fbpx
Wikipedia

History of Islamic economics

Between the 9th and 14th centuries, the Muslim world developed many advanced economic concepts, techniques and usages. These ranged from areas of production, investment, finance, economic development, taxation, property use such as Hawala: an early informal value transfer system, Islamic trusts, known as waqf, systems of contract relied upon by merchants, a widely circulated common currency, cheques, promissory notes, early contracts, bills of exchange, and forms of commercial partnership such as mufawada.

Specific Islamic concepts involving money, property, taxation, charity and the Five Pillars include:

  • zakat (the "taxing of certain goods, such as harvest, to allocate these taxes to expand that, are also explicitly defined, such as aid to the needy");
  • Gharar ("the interdiction of chance ... that is, of the presence of any element of uncertainty, in a contract (which excludes not only insurance but also the lending of money without participation in the risks); and
  • riba ("every kind of excess or unjustified disparity between the exchanged objects or counter values"[1]).

These concepts, like others in Islamic law and jurisprudence, came from the "prescriptions, anecdotes, examples, and words of the Prophet, all gathered together and systematized by commentators according to an inductive, casuistic method."[2] Sometimes other sources such as al-urf, (the custom), al-'aql (reason) or al-ijma (consensus of the jurists) were employed.[3] In addition, Islamic law has developed areas of law that correspond to secular laws of contracts and torts.

Contemporary Islamic scholars draw heavily on classical opinions.[4] Modern Islamic economics emerged in the 1945s, and as of 2004 Islamic Banks have been established in over 8 countries, and interest has been banned in three: Pakistan, Iran and the Sudan.[5]

Legal institutions edit

Hawala agency edit

The Hawala, an early informal value transfer system, has its origins in classical Islamic law, and is mentioned in texts of Islamic jurisprudence as early as the 8th century. Hawala itself later influenced the development of the agency in common law and in civil laws such as the aval in French law and the Cavallo in Italian law. The words aval and Cavallo were themselves derived from Hawala. The transfer of debt, which was "not permissible under Roman law but became widely practiced in medieval Europe, especially in commercial transactions", was due to the large extent of the "trade conducted by the Italian cities with the Muslim world in the Middle Ages." The agency was also "an institution unknown to Roman law" as no "individual could conclude a binding contract on behalf of another as his agent." In Roman law, the "contractor himself was considered the party to the contract and it took a second contract between the person who acted on behalf of a principal and the latter to transfer the rights and the obligations deriving from the contract to him." On the other hand, Islamic law and the later common law "had no difficulty in accepting agency as one of its institutions in the field of contracts and obligations in general."[6]

Waqf trust edit

The waqf in Islamic law, which developed in the medieval Islamic world from the 7th to 9th centuries, bears a notable resemblance to the English trust law.[7] Every waqf was required to have a waqif (founder), mutawillis (trustee), qadi (judge) and beneficiaries.[8] Under both a waqf and a trust, "property is reserved, and its usufruct appropriated, for the benefit of specific individuals, or for a general charitable purpose; the corpus becomes inalienable; estates for life in favor of successive beneficiaries can be created" and "without regard to the law of inheritance or the rights of the heirs; and continuity is secured by the successive appointment of trustees or mutawillis."[9]

The only significant distinction between the Islamic waqf and English trust was "the express or implied reversion of the waqf to charitable purposes when its specific object has ceased to exist",[10] though this difference only applied to the waqf ahli (Islamic family trust) rather than the waqf khairi (devoted to a charitable purpose from its inception). Another difference was the English vesting of "legal estate" over the trust property in the trustee, though the "trustee was still bound to administer that property for the benefit of the beneficiaries." In this sense, the "role of the English trustee, therefore, does not differ significantly from that of the mutually."[11]

The trust law developed in England at the time of the Crusades, during the 12th and 13th centuries was introduced by Crusaders who may have been influenced by the waqf institutions they came across in the Middle East.[12][13]

After the Islamic waqf law and madrassah foundations were firmly established by the 10th century, the number of Bimaristan hospitals multiplied throughout Islamic lands. In the 11th century, every Islamic city had at least several hospitals. The waqf trust institutions funded the hospitals for various expenses, including the wages of doctors, ophthalmologists, surgeons, chemists, pharmacists, domestics and all other staff, the purchase of foods and drugs; hospital equipment such as beds, mattresses, bowls and perfumes; and repairs to buildings. The waqf trusts also funded medical schools, and their revenues covered various expenses such as their maintenance and the payment of teachers and students.[14]

Classical Muslim commerce edit

The systems of contract relied upon by merchants was very effective. Merchants would buy and sell on commission, with money loaned to them by wealthy investors, or a joint investment of several merchants, who were often Muslim, Christian and Jewish. Recently, a collection of documents was found in an Egyptian synagogue shedding a very detailed and human light on the life of medieval Middle Eastern merchants. Business partnerships would be made for many commercial ventures, and bonds of kinship enabled trade networks to form over huge distances. During the ninth century banks enabled the drawing of check-in by a bank in Baghdad that could be cashed in Morocco.[15]

The concepts of welfare and pension[better source needed] were introduced in early Islamic law as forms of Zakat (charity), one of the Five Pillars of Islam, since the time of the Abbasid caliph Al-Mansur in the 8th century. The taxes (including Zakat and Jizya) collected in the treasury of an Islamic government was used to provide income for the needy, including the poor, elderly, orphans, widows, and the disabled. According to the Islamic jurist Al-Ghazali (Algazel, 1058–1111), the government was also expected to store up food supplies in every region in case of a disaster or famine occurs. The Caliphate was thus one of the earliest welfare states, particularly the Abbasid Caliphate.[16]

Economy in the Caliphate and Islamic empires edit

In the medieval Arab Agricultural Revolution, a social transformation took place as a result of changing land ownership giving individuals of any gender,[17] the right to buy, sell, mortgage and inherit land.

Early forms of proto-capitalism and free markets were present in the Caliphate.[18] An early market economy and early form of merchant capitalism developed between the 8th and 12th centuries.[19] A vigorous monetary economy developed based on the wide circulation of a common currency (the dinar) and the integration of previously independent monetary areas. Business techniques and forms of business organization employed during this time included early contracts, bills of exchange, long-distance international trade, early forms of partnership (mufawada) such as limited partnerships (mudaraba), and early forms of credit, debt, profit, loss, capital (al-mal), capital accumulation (nama al-mal),[20] circulating capital, capital expenditure, revenue, cheques, promissory notes,[21] trusts (waqf), savings accounts, transactional accounts, pawning, loaning, exchange rates, bankers, money changers, ledgers, deposits, assignments, the double-entry bookkeeping system,[22] and lawsuits.[23] Organizational enterprises similar to corporations independent from the state also existed in the medieval Islamic world.[24][25] Many of these concepts were adopted and further advanced in medieval Europe from the 13th century onwards.[20]

Islamic India edit

During the Muslim rule in India, realms such as the Delhi Sultanate, Bengal Sultanate, Mughal Empire,Nizam of Hyderabad and the Kingdom of Mysore made significant contributions to the South Asian economy. In the 17th century Mughal India became the world's largest economy[26][27][28] ,becoming the leading textile manufacturing power in the world, valued over 25% of world GDP.

The concepts of welfare and pension were present in early Islamic law as forms of zakat one of the Five Pillars of Islam, since the time of the Rashidun caliph Umar in the 7th century. The taxes (including zakat and jizya) collected in the treasury (bayt al-mal) of an Islamic government were used to provide income for the needy, including the poor, the elderly, orphans, widows, and the disabled. According to the Islamic jurist Al-Ghazali (Algazel, 1058–1111), the government was also expected to stockpile food supplies in every region in case of disaster or famine. The Caliphate was thus one of the earliest welfare states.[16][29]

Trade edit

During the Islamic Golden Age, isolated regions had contact with a far-reaching Muslim trade network extending from the Atlantic Ocean and the Mediterranean in the west to the Indian Ocean and South China Sea in the east, and covering most of the Old World,[30] including significant areas of Asia and Africa and much of Europe, with their trade networks.[31] Arabic silver dirham coins were being circulated throughout the Afro-Eurasian landmass, as far as sub-Saharan Africa in the south and northern Europe in the north, often in exchange for goods and slaves.[32]

This helped establish the Rashidun, Umayyad, Abbasid, Ayyubid and Fatimid Caliphates as the world's leading extensive economic powers in the 7th-13th centuries.[30]

Due to religious sanctions against debt, Tamil Muslims have historically been money changers (not money lenders) throughout South and South East Asia.[33]

Agriculture in the medieval Islamic world edit

From the 8th century to the 13th century in Muslim lands many crops and plants were planted along Muslim trade routes, farming techniques spread. In addition to changes in economy, population distribution, vegetation cover,[34] agricultural production, population levels, urban growth, the distribution of the labor force, and numerous other aspects of life in the Islamic world were affected according to Andrew Watson.[35] However this is disputed by other scholars, who claim cultivation and consumption of staples such as durum wheat, Asiatic rice, and sorghum, as well as cotton, were already commonplace centuries before,[36] or that agricultural production declined in areas brought under Muslim rule in the Middle Ages.[37]

The early Abbasid Caliphate also had the highest literacy rates among pre-modern societies, alongside the city of classical Athens in the 4th century BC,[38] and later, China after the introduction of printing from the 10th century.[39] One factor for the relatively high literacy rates in the early Islamic Empire[which?] was its parent-driven educational marketplace, as the state did not systematically subsidize educational services until the introduction of state funding under Nizam al-Mulk in the 11th century.[40] Another factor was the diffusion of paper from China,[41] which led to an efflorescence of books and written culture in Islamic society, thus papermaking technology transformed Islamic society (and later, the rest of Afro-Eurasia) from an oral to scribal culture, comparable to the later shifts from scribal to typographic culture, and from typographic culture to the Internet.[42] Other factors include the widespread use of paper books in Islamic society (more so than any other previously existing society), the study and memorization of the Qur' an, flourishing commercial activity, and the emergence of the Maktab and Madrasah educational institutions.[43]

Islamic capitalism edit

Early forms of mercantilism and capitalism are thought to have developed in the Islamic Golden Age from the 9th century.[20][31][44]

Early Islamic commerce applied a number of concepts and techniques, including bills of exchange, forms of partnership (mufawada) such as limited partnerships (mudaraba), and early forms of capital (al-mal), capital accumulation (nama al-mal),[20] cheques, promissory notes,[21] trusts (see waqf), transactional accounts, loans, ledgers and assignments.[22] Organizational enterprises independent of the state also existed in the medieval Islamic world, while the agency institution was also introduced.[24][25] Medieval Europe adopted and developed many of these concepts from the 13th century onwards.[20]

A market economy was established[by whom?] in the Islamic world on the basis of an economic system resembling merchant capitalism. Labour promoted capital formation in medieval Islamic society, and a considerable number of owners of monetary funds and precious metals developed financial capital. The capitalists (sahib al-mal) stood at the height of their power between the 9th and 12th centuries, but their influence declined after the arrival of the ikta (landowners) and after the state[which?] monopolized production; both these trends hampered any development of industrial capitalism in the Islamic world.[44] Some state enterprises still had a capitalist mode of production, such as pearl diving in Iraq and the textile industry in Egypt.[45]

From the 11th to the 13th centuries, the "Karimis", an enterprise and business group controlled by entrepreneurs, came to dominate much of the Islamic world's economy.[46] The group was controlled by about fifty Muslim merchants labeled as "Karimis", who were of Yemeni, Egyptian and sometimes Indian origin.[47] Each Karimi merchant had considerable wealth, ranging from at least 100,000 dinars to as much as 10 million dinars. The group had considerable influence in most important eastern markets, and sometimes influenced politics through its financing activities and through a variety of customers, including Emirs, Sultans, Viziers, foreign merchants, and common consumers. The Karimis dominated many of the trade routes across the Mediterranean, the Red Sea, and the Indian Ocean, and as far as Francia in the north, China in the east, and sub-Saharan Africa in the south, where they obtained gold from gold mines. Practices employed by the Karimis included the use of agents, the financing of projects as a method of acquiring capital, and a banking institution for loans and deposits.

Islamic socialism edit

Though medieval Islamic economics appears to have somewhat resembled a form of capitalism, some arguing that it laid the foundations for the development of modern capitalism,[48][49] Others see Islamic economics as neither completely capitalistic nor completely socialistic, but rather a balance between the two, emphasizing both "individual economic freedom and the need to serve the common good."[29]

Abū Dharr al-Ghifārī, a Companion of Muḥammad, is credited by many as the founder of Islamic socialism.[50][51][52][53][54]

The concepts of welfare and pension were introduced in early Islamic law as forms of Zakat (charity), one of the Five Pillars of Islam, during the time of the Rashidun caliph Umar in the 7th century. This practiced continued well into the era of the Abbasid Caliphate, as seen under Al-Ma'mun's rule in the 8th century, for example. The taxes (including Zakat and Jizya) collected in the treasury of an Islamic government were used to provide income for the needy, including the poor, elderly, orphans, widows, and the disabled. According to the Islamic jurist Al-Ghazali (Algazel, 1058–1111), the government was also expected to stockpile food supplies in every region in case a disaster or famine occurred. The Caliphate is thus considered the world's first major welfare state.[16][29]

Industrial development edit

Muslim engineers in the Islamic world were responsible for numerous innovative industrial uses of hydropower, early industrial uses of tide mills, wind power, and fossil fuels such as petroleum. A variety of industrial mills were used in the Islamic world, including fulling mills, gristmills, hullers, sawmills, shipmills, stamp mills, steel mills, sugar mills, tide mills, and windmills. By the 11th century, every province throughout the Islamic world had these industrial mills in operation, from al-Andalus and North Africa to the Middle East and Central Asia.[55] Muslim engineers also employed water turbines, and gears in mills and water-raising machines, and pioneered the use of dams as a source of water power, used to provide additional power to watermills and water-raising machines.[56] Such advances made it possible for many industrial tasks that were previously driven by manual labour in ancient times to be mechanized and driven by machinery instead in the medieval Islamic world. The transfer of these technologies to medieval Europe later laid the foundations for the Industrial Revolution in 18th century Europe.[55]

In addition to government-owned tiraz textile factories, there were also privately owned enterprises[when?] run largely by landlords who collected taxes and invested them in the textile industry.[57]

Labour force edit

The labor force in the Caliphate were employed from diverse ethnic and religious backgrounds, while both men and women were involved in diverse occupations and economic activities.[58] Women were employed in a wide range of commercial activities and diverse occupations[59] in the primary sector (as farmers for example), secondary sector (as construction workers, dyers, spinners, etc.) and tertiary sector (as investors, doctors, nurses, presidents of guilds, brokers, peddlers, lenders, scholars, etc.).[60]

Muslim women also held a monopoly over certain branches of the textile industry,[59][additional citation(s) needed] the largest and most specialized and market-oriented industry at the time, in occupations such as spinning, dyeing, and embroidery. In comparison, female property rights and wage labour were relatively uncommon in Europe until the Industrial Revolution in the 18th and 19th centuries.[61]

The division of labour was diverse and had been evolving over the centuries. During the 8th–11th centuries, there were on average 63 unique occupations in the primary sector of economic activity (extractive), 697 unique occupations in the secondary sector (manufacturing), and 736 unique occupations in the tertiary sector (service). By the 12th century, the number of unique occupations in the primary sector and secondary sector decreased to 35 and 679 respectively, while the number of unique occupations in the tertiary sector increased to 1,175. These changes in the division of labour reflect the increased mechanization and use of machinery to replace manual labour and the increased standard of living and quality of life of most citizens in the Caliphate.[62]

An economic transition occurred during this period, due to the diversity of the service sector being far greater than any other previous or contemporary society, and the high degree of economic integration between the labour force and the economy. Islamic society also experienced a change in attitude towards manual labour. In previous civilizations such as ancient Greece and in contemporary civilizations such as early medieval Europe, intellectuals saw manual labour in a negative light and looked down on them with contempt.[additional citation(s) needed] This resulted in technological stagnation as they did not see the need for machinery to replace manual labour.[additional citation(s) needed] In the Islamic world, however, manual labour was seen in a far more positive light, as intellectuals such as the Brethren of Purity likened them to a participant in the act of creation, while Ibn Khaldun alluded to the benefits of manual labour to the progress of society.[59]

By the early 10th century, the idea of the academic degree was introduced and being granted at Maktab schools, Madrasah colleges and Bimaristan hospitals. In the medical field in particular, the Ijazah certificate was granted to those qualified to be practicing physicians, in order to differentiate them from unqualified quacks.[63]

Urbanization edit

There was a significant increase in urbanization during this period, due to numerous scientific advances in fields such as agriculture, hygiene, sanitation, astronomy, medicine and engineering.[64] This also resulted in a rising middle class population.

The head of the family was given the position of authority in his household,[citation needed] although a qadi, or judge was able to negotiate and resolve differences in issues of disagreements within families and between them. The two senior representatives of municipal authority were the qadi and the muhtasib, who held the responsibilities of many issues, including quality of water, maintenance of city streets, containing outbreaks of disease, supervising the markets, and a prompt burial of the dead.

Another aspect of Islamic urban life was waqf, a religious charity directly dealing with the qadi and religious leaders. Through donations, the waqf owned many of the public baths and factories, using the revenue to fund education,[citation needed] and to provide irrigation for orchards outside the city. Following expansion, this system was introduced into Eastern Europe by Ottoman Turks.[citation needed]

Taxes were also levied on an unmarried man until he was wed. Non-Muslims were required to pay the jizya, an administrative tax on non-Muslims analogous to zakat (a Muslim only tax). The Jizya was applied only to young able-bodied adult males and exempted non-Muslims from military service. The Muslim state would then be responsible for the administration & security of the Non-Muslims.[65]

Classical Islamic economic thought edit

To some degree, the early Muslims based their economic analyses on the Qur'an (such as opposition to riba, meaning usury or interest), and from sunnah, the sayings and doings of Muhammad.

Early Islamic economic thinkers edit

Al-Ghazali (1058–1111) classified economics as one of the sciences connected with religion, along with metaphysics, ethics, and psychology. Authors have noted, however, that this connection has not caused early Muslim economic thought to remain static.[66] Iranian philosopher Nasir al-Din al-Tusi (1201–1274) presents an early definition of economics (what he calls hekmat-e-madani, the science of city life) in discourse three of his Ethics:

"the study of universal laws governing the public interest (welfare?) in so far as they are directed, through cooperation, toward the optimal (perfection)."[67]

Many scholars trace the history of economic thought through the Muslim world, which was in a Golden Age from the 8th to 13th century and whose philosophy continued the work of the Greek and Hellenistic thinkers and came to influence Aquinas when Europe "rediscovered" Greek philosophy through Arabic translation.[68] A common theme among these scholars was the praise of economic activity and even self-interested accumulation of wealth.[69]

Persian philosopher Ibn Miskawayh (b. 1030) notes:

"The creditor desires the well-being of the debtor in order to get his money back rather than because of his love for him. The debtor, on the other hand, does not take great interest in the creditor."[69]

This view is in conflict with an idea Joseph Schumpeter called the great gap. The great gap thesis comes out of Schumpeter's 1954 History of Economic Analysis which discusses a break in economic thought during the five hundred-year period between the decline of the Greco-Roman civilizations and the work of Thomas Aquinas (1225–1274).[70] However, in 1964, Joseph Spengler's "Economic Thought of Islam: Ibn Khaldun" appeared in the journal Comparative Studies in Society and History and took a large step in bringing early Muslim scholars to the attention of the contemporary West.[71]

The influence of earlier Greek and Hellenistic thought on the Muslim world began largely with Abbasid caliph al-Ma'mun, who sponsored the translation of Greek texts into Arabic in the 9th century by Syrian Christians in Baghdad. But already by that time numerous Muslim scholars had written on economic issues, and early Muslim leaders had shown sophisticated attempts to enforce fiscal and monetary financing, use deficit financing, use taxes to encourage production, the use of credit instruments for banking, including rudimentary savings and checking accounts, and contract law.[72]

Among the earliest Muslim economic thinkers was Abu Yusuf (731-798), a student of the founder of the Hanafi Sunni School of Islamic thought, Abu Hanifah. Abu Yusuf was chief jurist for Abbasid Caliph Harun al-Rashid, for whom he wrote the Book of Taxation (Kitab al-Kharaj). This book outlined Abu Yusuf's ideas on taxation, public finance, and agricultural production. He discussed proportional tax on produce instead of fixed taxes on property as being superior as an incentive to bring more land into cultivation. He also advocated forgiving tax policies which favor the producer and a centralized tax administration to reduce corruption. Abu Yusuf favored the use of tax revenues for socioeconomic infrastructure, and included discussion of various types of taxes, including sales tax, death taxes, and import tariffs.[73]

Early discussion of the benefits of division of labor are included in the writings of Qabus, al-Ghazali, al-Farabi (873–950), Ibn Sina (Avicenna) (980–1037), Ibn Miskawayh, Nasir al-Din al-Tusi (1201–74), Ibn Khaldun (1332–1406), and Asaad Davani (b. 1444). Among them, the discussions included division of labor within households, societies, factories, and among nations. Farabi notes that each society lacks at least some necessary resources, and thus an optimal society can only be achieved where domestic, regional, and international trade occur, and that such trade can be beneficial to all parties involved.[74] Ghazali was also noted for his subtle understanding of monetary theory and formulation of another version of Gresham's Law.

The power of supply and demand was understood to some extent by various early Muslim scholars as well. Ibn Taymiyyah illustrates:

"If desire for goods increases while its availability decreases, its price rises. On the other hand, if availability of the good increases and the desire for it decreases, the price comes down."[75]

Ibn Taymiyyah also elaborated on a circumstantial analysis of the market mechanism, with a theoretical insight unusual in his time. His discourses on the welfare advantages and disadvantages of market regulation and deregulation have an almost contemporary ring to them.[76]

Ghazali suggests an early version of price inelasticity of demand for certain goods, and he and Ibn Miskawayh discuss equilibrium prices.[77][better source needed] Other important Muslim scholars who wrote about economics include al-Mawardi (1075–1158), Ibn Taimiyah (1263–1328), and al-Maqrizi.

Ibn Khaldun edit

 
Statue of Ibn Khaldoun in Tunis
When civilization [population] increases, the available labor again increases. In turn, luxury again increases in correspondence with the increasing profit, and the customs and needs of luxury increase. Crafts are created to obtain luxury products. The value realized from them increases, and, as a result, profits are again multiplied in the town. Production there is thriving even more than before. And so it goes with the second and third increase. All the additional labor serves luxury and wealth, in contrast to the original labor that served the necessity of life.[78]
Ibn Khaldun on economic growth

Perhaps the best known Islamic scholar who wrote about economics was Ibn Khaldun of Tunisia (1332–1406),[79] who is considered a forerunner of modern economists.[80][81] Ibn Khaldun wrote on economic and political theory in the introduction, or Muqaddimah (Prolegomena), of his History of the World (Kitab al-Ibar). In the book, he discussed what he called asabiyya (social cohesion), which he sourced as the cause of some civilizations becoming great and others not. Ibn Khaldun felt that many social forces are cyclic, although there can be sudden sharp turns that break the pattern.[82] His idea about the benefits of the division of labor also relate to asabiyya, the greater the social cohesion, the more complex the successful division may be, the greater the economic growth. He noted that growth and development positively stimulates both supply and demand and that the forces of supply and demand are what determines the prices of goods.[83] He also noted macroeconomic forces of population growth, human capital development, and technological developments effects on development.[84] In fact, Ibn Khaldun thought that population growth was directly a function of wealth.[85]

Although he understood that money served as a standard of value, a medium of exchange, and a preserver of value, he did not realize that the value of gold and silver changed based on the forces of supply and demand.[86] He also introduced the concept known as the Khaldun-Laffer Curve (the relationship between tax rates and tax revenue increases as tax rates increase for a while, but then the increases in tax rates begin to cause a decrease in tax revenues as the taxes to impose too great a cost to producers in the economy).

Ibn Khaldun introduced the labor theory of value. He described labor as the source of value, necessary for all earnings and capital accumulation, obvious in the case of craft. He argued that even if earning "results from something other than a craft, the value of the resulting profit and acquired (capital) must (also) include the value of the labor by which it was obtained. Without labor, it would not have been acquired."[80]

His theory of asabiyyah has often been compared to modern Keynesian economics, with Ibn Khaldun's theory clearly containing the concept of the multiplier. A crucial difference, however, is that whereas for John Maynard Keynes it is the middle class's greater propensity to save that is to blame for economic depression, for Ibn Khaldun it is the governmental propensity to save at times when investment opportunities do not take up the slack which leads to aggregate demand.[87]

Another modern economic theory anticipated by Ibn Khaldun is supply-side economics.[88] He "argued that high taxes were often a factor in causing empires to collapse, with the result that lower revenue was collected from high rates." He wrote:[89]

"It should be known that at the beginning of the dynasty, taxation yields a large revenue from small assessments. At the end of the dynasty, taxation yields a small revenue from large assessments."

Post-colonial era edit

During the modern post-colonial era, as Western ideas, including Western economics, began to influence the Muslim world, some Muslim writers sought to produce an Islamic discipline of economics. In the 1960s and 70s Shia Islamic thinkers worked to develop a unique Islamic economic philosophy with "its answers to contemporary economic problems." Several works were particularly influential,

  • slam VA Malekiyyat (Islam and Property) by Mahmud Taleqani (1951),
  • Iqtisaduna (Our Economics) by Mohammad Baqir al-Sadr (1961) and
  • Eqtesad-e Towhidi (The Economics of Divine Harmony) by Abolhassan Banisadr (1978)
  • Some Interpretations of Property Rights, Capital, and Labor from Islamic Perspective by Habibullah Peyman (1979).[90][91]

Al-Sadr, in particular, has been described as having "almost single-handedly developed the notion of Islamic economics" [92]

In their writings, Sadr and the other Shia authors "sought to depict Islam as a religion committed to social justice, the equitable distribution of wealth, and the cause of the deprived classes", with doctrines "acceptable to Islamic jurists", while refuting existing non-Islamic theories of capitalism and Marxism. This version of Islamic economics, which influenced the Iranian Revolution, called for public ownership of land and large "industrial enterprises", while private economic activity continued "within reasonable limits."[93] These ideas helped shape the large public sector and public subsidy policies of the Iranian Islamic revolution.

In the 1980s and 1990s, as the Iranian revolution failed to reach the per capita income level achieved by the regime it overthrew, and Communist states and socialist parties in the non-Muslim world turned away from socialism, Muslim interest shifted away from government ownership and regulation. In Iran, it is reported that "entered-e Islami (meaning both Islamic economics and economy) ... once a revolutionary shibboleth is indubitably absent in all official documents and the media. It disappeared from Iranian political discourse about 15 years ago [1990]."[91]

But in other parts of the Muslim world, the term lived on, shifting form to the less ambitious goal of interest-free banking. Some Muslim bankers and religious leaders suggested ways to integrate Islamic law on the usage of money with modern concepts of ethical investing. In banking, this was done through the use of sales transactions (focusing on the fixed rate return modes) to achieve similar results to interest. This has been criticized by some western writers as a means of covering conventional banking with an Islamic facade.

Contemporary economics edit

In modern times, economic policies of the 1979 Islamic Revolution in predominantly Shia Iran were heavily statist with a very large public sector, and official rhetoric celebrating revolution and the rights of the dispossessed, although this tendency has faded over time.[94] In Sudan, the policies of the National Islamic Front party dominated regime in the 1990s have been the reverse, employing economic liberalism and accepting "market forces in the formulation of state policies." In Algeria, Jordan, Egypt, and Pakistan, Islamist parties have supported populist policies, showing a "marked reluctance to adopt austerity policies and decreased subsidies."[95] In recent years, Turkey had a rapidly growing economy and became a developed country according to the CIA.[96] Indonesia, Saudi Arabia and Turkey are members of the G-20 major economies.

In 2008, at least $500 billion in assets around the world were managed by Sharia, or Islamic law, and the sector was growing at more than 10% per year. Islamic finance seeks to promote social justice by banning exploitative practices. In reality, this boils down to a set of prohibitions—on paying interest, on gambling with derivatives and options, and on investing in firms that make pornography or pork.[97]

Another form of modern finance that originated from the Muslim world is microcredit and microfinance. It began in the 1970s in Bangladesh with Grameen Bank, founded by Muhammad Yunus, recipient of the 2006 Nobel Peace Prize. Among 6 representative studies selected from a sample of more than 100 studies as being methodologically most sound, five found no evidence that microcredit reduced poverty.[98][99]

Land reform edit

One issue "generally absent" from contemporary Islamist economic thought (except Sayyid Qutb) and action "whether moderate or radical" is the question of agrarian reform. Opposition to agrarian reform even played a role in Islamist uprisings (Iran 1963, Afghanistan, 1978).[100] At least one observer (Olivier Roy) believes this is primarily because it would "imply a reexamination of the concept of ownership", and in particular "throw into question the Waqf, endowments whose revenue ensures the functioning of religious institutions."[100] In the Islamic Republic of Iran, for example, waqf holdings are very large (in Khorasan Province, "50% of the cultivated lands belong to the religious foundation Astan-i Quds, which oversees" the Imam Reza shrine in Mashhad).[100] Thus questioning waqf property would mean questioning "the foundation of the financial autonomy of the mullahs and mosques", particularly among Shia Muslims.[100]

Islamic stock index edit

In June 2005, the Dow Jones Indexes in New York City and RHB Securities in Kuala Lumpur teamed up to launch a new "Islamic Malaysia Index"—a collection of 45 stocks representing Malaysian companies that comply with a variety of Sharia-based requirements. For example, total debt, cash plus interest-bearing securities and accounts receivables must each be less than 33% of the trailing 12-month average capitalization.[citation needed] Also, "gambling" on derivatives and options, and on investing in firms that make pornography or pork are also unacceptable. Islamic bonds, or sukuk, use asset returns to pay investors to comply with the religion's ban on interest and are currently traded privately on the over-the-counter market. In late December 2009 Bursa Malaysia announced it was considering enabling individuals to trade Shariah-compliant debt on its exchange as part of a plan to attract new investors.[101]

See also edit

Banks
Non-Bank Finance Institutions
  • Guidance Residential

References edit

  1. ^ El‐Sheikh, S., 2008. The moral economy of classical Islam: a hiqhiconomic model. The Muslim World, 98(1), p.120.
  2. ^ Roy (1994), p. 132.
  3. ^ Schirazi, Asghar, Constitution of Iran, (1997), p.170
  4. ^ Siegfried, N.A., 2001. Concepts of paper money in Islamic legal thought. Arab LQ, 16, p.319.
  5. ^ Martin, Richard C., ed. (2014). "Riba". Encyclopedia of Islam and the Muslim World. Macmillan Reference USA. pp. 596–7. ISBN 978-0-02-865912-1.
  6. ^ Badr, Gamal Moursi (Spring 1978), "Islamic Law: Its Relation to Other Legal Systems", The American Journal of Comparative Law, 26 (2 – Proceedings of an International Conference on Comparative Law, Salt Lake City, Utah, February 24–25, 1977), The American Journal of Comparative Law, Vol. 26, No. 2: 187–198, doi:10.2307/839667, JSTOR 839667
  7. ^ Gaudiosi (1988).
  8. ^ Gaudiosi (1988), pp. 1237–1240.
  9. ^ Gaudiosi (1988), p. 1246.
  10. ^ Gaudiosi (1988), pp. 1246–1247.
  11. ^ Gaudiosi (1988), p. 1247.
  12. ^ Hudson (2003), p. 32.
  13. ^ Gaudiosi (1988), pp. 1244–1245.
  14. ^ Micheau (1996), pp. 999–1001.
  15. ^ Peters, Edward. Europe and the Middle Ages, 1983. p. 125
  16. ^ a b c Crone, Patricia (2005). Medieval Islamic Political Thought. Edinburgh University Press. pp. 308–309. ISBN 0-7486-2194-6.
  17. ^ Shatzmiller (1994), p. 263.
  18. ^ The Cambridge economic history of Europe, p. 437. Cambridge University Press, ISBN 0-521-08709-0.
  19. ^ Timur Kuran (2005), "The Absence of the Corporation in Islamic Law: Origins and Persistence", American Journal of Comparative Law 53, pp. 785–834 [798–99].
  20. ^ a b c d e Jairus Banaji (2007), "Islam, the Mediterranean and the rise of capitalism", Historical Materialism 15 (1), pp. 47–74, Brill Publishers.
  21. ^ a b Robert Sabatino Lopez, Irving Woodworth Raymond, Olivia Remie Constable (2001), Medieval Trade in the Mediterranean World: Illustrative Documents, Columbia University Press, ISBN 0-231-12357-4.
  22. ^ a b Labib (1969), pp. 92–93.
  23. ^ Ray Spier (2002), "The history of the peer-review process", Trends in Biotechnology 20 (8), pp. 357–58 [357].
  24. ^ a b Said Amir Arjomand (1999), "The Law, Agency, and Policy in Medieval Islamic Society: Development of the Institutions of Learning from the Tenth to the Fifteenth Century", Comparative Studies in Society and History 41, pp. 263–93. Cambridge University Press.
  25. ^ a b Samir Amin (1978), "The Arab Nation: Some Conclusions and Problems", MERIP Reports 68, pp. 3–14 [8, 13].
  26. ^ M. Shahid Alam (2016). Poverty From The Wealth of Nations: Integration and Polarization in the Global Economy since 1760. Springer. p. 32. ISBN 978-0-333-98564-9.
  27. ^ Khandker, Hissam (31 July 2015). "Which India is claiming to have been colonised?". The Daily Star (Op-ed).
  28. ^ Maddison, Angus (2003). Development Centre Studies The World Economy Historical Statistics: Historical Statistics. OECD Publishing. pp. 259–261. ISBN 9264104143.
  29. ^ a b c Shadi Hamid (August 2003), , Renaissance: Monthly Islamic Journal, 13 (8), archived from the original on 2011-08-25, retrieved 2017-12-23)
  30. ^ a b John M. Hobson (2004), The Eastern Origins of Western Civilisation, p. 29-30, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 0-521-54724-5.
  31. ^ a b Labib (1969).
  32. ^ Roman K. Kovalev, Alexis C. Kaelin (2007), "Circulation of Arab Silver in Medieval Afro-Eurasia: Preliminary Observations", History Compass 5 (2), pp. 560–80.
  33. ^ Tyabji, Amini (1991). "Historical dominance on money changing business". In Mohamed Ariff (ed.). The Muslim Private Sector in Southeast Asia: Islam and the Economic Development of Southeast Asia (Social Issues in Southeast Asia). Institute of Southeast Asian Studies. ISBN 981-3016-10-8.
  34. ^ Andrew M. Watson (1983), Agricultural Innovation in the Early Islamic World, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 0-521-24711-X.
  35. ^ Andrew M. Watson (1974), "The Arab Agricultural Revolution and Its Diffusion, 700-1100", The Journal of Economic History 34 (1), p. 8-35.
  36. ^ Decker, Michael (2009), "Plants and Progress: Rethinking the Islamic Agricultural Revolution", Journal of World History 20 (2): 187–206, DOI:10.1353/jwh.0.0058.
  37. ^ Ashtor, E (1976), A Social and Economic History of the Near East in the Middle Ages, Berkeley: University of California Press, pp. 58–63.
  38. ^ Coulson, p. 117. "Reaching further back through the centuries, the civilizations regarded as having the highest literacy rates of their ages were parent-driven educational marketplaces. The ability to read and write was far more widely enjoyed in the early medieval Islamic empire and fourth-century-B.C.E. Athens than in any other cultures of their times."
  39. ^ Burke (2009). "The spread of written knowledge was at least the equal of what it was in China after printing became common there in the tenth century. (Chinese books were printed in small editions of a hundred or so copies.)"
  40. ^ Coulson, p. 117. "In neither case did the state supply or even systematically subsidize educational services. The Muslim world's eventual introduction of state funding under Nizam al-Mulk in the eleventh century was quickly followed by partisan religious squabbling over education and the gradual fall of Islam from its place of cultural and scientific preeminence."
  41. ^ Burke (2009). "According to legend, paper came to the Islamic world as a result of the capture of Chinese papermakers at the 751 C.E. Battle of Talas River."
  42. ^ Burke (2009). "Whatever the source, the diffusion of paper-making technology via the lands of Islam produced a shift from oral to scribal culture across the rest of Afroeurasia that was rivaled only by the move from scribal to typographic culture. (Perhaps it will prove to have been even more important than the recent move from typographic culture to the Internet.) The result was remarkable. As historian Jonathan Bloom informs us, paper encouraged "an efflorescence of books and written culture incomparably more brilliant than was known anywhere in Europe until the invention of printing with movable type in the fifteenth century."
  43. ^ Burke (2009). "More so than any previously existing society, Islamic society of the period 1000–1500 was profoundly a culture of books. [...] The emergence of a culture of books is closely tied to cultural dispositions toward literacy in Islamic societies. Muslim young men were encouraged to memorize the Qur'an as part of their transition to adulthood, and while most presumably did not (though little is known about literacy levels in pre-Mongol Muslim societies), others did. Types of literacy, in any event, varied, as Nelly Hanna has recently suggested, and are best studied as part of the complex social dynamics and contexts of individual Muslim societies. The need to conform commercial contracts and business arrangements to Islamic law provided a further impetus for literacy, especially likely in commercial centers. Scholars often engaged in commercial activity and craftsmen or tradesmen spent time studying in madrasas. The connection between what Brian Street has called "maktab literacy" and commercial literacy was real and exerted a steady pressure on individuals to upgrade their reading skills."
  44. ^ a b Shatzmiller (1994), pp. 402–403.
  45. ^ Judith Tucker (1975), "Islam and Capitalism by Maxime Rodinson", MERIP Reports 34, pp. 31–2 [31].
  46. ^ Labib (1969), pp. 81–82.
  47. ^ The Cambridge economic history of Europe, pp. 438–440. Cambridge University Press, ISBN 0-521-08709-0.
  48. ^ Heck, Gene W. (2006), Charlemagne, Muhammad, and the Arab roots of capitalism, Walter de Gruyter, ISBN 3-11-019229-2
  49. ^ Nolan, Peter (2007), Capitalism and Freedom: The Contradictory Character of Globalisation, Anthem Press, p. 277, ISBN 978-1-84331-280-2
  50. ^ Oxford Encyclopedia of the Modern Islamic World, New York: Oxford University Press, 1995, p. 19, ISBN 0-19-506613-8, OCLC 94030758
  51. ^ . Oxford Islamic Studies Online. Archived from the original on June 18, 2013. Retrieved 23 January 2010.
  52. ^ And Once Again Abu Dharr, retrieved 23 January 2010
  53. ^ Hanna, Sami A.; George H. Gardner (1969), Arab Socialism: A Documentary Survey, Leiden: E.J. Brill, p. 273, retrieved 23 January 2010
  54. ^ Hanna, Sami A. (1969), , The Muslim World, 59 (3–4): 275–286, doi:10.1111/j.1478-1913.1969.tb02639.x, archived from the original on 2010-09-13, retrieved 2010-04-13.
  55. ^ a b Adam Robert Lucas (2005), "Industrial Milling in the Ancient and Medieval Worlds: A Survey of the Evidence for an Industrial Revolution in Medieval Europe", Technology and Culture 46 (1), pp. 1–30 [10].
  56. ^ Ahmad Y Hassan, Transfer Of Islamic Technology To The West, Part II: Transmission Of Islamic Engineering 2008-02-18 at the Wayback Machine
  57. ^ Shatzmiller (1994), pp. 47–48.
  58. ^ Shatzmiller (1994), pp. 6–7.
  59. ^ a b c Shatzmiller (1994), pp. 400–401.
  60. ^ Shatzmiller (1994), pp. 350–362.
  61. ^ Shatzmiller (1997), pp. 175–177.
  62. ^ Shatzmiller (1994), pp. 169–170.
  63. ^ Alatas, Syed Farid (2006), "From Jami'ah to University: Multiculturalism and Christian–Muslim Dialogue", Current Sociology, 54 (1): 112–132, doi:10.1177/0011392106058837, S2CID 144509355, The idea of the degree most likely came from Islam. In 931 AD the Abbasid caliph al-Muqtadir had all practising physicians examined and those who passed were granted certificates (ijazah). In this way, Baghdad was able to get rid of its quacks (Hitti, 1970: 364). The ijazah was the principal means by which scholars and Sufis passed on their teachings to students, granting them permission to carry on their teachings. Although the learned scholars of Islam taught in formal institutions of learning such as the maktab, the kuttab, the madrasah and the jami`ah, the degree was personally granted by the scholar to the student.
  64. ^ Avner Greif (1989), "Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade: Evidence on the Maghribi Traders", The Journal of Economic History 49 (4), pp. 857–82 [862, 874].
  65. ^ "Question 18: What Is The Purpose of Jizya". Al-Islam.org.
  66. ^ Spengler (1964), p. 274.
  67. ^ Hosseini (2003), p. 39.
  68. ^ Matthew E. Falagas; Effie A. Zarkadoulia; George Samonis (August 2006). "Arab science in the golden age (750–1258 C.E.) and today". The FASEB Journal. 20 (10): 1581–1586. doi:10.1096/fj.06-0803ufm. PMID 16873881.
  69. ^ a b Hosseini (2003), p. 36.
  70. ^ Schumpeter (1954).
  71. ^ The prevalence and error of Schumpeter's thesis and the importance of Spengler's paper are discussed in Hosseini (2003).
  72. ^ Hosseini (2003), p. 33.
  73. ^ Hosseini (2003), p. 34.
  74. ^ Farabi, Abu Nassr 1982: Madineh Fazeleh (Good City), Persian translation by Sajadi. Teheran, Iran: Zuhuri. p25
  75. ^ Hosseini (2003), p. 28.
  76. ^ Baeck, Louis (1994), The Mediterranean tradition in economic thought, Routledge, p. 99, ISBN 0-415-09301-5
  77. ^ Hosseini (2003), p. 38.
  78. ^ Weiss (1995), p. 30 quotes Muqaddimah 2:272-273.
  79. ^ Schumpeter (1954), p. 136 mentions his sociology, others, including Hosseini (2003), emphasize him as well
  80. ^ a b I. M. Oweiss (1988), "Ibn Khaldun, the Father of Economics", Arab Civilization: Challenges and Responses, New York University Press, ISBN 0-88706-698-4.
  81. ^ Jean David C. Boulakia (1971), "Ibn Khaldun: A Fourteenth-Century Economist", The Journal of Political Economy 79 (5): 1105-1118.
  82. ^ Weiss (1995), pp. 29–30.
  83. ^ Weiss (1995), p. 31 quotes Muqaddimah 2:276-278.
  84. ^ Weiss (1995), p. 31 quotes Muqaddimah 2:272-273.
  85. ^ Weiss (1995), p. 33.
  86. ^ Weiss (1995), p. 32.
  87. ^ Gellner, Ernest (1983), Muslim Society, Cambridge University Press, pp. 34–5, ISBN 0-521-27407-9
  88. ^ Lawrence, Bruce B. (1983), "Introduction: Ibn Khaldun and Islamic Ideology", Journal of Asian and African Studies, XVIII (3–4): 154–165 [157 & 164], doi:10.1177/002190968301800302, S2CID 144858781
  89. ^ Bartlett, Bruce, "Supply-Side Economics: "Voodoo Economics" or Lasting Contribution?" (PDF), Laffer Associates (November 11, 2003), retrieved 2008-11-17
  90. ^ Bakhash, Shaul, The Reign of the Ayatollahs, Basic Books, c.1984, p. 167-168
  91. ^ a b Revolutionary Surge and Quiet Demise of Islamic Economics in Iran 2012-01-17 at the Wayback Machine
  92. ^ The Renewal of Islamic Law
  93. ^ Bakhash, Shaul, The Reign of the Ayatollahs, Basic Books, c.1984, p. 172-173
  94. ^ Roy (1994), p. 138.
  95. ^ Fuller, Graham E., The Future of Political Islam, Palgrave MacMillan, (2003), p.142
  96. ^ , World Factbook, CIA.
  97. ^ Islamic Finance, Forbes (April 21, 2008)
  98. ^ Westover, J. (2008). (PDF). Electronic Journal of Sociology. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2008-10-01. Some studies have found marked decreases in overall poverty levels, including declining levels of extreme poverty (Khandker, 2005), while other studies do not find the same direct effect (Morris and Barnes, 2005; Kan, Olds, and Kah, 2005; Goetz and Gupta, 1996). Still, other studies provide mixed results (Copestake, Bhalotra, and Johnson, 2001; Morduch, 1998).
  99. ^ Khandker, SR (2005). "Microfinance and poverty: evidence using panel data from Bangladesh". The World Bank Economic Review. 19 (2): 263–286. doi:10.1093/wber/lhi008. hdl:10986/16478. S2CID 15335913.
  100. ^ a b c d Roy (1994), p. 136.
  101. ^ Opalesque (30 December 2009). "Malaysia exchange reviewing sharia-compliant bonds".

Sources edit

  • Burke, Edmund (June 2009). "Islam at the Center: Technological Complexes and the Roots of Modernity". Journal of World History. 20 (2). University of Hawaii Press: 165–186. doi:10.1353/jwh.0.0045. S2CID 143484233.
  • Coulson, Andrew J. (PDF) (Report). Hoover Institution. pp. 105–145. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2011-08-17. Retrieved 2008-11-22.
  • Gaudiosi, Monica M. (April 1988), "The Influence of the Islamic Law of Waqf on the Development of the Trust in England: The Case of Merton College", University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 136 (4), University of Pennsylvania Law Review, Vol. 136, No. 4: 1231–1261, doi:10.2307/3312162, JSTOR 3312162
  • Hosseini, Hamid S. (2003), "Contributions of Medieval Muslim Scholars to the History of Economics and their Impact: A Refutation of the Schumpeterian Great Gap", in Biddle, Jeff E.; Davis, Jon B.; Samuels, Warren J. (eds.), A Companion to the History of Economic Thought, Malden, Massachusetts: Blackwell, pp. 28–45, doi:10.1002/9780470999059.ch3, ISBN 0-631-22573-0
  • Hudson, A. (2003), Equity and Trusts (3rd ed.), London: Cavendish Publishing, ISBN 1-85941-729-9
  • Labib, Subhi Y. (1969), "Capitalism in Medieval Islam", The Journal of Economic History, 29 (1): 79–96, doi:10.1017/S0022050700097837
  • Micheau, Françoise (1996). "The Scientific Institutions in the Medieval Near East". Encyclopedia of the History of Arabic Science, Volume 3: Technology, alchemy and life sciences. By Morelon, Régis. Rāshid, Rushdī (ed.). CRC Press. pp. 985–1007. ISBN 978-0-415-12412-6.
  • Roy, Olivier (1994). The Failure of Political Islam. Translated by Carol Volk. Harvard University Press.
  • Schumpeter, Joseph (1954), History of Economic Analysis, New York: Oxford University Press
  • Shatzmiller, Maya (1994), Labour in the Medieval Islamic World, Brill Publishers, ISBN 90-04-09896-8
  • Shatzmiller, Maya (1997). "Women and Wage Labour in the Medieval Islamic West: Legal Issues in an Economic Context". Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient. 40 (2): 174–206. doi:10.1163/1568520972600748.
  • Spengler, J. Joseph (1964). "Economic thought of Islam: Ibn Khaldun". Comparative Studies in Society and History. 6 (3). Cambridge University Press: 264–306. doi:10.1017/s0010417500002164. JSTOR 177577.
  • Weiss, Dieter (1995). "Ibn Khaldun on Economic Transformation". International Journal of Middle East Studies. 27 (1). Cambridge University Press: 29–37. doi:10.1017/S0020743800061560. JSTOR 176185.

Further reading edit

  • Badr, Gamal M. (Spring 1989), "To the Editor", The American Journal of Comparative Law, 37 (2), The American Journal of Comparative Law, Vol. 37, No. 2: 424–425, doi:10.2307/840180, JSTOR 840180
  • Koehler, Benedikt (2014), Early Islam and the Birth of Capitalism, Lexington Books, ISBN 978-0-7391-8882-8
  • Kuran, Timur. 2018. "Islam and Economic Performance: Historical and Contemporary Links." Journal of Economic Literature, 56(4):1292-1359.
  • Waleed Addas (2008). Methodology of Economics: Secular versus Islamic
  • Iqtisaduna

External links edit

    history, islamic, economics, this, article, needs, additional, citations, verification, please, help, improve, this, article, adding, citations, reliable, sources, unsourced, material, challenged, removed, find, sources, news, newspapers, books, scholar, jstor. This article needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources History of Islamic economics news newspapers books scholar JSTOR October 2016 Learn how and when to remove this message Between the 9th and 14th centuries the Muslim world developed many advanced economic concepts techniques and usages These ranged from areas of production investment finance economic development taxation property use such as Hawala an early informal value transfer system Islamic trusts known as waqf systems of contract relied upon by merchants a widely circulated common currency cheques promissory notes early contracts bills of exchange and forms of commercial partnership such as mufawada Specific Islamic concepts involving money property taxation charity and the Five Pillars include zakat the taxing of certain goods such as harvest to allocate these taxes to expand that are also explicitly defined such as aid to the needy Gharar the interdiction of chance that is of the presence of any element of uncertainty in a contract which excludes not only insurance but also the lending of money without participation in the risks and riba every kind of excess or unjustified disparity between the exchanged objects or counter values 1 These concepts like others in Islamic law and jurisprudence came from the prescriptions anecdotes examples and words of the Prophet all gathered together and systematized by commentators according to an inductive casuistic method 2 Sometimes other sources such as al urf the custom al aql reason or al ijma consensus of the jurists were employed 3 In addition Islamic law has developed areas of law that correspond to secular laws of contracts and torts Contemporary Islamic scholars draw heavily on classical opinions 4 Modern Islamic economics emerged in the 1945s and as of 2004 Islamic Banks have been established in over 8 countries and interest has been banned in three Pakistan Iran and the Sudan 5 Contents 1 Legal institutions 1 1 Hawala agency 1 2 Waqf trust 2 Classical Muslim commerce 2 1 Economy in the Caliphate and Islamic empires 2 2 Islamic India 2 3 Trade 2 4 Agriculture in the medieval Islamic world 2 5 Islamic capitalism 2 6 Islamic socialism 2 7 Industrial development 2 8 Labour force 2 9 Urbanization 3 Classical Islamic economic thought 3 1 Early Islamic economic thinkers 3 2 Ibn Khaldun 4 Post colonial era 4 1 Contemporary economics 4 1 1 Land reform 4 2 Islamic stock index 5 See also 6 References 6 1 Sources 7 Further reading 8 External linksLegal institutions editSee also Sharia and Fiqh Hawala agency edit Main article Hawala The Hawala an early informal value transfer system has its origins in classical Islamic law and is mentioned in texts of Islamic jurisprudence as early as the 8th century Hawala itself later influenced the development of the agency in common law and in civil laws such as the aval in French law and the Cavallo in Italian law The words aval and Cavallo were themselves derived from Hawala The transfer of debt which was not permissible under Roman law but became widely practiced in medieval Europe especially in commercial transactions was due to the large extent of the trade conducted by the Italian cities with the Muslim world in the Middle Ages The agency was also an institution unknown to Roman law as no individual could conclude a binding contract on behalf of another as his agent In Roman law the contractor himself was considered the party to the contract and it took a second contract between the person who acted on behalf of a principal and the latter to transfer the rights and the obligations deriving from the contract to him On the other hand Islamic law and the later common law had no difficulty in accepting agency as one of its institutions in the field of contracts and obligations in general 6 Waqf trust edit Main article Waqf The waqf in Islamic law which developed in the medieval Islamic world from the 7th to 9th centuries bears a notable resemblance to the English trust law 7 Every waqf was required to have a waqif founder mutawillis trustee qadi judge and beneficiaries 8 Under both a waqf and a trust property is reserved and its usufruct appropriated for the benefit of specific individuals or for a general charitable purpose the corpus becomes inalienable estates for life in favor of successive beneficiaries can be created and without regard to the law of inheritance or the rights of the heirs and continuity is secured by the successive appointment of trustees or mutawillis 9 The only significant distinction between the Islamic waqf and English trust was the express or implied reversion of the waqf to charitable purposes when its specific object has ceased to exist 10 though this difference only applied to the waqf ahli Islamic family trust rather than the waqf khairi devoted to a charitable purpose from its inception Another difference was the English vesting of legal estate over the trust property in the trustee though the trustee was still bound to administer that property for the benefit of the beneficiaries In this sense the role of the English trustee therefore does not differ significantly from that of the mutually 11 The trust law developed in England at the time of the Crusades during the 12th and 13th centuries was introduced by Crusaders who may have been influenced by the waqf institutions they came across in the Middle East 12 13 After the Islamic waqf law and madrassah foundations were firmly established by the 10th century the number of Bimaristan hospitals multiplied throughout Islamic lands In the 11th century every Islamic city had at least several hospitals The waqf trust institutions funded the hospitals for various expenses including the wages of doctors ophthalmologists surgeons chemists pharmacists domestics and all other staff the purchase of foods and drugs hospital equipment such as beds mattresses bowls and perfumes and repairs to buildings The waqf trusts also funded medical schools and their revenues covered various expenses such as their maintenance and the payment of teachers and students 14 Classical Muslim commerce editThe systems of contract relied upon by merchants was very effective Merchants would buy and sell on commission with money loaned to them by wealthy investors or a joint investment of several merchants who were often Muslim Christian and Jewish Recently a collection of documents was found in an Egyptian synagogue shedding a very detailed and human light on the life of medieval Middle Eastern merchants Business partnerships would be made for many commercial ventures and bonds of kinship enabled trade networks to form over huge distances During the ninth century banks enabled the drawing of check in by a bank in Baghdad that could be cashed in Morocco 15 The concepts of welfare and pension better source needed were introduced in early Islamic law as forms of Zakat charity one of the Five Pillars of Islam since the time of the Abbasid caliph Al Mansur in the 8th century The taxes including Zakat and Jizya collected in the treasury of an Islamic government was used to provide income for the needy including the poor elderly orphans widows and the disabled According to the Islamic jurist Al Ghazali Algazel 1058 1111 the government was also expected to store up food supplies in every region in case of a disaster or famine occurs The Caliphate was thus one of the earliest welfare states particularly the Abbasid Caliphate 16 Economy in the Caliphate and Islamic empires edit In the medieval Arab Agricultural Revolution a social transformation took place as a result of changing land ownership giving individuals of any gender 17 the right to buy sell mortgage and inherit land Early forms of proto capitalism and free markets were present in the Caliphate 18 An early market economy and early form of merchant capitalism developed between the 8th and 12th centuries 19 A vigorous monetary economy developed based on the wide circulation of a common currency the dinar and the integration of previously independent monetary areas Business techniques and forms of business organization employed during this time included early contracts bills of exchange long distance international trade early forms of partnership mufawada such as limited partnerships mudaraba and early forms of credit debt profit loss capital al mal capital accumulation nama al mal 20 circulating capital capital expenditure revenue cheques promissory notes 21 trusts waqf savings accounts transactional accounts pawning loaning exchange rates bankers money changers ledgers deposits assignments the double entry bookkeeping system 22 and lawsuits 23 Organizational enterprises similar to corporations independent from the state also existed in the medieval Islamic world 24 25 Many of these concepts were adopted and further advanced in medieval Europe from the 13th century onwards 20 Islamic India edit During the Muslim rule in India realms such as the Delhi Sultanate Bengal Sultanate Mughal Empire Nizam of Hyderabad and the Kingdom of Mysore made significant contributions to the South Asian economy In the 17th century Mughal India became the world s largest economy 26 27 28 becoming the leading textile manufacturing power in the world valued over 25 of world GDP The concepts of welfare and pension were present in early Islamic law as forms of zakat one of the Five Pillars of Islam since the time of the Rashidun caliph Umar in the 7th century The taxes including zakat and jizya collected in the treasury bayt al mal of an Islamic government were used to provide income for the needy including the poor the elderly orphans widows and the disabled According to the Islamic jurist Al Ghazali Algazel 1058 1111 the government was also expected to stockpile food supplies in every region in case of disaster or famine The Caliphate was thus one of the earliest welfare states 16 29 Trade edit See also Islamic geography During the Islamic Golden Age isolated regions had contact with a far reaching Muslim trade network extending from the Atlantic Ocean and the Mediterranean in the west to the Indian Ocean and South China Sea in the east and covering most of the Old World 30 including significant areas of Asia and Africa and much of Europe with their trade networks 31 Arabic silver dirham coins were being circulated throughout the Afro Eurasian landmass as far as sub Saharan Africa in the south and northern Europe in the north often in exchange for goods and slaves 32 This helped establish the Rashidun Umayyad Abbasid Ayyubid and Fatimid Caliphates as the world s leading extensive economic powers in the 7th 13th centuries 30 Due to religious sanctions against debt Tamil Muslims have historically been money changers not money lenders throughout South and South East Asia 33 Agriculture in the medieval Islamic world edit Further information Arab Agricultural Revolution From the 8th century to the 13th century in Muslim lands many crops and plants were planted along Muslim trade routes farming techniques spread In addition to changes in economy population distribution vegetation cover 34 agricultural production population levels urban growth the distribution of the labor force and numerous other aspects of life in the Islamic world were affected according to Andrew Watson 35 However this is disputed by other scholars who claim cultivation and consumption of staples such as durum wheat Asiatic rice and sorghum as well as cotton were already commonplace centuries before 36 or that agricultural production declined in areas brought under Muslim rule in the Middle Ages 37 The early Abbasid Caliphate also had the highest literacy rates among pre modern societies alongside the city of classical Athens in the 4th century BC 38 and later China after the introduction of printing from the 10th century 39 One factor for the relatively high literacy rates in the early Islamic Empire which was its parent driven educational marketplace as the state did not systematically subsidize educational services until the introduction of state funding under Nizam al Mulk in the 11th century 40 Another factor was the diffusion of paper from China 41 which led to an efflorescence of books and written culture in Islamic society thus papermaking technology transformed Islamic society and later the rest of Afro Eurasia from an oral to scribal culture comparable to the later shifts from scribal to typographic culture and from typographic culture to the Internet 42 Other factors include the widespread use of paper books in Islamic society more so than any other previously existing society the study and memorization of the Qur an flourishing commercial activity and the emergence of the Maktab and Madrasah educational institutions 43 Islamic capitalism edit Main article Capitalism and Islam Early forms of mercantilism and capitalism are thought to have developed in the Islamic Golden Age from the 9th century 20 31 44 Early Islamic commerce applied a number of concepts and techniques including bills of exchange forms of partnership mufawada such as limited partnerships mudaraba and early forms of capital al mal capital accumulation nama al mal 20 cheques promissory notes 21 trusts see waqf transactional accounts loans ledgers and assignments 22 Organizational enterprises independent of the state also existed in the medieval Islamic world while the agency institution was also introduced 24 25 Medieval Europe adopted and developed many of these concepts from the 13th century onwards 20 A market economy was established by whom in the Islamic world on the basis of an economic system resembling merchant capitalism Labour promoted capital formation in medieval Islamic society and a considerable number of owners of monetary funds and precious metals developed financial capital The capitalists sahib al mal stood at the height of their power between the 9th and 12th centuries but their influence declined after the arrival of the ikta landowners and after the state which monopolized production both these trends hampered any development of industrial capitalism in the Islamic world 44 Some state enterprises still had a capitalist mode of production such as pearl diving in Iraq and the textile industry in Egypt 45 From the 11th to the 13th centuries the Karimis an enterprise and business group controlled by entrepreneurs came to dominate much of the Islamic world s economy 46 The group was controlled by about fifty Muslim merchants labeled as Karimis who were of Yemeni Egyptian and sometimes Indian origin 47 Each Karimi merchant had considerable wealth ranging from at least 100 000 dinars to as much as 10 million dinars The group had considerable influence in most important eastern markets and sometimes influenced politics through its financing activities and through a variety of customers including Emirs Sultans Viziers foreign merchants and common consumers The Karimis dominated many of the trade routes across the Mediterranean the Red Sea and the Indian Ocean and as far as Francia in the north China in the east and sub Saharan Africa in the south where they obtained gold from gold mines Practices employed by the Karimis included the use of agents the financing of projects as a method of acquiring capital and a banking institution for loans and deposits Islamic socialism edit Main articles Islamic socialism and Bayt al mal Though medieval Islamic economics appears to have somewhat resembled a form of capitalism some arguing that it laid the foundations for the development of modern capitalism 48 49 Others see Islamic economics as neither completely capitalistic nor completely socialistic but rather a balance between the two emphasizing both individual economic freedom and the need to serve the common good 29 Abu Dharr al Ghifari a Companion of Muḥammad is credited by many as the founder of Islamic socialism 50 51 52 53 54 The concepts of welfare and pension were introduced in early Islamic law as forms of Zakat charity one of the Five Pillars of Islam during the time of the Rashidun caliph Umar in the 7th century This practiced continued well into the era of the Abbasid Caliphate as seen under Al Ma mun s rule in the 8th century for example The taxes including Zakat and Jizya collected in the treasury of an Islamic government were used to provide income for the needy including the poor elderly orphans widows and the disabled According to the Islamic jurist Al Ghazali Algazel 1058 1111 the government was also expected to stockpile food supplies in every region in case a disaster or famine occurred The Caliphate is thus considered the world s first major welfare state 16 29 Industrial development edit Muslim engineers in the Islamic world were responsible for numerous innovative industrial uses of hydropower early industrial uses of tide mills wind power and fossil fuels such as petroleum A variety of industrial mills were used in the Islamic world including fulling mills gristmills hullers sawmills shipmills stamp mills steel mills sugar mills tide mills and windmills By the 11th century every province throughout the Islamic world had these industrial mills in operation from al Andalus and North Africa to the Middle East and Central Asia 55 Muslim engineers also employed water turbines and gears in mills and water raising machines and pioneered the use of dams as a source of water power used to provide additional power to watermills and water raising machines 56 Such advances made it possible for many industrial tasks that were previously driven by manual labour in ancient times to be mechanized and driven by machinery instead in the medieval Islamic world The transfer of these technologies to medieval Europe later laid the foundations for the Industrial Revolution in 18th century Europe 55 In addition to government owned tiraz textile factories there were also privately owned enterprises when run largely by landlords who collected taxes and invested them in the textile industry 57 Labour force edit See also Female Labor Force Participation Rate in Majority Muslim Countries This section relies largely or entirely on a single source Relevant discussion may be found on the talk page Please help improve this article by introducing citations to additional sources Find sources History of Islamic economics news newspapers books scholar JSTOR January 2018 The labor force in the Caliphate were employed from diverse ethnic and religious backgrounds while both men and women were involved in diverse occupations and economic activities 58 Women were employed in a wide range of commercial activities and diverse occupations 59 in the primary sector as farmers for example secondary sector as construction workers dyers spinners etc and tertiary sector as investors doctors nurses presidents of guilds brokers peddlers lenders scholars etc 60 Muslim women also held a monopoly over certain branches of the textile industry 59 additional citation s needed the largest and most specialized and market oriented industry at the time in occupations such as spinning dyeing and embroidery In comparison female property rights and wage labour were relatively uncommon in Europe until the Industrial Revolution in the 18th and 19th centuries 61 The division of labour was diverse and had been evolving over the centuries During the 8th 11th centuries there were on average 63 unique occupations in the primary sector of economic activity extractive 697 unique occupations in the secondary sector manufacturing and 736 unique occupations in the tertiary sector service By the 12th century the number of unique occupations in the primary sector and secondary sector decreased to 35 and 679 respectively while the number of unique occupations in the tertiary sector increased to 1 175 These changes in the division of labour reflect the increased mechanization and use of machinery to replace manual labour and the increased standard of living and quality of life of most citizens in the Caliphate 62 An economic transition occurred during this period due to the diversity of the service sector being far greater than any other previous or contemporary society and the high degree of economic integration between the labour force and the economy Islamic society also experienced a change in attitude towards manual labour In previous civilizations such as ancient Greece and in contemporary civilizations such as early medieval Europe intellectuals saw manual labour in a negative light and looked down on them with contempt additional citation s needed This resulted in technological stagnation as they did not see the need for machinery to replace manual labour additional citation s needed In the Islamic world however manual labour was seen in a far more positive light as intellectuals such as the Brethren of Purity likened them to a participant in the act of creation while Ibn Khaldun alluded to the benefits of manual labour to the progress of society 59 By the early 10th century the idea of the academic degree was introduced and being granted at Maktab schools Madrasah colleges and Bimaristan hospitals In the medical field in particular the Ijazah certificate was granted to those qualified to be practicing physicians in order to differentiate them from unqualified quacks 63 Urbanization edit There was a significant increase in urbanization during this period due to numerous scientific advances in fields such as agriculture hygiene sanitation astronomy medicine and engineering 64 This also resulted in a rising middle class population The head of the family was given the position of authority in his household citation needed although a qadi or judge was able to negotiate and resolve differences in issues of disagreements within families and between them The two senior representatives of municipal authority were the qadi and the muhtasib who held the responsibilities of many issues including quality of water maintenance of city streets containing outbreaks of disease supervising the markets and a prompt burial of the dead Another aspect of Islamic urban life was waqf a religious charity directly dealing with the qadi and religious leaders Through donations the waqf owned many of the public baths and factories using the revenue to fund education citation needed and to provide irrigation for orchards outside the city Following expansion this system was introduced into Eastern Europe by Ottoman Turks citation needed Taxes were also levied on an unmarried man until he was wed Non Muslims were required to pay the jizya an administrative tax on non Muslims analogous to zakat a Muslim only tax The Jizya was applied only to young able bodied adult males and exempted non Muslims from military service The Muslim state would then be responsible for the administration amp security of the Non Muslims 65 Classical Islamic economic thought editTo some degree the early Muslims based their economic analyses on the Qur an such as opposition to riba meaning usury or interest and from sunnah the sayings and doings of Muhammad Early Islamic economic thinkers edit Al Ghazali 1058 1111 classified economics as one of the sciences connected with religion along with metaphysics ethics and psychology Authors have noted however that this connection has not caused early Muslim economic thought to remain static 66 Iranian philosopher Nasir al Din al Tusi 1201 1274 presents an early definition of economics what he calls hekmat e madani the science of city life in discourse three of his Ethics the study of universal laws governing the public interest welfare in so far as they are directed through cooperation toward the optimal perfection 67 Many scholars trace the history of economic thought through the Muslim world which was in a Golden Age from the 8th to 13th century and whose philosophy continued the work of the Greek and Hellenistic thinkers and came to influence Aquinas when Europe rediscovered Greek philosophy through Arabic translation 68 A common theme among these scholars was the praise of economic activity and even self interested accumulation of wealth 69 Persian philosopher Ibn Miskawayh b 1030 notes The creditor desires the well being of the debtor in order to get his money back rather than because of his love for him The debtor on the other hand does not take great interest in the creditor 69 This view is in conflict with an idea Joseph Schumpeter called the great gap The great gap thesis comes out of Schumpeter s 1954 History of Economic Analysis which discusses a break in economic thought during the five hundred year period between the decline of the Greco Roman civilizations and the work of Thomas Aquinas 1225 1274 70 However in 1964 Joseph Spengler s Economic Thought of Islam Ibn Khaldun appeared in the journal Comparative Studies in Society and History and took a large step in bringing early Muslim scholars to the attention of the contemporary West 71 The influence of earlier Greek and Hellenistic thought on the Muslim world began largely with Abbasid caliph al Ma mun who sponsored the translation of Greek texts into Arabic in the 9th century by Syrian Christians in Baghdad But already by that time numerous Muslim scholars had written on economic issues and early Muslim leaders had shown sophisticated attempts to enforce fiscal and monetary financing use deficit financing use taxes to encourage production the use of credit instruments for banking including rudimentary savings and checking accounts and contract law 72 Among the earliest Muslim economic thinkers was Abu Yusuf 731 798 a student of the founder of the Hanafi Sunni School of Islamic thought Abu Hanifah Abu Yusuf was chief jurist for Abbasid Caliph Harun al Rashid for whom he wrote the Book of Taxation Kitab al Kharaj This book outlined Abu Yusuf s ideas on taxation public finance and agricultural production He discussed proportional tax on produce instead of fixed taxes on property as being superior as an incentive to bring more land into cultivation He also advocated forgiving tax policies which favor the producer and a centralized tax administration to reduce corruption Abu Yusuf favored the use of tax revenues for socioeconomic infrastructure and included discussion of various types of taxes including sales tax death taxes and import tariffs 73 Early discussion of the benefits of division of labor are included in the writings of Qabus al Ghazali al Farabi 873 950 Ibn Sina Avicenna 980 1037 Ibn Miskawayh Nasir al Din al Tusi 1201 74 Ibn Khaldun 1332 1406 and Asaad Davani b 1444 Among them the discussions included division of labor within households societies factories and among nations Farabi notes that each society lacks at least some necessary resources and thus an optimal society can only be achieved where domestic regional and international trade occur and that such trade can be beneficial to all parties involved 74 Ghazali was also noted for his subtle understanding of monetary theory and formulation of another version of Gresham s Law The power of supply and demand was understood to some extent by various early Muslim scholars as well Ibn Taymiyyah illustrates If desire for goods increases while its availability decreases its price rises On the other hand if availability of the good increases and the desire for it decreases the price comes down 75 Ibn Taymiyyah also elaborated on a circumstantial analysis of the market mechanism with a theoretical insight unusual in his time His discourses on the welfare advantages and disadvantages of market regulation and deregulation have an almost contemporary ring to them 76 Ghazali suggests an early version of price inelasticity of demand for certain goods and he and Ibn Miskawayh discuss equilibrium prices 77 better source needed Other important Muslim scholars who wrote about economics include al Mawardi 1075 1158 Ibn Taimiyah 1263 1328 and al Maqrizi Ibn Khaldun edit Main articles Ibn Khaldun and Muqaddimah See also Asabiyyah nbsp Statue of Ibn Khaldoun in Tunis When civilization population increases the available labor again increases In turn luxury again increases in correspondence with the increasing profit and the customs and needs of luxury increase Crafts are created to obtain luxury products The value realized from them increases and as a result profits are again multiplied in the town Production there is thriving even more than before And so it goes with the second and third increase All the additional labor serves luxury and wealth in contrast to the original labor that served the necessity of life 78 Ibn Khaldun on economic growth Perhaps the best known Islamic scholar who wrote about economics was Ibn Khaldun of Tunisia 1332 1406 79 who is considered a forerunner of modern economists 80 81 Ibn Khaldun wrote on economic and political theory in the introduction or Muqaddimah Prolegomena of his History of the World Kitab al Ibar In the book he discussed what he called asabiyya social cohesion which he sourced as the cause of some civilizations becoming great and others not Ibn Khaldun felt that many social forces are cyclic although there can be sudden sharp turns that break the pattern 82 His idea about the benefits of the division of labor also relate to asabiyya the greater the social cohesion the more complex the successful division may be the greater the economic growth He noted that growth and development positively stimulates both supply and demand and that the forces of supply and demand are what determines the prices of goods 83 He also noted macroeconomic forces of population growth human capital development and technological developments effects on development 84 In fact Ibn Khaldun thought that population growth was directly a function of wealth 85 Although he understood that money served as a standard of value a medium of exchange and a preserver of value he did not realize that the value of gold and silver changed based on the forces of supply and demand 86 He also introduced the concept known as the Khaldun Laffer Curve the relationship between tax rates and tax revenue increases as tax rates increase for a while but then the increases in tax rates begin to cause a decrease in tax revenues as the taxes to impose too great a cost to producers in the economy Ibn Khaldun introduced the labor theory of value He described labor as the source of value necessary for all earnings and capital accumulation obvious in the case of craft He argued that even if earning results from something other than a craft the value of the resulting profit and acquired capital must also include the value of the labor by which it was obtained Without labor it would not have been acquired 80 His theory of asabiyyah has often been compared to modern Keynesian economics with Ibn Khaldun s theory clearly containing the concept of the multiplier A crucial difference however is that whereas for John Maynard Keynes it is the middle class s greater propensity to save that is to blame for economic depression for Ibn Khaldun it is the governmental propensity to save at times when investment opportunities do not take up the slack which leads to aggregate demand 87 Another modern economic theory anticipated by Ibn Khaldun is supply side economics 88 He argued that high taxes were often a factor in causing empires to collapse with the result that lower revenue was collected from high rates He wrote 89 It should be known that at the beginning of the dynasty taxation yields a large revenue from small assessments At the end of the dynasty taxation yields a small revenue from large assessments Post colonial era editDuring the modern post colonial era as Western ideas including Western economics began to influence the Muslim world some Muslim writers sought to produce an Islamic discipline of economics In the 1960s and 70s Shia Islamic thinkers worked to develop a unique Islamic economic philosophy with its answers to contemporary economic problems Several works were particularly influential slam VA Malekiyyat Islam and Property by Mahmud Taleqani 1951 Iqtisaduna Our Economics by Mohammad Baqir al Sadr 1961 and Eqtesad e Towhidi The Economics of Divine Harmony by Abolhassan Banisadr 1978 Some Interpretations of Property Rights Capital and Labor from Islamic Perspective by Habibullah Peyman 1979 90 91 Al Sadr in particular has been described as having almost single handedly developed the notion of Islamic economics 92 In their writings Sadr and the other Shia authors sought to depict Islam as a religion committed to social justice the equitable distribution of wealth and the cause of the deprived classes with doctrines acceptable to Islamic jurists while refuting existing non Islamic theories of capitalism and Marxism This version of Islamic economics which influenced the Iranian Revolution called for public ownership of land and large industrial enterprises while private economic activity continued within reasonable limits 93 These ideas helped shape the large public sector and public subsidy policies of the Iranian Islamic revolution In the 1980s and 1990s as the Iranian revolution failed to reach the per capita income level achieved by the regime it overthrew and Communist states and socialist parties in the non Muslim world turned away from socialism Muslim interest shifted away from government ownership and regulation In Iran it is reported that entered e Islami meaning both Islamic economics and economy once a revolutionary shibboleth is indubitably absent in all official documents and the media It disappeared from Iranian political discourse about 15 years ago 1990 91 But in other parts of the Muslim world the term lived on shifting form to the less ambitious goal of interest free banking Some Muslim bankers and religious leaders suggested ways to integrate Islamic law on the usage of money with modern concepts of ethical investing In banking this was done through the use of sales transactions focusing on the fixed rate return modes to achieve similar results to interest This has been criticized by some western writers as a means of covering conventional banking with an Islamic facade Contemporary economics edit See also Female labor force in the Muslim world and Islamic economics in Pakistan In modern times economic policies of the 1979 Islamic Revolution in predominantly Shia Iran were heavily statist with a very large public sector and official rhetoric celebrating revolution and the rights of the dispossessed although this tendency has faded over time 94 In Sudan the policies of the National Islamic Front party dominated regime in the 1990s have been the reverse employing economic liberalism and accepting market forces in the formulation of state policies In Algeria Jordan Egypt and Pakistan Islamist parties have supported populist policies showing a marked reluctance to adopt austerity policies and decreased subsidies 95 In recent years Turkey had a rapidly growing economy and became a developed country according to the CIA 96 Indonesia Saudi Arabia and Turkey are members of the G 20 major economies In 2008 at least 500 billion in assets around the world were managed by Sharia or Islamic law and the sector was growing at more than 10 per year Islamic finance seeks to promote social justice by banning exploitative practices In reality this boils down to a set of prohibitions on paying interest on gambling with derivatives and options and on investing in firms that make pornography or pork 97 Another form of modern finance that originated from the Muslim world is microcredit and microfinance It began in the 1970s in Bangladesh with Grameen Bank founded by Muhammad Yunus recipient of the 2006 Nobel Peace Prize Among 6 representative studies selected from a sample of more than 100 studies as being methodologically most sound five found no evidence that microcredit reduced poverty 98 99 Land reform edit One issue generally absent from contemporary Islamist economic thought except Sayyid Qutb and action whether moderate or radical is the question of agrarian reform Opposition to agrarian reform even played a role in Islamist uprisings Iran 1963 Afghanistan 1978 100 At least one observer Olivier Roy believes this is primarily because it would imply a reexamination of the concept of ownership and in particular throw into question the Waqf endowments whose revenue ensures the functioning of religious institutions 100 In the Islamic Republic of Iran for example waqf holdings are very large in Khorasan Province 50 of the cultivated lands belong to the religious foundation Astan i Quds which oversees the Imam Reza shrine in Mashhad 100 Thus questioning waqf property would mean questioning the foundation of the financial autonomy of the mullahs and mosques particularly among Shia Muslims 100 Islamic stock index edit In June 2005 the Dow Jones Indexes in New York City and RHB Securities in Kuala Lumpur teamed up to launch a new Islamic Malaysia Index a collection of 45 stocks representing Malaysian companies that comply with a variety of Sharia based requirements For example total debt cash plus interest bearing securities and accounts receivables must each be less than 33 of the trailing 12 month average capitalization citation needed Also gambling on derivatives and options and on investing in firms that make pornography or pork are also unacceptable Islamic bonds or sukuk use asset returns to pay investors to comply with the religion s ban on interest and are currently traded privately on the over the counter market In late December 2009 Bursa Malaysia announced it was considering enabling individuals to trade Shariah compliant debt on its exchange as part of a plan to attract new investors 101 See also editIslamic economics Dow Jones Islamic Fund Dow Jones Islamic Index Banks Islamic Development Bank Bank Islam Malaysia Bank Muamalat Malaysia Dubai Islamic Bank Islamic Bank of Britain Meezan Bank Limited Non Bank Finance Institutions Guidance ResidentialReferences edit El Sheikh S 2008 The moral economy of classical Islam a hiqhiconomic model The Muslim World 98 1 p 120 Roy 1994 p 132 Schirazi Asghar Constitution of Iran 1997 p 170 Siegfried N A 2001 Concepts of paper money in Islamic legal thought Arab LQ 16 p 319 Martin Richard C ed 2014 Riba Encyclopedia of Islam and the Muslim World Macmillan Reference USA pp 596 7 ISBN 978 0 02 865912 1 Badr Gamal Moursi Spring 1978 Islamic Law Its Relation to Other Legal Systems The American Journal of Comparative Law 26 2 Proceedings of an International Conference on Comparative Law Salt Lake City Utah February 24 25 1977 The American Journal of Comparative Law Vol 26 No 2 187 198 doi 10 2307 839667 JSTOR 839667 Gaudiosi 1988 Gaudiosi 1988 pp 1237 1240 Gaudiosi 1988 p 1246 Gaudiosi 1988 pp 1246 1247 Gaudiosi 1988 p 1247 Hudson 2003 p 32 Gaudiosi 1988 pp 1244 1245 Micheau 1996 pp 999 1001 Peters Edward Europe and the Middle Ages 1983 p 125 a b c Crone Patricia 2005 Medieval Islamic Political Thought Edinburgh University Press pp 308 309 ISBN 0 7486 2194 6 Shatzmiller 1994 p 263 The Cambridge economic history of Europe p 437 Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 08709 0 Timur Kuran 2005 The Absence of the Corporation in Islamic Law Origins and Persistence American Journal of Comparative Law 53 pp 785 834 798 99 a b c d e Jairus Banaji 2007 Islam the Mediterranean and the rise of capitalism Historical Materialism 15 1 pp 47 74 Brill Publishers a b Robert Sabatino Lopez Irving Woodworth Raymond Olivia Remie Constable 2001 Medieval Trade in the Mediterranean World Illustrative Documents Columbia University Press ISBN 0 231 12357 4 a b Labib 1969 pp 92 93 Ray Spier 2002 The history of the peer review process Trends in Biotechnology 20 8 pp 357 58 357 a b Said Amir Arjomand 1999 The Law Agency and Policy in Medieval Islamic Society Development of the Institutions of Learning from the Tenth to the Fifteenth Century Comparative Studies in Society and History 41 pp 263 93 Cambridge University Press a b Samir Amin 1978 The Arab Nation Some Conclusions and Problems MERIP Reports 68 pp 3 14 8 13 M Shahid Alam 2016 Poverty From The Wealth of Nations Integration and Polarization in the Global Economy since 1760 Springer p 32 ISBN 978 0 333 98564 9 Khandker Hissam 31 July 2015 Which India is claiming to have been colonised The Daily Star Op ed Maddison Angus 2003 Development Centre Studies The World Economy Historical Statistics Historical Statistics OECD Publishing pp 259 261 ISBN 9264104143 a b c Shadi Hamid August 2003 An Islamic Alternative Equality Redistributive Justice and the Welfare State in the Caliphate of Umar Renaissance Monthly Islamic Journal 13 8 archived from the original on 2011 08 25 retrieved 2017 12 23 a b John M Hobson 2004 The Eastern Origins of Western Civilisation p 29 30 Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 54724 5 a b Labib 1969 Roman K Kovalev Alexis C Kaelin 2007 Circulation of Arab Silver in Medieval Afro Eurasia Preliminary Observations History Compass 5 2 pp 560 80 Tyabji Amini 1991 Historical dominance on money changing business In Mohamed Ariff ed The Muslim Private Sector in Southeast Asia Islam and the Economic Development of Southeast Asia Social Issues in Southeast Asia Institute of Southeast Asian Studies ISBN 981 3016 10 8 Andrew M Watson 1983 Agricultural Innovation in the Early Islamic World Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 24711 X Andrew M Watson 1974 The Arab Agricultural Revolution and Its Diffusion 700 1100 The Journal of Economic History 34 1 p 8 35 Decker Michael 2009 Plants and Progress Rethinking the Islamic Agricultural Revolution Journal of World History 20 2 187 206 DOI 10 1353 jwh 0 0058 Ashtor E 1976 A Social and Economic History of the Near East in the Middle Ages Berkeley University of California Press pp 58 63 Coulson p 117 Reaching further back through the centuries the civilizations regarded as having the highest literacy rates of their ages were parent driven educational marketplaces The ability to read and write was far more widely enjoyed in the early medieval Islamic empire and fourth century B C E Athens than in any other cultures of their times Burke 2009 The spread of written knowledge was at least the equal of what it was in China after printing became common there in the tenth century Chinese books were printed in small editions of a hundred or so copies Coulson p 117 In neither case did the state supply or even systematically subsidize educational services The Muslim world s eventual introduction of state funding under Nizam al Mulk in the eleventh century was quickly followed by partisan religious squabbling over education and the gradual fall of Islam from its place of cultural and scientific preeminence Burke 2009 According to legend paper came to the Islamic world as a result of the capture of Chinese papermakers at the 751 C E Battle of Talas River Burke 2009 Whatever the source the diffusion of paper making technology via the lands of Islam produced a shift from oral to scribal culture across the rest of Afroeurasia that was rivaled only by the move from scribal to typographic culture Perhaps it will prove to have been even more important than the recent move from typographic culture to the Internet The result was remarkable As historian Jonathan Bloom informs us paper encouraged an efflorescence of books and written culture incomparably more brilliant than was known anywhere in Europe until the invention of printing with movable type in the fifteenth century Burke 2009 More so than any previously existing society Islamic society of the period 1000 1500 was profoundly a culture of books The emergence of a culture of books is closely tied to cultural dispositions toward literacy in Islamic societies Muslim young men were encouraged to memorize the Qur an as part of their transition to adulthood and while most presumably did not though little is known about literacy levels in pre Mongol Muslim societies others did Types of literacy in any event varied as Nelly Hanna has recently suggested and are best studied as part of the complex social dynamics and contexts of individual Muslim societies The need to conform commercial contracts and business arrangements to Islamic law provided a further impetus for literacy especially likely in commercial centers Scholars often engaged in commercial activity and craftsmen or tradesmen spent time studying in madrasas The connection between what Brian Street has called maktab literacy and commercial literacy was real and exerted a steady pressure on individuals to upgrade their reading skills a b Shatzmiller 1994 pp 402 403 Judith Tucker 1975 Islam and Capitalism by Maxime Rodinson MERIP Reports 34 pp 31 2 31 Labib 1969 pp 81 82 The Cambridge economic history of Europe pp 438 440 Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 08709 0 Heck Gene W 2006 Charlemagne Muhammad and the Arab roots of capitalism Walter de Gruyter ISBN 3 11 019229 2 Nolan Peter 2007 Capitalism and Freedom The Contradictory Character of Globalisation Anthem Press p 277 ISBN 978 1 84331 280 2 Oxford Encyclopedia of the Modern Islamic World New York Oxford University Press 1995 p 19 ISBN 0 19 506613 8 OCLC 94030758 Abu Dharr al Ghifari Oxford Islamic Studies Online Archived from the original on June 18 2013 Retrieved 23 January 2010 And Once Again Abu Dharr retrieved 23 January 2010 Hanna Sami A George H Gardner 1969 Arab Socialism A Documentary Survey Leiden E J Brill p 273 retrieved 23 January 2010 Hanna Sami A 1969 al Takaful al Ijtimai and Islamic Socialism The Muslim World 59 3 4 275 286 doi 10 1111 j 1478 1913 1969 tb02639 x archived from the original on 2010 09 13 retrieved 2010 04 13 a b Adam Robert Lucas 2005 Industrial Milling in the Ancient and Medieval Worlds A Survey of the Evidence for an Industrial Revolution in Medieval Europe Technology and Culture 46 1 pp 1 30 10 Ahmad Y Hassan Transfer Of Islamic Technology To The West Part II Transmission Of Islamic Engineering Archived 2008 02 18 at the Wayback Machine Shatzmiller 1994 pp 47 48 Shatzmiller 1994 pp 6 7 a b c Shatzmiller 1994 pp 400 401 Shatzmiller 1994 pp 350 362 Shatzmiller 1997 pp 175 177 Shatzmiller 1994 pp 169 170 Alatas Syed Farid 2006 From Jami ah to University Multiculturalism and Christian Muslim Dialogue Current Sociology 54 1 112 132 doi 10 1177 0011392106058837 S2CID 144509355 The idea of the degree most likely came from Islam In 931 AD the Abbasid caliph al Muqtadir had all practising physicians examined and those who passed were granted certificates ijazah In this way Baghdad was able to get rid of its quacks Hitti 1970 364 The ijazah was the principal means by which scholars and Sufis passed on their teachings to students granting them permission to carry on their teachings Although the learned scholars of Islam taught in formal institutions of learning such as the maktab the kuttab the madrasah and the jami ah the degree was personally granted by the scholar to the student Avner Greif 1989 Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade Evidence on the Maghribi Traders The Journal of Economic History 49 4 pp 857 82 862 874 Question 18 What Is The Purpose of Jizya Al Islam org Spengler 1964 p 274 Hosseini 2003 p 39 Matthew E Falagas Effie A Zarkadoulia George Samonis August 2006 Arab science in the golden age 750 1258 C E and today The FASEB Journal 20 10 1581 1586 doi 10 1096 fj 06 0803ufm PMID 16873881 a b Hosseini 2003 p 36 Schumpeter 1954 The prevalence and error of Schumpeter s thesis and the importance of Spengler s paper are discussed in Hosseini 2003 Hosseini 2003 p 33 Hosseini 2003 p 34 Farabi Abu Nassr 1982 Madineh Fazeleh Good City Persian translation by Sajadi Teheran Iran Zuhuri p25 Hosseini 2003 p 28 Baeck Louis 1994 The Mediterranean tradition in economic thought Routledge p 99 ISBN 0 415 09301 5 Hosseini 2003 p 38 Weiss 1995 p 30 quotes Muqaddimah 2 272 273 Schumpeter 1954 p 136 mentions his sociology others including Hosseini 2003 emphasize him as well a b I M Oweiss 1988 Ibn Khaldun the Father of Economics Arab Civilization Challenges and Responses New York University Press ISBN 0 88706 698 4 Jean David C Boulakia 1971 Ibn Khaldun A Fourteenth Century Economist The Journal of Political Economy 79 5 1105 1118 Weiss 1995 pp 29 30 Weiss 1995 p 31 quotes Muqaddimah 2 276 278 Weiss 1995 p 31 quotes Muqaddimah 2 272 273 Weiss 1995 p 33 Weiss 1995 p 32 Gellner Ernest 1983 Muslim Society Cambridge University Press pp 34 5 ISBN 0 521 27407 9 Lawrence Bruce B 1983 Introduction Ibn Khaldun and Islamic Ideology Journal of Asian and African Studies XVIII 3 4 154 165 157 amp 164 doi 10 1177 002190968301800302 S2CID 144858781 Bartlett Bruce Supply Side Economics Voodoo Economics or Lasting Contribution PDF Laffer Associates November 11 2003 retrieved 2008 11 17 Bakhash Shaul The Reign of the Ayatollahs Basic Books c 1984 p 167 168 a b Revolutionary Surge and Quiet Demise of Islamic Economics in Iran Archived 2012 01 17 at the Wayback Machine The Renewal of Islamic Law Bakhash Shaul The Reign of the Ayatollahs Basic Books c 1984 p 172 173 Roy 1994 p 138 Fuller Graham E The Future of Political Islam Palgrave MacMillan 2003 p 142 Developed Countries World Factbook CIA Islamic Finance Forbes April 21 2008 Westover J 2008 The Record of Microfinance The Effectiveness Ineffectiveness of Microfinance Programs as a Means of Alleviating Poverty PDF Electronic Journal of Sociology Archived from the original PDF on 2008 10 01 Some studies have found marked decreases in overall poverty levels including declining levels of extreme poverty Khandker 2005 while other studies do not find the same direct effect Morris and Barnes 2005 Kan Olds and Kah 2005 Goetz and Gupta 1996 Still other studies provide mixed results Copestake Bhalotra and Johnson 2001 Morduch 1998 Khandker SR 2005 Microfinance and poverty evidence using panel data from Bangladesh The World Bank Economic Review 19 2 263 286 doi 10 1093 wber lhi008 hdl 10986 16478 S2CID 15335913 a b c d Roy 1994 p 136 Opalesque 30 December 2009 Malaysia exchange reviewing sharia compliant bonds Sources edit Burke Edmund June 2009 Islam at the Center Technological Complexes and the Roots of Modernity Journal of World History 20 2 University of Hawaii Press 165 186 doi 10 1353 jwh 0 0045 S2CID 143484233 Coulson Andrew J Delivering Education PDF Report Hoover Institution pp 105 145 Archived from the original PDF on 2011 08 17 Retrieved 2008 11 22 Gaudiosi Monica M April 1988 The Influence of the Islamic Law of Waqf on the Development of the Trust in England The Case of Merton College University of Pennsylvania Law Review 136 4 University of Pennsylvania Law Review Vol 136 No 4 1231 1261 doi 10 2307 3312162 JSTOR 3312162 Hosseini Hamid S 2003 Contributions of Medieval Muslim Scholars to the History of Economics and their Impact A Refutation of the Schumpeterian Great Gap in Biddle Jeff E Davis Jon B Samuels Warren J eds A Companion to the History of Economic Thought Malden Massachusetts Blackwell pp 28 45 doi 10 1002 9780470999059 ch3 ISBN 0 631 22573 0 Hudson A 2003 Equity and Trusts 3rd ed London Cavendish Publishing ISBN 1 85941 729 9 Labib Subhi Y 1969 Capitalism in Medieval Islam The Journal of Economic History 29 1 79 96 doi 10 1017 S0022050700097837 Micheau Francoise 1996 The Scientific Institutions in the Medieval Near East Encyclopedia of the History of Arabic Science Volume 3 Technology alchemy and life sciences By Morelon Regis Rashid Rushdi ed CRC Press pp 985 1007 ISBN 978 0 415 12412 6 Roy Olivier 1994 The Failure of Political Islam Translated by Carol Volk Harvard University Press Schumpeter Joseph 1954 History of Economic Analysis New York Oxford University Press Shatzmiller Maya 1994 Labour in the Medieval Islamic World Brill Publishers ISBN 90 04 09896 8 Shatzmiller Maya 1997 Women and Wage Labour in the Medieval Islamic West Legal Issues in an Economic Context Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 40 2 174 206 doi 10 1163 1568520972600748 Spengler J Joseph 1964 Economic thought of Islam Ibn Khaldun Comparative Studies in Society and History 6 3 Cambridge University Press 264 306 doi 10 1017 s0010417500002164 JSTOR 177577 Weiss Dieter 1995 Ibn Khaldun on Economic Transformation International Journal of Middle East Studies 27 1 Cambridge University Press 29 37 doi 10 1017 S0020743800061560 JSTOR 176185 Further reading editBadr Gamal M Spring 1989 To the Editor The American Journal of Comparative Law 37 2 The American Journal of Comparative Law Vol 37 No 2 424 425 doi 10 2307 840180 JSTOR 840180 Koehler Benedikt 2014 Early Islam and the Birth of Capitalism Lexington Books ISBN 978 0 7391 8882 8 Kuran Timur 2018 Islam and Economic Performance Historical and Contemporary Links Journal of Economic Literature 56 4 1292 1359 Waleed Addas 2008 Methodology of Economics Secular versus Islamic IqtisadunaExternal links editArticle on Islamic Economy Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title History of Islamic economics amp oldid 1215636236, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

    article

    , read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.