wiley 3 3 249 264 doi 10 1111 j 1467 9477 1980 tb00248 x ISSN 0080 6757 Proportional Representation PR ACE Electoral Knowledge Network Retrieved 9 April 2014 a b c Amy Douglas J A Brief History of Proportional Representation in the United States FairVote Retrieved 16 October 2015 a b c d e Forder James 2011 The case against voting reform Oxford Oneworld Publications ISBN 978 1 85168 825 8 Abbott Lewis F British Democracy Its Restoration and Extension ISR Kindle Books 2019 ISBN 9780906321522 Chapter 7 Electoral System Reform Increasing Competition and Voter Choice and Influence 2020 Irish general election Koriyama Y Mace A Laslier J F Treibich R 2013 Optimal apportionment Journal of Political Economy 121 3 584 608 doi 10 1086 670380 S2CID 10158811 Amy Douglas Proportional Representation Voting Systems Fairvote org Takoma Park Retrieved 25 August 2017 a b c d Norris Pippa 1997 Choosing Electoral Systems Proportional Majoritarian and Mixed Systems PDF International Political Science Review Harvard University 18 3 297 312 doi 10 1177 019251297018003005 ISSN 0192 5121 S2CID 9523715 Archived from the original on 2015 04 01 Retrieved 9 April 2014 Colin Rallings Michael Thrasher The 2005 general election analysis of the results PDF Electoral Commission Research Electoral data London Electoral Commission Archived from the original PDF on 20 October 2017 Retrieved 29 March 2015 a b c Commission On Electoral Reform Hansard Society for Parliamentary Government 1976 Report of the Hansard Society Commission on Electoral Reform Hansard Society London a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r s Electoral System Design the New International IDEA Handbook International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance 2005 Retrieved 9 April 2014 1993 Canadian Federal Election Results University of British Columbia Retrieved 25 January 2016 Election 2015 BBC News BBC Retrieved 11 May 2015 Ana Nicolaci da Costa Charlotte Greenfield September 23 2017 New Zealand s ruling party ahead after poll but kingmaker in no rush to decide Reuters Roberts Iain 29 June 2010 People in broad church parties should think twice before attacking coalitions Liberal Democrat Voice Retrieved 29 July 2014 a b c A look at the evidence Fair Vote Canada Retrieved 2 January 2019 Amy Douglas J Single Transferable Vote Or Choice Voting FairVote Retrieved 9 April 2014 Electoral Reform Society s evidence to the Joint Committee on the Draft Bill for House of Lords Reform Electoral Reform Society 21 October 2011 Retrieved 10 May 2015 Harris Paul 20 November 2011 America is better than this paralysis at the top leaves voters desperate for change The Guardian Retrieved 17 November 2014 Krugman Paul 19 May 2012 Going To Extreme The Conscience of a Liberal Paul Krugman Blog The New York Times Co Retrieved 24 Nov 2014 a b c d e f g h Mollison Denis Fair votes in practice STV for Westminster PDF Heriot Watt University Retrieved 3 June 2014 Democrats Edge in House Popular Vote Would Have Increased if All Seats Had Been Contested FairVote Retrieved 7 July 2014 Cox Gary W Fiva Jon H Smith Daniel M 2016 The Contraction Effect How Proportional Representation Affects Mobilization and Turnout PDF The Journal of Politics 78 4 1249 1263 doi 10 1086 686804 hdl 11250 2429132 S2CID 55400647 a b c d Amy Douglas J 2002 Real Choices New Voices How Proportional Representation Elections Could Revitalize American Democracy Columbia University Press ISBN 9780231125499 Mollison Denis 2010 Fair votes in practice STV for Westminster Heriot Watt University Retrieved 3 June 2014 Scheppele Kim Lane April 13 2014 Legal But Not Fair Hungary The Conscience of a Liberal Paul Krugman Blog The New York Times Co Retrieved 12 July 2014 Office for Democratic Institutions and Human Rights 11 July 2014 Hungary Parliamentary Elections 6 April 2014 Final Report OSCE Voting Counts Electoral Reform for Canada PDF Law Commission of Canada 2004 p 22 a b Single Transferable Vote London Electoral Reform Society Retrieved 28 July 2014 a b Humphreys John H 1911 Proportional Representation A Study in Methods of Election London Methuen amp Co Ltd Dutch Evenredige vertegenwoordiging www parlement com in Dutch Retrieved 2020 01 28 a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a Check url value help Carey John M Hix Simon 2011 The Electoral Sweet Spot Low Magnitude Proportional Electoral Systems PDF American Journal of Political Science 55 2 383 397 doi 10 1111 j 1540 5907 2010 00495 x Electoral reform in Chile Tie breaker The Economist 14 February 2015 Retrieved 11 April 2018 a b Laver Michael 1998 A new electoral system for Ireland PDF The Policy Institute Trinity College Dublin Joint Committee on the Constitution PDF Dublin Houses of the Oireachtas July 2010 National projections PDF Monopoly Politics 2014 and the Fair Voting Solution FairVote Retrieved 9 July 2014 Turkey reduces election threshold to 7 percent Turkiye News Hurriyet Daily News Retrieved 2023 03 19 Lubell Maayan March 11 2014 Israel ups threshold for Knesset seats despite opposition boycott Thomson Reuters Retrieved 10 July 2014 Benoit Kenneth Which Electoral Formula Is the Most Proportional PDF doi 10 1093 oxfordjournals pan a029822 Archived from the original PDF on 2010 06 24 a b A Report on Alberta Elections 1905 1982 Party Magnitude and Candidate Selection ACE Electoral Knowledge Network O Kelly Michael The fall of Fianna Fail in the 2011 Irish general election Significance Royal Statistical Society American Statistical Association Archived from the original on 2014 08 06 a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a CS1 maint bot original URL status unknown link Hoag and Hallett Proportional Representation p 74 Karpov Alexander 2008 Measurement of disproportionality in proportional representation systems Mathematical and Computer Modelling 48 9 10 1421 1438 doi 10 1016 j mcm 2008 05 027 Dunleavy Patrick Margetts Helen 2004 How proportional are the British AMS systems Representation 40 4 317 329 doi 10 1080 00344890408523280 S2CID 154404168 Retrieved 25 November 2014 2020 GENERAL ELECTION OFFICIAL RESULTS AND STATISTICS ElectionResults govt nz Electoral Commission 30 November 2020 Wada Junichiro 2016 Apportionment behind the veil of uncertainty The Japanese Economic Review 67 3 348 360 doi 10 1111 jere 12093 S2CID 156608434 Canadian House of Commons Special Committee on Electoral Reform December 2016 Strengthening Democracy in Canada Principles Process and Public Engagement for Electoral Reform polrep Calculate Political Representation Scores version 0 32 7 from R Forge rdrr io Retrieved 2021 04 18 Kestelman Philip March 1999 Quantifying Representativity Voting Matters 10 Retrieved 10 August 2013 Hill I D May 1997 Measuring proportionality Voting Matters 8 As counted from the table in http www wahlrecht de ausland europa htm in German Vorzugsstimme n means open list Party List PR Electoral Reform Society Retrieved 23 May 2016 Gordon Gibson 2003 Fixing Canadian Democracy The Fraser Institute p 76 ISBN 9780889752016 Gallagher Michael Mitchell Paul 2005 The Politics of Electoral Systems Oxford New York Oxford University Press p 11 ISBN 978 0 19 925756 0 The Parliamentary Electoral System in Denmark Copenhagen Ministry of the Interior and Health 2011 Retrieved 1 Sep 2014 The main features of the Norwegian electoral system Oslo Ministry of Local Government and Modernisation 2017 07 06 Retrieved 1 Sep 2014 The Swedish electoral system Stockholm Election Authority 2011 Archived from the original on 18 August 2014 Retrieved 1 Sep 2014 ACE Project Electoral Knowledge Network Mixed Systems Retrieved 29 June 2016 Massicotte Louis 2004 In Search of Compensatory Mixed Electoral System for Quebec PDF Report Bochsler Daniel May 13 2010 Chapter 5 How Party Systems Develop in Mixed Electoral Systems Territory and Electoral Rules in Post Communist Democracies Palgrave Macmillan ISBN 9780230281424 Electoral Systems and the Delimitation of Constituencies International Foundation for Electoral Systems 2 Jul 2009 Moser Robert G December 2004 Mixed electoral systems and electoral system effects controlled comparison and cross national analysis Electoral Studies 23 4 575 599 doi 10 1016 S0261 3794 03 00056 8 Massicotte Louis September 1999 Mixed electoral systems a conceptual and empirical survey Electoral Studies 18 3 341 366 doi 10 1016 S0261 3794 98 00063 8 Additional Member System London Electoral Reform Society Retrieved 16 October 2015 MMP Voting System Wellington Electoral Commission New Zealand 2011 Retrieved 10 Aug 2014 Deutschland hat ein neues Wahlrecht in German Zeit Online 22 February 2013 Report of the Electoral Commission on the Review of the MMP Voting System Wellington Electoral Commission New Zealand 2011 Archived from the original on 7 July 2014 Retrieved 10 Aug 2014 Graham Sean 2016 Dual Member Mixed Proportional A New Electoral System for Canada doi 10 7939 R3 QPPP B676 Retrieved 2022 08 10 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Antony Hodgson Jan 21 2016 Why a referendum on electoral reform would be undemocratic The Tyee Kerry Campbell April 15 2016 P E I electoral reform committee proposes ranked ballot CBC News Elections PEI November 7 2016 Plebiscite Results Archived from the original on November 8 2016 Retrieved October 26 2017 Susan Bradley November 7 2016 P E I plebiscite favours mixed member proportional representation CBC News Eby David May 30 2018 How We Vote 2018 Electoral Reform Referendum Report and Recommendations of the Attorney General PDF Archived from the original PDF on August 31 2018 Retrieved June 9 2018 McElroy Justin June 2 2018 Know your voting systems three types of electoral reform on B C s ballot CBC News 2018 Referendum on Electoral Reform Voting Results Available Elections BC 20 December 2018 Retrieved November 1 2020 Pukelsheim Friedrich September 2009 Zurich s New Apportionment PDF German Research 31 2 10 12 doi 10 1002 germ 200990024 Retrieved 10 August 2014 a b Balinski Michel February 2008 Fair Majority Voting or How to Eliminate Gerrymandering The American Mathematical Monthly 115 2 97 113 doi 10 1080 00029890 2008 11920503 S2CID 1139441 Retrieved 10 August 2014 Akartunali Kerem Knight Philip A June 2017 Network models and biproportional rounding for fair seat allocations in the UK elections Annals of Operations Research University of Strathclyde 253 1 1 19 doi 10 1007 s10479 016 2323 0 ISSN 0254 5330 S2CID 30623821 Retrieved 10 August 2014 Fair Voting Proportional Representation FairVote Retrieved 9 April 2014 a b c Tideman Nicolaus 1995 The Single Transferable Vote Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 1 27 38 doi 10 1257 jep 9 1 27 O Neill Jeffrey C July 2006 Comments on the STV Rules Proposed by British Columbia Voting Matters 22 Retrieved 10 August 2013 Model City Charter National Civic League 9th edition 2021 a b David M Farrell Ian McAllister 2006 The Australian Electoral System Origins Variations and Consequences Sydney UNSW Press ISBN 978 0868408583 Referendum 2011 A look at the STV system The New Zealand Herald Auckland The New Zealand Herald 1 Nov 2011 Retrieved 21 Nov 2014 Change the Way We Elect Round Two of the Debate The Tyee Vancouver 30 Apr 2009 Retrieved 21 Nov 2014 Brill Markus Laslier Jean Francois Skowron Piotr 2016 Multiwinner Approval Rules as Apportionment Methods arXiv 1611 08691 cs GT a b Smith Warren 18 June 2006 Comparative survey of multiwinner election methods PDF Aziz Haris Serge Gaspers Joachim Gudmundsson Simon Mackenzie Nicholas Mattei Toby Walsh 2014 Computational Aspects of Multi Winner Approval Voting Proceedings of the 2015 International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems pp 107 115 arXiv 1407 3247v1 ISBN 978 1 4503 3413 6 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Faliszewski Piotr Skowron Piotr Szufa Stanislaw Talmon Nimrod 2019 05 08 Proportional Representation in Elections STV vs PAV Proceedings of the 18th International Conference on Autonomous Agents and MultiAgent Systems AAMAS 19 Richland SC International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems 1946 1948 ISBN 978 1 4503 6309 9 Lackner Martin Skowron Piotr 2023 Multi Winner Voting with Approval Preferences SpringerBriefs in Intelligent Systems arXiv 2007 01795 doi 10 1007 978 3 031 09016 5 ISBN 978 3 031 09015 8 S2CID 244921148 Kok Jan Smith Warren Reweighted Range Voting a Proportional Representation voting method that feels like range voting Retrieved 4 April 2016 Ryan Ivan Reweighted Range Voting a Proportional Representation voting method that feels like range voting Retrieved 4 April 2016 89th Annual Academy Awards of Merit for Achievements during 2017 PDF Retrieved 4 April 2016 Rule Twenty Two Special Rules for the Visual Effects Award Archived from the original on 14 September 2012 Retrieved 4 April 2016 a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a CS1 maint bot original URL status unknown link Sargent Felix 2019 06 19 Opinion Berkeley s City Council s switch to re weighted range voting adds fairness to the system Berkeleyside Retrieved 2022 05 11 Smith Warren 8 March 2005 Asset voting scheme for multiwinner elections PDF Dodgson Charles 1884 The Principles of Parliamentary Representation London Harrison and Sons Retrieved 28 June 2019 The Elector must understand that in giving his vote to A he gives it to him as his absolute property to use for himself or to transfer to other Candidates or to leave unused Smith Warren Asset voting an interesting and very simple multiwinner voting system Retrieved 4 April 2016 Balinski M amp Laraki R 2011 Majority Judgment MIT pp 389 and 394 Bosworth S et al 2020 Electing Legislatures by Evaluative Proportional Representation EPR An Algorithm https www jpolrisk com legislatures elected by evaluative proportional representation epr an algorithm v3 14 February 2023 M Balinski amp R Laraki 2010 Majority Judgment MIT ISBN 978 0 262 01513 4 Adams John 1776 Thoughts on Government The Adams Papers Digital Edition Massachusetts Historical Society Retrieved 26 July 2014 a b c d e Hoag Clarence Hallett George 1926 Proportional Representation New York The Macmillan Company Madison James Notes of Debates in the Federal Convention of 1787 Wednesday June 6 TeachingAmericanHistory org Retrieved 5 August 2014 Wilson James 1804 Vol 2 Part II Ch 1 Of the constitutions of the United States and of Pennsylvania Of the legislative department I of the election of its members The Works of the Honourable James Wilson Constitution Society Retrieved 5 August 2014 Constitution of the Commonwealth of Pennsylvania 1790 art I VII Of districts for electing Senators Duquesne University Retrieved 9 December 2014 Hoag Effective Voting 1914 p 31 Swain Civics for Montana Students 1912 p 163 Newman Hare Clark in Tasmania p 7 10 Hirczy de Mino Wolfgang 1997 Malta Single Transferable Vote with Some Twists ACE Electoral Knowledge Network Retrieved 5 Dec 2014 The Hare Clark System of Proportional Representation Melbourne Proportional Representation Society of Australia Retrieved 21 Nov 2014 Adoption of Plan E Welcome to the City of Cambridge City of Cambridge MA Archived from the original on 13 December 2014 Retrieved 25 November 2014 Proportional Representation in Most Robust Democracies Fair Vote The Center for Voting And Democracy 7 March 2016 Retrieved 9 October 2017 Jansen Harold John 1998 The Single Transferable Vote in Alberta and Manitoba PDF Library and Archives Canada University of Alberta Retrieved 23 March 2015 Santucci Jack 2016 11 10 Party Splits Not Progressives American Politics Research 45 3 494 526 doi 10 1177 1532673x16674774 ISSN 1532 673X S2CID 157400899 Barber Kathleen 1995 Proportional Representation and Election Reform in Ohio Columbus OH Ohio State University Press ISBN 978 0814206607 ACE Project The Electoral Knowledge Network Electoral Systems Comparative Data World Map Retrieved 24 October 2017 ACE Project The Electoral Knowledge Network Electoral Systems Comparative Data Table by Country Retrieved 24 October 2017 FINAL REPORT ON ALGERIA S LEGISLATIVE ELECTIONS pdf ACE Project National Democratic Institute 10 May 2012 Retrieved 10 January 2015 Following electoral system amendments introduced in April 2021 members of parliament are elected only through closed party lists by party list proportional representation method but with more seats added if leading party takes more than 2 3 of seats or after two round of voting no party takes more than 54 percent of the seats Armenia Parliamentary Elections 2 April 2017 Needs Assessment Mission Report www osce org Retrieved 2022 05 30 DocumentView www arlis am Greek MPs approve end to bonus seats lower voting age Reuters 2016 07 21 Retrieved 2019 06 22 Parliament votes to change election law Kathimerini www ekathimerini com Retrieved 2020 01 25 Saeimas velesanu likums LIKUMI LV in Latvian Section 7 Retrieved 2022 06 10 IPU PARLINE database SPAIN Congreso de los Diputados Electoral system archive ipu org IFES Election Guide Elections Sri Lanka Parliament 2020 www electionguide org IPU PARLINE database SRI LANKA Parliament Electoral system archive ipu org Archived copy PDF www ndi org Archived from the original PDF on 3 March 2016 Retrieved 12 January 2022 a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a CS1 maint archived copy as title link Sri Lanka electors can vote for one party three preferences in 2020 general elections polls chief EconomyNext August 4 2020 IPU PARLINE database SURINAME Nationale Assemblee Electoral system archive ipu org IFES Election Guide Elections Sweden Parliament 2018 www electionguide org IPU PARLINE database SWEDEN Riksdagen Electoral system archive ipu org Swedish Election Authority Elections in Sweden The way its done Archived 2009 02 25 at the Wayback Machine page 16 IPU PARLINE database SWITZERLAND Nationalrat Conseil national Consiglio nazionale Electoral system archive ipu org Shugart Matthew Soberg December 2005 Semi Presidential Systems Dual Executive And Mixed Authority Patterns French Politics 3 3 323 351 doi 10 1057 palgrave fp 8200087 S2CID 73642272 Elgie Robert 2016 Government Systems Party Politics and Institutional Engineering in the Round Insight Turkey 18 4 79 92 ISSN 1302 177X JSTOR 26300453 a b IFES Election Guide Elections Switzerland Council of States 2019 www electionguide org IPU PARLINE database SWITZERLAND Standerat Conseil des Etats Consiglio degli Stati Electoral system archive ipu org Thresholds moot due to these cantons only electing 2 Councillors As these cantons only send two members to the Council of States further subdividing these cantons into constituencies while retaining proportionality would be mathematically impossible Explainer New rules for the House of Representatives Bangkok Post IPU PARLINE database TOGO Assemblee nationale Electoral system archive ipu org IFES Election Guide Elections Tunisia Parliament 2019 www electionguide org IFES Election Guide Elections Turkey Grand National Assembly 2018 www electionguide org IPU PARLINE database URUGUAY Camara de Representantes Electoral system archive ipu org IPU PARLINE database URUGUAY Camara de Senadores Electoral system archive ipu org Rokkan Stein 1970 Citizens elections parties approaches to the comparative study of the processes of development McKay Boix Carles 1999 Setting the Rules of the Game The Choice of Electoral Systems in Advanced Democracies The American Political Science Review 93 3 609 624 doi 10 2307 2585577 hdl 10230 307 ISSN 0003 0554 JSTOR 2585577 S2CID 16429584 Ahmed Amel 2012 Democracy and the Politics of Electoral System Choice Engineering Electoral Dominance Cambridge Cambridge University Press doi 10 1017 cbo9781139382137 ISBN 9781139382137 S2CID 153171400 Gjerlow Haakon Rasmussen Magnus B 2021 Revolution Elite Fear and Electoral Institutions Comparative Politics 54 4 595 620 doi 10 5129 001041522x16316387001621 S2CID 244107337 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a CS1 maint url status link Cusack Thomas R Iversen Torben Soskice David 2007 Economic Interests and the Origins of Electoral Systems The American Political Science Review 101 3 373 391 doi 10 1017 S0003055407070384 hdl 10419 51231 ISSN 0003 0554 JSTOR 27644455 S2CID 2799521 Further reading EditBooks Edit Abbott Lewis F British Democracy Its Restoration and Extension ISR Kindle Books 2019 ISBN 9780906321522 Chapter 7 Electoral System Reform Increasing Competition and Voter Choice and Influence Ashworth H P C Ashworth T R 1900 Proportional Representation Applied to Party Government Melbourne Robertson and Co Amy Douglas J 1993 Real Choices New Voices The Case for Proportional Representation Elections in the United States Columbia University Press Batto Nathan F Huang Chi Tan Alexander C Cox Gary 2016 Mixed Member Electoral Systems in Constitutional Context Taiwan Japan and Beyond Ann Arbor University of Michigan Press Pilon Dennis 2007 The Politics of Voting Edmond Montgomery Publications Colomer Josep M 2003 Political Institutions Oxford University Press Colomer Josep M ed 2004 Handbook of Electoral System Choice Palgrave Macmillan Pukelsheim Friedrich 2014 Proportional Representation Springer Linton Martin Southcott Mary 1998 Making Votes Count The Case for Electoral Reform London Profile Books Forder James 2011 The case against voting reform Oxford Oneworld Publications ISBN 978 1 85168 825 8 Jenifer Hart Proportional Representation Critics of the British Electoral System 1820 1945 Clarendon Press 1992 F D Parsons Thomas Hare and Political Representation in Victorian Britain Palgrave Macmillan 2009 Sawer Marian amp Miskin Sarah 1999 Papers on Parliament No 34 Representation and Institutional Change 50 Years of Proportional Representation in the Senate PDF Department of the Senate ISBN 0 642 71061 9 Journals Edit Hickman John Little Chris November 2000 Seat vote proportionality in Romanian and Spanish parliamentary elections Journal of Southern Europe and the Balkans Online 2 2 197 212 doi 10 1080 713683348 S2CID 153800069 Galasso Vincenzo Nannicini Tommaso December 2015 So closed political selection in proportional systems European Journal of Political Economy 40 B 260 273 doi 10 1016 j ejpoleco 2015 04 008 S2CID 55902803 Golder Sona N Stephenson Laura B Van der Straeten Karine Blais Andre Bol Damien Harfst Philipp Laslier Jean Francois March 2017 Votes for women electoral systems and support for female candidates Politics amp Gender 13 1 107 131 doi 10 1017 S1743923X16000684 External links EditThe De Borda Institute A Northern Ireland based organisation promoting inclusive voting procedures Election Districts Voting improves PR with overlapping districts elections for first past the post alternative vote and single transferable vote voters Electoral Reform Society founded in England in 1884 the longest running PR organization Contains good information about single transferable vote the Society s preferred form of PR Electoral Reform Australia Proportional Representation Society of Australia Fair Vote Canada FairVote USA Why Not Proportional Representation Vote Dilution means Voters have Less Voice Law is Cool site Proportional Representation and British Democracy Debate on British electoral system reform RangeVoting org page on PR Australia s Upper Houses ABC Rear Vision A podcast about the development of Australia s upper houses into STV proportional representation elected chambers Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Proportional representation amp oldid 1154741229, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.