fbpx
Wikipedia

Income

Income is the consumption and saving opportunity gained by an entity within a specified timeframe, which is generally expressed in monetary terms.[1] Income is difficult to define conceptually and the definition may be different across fields.[2][page needed] For example, a person's income in an economic sense may be different from their income as defined by law.[2]

An extremely important definition of income is Haig–Simons income, which defines income as Consumption + Change in net worth and is widely used in economics.[2]

For households and individuals in the United States, income is defined by tax law as a sum that includes any wage, salary, profit, interest payment, rent, or other form of earnings received in a calendar year.[3] Discretionary income is often defined as gross income minus taxes and other deductions (e.g., mandatory pension contributions), and is widely used as a basis to compare the welfare of taxpayers.

In the field of public economics, the concept may comprise the accumulation of both monetary and non-monetary consumption ability, with the former (monetary) being used as a proxy for total income.

For a firm, gross income can be defined as sum of all revenue minus the cost of goods sold. Net income nets out expenses: net income equals revenue minus cost of goods sold, expenses, depreciation, interest, and taxes.[1]

Economic definitions edit

Full and Haig–Simons income edit

"Full income" refers to the accumulation of both the monetary and the non-monetary consumption-ability of any given entity, such as a person or a household. According to what the economist Nicholas Barr describes as the "classical definition of income" (the 1938 Haig–Simons definition): "income may be defined as the... sum of (1) the market value of rights exercised in consumption and (2) the change in the value of the store of property rights..." Since the consumption potential of non-monetary goods, such as leisure, cannot be measured, monetary income may be thought of as a proxy for full income.[1] As such, however, it is criticized[by whom?] for being unreliable, i.e. failing to accurately reflect affluence (and thus the consumption opportunities) of any given agent. It omits the utility a person may derive from non-monetary income and, on a macroeconomic level, fails to accurately chart social welfare. According to Barr, "in practice money income as a proportion of total income varies widely and unsystematically. Non-observability of full-income prevent a complete characterization of the individual opportunity set, forcing us to use the unreliable yardstick of money income.

Factor income edit

In economics, "factor income" is the return accruing for a person, or a nation, derived from the "factors of production": rental income, wages generated by labor, the interest created by capital, and profits from entrepreneurial ventures.[4]

In consumer theory 'income' is another name for the "budget constraint", an amount   to be spent on different goods x and y in quantities   and   at prices   and  . The basic equation for this is

 

This equation implies two things. First buying one more unit of good x implies buying   less units of good y. So,   is the relative price of a unit of x as to the number of units given up in y. Second, if the price of x falls for a fixed   and fixed   then its relative price falls. The usual hypothesis, the law of demand, is that the quantity demanded of x would increase at the lower price. The analysis can be generalized to more than two goods.

The theoretical generalization to more than one period is a multi-period wealth and income constraint. For example, the same person can gain more productive skills or acquire more productive income-earning assets to earn a higher income. In the multi-period case, something might also happen to the economy beyond the control of the individual to reduce (or increase) the flow of income. Changing measured income and its relation to consumption over time might be modeled accordingly, such as in the permanent income hypothesis.

Legal definitions edit

Definitions under the Internal Revenue Code edit

Except as otherwise provided in this subtitle, gross income means all income from whatever source derived, including (but not limited to) the following items: (1) Compensation for services, including fees, commissions, fringe benefits, and similar items; (2) Gross income derived from business; (3) Gains derived from dealings in property; (4) Interest; (5) Rents; (6) Royalties; (7) Dividends; (8) Annuities; (9) Income from life insurance and endowment contracts; (10) Pensions; (11) Income from discharge of indebtedness; (12) Distributive share of partnership gross income; (13) Income in respect of a decedent; and (14) Income from an interest in an estate or trust.

26 U.S. Code § 61 - Gross income defined. There are also some statutory exclusions from income.[2]

Definition under US Case law edit

Income is an "undeniable accessions to wealth, clearly realized, and over which the taxpayer has complete dominion." Commentators say that this is a pretty good definition of income.[2]

Taxable income is usually lower than Haig-Simons income.[2] This is because unrealized appreciation (e.g., the increase in the value of stock over the course of a year) is economic income but not taxable income, and because there are many statutory exclusions from taxable income, including workman's compensation, SSI, gifts, child support, and in-kind government transfers.[5]

Accounting definitions edit

The International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) uses the following definition: "Income is increases in economic benefits during the accounting period in the form of inflows or enhancements of assets or decreases of liabilities that result in increases in equity, other than those relating to contributions from equity participants." [F.70] (IFRS Framework).

Previously the IFRS conceptual framework (4.29) stated: "The definition of income encompasses both revenue and gains. Revenue arises in the course of the ordinary activities of an entity and is referred to by a variety of different names including sales, fees, interest, dividends, royalties and rent. 4.30: Gains represent other items that meet the definition of income and may, or may not, arise in the course of the ordinary activities of an entity. Gains represent increases in economic benefits and as such are no different in nature from revenue. Hence, they are not regarded as constituting a separate element in this Conceptual Framework."[6]

The current IFRS conceptual framework [7] (4.68) no longer draws a distinction between revenue and gains. Nevertheless, the distinction continues to be drawn at the standard and reporting levels. For example, IFRS 9.5.7.1 states: "A gain or loss on a financial asset or financial liability that is measured at fair value shall be recognised in profit or loss ..." while the IASB defined IFRS XBRL taxonomy [8] includes OtherGainsLosses, GainsLossesOnNetMonetaryPosition and similar items.

US GAAP does not define income but does define comprehensive income (CON 8.4.E75): Comprehensive income is the change in equity of a business entity during a period from transactions and other events and circumstances from nonowner sources. It includes all changes in equity during a period except those resulting from investments by owners and distributions to owners.

According to John Hicks' definitions, income "is the maximum amount which can be spent during a period if there is to be an expectation of maintaining intact, the capital value of prospective receipts (in money terms)".[9]

"Nonincome" edit

Debt edit

Borrowing or repaying money is not income under any definition, for either the borrower or the lender.[2] Interest and forgiveness of debt are income.

Psychic income edit

"Non-monetary joy," such as watching a sunset or having sex, simply is not income.[2] Similarly, nonmonetary suffering, such as heartbreak or labor, are not negative income. This may seem trivial, but the non-inclusion of psychic income has important effects on economics and tax policy.[2] It encourages people to find happiness in nonmonetary, nontaxable ways and means that reported income may overstate or understate the well-being of a given individual.[2]

Income growth edit

Income per capita has been increasing steadily in most countries.[10] Many factors contribute to people having a higher income, including education,[11] globalisation and favorable political circumstances such as economic freedom and peace. Increases in income also tend to lead to people choosing to work fewer hours. Developed countries (defined as countries with a "developed economy") have higher incomes as opposed to developing countries tending to have lower incomes.

Income inequality edit

Income inequality is the extent to which income is distributed in an uneven manner. It can be measured by various methods, including the Lorenz curve and the Gini coefficient. Many economists argue that certain amounts of inequality are necessary and desirable but that excessive inequality leads to efficiency problems and social injustice.[1] Thereby necessitating initiatives like the United Nations Sustainable Development Goal 10 aimed at reducing inequality.[12]

National income, measured by statistics such as net national income (NNI), measures the total income of individuals, corporations, and government in the economy. For more information see Measures of national income and output.

Income in philosophy and ethics edit

Throughout history, many have written about the impact of income on morality and society. Saint Paul wrote 'For the love of money is a root of all kinds of evil:' (1 Timothy 6:10 (ASV)).

Some scholars have come to the conclusion that material progress and prosperity, as manifested in continuous income growth at both the individual and the national level, provide the indispensable foundation for sustaining any kind of morality. This argument was explicitly given by Adam Smith in his Theory of Moral Sentiments,[13] and has more recently been developed by Harvard economist Benjamin Friedman in his book The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth.[14]

Income and health edit

A landmark systematic review from Harvard University researchers in the Cochrane Collaboration found that income given in the form of unconditional cash transfers leads to reductions in disease, improvements in food security and dietary diversity, increases in children's school attendance, decreases in extreme poverty, and higher health care spending.[15][16]

History edit

Income is conventionally denoted by "Y" in economics. John Hicks used "I" for income, but Keynes wrote to him in 1937, "after trying both, I believe it is easier to use Y for income and I for investment." Some consider Y as an alternative letter for the phoneme I in languages like Spanish,[17] although Y as the "Greek I" was actually pronounced like the modern German ü or the phonetic /y/.

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ a b c d Barr, N. (2004). Problems and definition of measurement. In Economics of the welfare state. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 121–124
  2. ^ a b c d e f g h i j McCaffery, Edward (2012). The Oxford Introductions to U.S. Law: Income Tax Law 1st Edition. Oxford University Press.
  3. ^ Case, K. & Fair, R. (2007). Principles of Economics. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education. p. 54.
  4. ^ Staff (2012). . BusinessDictionary.com. WebFinance, Inc. Archived from the original on 18 June 2012. Retrieved 20 June 2012. m
  5. ^ Brooks, John R., "The Definitions of Income" (2018). Georgetown Law Faculty Publications and Other Works. 1952. https://scholarship.law.georgetown.edu/facpub/1952/
  6. ^ admin. "Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting 2018". www.iasplus.com. Retrieved 2022-06-28.
  7. ^ "IASB".
  8. ^ "IASB".
  9. ^ "Oxbridge Notes". Retrieved 18 August 2016.
  10. ^ "Gapminder World". Gapminder Foundation.
  11. ^ "Gapminder World". Gapminder Foundation.
  12. ^ . UNDP. Archived from the original on 2020-11-27. Retrieved 2020-09-23.
  13. ^ Smith, Adam (2009). The theory of moral sentiments. Oxford: Clarendon. OCLC 1017407319.
  14. ^ Friedman, Benjamin M (2006). The moral consequences of economic growth. New York, NY: Vintage Books. ISBN 978-1-4000-9571-1. OCLC 71353264.
  15. ^ Pega, Frank; Liu, Sze; Walter, Stefan; Pabayo, Roman; Saith, Ruhi; Lhachimi, Stefan (2017). "Unconditional cash transfers for reducing poverty and vulnerabilities: effect on use of health services and health outcomes in low- and middle-income countries". Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews. 11 (4): CD011135. doi:10.1002/14651858.CD011135.pub2. PMC 6486161. PMID 29139110.
  16. ^ Pega, Frank; Pabayo, Roman; Benny, Claire; Lee, Eun-Young; Lhachimi, Stefan; Liu, Sze (2022). "Unconditional cash transfers for reducing poverty and vulnerabilities: effect on use of health services and health outcomes in low- and middle-income countries". Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews. 2022 (3): CD011135. doi:10.1002/14651858.CD011135.pub3. PMC 8962215. PMID 35348196.
  17. ^ "Why Y?". Greg Mankiw's Blog. December 21, 2016.

Further reading edit

income, concept, united, states, legal, definitions, this, article, needs, additional, citations, verification, please, help, improve, this, article, adding, citations, reliable, sources, unsourced, material, challenged, removed, find, sources, news, newspaper. For the concept in U S law see Income United States legal definitions This article needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Income news newspapers books scholar JSTOR October 2010 Learn how and when to remove this template message Income is the consumption and saving opportunity gained by an entity within a specified timeframe which is generally expressed in monetary terms 1 Income is difficult to define conceptually and the definition may be different across fields 2 page needed For example a person s income in an economic sense may be different from their income as defined by law 2 An extremely important definition of income is Haig Simons income which defines income as Consumption Change in net worth and is widely used in economics 2 For households and individuals in the United States income is defined by tax law as a sum that includes any wage salary profit interest payment rent or other form of earnings received in a calendar year 3 Discretionary income is often defined as gross income minus taxes and other deductions e g mandatory pension contributions and is widely used as a basis to compare the welfare of taxpayers In the field of public economics the concept may comprise the accumulation of both monetary and non monetary consumption ability with the former monetary being used as a proxy for total income For a firm gross income can be defined as sum of all revenue minus the cost of goods sold Net income nets out expenses net income equals revenue minus cost of goods sold expenses depreciation interest and taxes 1 Contents 1 Economic definitions 1 1 Full and Haig Simons income 1 2 Factor income 2 Legal definitions 2 1 Definitions under the Internal Revenue Code 2 2 Definition under US Case law 3 Accounting definitions 4 Nonincome 4 1 Debt 4 2 Psychic income 5 Income growth 6 Income inequality 7 Income in philosophy and ethics 8 Income and health 9 History 10 See also 11 References 12 Further readingEconomic definitions editFull and Haig Simons income edit Main article Haig Simons income Full income refers to the accumulation of both the monetary and the non monetary consumption ability of any given entity such as a person or a household According to what the economist Nicholas Barr describes as the classical definition of income the 1938 Haig Simons definition income may be defined as the sum of 1 the market value of rights exercised in consumption and 2 the change in the value of the store of property rights Since the consumption potential of non monetary goods such as leisure cannot be measured monetary income may be thought of as a proxy for full income 1 As such however it is criticized by whom for being unreliable i e failing to accurately reflect affluence and thus the consumption opportunities of any given agent It omits the utility a person may derive from non monetary income and on a macroeconomic level fails to accurately chart social welfare According to Barr in practice money income as a proportion of total income varies widely and unsystematically Non observability of full income prevent a complete characterization of the individual opportunity set forcing us to use the unreliable yardstick of money income Factor income edit In economics factor income is the return accruing for a person or a nation derived from the factors of production rental income wages generated by labor the interest created by capital and profits from entrepreneurial ventures 4 In consumer theory income is another name for the budget constraint an amount Y displaystyle Y nbsp to be spent on different goods x and y in quantities x displaystyle x nbsp and y displaystyle y nbsp at prices P x displaystyle P x nbsp and P y displaystyle P y nbsp The basic equation for this is Y P x x P y y displaystyle Y P x cdot x P y cdot y nbsp This equation implies two things First buying one more unit of good x implies buying P x P y displaystyle frac P x P y nbsp less units of good y So P x P y displaystyle frac P x P y nbsp is the relative price of a unit of x as to the number of units given up in y Second if the price of x falls for a fixed Y displaystyle Y nbsp and fixed P y displaystyle P y nbsp then its relative price falls The usual hypothesis the law of demand is that the quantity demanded of x would increase at the lower price The analysis can be generalized to more than two goods The theoretical generalization to more than one period is a multi period wealth and income constraint For example the same person can gain more productive skills or acquire more productive income earning assets to earn a higher income In the multi period case something might also happen to the economy beyond the control of the individual to reduce or increase the flow of income Changing measured income and its relation to consumption over time might be modeled accordingly such as in the permanent income hypothesis Legal definitions editDefinitions under the Internal Revenue Code edit Main article Internal Revenue Code section 61 Except as otherwise provided in this subtitle gross income means all income from whatever source derived including but not limited to the following items 1 Compensation for services including fees commissions fringe benefits and similar items 2 Gross income derived from business 3 Gains derived from dealings in property 4 Interest 5 Rents 6 Royalties 7 Dividends 8 Annuities 9 Income from life insurance and endowment contracts 10 Pensions 11 Income from discharge of indebtedness 12 Distributive share of partnership gross income 13 Income in respect of a decedent and 14 Income from an interest in an estate or trust 26 U S Code 61 Gross income defined There are also some statutory exclusions from income 2 Definition under US Case law edit Main article Commissioner v Glenshaw Glass Co Income is an undeniable accessions to wealth clearly realized and over which the taxpayer has complete dominion Commentators say that this is a pretty good definition of income 2 Taxable income is usually lower than Haig Simons income 2 This is because unrealized appreciation e g the increase in the value of stock over the course of a year is economic income but not taxable income and because there are many statutory exclusions from taxable income including workman s compensation SSI gifts child support and in kind government transfers 5 Accounting definitions editMain article Income United States legal definitions The International Accounting Standards Board IASB uses the following definition Income is increases in economic benefits during the accounting period in the form of inflows or enhancements of assets or decreases of liabilities that result in increases in equity other than those relating to contributions from equity participants F 70 IFRS Framework Previously the IFRS conceptual framework 4 29 stated The definition of income encompasses both revenue and gains Revenue arises in the course of the ordinary activities of an entity and is referred to by a variety of different names including sales fees interest dividends royalties and rent 4 30 Gains represent other items that meet the definition of income and may or may not arise in the course of the ordinary activities of an entity Gains represent increases in economic benefits and as such are no different in nature from revenue Hence they are not regarded as constituting a separate element in this Conceptual Framework 6 The current IFRS conceptual framework 7 4 68 no longer draws a distinction between revenue and gains Nevertheless the distinction continues to be drawn at the standard and reporting levels For example IFRS 9 5 7 1 states A gain or loss on a financial asset or financial liability that is measured at fair value shall be recognised in profit or loss while the IASB defined IFRS XBRL taxonomy 8 includes OtherGainsLosses GainsLossesOnNetMonetaryPosition and similar items US GAAP does not define income but does define comprehensive income CON 8 4 E75 Comprehensive income is the change in equity of a business entity during a period from transactions and other events and circumstances from nonowner sources It includes all changes in equity during a period except those resulting from investments by owners and distributions to owners According to John Hicks definitions income is the maximum amount which can be spent during a period if there is to be an expectation of maintaining intact the capital value of prospective receipts in money terms 9 Nonincome editDebt edit Borrowing or repaying money is not income under any definition for either the borrower or the lender 2 Interest and forgiveness of debt are income Psychic income edit Non monetary joy such as watching a sunset or having sex simply is not income 2 Similarly nonmonetary suffering such as heartbreak or labor are not negative income This may seem trivial but the non inclusion of psychic income has important effects on economics and tax policy 2 It encourages people to find happiness in nonmonetary nontaxable ways and means that reported income may overstate or understate the well being of a given individual 2 Income growth editIncome per capita has been increasing steadily in most countries 10 Many factors contribute to people having a higher income including education 11 globalisation and favorable political circumstances such as economic freedom and peace Increases in income also tend to lead to people choosing to work fewer hours Developed countries defined as countries with a developed economy have higher incomes as opposed to developing countries tending to have lower incomes Income inequality editIncome inequality is the extent to which income is distributed in an uneven manner It can be measured by various methods including the Lorenz curve and the Gini coefficient Many economists argue that certain amounts of inequality are necessary and desirable but that excessive inequality leads to efficiency problems and social injustice 1 Thereby necessitating initiatives like the United Nations Sustainable Development Goal 10 aimed at reducing inequality 12 National income measured by statistics such as net national income NNI measures the total income of individuals corporations and government in the economy For more information see Measures of national income and output Income in philosophy and ethics editThroughout history many have written about the impact of income on morality and society Saint Paul wrote For the love of money is a root of all kinds of evil 1 Timothy 6 10 ASV Some scholars have come to the conclusion that material progress and prosperity as manifested in continuous income growth at both the individual and the national level provide the indispensable foundation for sustaining any kind of morality This argument was explicitly given by Adam Smith in his Theory of Moral Sentiments 13 and has more recently been developed by Harvard economist Benjamin Friedman in his book The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth 14 Income and health editA landmark systematic review from Harvard University researchers in the Cochrane Collaboration found that income given in the form of unconditional cash transfers leads to reductions in disease improvements in food security and dietary diversity increases in children s school attendance decreases in extreme poverty and higher health care spending 15 16 History editIncome is conventionally denoted by Y in economics John Hicks used I for income but Keynes wrote to him in 1937 after trying both I believe it is easier to use Y for income and I for investment Some consider Y as an alternative letter for the phoneme I in languages like Spanish 17 although Y as the Greek I was actually pronounced like the modern German u or the phonetic y See also edit nbsp Look up income in Wiktionary the free dictionary Citizen s dividend Comprehensive income Guaranteed minimum income Income tax Revenue Social dividend Universal basic income Unpaid workReferences edit a b c d Barr N 2004 Problems and definition of measurement In Economics of the welfare state New York Oxford University Press pp 121 124 a b c d e f g h i j McCaffery Edward 2012 The Oxford Introductions to U S Law Income Tax Law 1st Edition Oxford University Press Case K amp Fair R 2007 Principles of Economics Upper Saddle River NJ Pearson Education p 54 Staff 2012 factor income BusinessDictionary com WebFinance Inc Archived from the original on 18 June 2012 Retrieved 20 June 2012 m Brooks John R The Definitions of Income 2018 Georgetown Law Faculty Publications and Other Works 1952 https scholarship law georgetown edu facpub 1952 admin Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting 2018 www iasplus com Retrieved 2022 06 28 IASB IASB Oxbridge Notes Retrieved 18 August 2016 Gapminder World Gapminder Foundation Gapminder World Gapminder Foundation Goal 10 targets UNDP Archived from the original on 2020 11 27 Retrieved 2020 09 23 Smith Adam 2009 The theory of moral sentiments Oxford Clarendon OCLC 1017407319 Friedman Benjamin M 2006 The moral consequences of economic growth New York NY Vintage Books ISBN 978 1 4000 9571 1 OCLC 71353264 Pega Frank Liu Sze Walter Stefan Pabayo Roman Saith Ruhi Lhachimi Stefan 2017 Unconditional cash transfers for reducing poverty and vulnerabilities effect on use of health services and health outcomes in low and middle income countries Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews 11 4 CD011135 doi 10 1002 14651858 CD011135 pub2 PMC 6486161 PMID 29139110 Pega Frank Pabayo Roman Benny Claire Lee Eun Young Lhachimi Stefan Liu Sze 2022 Unconditional cash transfers for reducing poverty and vulnerabilities effect on use of health services and health outcomes in low and middle income countries Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews 2022 3 CD011135 doi 10 1002 14651858 CD011135 pub3 PMC 8962215 PMID 35348196 Why Y Greg Mankiw s Blog December 21 2016 Further reading editD Usher 1987 real income The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics v 4 pp 104 5 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Income amp oldid 1192611726, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.