fbpx
Wikipedia

Instant-runoff voting

Instant-runoff voting (IRV) is a type of ranked preferential[1] voting method. It uses a majority voting rule in single-winner elections where there are more than two candidates. It is commonly referred to as ranked-choice voting (RCV) in the United States (although there are other forms of ranked voting),[2] preferential voting in Australia,[3][4] where it has seen the widest adoption; in the United Kingdom, it is generally called alternative vote (AV),[5] whereas in some other countries it is referred to as the single transferable vote, which usually means only its multi-winner variant. All these names are often used inconsistently.[6][7][8][9]

Voters in IRV elections rank the candidates in order of preference. Ballots are initially counted for each voter's top choice. If a candidate has more than half of the first-choice votes, that candidate wins. If not, then the candidate with the fewest votes is eliminated, and the voters who selected the defeated candidate as a first choice then have their votes added to the totals of their next choice. This process continues until a candidate has more than half of the votes. When the field is reduced to two, it has become an "instant runoff" that allows a comparison of the top two candidates head-to-head. IRV is not a proportional voting system but rather a "winner takes all" method, as it elects only one winner in an election (in one district).[10]

IRV is used in national elections in several countries. It is used to elect members of the Australian House of Representatives,[11] as well as most state lower houses and in some local government elections. It is the method used to elect the President of India, the President of Ireland,[12] and (in a modified form) the National Parliament of Papua New Guinea.[13] It is used by many political parties for internal primaries/elections to elect party leaders and presidential/prime ministerial candidates, and by private associations for various voting purposes such as choosing the Academy Award for Best Picture.

Election procedure

Process

 
Flowchart of Instant Runoff Voting

In instant-runoff voting, as with other ranked election methods, each voter ranks the list of candidates in order of preference. Under a common ballot layout, the voter marks a '1' beside the most preferred candidate, a '2' beside the second-most preferred, and so forth, in ascending order.

The mechanics of the process are the same regardless of how many candidates the voter ranks, and how many are left unranked. In most implementations, the voter ranks as many or as few choices as they wish.

The instant-runoff vote counting procedure is as follows:

  1. Eliminate the candidate appearing as the first preference on the fewest ballots.
  2. If only one candidate remains, elect this candidate and stop.
  3. Otherwise go to 1.

If there is an exact tie for last place in numbers of votes, various tie-breaking rules determine which candidate to eliminate. The set of all candidates with the fewest first-order votes whose votes together total less than any other candidate's can be eliminated without changing the outcome. This bulk elimination can bypass irrelevant ties, for example if one candidate receives 15 first-order votes and four others receive 5, 5, 3, and 1, and no other candidate receives fewer than 15, all four of the latter candidates will be eliminated during the next four rounds, and so can be eliminated immediately without considering the tie.

Ballots assigned to eliminated candidates are added to the totals of one of the remaining candidates based on the next preference ranked on each ballot. The process repeats until one candidate achieves a majority of votes cast for continuing candidates. Ballots on which all of a voter's ranked candidates are eliminated become inactive.

Candidate order on the ballot paper

 
The Australian Electoral Commission holding a blind ballot to determine the order of candidates on the ballot paper, 2004

The common ways to list candidates on a ballot paper are alphabetically or by random lot. In some cases, candidates may also be grouped by political party. Alternatively, Robson Rotation involves randomly changing candidate order for each print run.

Party strategies

Where preferential voting is used for the election of an assembly or council, parties and candidates often advise their supporters on their lower preferences, especially in Australia where a voter must rank all candidates to cast a valid ballot. This can lead to "preference deals", a form of pre-election bargaining, in which smaller parties agree to direct their voters in return for support from the winning party on issues critical to the small party.[citation needed] It can also sometimes lead to joint campaigning between candidates with similar platforms. However, these strategies rely on the assumption that supporters of a party or candidate are receptive to advice on the other preferences on their ballot.

Counting logistics

Most IRV elections historically have been tallied by hand, including in elections to Australia's House of Representatives and most state governments. In the modern era, voting equipment can be used to administer the count either partially or fully.

In Australia, the returning officer now usually declares the two candidates that are most likely to win each seat. The votes are always counted by hand at the polling station monitored by scrutineers from each candidate. The first part of the count is to record the first choice for all candidates. Votes for candidates other than the two likely winners are then allocated to them in a second pass. The whole process of counting the votes by hand and allocating preferences is typically completed within two hours on election night at a cost of $7.68 per elector in 2010 to run the entire election.[14]

Ireland in its presidential elections has several dozen counting centers around the nation. Each center reports its totals and receives instructions from the central office about which candidate or candidates to eliminate in the next round of counting based on which candidate is in last place. The count typically is completed the day after the election, as in 1997.[15]

In the United States, nearly all jurisdictions that use this format—like Maine, Oakland and San Francisco—administer IRV elections on voting machines, with optical scanning machines recording preferences and software tallying the IRV algorithm as soon as all ballots are recorded.[16] In its first use of IRV in 2009, Minneapolis tallied first choices on optical scan equipment at the polls and then used a central hand-count for the IRV tally, but has since administered elections without hand tallies[17] Portland, Maine in 2011 used its usual voting machines to tally first choice at the polls, then a central scan with different equipment if an IRV tally was necessary.[18]

The election results from IRV cannot be counted additively: all ballots must be present prior to the first elimination. Methods like plurality voting and pairwise voting can divide the work of counting and sum the results as more votes are reported. To produce pairwise results, each candidate ranked on a ballot receives one vote against each alternative ranked lower and each not ranked on that ballot; equal rankings, including non-ranked candidates, are ties and no vote is tallied. These tallies can be summed to produce a complete matrix of pairwise elections, which can then be used to compute the Smith set or to calculate the outcomes of Schulze, Minimax, Ranked Pairs, and other methods.[19]

IRV is very unlikely to give rise to a tie when the number of voters is large. For this reason it is sometimes advocated as part of a tie break for methods (such as the Smith set) which do not have this property: see Smith/IRV and Tideman's Alternative.

Voter confusion

Research shows that voters in general can understand and use IRV. Various surveys in the U.S. found 80%–90% of voters reported understanding the ballot very well, and 90% reported it was easy to use. Voter comprehension increased with repeated use, eliminating demographic disparities over time. Older voters were more likely to say they found the system confusing, but in practice correctly completed IRV ballots at the same rate.[20]

Invalid ballots and incomplete ballots

All forms of ranked choice voting reduce to plurality when all ballots rank only one candidate. By extension, ballots for which all candidates ranked are eliminated are equivalent to votes for any non-winner in plurality, and considered exhausted.

Because the ballot marking is more complex, there can be an increase in spoiled ballots. In Australia, voters are required to write a number beside every candidate,[21] and the rate of spoiled ballots can be five times higher than plurality voting elections.[22][unreliable source?] Since Australia has compulsory voting, however, it is difficult to tell how many ballots are deliberately spoiled.[23] Where complete rankings are not required, a ballot may become inactive if none of the ranked choices on that ballot advance to the next round.

Most jurisdictions with IRV do not require complete rankings and may use columns to indicate preference instead of numbers. In American elections with IRV, more than 99% of voters typically cast a valid ballot.[24]

A 2015 study of four local U.S. elections that used IRV found that inactive ballots occurred often enough in each of them that the winner of each election did not receive a majority of votes cast in the first round. The rate of inactive ballots in each election ranged from a low of 9.6% to a high of 27.1%.[25] As one point of comparison, the number of votes cast in the 190 regularly scheduled primary runoff elections for the U.S House and U.S. Senate from 1994 to 2016 decreased from the initial primary on average by 39%, according to a 2016 study by FairVote.[26]

Terminology

Instant-runoff voting derives its name from the way the ballot count simulates a series of runoffs, similar to an exhaustive ballot system, except that voter preferences do not change between rounds.[27] It is also known as the alternative vote, transferable vote, ranked-choice voting (RCV), single-seat ranked-choice voting, or preferential voting.[28]

Britons and New Zealanders generally call IRV the "alternative vote" (AV).[29][30] while in Canada it is called "ranked choice voting".[31] Australians, who use IRV for most single winner elections, call IRV "preferential voting".[32] American NGO FairVote uses the terminology "ranked choice voting" to refer to IRV in the case of single-winner offices and to refer to single transferable vote in the case of multi-winner offices.[33] Jurisdictions using IRV such as San Francisco, California, Maine, Alaska, and Minneapolis, Minnesota have codified the term "ranked choice voting" in their laws. San Francisco has argued the word "instant" in term "instant runoff voting" could confuse voters into expecting results to be immediately available.[34][35]

IRV is occasionally referred to (rather confusingly) either as Hare's method[36] (after Sir Thomas Hare) or as Ware's method after the American William Robert Ware. When the single transferable vote (STV) method is applied to a single-winner election, it becomes IRV; the government of Ireland has called IRV "proportional representation" based on the fact that the same ballot form is used to elect its president by IRV and parliamentary seats by STV, but IRV is a winner-take-all election method.[37] State law in South Carolina[38] and Arkansas[39] use "instant runoff" to describe the practice of having certain categories of absentee voters cast ranked-choice ballots before the first round of an election and counting those ballots in any subsequent runoff elections.

Properties, advantages and disadvantages

Wasted votes and Condorcet winners

Unlike a plurality voting system that just compares the top two vote getters, instant-runoff voting minimizes the problem of wasted votes.[40] However, it does not ensure the election of a Condorcet winner, which is the candidate that would win a direct election against any other candidate in the race. These issues are illustrated in the following election:

 
In IRV for a polarized election between left, right, and center, the votes for B are not wasted, but the consensus candidate (B) is not elected
Simple election example
First choice A B C
Second choice B A C B
Voters 36% 10% 20% 34%
  • A wins plurality vote: second place preferences are ignored, so candidate A wins with 36% of the vote as against 34% for C and 30% (10+20) for B.
  • C wins IRV vote: candidate B gets the fewest first place votes so is eliminated in the first round. Candidate C gets more of B's second choice preferences than candidate A, winning the second round by 54% (20+34) to 46% (36+10). This result is the same as would occur if there was a primary with 3 candidates and a general election with the two remaining candidates. Every voter gets a say in the final runoff, so no votes are wasted.
  • B wins IRV / bottom two runoff: in the first round candidates B and C are in last place, so they go head to head. Candidate A's second place votes go to candidate B, so candidate B wins 66% (36+10+20) to 34% over candidate C. In the second runoff round candidate C has been eliminated so candidates A and B go head to head. Candidate C's second place votes go to candidate B, so candidate B wins 64% (10+20+34) to 36% over candidate A. Bottom Two Runoff is an example of a Condorcet method of voting.

Resistance to strategy

Instant-runoff voting has notably high resistance to tactical voting but less to strategic nomination.

Tactical voting

The Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem demonstrates that no (deterministic, non-dictatorial) voting method using only the preference rankings of the voters can be entirely immune from tactical voting. This implies that IRV is susceptible to tactical voting in some circumstances.

Research concludes that IRV is one of the voting methods least vulnerable to tactical voting, with theorist Nicolaus Tideman noting that, "alternative voting is quite resistant to strategy,"[41] and Australian political analyst Antony Green dismissing suggestions of tactical voting.[42] James Green-Armytage tested four ranked-choice methods, and found the alternative vote to be the second-most-resistant to tactical voting, though it was beaten by a class of AV-Condorcet hybrids, and did not resist strategic withdrawal by candidates well.[43] These analyses only apply to tactical voting, but not to other forms of manipulation; for example, Tideman and Robinette demonstrate a method by which a candidate modifies their campaign to appeal to a slightly broader range of voters, including those of a popular opponent, so as to "bracket" that opponent out (cause them to be eliminated earlier).[44]

By not meeting the monotonicity, Condorcet winner, and participation criteria, IRV may incentivize forms of tactical voting (such as compromising) when voters have sufficient information about other voters' preferences, such as from accurate pre-election polling.[45] FairVote mentions that monotonicity failure can lead to situations where "having more voters rank [a] candidate first, can cause [the candidate] to switch from being a winner to being a loser."[46] This occurs when a mutual majority exists which would elect a different candidate than the Condorcet candidate and a minority coalition running off to a single candidate exceeds one-half the size of this majority: the minority candidate cannot be eliminated until the mutual majority runs off to a majority winner. Moving the winner to the top of the minority ballots can shrink the minority sufficiently for their candidate to be eliminated, and their votes then cause the election of a different candidate. This situation occurred in the 2009 Burlington mayoral election: had several Kurt Wright voters moved Bob Kiss to the top of their ballots, the winner would have changed from Bob Kiss to Andy Montroll. The change in lower candidates is important: whether votes are shifted to the leading candidate, shifted to a fringe candidate, or discarded altogether is of no importance.

Tactical voting in IRV seeks to alter the order of eliminations in early rounds, to ensure that the original winner is challenged by a stronger opponent in the final round. For example, in a three-party election where voters for both the left and right prefer the centrist candidate to stop the opposing candidate from winning, those voters who care more about defeating the opposition than electing their own candidate may cast a tactical first-preference vote for the centrist candidate.

The 2009 mayoral election in Burlington, Vermont provides an example in which strategy theoretically could have worked but would have been unlikely in practice. In that election, most supporters of the candidate who lost in the final round (a Republican who led in first choices) preferred the Condorcet winner, a Democrat, to the IRV winner, the Progressive Party nominee. If 371 (24.7%) out of the 1,510 backers of the Republican candidate (who also preferred the Democrat over the Progressive candidate for mayor) had insincerely raised the Democrat from their second choice to their first (not changing their rankings relative to their least favorite candidate, the Progressive), the Democrat would then have advanced to the final round (instead of their favorite), defeated any opponent, and proceeded to win the IRV election.[45] This is an example of potential voter regret in that these voters who sincerely ranked their favorite candidate as first, find out after the fact that they caused the election of their least favorite candidate, which can lead to the voting tactic of compromising. Yet because the Republican led in first choices and only narrowly lost the final instant runoff, his backers would have been highly unlikely to pursue such a strategy.[citation needed] This strategy still would not elect the Republican, due to a lack of preferences towards them.

Spoiler effect

The spoiler effect is when a difference is made to the anticipated outcome of an election due to the presence on the ballot paper of a candidate who (predictably) will lose. Most often this is when two or more politically similar candidates divide the vote for the more popular end of the political spectrum. That is, each receives fewer votes than a single opponent on the unpopular end of the spectrum who is disliked by the majority of voters but who wins from the advantage that, on that unpopular side, they are unopposed. Strategic nomination relies on triggering this situation, and requires understanding of both the electoral process and the demographics of the district.

Proponents of IRV claim that IRV eliminates the spoiler effect,[47][48][49][50] since IRV makes it safe to vote honestly for marginal parties: Under a plurality method, voters who sympathize most strongly with a marginal candidate are strongly encouraged to instead vote for a more popular candidate who shares some of the same principles, since that candidate has a much greater chance of being elected and a vote for the marginal candidate will not result in the marginal candidate's election. An IRV method reduces this problem, since the voter can rank the marginal candidate first and the mainstream candidate second; in the likely event that the fringe candidate is eliminated, the vote is not wasted but is transferred to the second preference.

However, when the third-party candidate is more competitive, they can still act as a spoiler under IRV,[51][52][53][54][55][56] by taking away first-choice votes from the more mainstream candidate until that candidate is eliminated, and then that candidate's second-choice votes helping a more-disliked candidate to win. In these scenarios, it would have been better for the third party voters if their candidate had not run at all (spoiler effect), or if they had voted dishonestly, ranking their favorite second rather than first (favorite betrayal.)[57][58] This is the same bracketing effect exploited by Robinette and Tideman in their research on strategic campaigning, where a candidate alters their campaign to cause a change in voter honest choice, resulting in the elimination of a candidate who nevertheless remains more preferred by voters.

For example, in the 2009 Burlington, Vermont mayoral election, if the Republican candidate who lost in the final instant runoff had not run, the Democratic candidate would have defeated the winning Progressive candidate. In that sense, the Republican candidate was a spoiler—(albeit for an opposing Democrat, rather than some political ally) even though leading in first choice support.[45][59]

By contrast, in the seat of Prahran during the 2014 Victorian State Election, despite the Greens candidate outlasting the more centrist Labor candidate during counting, most of the Labor preferences ultimately helped elect the Greens rather than the further right Liberal candidate. In this case, the Greens candidate, despite only having the third most primary votes, ultimately was not a spoiler and was able to be elected.

In practice, IRV does not seem to discourage candidacies. In Australia's House of Representatives elections in 2007, for example, the average number of candidates in a district was seven, and at least four candidates ran in every district; notwithstanding the fact that Australia only has two major political parties. Every seat was won with a majority of the vote, including several where results would have been different under plurality voting.[60] A study of ballot image data found that all of the 138 RCV elections held in four Bay Area cities in California elected the Condorcet winner, including many with large fields of candidates and 46 where multiple rounds of counting were required to determine a winner.[61]

Proportionality

IRV is a single-winner application of a proportional voting method, technically single-winner STV with a droop quota (50%+1). Like all winner-take-all voting methods, IRV tends to exaggerate the number of seats won by the largest parties; small parties without majority support in any given constituency are unlikely to earn seats in a legislature, although their supporters will be more likely to be part of the final choice between the two strongest candidates.[10] A simulation of IRV in the 2010 UK general election by the Electoral Reform Society concluded that the election would have altered the balance of seats among the three main parties, but the number of seats won by minor parties would have remained unchanged.[62]

Australia

Australia, a nation with a long record of using IRV for the election of legislative bodies, has had representation in its parliament broadly similar to that expected by plurality methods.

Medium-sized parties, such as the National Party of Australia, can co-exist with coalition partners such as the Liberal Party of Australia, and can compete against it without fear of losing seats to other parties due to vote splitting, although generally in practice these two parties only compete against each other when a sitting member of the coalition leaves Parliament.[63] IRV is more likely to result in legislatures where no single party has an absolute majority of seats (a hung parliament),[citation needed] but does not generally produce as fragmented a legislature as a fully proportional method, such as is used for the House of Representatives of the Netherlands, where coalitions of numerous small parties are needed for a majority.

Costs

The costs of printing and counting ballot papers for an IRV election are no different from those of any other method using the same technology. However, the more-complicated counting system may encourage officials to introduce more advanced technology, such as software counters or electronic voting machines. Pierce County, Washington, election officials outlined one-time costs of $857,000 to implement IRV for its elections in 2008, covering software and equipment, voter education and testing.[64]

Because it does not require two separate votes, IRV is assumed to cost less than two-round primary/general or general/runoff election methods.[65] However, in 2009, the auditor of Pierce County reported that the ongoing costs of the system were not necessarily balanced by the costs of eliminating runoffs for most county offices, because those elections may be needed for other offices not elected by IRV.[66] Other jurisdictions have reported immediate cost savings.[67]

Australian elections are counted by hand. The 2010 federal election cost a total of $7.68 per elector of which only a small proportion is the actual counting of votes.[14] Counting is now normally performed in a single pass at the polling center as described above.

The perceived costs or cost savings of adopting an IRV method are commonly used by both supporters and critics. In the 2011 referendum on the Alternative Vote in the UK, the NOtoAV campaign was launched with a claim that adopting the method would cost £250 million; commentators argued that this headline figure had been inflated by including £82 million for the cost of the referendum itself, and a further £130 million on the assumption that the UK would need to introduce electronic voting systems, when ministers had confirmed that there was no intention of implementing such technology, whatever the outcome of the election.[68] Automated vote counting is seen by some to have a greater potential for election fraud;[69] IRV supporters counter these claims with recommended audit procedures,[70] or note that automated counting is not required for the method at all.

Negative campaigning

John Russo, Oakland City Attorney, argued in the Oakland Tribune on 24 July 2006 that "Instant runoff voting is an antidote to the disease of negative campaigning. IRV led to San Francisco candidates campaigning more cooperatively. Under the method, their candidates were less likely to engage in negative campaigning because such tactics would risk alienating the voters who support 'attacked' candidates", reducing the chance that they would support the attacker as a second or third choice.[71][72] Campaign strategists in New York City reported that after IRV was introduced, they became more careful not to attack other candidates in ways that might offend voters that would otherwise give the campaign a second-choice ranking.[73]

In 2013–2014, the Rutgers-Eagleton Poll surveyed more than 4,800 likely voters in 21 cities after their local city elections—half in cities with IRV elections and 14 in control cities selected by project leaders Caroline Tolbert of the University of Iowa and Todd Donovan of Western Washington University. Among findings, respondents in IRV cities reported candidates spent less time criticizing opponents than in cities that did not use IRV. In the 2013 survey, for example, 5% of respondents said that candidates criticized each other "a great deal of the time" as opposed to 25% in non-IRV cities. An accompanying survey of candidates reported similar findings.[74]

Internationally, Benjamin Reilly suggests instant-runoff voting eases ethnic conflict in divided societies.[75] This feature was a leading argument for why Papua New Guinea adopted instant-runoff voting.[76] However, Lord Alexander's objections to the conclusions of the British Independent Commission on the Voting System's report[77] cites the example of Australia saying "their politicians tend to be, if anything, more blunt and outspoken than our own".

Plural voting

Some critics of IRV hold that voters supporting major candidates get their second and third place preferences ignored as those candidates are eliminated before their first choice is eliminated. Meanwhile, if you support a fringe candidate, it is more likely that your second and third place choices will be used. In Ann Arbor, Michigan, for example, arguments over IRV in letters to newspapers included the belief that IRV "gives minority candidate voters two votes", because some voters' ballots may count for their first choice in the first round and a lesser choice in a later round.[78] The argument that IRV represents plural voting is sometimes used in arguments over the "fairness" of the method, and has led to several legal challenges in the United States. In every instance, state and federal judges have rejected this argument.

The argument was addressed and rejected by a Michigan court in 1975; in Stephenson v. the Ann Arbor Board of City Canvassers, the court held "majority preferential voting" (as IRV was then known) to be in compliance with the Michigan and United States constitutions, writing:[79]

Under the "M.P.V. System", however, no one person or voter has more than one effective vote for one office. No voter's vote can be counted more than once for the same candidate. In the final analysis, no voter is given greater weight in his or her vote over the vote of another voter, although to understand this does require a conceptual understanding of how the effect of a "M.P.V. System" is like that of a run-off election. The form of majority preferential voting employed in the City of Ann Arbor's election of its Mayor does not violate the one-man, one-vote mandate nor does it deprive anyone of equal protection rights under the Michigan or United States Constitutions.

The same argument was advanced in opposition to IRV in Maine. Governor Paul LePage claimed, ahead of the 2018 primary elections, that IRV would result in "one person, five votes", as opposed to "one person, one vote".[80] In litigation following the results of the 2018 election for Maine's 2nd congressional district, Representative Bruce Poliquin claimed that IRV allowed his opponents to "cast ballots for three different candidates in the same election".[81] Federal judge Lance Walker rejected this claim, and the 1st circuit court denied Poliquin's emergency appeal, leading to Poliquin dropping his claim.[82]

Participation

Primary and runoff elections tend to have lower turnout than general elections. Consolidating these into a single election increases voter participation.[83]

History and use

History

This method was considered by Condorcet as early as 1788, though only to condemn it, for its ability to eliminate a candidate preferred by a majority of voters.[84][85]

IRV can be seen as a special case of the single transferable vote method, which began use in the 1850s. It is historically known as Ware's method, due to the implementation of STV in 1871 at Harvard College by American architect William Robert Ware, who suggested it could also be used for single-winner elections.[86][87] Unlike the single transferable vote in multi-seat elections, however, the only ballot transfers are from backers of candidates who have been eliminated.

The first known use of an IRV-like method in a governmental election was in the 1893 general election in the Colony of Queensland (in present-day Australia).[88] The variant used for this election was a "contingent vote", where all candidates but two are eliminated in the first round. IRV in its true form was first used in Western Australia, in the 1908 state election. The Hare-Clark system was introduced for the Tasmanian House of Assembly at the 1909 state election.

IRV was introduced for federal (nationwide) elections in Australia after the Swan by-election in October 1918, in response to the rise of the conservative Country Party, representing small farmers. The Country Party split the non-Labor vote in conservative country areas, allowing Labor candidates to win without a majority of the vote. The conservative government of Billy Hughes introduced IRV (in Australia called "preferential voting") as a means of allowing competition between the Coalition parties without putting seats at risk. It was first used at the Corangamite by-election on 14 December 1918, and at a national level at the 1919 election.[89] IRV continued to benefit the Coalition until the 1990 election, when for the first time Labor obtained a net benefit from IRV.[90]

Global use

National level elections

Country Body or office Type of body or office Electoral system Total seats Notes
Australia House of Representatives Lower chamber of legislature IRV 151
Ireland President Head of State IRV
Dáil Éireann Lower chamber of legislature Single transferable vote (STV), by-elections using IRV 158[91]
Papua New Guinea National Parliament Unicameral legislature Modified IRV: Ranking of maximum 3 candidates 109
United States President (via Electoral College) Head of State and Government Alaska and Maine use IRV to select the state winner. In Maine, 2 electors are allocated to the winner and the others (currently 2) are allocated by congressional district, while in Alaska, the winner gets all electors of the state in the Electoral College system (as Alaska has only one at-large district, the effect is the same).
House of Representatives Lower chamber of legislature IRV in Maine

Nonpartisan primary system with IRV in the second round (among top four candidates) in Alaska.[92][93][94][95]

Robert's Rules of Order

In the United States, the sequential elimination method used by IRV is described in Robert's Rules of Order Newly Revised[1] as an example of preferential voting:

The term preferential voting refers to any of a number of voting methods by which, on a single ballot when there are more than two possible choices, the second or less-preferred choices of voters can be taken into account if no candidate or proposition attains a majority. While it is more complicated than other methods of voting in common use, and is not a substitute for the normal procedure of repeated balloting until a majority is obtained, preferential voting is especially useful and fair in an election by mail if it is impractical to take more than one ballot. In such cases, it makes possible a more representative result than under a rule that a plurality shall elect ... Preferential voting has many variations. One method is described here by way of illustration.[96]

The instant-runoff voting method is then detailed.[97]Robert's Rules continues:

The system of preferential voting just described should not be used in cases where it is possible to follow the normal procedure of repeated balloting until one candidate or proposition attains a majority. Although this type of preferential ballot is preferable to an election by plurality, it affords less freedom of choice than repeated balloting, because it denies voters the opportunity of basing their second or lesser choices on the results of earlier ballots, and because the candidate or proposition in last place is automatically eliminated and may thus be prevented from becoming a compromise choice.[98]

Two other books on American parliamentary procedure take a similar stance, disapproving of plurality voting and describing preferential voting as an option, if authorized in the bylaws, when repeated balloting is impractical: The Standard Code of Parliamentary Procedure[99] and Riddick's Rules of Procedure.[100]

Similar methods

Runoff voting

The term instant runoff voting is derived from the name of a class of voting methods called runoff voting. In runoff voting voters do not rank candidates in order of preference on a single ballot. Instead a similar effect is achieved by using multiple rounds of voting. All multi-round runoff voting methods allow voters to change their preferences in each round, incorporating the results of the prior round to influence their decision. This is not possible in IRV, as participants vote only once, and this prohibits certain forms of tactical voting that can be prevalent in "standard" runoff voting.

Exhaustive ballot

A method closer to IRV is the exhaustive ballot. In this method—one familiar to fans of the television show American Idol—one candidate is eliminated after each round, and many rounds of voting are used, rather than just two.[101] Because holding many rounds of voting on separate days is generally expensive, the exhaustive ballot is not used for large-scale, public elections.

Two-round methods

The simplest form of runoff voting is the two-round system, which typically excludes all but two candidates after the first round, rather than gradually eliminating candidates over a series of rounds. Eliminations can occur with or without allowing and applying preference votes to choose the final two candidates. A second round of voting or counting is only necessary if no candidate receives an overall majority of votes. This method is used in Mali, France and the Finnish and Slovenian presidential election.

Contingent vote

 
Top-two IRV

The contingent vote, also known as Top-two IRV, or batch-style, is the same as IRV except that if no candidate achieves a majority in the first round of counting, all but the two candidates with the most votes are eliminated, and the second preferences for those ballots are counted. As in IRV, there is only one round of voting.

Under a variant of contingent voting used in Sri Lanka, and the elections for Mayor of London in the United Kingdom, voters rank a specified maximum number of candidates. In London, the Supplementary Vote allows voters to express first and second preferences only. Sri Lankan voters rank up to three candidates for the President of Sri Lanka.

While similar to "sequential-elimination" IRV, top-two can produce different results. Excluding more than one candidate after the first count might eliminate a candidate who would have won under sequential elimination IRV. Restricting voters to a maximum number of preferences is more likely to exhaust ballots if voters do not anticipate which candidates will finish in the top two. This can encourage voters to vote more tactically, by ranking at least one candidate they think is likely to win.

Conversely, a practical benefit of 'contingent voting' is expediency and confidence in the result with only two rounds. Particularly in elections with few (e.g., fewer than 100) voters, numerous ties can destroy confidence. Heavy use of tie-breaking rules leaves uncomfortable doubts over whether the winner might have changed if a recount had been performed.

Larger runoff process

IRV may also be part of a larger runoff process:

  • Some jurisdictions that hold runoff elections allow absentee (only) voters to submit IRV ballots, because the interval between votes is too short for a second round of absentee voting. IRV ballots enable absentee votes to count in the second (general) election round if their first choice does not make the runoff. Arkansas, South Carolina and Springfield, Illinois adopt this approach.[102] Louisiana uses it only for members of the United States Service or who reside overseas.[103]
  • IRV can quickly eliminate weak candidates in early rounds of an exhaustive ballot runoff, using rules to leave the desired number of candidates for further balloting.
  • IRV allows an arbitrary victory threshold in a single round of voting, e.g., 60%. In such cases a second vote may be held to confirm the winner.[104]
  • IRV elections that require a majority of cast ballots but not that voters rank all candidates may require more than a single IRV ballot due to exhausted ballots.
  • Robert's Rules recommends preferential voting for elections by mail and requiring a majority of cast votes to elect a winner, giving IRV as their example. For in-person elections, they recommend repeated balloting until one candidate receives an absolute majority of all votes cast. Repeated voting allows voters to turn to a candidate as a compromise who polled poorly in the initial election.[1]

The common feature of these IRV variations is that one vote is counted per ballot per round, with rules that eliminate the weakest candidate(s) in successive rounds. Most IRV implementations drop the requirement for a majority of cast ballots.[105]

Equal rankings

Unlike many single-winner methods, instant-runoff cannot accept equal rankings[citation needed], and must discard ballots with multiple first-preferred remaining alternatives: such ballots would be equivalent to casting multiple ballots in a plurality election. The inability to cast equal votes—including the inability to truncate ballots in some jurisdictional rules—creates difficulties for the epistemic properties of democracy. Under theories of public reason, a democratic decision uses the knowledge of the whole voting body. When a voter has no preference, or decides themselves that their ability to form a correct preference is insufficient, the correct vote is no vote. This is expressed by equal rankings, and when all rankings are equal it is expressed by no vote.

Comparison to first-past-the-post

At the Australian federal election in September 2013, 135 out of the 150 House of Representatives seats (or 90 percent) were won by the candidate who led on first preferences. The other 15 seats (10 percent) were won by the candidate who placed second on first preferences.[106]

Variations

 
Example of a full preferential ballot paper from the Australian House of Representatives

A number of IRV methods, varying as to ballot design and as to whether or not voters are obliged to provide a full list of preferences, are in use in different countries and local governments.

In an optional preferential voting system, voters can give a preference to as many candidates as they wish. They may make only a single choice, known as "bullet voting", and some jurisdictions accept a single box marked with an "X" (as opposed to a numeral "1") as valid for the first preference. This may result in exhausted ballots, where all of a voter's preferences are eliminated before a candidate is elected, such that the "majority" in the final round may only constitute a minority fraction of all ballots cast. Optional preferential voting is used for elections for the President of Ireland and the New South Wales Legislative Assembly. Optional preferential voting is used for some elections in Queensland.[107][108]

In a full-preferential voting method, voters are required to mark a preference for every candidate standing.[109] Ballots that do not contain a complete ordering of all candidates are in some jurisdictions considered spoilt or invalid, even if there are only two candidates standing. This can become burdensome in elections with many candidates and can lead to "donkey voting", in which some voters simply choose candidates at random or in top-to-bottom order, or a voter may order his or her preferred candidates and then fill in the remainder on a donkey basis. Full preferential voting is used for elections to the Australian federal parliament and for most State parliaments.

Other methods only allow marking preferences for a maximum of the voter's top three favorites, a form of partial preferential voting.[110]

A version of instant-runoff voting applying to the ranking of parties was first proposed for elections in Germany in 2013[111] as spare vote.[112]

Voting method criteria

Scholars rate voting methods using mathematically derived voting method criteria, which describe desirable features of a method. No ranked-preference method can meet all of the criteria, because some of them are mutually exclusive, as shown by statements such as Arrow's impossibility theorem and the Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem.

Many of the mathematical criteria by which voting methods are compared were formulated for voters with ordinal preferences. If voters vote according to the same ordinal preferences in both rounds, criteria can be applied to two-round systems of runoffs, and in that case, each of the criteria failed by IRV is also failed by the two-round system as they relate to automatic elimination of trailing candidates. Partial results exist for other models of voter behavior in the two-round method: see the two-round system article's criterion compliance section for more information.

A table summarising satisfaction of the criteria by IRV and other methods is shown in an appendix

Satisfied criteria

The Condorcet loser criterion states that "if a candidate would lose a head-to-head competition against every other candidate, then that candidate must not win the overall election". IRV (like all voting methods with a final runoff round) meets this criterion, since the Condorcet loser cannot win a runoff, however IRV can still elect the "second-worst" candidate, when the two worst candidates are the only ones remaining in the final round.[113]

The independence of clones criterion states that "the election outcome remains the same even if an identical candidate who is equally preferred decides to run." IRV meets this criterion.[114] The later-no-harm criterion states that "if a voter alters the order of candidates lower in his/her preference (e.g. swapping the second and third preferences), then that does not affect the chances of the most preferred candidate being elected."

The majority criterion states that "if one candidate is preferred by an absolute majority of voters, then that candidate must win." The mutual majority criterion states that "if an absolute majority of voters prefer every member of a group of candidates to every candidate not in that group, then one of the preferred group must win." Note that this is satisfied because when all but one candidate that a mutual majority prefer is eliminated, the votes of the majority all flow to the remaining candidate, in contrast to FPTP, where the majority would be treated as separate small groups. The resolvability criterion states that "the probability of an exact tie must diminish as more votes are cast."

Non-satisfied criteria

Condorcet winner criterion

The Condorcet winner criterion states that "if a candidate would win a head-to-head competition against every other candidate, then that candidate must win the overall election". It is incompatible with the later-no-harm criterion, so IRV does not meet this criterion.

IRV is more likely to elect the Condorcet winner than plurality voting and traditional runoff elections. The California cities of Oakland, San Francisco and San Leandro in 2010 provide an example; there were a total of four elections in which the plurality-voting leader in first-choice rankings was defeated, and in each case the IRV winner was the Condorcet winner, including a San Francisco election in which the IRV winner was in third place in first choice rankings.[115]

Systems which fail Condorcet but pass mutual majority can exclude voters outside the mutual majority from the vote, essentially becoming an election between the mutual majority.[citation needed] IRV demonstrates this exclusion of up to 50% of voters, notably in the 2009 Burlington, Vermont mayoral election where the later rounds became a runoff between the mutual majority of voters favoring Andy Montroll and Bob Kiss. This can recurse: if a mutual majority exists within the mutual majority, then the majority becomes a collegiate over the minority, and the inner mutual majority solely decides the votes of this collegiate.

Consistency criterion

The consistency criterion states that if dividing the electorate into two groups and running the same election separately with each group returns the same result for both groups, then the election over the whole electorate should return this result. IRV, like all preferential voting methods which are not positional, does not meet this criterion.

Independence of irrelevant alternatives criterion

The independence of irrelevant alternatives criterion states that "the election outcome remains the same even if a candidate who cannot win decides to run." In the general case, instant-runoff voting can be susceptible to strategic nomination: whether or not a candidate decides to run at all can affect the result even if the new candidate cannot themselves win.[116] This is much less likely to happen than under plurality.[citation needed]

Monotonicity criterion

The monotonicity criterion states that "a voter can't harm a candidate's chances of winning by voting that candidate higher, or help a candidate by voting that candidate lower, while keeping the relative order of all the other candidates equal." Allard[117] claims failure is unlikely, at a less than 0.03% chance per election. Some critics[118] argue in turn that Allard's calculations are wrong and the probability of monotonicity failure is much greater, at 14.5% under the impartial culture election model in the three-candidate case, or 7–10% in the case of a left-right spectrum. Lepelley et al. find a 2–5% probability of monotonicity failure under the same election model as Allard.[119] The diagram shows the non-monotonicity of IRV, where moving the center of opinion away from a candidate can help that candidate win, and moving the center of opinion towards a candidate can cause that candidate to lose.

Participation criterion

The participation criterion states that "the best way to help a candidate win must not be to abstain".[120] IRV does not meet this criterion: in some cases, the voter's preferred candidate can be best helped if the voter does not vote at all.[121] Depankar Ray finds a 50% probability that, when IRV elects a different candidate than Plurality, some voters would have been better off not showing up.[122]

Reversal symmetry criterion

The reversal symmetry criterion states that "if candidate A is the unique winner, and each voter's individual preferences are inverted, then A must not be elected". IRV does not meet this criterion: it is possible to construct an election where reversing the order of every ballot paper does not alter the final winner.[121]

Examples

Some examples of IRV elections are given below. The first two (fictional elections) demonstrate the principle of IRV. The others offer examples of the results of real elections.

Five voters, three candidates

A simple example is provided in the accompanying table. Three candidates are running for election, Bob, Bill and Sue. There are five voters, "a" through "e". The voters each have one vote. They rank the candidates first, second and third in the order they prefer them. To win, a candidate must have a majority of vote; that is, three or more.

In Round 1, the first-choice rankings are tallied, with the results that Bob and Sue both have two votes and Bill has one. No candidate has a majority, so a second "instant runoff" round is required. Since Bill is in bottom place, he is eliminated. The ballot from any voter who ranked Bill first (in this example solely voter "c" ) gets modified as follows: the original 2nd choice candidate for that voter becomes their new 1st choice, and their original 3rd choice becomes their new 2nd choice. This results in the Round 2 votes as seen below. This gives Sue 3 votes, which is a majority.

Round 1 Round 2
Candidate a b c d e Votes a b c d e Votes
Bob 1 2 3 1 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 2
Sue 3 1 2 3 1 2 2 1 1 2 1 3
Bill 2 3 1 2 3 1

Tennessee capital election

Most instant-runoff voting elections are won by the candidate who leads in first-choice rankings[citation needed], choosing the same winner as first-past-the-post voting. As an example Australia the 1972 federal election had the highest proportion of winners who would not have won under first past the post—with only 14 out of 125 seats not won by the plurality candidate.[123]

Some IRV elections are won by a candidate who finishes second after the first-round count. In this case, IRV chooses the same winner as a two-round system if all voters were to vote again and maintain their same preferences. A candidate may also win who is in third place or lower after the first count, but gains majority support (among the non-eliminated candidates) in the final round. In such cases, IRV would choose the same winner as a multi-round method that eliminated the last-place candidate before each new vote, assuming all voters kept voting and maintained their same preferences. Here is an example of this last case.

 

Imagine that Tennessee is having an election on the location of its capital. The population of Tennessee is concentrated around its four major cities, which are spread throughout the state. For this example, suppose that the entire electorate lives in these four cities and that everyone wants to live as near to the capital as possible.

The candidates for the capital are:

  • Memphis, the state's largest city, with 42% of the voters, but located far from the other cities
  • Nashville, with 26% of the voters, near the center of the state
  • Knoxville, with 17% of the voters
  • Chattanooga, with 15% of the voters

The preferences of the voters would be divided like this:

42% of voters
(close to Memphis)
26% of voters
(close to Nashville)
15% of voters
(close to Chattanooga)
17% of voters
(close to Knoxville)
  1. Memphis
  2. Nashville
  3. Chattanooga
  4. Knoxville
  1. Nashville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Knoxville
  4. Memphis
  1. Chattanooga
  2. Knoxville
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis
  1. Knoxville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis

It takes three rounds to determine a winner in this election.

 

Round 1 – In the first round no city gets a majority:

Votes in round/
City Choice
1st
Memphis 42%
Nashville 26%
Knoxville 17%
Chattanooga 15%

If one of the cities had achieved a majority vote (more than half), the election would end there. If this were a first-past-the-post election, Memphis would win because it received the most votes. But IRV does not allow a candidate to win on the first round without having an absolute majority of the vote. While 42% of the electorate voted for Memphis, 58% of the electorate voted against Memphis in this first round.

 

Round 2 – In the second round of tabulation, we remove the city with the least first-place support from consideration. Chattanooga received the lowest number of votes in the first round, so it is eliminated. The ballots that listed Chattanooga as first choice are added to the totals of the second-choice selection on each ballot. Everything else stays the same.

Chattanooga's 15% of the total votes are added to the second choices selected by the voters for whom that city was first-choice (in this example Knoxville):

Votes in round/
City Choice
1st 2nd
Memphis 42% 42%
Nashville 26% 26%
Knoxville 17% 32%
Chattanooga 15%

In the first round, Memphis was first, Nashville was second and Knoxville was third. With Chattanooga eliminated and its votes redistributed, the second round finds Memphis still in first place, followed by Knoxville in second and Nashville has moved down to third place.

 

Round 3 – No city yet has secured a majority of votes, so we move to the third round with the elimination of Nashville, and it becomes a contest between Memphis and Knoxville.

As in the second round with Chattanooga, all of the ballots currently counting for Nashville are added to the totals of Memphis or Knoxville based on which city is ranked next on that ballot. In this example the second-choice of the Nashville voters is Chattanooga, which is already eliminated. Therefore, the votes are added to their third-choice: Knoxville.

The third round of tabulation yields the following result:

Votes in round/
City Choice
1st 2nd 3rd
Memphis 42% 42% 42%
Nashville 26% 26%
Knoxville 17% 32% 58%
Chattanooga 15%

Result: Knoxville, which was running third in the first tabulation, has moved up from behind to take first place in the third and final round. The winner of the election is Knoxville. However, if 6% of voters in Memphis were to put Nashville first, the winner would be Nashville, a preferable outcome for voters in Memphis. This is an example of potential tactical voting, though one that would be difficult for voters to carry out in practice. Also, if 17% of voters in Memphis were to stay away from voting, the winner would be Nashville. This is an example of IRV failing the participation criterion.

For comparison, note that traditional first-past-the-post voting would elect Memphis, even though most citizens consider it the worst choice, because 42% is larger than any other single city. As Nashville is a Condorcet winner, Condorcet methods would elect Nashville. A two-round method would have a runoff between Memphis and Nashville where Nashville would win, too.

1990 Irish presidential election

Irish presidential election, 1990[124]
Candidate Round 1 Round 2
Mary Robinson 612,265 (38.9%) 817,830 (51.6%)
Brian Lenihan 694,484 (43.8%) 731,273 (46.2%)
Austin Currie 267,902 (16.9%)
Exhausted ballots 9,444 (0.6%) 34,992 (2.2%)
Total 1,584,095 (100%) 1,584,095 (100%)

The result of the 1990 Irish presidential election provides an example of how instant-runoff voting can produce a different result from first-past-the-post voting. The three candidates were Brian Lenihan of the traditionally dominant Fianna Fáil party, Austin Currie of Fine Gael, and Mary Robinson, nominated by the Labour Party and the Workers' Party. After the first round, Lenihan had the largest share of the first-choice rankings (and hence would have won a first-past-the-post vote), but no candidate attained the necessary majority. Currie was eliminated and his votes reassigned to the next choice ranked on each ballot; in this process, Robinson received 82% of Currie's votes, thereby overtaking Lenihan.

2014 Prahran election (Victoria)

A real-life example of IRV producing a result which differs from what would be expected under a first-past-the-post or the two-round voting system is the result for the seat of Prahran in the 2014 Victorian state election. In this instance, it was the candidate who initially finished third (Greens candidate Sam Hibbins) in the primary vote went on to win the seat on the back of favourable preferences from the other two minor parties and independents, narrowly beating the second-ranked candidate (Labor candidate Neil Pharaoh) by 31 votes, and the first-ranked candidate (Liberal candidate Clem Newton-Brown) by 277 votes. It was not until the final round of counting that one of the two remaining candidates (Hibbins) had more than 50% of the total vote.[125]

In theory, the elimination of the center-left Labor candidate before the left-wing Green candidate could have transferred enough votes to the center-right Liberal candidate for him to win, but instead roughly 8:1 Labor voters chose the Green ahead of the Liberal.

Candidate[125] Primary vote First round Second round Third round Fourth round Fifth round Sixth round
Clem Newton-Brown (LIB) 16,582 44.8% 16,592 16,644 16,726 16,843 17,076 18,363 49.6%
Neil Pharaoh (ALP) 9,586 25.9% 9,593 9,639 9,690 9,758 9,948
Sam Hibbins (GRN) 9,160 24.8% 9,171 9,218 9,310 9,403 9,979 18,640 50.4%
Eleonora Gullone (AJP) 837 2.3% 860 891 928 999
Alan Walker (FFP) 282 0.8% 283 295
Jason Goldsmith (IND) 247 0.7% 263 316 349
Steve Stefanopoulos (IND) 227 0.6% 241
Alan Menadue (IND) 82 0.2%
Total 37,003 100%

2009 Burlington mayoral election

Burlington mayoral election, 2009 (Round by round analysis of votes)
Candidates 1st Round 2nd Round 3rd Round
Candidate Party Votes ± Votes ± Votes ±
Bob Kiss Progressive 2585 +2585 2981 +396 4313 +1332
Kurt Wright Republican 2951 +2951 3294 +343 4061 +767
Andy Montroll Democrat 2063 +2063 2554 +491 0 −2554
Dan Smith Independent 1306 +1306 0 −1306
James Simpson Green 35 +35 0 −35
Write-in 36 +36 0 −36
EXHAUSTED PILE 4 +4 151 +147 606 +455
TOTALS[126] 8980 +8980

Unlike Burlington's first IRV mayoral election in 2006, the IRV winner in 2009 (Bob Kiss) was neither the same as the plurality winner (Kurt Wright) nor the Condorcet winner (Andy Montroll).[127][128][129][130] Burlington voters repealed IRV in 2010 by a vote of 52% to 48% and in 2021 voted to use RCV for city council elections by a vote of 64% to 36%.[131][132]

The organization FairVote, which advocates for IRV, claimed the election as a success, citing three reasons (1) it prevented the election of the presumed winner under a plurality system by avoiding the effect of vote-splitting between the other candidates, (2) 99.99% of the ballots were valid suggesting that voters handled the system without difficulty, and (3) "contributed to producing a campaign among four serious candidates that was widely praised for its substantive nature."[133]

However, the election was considered a failure by advocates of the Condorcet winner, who point out that "in a head-to-head election, Andy Montroll should have beaten Bob Kiss by a 7.8% margin".[128][129][134]

In this case, a mutual majority causes a lock-out of a sufficiently large (e.g. plurality) minority. In examples where a smaller minority would break the lock-out and would change the winner in their favor, the participation criterion is violated. Wright voters were 40%, versus voters who placed Montroll and Kiss above Wright at 51.5%. That means a lot of Wright voters would have had to stay home for their demographic to matter at all, causing a participation criterion failure. If Wright voters preferred Montroll over Kiss, it would have been more advantageous to abstain or not give Wright their first preference; this would then result in Montroll reaching the final runoff and beating Kiss (54% to 46%), as opposed to the actual final runoff between Wright and Kiss.

This would elect the candidate who started with only the third most primary votes, Montroll, and still would not be able to elect Wright without more of Montroll voters’ preferences or a higher primary vote (possibly to the point of having an outright majority)

Burlington mayoral election, 2009 (Summary analysis)
Party Candidate Maximum
round
Maximum
votes
Share in
maximum
round
Maximum votes
First round votesTransfer votes


Progressive Bob Kiss 3 4,313 48.0%
Republican Kurt Wright 3 4,061 45.2%
Democratic Andy Montroll 2 2,554 28.4%
Independent Dan Smith 1 1,306 14.5%
Green James Simpson 1 35 0.4%
Write-in 1 36 0.4%
Exhausted votes 606 6.7%

Comparison of Schulze to preferential voting systems

Comparison of preferential electoral systems
Sys­tem Mono­tonic Condorcet winner Majo­rity Condorcet loser Majority loser Mutual majority Smith ISDA LIIA Independence of clones Reversal symmetry Participation, consistency Later-no‑harm Later-no‑help Polynomial time Resol­vability
Schulze Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes No No No Yes Yes
Ranked pairs Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No Yes Yes
Tideman's Alternative No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No Yes Yes
Kemeny–Young Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No Yes
Copeland Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No Yes No No No Yes No
Nanson No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No Yes No No No Yes Yes
Black Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No Yes No No No Yes Yes
Instant-runoff voting No No Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No Yes No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Smith/IRV No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No Yes Yes
Borda Yes No No Yes Yes No No No No No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes
Baldwin No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No Yes Yes
Bucklin Yes No Yes No Yes Yes No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes
Plurality Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Contingent voting No No Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Coombs[135] No No Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No No Yes Yes
MiniMax Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No No No No No Yes Yes
Anti-plurality[135] Yes No No No Yes No No No No No No Yes No No Yes Yes
Sri Lankan contingent voting No No Yes No No No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Supplementary voting No No Yes No No No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Dodgson[135] No Yes Yes No No No No No No No No No No No No Yes

See also

References

  1. ^ a b c Robert, Henry (2011). Robert's Rules of Order Newly Revised (11th ed.). Da Capo Press. pp. 425–428. ISBN 978-0-306-82020-5.
  2. ^ FairVote.org. "Ranked Choice Voting / Instant Runoff". FairVote. Retrieved 30 May 2019.
  3. ^ "Explainer: What is preferential voting?". SBS News. Retrieved 30 May 2019.
  4. ^ "Preferential voting". Australian Electoral Commission. Retrieved 17 November 2020.
  5. ^ "Alternative Vote". www.electoral-reform.org.uk. Retrieved 30 May 2019.
  6. ^ Toplak, Jurij (2017). "Preferential Voting: Definition and Classification". Lex Localis – Journal of Local Self-Government. 15 (4): 737–61. doi:10.4335/15.4.737-761(2017).
  7. ^ "Ranked-Choice Voting (RCV)". www.opavote.com. Retrieved 30 May 2019. For some people, ranked-choice voting means any voting method where voters rank candidates. For these people, ranked-choice voting includes not only Instant-runoff voting and the single transferable vote, but also Condorcet voting and the Borda count.
  8. ^ FairVote.org. "Ranked Choice Voting / Instant Runoff". FairVote. Retrieved 31 May 2019. Examples of uses of RCV include: Australia (... multi-winner form of it for senate elections); Ireland (... multi-winner form for parliament and many local elections; Malta (multi-winner form for parliament)...
  9. ^ Rubel, Alex (24 May 2019). "'Ranked Choice' replaces 'Instant Runoff' as new election format in first Just Community decision this year". The Boiling Point. Retrieved 31 May 2019. The ranked choice system ... voters rank each candidate from favorite to least favorite, and the winner is the candidate who was, on average, voted the highest.
  10. ^ a b "Types of Voting Systems". Mtholyoke.edu. 8 April 2005. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  11. ^ "Australian Electoral Commission". Aec.gov.au. 23 April 2014. Retrieved 30 April 2014.
  12. ^ "Ireland Constitution, Article 12(2.3)". International Constitutional Law. 1995. Retrieved 15 February 2008.
  13. ^ "Understanding the Limited Preferential Voting system – EMTV Online". Retrieved 18 February 2021.
  14. ^ a b . Australian Electoral Commission. Archived from the original on 8 February 2013. Retrieved 3 November 2012.
  15. ^ "Declaration of Robert Richie in Support of Petition for Writ of Mandate" (PDF). Archive.fairvote.org. Retrieved 1 March 2015.
  16. ^ FairVote (25 June 2008). "Ranked Voting and Election Integrity". FairVote.org. Retrieved 30 April 2014.
  17. ^ "Minneapolis Ranked-Choice Voting History". City of Minneapolis. Retrieved 17 August 2019.
  18. ^ . Mpbn.net. Archived from the original on 19 March 2014. Retrieved 30 April 2014.
  19. ^ Tideman, Nicolaus (2006). Collective decisions and voting : the potential for public choice. Aldershot, England; Burlington, VT: Ashgate. p. 154. ISBN 978-0-7546-4717-1. OCLC 70334914.
  20. ^ Claim 1: Voters Can Understand RCV
  21. ^ "Voting in the House of Representatives". Australian Electoral Commission. 28 June 2016. Retrieved 9 December 2018.
  22. ^ . No2av.org. 25 October 2010. Archived from the original on 8 February 2011. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  23. ^ "Informal Voting – Two Ways of Allowing More Votes to Count". ABC Elections. 28 February 2011. Retrieved 15 August 2011.
  24. ^ (PDF). New America Foundation. 1 August 2008. Archived from the original (PDF) on 15 June 2011. Retrieved 15 August 2011.
  25. ^ Burnett, Craig M.; Kogan, Vladimir (March 2015). "Ballot (and voter) 'exhaustion' under Instant Runoff Voting: An examination of four ranked-choice elections". Electoral Studies. 37: 41–49. doi:10.1016/j.electstud.2014.11.006. S2CID 11159132.
  26. ^ "Box".
  27. ^ "Second Report: Election of a Speaker". House of Commons Select Committee on Procedure. 15 February 2001. Retrieved 18 February 2008.
  28. ^ Cary, David (1 January 2011). "Estimating the Margin of Victory for Instant-runoff Voting". Proceedings of the 2011 Conference on Electronic Voting Technology/Workshop on Trustworthy Elections. EVT/WOTE'11: 3.
  29. ^ "BBC News – Alternative vote". bbc.com. British Broadcasting Corporation. 8 February 2012. Retrieved 9 October 2019.
  30. ^ "Opinion: OUSA Needs the Alternative Vote". Critic – Te Arohi. Otago, New Zealand: Otago University Students' Association. 30 September 2017. Retrieved 9 October 2019.
  31. ^ . City of London. Archived from the original on 26 February 2018.
  32. ^ "Liberal plan to change federal voting laws may have crossbench support". The Guardian. 11 December 2020. Retrieved 13 February 2021.
  33. ^ "How RCV Works". FairVote. 17 August 2019. Retrieved 17 August 2018.
  34. ^ Appendix D, Instant Runoff Voting, San Francisco Charter § 13.102 https://sfgov.org/ccsfgsa/sites/default/files/Voting%20Systems%20Task%20Force/AppendixD__.pdf.
  35. ^ Arntz, John (2 February 2005). (PDF). Department of Elections: City and County of San Francisco. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2 December 2008. Retrieved 25 August 2009 – via FairVote. In San Francisco, ranked-choice voting is sometimes called 'instant run-off voting.' The Department of Elections generally uses the term ranked-choice voting, because it describes the voting method—voters are directed to rank their first-, second- and third-choice candidates. The Department also uses the term ranked-choice voting because the word 'instant' might create an expectation that final results will be available immediately after the polls close on election night.
  36. ^ Pacuit, Eric (24 June 2019) [[Original version published, 3 August 2011]. "Voting Methods". In Zalta, Edward N. (ed.). The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Fall 2019 ed.) – via plato.stanford.edu.
  37. ^ "Proportional Representation". Citizens Information Board. Retrieved 17 August 2019.
  38. ^ "South Carolina General Assembly : 116th Session, 2005–2006". Scstatehouse.gov. Retrieved 1 March 2015.
  39. ^ "Bill Information". Arkleg.state.ar.us. Retrieved 28 January 2015.
  40. ^ J. R. Chamberlin and M. D. Cohen, ‘Toward Applicable Social Choice Theory...’, (1978).
  41. ^ Bartholdi III, John J.; Orlin, James B. (1991). "Single transferable vote resists strategic voting" (PDF). Social Choice and Welfare. 8 (4): 341–354. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.127.97. doi:10.1007/bf00183045. S2CID 17749613.
  42. ^ "How to Vote Guide". Antony Green's Election Blog. 11 October 2011. Retrieved 29 January 2017. What is the best way to vote strategically? The best strategic vote is to number the candidates in the order you would like to see them elected. ... in electorate of more than 90,000 voters, and without perfect knowledge, such a strategy is not possible.
  43. ^ Green-Armytage, James. (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 3 June 2013. Retrieved 31 May 2011.
  44. ^ Robinette, Robbie; Tideman, Nicolaus (12 March 2021). What a Difference a Voting Rule Makes. Savannah, Georgia.
  45. ^ a b c Warren Smith (2009) "Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayor election; Thwarted-majority, non-monotonicity & other failures (oops)"
  46. ^ "Monotonicity and IRV – Why the Monotonicity Criterion is of Little Import". Archive.fairvote.org. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  47. ^ "Instant Run-Off Voting". archive.fairvote.org. Retrieved 29 January 2017. IRV removes the "spoiler effect" whereby minor party or independent candidates knock off major party candidates, increasing the choices available to the voters.
  48. ^ "Cal IRV FAQ". www.cfer.org. Retrieved 29 January 2017. IRV completely eliminates the 'spoiler' effect – that is, votes split between a weak and a strong candidate won't cause the strong candidate to lose if s/he is the second choice of the weak candidate's voters.
  49. ^ "OP-ED | No More Spoilers? Instant Runoff Voting Makes Third Parties Viable, Improves Democracy". CT News Junkie. Retrieved 20 April 2017. Instant-runoff voting ends the spoiler effect forever
  50. ^ CGP Grey (6 April 2011), The Alternative Vote Explained, retrieved 20 April 2017, Alternative Vote: Stops the Spoiler Effect
  51. ^ Borgers, Christoph (2010). Mathematics of Social Choice: Voting, Compensation, and Division. SIAM. ISBN 9780898716955. Candidates C and D spoiled the election for B ... With them in the running, A won, whereas without them in the running, B would have won. ... Instant runoff voting ... does not do away with the spoiler problem entirely, although it ... makes it less likely
  52. ^ Poundstone, William (2009). Gaming the Vote: Why Elections Aren't Fair (and What We Can Do About It). Farrar, Straus and Giroux. ISBN 9781429957649. IRV is excellent for preventing classic spoilers-minor candidates who irrationally tip the election from one major candidate to another. It is not so good when the 'spoiler' has a real chance of winning
  53. ^ "The Spoiler Effect". The Center for Election Science. 20 May 2015. Retrieved 29 January 2017.
  54. ^ "The Problem with Instant Runoff Voting". minguo.info. Retrieved 29 January 2017. After a minor party is strong enough to win, on the other hand, a vote for them could have the same spoiler effect that it could have under the current plurality system
  55. ^ "Example to demonstrate how IRV leads to 'spoilers,' 2-party domination". RangeVoting.org. Retrieved 29 January 2017. IRV means betraying your true favorite third party candidate pays off. Voting third party can mean wasting your vote under IRV, just like under plurality.
  56. ^ The Center for Election Science (2 December 2013), Favorite Betrayal in Plurality and Instant Runoff Voting, retrieved 29 January 2017
  57. ^ O'Neill, Jeffrey C. (2006). "Everything That Can be Counted Does Not Necessarily Count: The Right to Vote and the Choice of a Voting System". SSRN Working Paper Series: 340. doi:10.2139/ssrn.883058. ISSN 1556-5068. S2CID 155750146. With instant runoff voting ... The strategy for the liberal voter is the same as for plurality voting: Her favorite candidate cannot win, so she casts her vote for her favorite candidate with a realistic chance of winning
  58. ^ Comments (9 December 2016). "The False Promise of Instant Runoff Voting". Cato Unbound. Retrieved 29 January 2017. They'll have a strategic incentive to falsify their preferences.
  59. ^ "2009 Burlington Mayor IRV Failure". bolson.org. Retrieved 29 January 2017.
  60. ^ "House of Representatives Results". Results.aec.gov.au. Retrieved 1 March 2015.
  61. ^ "Every RCV Election in the Bay Area So Far Has Produced Condorcet Winners". fairvote.org. 6 January 2017. Retrieved 13 February 2017.
  62. ^ Travis, Alan (10 May 2010). "Electoral reform: Alternative vote system would have had minimal impact on outcome of general election". The Guardian. London. Retrieved 1 April 2011.
  63. ^ History of Preferential Voting in Australia, Australian Broadcasting Corporation, 2004 Election Guide. "Such a long lasting Coalition would not have been possible under first part the post voting"
  64. ^ (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 27 September 2011. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  65. ^ (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 18 October 2007.
  66. ^ . Blogs.thenewstribune.com. 30 August 2006. Archived from the original on 10 February 2017. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  67. ^ "Wake County Answers on IRV Election Administration". FairVote. Retrieved 30 April 2014.
  68. ^ "No to AV campaign reject rivals' 'scare stories' claim". Bbc.co.uk. 24 February 2011. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  69. ^ "Nc Voter". Nc Voter. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  70. ^ "Ranked Choice Voting and Election Integrity". FairVote. 25 June 2008. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  71. ^ Murphy, Dean E. (30 September 2004). "New Runoff System in San Francisco Has the Rival Candidates Cooperating". The New York Times.
  72. ^ Russo, John (24 July 2006). . Oakland Tribune. Archived from the original on 6 December 2008.
  73. ^ How Ranked Choice Voting Impacts Elections
  74. ^ "Ranked Choice Voting in Practice: Candidate Civility in Ranked Choice Elections" (PDF). fairvote.org. FairVote. Retrieved 2 December 2015.
  75. ^ "Project MUSE". Muse.jhu.edu. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  76. ^ "Papua New Guinea: Leaflet on Limited Preferential Voting System, Electoral Knowledge Network
  77. ^ "Recommendations and Conclusions". The Report of the Independent Commission on the Voting System. Archived from the original on 5 December 2013.
  78. ^ Walter, Benjamin. . Archived from the original on 8 February 2012.
  79. ^ "Ann Arbor Law Suit". FairVote. Retrieved 10 May 2011.
  80. ^ Leary, Mal (12 June 2018). "Opposed To Ranked-Choice Voting, LePage Says He Might Not Certify Primary Election Results". www.mainepublic.org. Retrieved 14 January 2019.
  81. ^ "Complaint" (PDF), Baber v. Dunlap (Court Filing), D.M.E., vol. No. 1:18-cv-00465, no. Docket 1, 13 November 2018, retrieved 13 January 2019 – via Recap
  82. ^ "1st Circuit ends Poliquin's efforts to keep House seat". Bangor Daily News. 22 December 2018. Retrieved 17 August 2019.
  83. ^ Claim 3: RCV Increases Voter Participation
  84. ^ Nanson, E. J. (1882). "Methods of election: Ware's Method". Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria. 17: 206. The method was, however, mentioned by Condorcet, but only to be condemned.
  85. ^ Condorcet, Jean-Antoine-Nicolas de Caritat (1788). On the Constitution and the Functions of Provincial Assemblies. Complete Works of Condorcet (in French). Vol. 13 (published 1804). p. 243. En effet, lorsqu'il y a plus de trois concurrents, le véritable vœu de la pluralité peut être pour un candidat qui n'ait eu aucune des voix dans le premier scrutin.
  86. ^ Ware, William R. (1871). Application of Mr. Hare's system of voting to the nomination of overseers of Harvard College. OCLC 81791186. It is equally efficient whether one candidate is to be chosen, or a dozen.
  87. ^ Benjamin Reilly. "The Global Spread of Preferential Voting: Australian Institutional Imperialism" (PDF). FairVote.org. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  88. ^ McLean, Iain (October 2002). "Australian electoral reform and two concepts of representation" (PDF). p. 11. Retrieved 22 February 2008.
  89. ^ . Australianpolitics.com. Archived from the original on 19 March 2011. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  90. ^ "The Origin of Senate Group Ticket Voting, and it didn't come from the Major Parties". ABC News. 22 September 2015.
  91. ^ The Ceann Comhairle or Speaker of Dáil Éireann is returned automatically for whichever constituency s/he was elected if they wish to seek re-election, reducing the number of seats contested in that constituency by one. (In that case, should the Ceann Comhairle be from a three-seater, only two seats are contested in the general election from there.) As a result, if the Ceann Comhairle wishes to be in the next Dáil, only 165 seats are actually contested in a general election.
  92. ^ "Maine became the first state in the country Tuesday to pass ranked choice voting". 10 November 2016. Retrieved 10 November 2016.
  93. ^ "Ranked Choice Voting | Maine Voters Rank Candidates". Maine Uses Ranked Choice Voting. Retrieved 8 April 2018.
  94. ^ Eric Russell (12 June 2018). "Mainers vote to keep ranked-choice voting, with supporters holding commanding lead". Portland Press Herald. Retrieved 13 June 2018.
  95. ^ "Alaska Ballot Measure 2, Top-Four Ranked-Choice Voting and Campaign Finance Laws Initiative (2020)". Ballotpedia. Retrieved 17 November 2020.
  96. ^ Robert 2011, p. 426
  97. ^ Robert 2011, pp. 426–428
  98. ^ Robert 2011, p. 428
  99. ^ Sturgis, Alice (2001). The Standard Code of Parliamentary Procedure, 4th ed.
  100. ^ Riddick & Butcher (1985). Riddick's Rules of Procedure, 1985 ed.
  101. ^ "Glossary: Exhaustive ballot". Securevote.com.au. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  102. ^ (PDF). Electionline.org. Archived from the original (PDF) on 16 May 2008. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  103. ^ IRV for Louisiana's Overseas Voters (web page), FairVote IRV America, retrieved 16 June 2013
  104. ^ For example, in 2006, the Independence Party of Minnesota used IRV for its endorsement elections, requiring 60% to win, and exhaustive balloting to follow if needed.
  105. ^ Vermont S.22 1(c)3 Sec. 7. (6) ... if neither of the last two remaining candidates in an election ... received a majority, the report and the tabulations performed by the instant runoff count committee shall be forwarded to the Washington superior court, which shall issue a certificate of election to whichever of the two remaining candidates received the greatest number of votes at the conclusion of the instant runoff tabulation, and send a certified copy of the tabulation and results to the secretary of state.
  106. ^ Antony Green (8 September 2015). Preferences, Donkey Votes and the Canning By-Election – Antony Green's Election Blog (Australian Broadcasting Corporation). Retrieved 8 September 2015.
  107. ^ "Voting system". www.ecq.qld.gov.au. Electoral Commission of Queensland. 28 January 2020. Retrieved 17 November 2020.
  108. ^ Stevens, Bronwyn. "Are Queenslanders in danger of 'wasting' their votes?". The Conversation. Retrieved 28 November 2020.
  109. ^ . Electoral Council of Australia. Archived from the original on 9 March 2008. Retrieved 15 February 2008.
  110. ^ "Ranked-Choice Voting". Registrar of Voters, Alameda County. Retrieved 15 December 2016. This format allows a voter to select a first-choice candidate in the first column, a second-choice candidate in the second column, and a third-choice candidate in the third column.
  111. ^ Breyer, Patrick (November 2013). "Alternative II: Einführung einer Ersatzstimme" (PDF). Anhörung zum Entwurf eines Gesetzes zur Abschaffung der Fünf-Prozent-Sperrklausel bei Landtagswahlen in Schleswig-Holstein [Hearing on the draft law to abolish the five percent threshold in state elections in Schleswig-Holstein (Discussion paper)] (Report) (in German). Piratenfraktion im Schleswig-Holsteinischen Landtag. (Drs. 18/385).
  112. ^ What is Dual Level Voting?
  113. ^ Nanson, E. J. (1882). "Methods of election". Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria. 19: 207–208. although Ware's method cannot return the worst, it may return the next worst.
  114. ^ Green-Armytage, James (2004). . Archived from the original on 3 June 2013.
  115. ^ FairVote. . FairVote.org. Archived from the original on 26 July 2011. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  116. ^ "Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayoral election". RangeVoting.org. Retrieved 17 April 2011.
  117. ^ Crispin Allard (January 1996). "Estimating the Probability of Monotonicity Failure in a UK General Election". Retrieved 4 May 2011.
  118. ^ Warren D. Smith. "Monotonicity and Instant Runoff Voting". Retrieved 4 May 2011.
  119. ^ Lepelley, Dominique; Chantreuil, Frederic; Berg, Sven (1996). "The likelihood of monotonicity paradoxes in run-off elections". Mathematical Social Sciences. 31 (3): 133–146. doi:10.1016/0165-4896(95)00804-7.
  120. ^ More precisely, submitting a ballot that ranks A ahead of B should never change the winner from A to B.
  121. ^ a b Smith, Warren D. "Lecture 'Mathematics and Democracy'". Retrieved 12 May 2011.
  122. ^ Ray, Depankar (1986). "On the practical possibility of a 'no show paradox' under the single transferable vote". Mathematical Social Sciences. 11 (2): 183–189. doi:10.1016/0165-4896(86)90024-7.
  123. ^ Green, Antony (11 May 2010). "Preferential Voting in Australia". www.abc.net.au. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  124. ^ "Presidential Election November 1990". ElectionsIreland.org. Retrieved 23 November 2009.
  125. ^ a b "State Election 2014: Prahran District (Distribution of preference votes)". Victorian Electoral Commission.
  126. ^ "2009 Burlington Mayor Election". votingsolutions.com. 3 March 2009. Archived from the original on 9 November 2009.
  127. ^ Bouricious, Terry (13 March 2009). . Vermont Daily Briefing. Archived from the original on 19 October 2015. Retrieved 27 September 2017. the 2009 election suffered from not only the 'thwarted majorities' or Condorcet's paradox, but also the 'no-show paradox' that shows that Wright voters who preferred Montroll over Kiss (that is, ranked Montroll 2nd) would have been better staying home and not voting at all.
  128. ^ a b Gierzynski, Anthony; Hamilton, Wes; Smith, Warren D. (March 2009). "Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayoral election". RangeVoting.org. Retrieved 1 October 2017. Montroll was favored over Republican Kurt Wright 56% to 44% ... and over Progressive Bob Kiss 54% to 46% ... In other words, in voting terminology, Montroll was a 'beats-all winner,' also called a 'Condorcet winner' ... However, in the IRV election, Montroll came in third!
  129. ^ a b Olson, Brian (2009). "2009 Burlington Mayor IRV Failure". bolson.org. Retrieved 1 October 2017. This is an IRV failure. The IRV result is clearly not what people actually wanted. More people liked Montroll over Kiss than the other way around, but IRV elected the loser.
  130. ^ Sheldon-hess, Dale (16 March 2009). "IRV Fails in Its Own Backyard". The Least of All Evils. Retrieved 27 September 2017. Montroll would have beaten any other candidate in a one-on-one election.
  131. ^ . Rutland Herald Online. Archived from the original on 4 March 2016. Retrieved 15 December 2016.
  132. ^ "Burlington, Vermont, Question 4, Ranked-Choice Voting Amendment (March)". Ballotpedia.org. Retrieved 18 April 2021.
  133. ^ Bouricius, Terry (17 March 2009). "Response to Faulty Analysis of Burlington IRV Election". FairVote.org. Retrieved 1 October 2017. successfully prevented the election of the candidate who would likely have won under plurality rules, but would have lost to either of the other top finishers in a runoff
  134. ^ "Burlington's 2009 Mayoral Election: Did IRV Fail The Voters?". Integral Psychosis. 16 March 2009. Retrieved 1 October 2017. Montroll was the 'Beats-All winner' (aka the 'Condorcet winner') as he would have beaten both Wright (56% to 44%) and Kiss (54% to 46%) in head-to-head races, demonstrating that he was the preferred candidate by the majority of voters.
  135. ^ a b c Anti-plurality, Coombs and Dodgson are assumed to receive truncated preferences by apportioning possible rankings of unlisted alternatives equally; for example, ballot A > B = C is counted as 1/2 A > B > C and 1/2 A > C > B. If these methods are assumed not to receive truncated preferences, then later-no-harm and later-no-help are not applicable.

External links

  • Preferential Voting at Australian Eelectoral Commission
  • 2010 articles from the and summarizing the proposed change in the United Kingdom to IRV/Alternative Vote

Practice

  • Advantages and disadvantages of AV from the ACE Project Electoral Design Reference Materials
  • A Handbook of Electoral System Design from International IDEA
  • Australian Electoral Commission Web Site
  • from Australian Politics.com
  • Alameda County Registrar of Voters, California
  • City of Minneapolis, Minnesota
  • Ranked Choice Voting Resource Center

Demonstrations and simulations

  • The Star Tribune: How ranked-choice voting works – an interactive graphic
  • RankedVote — Online ranked-choice voting platform for voter education with detailed results animations and explanations.
  • RCV123.org - Free, non-profit site with on-line and paper ballot ranked-choice voting systems for any group vote.
  • AmericanQuorum.com A ranked-choice ballot tool from the Indaba Application Network, including the animated display of an instant runoff.
  • BBC: Would the alternative vote have changed history?, illustration of how the results of the last six general elections might have looked had the 'alternative vote' system been in place.
  • OpenSTV – Open source software for computing IRV and STV
  • Favourite Futurama Character Poll
  • Voting System Visualizations – 2-dimensional plots of results of various methods, with assumptions of sincere voting behavior.
  • Simulation Of Various Voting Models for Close Elections Opposition article by Brian Olson.

Advocacy groups and positions

  • Yes to Fairer Votes campaign site for the Yes side of the 2011 United Kingdom Alternative Vote referendum
  • Washington Post
  • Ranked Choice Voting at FairVote
  • Ranked Choice Voting at [Represent.Us]
  • InstantRunoff.com
  • Ranked Ballot Initiative of Toronto, rabit.ca
  • Citizens for Voter Choice :: Massachusetts
  • FairVote Minnesota
  • Brookings Institution's "Empowering Moderate Voters" paper
  • Does the Alternative Vote Bring Tyranny to Australia? – Antony Green ABC

Opposition groups and positions

  • Center for Election Science compares Instant runoff to Approval voting
  • Fair Vote Canada paper on the Alternative Vote
  • IRV page at the Center for Range Voting
  • Values and Risks Report by the N.C. Coalition for Verified Voting

instant, runoff, voting, proportional, electoral, system, applying, ranked, ballots, multi, member, constituencies, single, transferable, vote, type, ranked, preferential, voting, method, uses, majority, voting, rule, single, winner, elections, where, there, m. For the proportional electoral system applying ranked ballots to multi member constituencies see Single transferable vote Instant runoff voting IRV is a type of ranked preferential 1 voting method It uses a majority voting rule in single winner elections where there are more than two candidates It is commonly referred to as ranked choice voting RCV in the United States although there are other forms of ranked voting 2 preferential voting in Australia 3 4 where it has seen the widest adoption in the United Kingdom it is generally called alternative vote AV 5 whereas in some other countries it is referred to as the single transferable vote which usually means only its multi winner variant All these names are often used inconsistently 6 7 8 9 Voters in IRV elections rank the candidates in order of preference Ballots are initially counted for each voter s top choice If a candidate has more than half of the first choice votes that candidate wins If not then the candidate with the fewest votes is eliminated and the voters who selected the defeated candidate as a first choice then have their votes added to the totals of their next choice This process continues until a candidate has more than half of the votes When the field is reduced to two it has become an instant runoff that allows a comparison of the top two candidates head to head IRV is not a proportional voting system but rather a winner takes all method as it elects only one winner in an election in one district 10 IRV is used in national elections in several countries It is used to elect members of the Australian House of Representatives 11 as well as most state lower houses and in some local government elections It is the method used to elect the President of India the President of Ireland 12 and in a modified form the National Parliament of Papua New Guinea 13 It is used by many political parties for internal primaries elections to elect party leaders and presidential prime ministerial candidates and by private associations for various voting purposes such as choosing the Academy Award for Best Picture Contents 1 Election procedure 1 1 Process 1 2 Candidate order on the ballot paper 1 3 Party strategies 1 4 Counting logistics 1 5 Voter confusion 1 6 Invalid ballots and incomplete ballots 2 Terminology 3 Properties advantages and disadvantages 3 1 Wasted votes and Condorcet winners 3 2 Resistance to strategy 3 2 1 Tactical voting 3 2 2 Spoiler effect 3 3 Proportionality 3 3 1 Australia 3 4 Costs 3 5 Negative campaigning 3 6 Plural voting 3 7 Participation 4 History and use 4 1 History 4 2 Global use 4 2 1 National level elections 4 3 Robert s Rules of Order 5 Similar methods 5 1 Runoff voting 5 2 Exhaustive ballot 5 3 Two round methods 5 4 Contingent vote 5 5 Larger runoff process 5 6 Equal rankings 5 7 Comparison to first past the post 5 8 Variations 6 Voting method criteria 6 1 Satisfied criteria 6 2 Non satisfied criteria 6 2 1 Condorcet winner criterion 6 2 2 Consistency criterion 6 2 3 Independence of irrelevant alternatives criterion 6 2 4 Monotonicity criterion 6 2 5 Participation criterion 6 2 6 Reversal symmetry criterion 7 Examples 7 1 Five voters three candidates 7 2 Tennessee capital election 7 3 1990 Irish presidential election 7 4 2014 Prahran election Victoria 7 5 2009 Burlington mayoral election 8 Comparison of Schulze to preferential voting systems 9 See also 10 References 11 External links 11 1 Practice 11 2 Demonstrations and simulations 11 3 Advocacy groups and positions 11 4 Opposition groups and positionsElection procedure EditProcess Edit Flowchart of Instant Runoff Voting In instant runoff voting as with other ranked election methods each voter ranks the list of candidates in order of preference Under a common ballot layout the voter marks a 1 beside the most preferred candidate a 2 beside the second most preferred and so forth in ascending order The mechanics of the process are the same regardless of how many candidates the voter ranks and how many are left unranked In most implementations the voter ranks as many or as few choices as they wish The instant runoff vote counting procedure is as follows Eliminate the candidate appearing as the first preference on the fewest ballots If only one candidate remains elect this candidate and stop Otherwise go to 1 If there is an exact tie for last place in numbers of votes various tie breaking rules determine which candidate to eliminate The set of all candidates with the fewest first order votes whose votes together total less than any other candidate s can be eliminated without changing the outcome This bulk elimination can bypass irrelevant ties for example if one candidate receives 15 first order votes and four others receive 5 5 3 and 1 and no other candidate receives fewer than 15 all four of the latter candidates will be eliminated during the next four rounds and so can be eliminated immediately without considering the tie Ballots assigned to eliminated candidates are added to the totals of one of the remaining candidates based on the next preference ranked on each ballot The process repeats until one candidate achieves a majority of votes cast for continuing candidates Ballots on which all of a voter s ranked candidates are eliminated become inactive Candidate order on the ballot paper Edit The Australian Electoral Commission holding a blind ballot to determine the order of candidates on the ballot paper 2004 The common ways to list candidates on a ballot paper are alphabetically or by random lot In some cases candidates may also be grouped by political party Alternatively Robson Rotation involves randomly changing candidate order for each print run Party strategies Edit Where preferential voting is used for the election of an assembly or council parties and candidates often advise their supporters on their lower preferences especially in Australia where a voter must rank all candidates to cast a valid ballot This can lead to preference deals a form of pre election bargaining in which smaller parties agree to direct their voters in return for support from the winning party on issues critical to the small party citation needed It can also sometimes lead to joint campaigning between candidates with similar platforms However these strategies rely on the assumption that supporters of a party or candidate are receptive to advice on the other preferences on their ballot Counting logistics Edit Most IRV elections historically have been tallied by hand including in elections to Australia s House of Representatives and most state governments In the modern era voting equipment can be used to administer the count either partially or fully In Australia the returning officer now usually declares the two candidates that are most likely to win each seat The votes are always counted by hand at the polling station monitored by scrutineers from each candidate The first part of the count is to record the first choice for all candidates Votes for candidates other than the two likely winners are then allocated to them in a second pass The whole process of counting the votes by hand and allocating preferences is typically completed within two hours on election night at a cost of 7 68 per elector in 2010 to run the entire election 14 Ireland in its presidential elections has several dozen counting centers around the nation Each center reports its totals and receives instructions from the central office about which candidate or candidates to eliminate in the next round of counting based on which candidate is in last place The count typically is completed the day after the election as in 1997 15 In the United States nearly all jurisdictions that use this format like Maine Oakland and San Francisco administer IRV elections on voting machines with optical scanning machines recording preferences and software tallying the IRV algorithm as soon as all ballots are recorded 16 In its first use of IRV in 2009 Minneapolis tallied first choices on optical scan equipment at the polls and then used a central hand count for the IRV tally but has since administered elections without hand tallies 17 Portland Maine in 2011 used its usual voting machines to tally first choice at the polls then a central scan with different equipment if an IRV tally was necessary 18 The election results from IRV cannot be counted additively all ballots must be present prior to the first elimination Methods like plurality voting and pairwise voting can divide the work of counting and sum the results as more votes are reported To produce pairwise results each candidate ranked on a ballot receives one vote against each alternative ranked lower and each not ranked on that ballot equal rankings including non ranked candidates are ties and no vote is tallied These tallies can be summed to produce a complete matrix of pairwise elections which can then be used to compute the Smith set or to calculate the outcomes of Schulze Minimax Ranked Pairs and other methods 19 IRV is very unlikely to give rise to a tie when the number of voters is large For this reason it is sometimes advocated as part of a tie break for methods such as the Smith set which do not have this property see Smith IRV and Tideman s Alternative Voter confusion Edit Research shows that voters in general can understand and use IRV Various surveys in the U S found 80 90 of voters reported understanding the ballot very well and 90 reported it was easy to use Voter comprehension increased with repeated use eliminating demographic disparities over time Older voters were more likely to say they found the system confusing but in practice correctly completed IRV ballots at the same rate 20 Invalid ballots and incomplete ballots Edit All forms of ranked choice voting reduce to plurality when all ballots rank only one candidate By extension ballots for which all candidates ranked are eliminated are equivalent to votes for any non winner in plurality and considered exhausted Because the ballot marking is more complex there can be an increase in spoiled ballots In Australia voters are required to write a number beside every candidate 21 and the rate of spoiled ballots can be five times higher than plurality voting elections 22 unreliable source Since Australia has compulsory voting however it is difficult to tell how many ballots are deliberately spoiled 23 Where complete rankings are not required a ballot may become inactive if none of the ranked choices on that ballot advance to the next round Most jurisdictions with IRV do not require complete rankings and may use columns to indicate preference instead of numbers In American elections with IRV more than 99 of voters typically cast a valid ballot 24 A 2015 study of four local U S elections that used IRV found that inactive ballots occurred often enough in each of them that the winner of each election did not receive a majority of votes cast in the first round The rate of inactive ballots in each election ranged from a low of 9 6 to a high of 27 1 25 As one point of comparison the number of votes cast in the 190 regularly scheduled primary runoff elections for the U S House and U S Senate from 1994 to 2016 decreased from the initial primary on average by 39 according to a 2016 study by FairVote 26 Terminology EditInstant runoff voting derives its name from the way the ballot count simulates a series of runoffs similar to an exhaustive ballot system except that voter preferences do not change between rounds 27 It is also known as the alternative vote transferable vote ranked choice voting RCV single seat ranked choice voting or preferential voting 28 Britons and New Zealanders generally call IRV the alternative vote AV 29 30 while in Canada it is called ranked choice voting 31 Australians who use IRV for most single winner elections call IRV preferential voting 32 American NGO FairVote uses the terminology ranked choice voting to refer to IRV in the case of single winner offices and to refer to single transferable vote in the case of multi winner offices 33 Jurisdictions using IRV such as San Francisco California Maine Alaska and Minneapolis Minnesota have codified the term ranked choice voting in their laws San Francisco has argued the word instant in term instant runoff voting could confuse voters into expecting results to be immediately available 34 35 IRV is occasionally referred to rather confusingly either as Hare s method 36 after Sir Thomas Hare or as Ware s method after the American William Robert Ware When the single transferable vote STV method is applied to a single winner election it becomes IRV the government of Ireland has called IRV proportional representation based on the fact that the same ballot form is used to elect its president by IRV and parliamentary seats by STV but IRV is a winner take all election method 37 State law in South Carolina 38 and Arkansas 39 use instant runoff to describe the practice of having certain categories of absentee voters cast ranked choice ballots before the first round of an election and counting those ballots in any subsequent runoff elections Properties advantages and disadvantages EditWasted votes and Condorcet winners Edit Unlike a plurality voting system that just compares the top two vote getters instant runoff voting minimizes the problem of wasted votes 40 However it does not ensure the election of a Condorcet winner which is the candidate that would win a direct election against any other candidate in the race These issues are illustrated in the following election In IRV for a polarized election between left right and center the votes for B are not wasted but the consensus candidate B is not elected Simple election example First choice A B CSecond choice B A C BVoters 36 10 20 34 A wins plurality vote second place preferences are ignored so candidate A wins with 36 of the vote as against 34 for C and 30 10 20 for B C wins IRV vote candidate B gets the fewest first place votes so is eliminated in the first round Candidate C gets more of B s second choice preferences than candidate A winning the second round by 54 20 34 to 46 36 10 This result is the same as would occur if there was a primary with 3 candidates and a general election with the two remaining candidates Every voter gets a say in the final runoff so no votes are wasted B wins IRV bottom two runoff in the first round candidates B and C are in last place so they go head to head Candidate A s second place votes go to candidate B so candidate B wins 66 36 10 20 to 34 over candidate C In the second runoff round candidate C has been eliminated so candidates A and B go head to head Candidate C s second place votes go to candidate B so candidate B wins 64 10 20 34 to 36 over candidate A Bottom Two Runoff is an example of a Condorcet method of voting Resistance to strategy Edit Instant runoff voting has notably high resistance to tactical voting but less to strategic nomination Tactical voting Edit See also Tactical voting Instant runoff voting The Gibbard Satterthwaite theorem demonstrates that no deterministic non dictatorial voting method using only the preference rankings of the voters can be entirely immune from tactical voting This implies that IRV is susceptible to tactical voting in some circumstances Research concludes that IRV is one of the voting methods least vulnerable to tactical voting with theorist Nicolaus Tideman noting that alternative voting is quite resistant to strategy 41 and Australian political analyst Antony Green dismissing suggestions of tactical voting 42 James Green Armytage tested four ranked choice methods and found the alternative vote to be the second most resistant to tactical voting though it was beaten by a class of AV Condorcet hybrids and did not resist strategic withdrawal by candidates well 43 These analyses only apply to tactical voting but not to other forms of manipulation for example Tideman and Robinette demonstrate a method by which a candidate modifies their campaign to appeal to a slightly broader range of voters including those of a popular opponent so as to bracket that opponent out cause them to be eliminated earlier 44 By not meeting the monotonicity Condorcet winner and participation criteria IRV may incentivize forms of tactical voting such as compromising when voters have sufficient information about other voters preferences such as from accurate pre election polling 45 FairVote mentions that monotonicity failure can lead to situations where having more voters rank a candidate first can cause the candidate to switch from being a winner to being a loser 46 This occurs when a mutual majority exists which would elect a different candidate than the Condorcet candidate and a minority coalition running off to a single candidate exceeds one half the size of this majority the minority candidate cannot be eliminated until the mutual majority runs off to a majority winner Moving the winner to the top of the minority ballots can shrink the minority sufficiently for their candidate to be eliminated and their votes then cause the election of a different candidate This situation occurred in the 2009 Burlington mayoral election had several Kurt Wright voters moved Bob Kiss to the top of their ballots the winner would have changed from Bob Kiss to Andy Montroll The change in lower candidates is important whether votes are shifted to the leading candidate shifted to a fringe candidate or discarded altogether is of no importance Tactical voting in IRV seeks to alter the order of eliminations in early rounds to ensure that the original winner is challenged by a stronger opponent in the final round For example in a three party election where voters for both the left and right prefer the centrist candidate to stop the opposing candidate from winning those voters who care more about defeating the opposition than electing their own candidate may cast a tactical first preference vote for the centrist candidate The 2009 mayoral election in Burlington Vermont provides an example in which strategy theoretically could have worked but would have been unlikely in practice In that election most supporters of the candidate who lost in the final round a Republican who led in first choices preferred the Condorcet winner a Democrat to the IRV winner the Progressive Party nominee If 371 24 7 out of the 1 510 backers of the Republican candidate who also preferred the Democrat over the Progressive candidate for mayor had insincerely raised the Democrat from their second choice to their first not changing their rankings relative to their least favorite candidate the Progressive the Democrat would then have advanced to the final round instead of their favorite defeated any opponent and proceeded to win the IRV election 45 This is an example of potential voter regret in that these voters who sincerely ranked their favorite candidate as first find out after the fact that they caused the election of their least favorite candidate which can lead to the voting tactic of compromising Yet because the Republican led in first choices and only narrowly lost the final instant runoff his backers would have been highly unlikely to pursue such a strategy citation needed This strategy still would not elect the Republican due to a lack of preferences towards them Spoiler effect Edit Main article Spoiler effect The spoiler effect is when a difference is made to the anticipated outcome of an election due to the presence on the ballot paper of a candidate who predictably will lose Most often this is when two or more politically similar candidates divide the vote for the more popular end of the political spectrum That is each receives fewer votes than a single opponent on the unpopular end of the spectrum who is disliked by the majority of voters but who wins from the advantage that on that unpopular side they are unopposed Strategic nomination relies on triggering this situation and requires understanding of both the electoral process and the demographics of the district Proponents of IRV claim that IRV eliminates the spoiler effect 47 48 49 50 since IRV makes it safe to vote honestly for marginal parties Under a plurality method voters who sympathize most strongly with a marginal candidate are strongly encouraged to instead vote for a more popular candidate who shares some of the same principles since that candidate has a much greater chance of being elected and a vote for the marginal candidate will not result in the marginal candidate s election An IRV method reduces this problem since the voter can rank the marginal candidate first and the mainstream candidate second in the likely event that the fringe candidate is eliminated the vote is not wasted but is transferred to the second preference However when the third party candidate is more competitive they can still act as a spoiler under IRV 51 52 53 54 55 56 by taking away first choice votes from the more mainstream candidate until that candidate is eliminated and then that candidate s second choice votes helping a more disliked candidate to win In these scenarios it would have been better for the third party voters if their candidate had not run at all spoiler effect or if they had voted dishonestly ranking their favorite second rather than first favorite betrayal 57 58 This is the same bracketing effect exploited by Robinette and Tideman in their research on strategic campaigning where a candidate alters their campaign to cause a change in voter honest choice resulting in the elimination of a candidate who nevertheless remains more preferred by voters For example in the 2009 Burlington Vermont mayoral election if the Republican candidate who lost in the final instant runoff had not run the Democratic candidate would have defeated the winning Progressive candidate In that sense the Republican candidate was a spoiler albeit for an opposing Democrat rather than some political ally even though leading in first choice support 45 59 By contrast in the seat of Prahran during the 2014 Victorian State Election despite the Greens candidate outlasting the more centrist Labor candidate during counting most of the Labor preferences ultimately helped elect the Greens rather than the further right Liberal candidate In this case the Greens candidate despite only having the third most primary votes ultimately was not a spoiler and was able to be elected In practice IRV does not seem to discourage candidacies In Australia s House of Representatives elections in 2007 for example the average number of candidates in a district was seven and at least four candidates ran in every district notwithstanding the fact that Australia only has two major political parties Every seat was won with a majority of the vote including several where results would have been different under plurality voting 60 A study of ballot image data found that all of the 138 RCV elections held in four Bay Area cities in California elected the Condorcet winner including many with large fields of candidates and 46 where multiple rounds of counting were required to determine a winner 61 Proportionality Edit IRV is a single winner application of a proportional voting method technically single winner STV with a droop quota 50 1 Like all winner take all voting methods IRV tends to exaggerate the number of seats won by the largest parties small parties without majority support in any given constituency are unlikely to earn seats in a legislature although their supporters will be more likely to be part of the final choice between the two strongest candidates 10 A simulation of IRV in the 2010 UK general election by the Electoral Reform Society concluded that the election would have altered the balance of seats among the three main parties but the number of seats won by minor parties would have remained unchanged 62 Australia Edit Australia a nation with a long record of using IRV for the election of legislative bodies has had representation in its parliament broadly similar to that expected by plurality methods Medium sized parties such as the National Party of Australia can co exist with coalition partners such as the Liberal Party of Australia and can compete against it without fear of losing seats to other parties due to vote splitting although generally in practice these two parties only compete against each other when a sitting member of the coalition leaves Parliament 63 IRV is more likely to result in legislatures where no single party has an absolute majority of seats a hung parliament citation needed but does not generally produce as fragmented a legislature as a fully proportional method such as is used for the House of Representatives of the Netherlands where coalitions of numerous small parties are needed for a majority Costs Edit The costs of printing and counting ballot papers for an IRV election are no different from those of any other method using the same technology However the more complicated counting system may encourage officials to introduce more advanced technology such as software counters or electronic voting machines Pierce County Washington election officials outlined one time costs of 857 000 to implement IRV for its elections in 2008 covering software and equipment voter education and testing 64 Because it does not require two separate votes IRV is assumed to cost less than two round primary general or general runoff election methods 65 However in 2009 the auditor of Pierce County reported that the ongoing costs of the system were not necessarily balanced by the costs of eliminating runoffs for most county offices because those elections may be needed for other offices not elected by IRV 66 Other jurisdictions have reported immediate cost savings 67 Australian elections are counted by hand The 2010 federal election cost a total of 7 68 per elector of which only a small proportion is the actual counting of votes 14 Counting is now normally performed in a single pass at the polling center as described above The perceived costs or cost savings of adopting an IRV method are commonly used by both supporters and critics In the 2011 referendum on the Alternative Vote in the UK the NOtoAV campaign was launched with a claim that adopting the method would cost 250 million commentators argued that this headline figure had been inflated by including 82 million for the cost of the referendum itself and a further 130 million on the assumption that the UK would need to introduce electronic voting systems when ministers had confirmed that there was no intention of implementing such technology whatever the outcome of the election 68 Automated vote counting is seen by some to have a greater potential for election fraud 69 IRV supporters counter these claims with recommended audit procedures 70 or note that automated counting is not required for the method at all Negative campaigning Edit John Russo Oakland City Attorney argued in the Oakland Tribune on 24 July 2006 that Instant runoff voting is an antidote to the disease of negative campaigning IRV led to San Francisco candidates campaigning more cooperatively Under the method their candidates were less likely to engage in negative campaigning because such tactics would risk alienating the voters who support attacked candidates reducing the chance that they would support the attacker as a second or third choice 71 72 Campaign strategists in New York City reported that after IRV was introduced they became more careful not to attack other candidates in ways that might offend voters that would otherwise give the campaign a second choice ranking 73 In 2013 2014 the Rutgers Eagleton Poll surveyed more than 4 800 likely voters in 21 cities after their local city elections half in cities with IRV elections and 14 in control cities selected by project leaders Caroline Tolbert of the University of Iowa and Todd Donovan of Western Washington University Among findings respondents in IRV cities reported candidates spent less time criticizing opponents than in cities that did not use IRV In the 2013 survey for example 5 of respondents said that candidates criticized each other a great deal of the time as opposed to 25 in non IRV cities An accompanying survey of candidates reported similar findings 74 Internationally Benjamin Reilly suggests instant runoff voting eases ethnic conflict in divided societies 75 This feature was a leading argument for why Papua New Guinea adopted instant runoff voting 76 However Lord Alexander s objections to the conclusions of the British Independent Commission on the Voting System s report 77 cites the example of Australia saying their politicians tend to be if anything more blunt and outspoken than our own Plural voting Edit Some critics of IRV hold that voters supporting major candidates get their second and third place preferences ignored as those candidates are eliminated before their first choice is eliminated Meanwhile if you support a fringe candidate it is more likely that your second and third place choices will be used In Ann Arbor Michigan for example arguments over IRV in letters to newspapers included the belief that IRV gives minority candidate voters two votes because some voters ballots may count for their first choice in the first round and a lesser choice in a later round 78 The argument that IRV represents plural voting is sometimes used in arguments over the fairness of the method and has led to several legal challenges in the United States In every instance state and federal judges have rejected this argument The argument was addressed and rejected by a Michigan court in 1975 in Stephenson v the Ann Arbor Board of City Canvassers the court held majority preferential voting as IRV was then known to be in compliance with the Michigan and United States constitutions writing 79 Under the M P V System however no one person or voter has more than one effective vote for one office No voter s vote can be counted more than once for the same candidate In the final analysis no voter is given greater weight in his or her vote over the vote of another voter although to understand this does require a conceptual understanding of how the effect of a M P V System is like that of a run off election The form of majority preferential voting employed in the City of Ann Arbor s election of its Mayor does not violate the one man one vote mandate nor does it deprive anyone of equal protection rights under the Michigan or United States Constitutions The same argument was advanced in opposition to IRV in Maine Governor Paul LePage claimed ahead of the 2018 primary elections that IRV would result in one person five votes as opposed to one person one vote 80 In litigation following the results of the 2018 election for Maine s 2nd congressional district Representative Bruce Poliquin claimed that IRV allowed his opponents to cast ballots for three different candidates in the same election 81 Federal judge Lance Walker rejected this claim and the 1st circuit court denied Poliquin s emergency appeal leading to Poliquin dropping his claim 82 Participation Edit Primary and runoff elections tend to have lower turnout than general elections Consolidating these into a single election increases voter participation 83 History and use EditMain article History and use of instant runoff voting History Edit This method was considered by Condorcet as early as 1788 though only to condemn it for its ability to eliminate a candidate preferred by a majority of voters 84 85 IRV can be seen as a special case of the single transferable vote method which began use in the 1850s It is historically known as Ware s method due to the implementation of STV in 1871 at Harvard College by American architect William Robert Ware who suggested it could also be used for single winner elections 86 87 Unlike the single transferable vote in multi seat elections however the only ballot transfers are from backers of candidates who have been eliminated The first known use of an IRV like method in a governmental election was in the 1893 general election in the Colony of Queensland in present day Australia 88 The variant used for this election was a contingent vote where all candidates but two are eliminated in the first round IRV in its true form was first used in Western Australia in the 1908 state election The Hare Clark system was introduced for the Tasmanian House of Assembly at the 1909 state election IRV was introduced for federal nationwide elections in Australia after the Swan by election in October 1918 in response to the rise of the conservative Country Party representing small farmers The Country Party split the non Labor vote in conservative country areas allowing Labor candidates to win without a majority of the vote The conservative government of Billy Hughes introduced IRV in Australia called preferential voting as a means of allowing competition between the Coalition parties without putting seats at risk It was first used at the Corangamite by election on 14 December 1918 and at a national level at the 1919 election 89 IRV continued to benefit the Coalition until the 1990 election when for the first time Labor obtained a net benefit from IRV 90 Global use Edit Main article History and use of instant runoff voting Use by country National level elections Edit Country Body or office Type of body or office Electoral system Total seats NotesAustralia House of Representatives Lower chamber of legislature IRV 151Ireland President Head of State IRVDail Eireann Lower chamber of legislature Single transferable vote STV by elections using IRV 158 91 Papua New Guinea National Parliament Unicameral legislature Modified IRV Ranking of maximum 3 candidates 109United States President via Electoral College Head of State and Government Alaska and Maine use IRV to select the state winner In Maine 2 electors are allocated to the winner and the others currently 2 are allocated by congressional district while in Alaska the winner gets all electors of the state in the Electoral College system as Alaska has only one at large district the effect is the same House of Representatives Lower chamber of legislature IRV in Maine Nonpartisan primary system with IRV in the second round among top four candidates in Alaska 92 93 94 95 Robert s Rules of Order EditIn the United States the sequential elimination method used by IRV is described in Robert s Rules of Order Newly Revised 1 as an example of preferential voting The term preferential voting refers to any of a number of voting methods by which on a single ballot when there are more than two possible choices the second or less preferred choices of voters can be taken into account if no candidate or proposition attains a majority While it is more complicated than other methods of voting in common use and is not a substitute for the normal procedure of repeated balloting until a majority is obtained preferential voting is especially useful and fair in an election by mail if it is impractical to take more than one ballot In such cases it makes possible a more representative result than under a rule that a plurality shall elect Preferential voting has many variations One method is described here by way of illustration 96 The instant runoff voting method is then detailed 97 Robert s Rules continues The system of preferential voting just described should not be used in cases where it is possible to follow the normal procedure of repeated balloting until one candidate or proposition attains a majority Although this type of preferential ballot is preferable to an election by plurality it affords less freedom of choice than repeated balloting because it denies voters the opportunity of basing their second or lesser choices on the results of earlier ballots and because the candidate or proposition in last place is automatically eliminated and may thus be prevented from becoming a compromise choice 98 Two other books on American parliamentary procedure take a similar stance disapproving of plurality voting and describing preferential voting as an option if authorized in the bylaws when repeated balloting is impractical The Standard Code of Parliamentary Procedure 99 and Riddick s Rules of Procedure 100 Similar methods EditRunoff voting Edit The term instant runoff voting is derived from the name of a class of voting methods called runoff voting In runoff voting voters do not rank candidates in order of preference on a single ballot Instead a similar effect is achieved by using multiple rounds of voting All multi round runoff voting methods allow voters to change their preferences in each round incorporating the results of the prior round to influence their decision This is not possible in IRV as participants vote only once and this prohibits certain forms of tactical voting that can be prevalent in standard runoff voting Exhaustive ballot Edit A method closer to IRV is the exhaustive ballot In this method one familiar to fans of the television show American Idol one candidate is eliminated after each round and many rounds of voting are used rather than just two 101 Because holding many rounds of voting on separate days is generally expensive the exhaustive ballot is not used for large scale public elections Two round methods Edit The simplest form of runoff voting is the two round system which typically excludes all but two candidates after the first round rather than gradually eliminating candidates over a series of rounds Eliminations can occur with or without allowing and applying preference votes to choose the final two candidates A second round of voting or counting is only necessary if no candidate receives an overall majority of votes This method is used in Mali France and the Finnish and Slovenian presidential election Contingent vote Edit Top two IRV The contingent vote also known as Top two IRV or batch style is the same as IRV except that if no candidate achieves a majority in the first round of counting all but the two candidates with the most votes are eliminated and the second preferences for those ballots are counted As in IRV there is only one round of voting Under a variant of contingent voting used in Sri Lanka and the elections for Mayor of London in the United Kingdom voters rank a specified maximum number of candidates In London the Supplementary Vote allows voters to express first and second preferences only Sri Lankan voters rank up to three candidates for the President of Sri Lanka While similar to sequential elimination IRV top two can produce different results Excluding more than one candidate after the first count might eliminate a candidate who would have won under sequential elimination IRV Restricting voters to a maximum number of preferences is more likely to exhaust ballots if voters do not anticipate which candidates will finish in the top two This can encourage voters to vote more tactically by ranking at least one candidate they think is likely to win Conversely a practical benefit of contingent voting is expediency and confidence in the result with only two rounds Particularly in elections with few e g fewer than 100 voters numerous ties can destroy confidence Heavy use of tie breaking rules leaves uncomfortable doubts over whether the winner might have changed if a recount had been performed Larger runoff process Edit IRV may also be part of a larger runoff process Some jurisdictions that hold runoff elections allow absentee only voters to submit IRV ballots because the interval between votes is too short for a second round of absentee voting IRV ballots enable absentee votes to count in the second general election round if their first choice does not make the runoff Arkansas South Carolina and Springfield Illinois adopt this approach 102 Louisiana uses it only for members of the United States Service or who reside overseas 103 IRV can quickly eliminate weak candidates in early rounds of an exhaustive ballot runoff using rules to leave the desired number of candidates for further balloting IRV allows an arbitrary victory threshold in a single round of voting e g 60 In such cases a second vote may be held to confirm the winner 104 IRV elections that require a majority of cast ballots but not that voters rank all candidates may require more than a single IRV ballot due to exhausted ballots Robert s Rules recommends preferential voting for elections by mail and requiring a majority of cast votes to elect a winner giving IRV as their example For in person elections they recommend repeated balloting until one candidate receives an absolute majority of all votes cast Repeated voting allows voters to turn to a candidate as a compromise who polled poorly in the initial election 1 The common feature of these IRV variations is that one vote is counted per ballot per round with rules that eliminate the weakest candidate s in successive rounds Most IRV implementations drop the requirement for a majority of cast ballots 105 Equal rankings Edit Unlike many single winner methods instant runoff cannot accept equal rankings citation needed and must discard ballots with multiple first preferred remaining alternatives such ballots would be equivalent to casting multiple ballots in a plurality election The inability to cast equal votes including the inability to truncate ballots in some jurisdictional rules creates difficulties for the epistemic properties of democracy Under theories of public reason a democratic decision uses the knowledge of the whole voting body When a voter has no preference or decides themselves that their ability to form a correct preference is insufficient the correct vote is no vote This is expressed by equal rankings and when all rankings are equal it is expressed by no vote Comparison to first past the post Edit At the Australian federal election in September 2013 135 out of the 150 House of Representatives seats or 90 percent were won by the candidate who led on first preferences The other 15 seats 10 percent were won by the candidate who placed second on first preferences 106 Variations Edit Example of a full preferential ballot paper from the Australian House of Representatives A number of IRV methods varying as to ballot design and as to whether or not voters are obliged to provide a full list of preferences are in use in different countries and local governments In an optional preferential voting system voters can give a preference to as many candidates as they wish They may make only a single choice known as bullet voting and some jurisdictions accept a single box marked with an X as opposed to a numeral 1 as valid for the first preference This may result in exhausted ballots where all of a voter s preferences are eliminated before a candidate is elected such that the majority in the final round may only constitute a minority fraction of all ballots cast Optional preferential voting is used for elections for the President of Ireland and the New South Wales Legislative Assembly Optional preferential voting is used for some elections in Queensland 107 108 In a full preferential voting method voters are required to mark a preference for every candidate standing 109 Ballots that do not contain a complete ordering of all candidates are in some jurisdictions considered spoilt or invalid even if there are only two candidates standing This can become burdensome in elections with many candidates and can lead to donkey voting in which some voters simply choose candidates at random or in top to bottom order or a voter may order his or her preferred candidates and then fill in the remainder on a donkey basis Full preferential voting is used for elections to the Australian federal parliament and for most State parliaments Other methods only allow marking preferences for a maximum of the voter s top three favorites a form of partial preferential voting 110 A version of instant runoff voting applying to the ranking of parties was first proposed for elections in Germany in 2013 111 as spare vote 112 Voting method criteria EditScholars rate voting methods using mathematically derived voting method criteria which describe desirable features of a method No ranked preference method can meet all of the criteria because some of them are mutually exclusive as shown by statements such as Arrow s impossibility theorem and the Gibbard Satterthwaite theorem Many of the mathematical criteria by which voting methods are compared were formulated for voters with ordinal preferences If voters vote according to the same ordinal preferences in both rounds criteria can be applied to two round systems of runoffs and in that case each of the criteria failed by IRV is also failed by the two round system as they relate to automatic elimination of trailing candidates Partial results exist for other models of voter behavior in the two round method see the two round system article s criterion compliance section for more information A table summarising satisfaction of the criteria by IRV and other methods is shown in an appendix Satisfied criteria Edit The Condorcet loser criterion states that if a candidate would lose a head to head competition against every other candidate then that candidate must not win the overall election IRV like all voting methods with a final runoff round meets this criterion since the Condorcet loser cannot win a runoff however IRV can still elect the second worst candidate when the two worst candidates are the only ones remaining in the final round 113 The independence of clones criterion states that the election outcome remains the same even if an identical candidate who is equally preferred decides to run IRV meets this criterion 114 The later no harm criterion states that if a voter alters the order of candidates lower in his her preference e g swapping the second and third preferences then that does not affect the chances of the most preferred candidate being elected The majority criterion states that if one candidate is preferred by an absolute majority of voters then that candidate must win The mutual majority criterion states that if an absolute majority of voters prefer every member of a group of candidates to every candidate not in that group then one of the preferred group must win Note that this is satisfied because when all but one candidate that a mutual majority prefer is eliminated the votes of the majority all flow to the remaining candidate in contrast to FPTP where the majority would be treated as separate small groups The resolvability criterion states that the probability of an exact tie must diminish as more votes are cast Non satisfied criteria Edit This section s factual accuracy is disputed Relevant discussion may be found on the talk page Please help to ensure that disputed statements are reliably sourced November 2020 Learn how and when to remove this template message Condorcet winner criterion Edit The Condorcet winner criterion states that if a candidate would win a head to head competition against every other candidate then that candidate must win the overall election It is incompatible with the later no harm criterion so IRV does not meet this criterion IRV is more likely to elect the Condorcet winner than plurality voting and traditional runoff elections The California cities of Oakland San Francisco and San Leandro in 2010 provide an example there were a total of four elections in which the plurality voting leader in first choice rankings was defeated and in each case the IRV winner was the Condorcet winner including a San Francisco election in which the IRV winner was in third place in first choice rankings 115 Systems which fail Condorcet but pass mutual majority can exclude voters outside the mutual majority from the vote essentially becoming an election between the mutual majority citation needed IRV demonstrates this exclusion of up to 50 of voters notably in the 2009 Burlington Vermont mayoral election where the later rounds became a runoff between the mutual majority of voters favoring Andy Montroll and Bob Kiss This can recurse if a mutual majority exists within the mutual majority then the majority becomes a collegiate over the minority and the inner mutual majority solely decides the votes of this collegiate Consistency criterion Edit The consistency criterion states that if dividing the electorate into two groups and running the same election separately with each group returns the same result for both groups then the election over the whole electorate should return this result IRV like all preferential voting methods which are not positional does not meet this criterion Independence of irrelevant alternatives criterion Edit The independence of irrelevant alternatives criterion states that the election outcome remains the same even if a candidate who cannot win decides to run In the general case instant runoff voting can be susceptible to strategic nomination whether or not a candidate decides to run at all can affect the result even if the new candidate cannot themselves win 116 This is much less likely to happen than under plurality citation needed Monotonicity criterion Edit Further information Monotonicity criterion Instant runoff voting and the two round system are not monotonic The monotonicity criterion states that a voter can t harm a candidate s chances of winning by voting that candidate higher or help a candidate by voting that candidate lower while keeping the relative order of all the other candidates equal Allard 117 claims failure is unlikely at a less than 0 03 chance per election Some critics 118 argue in turn that Allard s calculations are wrong and the probability of monotonicity failure is much greater at 14 5 under the impartial culture election model in the three candidate case or 7 10 in the case of a left right spectrum Lepelley et al find a 2 5 probability of monotonicity failure under the same election model as Allard 119 The diagram shows the non monotonicity of IRV where moving the center of opinion away from a candidate can help that candidate win and moving the center of opinion towards a candidate can cause that candidate to lose Participation criterion Edit The participation criterion states that the best way to help a candidate win must not be to abstain 120 IRV does not meet this criterion in some cases the voter s preferred candidate can be best helped if the voter does not vote at all 121 Depankar Ray finds a 50 probability that when IRV elects a different candidate than Plurality some voters would have been better off not showing up 122 Reversal symmetry criterion Edit The reversal symmetry criterion states that if candidate A is the unique winner and each voter s individual preferences are inverted then A must not be elected IRV does not meet this criterion it is possible to construct an election where reversing the order of every ballot paper does not alter the final winner 121 Examples EditSome examples of IRV elections are given below The first two fictional elections demonstrate the principle of IRV The others offer examples of the results of real elections Five voters three candidates Edit A simple example is provided in the accompanying table Three candidates are running for election Bob Bill and Sue There are five voters a through e The voters each have one vote They rank the candidates first second and third in the order they prefer them To win a candidate must have a majority of vote that is three or more In Round 1 the first choice rankings are tallied with the results that Bob and Sue both have two votes and Bill has one No candidate has a majority so a second instant runoff round is required Since Bill is in bottom place he is eliminated The ballot from any voter who ranked Bill first in this example solely voter c gets modified as follows the original 2nd choice candidate for that voter becomes their new 1st choice and their original 3rd choice becomes their new 2nd choice This results in the Round 2 votes as seen below This gives Sue 3 votes which is a majority Round 1 Round 2Candidate a b c d e Votes a b c d e VotesBob 1 2 3 1 2 2 1 2 2 1 2 2Sue 3 1 2 3 1 2 2 1 1 2 1 3Bill 2 3 1 2 3 1Tennessee capital election Edit See also Ranked choice voting in the United States Most instant runoff voting elections are won by the candidate who leads in first choice rankings citation needed choosing the same winner as first past the post voting As an example Australia the 1972 federal election had the highest proportion of winners who would not have won under first past the post with only 14 out of 125 seats not won by the plurality candidate 123 Some IRV elections are won by a candidate who finishes second after the first round count In this case IRV chooses the same winner as a two round system if all voters were to vote again and maintain their same preferences A candidate may also win who is in third place or lower after the first count but gains majority support among the non eliminated candidates in the final round In such cases IRV would choose the same winner as a multi round method that eliminated the last place candidate before each new vote assuming all voters kept voting and maintained their same preferences Here is an example of this last case vte Imagine that Tennessee is having an election on the location of its capital The population of Tennessee is concentrated around its four major cities which are spread throughout the state For this example suppose that the entire electorate lives in these four cities and that everyone wants to live as near to the capital as possible The candidates for the capital are Memphis the state s largest city with 42 of the voters but located far from the other cities Nashville with 26 of the voters near the center of the state Knoxville with 17 of the voters Chattanooga with 15 of the votersThe preferences of the voters would be divided like this 42 of voters close to Memphis 26 of voters close to Nashville 15 of voters close to Chattanooga 17 of voters close to Knoxville Memphis Nashville Chattanooga Knoxville Nashville Chattanooga Knoxville Memphis Chattanooga Knoxville Nashville Memphis Knoxville Chattanooga Nashville MemphisIt takes three rounds to determine a winner in this election Round 1 In the first round no city gets a majority Votes in round City Choice 1stMemphis 42 Nashville 26 Knoxville 17 Chattanooga 15 If one of the cities had achieved a majority vote more than half the election would end there If this were a first past the post election Memphis would win because it received the most votes But IRV does not allow a candidate to win on the first round without having an absolute majority of the vote While 42 of the electorate voted for Memphis 58 of the electorate voted against Memphis in this first round Round 2 In the second round of tabulation we remove the city with the least first place support from consideration Chattanooga received the lowest number of votes in the first round so it is eliminated The ballots that listed Chattanooga as first choice are added to the totals of the second choice selection on each ballot Everything else stays the same Chattanooga s 15 of the total votes are added to the second choices selected by the voters for whom that city was first choice in this example Knoxville Votes in round City Choice 1st 2ndMemphis 42 42 Nashville 26 26 Knoxville 17 32 Chattanooga 15 In the first round Memphis was first Nashville was second and Knoxville was third With Chattanooga eliminated and its votes redistributed the second round finds Memphis still in first place followed by Knoxville in second and Nashville has moved down to third place Round 3 No city yet has secured a majority of votes so we move to the third round with the elimination of Nashville and it becomes a contest between Memphis and Knoxville As in the second round with Chattanooga all of the ballots currently counting for Nashville are added to the totals of Memphis or Knoxville based on which city is ranked next on that ballot In this example the second choice of the Nashville voters is Chattanooga which is already eliminated Therefore the votes are added to their third choice Knoxville The third round of tabulation yields the following result Votes in round City Choice 1st 2nd 3rdMemphis 42 42 42 Nashville 26 26 Knoxville 17 32 58 Chattanooga 15 Result Knoxville which was running third in the first tabulation has moved up from behind to take first place in the third and final round The winner of the election is Knoxville However if 6 of voters in Memphis were to put Nashville first the winner would be Nashville a preferable outcome for voters in Memphis This is an example of potential tactical voting though one that would be difficult for voters to carry out in practice Also if 17 of voters in Memphis were to stay away from voting the winner would be Nashville This is an example of IRV failing the participation criterion For comparison note that traditional first past the post voting would elect Memphis even though most citizens consider it the worst choice because 42 is larger than any other single city As Nashville is a Condorcet winner Condorcet methods would elect Nashville A two round method would have a runoff between Memphis and Nashville where Nashville would win too 1990 Irish presidential election Edit See also Irish presidential election 1990 Irish presidential election 1990 124 Candidate Round 1 Round 2Mary Robinson 612 265 38 9 817 830 51 6 Brian Lenihan 694 484 43 8 731 273 46 2 Austin Currie 267 902 16 9 Exhausted ballots 9 444 0 6 34 992 2 2 Total 1 584 095 100 1 584 095 100 The result of the 1990 Irish presidential election provides an example of how instant runoff voting can produce a different result from first past the post voting The three candidates were Brian Lenihan of the traditionally dominant Fianna Fail party Austin Currie of Fine Gael and Mary Robinson nominated by the Labour Party and the Workers Party After the first round Lenihan had the largest share of the first choice rankings and hence would have won a first past the post vote but no candidate attained the necessary majority Currie was eliminated and his votes reassigned to the next choice ranked on each ballot in this process Robinson received 82 of Currie s votes thereby overtaking Lenihan 2014 Prahran election Victoria Edit A real life example of IRV producing a result which differs from what would be expected under a first past the post or the two round voting system is the result for the seat of Prahran in the 2014 Victorian state election In this instance it was the candidate who initially finished third Greens candidate Sam Hibbins in the primary vote went on to win the seat on the back of favourable preferences from the other two minor parties and independents narrowly beating the second ranked candidate Labor candidate Neil Pharaoh by 31 votes and the first ranked candidate Liberal candidate Clem Newton Brown by 277 votes It was not until the final round of counting that one of the two remaining candidates Hibbins had more than 50 of the total vote 125 In theory the elimination of the center left Labor candidate before the left wing Green candidate could have transferred enough votes to the center right Liberal candidate for him to win but instead roughly 8 1 Labor voters chose the Green ahead of the Liberal Candidate 125 Primary vote First round Second round Third round Fourth round Fifth round Sixth roundClem Newton Brown LIB 16 582 44 8 16 592 16 644 16 726 16 843 17 076 18 363 49 6 Neil Pharaoh ALP 9 586 25 9 9 593 9 639 9 690 9 758 9 948Sam Hibbins GRN 9 160 24 8 9 171 9 218 9 310 9 403 9 979 18 640 50 4 Eleonora Gullone AJP 837 2 3 860 891 928 999Alan Walker FFP 282 0 8 283 295Jason Goldsmith IND 247 0 7 263 316 349Steve Stefanopoulos IND 227 0 6 241Alan Menadue IND 82 0 2 Total 37 003 100 2009 Burlington mayoral election Edit See also 2009 Burlington mayoral election Burlington mayoral election 2009 Round by round analysis of votes Candidates 1st Round 2nd Round 3rd RoundCandidate Party Votes Votes Votes Bob Kiss Progressive 2585 2585 2981 396 4313 1332Kurt Wright Republican 2951 2951 3294 343 4061 767Andy Montroll Democrat 2063 2063 2554 491 0 2554Dan Smith Independent 1306 1306 0 1306James Simpson Green 35 35 0 35Write in 36 36 0 36EXHAUSTED PILE 4 4 151 147 606 455TOTALS 126 8980 8980Unlike Burlington s first IRV mayoral election in 2006 the IRV winner in 2009 Bob Kiss was neither the same as the plurality winner Kurt Wright nor the Condorcet winner Andy Montroll 127 128 129 130 Burlington voters repealed IRV in 2010 by a vote of 52 to 48 and in 2021 voted to use RCV for city council elections by a vote of 64 to 36 131 132 The organization FairVote which advocates for IRV claimed the election as a success citing three reasons 1 it prevented the election of the presumed winner under a plurality system by avoiding the effect of vote splitting between the other candidates 2 99 99 of the ballots were valid suggesting that voters handled the system without difficulty and 3 contributed to producing a campaign among four serious candidates that was widely praised for its substantive nature 133 However the election was considered a failure by advocates of the Condorcet winner who point out that in a head to head election Andy Montroll should have beaten Bob Kiss by a 7 8 margin 128 129 134 In this case a mutual majority causes a lock out of a sufficiently large e g plurality minority In examples where a smaller minority would break the lock out and would change the winner in their favor the participation criterion is violated Wright voters were 40 versus voters who placed Montroll and Kiss above Wright at 51 5 That means a lot of Wright voters would have had to stay home for their demographic to matter at all causing a participation criterion failure If Wright voters preferred Montroll over Kiss it would have been more advantageous to abstain or not give Wright their first preference this would then result in Montroll reaching the final runoff and beating Kiss 54 to 46 as opposed to the actual final runoff between Wright and Kiss This would elect the candidate who started with only the third most primary votes Montroll and still would not be able to elect Wright without more of Montroll voters preferences or a higher primary vote possibly to the point of having an outright majority Burlington mayoral election 2009 Summary analysis Party Candidate Maximumround Maximumvotes Share inmaximumround Maximum votesFirst round votes Transfer votesProgressive Bob Kiss 3 4 313 48 0 Republican Kurt Wright 3 4 061 45 2 Democratic Andy Montroll 2 2 554 28 4 Independent Dan Smith 1 1 306 14 5 Green James Simpson 1 35 0 4 Write in 1 36 0 4 Exhausted votes 606 6 7 Comparison of Schulze to preferential voting systems EditComparison of preferential electoral systems Sys tem Mono tonic Condorcet winner Majo rity Condorcet loser Majority loser Mutual majority Smith ISDA LIIA Independence of clones Reversal symmetry Participation consistency Later no harm Later no help Polynomial time Resol vabilitySchulze Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes No No No Yes YesRanked pairs Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No Yes YesTideman s Alternative No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No Yes YesKemeny Young Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No YesCopeland Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No Yes No No No Yes NoNanson No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No Yes No No No Yes YesBlack Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No Yes No No No Yes YesInstant runoff voting No No Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No Yes No No Yes Yes Yes YesSmith IRV No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No Yes YesBorda Yes No No Yes Yes No No No No No Yes Yes No Yes Yes YesBaldwin No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No Yes YesBucklin Yes No Yes No Yes Yes No No No No No No No Yes Yes YesPlurality Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes YesContingent voting No No Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes YesCoombs 135 No No Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No No Yes YesMiniMax Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No No No No No Yes YesAnti plurality 135 Yes No No No Yes No No No No No No Yes No No Yes YesSri Lankan contingent voting No No Yes No No No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes YesSupplementary voting No No Yes No No No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes YesDodgson 135 No Yes Yes No No No No No No No No No No No No YesSee also EditAlternative vote plus AV or alternative vote top up proposed by the Jenkins Commission in the UK Comparison of electoral systems First past the post voting None of the above NOTA or Re open Nominations RON Outline of democracy Ranked choice voting in the United States Ranked voting Single transferable vote AV method for elections with multiple positions to be filled for example the Australian Senate References Edit a b c Robert Henry 2011 Robert s Rules of Order Newly Revised 11th ed Da Capo Press pp 425 428 ISBN 978 0 306 82020 5 FairVote org Ranked Choice Voting Instant Runoff FairVote Retrieved 30 May 2019 Explainer What is preferential voting SBS News Retrieved 30 May 2019 Preferential voting Australian Electoral Commission Retrieved 17 November 2020 Alternative Vote www electoral reform org uk Retrieved 30 May 2019 Toplak Jurij 2017 Preferential Voting Definition and Classification Lex Localis Journal of Local Self Government 15 4 737 61 doi 10 4335 15 4 737 761 2017 Ranked Choice Voting RCV www opavote com Retrieved 30 May 2019 For some people ranked choice voting means any voting method where voters rank candidates For these people ranked choice voting includes not only Instant runoff voting and the single transferable vote but also Condorcet voting and the Borda count FairVote org Ranked Choice Voting Instant Runoff FairVote Retrieved 31 May 2019 Examples of uses of RCV include Australia multi winner form of it for senate elections Ireland multi winner form for parliament and many local elections Malta multi winner form for parliament Rubel Alex 24 May 2019 Ranked Choice replaces Instant Runoff as new election format in first Just Community decision this year The Boiling Point Retrieved 31 May 2019 The ranked choice system voters rank each candidate from favorite to least favorite and the winner is the candidate who was on average voted the highest a b Types of Voting Systems Mtholyoke edu 8 April 2005 Retrieved 6 May 2010 Australian Electoral Commission Aec gov au 23 April 2014 Retrieved 30 April 2014 Ireland Constitution Article 12 2 3 International Constitutional Law 1995 Retrieved 15 February 2008 Understanding the Limited Preferential Voting system EMTV Online Retrieved 18 February 2021 a b Electoral Pocketbook 2011 3 The electoral process Australian Electoral Commission Archived from the original on 8 February 2013 Retrieved 3 November 2012 Declaration of Robert Richie in Support of Petition for Writ of Mandate PDF Archive fairvote org Retrieved 1 March 2015 FairVote 25 June 2008 Ranked Voting and Election Integrity FairVote org Retrieved 30 April 2014 Minneapolis Ranked Choice Voting History City of Minneapolis Retrieved 17 August 2019 Maine Public Broadcasting Network Maine News amp Programming Mpbn net Archived from the original on 19 March 2014 Retrieved 30 April 2014 Tideman Nicolaus 2006 Collective decisions and voting the potential for public choice Aldershot England Burlington VT Ashgate p 154 ISBN 978 0 7546 4717 1 OCLC 70334914 Claim 1 Voters Can Understand RCV Voting in the House of Representatives Australian Electoral Commission 28 June 2016 Retrieved 9 December 2018 Busting the Myths of AV No2av org 25 October 2010 Archived from the original on 8 February 2011 Retrieved 17 April 2011 Informal Voting Two Ways of Allowing More Votes to Count ABC Elections 28 February 2011 Retrieved 15 August 2011 Instant Runoff Voting and Its Impact on Racial Minorities PDF New America Foundation 1 August 2008 Archived from the original PDF on 15 June 2011 Retrieved 15 August 2011 Burnett Craig M Kogan Vladimir March 2015 Ballot and voter exhaustion under Instant Runoff Voting An examination of four ranked choice elections Electoral Studies 37 41 49 doi 10 1016 j electstud 2014 11 006 S2CID 11159132 Box Second Report Election of a Speaker House of Commons Select Committee on Procedure 15 February 2001 Retrieved 18 February 2008 Cary David 1 January 2011 Estimating the Margin of Victory for Instant runoff Voting Proceedings of the 2011 Conference on Electronic Voting Technology Workshop on Trustworthy Elections EVT WOTE 11 3 BBC News Alternative vote bbc com British Broadcasting Corporation 8 February 2012 Retrieved 9 October 2019 Opinion OUSA Needs the Alternative Vote Critic Te Arohi Otago New Zealand Otago University Students Association 30 September 2017 Retrieved 9 October 2019 What is Ranked Choice Voting City of London Archived from the original on 26 February 2018 Liberal plan to change federal voting laws may have crossbench support The Guardian 11 December 2020 Retrieved 13 February 2021 How RCV Works FairVote 17 August 2019 Retrieved 17 August 2018 Appendix D Instant Runoff Voting San Francisco Charter 13 102 https sfgov org ccsfgsa sites default files Voting 20Systems 20Task 20Force AppendixD pdf Arntz John 2 February 2005 Ranked Choice Voting A Guide for Candidates PDF Department of Elections City and County of San Francisco Archived from the original PDF on 2 December 2008 Retrieved 25 August 2009 via FairVote In San Francisco ranked choice voting is sometimes called instant run off voting The Department of Elections generally uses the term ranked choice voting because it describes the voting method voters are directed to rank their first second and third choice candidates The Department also uses the term ranked choice voting because the word instant might create an expectation that final results will be available immediately after the polls close on election night Pacuit Eric 24 June 2019 Original version published 3 August 2011 Voting Methods In Zalta Edward N ed The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy Fall 2019 ed via plato stanford edu Proportional Representation Citizens Information Board Retrieved 17 August 2019 South Carolina General Assembly 116th Session 2005 2006 Scstatehouse gov Retrieved 1 March 2015 Bill Information Arkleg state ar us Retrieved 28 January 2015 J R Chamberlin and M D Cohen Toward Applicable Social Choice Theory 1978 Bartholdi III John J Orlin James B 1991 Single transferable vote resists strategic voting PDF Social Choice and Welfare 8 4 341 354 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 127 97 doi 10 1007 bf00183045 S2CID 17749613 How to Vote Guide Antony Green s Election Blog 11 October 2011 Retrieved 29 January 2017 What is the best way to vote strategically The best strategic vote is to number the candidates in the order you would like to see them elected in electorate of more than 90 000 voters and without perfect knowledge such a strategy is not possible Green Armytage James Four Condorcet Hare Hybrid Methods for Single Winner Elections PDF Archived from the original PDF on 3 June 2013 Retrieved 31 May 2011 Robinette Robbie Tideman Nicolaus 12 March 2021 What a Difference a Voting Rule Makes Savannah Georgia a b c Warren Smith 2009 Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayor election Thwarted majority non monotonicity amp other failures oops Monotonicity and IRV Why the Monotonicity Criterion is of Little Import Archive fairvote org Retrieved 17 April 2011 Instant Run Off Voting archive fairvote org Retrieved 29 January 2017 IRV removes the spoiler effect whereby minor party or independent candidates knock off major party candidates increasing the choices available to the voters Cal IRV FAQ www cfer org Retrieved 29 January 2017 IRV completely eliminates the spoiler effect that is votes split between a weak and a strong candidate won t cause the strong candidate to lose if s he is the second choice of the weak candidate s voters OP ED No More Spoilers Instant Runoff Voting Makes Third Parties Viable Improves Democracy CT News Junkie Retrieved 20 April 2017 Instant runoff voting ends the spoiler effect forever CGP Grey 6 April 2011 The Alternative Vote Explained retrieved 20 April 2017 Alternative Vote Stops the Spoiler Effect Borgers Christoph 2010 Mathematics of Social Choice Voting Compensation and Division SIAM ISBN 9780898716955 Candidates C and D spoiled the election for B With them in the running A won whereas without them in the running B would have won Instant runoff voting does not do away with the spoiler problem entirely although it makes it less likely Poundstone William 2009 Gaming the Vote Why Elections Aren t Fair and What We Can Do About It Farrar Straus and Giroux ISBN 9781429957649 IRV is excellent for preventing classic spoilers minor candidates who irrationally tip the election from one major candidate to another It is not so good when the spoiler has a real chance of winning The Spoiler Effect The Center for Election Science 20 May 2015 Retrieved 29 January 2017 The Problem with Instant Runoff Voting minguo info Retrieved 29 January 2017 After a minor party is strong enough to win on the other hand a vote for them could have the same spoiler effect that it could have under the current plurality system Example to demonstrate how IRV leads to spoilers 2 party domination RangeVoting org Retrieved 29 January 2017 IRV means betraying your true favorite third party candidate pays off Voting third party can mean wasting your vote under IRV just like under plurality The Center for Election Science 2 December 2013 Favorite Betrayal in Plurality and Instant Runoff Voting retrieved 29 January 2017 O Neill Jeffrey C 2006 Everything That Can be Counted Does Not Necessarily Count The Right to Vote and the Choice of a Voting System SSRN Working Paper Series 340 doi 10 2139 ssrn 883058 ISSN 1556 5068 S2CID 155750146 With instant runoff voting The strategy for the liberal voter is the same as for plurality voting Her favorite candidate cannot win so she casts her vote for her favorite candidate with a realistic chance of winning Comments 9 December 2016 The False Promise of Instant Runoff Voting Cato Unbound Retrieved 29 January 2017 They ll have a strategic incentive to falsify their preferences 2009 Burlington Mayor IRV Failure bolson org Retrieved 29 January 2017 House of Representatives Results Results aec gov au Retrieved 1 March 2015 Every RCV Election in the Bay Area So Far Has Produced Condorcet Winners fairvote org 6 January 2017 Retrieved 13 February 2017 Travis Alan 10 May 2010 Electoral reform Alternative vote system would have had minimal impact on outcome of general election The Guardian London Retrieved 1 April 2011 History of Preferential Voting in Australia Australian Broadcasting Corporation 2004 Election Guide Such a long lasting Coalition would not have been possible under first part the post voting Pierce County RCV Overview City of LA Briefing PDF Archived from the original PDF on 27 September 2011 Retrieved 6 May 2010 City and County of San Francisco Voter Information Pamphlet and Sample Ballot Consolidated Primary Election March 5 2002 PDF Archived from the original PDF on 18 October 2007 County auditor sees savings from scrapping ranked choice voting Blogs thenewstribune com 30 August 2006 Archived from the original on 10 February 2017 Retrieved 6 May 2010 Wake County Answers on IRV Election Administration FairVote Retrieved 30 April 2014 No to AV campaign reject rivals scare stories claim Bbc co uk 24 February 2011 Retrieved 17 April 2011 Nc Voter Nc Voter Retrieved 6 May 2010 Ranked Choice Voting and Election Integrity FairVote 25 June 2008 Retrieved 6 May 2010 Murphy Dean E 30 September 2004 New Runoff System in San Francisco Has the Rival Candidates Cooperating The New York Times Russo John 24 July 2006 Instant runoff voting is right way to go for Oakland Oakland Tribune Archived from the original on 6 December 2008 How Ranked Choice Voting Impacts Elections Ranked Choice Voting in Practice Candidate Civility in Ranked Choice Elections PDF fairvote org FairVote Retrieved 2 December 2015 Project MUSE Muse jhu edu Retrieved 6 May 2010 Papua New Guinea Leaflet on Limited Preferential Voting System Electoral Knowledge Network Recommendations and Conclusions The Report of the Independent Commission on the Voting System Archived from the original on 5 December 2013 Walter Benjamin History of Preferential Voting in Ann Arbor Archived from the original on 8 February 2012 Ann Arbor Law Suit FairVote Retrieved 10 May 2011 Leary Mal 12 June 2018 Opposed To Ranked Choice Voting LePage Says He Might Not Certify Primary Election Results www mainepublic org Retrieved 14 January 2019 Complaint PDF Baber v Dunlap Court Filing D M E vol No 1 18 cv 00465 no Docket 1 13 November 2018 retrieved 13 January 2019 via Recap 1st Circuit ends Poliquin s efforts to keep House seat Bangor Daily News 22 December 2018 Retrieved 17 August 2019 Claim 3 RCV Increases Voter Participation Nanson E J 1882 Methods of election Ware s Method Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria 17 206 The method was however mentioned by Condorcet but only to be condemned Condorcet Jean Antoine Nicolas de Caritat 1788 On the Constitution and the Functions of Provincial Assemblies Complete Works of Condorcet in French Vol 13 published 1804 p 243 En effet lorsqu il y a plus de trois concurrents le veritable vœu de la pluralite peut etre pour un candidat qui n ait eu aucune des voix dans le premier scrutin Ware William R 1871 Application of Mr Hare s system of voting to the nomination of overseers of Harvard College OCLC 81791186 It is equally efficient whether one candidate is to be chosen or a dozen Benjamin Reilly The Global Spread of Preferential Voting Australian Institutional Imperialism PDF FairVote org Retrieved 17 April 2011 McLean Iain October 2002 Australian electoral reform and two concepts of representation PDF p 11 Retrieved 22 February 2008 Australian Electoral History Voting Methods Australianpolitics com Archived from the original on 19 March 2011 Retrieved 17 April 2011 The Origin of Senate Group Ticket Voting and it didn t come from the Major Parties ABC News 22 September 2015 The Ceann Comhairle or Speaker of Dail Eireann is returned automatically for whichever constituency s he was elected if they wish to seek re election reducing the number of seats contested in that constituency by one In that case should the Ceann Comhairle be from a three seater only two seats are contested in the general election from there As a result if the Ceann Comhairle wishes to be in the next Dail only 165 seats are actually contested in a general election Maine became the first state in the country Tuesday to pass ranked choice voting 10 November 2016 Retrieved 10 November 2016 Ranked Choice Voting Maine Voters Rank Candidates Maine Uses Ranked Choice Voting Retrieved 8 April 2018 Eric Russell 12 June 2018 Mainers vote to keep ranked choice voting with supporters holding commanding lead Portland Press Herald Retrieved 13 June 2018 Alaska Ballot Measure 2 Top Four Ranked Choice Voting and Campaign Finance Laws Initiative 2020 Ballotpedia Retrieved 17 November 2020 Robert 2011 p 426 Robert 2011 pp 426 428 Robert 2011 p 428 Sturgis Alice 2001 The Standard Code of Parliamentary Procedure 4th ed Riddick amp Butcher 1985 Riddick s Rules of Procedure 1985 ed Glossary Exhaustive ballot Securevote com au Retrieved 6 May 2010 Initiatives Pew Center on the States PDF Electionline org Archived from the original PDF on 16 May 2008 Retrieved 6 May 2010 IRV for Louisiana s Overseas Voters web page FairVote IRV America retrieved 16 June 2013 For example in 2006 the Independence Party of Minnesota used IRV for its endorsement elections requiring 60 to win and exhaustive balloting to follow if needed Vermont S 22 1 c 3 Sec 7 6 if neither of the last two remaining candidates in an election received a majority the report and the tabulations performed by the instant runoff count committee shall be forwarded to the Washington superior court which shall issue a certificate of election to whichever of the two remaining candidates received the greatest number of votes at the conclusion of the instant runoff tabulation and send a certified copy of the tabulation and results to the secretary of state Antony Green 8 September 2015 Preferences Donkey Votes and the Canning By Election Antony Green s Election Blog Australian Broadcasting Corporation Retrieved 8 September 2015 Voting system www ecq qld gov au Electoral Commission of Queensland 28 January 2020 Retrieved 17 November 2020 Stevens Bronwyn Are Queenslanders in danger of wasting their votes The Conversation Retrieved 28 November 2020 Electoral Systems Electoral Council of Australia Archived from the original on 9 March 2008 Retrieved 15 February 2008 Ranked Choice Voting Registrar of Voters Alameda County Retrieved 15 December 2016 This format allows a voter to select a first choice candidate in the first column a second choice candidate in the second column and a third choice candidate in the third column Breyer Patrick November 2013 Alternative II Einfuhrung einer Ersatzstimme PDF Anhorung zum Entwurf eines Gesetzes zur Abschaffung der Funf Prozent Sperrklausel bei Landtagswahlen in Schleswig Holstein Hearing on the draft law to abolish the five percent threshold in state elections in Schleswig Holstein Discussion paper Report in German Piratenfraktion im Schleswig Holsteinischen Landtag Drs 18 385 What is Dual Level Voting Nanson E J 1882 Methods of election Transactions and Proceedings of the Royal Society of Victoria 19 207 208 although Ware s method cannot return the worst it may return the next worst Green Armytage James 2004 A Survey of Basic Voting Methods Archived from the original on 3 June 2013 FairVote Understanding the RCV Election Results in District 10 FairVote org Archived from the original on 26 July 2011 Retrieved 17 April 2011 Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayoral election RangeVoting org Retrieved 17 April 2011 Crispin Allard January 1996 Estimating the Probability of Monotonicity Failure in a UK General Election Retrieved 4 May 2011 Warren D Smith Monotonicity and Instant Runoff Voting Retrieved 4 May 2011 Lepelley Dominique Chantreuil Frederic Berg Sven 1996 The likelihood of monotonicity paradoxes in run off elections Mathematical Social Sciences 31 3 133 146 doi 10 1016 0165 4896 95 00804 7 More precisely submitting a ballot that ranks A ahead of B should never change the winner from A to B a b Smith Warren D Lecture Mathematics and Democracy Retrieved 12 May 2011 Ray Depankar 1986 On the practical possibility of a no show paradox under the single transferable vote Mathematical Social Sciences 11 2 183 189 doi 10 1016 0165 4896 86 90024 7 Green Antony 11 May 2010 Preferential Voting in Australia www abc net au Retrieved 1 November 2020 Presidential Election November 1990 ElectionsIreland org Retrieved 23 November 2009 a b State Election 2014 Prahran District Distribution of preference votes Victorian Electoral Commission 2009 Burlington Mayor Election votingsolutions com 3 March 2009 Archived from the original on 9 November 2009 Bouricious Terry 13 March 2009 Point Counterpoint Terry Bouricius Attempts To Rip Professor Gierzynski A New One Over Instant Runoff Voting Controversy Now With All New Gierzynski Update Vermont Daily Briefing Archived from the original on 19 October 2015 Retrieved 27 September 2017 the 2009 election suffered from not only the thwarted majorities or Condorcet s paradox but also the no show paradox that shows that Wright voters who preferred Montroll over Kiss that is ranked Montroll 2nd would have been better staying home and not voting at all a b Gierzynski Anthony Hamilton Wes Smith Warren D March 2009 Burlington Vermont 2009 IRV mayoral election RangeVoting org Retrieved 1 October 2017 Montroll was favored over Republican Kurt Wright 56 to 44 and over Progressive Bob Kiss 54 to 46 In other words in voting terminology Montroll was a beats all winner also called a Condorcet winner However in the IRV election Montroll came in third a b Olson Brian 2009 2009 Burlington Mayor IRV Failure bolson org Retrieved 1 October 2017 This is an IRV failure The IRV result is clearly not what people actually wanted More people liked Montroll over Kiss than the other way around but IRV elected the loser Sheldon hess Dale 16 March 2009 IRV Fails in Its Own Backyard The Least of All Evils Retrieved 27 September 2017 Montroll would have beaten any other candidate in a one on one election Instant run off voting experiment ends in Burlington Rutland Herald Online Archived from the original on 4 March 2016 Retrieved 15 December 2016 Burlington Vermont Question 4 Ranked Choice Voting Amendment March Ballotpedia org Retrieved 18 April 2021 Bouricius Terry 17 March 2009 Response to Faulty Analysis of Burlington IRV Election FairVote org Retrieved 1 October 2017 successfully prevented the election of the candidate who would likely have won under plurality rules but would have lost to either of the other top finishers in a runoff Burlington s 2009 Mayoral Election Did IRV Fail The Voters Integral Psychosis 16 March 2009 Retrieved 1 October 2017 Montroll was the Beats All winner aka the Condorcet winner as he would have beaten both Wright 56 to 44 and Kiss 54 to 46 in head to head races demonstrating that he was the preferred candidate by the majority of voters a b c Anti plurality Coombs and Dodgson are assumed to receive truncated preferences by apportioning possible rankings of unlisted alternatives equally for example ballot A gt B C is counted as 1 2 A gt B gt C and 1 2 A gt C gt B If these methods are assumed not to receive truncated preferences then later no harm and later no help are not applicable External links EditPreferential Voting at Australian Eelectoral Commission 2010 articles from the Constitution Society and Electoral Reform Society summarizing the proposed change in the United Kingdom to IRV Alternative VotePractice Edit Advantages and disadvantages of AV from the ACE Project Electoral Design Reference Materials A Handbook of Electoral System Design from International IDEA Australian Electoral Commission Web Site Australian Senate example needed Australian House of Representatives example needed Preferential Voting in Australia from Australian Politics com San Francisco Department of Elections California Alameda County Registrar of Voters California City of Minneapolis Minnesota Ranked Choice Voting Resource CenterDemonstrations and simulations Edit The Star Tribune How ranked choice voting works an interactive graphic RankedVote Online ranked choice voting platform for voter education with detailed results animations and explanations RCV123 org Free non profit site with on line and paper ballot ranked choice voting systems for any group vote AmericanQuorum com A ranked choice ballot tool from the Indaba Application Network including the animated display of an instant runoff BBC Would the alternative vote have changed history illustration of how the results of the last six general elections might have looked had the alternative vote system been in place OpenSTV Open source software for computing IRV and STV Favourite Futurama Character Poll Voting System Visualizations 2 dimensional plots of results of various methods with assumptions of sincere voting behavior Simulation Of Various Voting Models for Close Elections Opposition article by Brian Olson Advocacy groups and positions Edit Yes to Fairer Votes campaign site for the Yes side of the 2011 United Kingdom Alternative Vote referendum Washington Post Ranked Choice Voting at FairVote League of Women Voters of Vermont Ranked Choice Voting at Represent Us InstantRunoff com Ranked Ballot Initiative of Toronto rabit ca Roosevelt Institution Citizens for Voter Choice Massachusetts FairVote Minnesota Common Cause Massachusetts Brookings Institution s Empowering Moderate Voters paper Does the Alternative Vote Bring Tyranny to Australia Antony Green ABCOpposition groups and positions Edit Center for Election Science compares Instant runoff to Approval voting Fair Vote Canada paper on the Alternative Vote IRV page at the Center for Range Voting Instant Runoff Voting Report Values and Risks Report by the N C Coalition for Verified Voting Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Instant runoff voting amp oldid 1128170709, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.