fbpx
Wikipedia

Interest

In finance and economics, interest is payment from a borrower or deposit-taking financial institution to a lender or depositor of an amount above repayment of the principal sum (that is, the amount borrowed), at a particular rate.[1] It is distinct from a fee which the borrower may pay to the lender or some third party. It is also distinct from dividend which is paid by a company to its shareholders (owners) from its profit or reserve, but not at a particular rate decided beforehand, rather on a pro rata basis as a share in the reward gained by risk taking entrepreneurs when the revenue earned exceeds the total costs.[2][3]

A bank sign in Malawi listing the interest rates for deposit accounts at the institution and the base rate for lending money to its customers

For example, a customer would usually pay interest to borrow from a bank, so they pay the bank an amount which is more than the amount they borrowed; or a customer may earn interest on their savings, and so they may withdraw more than they originally deposited. In the case of savings, the customer is the lender, and the bank plays the role of the borrower.

Interest differs from profit, in that interest is received by a lender, whereas profit is received by the owner of an asset, investment or enterprise. (Interest may be part or the whole of the profit on an investment, but the two concepts are distinct from each other from an accounting perspective.)

The rate of interest is equal to the interest amount paid or received over a particular period divided by the principal sum borrowed or lent (usually expressed as a percentage).

Compound interest means that interest is earned on prior interest in addition to the principal. Due to compounding, the total amount of debt grows exponentially, and its mathematical study led to the discovery of the number e.[4] In practice, interest is most often calculated on a daily, monthly, or yearly basis, and its impact is influenced greatly by its compounding rate.

History edit

Credit is thought to have preceded the existence of coinage by several thousands of years. The first recorded instance of credit is a collection of old Sumerian documents from 3000 BC that show systematic use of credit to loan both grain and metals.[5] The rise of interest as a concept is unknown, though its use in Sumeria argue that it was well established as a concept by 3000BC if not earlier, with historians believing that the concept in its modern sense may have arisen from the lease of animal or seeds for productive purposes.[5] The argument that acquired seeds and animals could reproduce themselves was used to justify interest, but ancient Jewish religious prohibitions against usury (נשך NeSheKh) represented a "different view".[6]

The first written evidence of compound interest dates roughly 2400 BC.[7] The annual interest rate was roughly 20%. Compound interest was necessary for the development of agriculture and important for urbanization.[8][dubious ]

While the traditional Middle Eastern views on interest were the result of the urbanized, economically developed character of the societies that produced them, the new Jewish prohibition on interest showed a pastoral, tribal influence.[9] In the early 2nd millennium BC, since silver used in exchange for livestock or grain could not multiply of its own, the Laws of Eshnunna instituted a legal interest rate, specifically on deposits of dowry. Early Muslims called this riba, translated today as the charging of interest.[10]

The First Council of Nicaea, in 325, forbade clergy from engaging in usury[11] which was defined as lending on interest above 1 percent per month (12.7% AER). Ninth-century ecumenical councils applied this regulation to the laity.[11][12] Catholic Church opposition to interest hardened in the era of scholastics, when even defending it was considered a heresy. St. Thomas Aquinas, the leading theologian of the Catholic Church, argued that the charging of interest is wrong because it amounts to "double charging", charging for both the thing and the use of the thing.

In the medieval economy, loans were entirely a consequence of necessity (bad harvests, fire in a workplace) and, under those conditions, it was considered morally reproachable to charge interest.[citation needed] It was also considered morally dubious, since no goods were produced through the lending of money, and thus it should not be compensated, unlike other activities with direct physical output such as blacksmithing or farming.[13] For the same reason, interest has often been looked down upon in Islamic civilization, with almost all scholars agreeing that the Qur'an explicitly forbids charging interest.

Medieval jurists developed several financial instruments to encourage responsible lending and circumvent prohibitions on usury, such as the Contractum trinius.

 
Of Usury, from Brant's Stultifera Navis (the Ship of Fools); woodcut attributed to Albrecht Dürer

In the Renaissance era, greater mobility of people facilitated an increase in commerce and the appearance of appropriate conditions for entrepreneurs to start new, lucrative businesses. Given that borrowed money was no longer strictly for consumption but for production as well, interest was no longer viewed in the same manner.

The first attempt to control interest rates through manipulation of the money supply was made by the Banque de France in 1847.[citation needed]

Islamic finance edit

The latter half of the 20th century saw the rise of interest-free Islamic banking and finance, a movement that applies Islamic law to financial institutions and the economy. Some countries, including Iran, Sudan, and Pakistan, have taken steps to eradicate interest from their financial systems.[14] Rather than charging interest, the interest-free lender shares the risk by investing as a partner in profit loss sharing scheme, because predetermined loan repayment as interest is prohibited, as well as making money out of money is unacceptable. All financial transactions must be asset-backed and it does not charge any interest or fee for the service of lending.

In the history of mathematics edit

It is thought that Jacob Bernoulli discovered the mathematical constant e by studying a question about compound interest.[15] He realized that if an account that starts with $1.00 and pays say 100% interest per year, at the end of the year, the value is $2.00; but if the interest is computed and added twice in the year, the $1 is multiplied by 1.5 twice, yielding $1.00×1.52 = $2.25. Compounding quarterly yields $1.00×1.254 = $2.4414..., and so on.

Bernoulli noticed that if the frequency of compounding is increased without limit, this sequence can be modeled as follows:

 

where n is the number of times the interest is to be compounded in a year.

Economics edit

In economics, the rate of interest is the price of credit, and it plays the role of the cost of capital. In a free market economy, interest rates are subject to the law of supply and demand of the money supply, and one explanation of the tendency of interest rates to be generally greater than zero is the scarcity of loanable funds.

Over centuries, various schools of thought have developed explanations of interest and interest rates. The School of Salamanca justified paying interest in terms of the benefit to the borrower, and interest received by the lender in terms of a premium for the risk of default.[16] In the sixteenth century, Martín de Azpilcueta applied a time preference argument: it is preferable to receive a given good now rather than in the future. Accordingly, interest is compensation for the time the lender forgoes the benefit of spending the money.

On the question of why interest rates are normally greater than zero, in 1770, French economist Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot, Baron de Laune proposed the theory of fructification. By applying an opportunity cost argument, comparing the loan rate with the rate of return on agricultural land, and a mathematical argument, applying the formula for the value of a perpetuity to a plantation, he argued that the land value would rise without limit, as the interest rate approached zero. For the land value to remain positive and finite keeps the interest rate above zero.

Adam Smith, Carl Menger, and Frédéric Bastiat also propounded theories of interest rates.[17] In the late 19th century, Swedish economist Knut Wicksell in his 1898 Interest and Prices elaborated a comprehensive theory of economic crises based upon a distinction between natural and nominal interest rates. In the 1930s, Wicksell's approach was refined by Bertil Ohlin and Dennis Robertson and became known as the loanable funds theory. Other notable interest rate theories of the period are those of Irving Fisher and John Maynard Keynes.

Calculation edit

Simple interest edit

Simple interest is calculated only on the principal amount, or on that portion of the principal amount that remains. It excludes the effect of compounding. Simple interest can be applied over a time period other than a year, for example, every month.

Simple interest is calculated according to the following formula:

 

where

r is the simple annual interest rate
B is the initial balance
m is the number of time periods elapsed and
n is the frequency of applying interest.

For example, imagine that a credit card holder has an outstanding balance of $2500 and that the simple annual interest rate is 12.99% per annum, applied monthly, so the frequency of applying interest is 12 per year. Over one month,

 

interest is due (rounded to the nearest cent).

Simple interest applied over 3 months would be

 

If the card holder pays off only interest at the end of each of the 3 months, the total amount of interest paid would be

 

which is the simple interest applied over 3 months, as calculated above. (The one cent difference arises due to rounding to the nearest cent.)

Compound interest edit

Compound interest includes interest earned on the interest that was previously accumulated.

Compare, for example, a bond paying 6 percent semiannually (that is, coupons of 3 percent twice a year) with a certificate of deposit (GIC) that pays 6 percent interest once a year. The total interest payment is $6 per $100 par value in both cases, but the holder of the semiannual bond receives half the $6 per year after only 6 months (time preference), and so has the opportunity to reinvest the first $3 coupon payment after the first 6 months, and earn additional interest.

For example, suppose an investor buys $10,000 par value of a US dollar bond, which pays coupons twice a year, and that the bond's simple annual coupon rate is 6 percent per year. This means that every 6 months, the issuer pays the holder of the bond a coupon of 3 dollars per 100 dollars par value. At the end of 6 months, the issuer pays the holder:

 

Assuming the market price of the bond is 100, so it is trading at par value, suppose further that the holder immediately reinvests the coupon by spending it on another $300 par value of the bond. In total, the investor therefore now holds:

 

and so earns a coupon at the end of the next 6 months of:

 

Assuming the bond remains priced at par, the investor accumulates at the end of a full 12 months a total value of:

 

and the investor earned in total:

 

The formula for the annual equivalent compound interest rate is:

 

where

r is the simple annual rate of interest
n is the frequency of applying interest

For example, in the case of a 6% simple annual rate, the annual equivalent compound rate is:

 

Other formulations edit

The outstanding balance Bn of a loan after n regular payments increases each period by a growth factor according to the periodic interest, and then decreases by the amount paid p at the end of each period:

 

where

i = simple annual loan rate in decimal form (for example, 10% = 0.10. The loan rate is the rate used to compute payments and balances.)
r = period interest rate (for example, i/12 for monthly payments) [2]
B0 = initial balance, which equals the principal sum

By repeated substitution, one obtains expressions for Bn, which are linearly proportional to B0 and p, and use of the formula for the partial sum of a geometric series results in

 

A solution of this expression for p in terms of B0 and Bn reduces to

 

To find the payment if the loan is to be finished in n payments, one sets Bn = 0.

The PMT function found in spreadsheet programs can be used to calculate the monthly payment of a loan:

 

An interest-only payment on the current balance would be

 

The total interest, IT, paid on the loan is

 

The formulas for a regular savings program are similar, but the payments are added to the balances instead of being subtracted, and the formula for the payment is the negative of the one above. These formulas are only approximate since actual loan balances are affected by rounding. To avoid an underpayment at the end of the loan, the payment must be rounded up to the next cent.

Consider a similar loan but with a new period equal to k periods of the problem above. If rk and pk are the new rate and payment, we now have

 

Comparing this with the expression for Bk above, we note that

 

and

 

The last equation allows us to define a constant that is the same for both problems:

 

and Bk can be written as

 

Solving for rk, we find a formula for rk involving known quantities and Bk, the balance after k periods:

 .

Since B0 could be any balance in the loan, the formula works for any two balances separate by k periods and can be used to compute a value for the annual interest rate.

B* is a scale invariant, since it does not change with changes in the length of the period.

Rearranging the equation for B*, one obtains a transformation coefficient (scale factor):

  (see binomial theorem)

and we see that r and p transform in the same manner:

 
 .

The change in the balance transforms likewise:

 ,

which gives an insight into the meaning of some of the coefficients found in the formulas above. The annual rate, r12, assumes only one payment per year and is not an "effective" rate for monthly payments. With monthly payments, the monthly interest is paid out of each payment and so should not be compounded, and an annual rate of 12·r would make more sense. If one just made interest-only payments, the amount paid for the year would be 12·r·B0.

Substituting pk = rk B* into the equation for the Bk, we obtain

 .

Since Bn = 0, we can solve for B*:

 

Substituting back into the formula for the Bk shows that they are a linear function of the rk and therefore the λk:

 .

This is the easiest way of estimating the balances if the λk are known. Substituting into the first formula for Bk above and solving for λk+1, we obtain

 .

λ0 and λn can be found using the formula for λk above or computing the λk recursively from λ0 = 0 to λn.

Since p = rB*, the formula for the payment reduces to

 

and the average interest rate over the period of the loan is

 

which is less than r if n > 1.

Discount instruments edit

  • US and Canadian T-Bills (short term Government debt) have a different calculation for interest. Their interest is calculated as (100 − P)/P where P is the price paid. Instead of normalizing it to a year, the interest is prorated by the number of days t: (365/t)·100. (See also: Day count convention). The total calculation is ((100 − P)/P)·((365/t)·100). This is equivalent to calculating the price by a process called discounting at a simple interest rate.

Rules of thumb edit

Rule of 78s edit

In the age before electronic computing power was widely available, flat rate consumer loans in the United States of America would be priced using the Rule of 78s, or "sum of digits" method. (The sum of the integers from 1 to 12 is 78.) The technique required only a simple calculation.

Payments remain constant over the life of the loan; however, payments are allocated to interest in progressively smaller amounts. In a one-year loan, in the first month, 12/78 of all interest owed over the life of the loan is due; in the second month, 11/78; progressing to the twelfth month where only 1/78 of all interest is due. The practical effect of the Rule of 78s is to make early pay-offs of term loans more expensive. For a one-year loan, approximately 3/4 of all interest due is collected by the sixth month, and pay-off of the principal then will cause the effective interest rate to be much higher than the APR used to calculate the payments.[18]

In 1992, the United States outlawed the use of "Rule of 78s" interest in connection with mortgage refinancing and other consumer loans over five years in term.[19] Certain other jurisdictions have outlawed application of the Rule of 78s in certain types of loans, particularly consumer loans.[18]

Rule of 72 edit

To approximate how long it takes for money to double at a given interest rate, that is, for accumulated compound interest to reach or exceed the initial deposit, divide 72 by the percentage interest rate. For example, compounding at an annual interest rate of 6 percent, it will take 72/6 = 12 years for the money to double.

The rule provides a good indication for interest rates up to 10%.

In the case of an interest rate of 18 percent, the rule of 72 predicts that money will double after 72/18 = 4 years.

 

In the case of an interest rate of 24 percent, the rule predicts that money will double after 72/24 = 3 years.

 

Market interest rates edit

There are markets for investments (which include the money market, bond market, as well as retail financial institutions like banks) that set interest rates. Each specific debt takes into account the following factors in determining its interest rate:

Opportunity cost and deferred consumption edit

Opportunity cost encompasses any other use to which the money could be put, including lending to others, investing elsewhere, holding cash, or spending the funds.

Charging interest equal to inflation preserves the lender's purchasing power, but does not compensate for the time value of money in real terms. The lender may prefer to invest in another product rather than consume. The return they might obtain from competing investments is a factor in determining the interest rate they demand.

Inflation edit

Since the lender is deferring consumption, they will wish, as a bare minimum, to recover enough to pay the increased cost of goods due to inflation. Because future inflation is unknown, there are three ways this might be achieved:

  • Charge X% interest "plus inflation" Many governments issue "real-return" or "inflation indexed" bonds. The principal amount or the interest payments are continually increased by the rate of inflation. See the discussion at real interest rate.
  • Decide on the "expected" inflation rate. This still leaves the lender exposed to the risk of "unexpected" inflation.
  • Allow the interest rate to be periodically changed. While a "fixed interest rate" remains the same throughout the life of the debt, "variable" or "floating" rates can be reset. There are derivative products that allow for hedging and swaps between the two.

However interest rates are set by the market, and it happens frequently that they are insufficient to compensate for inflation: for example at times of high inflation during, for example, the oil crisis; and during 2011 when real yields on many inflation-linked government stocks are negative.

Default edit

There is always the risk the borrower will become bankrupt, abscond or otherwise default on the loan. The risk premium attempts to measure the integrity of the borrower, the risk of his enterprise succeeding and the security of any collateral pledged. For example, loans to developing countries have higher risk premiums than those to the US government due to the difference in creditworthiness. An operating line of credit to a business will have a higher rate than a mortgage loan.

The creditworthiness of businesses is measured by bond rating services and individual's credit scores by credit bureaus. The risks of an individual debt may have a large standard deviation of possibilities. The lender may want to cover his maximum risk, but lenders with portfolios of debt can lower the risk premium to cover just the most probable outcome.

Composition of interest rates edit

In economics, interest is considered the price of credit, therefore, it is also subject to distortions due to inflation. The nominal interest rate, which refers to the price before adjustment to inflation, is the one visible to the consumer (that is, the interest tagged in a loan contract, credit card statement, etc.). Nominal interest is composed of the real interest rate plus inflation, among other factors. An approximate formula for the nominal interest is:

 

Where

i is the nominal interest rate
r is the real interest rate
and π is inflation.

However, not all borrowers and lenders have access to the same interest rate, even if they are subject to the same inflation. Furthermore, expectations of future inflation vary, so a forward-looking interest rate cannot depend on a single real interest rate plus a single expected rate of inflation.

Interest rates also depend on credit quality or risk of default. Governments are normally highly reliable debtors, and the interest rate on government securities is normally lower than the interest rate available to other borrowers.

The equation:

 

relates expectations of inflation and credit risk to nominal and expected real interest rates, over the life of a loan, where

i is the nominal interest applied
r is the real interest expected
π is the inflation expected and
c is yield spread according to the perceived credit risk.

Default interest edit

Default interest is the rate of interest that a borrower must pay after material breach of a loan covenant.

The default interest is usually much higher than the original interest rate since it is reflecting the aggravation in the financial risk of the borrower. Default interest compensates the lender for the added risk.

From the borrower's perspective, this means failure to make their regular payment for one or two payment periods or failure to pay taxes or insurance premiums for the loan collateral will lead to substantially higher interest for the entire remaining term of the loan.

Banks tend to add default interest to the loan agreements in order to separate between different scenarios.

In some jurisdictions, default interest clauses are unenforceable as against public policy.

Term edit

Shorter terms often have less risk of default and exposure to inflation because the near future is easier to predict. In these circumstances, short-term interest rates are lower than longer-term interest rates (an upward sloping yield curve).

Government intervention edit

Interest rates are generally determined by the market, but government intervention - usually by a central bank - may strongly influence short-term interest rates, and is one of the main tools of monetary policy. The central bank offers to borrow (or lend) large quantities of money at a rate which they determine (sometimes this is money that they have created ex nihilo, that is, printed) which has a major influence on supply and demand and hence on market interest rates.

Open market operations in the United States edit

 
The effective federal funds rate charted over more than fifty years[citation needed]

The Federal Reserve (Fed) implements monetary policy largely by targeting the federal funds rate. This is the rate that banks charge each other for overnight loans of federal funds. Federal funds are the reserves held by banks at the Fed.

Open market operations are one tool within monetary policy implemented by the Federal Reserve to steer short-term interest rates. Using the power to buy and sell treasury securities, the Open Market Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York can supply the market with dollars by purchasing U.S. Treasury notes, hence increasing the nation's money supply. By increasing the money supply or Aggregate Supply of Funding (ASF), interest rates will fall due to the excess of dollars banks will end up with in their reserves. Excess reserves may be lent in the Fed funds market to other banks, thus driving down rates.

Interest rates and credit risk edit

It is increasingly recognized that during the business cycle, interest rates and credit risk are tightly interrelated. The Jarrow-Turnbull model was the first model of credit risk that explicitly had random interest rates at its core. Lando (2004), Darrell Duffie and Singleton (2003), and van Deventer and Imai (2003) discuss interest rates when the issuer of the interest-bearing instrument can default.

Money and inflation edit

Loans and bonds have some of the characteristics of money and are included in the broad money supply.

National governments (provided, of course, that the country has retained its own currency) can influence interest rates and thus the supply and demand for such loans, thus altering the total of loans and bonds issued. Generally speaking, a higher real interest rate reduces the broad money supply.

Through the quantity theory of money, increases in the money supply lead to inflation. This means that interest rates can affect inflation in the future.[20]

Liquidity edit

Liquidity is the ability to quickly re-sell an asset for fair or near-fair value. All else equal, an investor will want a higher return on an illiquid asset than a liquid one, to compensate for the loss of the option to sell it at any time. U.S. Treasury bonds are highly liquid with an active secondary market, while some other debts are less liquid. In the mortgage market, the lowest rates are often issued on loans that can be re-sold as securitized loans. Highly non-traditional loans such as seller financing often carry higher interest rates due to a lack of liquidity.

Theories of interest edit

Aristotle's view of interest edit

Aristotle and the Scholastics held that it was unjust to claim payment except in compensation for one's own efforts and sacrifices, and that since money is by its nature sterile, there is no loss in being temporarily separated from it. Compensation for risk or for the trouble of setting up a loan was not necessarily impermissible on these grounds.[21]

Development of the theory of interest during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries edit

Nicholas Barbon (c.1640–c.1698) described as a "mistake" the view that interest is a monetary value, arguing that because money is typically borrowed to buy assets (goods and stock), the interest that is charged on a loan is a type of rent – "a payment for the use of goods".[22][21][23] According to Schumpeter, Barbon's theories were forgotten until similar views were put forward by Joseph Massie in 1750.[note 1]

In 1752 David Hume published his essay "Of money" which relates interest to the "demand for borrowing", the "riches available to supply that demand" and the "profits arising from commerce". Schumpeter[26][page needed] considered Hume's theory superior to that of Ricardo and Mill, but the reference to profits concentrates to a surprising degree on 'commerce' rather than on industry.

Turgot brought the theory of interest close to its classical form. Industrialists...

... share their profits with capitalists who supply the funds (Réflexions, LXXI). The share that goes to the latter is determined like all other prices (LXXV) by the play of supply and demand amongst borrowers and lenders, so that the analysis is from the outset firmly planted in the general theory of prices.[note 2]

The classical theory of the interest rate edit

The classical theory was the work of a number of authors, including Turgot, Ricardo,[note 3] Mountifort Longfield,[28] J. S. Mill, and Irving Fisher.[29] It was strongly criticised by Keynes[note 4] whose remarks nonetheless made a positive contribution to it.

Mill's theory is set out the chapter "Of the rate of interest" in his "Principles of political economy".[note 5] He says that the interest rate adjusts to maintain equilibrium between the demands for lending and borrowing.[30] Individuals lend in order to defer consumption or for the sake of the greater quantity they will be able to consume at a later date owing to interest earned. They borrow in order to anticipate consumption (whose relative desirability is reflected by the time value of money), but entrepreneurs also borrow to fund investment and governments borrow for their own reasons. The three sources of demand compete for loans.[31]

For entrepreneurial borrowing to be in equilibrium with lending:

The interest for money... is... regulated... by the rate of profits which can be made by the employment of capital...[32]

Ricardo's and Mill's 'profit' is made more precise by the concept of the marginal efficiency of capital (the expression, though not the concept, is due to Keynes[note 6]), which may be defined as the annual revenue which will be yielded by an extra increment of capital as a proportion of its cost. So the interest rate r in equilibrium will be equal to the marginal efficiency of capital r'. Rather than work with r and r' as separate variables, we can assume that they are equal and let the single variable r denote their common value.

 
Classical theory of the determination of the interest rate. The solid red curve in the diagram shows the desired level of saving s as a function of r for the current income .

The investment schedule i (r) shows how much investment is possible with a return of at least r.[note 7] In a stationary economy it is likely to resemble the blue curve in the diagram, with a step shape arising from the assumption that opportunities to invest with yields greater than have been largely exhausted while there is untapped scope to invest with a lower return.[33]

Saving is the excess of deferred over anticipated consumption, and its dependence on income is much as described by Keynes (see The General Theory), but in classical theory definitely an increasing function of r. (The dependence of s on income y was not relevant to classical concerns prior to the development of theories of unemployment.) The rate of interest is given by the intersection of the solid red saving curve with the blue investment schedule. But so long as the investment schedule is almost vertical, a change in income (leading in extreme cases to the broken red saving curve) will make little difference to the interest rate.

In some cases the analysis will be less simple. The introduction of a new technique, leading to demand for new forms of capital, will shift the step to the right and reduce its steepness.[33] Or a sudden increase in the desire to anticipate consumption (perhaps through military spending in time of war) will absorb most available loans; the interest rate will increase and investment will be reduced to the amount whose return exceeds it.[34] This is illustrated by the dotted red saving curve.

Keynes's criticisms edit

In the case of extraordinary spending in time of war the government may wish to borrow more than the public would be willing to lend at a normal interest rate. If the dotted red curve started negative and showed no tendency to increase with r, then the government would be trying to buy what the public was unwilling to sell at any price. Keynes mentions this possibility as a point "which might, perhaps, have warned the classical school that something was wrong" (p. 182).

He also remarks (on the same page) that the classical theory does not explain the usual supposition that "an increase in the quantity of money has a tendency to reduce the rate of interest, at any rate in the first instance".

Keynes's diagram of the investment schecule lacks the step shape which can be seen as part of the classical theory. He objects that

the functions used by classical theory... do not furnish material for a theory of the rate of interest; but they could be used to tell us... what the rate of interest will have to be, if the level of employment [which determines income] is maintained at a given figure.[35]

Later (p. 184) Keynes claims that "it involves a circular argument" to construct a theory of interest from the investment schedule since

the 'marginal efficiency of capital' partly depends on the scale of current investment, and we must already know the rate of interest before we can calculate what this scale will be.

Theories of exploitation, productivity and abstinence edit

The classical theory of interest explains it as the capitalist's share of business profits, but the pre-marginalist authors were unable to reconcile these profits with the labor theory of value (excluding Longfield, who was essentially a marginalist). Their responses often had a moral tone: Ricardo and Marx viewed profits as exploitation, and McCulloch's productivity theory justified profits by portraying capital equipment as an embodiment of accumulated labor.[26][page needed] The theory that interest is a payment for abstinence is attributed to Nassau Senior, and according to Schumpeter[26][page needed] was intended neutrally, but it can easily be understood as making a moral claim and was sharply criticised by Marx and Lassalle.

Wicksell's theory edit

Knut Wicksell published his "Interest and Prices" in 1898, elaborating a comprehensive theory of economic crises based upon a distinction between natural and nominal interest rates.

Wicksell's contribution, in fact, was twofold. First he separated the monetary rate of interest from the hypothetical "natural" rate that would have resulted from equilibrium of capital supply and demand in a barter economy, and he assumed that as a result of the presence of money alone, the effective market rate could fail to correspond to this ideal rate in actuality. Next he supposed that through the mechanism of credit, the rate of interest had an influence on prices; that a rise of the monetary rate above the "natural" level produced a fall, and a decline below that level a rise, in prices. But Wicksell went on to conclude that if the natural rate coincided with the monetary rate, stability of prices would follow.[36]

In the 1930s Wicksell's approach was refined by Bertil Ohlin and Dennis Robertson and became known as the loanable funds theory.

Austrian theories edit

Eugen Böhm von Bawerk and other members of the Austrian School also put forward notable theories of the interest rate.

The doyen of the Austrian school, Murray N. Rothbard, sees the emphasis on the loan market which makes up the general analysis on interest as a mistaken view to take. As he explains in his primary economic work, Man, Economy, and State, the market rate of interest is but a manifestation of the natural phenomenon of time preference, which is to prefer present goods to future goods.[37] To Rothbard,

Too many writers consider the rate of interest as only the price of loans on the loan market. In reality...the rate of interest pervades all time markets, and the productive loan market is a strictly subsidiary time market of only derivative importance.[38]

Interest is explainable by the rate of time preference among the people. To point to the loan market is insufficient at best. Rather, the rate of interest is what would be observed between the "stages of production", indeed a time market itself, where capital goods which are used to make consumers' goods are ordered out further in time away from the final consumers' goods stage of the economy where consumption takes place. It is this spread (between these various stages which will tend toward uniformity), with consumers' goods representing present goods and producers' goods representing future goods, that the real rate of interest is observed. Rothbard has said that

Interest rate is equal to the rate of price spread in the various stages.[38]

Rothbard has furthermore criticized the Keynesian conception of interest, saying

One grave and fundamental Keynesian error is to persist in regarding the interest rate as a contract rate on loans, instead of the price spreads between stages of production.[39]

Pareto's indifference edit

Pareto held that

The interest rate, being one of the many elements of the general system of equilibrium, was, of course, simultaneously determined with all of them so that there was no point at all in looking for any particular element that 'caused' interest.[note 8]

Keynes's theory of the interest rate edit

Interest is one of the main components of the economic theories developed in Keynes's 1936 General theory of employment, interest, and money. In his initial account of liquidity preference (the demand for money) in Chapter 13, this demand is solely a function of the interest rate; and since the supply is given and equilibrium is assumed, the interest rate is determined by the money supply.

In his later account (Chapter 15), interest cannot be separated from other economic variables and needs to be analysed together with them. See The General Theory for details.

In religious contexts edit

Judaism edit

Jews are forbidden from usury in dealing with fellow Jews, and this lending is to be considered tzedakah, or charity. However, there are permissions to charge interest on loans to non-Jews.[41] This is outlined in the Jewish scriptures of the Torah, which Christians hold as part of the Old Testament, and other books of the Tanakh. From the Jewish Publication Society's 1917 Tanakh,[42] with Christian verse numbers, where different, in parentheses:

If thou lend money to any of My people, even to the poor with thee, thou shalt not be to him as a creditor; neither shall ye lay upon him interest.

— Exodus 22:24 (25)

Take thou no interest of him or increase; but fear thy God; that thy brother may live with thee.

— Leviticus 25:36

Thou shalt not give him thy money upon interest, nor give him thy victuals for increase.

— Leviticus 25:37

Thou shalt not lend upon interest to thy brother: interest of money, interest of victuals, interest of any thing that is lent upon interest.

— Deuteronomy 23:20 (19)

Unto a foreigner thou mayest lend upon interest; but unto thy brother thou shalt not lend upon interest; that the LORD thy God may bless thee in all that thou puttest thy hand unto, in the land whither thou goest in to possess it.

— Deuteronomy 23:21 (20)

... that hath withdrawn his hand from the poor, that hath not received interest nor increase, hath executed Mine ordinances, hath walked in My statutes; he shall not die for the iniquity of his father, he shall surely live.

— Ezekiel 18:17

He that putteth not out his money on interest, nor taketh a bribe against the innocent. He that doeth these things shall never be moved.

— Psalm 15:5

Several historical rulings in Jewish law have mitigated the allowances for usury toward non-Jews. For instance, the 15th-century commentator Rabbi Isaac Abrabanel specified that the rubric for allowing interest does not apply to Christians or Muslims, because their faith systems have a common ethical basis originating from Judaism. The medieval commentator Rabbi David Kimchi extended this principle to non-Jews who show consideration for Jews, saying they should be treated with the same consideration when they borrow.[43]

Islam edit

The following quotations are English translations from the Qur'an:

Those who charge usury are in the same position as those controlled by the devil's influence. This is because they claim that usury is the same as commerce. However, God permits commerce, and prohibits usury. Thus, whoever heeds this commandment from his Lord, and refrains from usury, he may keep his past earnings, and his judgment rests with God. As for those who persist in usury, they incur Hell, wherein they abide forever.

— Al-Baqarah 2:275

God condemns usury, and blesses charities. God dislikes every sinning disbeliever. Those who believe and do good works and establish worship and pay the poor-due, their reward is with their Lord and there shall no fear come upon them neither shall they grieve. O you who believe, you shall observe God and refrain from all kinds of usury, if you are believers. If you do not, then expect a war from God and His messenger. But if you repent, you may keep your capitals, without inflicting injustice, or incurring injustice. If the debtor is unable to pay, wait for a better time. If you give up the loan as a charity, it would be better for you, if you only knew.

— Al-Baqarah 2:276–280

O you who believe, you shall not take usury, compounded over and over. Observe God, that you may succeed.

— Al-'Imran 3:130

And for practicing usury, which was forbidden, and for consuming the people's money illicitly. We have prepared for the disbelievers among them painful retribution.

— Al-Nisa 4:161

The usury that is practiced to increase some people's wealth, does not gain anything at God. But if people give to charity, seeking God's pleasure, these are the ones who receive their reward many fold.

— Ar-Rum 30:39

The attitude of Muhammad to usury is articulated in his Last Sermon:

O People, just as you regard this month, this day, this city as Sacred, so regard the life and property of every Muslim as a sacred trust. Return the goods entrusted to you to their rightful owners. Hurt no one so that no one may hurt you. Remember that you will indeed meet your Lord, and that He will indeed reckon your deeds. Allah has forbidden you to take usury, therefore all usurious obligation shall henceforth be waived. Your capital, however, is yours to keep. You will neither inflict nor suffer any inequity. Allah has Judged that there shall be no usury and that all the usury due to Abbas ibn 'Abd'al Muttalib (Prophet's uncle) shall henceforth be waived ...[44][unreliable source?]

Christianity edit

 
Christ drives the Usurers out of the Temple, a woodcut by Lucas Cranach the Elder in Passionary of Christ and Antichrist[45]

The Old Testament "condemns the practice of charging interest because a loan should be an act of compassion and taking care of one's neighbor"; it teaches that "making a profit off a loan is exploiting that person and dishonoring God's covenant (Exodus 22:25–27)".[46]

The first of the scholastic Christian theologians, Saint Anselm of Canterbury, led the shift in thought that labeled charging interest the same as theft.[citation needed] Previously usury had been seen as a lack of charity.

St. Thomas Aquinas, the leading scholastic theologian of the Roman Catholic Church, argued charging of interest is wrong because it amounts to "double charging", charging for both the thing and the use of the thing. Aquinas said this would be morally wrong in the same way as if one sold a bottle of wine, charged for the bottle of wine, and then charged for the person using the wine to actually drink it.[47] Similarly, one cannot charge for a piece of cake and for the eating of the piece of cake. Yet this, said Aquinas, is what usury does. Money is a medium of exchange, and is used up when it is spent. To charge for the money and for its use (by spending) is therefore to charge for the money twice. It is also to sell time since the usurer charges, in effect, for the time that the money is in the hands of the borrower. Time, however, is not a commodity that anyone can charge. In condemning usury Aquinas was much influenced by the recently rediscovered philosophical writings of Aristotle and his desire to assimilate Greek philosophy with Christian theology. Aquinas argued that in the case of usury, as in other aspects of Christian revelation, Christian doctrine is reinforced by Aristotelian natural law rationalism. Aristotle's argument is that interest is unnatural, since money, as a sterile element, cannot naturally reproduce itself. Thus, usury conflicts with natural law just as it offends Christian revelation: see Thought of Thomas Aquinas. As such, Aquinas taught that interest is inherently unjust and one who charges interest sins.[46]

Outlawing usury did not prevent investment, but stipulated that in order for the investor to share in the profit he must share the risk. In short he must be a joint-venturer. Simply to invest the money and expect it to be returned regardless of the success of the venture was to make money simply by having money and not by taking any risk or by doing any work or by any effort or sacrifice at all, which is usury. St Thomas quotes Aristotle as saying that "to live by usury is exceedingly unnatural". Islam likewise condemns usury but allowed commerce (Al-Baqarah 2:275) – an alternative that suggests investment and sharing of profit and loss instead of sharing only profit through interests. Judaism condemns usury towards Jews, but allows it towards non-Jews (Deut. 23:19–20). St Thomas allows, however, charges for actual services provided. Thus a banker or credit-lender could charge for such actual work or effort as he did carry out, for example, any fair administrative charges. The Catholic Church, in a decree of the Fifth Council of the Lateran, expressly allowed such charges in respect of credit-unions run for the benefit of the poor known as "montes pietatis".[48]

In the 13th century Cardinal Hostiensis enumerated thirteen situations in which charging interest was not immoral.[49] The most important of these was lucrum cessans (profits given up) which allowed for the lender to charge interest "to compensate him for profit foregone in investing the money himself".[50] This idea is very similar to opportunity cost. Many scholastic thinkers who argued for a ban on interest charges also argued for the legitimacy of lucrum cessans profits (for example, Pierre Jean Olivi and St. Bernardino of Siena). However, Hostiensis' exceptions, including for lucrum cessans, were never accepted as official by the Roman Catholic Church.

The Westminster Confession of Faith, a confession of faith upheld by the Reformed Churches, teaches that usury--charging interest at any rate--is a sin prohibited by the eighth commandment.[51]

The Roman Catholic Church has always condemned usury, but in modern times, with the rise of capitalism and the disestablishment of the Catholic Church in majority Catholic countries, this prohibition on usury has not been enforced.

Pope Benedict XIV's encyclical Vix Pervenit gives the reasons why usury is sinful:[52]

The nature of the sin called usury has its proper place and origin in a loan contract ... [which] demands, by its very nature, that one return to another only as much as he has received. The sin rests on the fact that sometimes the creditor desires more than he has given ..., but any gain which exceeds the amount he gave is illicit and usurious. One cannot condone the sin of usury by arguing that the gain is not great or excessive, but rather moderate or small; neither can it be condoned by arguing that the borrower is rich; nor even by arguing that the money borrowed is not left idle, but is spent usefully ...[53]

The Congregation of the Missionary Sons of the Immaculate Heart of Mary, a Catholic Christian religious order, thus teaches that:[46]

It might initially seem like little is at stake when it comes to interest, but this is an issue of human dignity. A person is made in God's own image and therefore may never be treated as a thing. Interest can diminish the human person to a thing to be manipulated for money. In an article for The Catholic Worker, Dorothy Day articulated this well: "Can I talk about the people living off usury . . . not knowing the way that their infertile money has bred more money by wise investment in God knows what devilish nerve gas, drugs, napalm, missiles, or vanities, when housing and employment . . . for the poor were needed, and money could have been invested there?" Her thoughts were a precursor to what Pope Francis now calls an "economy that kills." To sin is to say "no" to God and God's presence by harming others, ourselves, or all of creation. Charging interest is indeed sinful when doing so takes advantage of a person in need as well as when it means investing in corporations involved in the harming of God's creatures.[46]

See also edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ "Barbon's Discourse, on this point at all events, did not meet with success. The tract seems indeed to have been forgotten very soon. Thus, Barbon's fundamental idea remained in abeyance until 1750, when it was again expounded—for all we know, independently rediscovered—by Massie,[24] whose analysis not only went further than Barbon's but also gathered force from its criticism of the views of Petty and Locke."[25]
  2. ^ Schumpeter;[27] the references are to paragraph numbers in Turgot's "Réflexions sur la formation et la distribution des richesses" written in 1766, first published in 1769-70 in a journal, and then separately in 1776.
  3. ^ Isolated remarks in the chapters "Effects of accumulation on profits and interest" and "On currency and banks" in "Principles of political economy and taxation"
  4. ^ "The general theory of employment, interest and money", especially the appendix to Chapter 14. Page numbers refer to the widely available edition published by Macmillan for the Royal Economic Society as part of Keynes's collected writings, which appear to correspond to those of the first edition.
  5. ^ See also his chapters "Of the law of the increase of capital" and "Of profits"
  6. ^ Chapter 11 of The General Theory is titled "The Marginal Efficiency of Capital." Marshall used the term marginal utility of capital and Fisher rate of return over cost. Fisher also referred to it as representing the "investment opportunity side of interest theory".
  7. ^ Keynes called this function the 'schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital' and also the 'investment demand schedule'.
  8. ^ Unsourced observation in Schumpeter[40]
  1. ^ . English Oxford Living Dictionaries. Oxford University Press. Archived from the original on December 27, 2017. Retrieved 27 December 2017. Money paid regularly at a particular rate for the use of money lent, or for delaying the repayment of a debt.
  2. ^ "Definition of dividend". Merriam Webster. from the original on 27 December 2017. Retrieved 27 December 2017. a share in a pro rata distribution (as of profits) to stockholders.
  3. ^ "Profit". Economics Online. from the original on 27 December 2017. Retrieved 27 December 2017.
  4. ^ O'Connor, J J. "The number e". MacTutor History of Mathematics. from the original on 2 October 2012. Retrieved 26 August 2012.
  5. ^ a b Sylla, Richard (2011). A History of Interest Rates. Wiley. p. 17. ISBN 9781118046227.
  6. ^ Johnson, Paul: A History of the Jews (New York: HarperCollins Publishers, 1987) ISBN 0-06-091533-1, pp. 172–73.
  7. ^ "How the world's first accountants counted on cuneiform". BBC World Service. 12 June 2017. from the original on 27 May 2023. Retrieved 10 December 2018.
  8. ^ "A Simple Math Formula Is Basically Responsible For All Of Modern Civilization". Business Insider. 5 June 2013. from the original on 11 December 2018. Retrieved 10 December 2018.
  9. ^ Gnuse, Robert (2011-08-05). You Shall Not Steal: Community and Property in the Biblical Tradition. Wipf and Stock Publishers. ISBN 9781610975803.
  10. ^ . www.islamic-banking.com. Archived from the original on 2018-06-21. Retrieved 2015-10-12.
  11. ^ a b Conrad Henry Moehlman (1934). The Christianization of Interest. Church History, 3, p 6. doi:10.2307/3161033.
  12. ^ Noonan, John T., Jr. 1993. "Development of Moral Doctrine." 54 Theological Stud. 662.
  13. ^ "No. 2547: Charging Interest". from the original on 2011-05-03. Retrieved 2010-01-11.
  14. ^ Anwer, Zaheer; Khan, Shabeer; Abu Bakar, Muhammad (2020-01-01). "Sharīʿah-compliant central banking practices: lessons from Muslim countries' experience". ISRA International Journal of Islamic Finance. 12 (1): 7–26. doi:10.1108/IJIF-01-2019-0007. ISSN 0128-1976. S2CID 216217732.
  15. ^ O'Connor, J J; Robertson, E F. . MacTutor History of Mathematics. Archived from the original on 2008-08-28.
  16. ^ Izbicki, Thomas; Kaufmann, Matthias (2019), "School of Salamanca", in Zalta, Edward N. (ed.), The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Summer 2019 ed.), Metaphysics Research Lab, Stanford University, from the original on 2022-06-29, retrieved 2022-06-29
  17. ^ Bohm-Bawerk, E. (1884) Capital and Interest: A Critical History of Economic Theory 2017-12-30 at the Wayback Machine.
  18. ^ a b "Rule of 78 – Watch out for this auto loan trick". from the original on 2016-11-29. Retrieved 2016-11-28.
  19. ^ 15 U.S.C. § 1615
  20. ^ "What's the Relationship Between Inflation and Interest Rates?". PBS NewsHour. 2009-06-23. from the original on 2021-01-24. Retrieved 2020-08-31.
  21. ^ a b Schumpeter 1954, p. 61.
  22. ^ Barbon, "A discourse of trade", 1690
  23. ^ William Letwin, "Origins of Scientific Economics: English Economic Thought, 1660–1776".
  24. ^ Massie, Joseph (1750). Essay on the Governing Causes of the Natural Rate of Interest.
  25. ^ Schumpeter 1954, p. 314.
  26. ^ a b c Schumpeter 1954.
  27. ^ Schumpeter 1954, p. 316.
  28. ^ "Lectures on political economy", IX.
  29. ^ "The rate of interest", 1907.
  30. ^ "Of the rate of interest", §1.
  31. ^ §2.
  32. ^ Ricardo, chapter "On currency and banks"
  33. ^ a b Mill §3; Longfield.
  34. ^ §3.
  35. ^ p181.
  36. ^ Étienne Mantoux, "Mr Keynes' General Theory", Revue d'Économie Politique, 1937, tr. in Henry Hazlitt, "The critics of Keynesian economics", 1960.
  37. ^ Rothbard 2001.
  38. ^ a b Rothbard 2001, p. 371.
  39. ^ Rothbard 2001, p. 789.
  40. ^ Schumpeter 1954, p. 892.
  41. ^ Robinson, George. "Interest-Free Loans in Judaism". from the original on 5 March 2021. Retrieved 12 March 2015.
  42. ^ "A Hebrew – English Bible According to the Masoretic Text and the JPS 1917 Edition". from the original on 10 February 2009. Retrieved 4 January 2013.
  43. ^ "Encyclopedia Judaica: Moneylending". Jewish Virtual Library. 2008. from the original on October 16, 2021. Retrieved October 16, 2017.
  44. ^ "IslamiCity.com - Mosque - The Prophet Muhammad's (PBUH) Last Sermon". www.islamicity.com. from the original on 2019-01-29. Retrieved 2019-01-24.
  45. ^ The references cited in the Passionary for this woodcut: 1 John 2:14–16, Matthew 10:8, and The Apology of the Augsburg Confession, Article 8, Of the Church 2010-07-15 at the Wayback Machine
  46. ^ a b c d Considine, Kevin P. (2016). "Is it sinful to charge interest on a loan?". U.S. Catholic. from the original on 29 July 2020. Retrieved 4 June 2020.
  47. ^ Thomas Aquinas. Summa Theologica, "Of Cheating, Which Is Committed in Buying and Selling". Translated by The Fathers of the English Dominican Province. pp. 1–10 [1] 2016-03-03 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved June 19, 2012
  48. ^ Session Ten: On the reform of credit organisations (Montes pietatis). Fifth Lateran Council. Rome, Italy: Catholic Church. 4 May 1515. Retrieved 2008-04-05.
  49. ^ Roover, Raymond (Autumn 1967). "The Scholastics, Usury, and Foreign Exchange". Business History Review. The Business History Review, Vol. 41, No. 3. 41 (3): 257–271. doi:10.2307/3112192. JSTOR 3112192. S2CID 154706783.
  50. ^ Rothbard 2001, p. 46
  51. ^ Cox, Robert (1853). Sabbath Laws and Sabbath Duties: Considered in Relation to Their Natural and Scriptural Grounds, and to the Principles of Religious Liberty. Maclachlan and Stewart. p. 180.
  52. ^ See also: Church and the Usurers: Unprofitable Lending for the Modern Economy 2015-10-17 at the Wayback Machine by Dr. Brian McCall 2013-12-06 at the Wayback Machine or Interest and Usury 2019-08-28 at the Wayback Machine by Fr. Bernard W. Dempsey, S.J. 2019-01-25 at the Wayback Machine (1903–1960).)
  53. ^ "Vix Pervenit - Papal Encyclicals". 1 November 1745. from the original on 7 September 2021. Retrieved 24 January 2019.

References edit

  • Duffie, Darrell and Kenneth J. Singleton (2003). Credit Risk: Pricing, Measurement, and Management. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-09046-7.
  • Kellison, Stephen G. (1970). The Theory of Interest. Richard D. Irwin, Inc. Library of Congress Catalog Card No. 79-98251.
  • Lando, David (2004). Credit Risk Modeling: Theory and Applications. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-08929-4.
  • van Deventer, Donald R. and Kenji Imai (2003). Credit Risk Models and the Basel Accords. John Wiley & Sons. ISBN 978-0-470-82091-9.
  • Rothbard, Murray N. (2001). Man, economy, and state : a treatise on economic principles (Rev ed.). Auburn, Alabama: Mises Institute. ISBN 0945466323. OCLC 47279566.
  • Schumpeter, Joseph (1954). History of Economic Analysis. Allen & Unwin.

External links edit

  • White Paper: More than Math, The Lost Art of Interest calculation
  • Financial Services Authority (UK)
  • List of current interest rates:
  • Deposit Rates in European Countries

interest, other, uses, disambiguation, finance, economics, interest, payment, from, borrower, deposit, taking, financial, institution, lender, depositor, amount, above, repayment, principal, that, amount, borrowed, particular, rate, distinct, from, which, borr. For other uses see Interest disambiguation In finance and economics interest is payment from a borrower or deposit taking financial institution to a lender or depositor of an amount above repayment of the principal sum that is the amount borrowed at a particular rate 1 It is distinct from a fee which the borrower may pay to the lender or some third party It is also distinct from dividend which is paid by a company to its shareholders owners from its profit or reserve but not at a particular rate decided beforehand rather on a pro rata basis as a share in the reward gained by risk taking entrepreneurs when the revenue earned exceeds the total costs 2 3 A bank sign in Malawi listing the interest rates for deposit accounts at the institution and the base rate for lending money to its customersFor example a customer would usually pay interest to borrow from a bank so they pay the bank an amount which is more than the amount they borrowed or a customer may earn interest on their savings and so they may withdraw more than they originally deposited In the case of savings the customer is the lender and the bank plays the role of the borrower Interest differs from profit in that interest is received by a lender whereas profit is received by the owner of an asset investment or enterprise Interest may be part or the whole of the profit on an investment but the two concepts are distinct from each other from an accounting perspective The rate of interest is equal to the interest amount paid or received over a particular period divided by the principal sum borrowed or lent usually expressed as a percentage Compound interest means that interest is earned on prior interest in addition to the principal Due to compounding the total amount of debt grows exponentially and its mathematical study led to the discovery of the number e 4 In practice interest is most often calculated on a daily monthly or yearly basis and its impact is influenced greatly by its compounding rate Contents 1 History 1 1 Islamic finance 1 2 In the history of mathematics 2 Economics 3 Calculation 3 1 Simple interest 3 2 Compound interest 3 3 Other formulations 4 Discount instruments 5 Rules of thumb 5 1 Rule of 78s 5 2 Rule of 72 6 Market interest rates 6 1 Opportunity cost and deferred consumption 6 2 Inflation 6 3 Default 6 4 Composition of interest rates 6 5 Default interest 6 6 Term 6 7 Government intervention 6 8 Open market operations in the United States 6 9 Interest rates and credit risk 6 10 Money and inflation 6 11 Liquidity 7 Theories of interest 7 1 Aristotle s view of interest 7 2 Development of the theory of interest during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries 7 3 The classical theory of the interest rate 7 3 1 Keynes s criticisms 7 4 Theories of exploitation productivity and abstinence 7 5 Wicksell s theory 7 6 Austrian theories 7 7 Pareto s indifference 7 8 Keynes s theory of the interest rate 8 In religious contexts 8 1 Judaism 8 2 Islam 8 3 Christianity 9 See also 10 Notes 11 References 12 External linksHistory editFurther information Compound interest History Credit is thought to have preceded the existence of coinage by several thousands of years The first recorded instance of credit is a collection of old Sumerian documents from 3000 BC that show systematic use of credit to loan both grain and metals 5 The rise of interest as a concept is unknown though its use in Sumeria argue that it was well established as a concept by 3000BC if not earlier with historians believing that the concept in its modern sense may have arisen from the lease of animal or seeds for productive purposes 5 The argument that acquired seeds and animals could reproduce themselves was used to justify interest but ancient Jewish religious prohibitions against usury נשך NeSheKh represented a different view 6 The first written evidence of compound interest dates roughly 2400 BC 7 The annual interest rate was roughly 20 Compound interest was necessary for the development of agriculture and important for urbanization 8 dubious discuss While the traditional Middle Eastern views on interest were the result of the urbanized economically developed character of the societies that produced them the new Jewish prohibition on interest showed a pastoral tribal influence 9 In the early 2nd millennium BC since silver used in exchange for livestock or grain could not multiply of its own the Laws of Eshnunna instituted a legal interest rate specifically on deposits of dowry Early Muslims called this riba translated today as the charging of interest 10 The First Council of Nicaea in 325 forbade clergy from engaging in usury 11 which was defined as lending on interest above 1 percent per month 12 7 AER Ninth century ecumenical councils applied this regulation to the laity 11 12 Catholic Church opposition to interest hardened in the era of scholastics when even defending it was considered a heresy St Thomas Aquinas the leading theologian of the Catholic Church argued that the charging of interest is wrong because it amounts to double charging charging for both the thing and the use of the thing In the medieval economy loans were entirely a consequence of necessity bad harvests fire in a workplace and under those conditions it was considered morally reproachable to charge interest citation needed It was also considered morally dubious since no goods were produced through the lending of money and thus it should not be compensated unlike other activities with direct physical output such as blacksmithing or farming 13 For the same reason interest has often been looked down upon in Islamic civilization with almost all scholars agreeing that the Qur an explicitly forbids charging interest Medieval jurists developed several financial instruments to encourage responsible lending and circumvent prohibitions on usury such as the Contractum trinius nbsp Of Usury from Brant s Stultifera Navis the Ship of Fools woodcut attributed to Albrecht DurerIn the Renaissance era greater mobility of people facilitated an increase in commerce and the appearance of appropriate conditions for entrepreneurs to start new lucrative businesses Given that borrowed money was no longer strictly for consumption but for production as well interest was no longer viewed in the same manner The first attempt to control interest rates through manipulation of the money supply was made by the Banque de France in 1847 citation needed Islamic finance edit Main article Islamic banking and finance The latter half of the 20th century saw the rise of interest free Islamic banking and finance a movement that applies Islamic law to financial institutions and the economy Some countries including Iran Sudan and Pakistan have taken steps to eradicate interest from their financial systems 14 Rather than charging interest the interest free lender shares the risk by investing as a partner in profit loss sharing scheme because predetermined loan repayment as interest is prohibited as well as making money out of money is unacceptable All financial transactions must be asset backed and it does not charge any interest or fee for the service of lending In the history of mathematics edit It is thought that Jacob Bernoulli discovered the mathematical constant e by studying a question about compound interest 15 He realized that if an account that starts with 1 00 and pays say 100 interest per year at the end of the year the value is 2 00 but if the interest is computed and added twice in the year the 1 is multiplied by 1 5 twice yielding 1 00 1 52 2 25 Compounding quarterly yields 1 00 1 254 2 4414 and so on Bernoulli noticed that if the frequency of compounding is increased without limit this sequence can be modeled as follows lim n 1 1 n n e displaystyle lim n rightarrow infty left 1 dfrac 1 n right n e nbsp where n is the number of times the interest is to be compounded in a year Economics editIn economics the rate of interest is the price of credit and it plays the role of the cost of capital In a free market economy interest rates are subject to the law of supply and demand of the money supply and one explanation of the tendency of interest rates to be generally greater than zero is the scarcity of loanable funds Over centuries various schools of thought have developed explanations of interest and interest rates The School of Salamanca justified paying interest in terms of the benefit to the borrower and interest received by the lender in terms of a premium for the risk of default 16 In the sixteenth century Martin de Azpilcueta applied a time preference argument it is preferable to receive a given good now rather than in the future Accordingly interest is compensation for the time the lender forgoes the benefit of spending the money On the question of why interest rates are normally greater than zero in 1770 French economist Anne Robert Jacques Turgot Baron de Laune proposed the theory of fructification By applying an opportunity cost argument comparing the loan rate with the rate of return on agricultural land and a mathematical argument applying the formula for the value of a perpetuity to a plantation he argued that the land value would rise without limit as the interest rate approached zero For the land value to remain positive and finite keeps the interest rate above zero Adam Smith Carl Menger and Frederic Bastiat also propounded theories of interest rates 17 In the late 19th century Swedish economist Knut Wicksell in his 1898 Interest and Prices elaborated a comprehensive theory of economic crises based upon a distinction between natural and nominal interest rates In the 1930s Wicksell s approach was refined by Bertil Ohlin and Dennis Robertson and became known as the loanable funds theory Other notable interest rate theories of the period are those of Irving Fisher and John Maynard Keynes Calculation editSimple interest edit Simple interest is calculated only on the principal amount or on that portion of the principal amount that remains It excludes the effect of compounding Simple interest can be applied over a time period other than a year for example every month Simple interest is calculated according to the following formula r B m n displaystyle frac r cdot B cdot m n nbsp where r is the simple annual interest rate B is the initial balance m is the number of time periods elapsed and n is the frequency of applying interest For example imagine that a credit card holder has an outstanding balance of 2500 and that the simple annual interest rate is 12 99 per annum applied monthly so the frequency of applying interest is 12 per year Over one month 0 1299 2500 12 27 06 displaystyle frac 0 1299 times 2500 12 27 06 nbsp interest is due rounded to the nearest cent Simple interest applied over 3 months would be 0 1299 2500 3 12 81 19 displaystyle frac 0 1299 times 2500 times 3 12 81 19 nbsp If the card holder pays off only interest at the end of each of the 3 months the total amount of interest paid would be 0 1299 2500 12 3 27 06 per month 3 months 81 18 displaystyle frac 0 1299 times 2500 12 times 3 27 06 text per month times 3 text months 81 18 nbsp which is the simple interest applied over 3 months as calculated above The one cent difference arises due to rounding to the nearest cent Compound interest edit Main article Compound interest See also Rate of return Compound interest includes interest earned on the interest that was previously accumulated Compare for example a bond paying 6 percent semiannually that is coupons of 3 percent twice a year with a certificate of deposit GIC that pays 6 percent interest once a year The total interest payment is 6 per 100 par value in both cases but the holder of the semiannual bond receives half the 6 per year after only 6 months time preference and so has the opportunity to reinvest the first 3 coupon payment after the first 6 months and earn additional interest For example suppose an investor buys 10 000 par value of a US dollar bond which pays coupons twice a year and that the bond s simple annual coupon rate is 6 percent per year This means that every 6 months the issuer pays the holder of the bond a coupon of 3 dollars per 100 dollars par value At the end of 6 months the issuer pays the holder r B m n 6 10 000 1 2 300 displaystyle frac r cdot B cdot m n frac 6 times 10 000 times 1 2 300 nbsp Assuming the market price of the bond is 100 so it is trading at par value suppose further that the holder immediately reinvests the coupon by spending it on another 300 par value of the bond In total the investor therefore now holds 10 000 300 1 r n B 1 6 2 10 000 displaystyle 10 000 300 left 1 frac r n right cdot B left 1 frac 6 2 right times 10 000 nbsp and so earns a coupon at the end of the next 6 months of r B m n 6 10 000 300 2 6 1 6 2 10 000 2 309 displaystyle begin aligned frac r cdot B cdot m n amp frac 6 times left 10 000 300 right 2 amp frac 6 times left 1 frac 6 2 right times 10 000 2 amp 309 end aligned nbsp Assuming the bond remains priced at par the investor accumulates at the end of a full 12 months a total value of 10 000 300 309 10 000 6 10 000 2 6 1 6 2 10 000 2 10 000 1 6 2 2 displaystyle begin aligned 10 000 300 309 amp 10 000 frac 6 times 10 000 2 frac 6 times left 1 frac 6 2 right times 10 000 2 amp 10 000 times left 1 frac 6 2 right 2 end aligned nbsp and the investor earned in total 10 000 1 6 2 2 10 000 10 000 1 6 2 2 1 displaystyle begin aligned 10 000 times left 1 frac 6 2 right 2 10 000 10 000 times left left 1 frac 6 2 right 2 1 right end aligned nbsp The formula for the annual equivalent compound interest rate is 1 r n n 1 displaystyle left 1 frac r n right n 1 nbsp where r is the simple annual rate of interest n is the frequency of applying interestFor example in the case of a 6 simple annual rate the annual equivalent compound rate is 1 6 2 2 1 1 03 2 1 6 09 displaystyle left 1 frac 6 2 right 2 1 1 03 2 1 6 09 nbsp Other formulations edit The outstanding balance Bn of a loan after n regular payments increases each period by a growth factor according to the periodic interest and then decreases by the amount paid p at the end of each period B n 1 r B n 1 p displaystyle B n big 1 r big B n 1 p nbsp where i simple annual loan rate in decimal form for example 10 0 10 The loan rate is the rate used to compute payments and balances r period interest rate for example i 12 for monthly payments 2 B0 initial balance which equals the principal sumBy repeated substitution one obtains expressions for Bn which are linearly proportional to B0 and p and use of the formula for the partial sum of a geometric series results in B n 1 r n B 0 1 r n 1 r p displaystyle B n 1 r n B 0 frac 1 r n 1 r p nbsp A solution of this expression for p in terms of B0 and Bn reduces to p r 1 r n B 0 B n 1 r n 1 displaystyle p r left frac 1 r n B 0 B n 1 r n 1 right nbsp To find the payment if the loan is to be finished in n payments one sets Bn 0 The PMT function found in spreadsheet programs can be used to calculate the monthly payment of a loan p P M T rate num PV FV P M T r n B 0 B n displaystyle p mathrm PMT text rate text num text PV text FV mathrm PMT r n B 0 B n nbsp An interest only payment on the current balance would be p I r B displaystyle p I rB nbsp The total interest IT paid on the loan is I T n p B 0 displaystyle I T np B 0 nbsp The formulas for a regular savings program are similar but the payments are added to the balances instead of being subtracted and the formula for the payment is the negative of the one above These formulas are only approximate since actual loan balances are affected by rounding To avoid an underpayment at the end of the loan the payment must be rounded up to the next cent Consider a similar loan but with a new period equal to k periods of the problem above If rk and pk are the new rate and payment we now have B k B 0 1 r k B 0 p k displaystyle B k B 0 1 r k B 0 p k nbsp Comparing this with the expression for Bk above we note that r k 1 r k 1 displaystyle r k 1 r k 1 nbsp and p k p r r k displaystyle p k frac p r r k nbsp The last equation allows us to define a constant that is the same for both problems B p r p k r k displaystyle B frac p r frac p k r k nbsp and Bk can be written as B k 1 r k B 0 r k B displaystyle B k 1 r k B 0 r k B nbsp Solving for rk we find a formula for rk involving known quantities and Bk the balance after k periods r k B 0 B k B B 0 displaystyle r k frac B 0 B k B B 0 nbsp Since B0 could be any balance in the loan the formula works for any two balances separate by k periods and can be used to compute a value for the annual interest rate B is a scale invariant since it does not change with changes in the length of the period Rearranging the equation for B one obtains a transformation coefficient scale factor l k p k p r k r 1 r k 1 r k 1 k 1 r 2 displaystyle lambda k frac p k p frac r k r frac 1 r k 1 r k left 1 frac k 1 r 2 cdots right nbsp see binomial theorem and we see that r and p transform in the same manner r k l k r displaystyle r k lambda k r nbsp p k l k p displaystyle p k lambda k p nbsp The change in the balance transforms likewise D B k B B l k r B l k p l k D B displaystyle Delta B k B B lambda k rB lambda k p lambda k Delta B nbsp which gives an insight into the meaning of some of the coefficients found in the formulas above The annual rate r12 assumes only one payment per year and is not an effective rate for monthly payments With monthly payments the monthly interest is paid out of each payment and so should not be compounded and an annual rate of 12 r would make more sense If one just made interest only payments the amount paid for the year would be 12 r B0 Substituting pk rk B into the equation for the Bk we obtain B k B 0 r k B B 0 displaystyle B k B 0 r k B B 0 nbsp Since Bn 0 we can solve for B B B 0 1 r n 1 displaystyle B B 0 left frac 1 r n 1 right nbsp Substituting back into the formula for the Bk shows that they are a linear function of the rk and therefore the lk B k B 0 1 r k r n B 0 1 l k l n displaystyle B k B 0 left 1 frac r k r n right B 0 left 1 frac lambda k lambda n right nbsp This is the easiest way of estimating the balances if the lk are known Substituting into the first formula for Bk above and solving for lk 1 we obtain l k 1 1 1 r l k displaystyle lambda k 1 1 1 r lambda k nbsp l0 and ln can be found using the formula for lk above or computing the lk recursively from l0 0 to ln Since p rB the formula for the payment reduces to p r 1 l n B 0 displaystyle p left r frac 1 lambda n right B 0 nbsp and the average interest rate over the period of the loan is r loan I T n B 0 r 1 l n 1 n displaystyle r text loan frac I T nB 0 r frac 1 lambda n frac 1 n nbsp which is less than r if n gt 1 Discount instruments editUS and Canadian T Bills short term Government debt have a different calculation for interest Their interest is calculated as 100 P P where P is the price paid Instead of normalizing it to a year the interest is prorated by the number of days t 365 t 100 See also Day count convention The total calculation is 100 P P 365 t 100 This is equivalent to calculating the price by a process called discounting at a simple interest rate Rules of thumb editRule of 78s edit Main article Rule of 78s In the age before electronic computing power was widely available flat rate consumer loans in the United States of America would be priced using the Rule of 78s or sum of digits method The sum of the integers from 1 to 12 is 78 The technique required only a simple calculation Payments remain constant over the life of the loan however payments are allocated to interest in progressively smaller amounts In a one year loan in the first month 12 78 of all interest owed over the life of the loan is due in the second month 11 78 progressing to the twelfth month where only 1 78 of all interest is due The practical effect of the Rule of 78s is to make early pay offs of term loans more expensive For a one year loan approximately 3 4 of all interest due is collected by the sixth month and pay off of the principal then will cause the effective interest rate to be much higher than the APR used to calculate the payments 18 In 1992 the United States outlawed the use of Rule of 78s interest in connection with mortgage refinancing and other consumer loans over five years in term 19 Certain other jurisdictions have outlawed application of the Rule of 78s in certain types of loans particularly consumer loans 18 Rule of 72 edit Main article Rule of 72 To approximate how long it takes for money to double at a given interest rate that is for accumulated compound interest to reach or exceed the initial deposit divide 72 by the percentage interest rate For example compounding at an annual interest rate of 6 percent it will take 72 6 12 years for the money to double The rule provides a good indication for interest rates up to 10 In the case of an interest rate of 18 percent the rule of 72 predicts that money will double after 72 18 4 years 1 18 4 1 9388 4 d p displaystyle 1 18 4 1 9388 text 4 d p nbsp In the case of an interest rate of 24 percent the rule predicts that money will double after 72 24 3 years 1 24 3 1 9066 4 d p displaystyle 1 24 3 1 9066 text 4 d p nbsp Market interest rates editThis section does not cite any sources Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed January 2009 Learn how and when to remove this template message There are markets for investments which include the money market bond market as well as retail financial institutions like banks that set interest rates Each specific debt takes into account the following factors in determining its interest rate Opportunity cost and deferred consumption edit Opportunity cost encompasses any other use to which the money could be put including lending to others investing elsewhere holding cash or spending the funds Charging interest equal to inflation preserves the lender s purchasing power but does not compensate for the time value of money in real terms The lender may prefer to invest in another product rather than consume The return they might obtain from competing investments is a factor in determining the interest rate they demand Inflation edit Since the lender is deferring consumption they will wish as a bare minimum to recover enough to pay the increased cost of goods due to inflation Because future inflation is unknown there are three ways this might be achieved Charge X interest plus inflation Many governments issue real return or inflation indexed bonds The principal amount or the interest payments are continually increased by the rate of inflation See the discussion at real interest rate Decide on the expected inflation rate This still leaves the lender exposed to the risk of unexpected inflation Allow the interest rate to be periodically changed While a fixed interest rate remains the same throughout the life of the debt variable or floating rates can be reset There are derivative products that allow for hedging and swaps between the two However interest rates are set by the market and it happens frequently that they are insufficient to compensate for inflation for example at times of high inflation during for example the oil crisis and during 2011 when real yields on many inflation linked government stocks are negative Default edit There is always the risk the borrower will become bankrupt abscond or otherwise default on the loan The risk premium attempts to measure the integrity of the borrower the risk of his enterprise succeeding and the security of any collateral pledged For example loans to developing countries have higher risk premiums than those to the US government due to the difference in creditworthiness An operating line of credit to a business will have a higher rate than a mortgage loan The creditworthiness of businesses is measured by bond rating services and individual s credit scores by credit bureaus The risks of an individual debt may have a large standard deviation of possibilities The lender may want to cover his maximum risk but lenders with portfolios of debt can lower the risk premium to cover just the most probable outcome Composition of interest rates edit In economics interest is considered the price of credit therefore it is also subject to distortions due to inflation The nominal interest rate which refers to the price before adjustment to inflation is the one visible to the consumer that is the interest tagged in a loan contract credit card statement etc Nominal interest is composed of the real interest rate plus inflation among other factors An approximate formula for the nominal interest is i r p displaystyle i r pi nbsp Where i is the nominal interest rate r is the real interest rate and p is inflation See also Fisher equation However not all borrowers and lenders have access to the same interest rate even if they are subject to the same inflation Furthermore expectations of future inflation vary so a forward looking interest rate cannot depend on a single real interest rate plus a single expected rate of inflation Interest rates also depend on credit quality or risk of default Governments are normally highly reliable debtors and the interest rate on government securities is normally lower than the interest rate available to other borrowers The equation i r p c displaystyle i r pi c nbsp relates expectations of inflation and credit risk to nominal and expected real interest rates over the life of a loan where i is the nominal interest applied r is the real interest expected p is the inflation expected and c is yield spread according to the perceived credit risk Default interest edit Default interest is the rate of interest that a borrower must pay after material breach of a loan covenant The default interest is usually much higher than the original interest rate since it is reflecting the aggravation in the financial risk of the borrower Default interest compensates the lender for the added risk From the borrower s perspective this means failure to make their regular payment for one or two payment periods or failure to pay taxes or insurance premiums for the loan collateral will lead to substantially higher interest for the entire remaining term of the loan Banks tend to add default interest to the loan agreements in order to separate between different scenarios In some jurisdictions default interest clauses are unenforceable as against public policy Term edit Shorter terms often have less risk of default and exposure to inflation because the near future is easier to predict In these circumstances short term interest rates are lower than longer term interest rates an upward sloping yield curve Government intervention edit Interest rates are generally determined by the market but government intervention usually by a central bank may strongly influence short term interest rates and is one of the main tools of monetary policy The central bank offers to borrow or lend large quantities of money at a rate which they determine sometimes this is money that they have created ex nihilo that is printed which has a major influence on supply and demand and hence on market interest rates Open market operations in the United States edit nbsp The effective federal funds rate charted over more than fifty years citation needed The Federal Reserve Fed implements monetary policy largely by targeting the federal funds rate This is the rate that banks charge each other for overnight loans of federal funds Federal funds are the reserves held by banks at the Fed Open market operations are one tool within monetary policy implemented by the Federal Reserve to steer short term interest rates Using the power to buy and sell treasury securities the Open Market Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York can supply the market with dollars by purchasing U S Treasury notes hence increasing the nation s money supply By increasing the money supply or Aggregate Supply of Funding ASF interest rates will fall due to the excess of dollars banks will end up with in their reserves Excess reserves may be lent in the Fed funds market to other banks thus driving down rates Interest rates and credit risk edit It is increasingly recognized that during the business cycle interest rates and credit risk are tightly interrelated The Jarrow Turnbull model was the first model of credit risk that explicitly had random interest rates at its core Lando 2004 Darrell Duffie and Singleton 2003 and van Deventer and Imai 2003 discuss interest rates when the issuer of the interest bearing instrument can default Money and inflation edit Loans and bonds have some of the characteristics of money and are included in the broad money supply National governments provided of course that the country has retained its own currency can influence interest rates and thus the supply and demand for such loans thus altering the total of loans and bonds issued Generally speaking a higher real interest rate reduces the broad money supply Through the quantity theory of money increases in the money supply lead to inflation This means that interest rates can affect inflation in the future 20 Liquidity edit Liquidity is the ability to quickly re sell an asset for fair or near fair value All else equal an investor will want a higher return on an illiquid asset than a liquid one to compensate for the loss of the option to sell it at any time U S Treasury bonds are highly liquid with an active secondary market while some other debts are less liquid In the mortgage market the lowest rates are often issued on loans that can be re sold as securitized loans Highly non traditional loans such as seller financing often carry higher interest rates due to a lack of liquidity Theories of interest editAristotle s view of interest edit Aristotle and the Scholastics held that it was unjust to claim payment except in compensation for one s own efforts and sacrifices and that since money is by its nature sterile there is no loss in being temporarily separated from it Compensation for risk or for the trouble of setting up a loan was not necessarily impermissible on these grounds 21 Development of the theory of interest during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries edit Nicholas Barbon c 1640 c 1698 described as a mistake the view that interest is a monetary value arguing that because money is typically borrowed to buy assets goods and stock the interest that is charged on a loan is a type of rent a payment for the use of goods 22 21 23 According to Schumpeter Barbon s theories were forgotten until similar views were put forward by Joseph Massie in 1750 note 1 In 1752 David Hume published his essay Of money which relates interest to the demand for borrowing the riches available to supply that demand and the profits arising from commerce Schumpeter 26 page needed considered Hume s theory superior to that of Ricardo and Mill but the reference to profits concentrates to a surprising degree on commerce rather than on industry Turgot brought the theory of interest close to its classical form Industrialists share their profits with capitalists who supply the funds Reflexions LXXI The share that goes to the latter is determined like all other prices LXXV by the play of supply and demand amongst borrowers and lenders so that the analysis is from the outset firmly planted in the general theory of prices note 2 The classical theory of the interest rate edit The classical theory was the work of a number of authors including Turgot Ricardo note 3 Mountifort Longfield 28 J S Mill and Irving Fisher 29 It was strongly criticised by Keynes note 4 whose remarks nonetheless made a positive contribution to it Mill s theory is set out the chapter Of the rate of interest in his Principles of political economy note 5 He says that the interest rate adjusts to maintain equilibrium between the demands for lending and borrowing 30 Individuals lend in order to defer consumption or for the sake of the greater quantity they will be able to consume at a later date owing to interest earned They borrow in order to anticipate consumption whose relative desirability is reflected by the time value of money but entrepreneurs also borrow to fund investment and governments borrow for their own reasons The three sources of demand compete for loans 31 For entrepreneurial borrowing to be in equilibrium with lending The interest for money is regulated by the rate of profits which can be made by the employment of capital 32 Ricardo s and Mill s profit is made more precise by the concept of the marginal efficiency of capital the expression though not the concept is due to Keynes note 6 which may be defined as the annual revenue which will be yielded by an extra increment of capital as a proportion of its cost So the interest rate r in equilibrium will be equal to the marginal efficiency of capital r Rather than work with r and r as separate variables we can assume that they are equal and let the single variable r denote their common value nbsp Classical theory of the determination of the interest rate The solid red curve in the diagram shows the desired level of saving s as a function of r for the current income y The investment schedule i r shows how much investment is possible with a return of at least r note 7 In a stationary economy it is likely to resemble the blue curve in the diagram with a step shape arising from the assumption that opportunities to invest with yields greater than r have been largely exhausted while there is untapped scope to invest with a lower return 33 Saving is the excess of deferred over anticipated consumption and its dependence on income is much as described by Keynes see The General Theory but in classical theory definitely an increasing function of r The dependence of s on income y was not relevant to classical concerns prior to the development of theories of unemployment The rate of interest is given by the intersection of the solid red saving curve with the blue investment schedule But so long as the investment schedule is almost vertical a change in income leading in extreme cases to the broken red saving curve will make little difference to the interest rate In some cases the analysis will be less simple The introduction of a new technique leading to demand for new forms of capital will shift the step to the right and reduce its steepness 33 Or a sudden increase in the desire to anticipate consumption perhaps through military spending in time of war will absorb most available loans the interest rate will increase and investment will be reduced to the amount whose return exceeds it 34 This is illustrated by the dotted red saving curve Keynes s criticisms edit In the case of extraordinary spending in time of war the government may wish to borrow more than the public would be willing to lend at a normal interest rate If the dotted red curve started negative and showed no tendency to increase with r then the government would be trying to buy what the public was unwilling to sell at any price Keynes mentions this possibility as a point which might perhaps have warned the classical school that something was wrong p 182 He also remarks on the same page that the classical theory does not explain the usual supposition that an increase in the quantity of money has a tendency to reduce the rate of interest at any rate in the first instance Keynes s diagram of the investment schecule lacks the step shape which can be seen as part of the classical theory He objects that the functions used by classical theory do not furnish material for a theory of the rate of interest but they could be used to tell us what the rate of interest will have to be if the level of employment which determines income is maintained at a given figure 35 Later p 184 Keynes claims that it involves a circular argument to construct a theory of interest from the investment schedule since the marginal efficiency of capital partly depends on the scale of current investment and we must already know the rate of interest before we can calculate what this scale will be Theories of exploitation productivity and abstinence edit The classical theory of interest explains it as the capitalist s share of business profits but the pre marginalist authors were unable to reconcile these profits with the labor theory of value excluding Longfield who was essentially a marginalist Their responses often had a moral tone Ricardo and Marx viewed profits as exploitation and McCulloch s productivity theory justified profits by portraying capital equipment as an embodiment of accumulated labor 26 page needed The theory that interest is a payment for abstinence is attributed to Nassau Senior and according to Schumpeter 26 page needed was intended neutrally but it can easily be understood as making a moral claim and was sharply criticised by Marx and Lassalle Wicksell s theory edit Knut Wicksell published his Interest and Prices in 1898 elaborating a comprehensive theory of economic crises based upon a distinction between natural and nominal interest rates Wicksell s contribution in fact was twofold First he separated the monetary rate of interest from the hypothetical natural rate that would have resulted from equilibrium of capital supply and demand in a barter economy and he assumed that as a result of the presence of money alone the effective market rate could fail to correspond to this ideal rate in actuality Next he supposed that through the mechanism of credit the rate of interest had an influence on prices that a rise of the monetary rate above the natural level produced a fall and a decline below that level a rise in prices But Wicksell went on to conclude that if the natural rate coincided with the monetary rate stability of prices would follow 36 In the 1930s Wicksell s approach was refined by Bertil Ohlin and Dennis Robertson and became known as the loanable funds theory Austrian theories edit Eugen Bohm von Bawerk and other members of the Austrian School also put forward notable theories of the interest rate The doyen of the Austrian school Murray N Rothbard sees the emphasis on the loan market which makes up the general analysis on interest as a mistaken view to take As he explains in his primary economic work Man Economy and State the market rate of interest is but a manifestation of the natural phenomenon of time preference which is to prefer present goods to future goods 37 To Rothbard Too many writers consider the rate of interest as only the price of loans on the loan market In reality the rate of interest pervades all time markets and the productive loan market is a strictly subsidiary time market of only derivative importance 38 Interest is explainable by the rate of time preference among the people To point to the loan market is insufficient at best Rather the rate of interest is what would be observed between the stages of production indeed a time market itself where capital goods which are used to make consumers goods are ordered out further in time away from the final consumers goods stage of the economy where consumption takes place It is this spread between these various stages which will tend toward uniformity with consumers goods representing present goods and producers goods representing future goods that the real rate of interest is observed Rothbard has said thatInterest rate is equal to the rate of price spread in the various stages 38 Rothbard has furthermore criticized the Keynesian conception of interest sayingOne grave and fundamental Keynesian error is to persist in regarding the interest rate as a contract rate on loans instead of the price spreads between stages of production 39 Pareto s indifference edit Pareto held that The interest rate being one of the many elements of the general system of equilibrium was of course simultaneously determined with all of them so that there was no point at all in looking for any particular element that caused interest note 8 Keynes s theory of the interest rate edit Interest is one of the main components of the economic theories developed in Keynes s 1936 General theory of employment interest and money In his initial account of liquidity preference the demand for money in Chapter 13 this demand is solely a function of the interest rate and since the supply is given and equilibrium is assumed the interest rate is determined by the money supply In his later account Chapter 15 interest cannot be separated from other economic variables and needs to be analysed together with them See The General Theory for details In religious contexts editJudaism edit Main article Loans and interest in Judaism Jews are forbidden from usury in dealing with fellow Jews and this lending is to be considered tzedakah or charity However there are permissions to charge interest on loans to non Jews 41 This is outlined in the Jewish scriptures of the Torah which Christians hold as part of the Old Testament and other books of the Tanakh From the Jewish Publication Society s 1917 Tanakh 42 with Christian verse numbers where different in parentheses If thou lend money to any of My people even to the poor with thee thou shalt not be to him as a creditor neither shall ye lay upon him interest Exodus 22 24 25 Take thou no interest of him or increase but fear thy God that thy brother may live with thee Leviticus 25 36 Thou shalt not give him thy money upon interest nor give him thy victuals for increase Leviticus 25 37 Thou shalt not lend upon interest to thy brother interest of money interest of victuals interest of any thing that is lent upon interest Deuteronomy 23 20 19 Unto a foreigner thou mayest lend upon interest but unto thy brother thou shalt not lend upon interest that the LORD thy God may bless thee in all that thou puttest thy hand unto in the land whither thou goest in to possess it Deuteronomy 23 21 20 that hath withdrawn his hand from the poor that hath not received interest nor increase hath executed Mine ordinances hath walked in My statutes he shall not die for the iniquity of his father he shall surely live Ezekiel 18 17 He that putteth not out his money on interest nor taketh a bribe against the innocent He that doeth these things shall never be moved Psalm 15 5 Several historical rulings in Jewish law have mitigated the allowances for usury toward non Jews For instance the 15th century commentator Rabbi Isaac Abrabanel specified that the rubric for allowing interest does not apply to Christians or Muslims because their faith systems have a common ethical basis originating from Judaism The medieval commentator Rabbi David Kimchi extended this principle to non Jews who show consideration for Jews saying they should be treated with the same consideration when they borrow 43 Islam edit Main articles Riba and Islamic banking and finance The following quotations are English translations from the Qur an Those who charge usury are in the same position as those controlled by the devil s influence This is because they claim that usury is the same as commerce However God permits commerce and prohibits usury Thus whoever heeds this commandment from his Lord and refrains from usury he may keep his past earnings and his judgment rests with God As for those who persist in usury they incur Hell wherein they abide forever Al Baqarah 2 275 God condemns usury and blesses charities God dislikes every sinning disbeliever Those who believe and do good works and establish worship and pay the poor due their reward is with their Lord and there shall no fear come upon them neither shall they grieve O you who believe you shall observe God and refrain from all kinds of usury if you are believers If you do not then expect a war from God and His messenger But if you repent you may keep your capitals without inflicting injustice or incurring injustice If the debtor is unable to pay wait for a better time If you give up the loan as a charity it would be better for you if you only knew Al Baqarah 2 276 280 O you who believe you shall not take usury compounded over and over Observe God that you may succeed Al Imran 3 130 And for practicing usury which was forbidden and for consuming the people s money illicitly We have prepared for the disbelievers among them painful retribution Al Nisa 4 161 The usury that is practiced to increase some people s wealth does not gain anything at God But if people give to charity seeking God s pleasure these are the ones who receive their reward many fold Ar Rum 30 39 The attitude of Muhammad to usury is articulated in his Last Sermon O People just as you regard this month this day this city as Sacred so regard the life and property of every Muslim as a sacred trust Return the goods entrusted to you to their rightful owners Hurt no one so that no one may hurt you Remember that you will indeed meet your Lord and that He will indeed reckon your deeds Allah has forbidden you to take usury therefore all usurious obligation shall henceforth be waived Your capital however is yours to keep You will neither inflict nor suffer any inequity Allah has Judged that there shall be no usury and that all the usury due to Abbas ibn Abd al Muttalib Prophet s uncle shall henceforth be waived 44 unreliable source Christianity edit nbsp Christ drives the Usurers out of the Temple a woodcut by Lucas Cranach the Elder in Passionary of Christ and Antichrist 45 The Old Testament condemns the practice of charging interest because a loan should be an act of compassion and taking care of one s neighbor it teaches that making a profit off a loan is exploiting that person and dishonoring God s covenant Exodus 22 25 27 46 The first of the scholastic Christian theologians Saint Anselm of Canterbury led the shift in thought that labeled charging interest the same as theft citation needed Previously usury had been seen as a lack of charity St Thomas Aquinas the leading scholastic theologian of the Roman Catholic Church argued charging of interest is wrong because it amounts to double charging charging for both the thing and the use of the thing Aquinas said this would be morally wrong in the same way as if one sold a bottle of wine charged for the bottle of wine and then charged for the person using the wine to actually drink it 47 Similarly one cannot charge for a piece of cake and for the eating of the piece of cake Yet this said Aquinas is what usury does Money is a medium of exchange and is used up when it is spent To charge for the money and for its use by spending is therefore to charge for the money twice It is also to sell time since the usurer charges in effect for the time that the money is in the hands of the borrower Time however is not a commodity that anyone can charge In condemning usury Aquinas was much influenced by the recently rediscovered philosophical writings of Aristotle and his desire to assimilate Greek philosophy with Christian theology Aquinas argued that in the case of usury as in other aspects of Christian revelation Christian doctrine is reinforced by Aristotelian natural law rationalism Aristotle s argument is that interest is unnatural since money as a sterile element cannot naturally reproduce itself Thus usury conflicts with natural law just as it offends Christian revelation see Thought of Thomas Aquinas As such Aquinas taught that interest is inherently unjust and one who charges interest sins 46 Outlawing usury did not prevent investment but stipulated that in order for the investor to share in the profit he must share the risk In short he must be a joint venturer Simply to invest the money and expect it to be returned regardless of the success of the venture was to make money simply by having money and not by taking any risk or by doing any work or by any effort or sacrifice at all which is usury St Thomas quotes Aristotle as saying that to live by usury is exceedingly unnatural Islam likewise condemns usury but allowed commerce Al Baqarah 2 275 an alternative that suggests investment and sharing of profit and loss instead of sharing only profit through interests Judaism condemns usury towards Jews but allows it towards non Jews Deut 23 19 20 St Thomas allows however charges for actual services provided Thus a banker or credit lender could charge for such actual work or effort as he did carry out for example any fair administrative charges The Catholic Church in a decree of the Fifth Council of the Lateran expressly allowed such charges in respect of credit unions run for the benefit of the poor known as montes pietatis 48 In the 13th century Cardinal Hostiensis enumerated thirteen situations in which charging interest was not immoral 49 The most important of these was lucrum cessans profits given up which allowed for the lender to charge interest to compensate him for profit foregone in investing the money himself 50 This idea is very similar to opportunity cost Many scholastic thinkers who argued for a ban on interest charges also argued for the legitimacy of lucrum cessans profits for example Pierre Jean Olivi and St Bernardino of Siena However Hostiensis exceptions including for lucrum cessans were never accepted as official by the Roman Catholic Church The Westminster Confession of Faith a confession of faith upheld by the Reformed Churches teaches that usury charging interest at any rate is a sin prohibited by the eighth commandment 51 The Roman Catholic Church has always condemned usury but in modern times with the rise of capitalism and the disestablishment of the Catholic Church in majority Catholic countries this prohibition on usury has not been enforced Pope Benedict XIV s encyclical Vix Pervenit gives the reasons why usury is sinful 52 The nature of the sin called usury has its proper place and origin in a loan contract which demands by its very nature that one return to another only as much as he has received The sin rests on the fact that sometimes the creditor desires more than he has given but any gain which exceeds the amount he gave is illicit and usurious One cannot condone the sin of usury by arguing that the gain is not great or excessive but rather moderate or small neither can it be condoned by arguing that the borrower is rich nor even by arguing that the money borrowed is not left idle but is spent usefully 53 The Congregation of the Missionary Sons of the Immaculate Heart of Mary a Catholic Christian religious order thus teaches that 46 It might initially seem like little is at stake when it comes to interest but this is an issue of human dignity A person is made in God s own image and therefore may never be treated as a thing Interest can diminish the human person to a thing to be manipulated for money In an article for The Catholic Worker Dorothy Day articulated this well Can I talk about the people living off usury not knowing the way that their infertile money has bred more money by wise investment in God knows what devilish nerve gas drugs napalm missiles or vanities when housing and employment for the poor were needed and money could have been invested there Her thoughts were a precursor to what Pope Francis now calls an economy that kills To sin is to say no to God and God s presence by harming others ourselves or all of creation Charging interest is indeed sinful when doing so takes advantage of a person in need as well as when it means investing in corporations involved in the harming of God s creatures 46 See also editActuarial notation Credit card interest Credit rating agency DIRTI 5 Discount Fisher equation Hire purchase Interest expense Leasing Promissory note Risk free interest rateNotes edit Barbon s Discourse on this point at all events did not meet with success The tract seems indeed to have been forgotten very soon Thus Barbon s fundamental idea remained in abeyance until 1750 when it was again expounded for all we know independently rediscovered by Massie 24 whose analysis not only went further than Barbon s but also gathered force from its criticism of the views of Petty and Locke 25 Schumpeter 27 the references are to paragraph numbers in Turgot s Reflexions sur la formation et la distribution des richesses written in 1766 first published in 1769 70 in a journal and then separately in 1776 Isolated remarks in the chapters Effects of accumulation on profits and interest and On currency and banks in Principles of political economy and taxation The general theory of employment interest and money especially the appendix to Chapter 14 Page numbers refer to the widely available edition published by Macmillan for the Royal Economic Society as part of Keynes s collected writings which appear to correspond to those of the first edition See also his chapters Of the law of the increase of capital and Of profits Chapter 11 of The General Theory is titled The Marginal Efficiency of Capital Marshall used the term marginal utility of capital and Fisher rate of return over cost Fisher also referred to it as representing the investment opportunity side of interest theory Keynes called this function the schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital and also the investment demand schedule Unsourced observation in Schumpeter 40 Constructs such as ibid loc cit and idem are discouraged by Wikipedia s style guide for footnotes as they are easily broken Please improve this article by replacing them with named references quick guide or an abbreviated title May 2019 Learn how and when to remove this template message Definition of interest in English English Oxford Living Dictionaries Oxford University Press Archived from the original on December 27 2017 Retrieved 27 December 2017 Money paid regularly at a particular rate for the use of money lent or for delaying the repayment of a debt Definition of dividend Merriam Webster Archived from the original on 27 December 2017 Retrieved 27 December 2017 a share in a pro rata distribution as of profits to stockholders Profit Economics Online Archived from the original on 27 December 2017 Retrieved 27 December 2017 O Connor J J The number e MacTutor History of Mathematics Archived from the original on 2 October 2012 Retrieved 26 August 2012 a b Sylla Richard 2011 A History of Interest Rates Wiley p 17 ISBN 9781118046227 Johnson Paul A History of the Jews New York HarperCollins Publishers 1987 ISBN 0 06 091533 1 pp 172 73 How the world s first accountants counted on cuneiform BBC World Service 12 June 2017 Archived from the original on 27 May 2023 Retrieved 10 December 2018 A Simple Math Formula Is Basically Responsible For All Of Modern Civilization Business Insider 5 June 2013 Archived from the original on 11 December 2018 Retrieved 10 December 2018 Gnuse Robert 2011 08 05 You Shall Not Steal Community and Property in the Biblical Tradition Wipf and Stock Publishers ISBN 9781610975803 Institute of Islamic Banking and Insurance Prohibition of Interest www islamic banking com Archived from the original on 2018 06 21 Retrieved 2015 10 12 a b Conrad Henry Moehlman 1934 The Christianization of Interest Church History 3 p 6 doi 10 2307 3161033 Noonan John T Jr 1993 Development of Moral Doctrine 54 Theological Stud 662 No 2547 Charging Interest Archived from the original on 2011 05 03 Retrieved 2010 01 11 Anwer Zaheer Khan Shabeer Abu Bakar Muhammad 2020 01 01 Shariʿah compliant central banking practices lessons from Muslim countries experience ISRA International Journal of Islamic Finance 12 1 7 26 doi 10 1108 IJIF 01 2019 0007 ISSN 0128 1976 S2CID 216217732 O Connor J J Robertson E F The number e MacTutor History of Mathematics Archived from the original on 2008 08 28 Izbicki Thomas Kaufmann Matthias 2019 School of Salamanca in Zalta Edward N ed The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy Summer 2019 ed Metaphysics Research Lab Stanford University archived from the original on 2022 06 29 retrieved 2022 06 29 Bohm Bawerk E 1884 Capital and Interest A Critical History of Economic Theory Archived 2017 12 30 at the Wayback Machine a b Rule of 78 Watch out for this auto loan trick Archived from the original on 2016 11 29 Retrieved 2016 11 28 15 U S C 1615 What s the Relationship Between Inflation and Interest Rates PBS NewsHour 2009 06 23 Archived from the original on 2021 01 24 Retrieved 2020 08 31 a b Schumpeter 1954 p 61 Barbon A discourse of trade 1690 William Letwin Origins of Scientific Economics English Economic Thought 1660 1776 Massie Joseph 1750 Essay on the Governing Causes of the Natural Rate of Interest Schumpeter 1954 p 314 a b c Schumpeter 1954 Schumpeter 1954 p 316 Lectures on political economy IX The rate of interest 1907 Of the rate of interest 1 2 Ricardo chapter On currency and banks a b Mill 3 Longfield 3 p181 Etienne Mantoux Mr Keynes General Theory Revue d Economie Politique 1937 tr in Henry Hazlitt The critics of Keynesian economics 1960 Rothbard 2001 a b Rothbard 2001 p 371 Rothbard 2001 p 789 Schumpeter 1954 p 892 Robinson George Interest Free Loans in Judaism Archived from the original on 5 March 2021 Retrieved 12 March 2015 A Hebrew English Bible According to the Masoretic Text and the JPS 1917 Edition Archived from the original on 10 February 2009 Retrieved 4 January 2013 Encyclopedia Judaica Moneylending Jewish Virtual Library 2008 Archived from the original on October 16 2021 Retrieved October 16 2017 IslamiCity com Mosque The Prophet Muhammad s PBUH Last Sermon www islamicity com Archived from the original on 2019 01 29 Retrieved 2019 01 24 The references cited in the Passionary for this woodcut 1 John 2 14 16 Matthew 10 8 and The Apology of the Augsburg Confession Article 8 Of the Church Archived 2010 07 15 at the Wayback Machine a b c d Considine Kevin P 2016 Is it sinful to charge interest on a loan U S Catholic Archived from the original on 29 July 2020 Retrieved 4 June 2020 Thomas Aquinas Summa Theologica Of Cheating Which Is Committed in Buying and Selling Translated by The Fathers of the English Dominican Province pp 1 10 1 Archived 2016 03 03 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved June 19 2012 Session Ten On the reform of credit organisations Montes pietatis Fifth Lateran Council Rome Italy Catholic Church 4 May 1515 Retrieved 2008 04 05 Roover Raymond Autumn 1967 The Scholastics Usury and Foreign Exchange Business History Review The Business History Review Vol 41 No 3 41 3 257 271 doi 10 2307 3112192 JSTOR 3112192 S2CID 154706783 Rothbard 2001 p 46 Cox Robert 1853 Sabbath Laws and Sabbath Duties Considered in Relation to Their Natural and Scriptural Grounds and to the Principles of Religious Liberty Maclachlan and Stewart p 180 See also Church and the Usurers Unprofitable Lending for the Modern Economy Archived 2015 10 17 at the Wayback Machine by Dr Brian McCall Archived 2013 12 06 at the Wayback Machine or Interest and Usury Archived 2019 08 28 at the Wayback Machine by Fr Bernard W Dempsey S J Archived 2019 01 25 at the Wayback Machine 1903 1960 Vix Pervenit Papal Encyclicals 1 November 1745 Archived from the original on 7 September 2021 Retrieved 24 January 2019 References editDuffie Darrell and Kenneth J Singleton 2003 Credit Risk Pricing Measurement and Management Princeton University Press ISBN 978 0 691 09046 7 Kellison Stephen G 1970 The Theory of Interest Richard D Irwin Inc Library of Congress Catalog Card No 79 98251 Lando David 2004 Credit Risk Modeling Theory and Applications Princeton University Press ISBN 978 0 691 08929 4 van Deventer Donald R and Kenji Imai 2003 Credit Risk Models and the Basel Accords John Wiley amp Sons ISBN 978 0 470 82091 9 Rothbard Murray N 2001 Man economy and state a treatise on economic principles Rev ed Auburn Alabama Mises Institute ISBN 0945466323 OCLC 47279566 Schumpeter Joseph 1954 History of Economic Analysis Allen amp Unwin External links edit nbsp Look up interest in Wiktionary the free dictionary White Paper More than Math The Lost Art of Interest calculation Mortgages made clear Financial Services Authority UK List of current interest rates World Interest Rates Forex Motion Which way to pay Archived 2011 04 19 at the Wayback Machine Deposit Rates in European Countries Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Interest amp oldid 1179011736, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.