fbpx
Wikipedia

D'Hondt method

The D'Hondt method,[a] also called the Jefferson method or the greatest divisors method, is an apportionment method for allocating seats in parliaments among federal states, or in proportional representation among political parties. It belongs to the class of highest-averages methods.

The method was first described in 1792 by future U.S. president Thomas Jefferson. It was re-invented independently in 1878 by Belgian mathematician Victor D'Hondt, which is the reason for its two different names.

Motivation

Proportional representation systems aim to allocate seats to parties approximately in proportion to the number of votes received. For example, if a party wins one-third of the votes then it should gain about one-third of the seats. In general, exact proportionality is not possible because these divisions produce fractional numbers of seats. As a result, several methods, of which the D'Hondt method is one, have been devised which ensure that the parties' seat allocations, which are of whole numbers, are as proportional as possible.[1] Although all of these methods approximate proportionality, they do so by minimizing different kinds of disproportionality. The D'Hondt method minimizes the largest seats-to-votes ratio.[2] Empirical studies based on other, more popular concepts of disproportionality show that the D'Hondt method is one of the least proportional among the proportional representation methods. The D'Hondt favours large parties and coalitions over small parties due to strategic voting.[3][4][5][6] In comparison, the Sainte-Laguë method, reduces the disproportional bias towards large parties and it generally has a more equal seats-to-votes ratio for different sized parties.[3]

The axiomatic properties of the D'Hondt method were studied and they proved that the D'Hondt method is a consistent and monotone method that reduces political fragmentation by encouraging coalitions.[7][8] A method is consistent if it treats parties that received tied votes equally. By monotonicity, the number of seats provided to any state or party will not decrease if the house size increases.

Procedure

After all the votes have been tallied, successive quotients are calculated for each party. The party with the largest quotient wins one seat, and its quotient is recalculated. This is repeated until the required number of seats is filled. The formula for the quotient is[9][1]

 

where:

  • V is the total number of votes that party received, and
  • s is the number of seats that party has been allocated so far, initially 0 for all parties.

The total votes cast for each party in the electoral district is divided, first by 1, then by 2, then 3, up to the total number of seats to be allocated for the district/constituency. Say there are p parties and s seats. Then a grid of numbers can be created, with p rows and s columns, where the entry in the ith row and jth column is the number of votes won by the ith party, divided by j. The s winning entries are the s highest numbers in the whole grid; each party is given as many seats as there are winning entries in its row.

Example

In this example, 230,000 voters decide the disposition of 8 seats among 4 parties. Since 8 seats are to be allocated, each party's total votes are divided by 1, then by 2, 3, and 4 (and then, if necessary, by 5, 6, 7, and so on). The 8 highest entries, marked with asterisks, range from 100,000 down to 25,000. For each, the corresponding party gets a seat. Note that in Round 1, the quotient shown in the table, as derived from the formula, is precisely the number of votes returned in the ballot.

Round

(1 seat per round)

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Seats won
(bold)
Party A quotient

seats after round

100,000
1
50,000
1
50,000
2
33,333
2
33,333
3
25,000
3
25,000
3
25,000
4
4
Party B quotient

seats after round

80,000
0
80,000
1
40,000
1
40,000
2
26,667
2
26,667
2
26,667
3
20,000
3
3
Party C quotient

seats after round

30,000
0
30,000
0
30,000
0
30,000
0
30,000
0
30,000
1
15,000
1
15,000
1
1
Party D quotient

seats after round

20,000
0
20,000
0
20,000
0
20,000
0
20,000
0
20,000
0
20,000
0
20,000
0
0

While in this example, parties B, C, and D formed a coalition against Party A. You can see that Party A received 3 seats instead of 4 due to the coalition having 30,000 more votes than Party A.

Round

(1 seat per round)

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Seats won

(bold)

Party A quotient

seats after round

100,000
0
100,000
1
50,000
1
50,000
2
33,333
2
33,333
3
25,000
3
25,000
3
3
Coalition B-C-D

quotient seats after round

130,000
1
65,000
1
65,000
2
43,333
2
43,333
3
32,500
3
32,500
4
26,000
5
5

The chart below shows an easy way to perform the calculation. Each party's vote is divided by 1, 2, 3, or 4 in consecutive columns, then the 8 highest values resulting are selected. The quantity of highest values in each row is the number of seats won.

For comparison, the "True proportion" column shows the exact fractional numbers of seats due, calculated in proportion to the number of votes received. (For example, 100,000/230,000 × 8 = 3.48) The slight favouring of the largest party over the smallest is apparent.

Denominator /1 /2 /3 /4 Seats
won (*)
True proportion
Party A 100,000* 50,000* 33,333* 25,000* 4 3.5
Party B 80,000* 40,000* 26,667* 20,000 3 2.8
Party C 30,000* 15,000 10,000 7,500 1 1.0
Party D 20,000 10,000 6,667 5,000 0 0.7
Total 8 8

Further examples

A worked-through example for non-experts relating to the 2019 elections in the UK for the European Parliament written by Christina Pagel is available as an online article with the institute UK in a Changing Europe.[10]

A more mathematically detailed example has been written by British mathematician Professor Helen Wilson.[11]

Approximate proportionality under D'Hondt

The D'Hondt method approximates proportionality by minimizing the largest seats-to-votes ratio among all parties.[12] This ratio is also known as the advantage ratio. In contrast, the average seats-to-votes ratio is optimized by the Webster/Sainte-Laguë method. For party  , where   is the overall number of parties, the advantage ratio is

 

where

  •   – the seat share of party  ,  ,
  •   – the vote share of party  ,  .

The largest advantage ratio,

 

captures how over-represented is the most over-represented party.

The D'Hondt method assigns seats so that this ratio attains its smallest possible value,

 

where   is a seat allocation from the set of all allowed seat allocations  . Thanks to this, as shown by Juraj Medzihorsky,[2] the D'Hondt method splits the votes into exactly proportionally represented ones and residual ones. The overall fraction of residual votes is

 

The residuals of party p are

 

For illustration, continue with the above example of four parties. The advantage ratios of the four parties are 1.2 for A, 1.1 for B, 1 for C, and 0 for D. The reciprocal of the largest advantage ratio is 1/1.15 = 0.87 = 1 − π*. The residuals as shares of the total vote are 0% for A, 2.2% for B, 2.2% for C, and 8.7% for party D. Their sum is 13%, i.e., 1 − 0.87 = 0.13. The decomposition of the votes into represented and residual ones is shown in the table below.

Allocation of eight seats under the D'Hondt method
Party Vote
share
Seat
share
Advantage
ratio
Residual
votes
Represented
votes
A 43.5% 50.0% 1.15 0.0% 43.5%
B 34.8% 37.5% 1.08 2.2% 32.6%
C 13.0% 12.5% 0.96 2.2% 10.9%
D 8.7% 0.0% 0.00 8.7% 0.0%
Total 100% 100% 13% 87%

Jefferson and D'Hondt

The method was first described in 1792 by Thomas Jefferson, in a letter to George Washington regarding the apportionment of seats in the United States House of Representatives:[7]

For representatives there can be no such common ratio, or divisor which ... will divide them exactly without a remainder or fraction. I answer then ... that representatives [must be divided] as nearly as the nearest ratio will admit; and the fractions must be neglected.

It was invented independently in 1878 in Europe, by Belgian mathematician Victor D'Hondt, who wrote:

to allocate discrete entities proportionally among several numbers, it is necessary to divide these numbers by a common divisor, producing quotients whose sum is equal to the number of entities to be allocated.

The Jefferson and the D'Hondt methods are equivalent. They always give the same results, but the methods of presenting the calculation are different. George Washington exercised his first veto power on a bill that introduced a new plan for dividing seats in the House of Representatives that would have increased the number of seats for northern states.[13] Ten days after the veto, Congress passed a new method of apportionment, now known as Jefferson's Method. Statesman and future US President Thomas Jefferson devised the method in 1792 for the U.S. congressional apportionment pursuant to the First United States Census. It was used to achieve the proportional distribution of seats in the House of Representatives among the states until 1842.[14]

Victor D'Hondt presented his method in his publication Système pratique et raisonné de représentation proportionnelle, published in Brussels in 1882.

The system can be used both for distributing seats in a legislature among states pursuant to populations or among parties pursuant to an election result. The tasks are mathematically equivalent, putting states in the place of parties and population in place of votes. In some countries, the Jefferson system is known by the names of local politicians or experts who introduced them locally. For example, it is known in Israel as the Bader–Ofer system.

Jefferson's method uses a quota (called a divisor), as in the largest remainder method. The divisor is chosen as necessary so that the resulting quotients, disregarding any fractional remainders, sum to the required total; in other words, pick a number so that there is no need to examine the remainders. Any number in one range of quotas will accomplish this, with the highest number in the range always being the same as the lowest number used by the D'Hondt method to award a seat (if it is used rather than the Jefferson method), and the lowest number in the range being the smallest number larger than the next number which would award a seat in the D'Hondt calculations.

Applied to the above example of party lists, this range extends as integers from 20,001 to 25,000. More precisely, any number n for which 20,000 < n ≤ 25,000 can be used.

Threshold

The D'Hondt method reduces political fragmentation through allocating more seats to larger parties, this effect is strongest for small electoral district sizes. An additional approach to reduce political fragmentation are electoral thresholds, where any list which does not achieve that threshold will not have any seats allocated to it (wasted vote), even if it received enough votes to have otherwise been rewarded with a seat. Examples of countries using the D'Hondt method with a threshold are Albania (3% for single parties, 5% for coalitions of two or more parties, 1% for independent individuals); Denmark (2%); East Timor, Spain, Serbia, and Montenegro (3%); Israel (3.25%); Slovenia and Bulgaria (4%); Croatia, Fiji, Romania, Russia and Tanzania (5%); Turkey (7%); Poland (5%, or 8% for coalitions; but does not apply for ethnic-minority parties),[15] Hungary (5% for single party, 10% for two-party coalitions, 15% for coalitions of 3 or more parties) and Belgium (5%, on regional basis). In the Netherlands, a party must win enough votes for one strictly proportional full seat (note that this is not necessary in plain D'Hondt), which with 150 seats in the lower chamber gives an effective threshold of 0.67%. In Estonia, candidates receiving the simple quota in their electoral districts are considered elected, but in the second (district level) and third round of counting (nationwide, modified D'Hondt method) mandates are awarded only to candidate lists receiving more than the threshold of 5% of the votes nationally. The vote threshold simplifies the process of seat allocation and discourages fringe parties (those that are likely to gain very few votes) from competing in the elections. Obviously, the higher the vote threshold, the fewer the parties that will be represented in parliament.[16]

The method can cause a natural threshold.[17][18] It depends on the number of seats that are allocated with the D'Hondt method. In Finland's parliamentary elections, there is no official threshold, but the effective threshold is gaining one seat. The country is divided into districts with different numbers of representatives, so there is a natural threshold, different in each district. The largest district, Uusimaa with 33 representatives, has a natural threshold of 3%, while the smallest district, South Savo with 6 representatives, has a natural threshold of 14%.[19] This favors large parties in the small districts. In Croatia, the official threshold is 5% for parties and coalitions. However, since the country is divided into 10 voting districts with 14 elected representatives each, sometimes the threshold can be higher, depending on the number of votes of "fallen lists" (lists that do not receive at least 5%). If many votes are lost in this manner, a list that gets 5% will still get a seat, whereas if there is a small number votes for parties that do not pass the threshold, the actual ("natural") threshold is close to 7.15%. Some systems allow parties to associate their lists together into a single "cartel" in order to overcome the threshold, while some systems set a separate threshold for such cartels. Smaller parties often form pre-election coalitions to make sure they get past the election threshold creating a coalition government. In the Netherlands, cartels (lijstverbindingen) (until 2017, when they were abolished) could not be used to overcome the threshold, but they do influence the distribution of remainder seats; thus, smaller parties can use them to get a chance which is more like that of the big parties.

In French municipal and regional elections, the D'Hondt method is used to attribute a number of council seats; however, a fixed proportion of them (50% for municipal elections, 25% for regional elections) is automatically given to the list with the greatest number of votes, to ensure that it has a working majority: this is called the "majority bonus" (prime à la majorité), and only the remainder of the seats are distributed proportionally (including to the list which has already received the majority bonus). In Italian local elections a similar system is used, where the party or coalition of parties linked to the elected mayor automatically receives 60% of seats; unlike the French model though the remainder of the seats are not distributed again to the largest party.

Variations

The D'Hondt method can also be used in conjunction with a quota formula to allocate most seats, applying the D'Hondt method to allocate any remaining seats to get a result identical to that achieved by the standard D'Hondt formula. This variation is known as the Hagenbach-Bischoff System, and is the formula frequently used when a country's electoral system is referred to simply as 'D'Hondt'.

In the election of Legislative Assembly of Macau, a modified D'Hondt method is used. The formula for the quotient in this system is  .

In some cases such as the Czech regional elections, the first divisor (when the party has no seats so far, which is normally 1) was raised to favour larger parties and eliminate small ones. In the Czech case, it is set to 1.42 (approximately  , termed the Koudelka coefficient after the politician who introduced it).

The term "modified D'Hondt" has also been given to the use of the D'Hondt method in the additional member system used for the Scottish Parliament, Senedd (Welsh Parliament), and London Assembly, in which after constituency seats have been allocated to parties by first-past-the-post, D'Hondt is applied for the allocation of list seats, taking into account for each party the number of constituency seats it has won. When the seats allocated by D'hondt to a party are greater than the constituency seats that party has won, the extra seats are taken from list seats.

In 1989 and 1992, ACT Legislative Assembly elections were conducted by the Australian Electoral Commission using the "modified d'Hondt" electoral system. The electoral system consisted of the d'Hondt system, the Australian Senate system of proportional representation, and various methods for preferential voting for candidates and parties, both within and across party lines.[20] The process involves 8 stages of scrutiny. ABC elections analyst Antony Green has described the modified d'Hondt system used in the ACT as a "monster ... that few understood, even electoral officials who had to wrestle with its intricacies while spending several weeks counting the votes".[21]

Some systems allow parties to associate their lists together into a single kartel in order to overcome the threshold, while some systems set a separate threshold for cartels. In a system of proportional representation in which the country is divided in multiple electoral districts, such as Belgium the threshold to obtain one seat can be very high (5% of votes since 2003), which also favors larger parties. Therefore, some parties pool their voters in order to gain more (or any) seats.

The modified d'Hondt electoral system is similar to single transferable voting. It was used in the 1989 and 1992 Australian Capital Territory Legislative Assembly elections.

Regional D'Hondt

In most countries, seats for the national assembly are divided on a regional or even a provincial level. This means that seats are first divided between individual regions (or provinces) and are then allocated to the parties in each region separately (based on only the votes cast in the given region). The votes for parties that have not gained a seat at the regional level are thus discarded, so they do not aggregate at a national level. This means that parties which would have gained seats in a national distribution of seats may still end up with no seats as they did not gain enough votes in any region. This may also lead to skewed seat allocation at a national level, such as in Spain in 2011 where the People's Party gained an absolute majority in the Congress of Deputies with only 44% of the national vote.[1] It may also skew results for small parties with broad appeal at a national level compared to small parties with a local appeal (e.g. nationalist parties). For instance, in the 2008 Spanish general election, United Left (Spain) gained 1 seat for 969,946 votes, whereas Convergence and Union (Catalonia) gained 10 seats for 779,425 votes.

Usage by country

The D'Hondt method is used to elect the legislatures in Åland, Albania, Angola, Argentina, Armenia, Aruba, Austria, Belgium, Bolivia, Brazil, Burundi, Cambodia, Cape Verde, Chile, Colombia, Croatia, Denmark, the Dominican Republic, East Timor, Estonia, Fiji, Finland, Greenland, Guatemala, Hungary (in a mixed system), Iceland, Israel, Italy (in a mixed system), Japan, Luxembourg, Moldova, Monaco, Montenegro, Mozambique, Netherlands, Nicaragua, North Macedonia, Paraguay, Peru, Poland, Portugal, Romania, San Marino, Serbia, Slovenia, Spain, Switzerland, Turkey, Uruguay and Venezuela.

The system is used for the "top-up" seats in the Scottish Parliament, the Senedd (Welsh Parliament) and the London Assembly; in some countries for elections to the European Parliament; and was used during the 1997 constitution era to allocate party-list parliamentary seats in Thailand.[22] The system is also used in practice for the allocation between political groups of numerous posts (vice presidents, committee chairmen and vice-chairmen, delegation chairmen and vice-chairmen) in the European Parliament and for the allocation of ministers in the Northern Ireland Assembly.[23] It is also used to calculate the results in German and Austrian works council elections.[24]

Notes

  1. ^ English: /dəˈhɒnt/ də-HONT, Dutch: [tɔnt], French: [dɔ̃t]. The name D'Hondt is sometimes spelt as "d'Hondt". Notably, it is customary in the Netherlands to write such surnames with a lower-case "d" when preceded by the forename: thus Victor d'Hondt (with a small d), while the surname all by itself would be D'Hondt (with a capital D). However, in Belgium it is always capitalized, hence: Victor D'Hondt.

References

  1. ^ a b c Gallagher, Michael (1991). (PDF). Electoral Studies. 10 (1): 33–51. doi:10.1016/0261-3794(91)90004-C. Archived from the original (PDF) on 16 November 2013. Retrieved 30 January 2016.
  2. ^ a b Juraj Medzihorsky (2019). "Rethinking the D'Hondt method". Political Research Exchange. 1 (1): 1625712. doi:10.1080/2474736X.2019.1625712.
  3. ^ a b Pukelsheim, Friedrich (2007). (PDF). 4th ECPR General Conference. Archived from the original (PDF) on 7 February 2009.
  4. ^ Schuster, Karsten; Pukelsheim, Friedrich; Drton, Mathias; Draper, Norman R. (2003). (PDF). Electoral Studies. 22 (4): 651–676. doi:10.1016/S0261-3794(02)00027-6. Archived from the original (PDF) on 15 February 2016. Retrieved 2 February 2016.
  5. ^ Benoit, Kenneth (2000). (PDF). Political Analysis. 8 (4): 381–388. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.pan.a029822. Archived from the original (PDF) on 28 July 2018. Retrieved 11 February 2016.
  6. ^ Lijphart, Arend (1990). "The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws, 1945-85". The American Political Science Review. 84 (2): 481–496. doi:10.2307/1963530. JSTOR 1963530. S2CID 146438586.
  7. ^ a b Balinski, M. L.; Young, H. P. (1978). "The Jefferson method of Apportionment" (PDF). SIAM Rev. 20 (2): 278–284. doi:10.1137/1020040. S2CID 122291481.
  8. ^ Balinski, M. L.; Young, H. P. (1979). "Criteria for proportional representation" (PDF). Operations Research. 27: 80–95. doi:10.1287/opre.27.1.80.
  9. ^ Lijphart, Arend (2003), "Degrees of proportionality of proportional representation formulas", in Grofman, Bernard; Lijphart, Arend (eds.), Electoral Laws and Their Political Consequences, Agathon series on representation, vol. 1, Algora Publishing, pp. 170–179, ISBN 9780875862675. See in particular the section "Sainte-Lague", pp. 174–175.
  10. ^ "EU elections voting system explained: D'Hondt worry". UK in a changing Europe. 20 May 2019. Retrieved 6 October 2019.
  11. ^ Helen J. Wilson. "The D'Hondt Method Explained" (PDF). ucl.ac.uk. Retrieved 23 June 2023.
  12. ^ André Sainte-Laguë (1910). "La représentation Proportionnelle et la méthode des moindres carrés" (PDF). Annales Scientifiques de l'École Normale Supérieure. l'École Normale Supérieure. 27.
  13. ^ "Founders Online: Proportional Representation, [22 March] 1792".
  14. ^ Caulfield, Michael. "Apportioning Representatives in the United States Congress – Jefferson's Method of Apportionment". Mathematical Association of America. Retrieved 25 June 2017.
  15. ^ Lebeda, Tomáš (2001), "Hlavní proměnné proporčních volebních systémů" [The Main Variables of Systems of Proportional Representation] (PDF), Sociologický Ćasopis, Sociologický časopis, 37 (4): 442, ISSN 0038-0288
  16. ^ King, Charles. "Electoral Systems". Prof. King’s Teaching and Learning Resources. Retrieved 5 May 2018.
  17. ^ Venice Commission (2008). Comparative report on thresholds and other features of electoral systems which bar parties from access to parliament (Report). Council of Europe. Retrieved 14 February 2016.
  18. ^ Gallagher, Michael; Mitchell, Paul (2005). (PDF). The Politics of Electoral Systems. Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780199257560. Archived from the original (PDF) on 10 October 2015.
  19. ^ Oikeusministeriö. Suhteellisuuden parantaminen eduskuntavaaleissa.
  20. ^ "Modified d'Hondt Electoral System". elections.act.gov.au. 6 January 2015. Retrieved 5 May 2018.
  21. ^ Green, Antony. "Election Preview". ACT Votes 2020. Australian Broadcasting Corporation. Retrieved 16 April 2021.
  22. ^ Aurel Croissant and Daniel J. Pojar, Jr., "Quo Vadis Thailand? Thai Politics after the 2005 Parliamentary Election" April 19, 2009, at the Wayback Machine, Strategic Insights, Volume IV, Issue 6 (June 2005)
  23. ^ "D'Hondt system for picking NI ministers in Stormont". BBC News. 11 May 2011. Retrieved 7 July 2013.
  24. ^ Betriebsräten, ifb-Institut zur Fortbildung von. "D'Hondtsches Höchstzahlenverfahren". D'Hondtsches Höchstzahlenverfahren. Retrieved 28 January 2022.

External links

  • Simulator Election calculus simulator based on the modified D'Hondt system
  • Calculations using the pure d'Hondt method
  • PHP Implementation of D'Hondt system
  • Java D'Hondt, Saint-Lague and Hare-Niemeyer calculator
  • SciencesPo, R package for performing seats allocation based on the D'Hondt system
  • Downloadable Excel calculator for the D'Hondt method


hondt, method, also, called, jefferson, method, greatest, divisors, method, apportionment, method, allocating, seats, parliaments, among, federal, states, proportional, representation, among, political, parties, belongs, class, highest, averages, methods, meth. The D Hondt method a also called the Jefferson method or the greatest divisors method is an apportionment method for allocating seats in parliaments among federal states or in proportional representation among political parties It belongs to the class of highest averages methods The method was first described in 1792 by future U S president Thomas Jefferson It was re invented independently in 1878 by Belgian mathematician Victor D Hondt which is the reason for its two different names Contents 1 Motivation 2 Procedure 3 Example 3 1 Further examples 4 Approximate proportionality under D Hondt 5 Jefferson and D Hondt 6 Threshold 7 Variations 7 1 Regional D Hondt 8 Usage by country 9 Notes 10 References 11 External linksMotivation EditProportional representation systems aim to allocate seats to parties approximately in proportion to the number of votes received For example if a party wins one third of the votes then it should gain about one third of the seats In general exact proportionality is not possible because these divisions produce fractional numbers of seats As a result several methods of which the D Hondt method is one have been devised which ensure that the parties seat allocations which are of whole numbers are as proportional as possible 1 Although all of these methods approximate proportionality they do so by minimizing different kinds of disproportionality The D Hondt method minimizes the largest seats to votes ratio 2 Empirical studies based on other more popular concepts of disproportionality show that the D Hondt method is one of the least proportional among the proportional representation methods The D Hondt favours large parties and coalitions over small parties due to strategic voting 3 4 5 6 In comparison the Sainte Lague method reduces the disproportional bias towards large parties and it generally has a more equal seats to votes ratio for different sized parties 3 The axiomatic properties of the D Hondt method were studied and they proved that the D Hondt method is a consistent and monotone method that reduces political fragmentation by encouraging coalitions 7 8 A method is consistent if it treats parties that received tied votes equally By monotonicity the number of seats provided to any state or party will not decrease if the house size increases Procedure EditAfter all the votes have been tallied successive quotients are calculated for each party The party with the largest quotient wins one seat and its quotient is recalculated This is repeated until the required number of seats is filled The formula for the quotient is 9 1 quot V s 1 displaystyle text quot frac V s 1 where V is the total number of votes that party received and s is the number of seats that party has been allocated so far initially 0 for all parties The total votes cast for each party in the electoral district is divided first by 1 then by 2 then 3 up to the total number of seats to be allocated for the district constituency Say there are p parties and s seats Then a grid of numbers can be created with p rows and s columns where the entry in the i th row and j th column is the number of votes won by the i th party divided by j The s winning entries are the s highest numbers in the whole grid each party is given as many seats as there are winning entries in its row Example EditIn this example 230 000 voters decide the disposition of 8 seats among 4 parties Since 8 seats are to be allocated each party s total votes are divided by 1 then by 2 3 and 4 and then if necessary by 5 6 7 and so on The 8 highest entries marked with asterisks range from 100 000 down to 25 000 For each the corresponding party gets a seat Note that in Round 1 the quotient shown in the table as derived from the formula is precisely the number of votes returned in the ballot Round 1 seat per round 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Seats won bold Party A quotient seats after round 100 0001 50 0001 50 0002 33 3332 33 3333 25 0003 25 0003 25 0004 4Party B quotient seats after round 80 0000 80 0001 40 0001 40 0002 26 6672 26 6672 26 6673 20 0003 3Party C quotient seats after round 30 0000 30 0000 30 0000 30 0000 30 0000 30 0001 15 0001 15 0001 1Party D quotient seats after round 20 0000 20 0000 20 0000 20 0000 20 0000 20 0000 20 0000 20 0000 0While in this example parties B C and D formed a coalition against Party A You can see that Party A received 3 seats instead of 4 due to the coalition having 30 000 more votes than Party A Round 1 seat per round 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Seats won bold Party A quotient seats after round 100 0000 100 0001 50 0001 50 0002 33 3332 33 3333 25 0003 25 0003 3Coalition B C D quotient seats after round 130 0001 65 0001 65 0002 43 3332 43 3333 32 5003 32 5004 26 0005 5The chart below shows an easy way to perform the calculation Each party s vote is divided by 1 2 3 or 4 in consecutive columns then the 8 highest values resulting are selected The quantity of highest values in each row is the number of seats won For comparison the True proportion column shows the exact fractional numbers of seats due calculated in proportion to the number of votes received For example 100 000 230 000 8 3 48 The slight favouring of the largest party over the smallest is apparent Denominator 1 2 3 4 Seatswon True proportionParty A 100 000 50 000 33 333 25 000 4 3 5Party B 80 000 40 000 26 667 20 000 3 2 8Party C 30 000 15 000 10 000 7 500 1 1 0Party D 20 000 10 000 6 667 5 000 0 0 7Total 8 8Further examples Edit A worked through example for non experts relating to the 2019 elections in the UK for the European Parliament written by Christina Pagel is available as an online article with the institute UK in a Changing Europe 10 A more mathematically detailed example has been written by British mathematician Professor Helen Wilson 11 Approximate proportionality under D Hondt EditThe D Hondt method approximates proportionality by minimizing the largest seats to votes ratio among all parties 12 This ratio is also known as the advantage ratio In contrast the average seats to votes ratio is optimized by the Webster Sainte Lague method For party p 1 P displaystyle p in 1 dots P where P displaystyle P is the overall number of parties the advantage ratio isa p s p v p displaystyle a p frac s p v p where s p displaystyle s p the seat share of party p displaystyle p s p 0 1 p s p 1 displaystyle s p in 0 1 sum p s p 1 v p displaystyle v p the vote share of party p displaystyle p v p 0 1 p v p 1 displaystyle v p in 0 1 sum p v p 1 The largest advantage ratio d max p a p displaystyle delta max p a p captures how over represented is the most over represented party The D Hondt method assigns seats so that this ratio attains its smallest possible value d min s S max p a p displaystyle delta min mathbf s in mathcal S max p a p where s s 1 s P displaystyle mathbf s s 1 dots s P is a seat allocation from the set of all allowed seat allocations S displaystyle mathcal S Thanks to this as shown by Juraj Medzihorsky 2 the D Hondt method splits the votes into exactly proportionally represented ones and residual ones The overall fraction of residual votes isp 1 1 d displaystyle pi 1 frac 1 delta The residuals of party p arer p v p 1 p s p r p 0 v p p r p p displaystyle r p v p 1 pi s p r p in 0 v p sum p r p pi For illustration continue with the above example of four parties The advantage ratios of the four parties are 1 2 for A 1 1 for B 1 for C and 0 for D The reciprocal of the largest advantage ratio is 1 1 15 0 87 1 p The residuals as shares of the total vote are 0 for A 2 2 for B 2 2 for C and 8 7 for party D Their sum is 13 i e 1 0 87 0 13 The decomposition of the votes into represented and residual ones is shown in the table below Allocation of eight seats under the D Hondt method Party Voteshare Seatshare Advantageratio Residualvotes RepresentedvotesA 43 5 50 0 1 15 0 0 43 5 B 34 8 37 5 1 08 2 2 32 6 C 13 0 12 5 0 96 2 2 10 9 D 8 7 0 0 0 00 8 7 0 0 Total 100 100 13 87 Jefferson and D Hondt EditThe method was first described in 1792 by Thomas Jefferson in a letter to George Washington regarding the apportionment of seats in the United States House of Representatives 7 For representatives there can be no such common ratio or divisor which will divide them exactly without a remainder or fraction I answer then that representatives must be divided as nearly as the nearest ratio will admit and the fractions must be neglected It was invented independently in 1878 in Europe by Belgian mathematician Victor D Hondt who wrote to allocate discrete entities proportionally among several numbers it is necessary to divide these numbers by a common divisor producing quotients whose sum is equal to the number of entities to be allocated The Jefferson and the D Hondt methods are equivalent They always give the same results but the methods of presenting the calculation are different George Washington exercised his first veto power on a bill that introduced a new plan for dividing seats in the House of Representatives that would have increased the number of seats for northern states 13 Ten days after the veto Congress passed a new method of apportionment now known as Jefferson s Method Statesman and future US President Thomas Jefferson devised the method in 1792 for the U S congressional apportionment pursuant to the First United States Census It was used to achieve the proportional distribution of seats in the House of Representatives among the states until 1842 14 Victor D Hondt presented his method in his publication Systeme pratique et raisonne de representation proportionnelle published in Brussels in 1882 The system can be used both for distributing seats in a legislature among states pursuant to populations or among parties pursuant to an election result The tasks are mathematically equivalent putting states in the place of parties and population in place of votes In some countries the Jefferson system is known by the names of local politicians or experts who introduced them locally For example it is known in Israel as the Bader Ofer system Jefferson s method uses a quota called a divisor as in the largest remainder method The divisor is chosen as necessary so that the resulting quotients disregarding any fractional remainders sum to the required total in other words pick a number so that there is no need to examine the remainders Any number in one range of quotas will accomplish this with the highest number in the range always being the same as the lowest number used by the D Hondt method to award a seat if it is used rather than the Jefferson method and the lowest number in the range being the smallest number larger than the next number which would award a seat in the D Hondt calculations Applied to the above example of party lists this range extends as integers from 20 001 to 25 000 More precisely any number n for which 20 000 lt n 25 000 can be used Threshold EditThe D Hondt method reduces political fragmentation through allocating more seats to larger parties this effect is strongest for small electoral district sizes An additional approach to reduce political fragmentation are electoral thresholds where any list which does not achieve that threshold will not have any seats allocated to it wasted vote even if it received enough votes to have otherwise been rewarded with a seat Examples of countries using the D Hondt method with a threshold are Albania 3 for single parties 5 for coalitions of two or more parties 1 for independent individuals Denmark 2 East Timor Spain Serbia and Montenegro 3 Israel 3 25 Slovenia and Bulgaria 4 Croatia Fiji Romania Russia and Tanzania 5 Turkey 7 Poland 5 or 8 for coalitions but does not apply for ethnic minority parties 15 Hungary 5 for single party 10 for two party coalitions 15 for coalitions of 3 or more parties and Belgium 5 on regional basis In the Netherlands a party must win enough votes for one strictly proportional full seat note that this is not necessary in plain D Hondt which with 150 seats in the lower chamber gives an effective threshold of 0 67 In Estonia candidates receiving the simple quota in their electoral districts are considered elected but in the second district level and third round of counting nationwide modified D Hondt method mandates are awarded only to candidate lists receiving more than the threshold of 5 of the votes nationally The vote threshold simplifies the process of seat allocation and discourages fringe parties those that are likely to gain very few votes from competing in the elections Obviously the higher the vote threshold the fewer the parties that will be represented in parliament 16 The method can cause a natural threshold 17 18 It depends on the number of seats that are allocated with the D Hondt method In Finland s parliamentary elections there is no official threshold but the effective threshold is gaining one seat The country is divided into districts with different numbers of representatives so there is a natural threshold different in each district The largest district Uusimaa with 33 representatives has a natural threshold of 3 while the smallest district South Savo with 6 representatives has a natural threshold of 14 19 This favors large parties in the small districts In Croatia the official threshold is 5 for parties and coalitions However since the country is divided into 10 voting districts with 14 elected representatives each sometimes the threshold can be higher depending on the number of votes of fallen lists lists that do not receive at least 5 If many votes are lost in this manner a list that gets 5 will still get a seat whereas if there is a small number votes for parties that do not pass the threshold the actual natural threshold is close to 7 15 Some systems allow parties to associate their lists together into a single cartel in order to overcome the threshold while some systems set a separate threshold for such cartels Smaller parties often form pre election coalitions to make sure they get past the election threshold creating a coalition government In the Netherlands cartels lijstverbindingen until 2017 when they were abolished could not be used to overcome the threshold but they do influence the distribution of remainder seats thus smaller parties can use them to get a chance which is more like that of the big parties In French municipal and regional elections the D Hondt method is used to attribute a number of council seats however a fixed proportion of them 50 for municipal elections 25 for regional elections is automatically given to the list with the greatest number of votes to ensure that it has a working majority this is called the majority bonus prime a la majorite and only the remainder of the seats are distributed proportionally including to the list which has already received the majority bonus In Italian local elections a similar system is used where the party or coalition of parties linked to the elected mayor automatically receives 60 of seats unlike the French model though the remainder of the seats are not distributed again to the largest party Variations EditThe D Hondt method can also be used in conjunction with a quota formula to allocate most seats applying the D Hondt method to allocate any remaining seats to get a result identical to that achieved by the standard D Hondt formula This variation is known as the Hagenbach Bischoff System and is the formula frequently used when a country s electoral system is referred to simply as D Hondt In the election of Legislative Assembly of Macau a modified D Hondt method is used The formula for the quotient in this system is V 2 s displaystyle textstyle frac V 2 s In some cases such as the Czech regional elections the first divisor when the party has no seats so far which is normally 1 was raised to favour larger parties and eliminate small ones In the Czech case it is set to 1 42 approximately 2 displaystyle sqrt 2 termed the Koudelka coefficient after the politician who introduced it The term modified D Hondt has also been given to the use of the D Hondt method in the additional member system used for the Scottish Parliament Senedd Welsh Parliament and London Assembly in which after constituency seats have been allocated to parties by first past the post D Hondt is applied for the allocation of list seats taking into account for each party the number of constituency seats it has won When the seats allocated by D hondt to a party are greater than the constituency seats that party has won the extra seats are taken from list seats In 1989 and 1992 ACT Legislative Assembly elections were conducted by the Australian Electoral Commission using the modified d Hondt electoral system The electoral system consisted of the d Hondt system the Australian Senate system of proportional representation and various methods for preferential voting for candidates and parties both within and across party lines 20 The process involves 8 stages of scrutiny ABC elections analyst Antony Green has described the modified d Hondt system used in the ACT as a monster that few understood even electoral officials who had to wrestle with its intricacies while spending several weeks counting the votes 21 Some systems allow parties to associate their lists together into a single kartel in order to overcome the threshold while some systems set a separate threshold for cartels In a system of proportional representation in which the country is divided in multiple electoral districts such as Belgium the threshold to obtain one seat can be very high 5 of votes since 2003 which also favors larger parties Therefore some parties pool their voters in order to gain more or any seats The modified d Hondt electoral system is similar to single transferable voting It was used in the 1989 and 1992 Australian Capital Territory Legislative Assembly elections Regional D Hondt Edit In most countries seats for the national assembly are divided on a regional or even a provincial level This means that seats are first divided between individual regions or provinces and are then allocated to the parties in each region separately based on only the votes cast in the given region The votes for parties that have not gained a seat at the regional level are thus discarded so they do not aggregate at a national level This means that parties which would have gained seats in a national distribution of seats may still end up with no seats as they did not gain enough votes in any region This may also lead to skewed seat allocation at a national level such as in Spain in 2011 where the People s Party gained an absolute majority in the Congress of Deputies with only 44 of the national vote 1 It may also skew results for small parties with broad appeal at a national level compared to small parties with a local appeal e g nationalist parties For instance in the 2008 Spanish general election United Left Spain gained 1 seat for 969 946 votes whereas Convergence and Union Catalonia gained 10 seats for 779 425 votes Usage by country EditThe D Hondt method is used to elect the legislatures in Aland Albania Angola Argentina Armenia Aruba Austria Belgium Bolivia Brazil Burundi Cambodia Cape Verde Chile Colombia Croatia Denmark the Dominican Republic East Timor Estonia Fiji Finland Greenland Guatemala Hungary in a mixed system Iceland Israel Italy in a mixed system Japan Luxembourg Moldova Monaco Montenegro Mozambique Netherlands Nicaragua North Macedonia Paraguay Peru Poland Portugal Romania San Marino Serbia Slovenia Spain Switzerland Turkey Uruguay and Venezuela The system is used for the top up seats in the Scottish Parliament the Senedd Welsh Parliament and the London Assembly in some countries for elections to the European Parliament and was used during the 1997 constitution era to allocate party list parliamentary seats in Thailand 22 The system is also used in practice for the allocation between political groups of numerous posts vice presidents committee chairmen and vice chairmen delegation chairmen and vice chairmen in the European Parliament and for the allocation of ministers in the Northern Ireland Assembly 23 It is also used to calculate the results in German and Austrian works council elections 24 Notes Edit English d e ˈ h ɒ n t de HONT Dutch tɔnt French dɔ t The name D Hondt is sometimes spelt as d Hondt Notably it is customary in the Netherlands to write such surnames with a lower case d when preceded by the forename thus Victor d Hondt with a small d while the surname all by itself would be D Hondt with a capital D However in Belgium it is always capitalized hence Victor D Hondt References Edit a b c Gallagher Michael 1991 Proportionality disproportionality and electoral systems PDF Electoral Studies 10 1 33 51 doi 10 1016 0261 3794 91 90004 C Archived from the original PDF on 16 November 2013 Retrieved 30 January 2016 a b Juraj Medzihorsky 2019 Rethinking the D Hondt method Political Research Exchange 1 1 1625712 doi 10 1080 2474736X 2019 1625712 a b Pukelsheim Friedrich 2007 Seat bias formulas in proportional representation systems PDF 4th ECPR General Conference Archived from the original PDF on 7 February 2009 Schuster Karsten Pukelsheim Friedrich Drton Mathias Draper Norman R 2003 Seat biases of apportionment methods for proportional representation PDF Electoral Studies 22 4 651 676 doi 10 1016 S0261 3794 02 00027 6 Archived from the original PDF on 15 February 2016 Retrieved 2 February 2016 Benoit Kenneth 2000 Which Electoral Formula Is the Most Proportional A New Look with New Evidence PDF Political Analysis 8 4 381 388 doi 10 1093 oxfordjournals pan a029822 Archived from the original PDF on 28 July 2018 Retrieved 11 February 2016 Lijphart Arend 1990 The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws 1945 85 The American Political Science Review 84 2 481 496 doi 10 2307 1963530 JSTOR 1963530 S2CID 146438586 a b Balinski M L Young H P 1978 The Jefferson method of Apportionment PDF SIAM Rev 20 2 278 284 doi 10 1137 1020040 S2CID 122291481 Balinski M L Young H P 1979 Criteria for proportional representation PDF Operations Research 27 80 95 doi 10 1287 opre 27 1 80 Lijphart Arend 2003 Degrees of proportionality of proportional representation formulas in Grofman Bernard Lijphart Arend eds Electoral Laws and Their Political Consequences Agathon series on representation vol 1 Algora Publishing pp 170 179 ISBN 9780875862675 See in particular the section Sainte Lague pp 174 175 EU elections voting system explained D Hondt worry UK in a changing Europe 20 May 2019 Retrieved 6 October 2019 Helen J Wilson The D Hondt Method Explained PDF ucl ac uk Retrieved 23 June 2023 Andre Sainte Lague 1910 La representation Proportionnelle et la methode des moindres carres PDF Annales Scientifiques de l Ecole Normale Superieure l Ecole Normale Superieure 27 Founders Online Proportional Representation 22 March 1792 Caulfield Michael Apportioning Representatives in the United States Congress Jefferson s Method of Apportionment Mathematical Association of America Retrieved 25 June 2017 Lebeda Tomas 2001 Hlavni promenne proporcnich volebnich systemu The Main Variables of Systems of Proportional Representation PDF Sociologicky Casopis Sociologicky casopis 37 4 442 ISSN 0038 0288 King Charles Electoral Systems Prof King s Teaching and Learning Resources Retrieved 5 May 2018 Venice Commission 2008 Comparative report on thresholds and other features of electoral systems which bar parties from access to parliament Report Council of Europe Retrieved 14 February 2016 Gallagher Michael Mitchell Paul 2005 Appendix C Effective threshold and effective magnitude PDF The Politics of Electoral Systems Oxford University Press ISBN 9780199257560 Archived from the original PDF on 10 October 2015 Oikeusministerio Suhteellisuuden parantaminen eduskuntavaaleissa Modified d Hondt Electoral System elections act gov au 6 January 2015 Retrieved 5 May 2018 Green Antony Election Preview ACT Votes 2020 Australian Broadcasting Corporation Retrieved 16 April 2021 Aurel Croissant and Daniel J Pojar Jr Quo Vadis Thailand Thai Politics after the 2005 Parliamentary Election Archived April 19 2009 at the Wayback Machine Strategic Insights Volume IV Issue 6 June 2005 D Hondt system for picking NI ministers in Stormont BBC News 11 May 2011 Retrieved 7 July 2013 Betriebsraten ifb Institut zur Fortbildung von D Hondtsches Hochstzahlenverfahren D Hondtsches Hochstzahlenverfahren Retrieved 28 January 2022 External links EditSimulator Election calculus simulator based on the modified D Hondt system Calculations using the pure d Hondt method PHP Implementation of D Hondt system Java D Hondt Saint Lague and Hare Niemeyer calculator SciencesPo R package for performing seats allocation based on the D Hondt system Downloadable Excel calculator for the D Hondt method Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title D 27Hondt method amp oldid 1169433954, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.