fbpx
Wikipedia

Mathematical economics

Mathematical economics is the application of mathematical methods to represent theories and analyze problems in economics. Often, these applied methods are beyond simple geometry, and may include differential and integral calculus, difference and differential equations, matrix algebra, mathematical programming, or other computational methods.[1][2] Proponents of this approach claim that it allows the formulation of theoretical relationships with rigor, generality, and simplicity.[3]

Mathematics allows economists to form meaningful, testable propositions about wide-ranging and complex subjects which could less easily be expressed informally. Further, the language of mathematics allows economists to make specific, positive claims about controversial or contentious subjects that would be impossible without mathematics.[4] Much of economic theory is currently presented in terms of mathematical economic models, a set of stylized and simplified mathematical relationships asserted to clarify assumptions and implications.[5]

Broad applications include:

  • optimization problems as to goal equilibrium, whether of a household, business firm, or policy maker
  • static (or equilibrium) analysis in which the economic unit (such as a household) or economic system (such as a market or the economy) is modeled as not changing
  • comparative statics as to a change from one equilibrium to another induced by a change in one or more factors
  • dynamic analysis, tracing changes in an economic system over time, for example from economic growth.[2][6][7]

Formal economic modeling began in the 19th century with the use of differential calculus to represent and explain economic behavior, such as utility maximization, an early economic application of mathematical optimization. Economics became more mathematical as a discipline throughout the first half of the 20th century, but introduction of new and generalized techniques in the period around the Second World War, as in game theory, would greatly broaden the use of mathematical formulations in economics.[8][7]

This rapid systematizing of economics alarmed critics of the discipline as well as some noted economists. John Maynard Keynes, Robert Heilbroner, Friedrich Hayek and others have criticized the broad use of mathematical models for human behavior, arguing that some human choices are irreducible to mathematics.

History

The use of mathematics in the service of social and economic analysis dates back to the 17th century. Then, mainly in German universities, a style of instruction emerged which dealt specifically with detailed presentation of data as it related to public administration. Gottfried Achenwall lectured in this fashion, coining the term statistics. At the same time, a small group of professors in England established a method of "reasoning by figures upon things relating to government" and referred to this practice as Political Arithmetick.[9] Sir William Petty wrote at length on issues that would later concern economists, such as taxation, Velocity of money and national income, but while his analysis was numerical, he rejected abstract mathematical methodology. Petty's use of detailed numerical data (along with John Graunt) would influence statisticians and economists for some time, even though Petty's works were largely ignored by English scholars.[10]

The mathematization of economics began in earnest in the 19th century. Most of the economic analysis of the time was what would later be called classical economics. Subjects were discussed and dispensed with through algebraic means, but calculus was not used. More importantly, until Johann Heinrich von Thünen's The Isolated State in 1826, economists did not develop explicit and abstract models for behavior in order to apply the tools of mathematics. Thünen's model of farmland use represents the first example of marginal analysis.[11] Thünen's work was largely theoretical, but he also mined empirical data in order to attempt to support his generalizations. In comparison to his contemporaries, Thünen built economic models and tools, rather than applying previous tools to new problems.[12]

Meanwhile, a new cohort of scholars trained in the mathematical methods of the physical sciences gravitated to economics, advocating and applying those methods to their subject,[13] and described today as moving from geometry to mechanics.[14] These included W.S. Jevons who presented paper on a "general mathematical theory of political economy" in 1862, providing an outline for use of the theory of marginal utility in political economy.[15] In 1871, he published The Principles of Political Economy, declaring that the subject as science "must be mathematical simply because it deals with quantities". Jevons expected that only collection of statistics for price and quantities would permit the subject as presented to become an exact science.[16] Others preceded and followed in expanding mathematical representations of economic problems. [17]

Marginalists and the roots of neoclassical economics

 
Equilibrium quantities as a solution to two reaction functions in Cournot duopoly. Each reaction function is expressed as a linear equation dependent upon quantity demanded.

Augustin Cournot and Léon Walras built the tools of the discipline axiomatically around utility, arguing that individuals sought to maximize their utility across choices in a way that could be described mathematically.[18] At the time, it was thought that utility was quantifiable, in units known as utils.[19] Cournot, Walras and Francis Ysidro Edgeworth are considered the precursors to modern mathematical economics.[20]

Augustin Cournot

Cournot, a professor of mathematics, developed a mathematical treatment in 1838 for duopoly—a market condition defined by competition between two sellers.[20] This treatment of competition, first published in Researches into the Mathematical Principles of Wealth,[21] is referred to as Cournot duopoly. It is assumed that both sellers had equal access to the market and could produce their goods without cost. Further, it assumed that both goods were homogeneous. Each seller would vary her output based on the output of the other and the market price would be determined by the total quantity supplied. The profit for each firm would be determined by multiplying their output by the per unit market price. Differentiating the profit function with respect to quantity supplied for each firm left a system of linear equations, the simultaneous solution of which gave the equilibrium quantity, price and profits.[22] Cournot's contributions to the mathematization of economics would be neglected for decades, but eventually influenced many of the marginalists.[22][23] Cournot's models of duopoly and oligopoly also represent one of the first formulations of non-cooperative games. Today the solution can be given as a Nash equilibrium but Cournot's work preceded modern game theory by over 100 years.[24]

Léon Walras

While Cournot provided a solution for what would later be called partial equilibrium, Léon Walras attempted to formalize discussion of the economy as a whole through a theory of general competitive equilibrium. The behavior of every economic actor would be considered on both the production and consumption side. Walras originally presented four separate models of exchange, each recursively included in the next. The solution of the resulting system of equations (both linear and non-linear) is the general equilibrium.[25] At the time, no general solution could be expressed for a system of arbitrarily many equations, but Walras's attempts produced two famous results in economics. The first is Walras' law and the second is the principle of tâtonnement. Walras' method was considered highly mathematical for the time and Edgeworth commented at length about this fact in his review of Éléments d'économie politique pure (Elements of Pure Economics).[26]

Walras' law was introduced as a theoretical answer to the problem of determining the solutions in general equilibrium. His notation is different from modern notation but can be constructed using more modern summation notation. Walras assumed that in equilibrium, all money would be spent on all goods: every good would be sold at the market price for that good and every buyer would expend their last dollar on a basket of goods. Starting from this assumption, Walras could then show that if there were n markets and n-1 markets cleared (reached equilibrium conditions) that the nth market would clear as well. This is easiest to visualize with two markets (considered in most texts as a market for goods and a market for money). If one of two markets has reached an equilibrium state, no additional goods (or conversely, money) can enter or exit the second market, so it must be in a state of equilibrium as well. Walras used this statement to move toward a proof of existence of solutions to general equilibrium but it is commonly used today to illustrate market clearing in money markets at the undergraduate level.[27]

Tâtonnement (roughly, French for groping toward) was meant to serve as the practical expression of Walrasian general equilibrium. Walras abstracted the marketplace as an auction of goods where the auctioneer would call out prices and market participants would wait until they could each satisfy their personal reservation prices for the quantity desired (remembering here that this is an auction on all goods, so everyone has a reservation price for their desired basket of goods).[28]

Only when all buyers are satisfied with the given market price would transactions occur. The market would "clear" at that price—no surplus or shortage would exist. The word tâtonnement is used to describe the directions the market takes in groping toward equilibrium, settling high or low prices on different goods until a price is agreed upon for all goods. While the process appears dynamic, Walras only presented a static model, as no transactions would occur until all markets were in equilibrium. In practice, very few markets operate in this manner.[29]

Francis Ysidro Edgeworth

Edgeworth introduced mathematical elements to Economics explicitly in Mathematical Psychics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences, published in 1881.[30] He adopted Jeremy Bentham's felicific calculus to economic behavior, allowing the outcome of each decision to be converted into a change in utility.[31] Using this assumption, Edgeworth built a model of exchange on three assumptions: individuals are self-interested, individuals act to maximize utility, and individuals are "free to recontract with another independently of...any third party".[32]

 
An Edgeworth box displaying the contract curve on an economy with two participants. Referred to as the "core" of the economy in modern parlance, there are infinitely many solutions along the curve for economies with two participants[33]

Given two individuals, the set of solutions where both individuals can maximize utility is described by the contract curve on what is now known as an Edgeworth Box. Technically, the construction of the two-person solution to Edgeworth's problem was not developed graphically until 1924 by Arthur Lyon Bowley.[34] The contract curve of the Edgeworth box (or more generally on any set of solutions to Edgeworth's problem for more actors) is referred to as the core of an economy.[35]

Edgeworth devoted considerable effort to insisting that mathematical proofs were appropriate for all schools of thought in economics. While at the helm of The Economic Journal, he published several articles criticizing the mathematical rigor of rival researchers, including Edwin Robert Anderson Seligman, a noted skeptic of mathematical economics.[36] The articles focused on a back and forth over tax incidence and responses by producers. Edgeworth noticed that a monopoly producing a good that had jointness of supply but not jointness of demand (such as first class and economy on an airplane, if the plane flies, both sets of seats fly with it) might actually lower the price seen by the consumer for one of the two commodities if a tax were applied. Common sense and more traditional, numerical analysis seemed to indicate that this was preposterous. Seligman insisted that the results Edgeworth achieved were a quirk of his mathematical formulation. He suggested that the assumption of a continuous demand function and an infinitesimal change in the tax resulted in the paradoxical predictions. Harold Hotelling later showed that Edgeworth was correct and that the same result (a "diminution of price as a result of the tax") could occur with a discontinuous demand function and large changes in the tax rate.[37]

Modern mathematical economics

From the later-1930s, an array of new mathematical tools from the differential calculus and differential equations, convex sets, and graph theory were deployed to advance economic theory in a way similar to new mathematical methods earlier applied to physics.[8][38] The process was later described as moving from mechanics to axiomatics.[39]

Differential calculus

Vilfredo Pareto analyzed microeconomics by treating decisions by economic actors as attempts to change a given allotment of goods to another, more preferred allotment. Sets of allocations could then be treated as Pareto efficient (Pareto optimal is an equivalent term) when no exchanges could occur between actors that could make at least one individual better off without making any other individual worse off.[40] Pareto's proof is commonly conflated with Walrassian equilibrium or informally ascribed to Adam Smith's Invisible hand hypothesis.[41] Rather, Pareto's statement was the first formal assertion of what would be known as the first fundamental theorem of welfare economics.[42] These models lacked the inequalities of the next generation of mathematical economics.

In the landmark treatise Foundations of Economic Analysis (1947), Paul Samuelson identified a common paradigm and mathematical structure across multiple fields in the subject, building on previous work by Alfred Marshall. Foundations took mathematical concepts from physics and applied them to economic problems. This broad view (for example, comparing Le Chatelier's principle to tâtonnement) drives the fundamental premise of mathematical economics: systems of economic actors may be modeled and their behavior described much like any other system. This extension followed on the work of the marginalists in the previous century and extended it significantly. Samuelson approached the problems of applying individual utility maximization over aggregate groups with comparative statics, which compares two different equilibrium states after an exogenous change in a variable. This and other methods in the book provided the foundation for mathematical economics in the 20th century.[7][43]

Linear models

Restricted models of general equilibrium were formulated by John von Neumann in 1937.[44] Unlike earlier versions, the models of von Neumann had inequality constraints. For his model of an expanding economy, von Neumann proved the existence and uniqueness of an equilibrium using his generalization of Brouwer's fixed point theorem. Von Neumann's model of an expanding economy considered the matrix pencil  A - λ B with nonnegative matrices A and B; von Neumann sought probability vectors p and q and a positive number λ that would solve the complementarity equation

pT (Aλ Bq = 0,

along with two inequality systems expressing economic efficiency. In this model, the (transposed) probability vector p represents the prices of the goods while the probability vector q represents the "intensity" at which the production process would run. The unique solution λ represents the rate of growth of the economy, which equals the interest rate. Proving the existence of a positive growth rate and proving that the growth rate equals the interest rate were remarkable achievements, even for von Neumann.[45][46][47] Von Neumann's results have been viewed as a special case of linear programming, where von Neumann's model uses only nonnegative matrices.[48] The study of von Neumann's model of an expanding economy continues to interest mathematical economists with interests in computational economics.[49][50][51]

Input-output economics

In 1936, the Russian–born economist Wassily Leontief built his model of input-output analysis from the 'material balance' tables constructed by Soviet economists, which themselves followed earlier work by the physiocrats. With his model, which described a system of production and demand processes, Leontief described how changes in demand in one economic sector would influence production in another.[52] In practice, Leontief estimated the coefficients of his simple models, to address economically interesting questions. In production economics, "Leontief technologies" produce outputs using constant proportions of inputs, regardless of the price of inputs, reducing the value of Leontief models for understanding economies but allowing their parameters to be estimated relatively easily. In contrast, the von Neumann model of an expanding economy allows for choice of techniques, but the coefficients must be estimated for each technology.[53][54]

Mathematical optimization

 
Red dot in z direction as maximum for paraboloid function of (x, y) inputs

In mathematics, mathematical optimization (or optimization or mathematical programming) refers to the selection of a best element from some set of available alternatives.[55] In the simplest case, an optimization problem involves maximizing or minimizing a real function by selecting input values of the function and computing the corresponding values of the function. The solution process includes satisfying general necessary and sufficient conditions for optimality. For optimization problems, specialized notation may be used as to the function and its input(s). More generally, optimization includes finding the best available element of some function given a defined domain and may use a variety of different computational optimization techniques.[56]

Economics is closely enough linked to optimization by agents in an economy that an influential definition relatedly describes economics qua science as the "study of human behavior as a relationship between ends and scarce means" with alternative uses.[57] Optimization problems run through modern economics, many with explicit economic or technical constraints. In microeconomics, the utility maximization problem and its dual problem, the expenditure minimization problem for a given level of utility, are economic optimization problems.[58] Theory posits that consumers maximize their utility, subject to their budget constraints and that firms maximize their profits, subject to their production functions, input costs, and market demand.[59]

Economic equilibrium is studied in optimization theory as a key ingredient of economic theorems that in principle could be tested against empirical data.[7][60] Newer developments have occurred in dynamic programming and modeling optimization with risk and uncertainty, including applications to portfolio theory, the economics of information, and search theory.[59]

Optimality properties for an entire market system may be stated in mathematical terms, as in formulation of the two fundamental theorems of welfare economics[61] and in the Arrow–Debreu model of general equilibrium (also discussed below).[62] More concretely, many problems are amenable to analytical (formulaic) solution. Many others may be sufficiently complex to require numerical methods of solution, aided by software.[56] Still others are complex but tractable enough to allow computable methods of solution, in particular computable general equilibrium models for the entire economy.[63]

Linear and nonlinear programming have profoundly affected microeconomics, which had earlier considered only equality constraints.[64] Many of the mathematical economists who received Nobel Prizes in Economics had conducted notable research using linear programming: Leonid Kantorovich, Leonid Hurwicz, Tjalling Koopmans, Kenneth J. Arrow, Robert Dorfman, Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow.[65] Both Kantorovich and Koopmans acknowledged that George B. Dantzig deserved to share their Nobel Prize for linear programming. Economists who conducted research in nonlinear programming also have won the Nobel prize, notably Ragnar Frisch in addition to Kantorovich, Hurwicz, Koopmans, Arrow, and Samuelson.

Linear optimization

Linear programming was developed to aid the allocation of resources in firms and in industries during the 1930s in Russia and during the 1940s in the United States. During the Berlin airlift (1948), linear programming was used to plan the shipment of supplies to prevent Berlin from starving after the Soviet blockade.[66][67]

Nonlinear programming

Extensions to nonlinear optimization with inequality constraints were achieved in 1951 by Albert W. Tucker and Harold Kuhn, who considered the nonlinear optimization problem:

Minimize   subject to   and   where
  is the function to be minimized
  are the functions of the   inequality constraints where  
  are the functions of the   equality constraints where  .

In allowing inequality constraints, the Kuhn–Tucker approach generalized the classic method of Lagrange multipliers, which (until then) had allowed only equality constraints.[68] The Kuhn–Tucker approach inspired further research on Lagrangian duality, including the treatment of inequality constraints.[69][70] The duality theory of nonlinear programming is particularly satisfactory when applied to convex minimization problems, which enjoy the convex-analytic duality theory of Fenchel and Rockafellar; this convex duality is particularly strong for polyhedral convex functions, such as those arising in linear programming. Lagrangian duality and convex analysis are used daily in operations research, in the scheduling of power plants, the planning of production schedules for factories, and the routing of airlines (routes, flights, planes, crews).[70]

Variational calculus and optimal control

Economic dynamics allows for changes in economic variables over time, including in dynamic systems. The problem of finding optimal functions for such changes is studied in variational calculus and in optimal control theory. Before the Second World War, Frank Ramsey and Harold Hotelling used the calculus of variations to that end.

Following Richard Bellman's work on dynamic programming and the 1962 English translation of L. Pontryagin et al.'s earlier work,[71] optimal control theory was used more extensively in economics in addressing dynamic problems, especially as to economic growth equilibrium and stability of economic systems,[72] of which a textbook example is optimal consumption and saving.[73] A crucial distinction is between deterministic and stochastic control models.[74] Other applications of optimal control theory include those in finance, inventories, and production for example.[75]

Functional analysis

It was in the course of proving of the existence of an optimal equilibrium in his 1937 model of economic growth that John von Neumann introduced functional analytic methods to include topology in economic theory, in particular, fixed-point theory through his generalization of Brouwer's fixed-point theorem.[8][44][76] Following von Neumann's program, Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu formulated abstract models of economic equilibria using convex sets and fixed–point theory. In introducing the Arrow–Debreu model in 1954, they proved the existence (but not the uniqueness) of an equilibrium and also proved that every Walras equilibrium is Pareto efficient; in general, equilibria need not be unique.[77] In their models, the ("primal") vector space represented quantities while the "dual" vector space represented prices.[78]

In Russia, the mathematician Leonid Kantorovich developed economic models in partially ordered vector spaces, that emphasized the duality between quantities and prices.[79] Kantorovich renamed prices as "objectively determined valuations" which were abbreviated in Russian as "o. o. o.", alluding to the difficulty of discussing prices in the Soviet Union.[78][80][81]

Even in finite dimensions, the concepts of functional analysis have illuminated economic theory, particularly in clarifying the role of prices as normal vectors to a hyperplane supporting a convex set, representing production or consumption possibilities. However, problems of describing optimization over time or under uncertainty require the use of infinite–dimensional function spaces, because agents are choosing among functions or stochastic processes.[78][82][83][84]

Differential decline and rise

John von Neumann's work on functional analysis and topology broke new ground in mathematics and economic theory.[44][85] It also left advanced mathematical economics with fewer applications of differential calculus. In particular, general equilibrium theorists used general topology, convex geometry, and optimization theory more than differential calculus, because the approach of differential calculus had failed to establish the existence of an equilibrium.

However, the decline of differential calculus should not be exaggerated, because differential calculus has always been used in graduate training and in applications. Moreover, differential calculus has returned to the highest levels of mathematical economics, general equilibrium theory (GET), as practiced by the "GET-set" (the humorous designation due to Jacques H. Drèze). In the 1960s and 1970s, however, Gérard Debreu and Stephen Smale led a revival of the use of differential calculus in mathematical economics. In particular, they were able to prove the existence of a general equilibrium, where earlier writers had failed, because of their novel mathematics: Baire category from general topology and Sard's lemma from differential topology. Other economists associated with the use of differential analysis include Egbert Dierker, Andreu Mas-Colell, and Yves Balasko.[86][87] These advances have changed the traditional narrative of the history of mathematical economics, following von Neumann, which celebrated the abandonment of differential calculus.

Game theory

John von Neumann, working with Oskar Morgenstern on the theory of games, broke new mathematical ground in 1944 by extending functional analytic methods related to convex sets and topological fixed-point theory to economic analysis.[8][85] Their work thereby avoided the traditional differential calculus, for which the maximum–operator did not apply to non-differentiable functions. Continuing von Neumann's work in cooperative game theory, game theorists Lloyd S. Shapley, Martin Shubik, Hervé Moulin, Nimrod Megiddo, Bezalel Peleg influenced economic research in politics and economics. For example, research on the fair prices in cooperative games and fair values for voting games led to changed rules for voting in legislatures and for accounting for the costs in public–works projects. For example, cooperative game theory was used in designing the water distribution system of Southern Sweden and for setting rates for dedicated telephone lines in the USA.

Earlier neoclassical theory had bounded only the range of bargaining outcomes and in special cases, for example bilateral monopoly or along the contract curve of the Edgeworth box.[88] Von Neumann and Morgenstern's results were similarly weak. Following von Neumann's program, however, John Nash used fixed–point theory to prove conditions under which the bargaining problem and noncooperative games can generate a unique equilibrium solution.[89] Noncooperative game theory has been adopted as a fundamental aspect of experimental economics,[90] behavioral economics,[91] information economics,[92] industrial organization,[93] and political economy.[94] It has also given rise to the subject of mechanism design (sometimes called reverse game theory), which has private and public-policy applications as to ways of improving economic efficiency through incentives for information sharing.[95]

In 1994, Nash, John Harsanyi, and Reinhard Selten received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences their work on non–cooperative games. Harsanyi and Selten were awarded for their work on repeated games. Later work extended their results to computational methods of modeling.[96]

Agent-based computational economics

Agent-based computational economics (ACE) as a named field is relatively recent, dating from about the 1990s as to published work. It studies economic processes, including whole economies, as dynamic systems of interacting agents over time. As such, it falls in the paradigm of complex adaptive systems.[97] In corresponding agent-based models, agents are not real people but "computational objects modeled as interacting according to rules" ... "whose micro-level interactions create emergent patterns" in space and time.[98] The rules are formulated to predict behavior and social interactions based on incentives and information. The theoretical assumption of mathematical optimization by agents markets is replaced by the less restrictive postulate of agents with bounded rationality adapting to market forces.[99]

ACE models apply numerical methods of analysis to computer-based simulations of complex dynamic problems for which more conventional methods, such as theorem formulation, may not find ready use.[100] Starting from specified initial conditions, the computational economic system is modeled as evolving over time as its constituent agents repeatedly interact with each other. In these respects, ACE has been characterized as a bottom-up culture-dish approach to the study of the economy.[101] In contrast to other standard modeling methods, ACE events are driven solely by initial conditions, whether or not equilibria exist or are computationally tractable. ACE modeling, however, includes agent adaptation, autonomy, and learning.[102] It has a similarity to, and overlap with, game theory as an agent-based method for modeling social interactions.[96] Other dimensions of the approach include such standard economic subjects as competition and collaboration,[103] market structure and industrial organization,[104] transaction costs,[105] welfare economics[106] and mechanism design,[95] information and uncertainty,[107] and macroeconomics.[108][109]

The method is said to benefit from continuing improvements in modeling techniques of computer science and increased computer capabilities. Issues include those common to experimental economics in general[110] and by comparison[111] and to development of a common framework for empirical validation and resolving open questions in agent-based modeling.[112] The ultimate scientific objective of the method has been described as "test[ing] theoretical findings against real-world data in ways that permit empirically supported theories to cumulate over time, with each researcher's work building appropriately on the work that has gone before".[113]

Mathematicization of economics

 
The surface of the Volatility smile is a 3-D surface whereby the current market implied volatility (Z-axis) for all options on the underlier is plotted against strike price and time to maturity (X & Y-axes).[114]

Over the course of the 20th century, articles in "core journals"[115] in economics have been almost exclusively written by economists in academia. As a result, much of the material transmitted in those journals relates to economic theory, and "economic theory itself has been continuously more abstract and mathematical."[116] A subjective assessment of mathematical techniques[117] employed in these core journals showed a decrease in articles that use neither geometric representations nor mathematical notation from 95% in 1892 to 5.3% in 1990.[118] A 2007 survey of ten of the top economic journals finds that only 5.8% of the articles published in 2003 and 2004 both lacked statistical analysis of data and lacked displayed mathematical expressions that were indexed with numbers at the margin of the page.[119]

Econometrics

Between the world wars, advances in mathematical statistics and a cadre of mathematically trained economists led to econometrics, which was the name proposed for the discipline of advancing economics by using mathematics and statistics. Within economics, "econometrics" has often been used for statistical methods in economics, rather than mathematical economics. Statistical econometrics features the application of linear regression and time series analysis to economic data.

Ragnar Frisch coined the word "econometrics" and helped to found both the Econometric Society in 1930 and the journal Econometrica in 1933.[120][121] A student of Frisch's, Trygve Haavelmo published The Probability Approach in Econometrics in 1944, where he asserted that precise statistical analysis could be used as a tool to validate mathematical theories about economic actors with data from complex sources.[122] This linking of statistical analysis of systems to economic theory was also promulgated by the Cowles Commission (now the Cowles Foundation) throughout the 1930s and 1940s.[123]

The roots of modern econometrics can be traced to the American economist Henry L. Moore. Moore studied agricultural productivity and attempted to fit changing values of productivity for plots of corn and other crops to a curve using different values of elasticity. Moore made several errors in his work, some from his choice of models and some from limitations in his use of mathematics. The accuracy of Moore's models also was limited by the poor data for national accounts in the United States at the time. While his first models of production were static, in 1925 he published a dynamic "moving equilibrium" model designed to explain business cycles—this periodic variation from over-correction in supply and demand curves is now known as the cobweb model. A more formal derivation of this model was made later by Nicholas Kaldor, who is largely credited for its exposition.[124]

Application

 
The IS/LM model is a Keynesian macroeconomic model designed to make predictions about the intersection of "real" economic activity (e.g. spending, income, savings rates) and decisions made in the financial markets (Money supply and Liquidity preference). The model is no longer widely taught at the graduate level but is common in undergraduate macroeconomics courses.[125]

Much of classical economics can be presented in simple geometric terms or elementary mathematical notation. Mathematical economics, however, conventionally makes use of calculus and matrix algebra in economic analysis in order to make powerful claims that would be more difficult without such mathematical tools. These tools are prerequisites for formal study, not only in mathematical economics but in contemporary economic theory in general. Economic problems often involve so many variables that mathematics is the only practical way of attacking and solving them. Alfred Marshall argued that every economic problem which can be quantified, analytically expressed and solved, should be treated by means of mathematical work.[126]

Economics has become increasingly dependent upon mathematical methods and the mathematical tools it employs have become more sophisticated. As a result, mathematics has become considerably more important to professionals in economics and finance. Graduate programs in both economics and finance require strong undergraduate preparation in mathematics for admission and, for this reason, attract an increasingly high number of mathematicians. Applied mathematicians apply mathematical principles to practical problems, such as economic analysis and other economics-related issues, and many economic problems are often defined as integrated into the scope of applied mathematics.[18]

This integration results from the formulation of economic problems as stylized models with clear assumptions and falsifiable predictions. This modeling may be informal or prosaic, as it was in Adam Smith's The Wealth of Nations, or it may be formal, rigorous and mathematical.

Broadly speaking, formal economic models may be classified as stochastic or deterministic and as discrete or continuous. At a practical level, quantitative modeling is applied to many areas of economics and several methodologies have evolved more or less independently of each other.[127]

Example: The effect of a corporate tax cut on wages

The great appeal of mathematical economics is that it brings a degree of rigor to economic thinking, particularly around charged political topics. For example, during the discussion of the efficacy of a corporate tax cut for increasing the wages of workers, a simple mathematical model proved beneficial to understanding the issues at hand.

As an intellectual exercise, the following problem was posed by Prof. Greg Mankiw of Harvard University:[128]

An open economy has the production function  , where   is output per worker and   is capital per worker. The capital stock adjusts so that the after-tax marginal product of capital equals the exogenously given world interest rate  ...How much will the tax cut increase wages?

To answer this question, we follow John H. Cochrane of the Hoover Institution.[129] Suppose an open economy has the production function:

 
Where the variables in this equation are:
  •   is the total output
  •   is the production function
  •   is the total capital stock
  •   is the total labor stock

The standard choice for the production function is the Cobb-Douglas production function:

 
where   is the factor of productivity - assumed to be a constant. A corporate tax cut in this model is equivalent to a tax on capital. With taxes, firms look to maximize:
 
where   is the capital tax rate,   is wages per worker, and   is the exogenous interest rate. Then the first-order optimality conditions become:
 
Therefore, the optimality conditions imply that:
 
Define total taxes  . This implies that taxes per worker   are:
 
Then the change in taxes per worker, given the tax rate, is:
 
To find the change in wages, we differentiate the second optimality condition for the per worker wages to obtain:
 
Assuming that the interest rate is fixed at  , so that  , we may differentiate the first optimality condition for the interest rate to find:
 
For the moment, let's focus only on the static effect of a capital tax cut, so that  . If we substitute this equation into equation for wage changes with respect to the tax rate, then we find that:
 
Therefore, the static effect of a capital tax cut on wages is:
 
Based on the model, it seems possible that we may achieve a rise in the wage of a worker greater than the amount of the tax cut. But that only considers the static effect, and we know that the dynamic effect must be accounted for. In the dynamic model, we may rewrite the equation for changes in taxes per worker with respect to the tax rate as:
 
Recalling that  , we have that:
 
Using the Cobb-Douglas production function, we have that:
 
Therefore, the dynamic effect of a capital tax cut on wages is:
 
If we take  , then the dynamic effect of lowering capital taxes on wages will be even larger than the static effect. Moreover, if there are positive externalities to capital accumulation, the effect of the tax cut on wages would be larger than in the model we just derived. It is important to note that the result is a combination of:
  1. The standard result that in a small open economy labor bears 100% of a small capital income tax
  2. The fact that, starting at a positive tax rate, the burden of a tax increase exceeds revenue collection due to the first-order deadweight loss

This result showing that, under certain assumptions, a corporate tax cut can boost the wages of workers by more than the lost revenue does not imply that the magnitude is correct. Rather, it suggests a basis for policy analysis that is not grounded in handwaving. If the assumptions are reasonable, then the model is an acceptable approximation of reality; if they are not, then better models should be developed.

CES production function

Now let's assume that instead of the Cobb-Douglas production function we have a more general constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function:

 
where  ;   is the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor. The relevant quantity we want to calculate is  , which may be derived as:
 
Therefore, we may use this to find that:
 
Therefore, under a general CES model, the dynamic effect of a capital tax cut on wages is:
 
We recover the Cobb-Douglas solution when  . When  , which is the case when perfect substitutes exist, we find that   - there is no effect of changes in capital taxes on wages. And when  , which is the case when perfect complements exist, we find that   - a cut in capital taxes increases wages by exactly one dollar.

Criticisms and defences

Adequacy of mathematics for qualitative and complicated economics

The Austrian school — while making many of the same normative economic arguments as mainstream economists from marginalist traditions, such as the Chicago school — differs methodologically from mainstream neoclassical schools of economics, in particular in their sharp critiques of the mathematization of economics.[130] Friedrich Hayek contended that the use of formal techniques projects a scientific exactness that does not appropriately account for informational limitations faced by real economic agents. [131]

In an interview in 1999, the economic historian Robert Heilbroner stated:[132]

I guess the scientific approach began to penetrate and soon dominate the profession in the past twenty to thirty years. This came about in part because of the "invention" of mathematical analysis of various kinds and, indeed, considerable improvements in it. This is the age in which we have not only more data but more sophisticated use of data. So there is a strong feeling that this is a data-laden science and a data-laden undertaking, which, by virtue of the sheer numerics, the sheer equations, and the sheer look of a journal page, bears a certain resemblance to science . . . That one central activity looks scientific. I understand that. I think that is genuine. It approaches being a universal law. But resembling a science is different from being a science.

Heilbroner stated that "some/much of economics is not naturally quantitative and therefore does not lend itself to mathematical exposition."[133]

Testing predictions of mathematical economics

Philosopher Karl Popper discussed the scientific standing of economics in the 1940s and 1950s. He argued that mathematical economics suffered from being tautological. In other words, insofar as economics became a mathematical theory, mathematical economics ceased to rely on empirical refutation but rather relied on mathematical proofs and disproof.[134] According to Popper, falsifiable assumptions can be tested by experiment and observation while unfalsifiable assumptions can be explored mathematically for their consequences and for their consistency with other assumptions.[135]

Sharing Popper's concerns about assumptions in economics generally, and not just mathematical economics, Milton Friedman declared that "all assumptions are unrealistic". Friedman proposed judging economic models by their predictive performance rather than by the match between their assumptions and reality.[136]

Mathematical economics as a form of pure mathematics

Considering mathematical economics, J.M. Keynes wrote in The General Theory:[137]

It is a great fault of symbolic pseudo-mathematical methods of formalising a system of economic analysis ... that they expressly assume strict independence between the factors involved and lose their cogency and authority if this hypothesis is disallowed; whereas, in ordinary discourse, where we are not blindly manipulating and know all the time what we are doing and what the words mean, we can keep ‘at the back of our heads’ the necessary reserves and qualifications and the adjustments which we shall have to make later on, in a way in which we cannot keep complicated partial differentials ‘at the back’ of several pages of algebra which assume they all vanish. Too large a proportion of recent ‘mathematical’ economics are merely concoctions, as imprecise as the initial assumptions they rest on, which allow the author to lose sight of the complexities and interdependencies of the real world in a maze of pretentious and unhelpful symbols.

Defense of mathematical economics

In response to these criticisms, Paul Samuelson argued that mathematics is a language, repeating a thesis of Josiah Willard Gibbs. In economics, the language of mathematics is sometimes necessary for representing substantive problems. Moreover, mathematical economics has led to conceptual advances in economics.[138] In particular, Samuelson gave the example of microeconomics, writing that "few people are ingenious enough to grasp [its] more complex parts... without resorting to the language of mathematics, while most ordinary individuals can do so fairly easily with the aid of mathematics."[139]

Some economists state that mathematical economics deserves support just like other forms of mathematics, particularly its neighbors in mathematical optimization and mathematical statistics and increasingly in theoretical computer science. Mathematical economics and other mathematical sciences have a history in which theoretical advances have regularly contributed to the reform of the more applied branches of economics. In particular, following the program of John von Neumann, game theory now provides the foundations for describing much of applied economics, from statistical decision theory (as "games against nature") and econometrics to general equilibrium theory and industrial organization. In the last decade, with the rise of the internet, mathematical economists and optimization experts and computer scientists have worked on problems of pricing for on-line services --- their contributions using mathematics from cooperative game theory, nondifferentiable optimization, and combinatorial games.

Robert M. Solow concluded that mathematical economics was the core "infrastructure" of contemporary economics:

Economics is no longer a fit conversation piece for ladies and gentlemen. It has become a technical subject. Like any technical subject it attracts some people who are more interested in the technique than the subject. That is too bad, but it may be inevitable. In any case, do not kid yourself: the technical core of economics is indispensable infrastructure for the political economy. That is why, if you consult [a reference in contemporary economics] looking for enlightenment about the world today, you will be led to technical economics, or history, or nothing at all.[140]

Mathematical economists

Prominent mathematical economists include the following.

19th century

20th century

See also

References

  1. ^ Elaborated at the JEL classification codes, Mathematical and quantitative methods JEL: C Subcategories.
  2. ^ a b Chiang, Alpha C.; Kevin Wainwright (2005). Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics. McGraw-Hill Irwin. pp. 3–4. ISBN 978-0-07-010910-0. TOC. 2012-03-08 at the Wayback Machine
  3. ^ Debreu, Gérard ([1987] 2008). "mathematical economics", section II, The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract. 2013-05-16 at the Wayback Machine Republished with revisions from 1986, "Theoretic Models: Mathematical Form and Economic Content", Econometrica, 54(6), pp. 1259 2017-08-05 at the Wayback Machine-1270.
  4. ^ Varian, Hal (1997). "What Use Is Economic Theory?" in A. D'Autume and J. Cartelier, ed., Is Economics Becoming a Hard Science?, Edward Elgar. Pre-publication PDF. 2006-06-25 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 2008-04-01.
  5. ^ * As in Handbook of Mathematical Economics, 1st-page chapter links:
         Arrow, Kenneth J., and Michael D. Intriligator, ed., (1981), v. 1
         _____ (1982). v. 2
         _____ (1986). v. 3
         Hildenbrand, Werner, and Hugo Sonnenschein, ed. (1991). v. 4. 2013-04-15 at the Wayback Machine
    • Debreu, Gérard (1983). Mathematical Economics: Twenty Papers of Gérard Debreu, Contents 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Glaister, Stephen (1984). Mathematical Methods for Economists, 3rd ed., Blackwell. Contents. 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine
    • Takayama, Akira (1985). Mathematical Economics, 2nd ed. Cambridge.
    Description 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine and Contents 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Michael Carter (2001). Foundations of Mathematical Economics, MIT Press. and Contents 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine.
  6. ^ Chiang, Alpha C. (1992). Elements of Dynamic Optimization, Waveland. & Amazon.com link 2016-03-03 at the Wayback Machine to inside, first pp.
  7. ^ a b c d Samuelson, Paul (1947) [1983]. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0-674-31301-9.
  8. ^ a b c d * Debreu, Gérard ([1987] 2008). "mathematical economics", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract. 2013-05-16 at the Wayback Machine Republished with revisions from 1986, "Theoretic Models: Mathematical Form and Economic Content", Econometrica, 54(6), pp. 1259 2017-08-05 at the Wayback Machine-1270.
  9. ^ Schumpeter, J.A. (1954). Elizabeth B. Schumpeter (ed.). History of Economic Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 209–212. ISBN 978-0-04-330086-2. OCLC 13498913. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2020-05-28.
  10. ^ Schumpeter (1954) p. 212-215
  11. ^ Schnieder, Erich (1934). "Johann Heinrich von Thünen". Econometrica. 2 (1): 1–12. doi:10.2307/1907947. ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 1907947. OCLC 35705710.
  12. ^ Schumpeter (1954) p. 465-468
  13. ^ Philip Mirowski, 1991. "The When, the How and the Why of Mathematical Expression in the History of Economics Analysis", Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1) pp. 145-157.[permanent dead link]
  14. ^ Weintraub, E. Roy (2008). "mathematics and economics", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2013-05-16 at the Wayback Machine.
  15. ^ Jevons, W.S. (1866). "Brief Account of a General Mathematical Theory of Political Economy", Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, XXIX (June) pp. 282–87. Read in Section F of the British Association, 1862.
  16. ^ Jevons, W. Stanley (1871). The Principles of Political Economy, pp. 4, 25. Macmillan. The Theory of Political Economy, jevons 1871.
  17. ^ See the preface 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine to Irving Fisher's 1897 work, A brief introduction to the infinitesimal calculus: designed especially to aid in reading mathematical economics and statistics.
  18. ^ a b Sheila C., Dow (1999-05-21). "The Use of Mathematics in Economics". ESRC Public Understanding of Mathematics Seminar. Birmingham: Economic and Social Research Council. Retrieved 2008-07-06.
  19. ^ While the concept of cardinality has fallen out of favor in neoclassical economics, the differences between cardinal utility and ordinal utility are minor for most applications.
  20. ^ a b Nicola, PierCarlo (2000). Mainstream Mathermatical Economics in the 20th Century. Springer. p. 4. ISBN 978-3-540-67084-1. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2008-08-21.
  21. ^ Augustin Cournot (1838, tr. 1897) Researches into the Mathematical Principles of Wealth. Links to description 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine and chapters. 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine
  22. ^ a b Hotelling, Harold (1990). "Stability in Competition". In Darnell, Adrian C. (ed.). The Collected Economics Articles of Harold Hotelling. Springer. pp. 51, 52. ISBN 978-3-540-97011-8. OCLC 20217006. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2008-08-21.
  23. ^ . The History of Economic Thought Website. The New School for Social Research. Archived from the original on 2000-07-09. Retrieved 2008-08-21.
  24. ^ Gibbons, Robert (1992). Game Theory for Applied Economists. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. pp. 14, 15. ISBN 978-0-691-00395-5.[permanent dead link]
  25. ^ Nicola, p. 9-12
  26. ^ Edgeworth, Francis Ysidro (September 5, 1889). (PDF). Nature. 40 (1036): 434–436. doi:10.1038/040434a0. ISSN 0028-0836. S2CID 21004543. Archived from the original (PDF) on April 11, 2003. Retrieved 2008-08-21.
  27. ^ Nicholson, Walter; Snyder, Christopher, p. 350-353.
  28. ^ Dixon, Robert. . Walras Law Guide. Department of Economics, University of Melbourne. Archived from the original on April 17, 2008. Retrieved 2008-09-28.
  29. ^ Dixon, Robert. . Walras Law Guide. Department of Economics, University of Melbourne. Archived from the original on April 30, 2008. Retrieved 2008-09-28.
  30. ^ Rima, Ingrid H. (1977). "Neoclassicism and Dissent 1890-1930". In Weintraub, Sidney (ed.). Modern Economic Thought. University of Pennsylvania Press. pp. 10, 11. ISBN 978-0-8122-7712-8. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2021-05-31.
  31. ^ Heilbroner, Robert L. (1999) [1953]. The Worldly Philosophers (Seventh ed.). New York: Simon and Schuster. pp. 172–175, 313. ISBN 978-0-684-86214-9. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2020-05-28.
  32. ^ Edgeworth, Francis Ysidro (1961) [1881]. Mathematical Psychics. London: Kegan Paul [A. M. Kelley]. pp. 15–19. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2020-05-28.
  33. ^ Nicola, p. 14, 15, 258-261
  34. ^ Bowley, Arthur Lyon (1960) [1924]. The Mathematical Groundwork of Economics: an Introductory Treatise. Oxford: Clarendon Press [Kelly]. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2020-05-28.
  35. ^ Gillies, D. B. (1969). "Solutions to general non-zero-sum games". In Tucker, A. W.; Luce, R. D. (eds.). Contributions to the Theory of Games. Annals of Mathematics. Vol. 40. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. pp. 47–85. ISBN 978-0-691-07937-0. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2020-05-28.
  36. ^ Moss, Lawrence S. (2003). "The Seligman-Edgeworth Debate about the Analysis of Tax Incidence: The Advent of Mathematical Economics, 1892–1910". History of Political Economy. 35 (2): 207, 212, 219, 234–237. doi:10.1215/00182702-35-2-205. ISSN 0018-2702.
  37. ^ Hotelling, Harold (1990). "Note on Edgeworth's Taxation Phenomenon and Professor Garver's Additional Condition on Demand Functions". In Darnell, Adrian C. (ed.). The Collected Economics Articles of Harold Hotelling. Springer. pp. 94–122. ISBN 978-3-540-97011-8. OCLC 20217006. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2008-08-26.
  38. ^ Herstein, I.N. (October 1953). "Some Mathematical Methods and Techniques in Economics". Quarterly of Applied Mathematics. 11 (3): 249–262. doi:10.1090/qam/60205. ISSN 1552-4485. [Pp. .
  39. ^ * Weintraub, E. Roy (2008). "mathematics and economics", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2013-05-16 at the Wayback Machine.
    • _____ (2002). How Economics Became a Mathematical Science. Duke University Press. and preview 2023-06-04 at the Wayback Machine.
  40. ^ Nicholson, Walter; Snyder, Christopher (2007). "General Equilibrium and Welfare". Intermediate Microeconomics and Its Applications (10th ed.). Thompson. pp. 364, 365. ISBN 978-0-324-31968-2.
  41. ^ * Jolink, Albert (2006). "What Went Wrong with Walras?". In Backhaus, Juergen G.; Maks, J.A. Hans (eds.). From Walras to Pareto. The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences. Vol. IV. Springer. pp. 69–80. doi:10.1007/978-0-387-33757-9_6. ISBN 978-0-387-33756-2.
    • Blaug, Mark (2007). "The Fundamental Theorems of Modern Welfare Economics, Historically Contemplated". History of Political Economy. 39 (2): 186–188. doi:10.1215/00182702-2007-001. ISSN 0018-2702. S2CID 154074343. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2020-01-27.
  42. ^ Blaug (2007), p. 185, 187
  43. ^ Metzler, Lloyd (1948). "Review of Foundations of Economic Analysis". American Economic Review. 38 (5): 905–910. ISSN 0002-8282. JSTOR 1811704.
  44. ^ a b c Neumann, J. von (1937). "Über ein ökonomisches Gleichungssystem und ein Verallgemeinerung des Brouwerschen Fixpunktsatzes", Ergebnisse eines Mathematischen Kolloquiums, 8, pp. 73–83, translated and published in 1945-46, as "A Model of General Equilibrium", Review of Economic Studies, 13, pp. 1–9.
  45. ^ For this problem to have a unique solution, it suffices that the nonnegative matrices A and B satisfy an irreducibility condition, generalizing that of the Perron–Frobenius theorem of nonnegative matrices, which considers the (simplified) eigenvalue problem
    Aλ I q = 0,
    where the nonnegative matrix A must be square and where the diagonal matrix I is the identity matrix. Von Neumann's irreducibility condition was called the "whales and wranglers" hypothesis by David Champernowne, who provided a verbal and economic commentary on the English translation of von Neumann's article. Von Neumann's hypothesis implied that every economic process used a positive amount of every economic good. Weaker "irreducibility" conditions were given by David Gale and by John Kemeny, Oskar Morgenstern, and Gerald L. Thompson in the 1950s and then by Stephen M. Robinson in the 1970s.
  46. ^ David Gale. The theory of linear economic models. McGraw-Hill, New York, 1960.
  47. ^ Morgenstern, Oskar; Thompson, Gerald L. (1976). Mathematical theory of expanding and contracting economies. Lexington Books. Lexington, Massachusetts: D. C. Heath and Company. pp. xviii+277.
  48. ^ Alexander Schrijver, Theory of Linear and Integer Programming. John Wiley & sons, 1998, ISBN 0-471-98232-6.
  49. ^
    • Rockafellar, R. Tyrrell (1967). Monotone processes of convex and concave type. Memoirs of the American Mathematical Society. Providence, R.I.: American Mathematical Society. pp. i+74.
    • Rockafellar, R. T. (1974). "Convex algebra and duality in dynamic models of production". In Josef Loz; Maria Loz (eds.). Mathematical models in economics (Proc. Sympos. and Conf. von Neumann Models, Warsaw, 1972). Amsterdam: North-Holland and Polish Academy of Sciences (PAN). pp. 351–378.
    • Rockafellar, R. T. (1997) [1970]. Convex analysis. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
  50. ^ Kenneth Arrow, Paul Samuelson, John Harsanyi, Sidney Afriat, Gerald L. Thompson, and Nicholas Kaldor. (1989). Mohammed Dore; Sukhamoy Chakravarty; Richard Goodwin (eds.). John Von Neumann and modern economics. Oxford:Clarendon. p. 261.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  51. ^ Chapter 9.1 "The von Neumann growth model" (pages 277–299): Yinyu Ye. Interior point algorithms: Theory and analysis. Wiley. 1997.
  52. ^ Screpanti, Ernesto; Zamagni, Stefano (1993). An Outline of the History of Economic Thought. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 288–290. ISBN 978-0-19-828370-6. OCLC 57281275.
  53. ^ David Gale. The theory of linear economic models. McGraw-Hill, New York, 1960.
  54. ^ Morgenstern, Oskar; Thompson, Gerald L. (1976). Mathematical theory of expanding and contracting economies. Lexington Books. Lexington, Massachusetts: D. C. Heath and Company. pp. xviii+277.
  55. ^ "", Mathematical Programming Glossary, INFORMS Computing Society.
  56. ^ a b Schmedders, Karl (2008). "numerical optimization methods in economics", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition, v. 6, pp. 138–57. Abstract. 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine
  57. ^ Robbins, Lionel (1935, 2nd ed.). An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science, Macmillan, p. 16.
  58. ^ Blume, Lawrence E. (2008). "duality", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract. 2017-02-02 at the Wayback Machine
  59. ^ a b Dixit, A. K. ([1976] 1990). Optimization in Economic Theory, 2nd ed., Oxford. Description 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine and contents preview 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine.
  60. ^ * Samuelson, Paul A., 1998. "How Foundations Came to Be", Journal of Economic Literature, 36(3), pp. 1375–1386.
    • _____ (1970)."Maximum Principles in Analytical Economics" 2012-10-11 at the Wayback Machine, Nobel Prize lecture.
  61. ^ * Allan M. Feldman (3008). "welfare economics", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine.
  62. ^ * Geanakoplos, John ([1987] 2008). "Arrow–Debreu model of general equilibrium", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Arrow, Kenneth J., and Gérard Debreu (1954). "Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy", Econometrica 22(3), pp. 265-290.
  63. ^ * Scarf, Herbert E. (2008). "computation of general equilibria", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract. 2009-05-23 at the Wayback Machine
     
    • Kubler, Felix (2008). "computation of general equilibria (new developments)", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract. 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine
  64. ^ Nicola, p. 133
  65. ^ Dorfman, Robert, Paul A. Samuelson, and Robert M. Solow (1958). Linear Programming and Economic Analysis. McGraw–Hill. Chapter-preview links. 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine
  66. ^ M. Padberg, Linear Optimization and Extensions, Second Edition, Springer-Verlag, 1999.
  67. ^ Dantzig, George B. ([1987] 2008). "linear programming", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine.
  68. ^ * Intriligator, Michael D. (2008). "nonlinear programming", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. TOC 2016-03-04 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Blume, Lawrence E. (2008). "convex programming", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition.
    Abstract 2017-10-18 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Kuhn, H. W.; Tucker, A. W. (1951). "Nonlinear programming". Proceedings of 2nd Berkeley Symposium. Berkeley: University of California Press. pp. 481–492.
  69. ^
    • Bertsekas, Dimitri P. (1999). Nonlinear Programming (Second ed.). Cambridge, Massachusetts.: Athena Scientific. ISBN 978-1-886529-00-7.
    • Vapnyarskii, I.B. (2001) [1994], "Lagrange multipliers", Encyclopedia of Mathematics, EMS Press.
    • Lasdon, Leon S. (1970). Optimization theory for large systems. Macmillan series in operations research. New York: The Macmillan Company. pp. xi+523. MR 0337317.
    • Lasdon, Leon S. (2002). Optimization theory for large systems (reprint of the 1970 Macmillan ed.). Mineola, New York: Dover Publications, Inc. pp. xiii+523. MR 1888251.
    • Hiriart-Urruty, Jean-Baptiste; Lemaréchal, Claude (1993). "XII Abstract duality for practitioners". Convex analysis and minimization algorithms, Volume II: Advanced theory and bundle methods. Grundlehren der Mathematischen Wissenschaften [Fundamental Principles of Mathematical Sciences]. Vol. 306. Berlin: Springer-Verlag. pp. 136–193 (and Bibliographical comments on pp. 334–335). ISBN 978-3-540-56852-0. MR 1295240.
  70. ^ a b Lemaréchal, Claude (2001). "Lagrangian relaxation". In Michael Jünger; Denis Naddef (eds.). Computational combinatorial optimization: Papers from the Spring School held in Schloß Dagstuhl, May 15–19, 2000. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. Vol. 2241. Berlin: Springer-Verlag. pp. 112–156. doi:10.1007/3-540-45586-8_4. ISBN 978-3-540-42877-0. MR 1900016. S2CID 9048698.
  71. ^ Pontryagin, L. S.; Boltyanski, V. G., Gamkrelidze, R. V., Mischenko, E. F. (1962). The Mathematical Theory of Optimal Processes. New York: Wiley. ISBN 9782881240775. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2015-06-27.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  72. ^ * Zelikin, M. I. ([1987] 2008). "Pontryagin's principle of optimality", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Preview link 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Martos, Béla (1987). "control and coordination of economic activity", The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. Description link 2016-03-06 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Brock, W. A. (1987). "optimal control and economic dynamics", The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. Outline 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Shell, K., ed. (1967). Essays on the Theory of Optimal Economic Growth. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-19036-7.]
  73. ^ Stokey, Nancy L. and Robert E. Lucas with Edward Prescott (1989). Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics, Harvard University Press, chapter 5. Desecription 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine and chapter-preview links 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine.
  74. ^ Malliaris, A.G. (2008). "stochastic optimal control", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2017-10-18 at the Wayback Machine.
  75. ^ * Arrow, K. J.; Kurz, M. (1970). Public Investment, the Rate of Return, and Optimal Fiscal Policy. Baltimore, Maryland: The Johns Hopkins Press. ISBN 978-0-8018-1124-1. Abstract. 2013-03-09 at the Wayback Machine
  76. ^ Andrew McLennan, 2008. "fixed point theorems", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2016-03-06 at the Wayback Machine.
  77. ^ Weintraub, E. Roy (1977). "General Equilibrium Theory". In Weintraub, Sidney (ed.). Modern Economic Thought. University of Pennsylvania Press. pp. 107–109. ISBN 978-0-8122-7712-8. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2020-05-28.
  78. ^ a b c Kantorovich, Leonid, and Victor Polterovich (2008). "Functional analysis", in S. Durlauf and L. Blume, ed., The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract. 2016-03-03 at the Wayback Machine, ed., Palgrave Macmillan.
  79. ^ Kantorovich, L. V (1990). ""My journey in science (supposed report to the Moscow Mathematical Society)" [expanding Russian Math. Surveys 42 (1987), no. 2, pp. 233–270]". In Lev J. Leifman (ed.). Functional analysis, optimization, and mathematical economics: A collection of papers dedicated to the memory of Leonid Vitalʹevich Kantorovich. New York: The Clarendon Press, Oxford University Press. pp. 8–45. ISBN 978-0-19-505729-4. MR 0898626.
  80. ^ Page 406: Polyak, B. T. (2002). "History of mathematical programming in the USSR: Analyzing the phenomenon (Chapter 3 The pioneer: L. V. Kantorovich, 1912–1986, pp. 405–407)". Mathematical Programming. Series B. 91 (ISMP 2000, Part 1 (Atlanta, GA), number 3): 401–416. doi:10.1007/s101070100258. MR 1888984. S2CID 13089965.
  81. ^ "Leonid Vitaliyevich Kantorovich — Prize Lecture ("Mathematics in economics: Achievements, difficulties, perspectives")". Nobelprize.org. from the original on 14 December 2010. Retrieved 12 Dec 2010.
  82. ^ Aliprantis, Charalambos D.; Brown, Donald J.; Burkinshaw, Owen (1990). Existence and optimality of competitive equilibria. Berlin: Springer–Verlag. pp. xii+284. ISBN 978-3-540-52866-1. MR 1075992.
  83. ^ Rockafellar, R. Tyrrell. Conjugate duality and optimization. Lectures given at the Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, Maryland, June, 1973. Conference Board of the Mathematical Sciences Regional Conference Series in Applied Mathematics, No. 16. Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, Philadelphia, Pa., 1974. vi+74 pp.
  84. ^ Lester G. Telser and Robert L. Graves Functional Analysis in Mathematical Economics: Optimization Over Infinite Horizons 1972. University of Chicago Press, 1972, ISBN 978-0-226-79190-6.
  85. ^ a b Neumann, John von, and Oskar Morgenstern (1944) Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, Princeton.
  86. ^ Mas-Colell, Andreu (1985). The Theory of general economic equilibrium: A differentiable approach. Econometric Society monographs. Cambridge UP. ISBN 978-0-521-26514-0. MR 1113262.
  87. ^ Yves Balasko. Foundations of the Theory of General Equilibrium, 1988, ISBN 0-12-076975-1.
  88. ^ Creedy, John (2008). "Francis Ysidro (1845–1926)", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine.
  89. ^ * Nash, John F., Jr. (1950). "The Bargaining Problem", Econometrica, 18(2), pp. 155-162 2016-03-04 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Serrano, Roberto (2008). "bargaining", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine.
  90. ^ * Smith, Vernon L. (1992). "Game Theory and Experimental Economics: Beginnings and Early Influences", in E. R. Weintraub, ed., Towards a History of Game Theory, pp. 241- 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine 282.
    • _____ (2001). "Experimental Economics", International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, pp. 5100–5108. Abstract 2018-10-14 at the Wayback Machine per sect. 1.1 & 2.1.
    • Plott, Charles R., and Vernon L. Smith, ed. (2008). Handbook of Experimental Economics Results, v. 1, Elsevier, Part 4, Games, ch. 45-66 preview links.
    • Shubik, Martin (2002). "Game Theory and Experimental Gaming", in R. Aumann and S. Hart, ed., Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications, Elsevier, v. 3, pp. 2327–2351. Abstract 2018-11-07 at the Wayback Machine.
  91. ^ From The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2008), 2nd Edition:
  92. ^ * Rasmusen, Eric (2007). Games and Information, 4th ed. Description 2017-06-24 at the Wayback Machine and chapter-preview links. 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine
    • Aumann, R., and S. Hart, ed. (1992, 2002). Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications v. 1, links at ch. 3-6 2017-08-16 at the Wayback Machine and v. 3, ch. 43 2018-10-14 at the Wayback Machine.
  93. ^ * Tirole, Jean (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT Press. and chapter-preview links, pp. vii-ix, "General Organization", pp. 5-6, and "Non-Cooperative Game Theory: A User's Guide Manual,' " ch. 11, pp. 423-59.
    • Bagwell, Kyle, and Asher Wolinsky (2002). "Game theory and Industrial Organization", ch. 49, Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications,
    v. 3, pp. 1851 2016-01-02 at the Wayback Machine-1895.
  94. ^
    • Shubik, Martin (1981). "Game Theory Models and Methods in Political Economy", in Handbook of Mathematical Economics,, v. 1, pp. 285[dead link]-330.
  95. ^ a b * The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2008), 2nd Edition:
         Myerson, Roger B. "mechanism design." Abstract. 2011-11-23 at the Wayback Machine
         _____. "revelation principle." Abstract. 2013-05-16 at the Wayback Machine
         Sandholm, Tuomas. "computing in mechanism design." Abstract. 2011-11-23 at the Wayback Machine
    • Nisan, Noam, and Amir Ronen (2001). "Algorithmic Mechanism Design", Games and Economic Behavior, 35(1-2), pp. 166–196 2018-10-14 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Nisan, Noam, et al., ed. (2007). Algorithmic Game Theory, Cambridge University Press. Description 2012-05-05 at the Wayback Machine.
  96. ^ a b * Halpern, Joseph Y. (2008). "computer science and game theory", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2017-11-05 at the Wayback Machine.
            
    • Shoham, Yoav (2008). "Computer Science and Game Theory", Communications of the ACM, 51(8), pp.
    75-79 2012-04-26 at the Wayback Machine.
            
    • Roth, Alvin E. (2002). "The Economist as Engineer: Game Theory, Experimentation, and Computation as Tools for Design Economics", Econometrica, 70(4), pp. .
  97. ^ * Kirman, Alan (2008). "economy as a complex system", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics , 2nd Edition. Abstract 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Tesfatsion, Leigh (2003). "Agent-based Computational Economics: Modeling Economies as Complex Adaptive Systems", Information Sciences, 149(4), pp. .
  98. ^ Scott E. Page (2008), "agent-based models", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2018-02-10 at the Wayback Machine.
  99. ^ * Holland, John H., and John H. Miller (1991). "Artificial Adaptive Agents in Economic Theory", American Economic Review, 81(2), pp. 365-370 2011-01-05 at the Wayback Machine p. 366.
  100. ^ * Judd, Kenneth L. (2006). "Computationally Intensive Analyses in Economics", Handbook of Computational Economics, v. 2, ch. 17, Introduction, p. 883. Pp. 881- 893. Pre-pub PDF 2022-01-21 at the Wayback Machine.
      • _____ (1998). Numerical Methods in Economics, MIT Press. Links to and chapter previews.
  101. ^ * Tesfatsion, Leigh (2002). "Agent-Based Computational Economics: Growing Economies from the Bottom Up", Artificial Life, 8(1), pp.55-82. Abstract 2020-03-06 at the Wayback Machine and pre-pub .
      • _____ (1997). "How Economists Can Get Alife", in W. B. Arthur, S. Durlauf, and D. Lane, eds., The Economy as an Evolving Complex System, II, pp. 533–564. Addison-Wesley. Pre-pub PDF 2012-04-15 at the Wayback Machine.
  102. ^ Tesfatsion, Leigh (2006), "Agent-Based Computational Economics: A Constructive Approach to Economic Theory", ch. 16, Handbook of Computational Economics, v. 2, part 2, ACE study of economic system. Abstract 2018-08-09 at the Wayback Machine and pre-pub PDF 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine.
  103. ^ Axelrod, Robert (1997). The Complexity of Cooperation: Agent-Based Models of Competition and Collaboration, Princeton. Description 2018-01-02 at the Wayback Machine, contents 2018-01-02 at the Wayback Machine, and preview 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine.
  104. ^ * Leombruni, Roberto, and Matteo Richiardi, ed. (2004), Industry and Labor Dynamics: The Agent-Based Computational Economics Approach. World Scientific Publishing ISBN 981-256-100-5. Description 2010-07-27 at the Wayback Machine and chapter-preview links 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine.
  105. ^ Klosa, Tomas B., and Bart Nooteboom, 2001. "Agent-based Computational Transaction Cost Economics", Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 25(3–4), pp. 503–52. Abstract. 2020-06-22 at the Wayback Machine
  106. ^ Axtell, Robert (2005). "The Complexity of Exchange", Economic Journal, 115(504, Features), pp. F193-F210 2017-08-08 at the Wayback Machine.
  107. ^ Sandholm, Tuomas W., and Victor R. Lesser (2001)."Leveled Commitment Contracts and Strategic Breach", Games and Economic Behavior, 35(1-2), pp. 212-270 2020-12-04 at the Wayback Machine.
  108. ^ * Colander, David, Peter Howitt, Alan Kirman, Axel Leijonhufvud, and Perry Mehrling (2008). "Beyond DSGE Models: Toward an Empirically Based Macroeconomics", American Economic Review, 98(2), pp. 236-240. Pre-pub .
  109. ^ Tesfatsion, Leigh (2006), "Agent-Based Computational Economics: A Constructive Approach to Economic Theory", ch. 16, Handbook of Computational Economics, v. 2, pp. 832–865. Abstract 2018-08-09 at the Wayback Machine and pre-pub PDF 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine.
  110. ^ Smith, Vernon L. (2008). "experimental economics", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract 2012-01-19 at the Wayback Machine.
  111. ^ Duffy, John (2006). "Agent-Based Models and Human Subject Experiments", ch. 19, Handbook of Computational Economics, v.2, pp. 949–101. Abstract 2015-09-24 at the Wayback Machine.
  112. ^ * Namatame, Akira, and Takao Terano (2002). "The Hare and the Tortoise: Cumulative Progress in Agent-based Simulation", in Agent-based Approaches in Economic and Social Complex Systems. pp. 3- 14, IOS Press. Description 2012-04-05 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Fagiolo, Giorgio, Alessio Moneta, and Paul Windrum (2007). "A Critical Guide to Empirical Validation of Agent-Based Models in Economics: Methodologies, Procedures, and Open Problems", Computational Economics, 30, pp. 195 2023-07-01 at the Wayback Machine–226.
  113. ^ * Tesfatsion, Leigh (2006). "Agent-Based Computational Economics: A Constructive Approach to Economic Theory", ch. 16, Handbook of Computational Economics, v. 2, [pp. 831–880] sect. 5. Abstract 2018-08-09 at the Wayback Machine and pre-pub PDF 2017-08-11 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Judd, Kenneth L. (2006). "Computationally Intensive Analyses in Economics", Handbook of Computational Economics, v. 2, ch. 17, pp. 881- 893. Pre-pub PDF 2022-01-21 at the Wayback Machine.
    • Tesfatsion, Leigh, and Kenneth L. Judd, ed. (2006). Handbook of Computational Economics, v. 2. Description 2012-03-06 at the Wayback Machine & and chapter-preview
    links.
  114. ^ Brockhaus, Oliver; Farkas, Michael; Ferraris, Andrew; Long, Douglas; Overhaus, Marcus (2000). Equity Derivatives and Market Risk Models. Risk Books. pp. 13–17. ISBN 978-1-899332-87-8. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2008-08-17.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  115. ^ Liner, Gaines H. (2002). "Core Journals in Economics". Economic Inquiry. 40 (1): 140. doi:10.1093/ei/40.1.138.
  116. ^ Stigler, George J.; Stigler, Steven J.; Friedland, Claire (April 1995). "The Journals of Economics". The Journal of Political Economy. 103 (2): 331–359. doi:10.1086/261986. ISSN 0022-3808. JSTOR 2138643. S2CID 154780520. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2020-01-27.
  117. ^ Stigler et al. reviewed journal articles in core economic journals (as defined by the authors but meaning generally non-specialist journals) throughout the 20th century. Journal articles which at any point used geometric representation or mathematical notation were noted as using that level of mathematics as its "highest level of mathematical technique". The authors refer to "verbal techniques" as those which conveyed the subject of the piece without notation from geometry, algebra or calculus.
  118. ^ Stigler et al., p. 342
  119. ^ Sutter, Daniel and Rex Pjesky. "Where Would Adam Smith Publish Today?: The Near Absence of Math-free Research in Top Journals" (May 2007). [2] 2017-10-10 at the Wayback Machine
  120. ^ Arrow, Kenneth J. (April 1960). "The Work of Ragnar Frisch, Econometrician". Econometrica. 28 (2): 175–192. doi:10.2307/1907716. ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 1907716.
  121. ^ Bjerkholt, Olav (July 1995). "Ragnar Frisch, Editor of Econometrica 1933-1954". Econometrica. 63 (4): 755–765. doi:10.2307/2171799. ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 1906940.
  122. ^ Lange, Oskar (1945). "The Scope and Method of Economics". Review of Economic Studies. 13 (1): 19–32. doi:10.2307/2296113. ISSN 0034-6527. JSTOR 2296113. S2CID 4140287.
  123. ^ Aldrich, John (January 1989). "Autonomy". Oxford Economic Papers. 41 (1, History and Methodology of Econometrics): 15–34. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a041889. ISSN 0030-7653. JSTOR 2663180.
  124. ^ Epstein, Roy J. (1987). A History of Econometrics. Contributions to Economic Analysis. North-Holland. pp. 13–19. ISBN 978-0-444-70267-8. OCLC 230844893.
  125. ^ Colander, David C. (2004). "The Strange Persistence of the IS-LM Model". History of Political Economy. 36 (Annual Supplement): 305–322. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.692.6446. doi:10.1215/00182702-36-Suppl_1-305. ISSN 0018-2702. S2CID 6705939.
  126. ^ Brems, Hans (October 1975). "Marshall on Mathematics". Journal of Law and Economics. 18 (2): 583–585. doi:10.1086/466825. ISSN 0022-2186. JSTOR 725308. S2CID 154881432.
  127. ^ Frigg, R.; Hartman, S. (February 27, 2006). Edward N. Zalta (ed.). Models in Science. Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. Stanford, California: The Metaphysics Research Lab. ISSN 1095-5054. from the original on 2007-06-09. Retrieved 2008-08-16.
  128. ^ "Greg Mankiw's Blog: An Exercise for My Readers". from the original on 2019-08-07. Retrieved 2019-08-07.
  129. ^ Cochrane, John H. (2017-10-21). "The Grumpy Economist: Greg's algebra". The Grumpy Economist. from the original on 2023-07-01. Retrieved 2019-08-07.
  130. ^ Ekelund, Robert; Hébert, Robert (2014). A History of Economic Theory & Method (6th ed.). Long Grove, IL: Waveland Press. pp. 574–575.
  131. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (September 1945). "The Use of Knowledge in Society". American Economic Review. 35 (4): 519–530. JSTOR 1809376.
  132. ^ Heilbroner, Robert (May–June 1999). . Challenge Magazine. Archived from the original on 2008-12-10.
  133. ^ Beed & Owen, 584
  134. ^ Boland, L. A. (2007). "Seven Decades of Economic Methodology". In I. C. Jarvie; K. Milford; D.W. Miller (eds.). Karl Popper:A Centenary Assessment. London: Ashgate Publishing. p. 219. ISBN 978-0-7546-5375-2. Retrieved 2008-06-10.
  135. ^ Beed, Clive; Kane, Owen (1991). "What Is the Critique of the Mathematization of Economics?". Kyklos. 44 (4): 581–612. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6435.1991.tb01798.x.
  136. ^ Friedman, Milton (1953). Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. pp. 30, 33, 41. ISBN 978-0-226-26403-5.
  137. ^ Keynes, John Maynard (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Cambridge: Macmillan. p. 297. ISBN 978-0-333-10729-4. from the original on 2019-05-28. Retrieved 2009-04-30.
  138. ^ Paul A. Samuelson (1952). "Economic Theory and Mathematics — An Appraisal", American Economic Review, 42(2), pp. (press +).
  139. ^ D.W. Bushaw and R.W. Clower (1957). Introduction to Mathematical Economics, p. vii. 2022-03-18 at the Wayback Machine
  140. ^ Solow, Robert M. (20 March 1988). "The Wide, Wide World Of Wealth (The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. Edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate and Peter Newman. Four volumes. 4,103 pp. New York: Stockton Press. $650)". New York Times. from the original on 1 August 2017. Retrieved 11 February 2017.

Further reading

  • Alpha C. Chiang and Kevin Wainwright, [1967] 2005. Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics, McGraw-Hill Irwin. Contents.
  • E. Roy Weintraub, 1982. Mathematics for Economists, Cambridge. Contents.
  • Stephen Glaister, 1984. Mathematical Methods for Economists, 3rd ed., Blackwell. Contents.
  • Akira Takayama, 1985. Mathematical Economics, 2nd ed. Cambridge. Contents.
  • Nancy L. Stokey and Robert E. Lucas with Edward Prescott, 1989. Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics, Harvard University Press. Desecription and chapter-preview links.
  • A. K. Dixit, [1976] 1990. Optimization in Economic Theory, 2nd ed., Oxford. Description and contents preview.
  • Kenneth L. Judd, 1998. Numerical Methods in Economics, MIT Press. and chapter-preview links.
  • Michael Carter, 2001. Foundations of Mathematical Economics, MIT Press. Contents.
  • Ferenc Szidarovszky and Sándor Molnár, 2002. Introduction to Matrix Theory: With Applications to Business and Economics, World Scientific Publishing. Description and preview.
  • D. Wade Hands, 2004. Introductory Mathematical Economics, 2nd ed. Oxford. Contents.
  • Giancarlo Gandolfo, [1997] 2009. Economic Dynamics, 4th ed., Springer. Description and preview.
  • John Stachurski, 2009. Economic Dynamics: Theory and Computation, MIT Press. and preview.

External links

  • Journal of Mathematical Economics Aims & Scope
  • Mathematical Economics and Financial Mathematics at Curlie
  • Erasmus Mundus Master QEM - Models and Methods of Quantitative Economics, The Models and Methods of Quantitative Economics - QEM

mathematical, economics, application, mathematical, methods, represent, theories, analyze, problems, economics, often, these, applied, methods, beyond, simple, geometry, include, differential, integral, calculus, difference, differential, equations, matrix, al. Mathematical economics is the application of mathematical methods to represent theories and analyze problems in economics Often these applied methods are beyond simple geometry and may include differential and integral calculus difference and differential equations matrix algebra mathematical programming or other computational methods 1 2 Proponents of this approach claim that it allows the formulation of theoretical relationships with rigor generality and simplicity 3 Mathematics allows economists to form meaningful testable propositions about wide ranging and complex subjects which could less easily be expressed informally Further the language of mathematics allows economists to make specific positive claims about controversial or contentious subjects that would be impossible without mathematics 4 Much of economic theory is currently presented in terms of mathematical economic models a set of stylized and simplified mathematical relationships asserted to clarify assumptions and implications 5 Broad applications include optimization problems as to goal equilibrium whether of a household business firm or policy maker static or equilibrium analysis in which the economic unit such as a household or economic system such as a market or the economy is modeled as not changing comparative statics as to a change from one equilibrium to another induced by a change in one or more factors dynamic analysis tracing changes in an economic system over time for example from economic growth 2 6 7 Formal economic modeling began in the 19th century with the use of differential calculus to represent and explain economic behavior such as utility maximization an early economic application of mathematical optimization Economics became more mathematical as a discipline throughout the first half of the 20th century but introduction of new and generalized techniques in the period around the Second World War as in game theory would greatly broaden the use of mathematical formulations in economics 8 7 This rapid systematizing of economics alarmed critics of the discipline as well as some noted economists John Maynard Keynes Robert Heilbroner Friedrich Hayek and others have criticized the broad use of mathematical models for human behavior arguing that some human choices are irreducible to mathematics Contents 1 History 1 1 Marginalists and the roots of neoclassical economics 1 1 1 Augustin Cournot 1 1 2 Leon Walras 1 1 3 Francis Ysidro Edgeworth 2 Modern mathematical economics 2 1 Differential calculus 2 2 Linear models 2 2 1 Input output economics 2 3 Mathematical optimization 2 3 1 Linear optimization 2 3 2 Nonlinear programming 2 3 3 Variational calculus and optimal control 2 3 4 Functional analysis 2 4 Differential decline and rise 2 5 Game theory 2 6 Agent based computational economics 3 Mathematicization of economics 4 Econometrics 5 Application 6 Example The effect of a corporate tax cut on wages 6 1 CES production function 7 Criticisms and defences 7 1 Adequacy of mathematics for qualitative and complicated economics 7 2 Testing predictions of mathematical economics 7 3 Mathematical economics as a form of pure mathematics 7 4 Defense of mathematical economics 8 Mathematical economists 8 1 19th century 8 2 20th century 9 See also 10 References 11 Further reading 12 External linksHistory EditMain article History of economic thought The use of mathematics in the service of social and economic analysis dates back to the 17th century Then mainly in German universities a style of instruction emerged which dealt specifically with detailed presentation of data as it related to public administration Gottfried Achenwall lectured in this fashion coining the term statistics At the same time a small group of professors in England established a method of reasoning by figures upon things relating to government and referred to this practice as Political Arithmetick 9 Sir William Petty wrote at length on issues that would later concern economists such as taxation Velocity of money and national income but while his analysis was numerical he rejected abstract mathematical methodology Petty s use of detailed numerical data along with John Graunt would influence statisticians and economists for some time even though Petty s works were largely ignored by English scholars 10 The mathematization of economics began in earnest in the 19th century Most of the economic analysis of the time was what would later be called classical economics Subjects were discussed and dispensed with through algebraic means but calculus was not used More importantly until Johann Heinrich von Thunen s The Isolated State in 1826 economists did not develop explicit and abstract models for behavior in order to apply the tools of mathematics Thunen s model of farmland use represents the first example of marginal analysis 11 Thunen s work was largely theoretical but he also mined empirical data in order to attempt to support his generalizations In comparison to his contemporaries Thunen built economic models and tools rather than applying previous tools to new problems 12 Meanwhile a new cohort of scholars trained in the mathematical methods of the physical sciences gravitated to economics advocating and applying those methods to their subject 13 and described today as moving from geometry to mechanics 14 These included W S Jevons who presented paper on a general mathematical theory of political economy in 1862 providing an outline for use of the theory of marginal utility in political economy 15 In 1871 he published The Principles of Political Economy declaring that the subject as science must be mathematical simply because it deals with quantities Jevons expected that only collection of statistics for price and quantities would permit the subject as presented to become an exact science 16 Others preceded and followed in expanding mathematical representations of economic problems 17 Marginalists and the roots of neoclassical economics Edit Main article Marginalism Equilibrium quantities as a solution to two reaction functions in Cournot duopoly Each reaction function is expressed as a linear equation dependent upon quantity demanded Augustin Cournot and Leon Walras built the tools of the discipline axiomatically around utility arguing that individuals sought to maximize their utility across choices in a way that could be described mathematically 18 At the time it was thought that utility was quantifiable in units known as utils 19 Cournot Walras and Francis Ysidro Edgeworth are considered the precursors to modern mathematical economics 20 Augustin Cournot Edit Cournot a professor of mathematics developed a mathematical treatment in 1838 for duopoly a market condition defined by competition between two sellers 20 This treatment of competition first published in Researches into the Mathematical Principles of Wealth 21 is referred to as Cournot duopoly It is assumed that both sellers had equal access to the market and could produce their goods without cost Further it assumed that both goods were homogeneous Each seller would vary her output based on the output of the other and the market price would be determined by the total quantity supplied The profit for each firm would be determined by multiplying their output by the per unit market price Differentiating the profit function with respect to quantity supplied for each firm left a system of linear equations the simultaneous solution of which gave the equilibrium quantity price and profits 22 Cournot s contributions to the mathematization of economics would be neglected for decades but eventually influenced many of the marginalists 22 23 Cournot s models of duopoly and oligopoly also represent one of the first formulations of non cooperative games Today the solution can be given as a Nash equilibrium but Cournot s work preceded modern game theory by over 100 years 24 Leon Walras Edit While Cournot provided a solution for what would later be called partial equilibrium Leon Walras attempted to formalize discussion of the economy as a whole through a theory of general competitive equilibrium The behavior of every economic actor would be considered on both the production and consumption side Walras originally presented four separate models of exchange each recursively included in the next The solution of the resulting system of equations both linear and non linear is the general equilibrium 25 At the time no general solution could be expressed for a system of arbitrarily many equations but Walras s attempts produced two famous results in economics The first is Walras law and the second is the principle of tatonnement Walras method was considered highly mathematical for the time and Edgeworth commented at length about this fact in his review of Elements d economie politique pure Elements of Pure Economics 26 Walras law was introduced as a theoretical answer to the problem of determining the solutions in general equilibrium His notation is different from modern notation but can be constructed using more modern summation notation Walras assumed that in equilibrium all money would be spent on all goods every good would be sold at the market price for that good and every buyer would expend their last dollar on a basket of goods Starting from this assumption Walras could then show that if there were n markets and n 1 markets cleared reached equilibrium conditions that the nth market would clear as well This is easiest to visualize with two markets considered in most texts as a market for goods and a market for money If one of two markets has reached an equilibrium state no additional goods or conversely money can enter or exit the second market so it must be in a state of equilibrium as well Walras used this statement to move toward a proof of existence of solutions to general equilibrium but it is commonly used today to illustrate market clearing in money markets at the undergraduate level 27 Tatonnement roughly French for groping toward was meant to serve as the practical expression of Walrasian general equilibrium Walras abstracted the marketplace as an auction of goods where the auctioneer would call out prices and market participants would wait until they could each satisfy their personal reservation prices for the quantity desired remembering here that this is an auction on all goods so everyone has a reservation price for their desired basket of goods 28 Only when all buyers are satisfied with the given market price would transactions occur The market would clear at that price no surplus or shortage would exist The word tatonnement is used to describe the directions the market takes in groping toward equilibrium settling high or low prices on different goods until a price is agreed upon for all goods While the process appears dynamic Walras only presented a static model as no transactions would occur until all markets were in equilibrium In practice very few markets operate in this manner 29 Francis Ysidro Edgeworth Edit Edgeworth introduced mathematical elements to Economics explicitly in Mathematical Psychics An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences published in 1881 30 He adopted Jeremy Bentham s felicific calculus to economic behavior allowing the outcome of each decision to be converted into a change in utility 31 Using this assumption Edgeworth built a model of exchange on three assumptions individuals are self interested individuals act to maximize utility and individuals are free to recontract with another independently of any third party 32 An Edgeworth box displaying the contract curve on an economy with two participants Referred to as the core of the economy in modern parlance there are infinitely many solutions along the curve for economies with two participants 33 Given two individuals the set of solutions where both individuals can maximize utility is described by the contract curve on what is now known as an Edgeworth Box Technically the construction of the two person solution to Edgeworth s problem was not developed graphically until 1924 by Arthur Lyon Bowley 34 The contract curve of the Edgeworth box or more generally on any set of solutions to Edgeworth s problem for more actors is referred to as the core of an economy 35 Edgeworth devoted considerable effort to insisting that mathematical proofs were appropriate for all schools of thought in economics While at the helm of The Economic Journal he published several articles criticizing the mathematical rigor of rival researchers including Edwin Robert Anderson Seligman a noted skeptic of mathematical economics 36 The articles focused on a back and forth over tax incidence and responses by producers Edgeworth noticed that a monopoly producing a good that had jointness of supply but not jointness of demand such as first class and economy on an airplane if the plane flies both sets of seats fly with it might actually lower the price seen by the consumer for one of the two commodities if a tax were applied Common sense and more traditional numerical analysis seemed to indicate that this was preposterous Seligman insisted that the results Edgeworth achieved were a quirk of his mathematical formulation He suggested that the assumption of a continuous demand function and an infinitesimal change in the tax resulted in the paradoxical predictions Harold Hotelling later showed that Edgeworth was correct and that the same result a diminution of price as a result of the tax could occur with a discontinuous demand function and large changes in the tax rate 37 Modern mathematical economics EditFrom the later 1930s an array of new mathematical tools from the differential calculus and differential equations convex sets and graph theory were deployed to advance economic theory in a way similar to new mathematical methods earlier applied to physics 8 38 The process was later described as moving from mechanics to axiomatics 39 Differential calculus Edit Main articles Foundations of Economic Analysis and Differential calculus See also Pareto efficiency and Walrasian auction Vilfredo Pareto analyzed microeconomics by treating decisions by economic actors as attempts to change a given allotment of goods to another more preferred allotment Sets of allocations could then be treated as Pareto efficient Pareto optimal is an equivalent term when no exchanges could occur between actors that could make at least one individual better off without making any other individual worse off 40 Pareto s proof is commonly conflated with Walrassian equilibrium or informally ascribed to Adam Smith s Invisible hand hypothesis 41 Rather Pareto s statement was the first formal assertion of what would be known as the first fundamental theorem of welfare economics 42 These models lacked the inequalities of the next generation of mathematical economics In the landmark treatise Foundations of Economic Analysis 1947 Paul Samuelson identified a common paradigm and mathematical structure across multiple fields in the subject building on previous work by Alfred Marshall Foundations took mathematical concepts from physics and applied them to economic problems This broad view for example comparing Le Chatelier s principle to tatonnement drives the fundamental premise of mathematical economics systems of economic actors may be modeled and their behavior described much like any other system This extension followed on the work of the marginalists in the previous century and extended it significantly Samuelson approached the problems of applying individual utility maximization over aggregate groups with comparative statics which compares two different equilibrium states after an exogenous change in a variable This and other methods in the book provided the foundation for mathematical economics in the 20th century 7 43 Linear models Edit See also Linear algebra Linear programming and Perron Frobenius theorem Restricted models of general equilibrium were formulated by John von Neumann in 1937 44 Unlike earlier versions the models of von Neumann had inequality constraints For his model of an expanding economy von Neumann proved the existence and uniqueness of an equilibrium using his generalization of Brouwer s fixed point theorem Von Neumann s model of an expanding economy considered the matrix pencil A l B with nonnegative matrices A and B von Neumann sought probability vectors p and q and a positive number l that would solve the complementarity equation pT A l B q 0 along with two inequality systems expressing economic efficiency In this model the transposed probability vector p represents the prices of the goods while the probability vector q represents the intensity at which the production process would run The unique solution l represents the rate of growth of the economy which equals the interest rate Proving the existence of a positive growth rate and proving that the growth rate equals the interest rate were remarkable achievements even for von Neumann 45 46 47 Von Neumann s results have been viewed as a special case of linear programming where von Neumann s model uses only nonnegative matrices 48 The study of von Neumann s model of an expanding economy continues to interest mathematical economists with interests in computational economics 49 50 51 Input output economics Edit Main article Input output model In 1936 the Russian born economist Wassily Leontief built his model of input output analysis from the material balance tables constructed by Soviet economists which themselves followed earlier work by the physiocrats With his model which described a system of production and demand processes Leontief described how changes in demand in one economic sector would influence production in another 52 In practice Leontief estimated the coefficients of his simple models to address economically interesting questions In production economics Leontief technologies produce outputs using constant proportions of inputs regardless of the price of inputs reducing the value of Leontief models for understanding economies but allowing their parameters to be estimated relatively easily In contrast the von Neumann model of an expanding economy allows for choice of techniques but the coefficients must be estimated for each technology 53 54 Mathematical optimization Edit Red dot in z direction as maximum for paraboloid function of x y inputsMain articles Mathematical optimization and Dual problem See also Convexity in economics and Non convexity economics In mathematics mathematical optimization or optimization or mathematical programming refers to the selection of a best element from some set of available alternatives 55 In the simplest case an optimization problem involves maximizing or minimizing a real function by selecting input values of the function and computing the corresponding values of the function The solution process includes satisfying general necessary and sufficient conditions for optimality For optimization problems specialized notation may be used as to the function and its input s More generally optimization includes finding the best available element of some function given a defined domain and may use a variety of different computational optimization techniques 56 Economics is closely enough linked to optimization by agents in an economy that an influential definition relatedly describes economics qua science as the study of human behavior as a relationship between ends and scarce means with alternative uses 57 Optimization problems run through modern economics many with explicit economic or technical constraints In microeconomics the utility maximization problem and its dual problem the expenditure minimization problem for a given level of utility are economic optimization problems 58 Theory posits that consumers maximize their utility subject to their budget constraints and that firms maximize their profits subject to their production functions input costs and market demand 59 Economic equilibrium is studied in optimization theory as a key ingredient of economic theorems that in principle could be tested against empirical data 7 60 Newer developments have occurred in dynamic programming and modeling optimization with risk and uncertainty including applications to portfolio theory the economics of information and search theory 59 Optimality properties for an entire market system may be stated in mathematical terms as in formulation of the two fundamental theorems of welfare economics 61 and in the Arrow Debreu model of general equilibrium also discussed below 62 More concretely many problems are amenable to analytical formulaic solution Many others may be sufficiently complex to require numerical methods of solution aided by software 56 Still others are complex but tractable enough to allow computable methods of solution in particular computable general equilibrium models for the entire economy 63 Linear and nonlinear programming have profoundly affected microeconomics which had earlier considered only equality constraints 64 Many of the mathematical economists who received Nobel Prizes in Economics had conducted notable research using linear programming Leonid Kantorovich Leonid Hurwicz Tjalling Koopmans Kenneth J Arrow Robert Dorfman Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow 65 Both Kantorovich and Koopmans acknowledged that George B Dantzig deserved to share their Nobel Prize for linear programming Economists who conducted research in nonlinear programming also have won the Nobel prize notably Ragnar Frisch in addition to Kantorovich Hurwicz Koopmans Arrow and Samuelson Linear optimization Edit Main articles Linear programming and Simplex algorithm Linear programming was developed to aid the allocation of resources in firms and in industries during the 1930s in Russia and during the 1940s in the United States During the Berlin airlift 1948 linear programming was used to plan the shipment of supplies to prevent Berlin from starving after the Soviet blockade 66 67 Nonlinear programming Edit See also Nonlinear programming Lagrangian multiplier Karush Kuhn Tucker conditions and Shadow price Extensions to nonlinear optimization with inequality constraints were achieved in 1951 by Albert W Tucker and Harold Kuhn who considered the nonlinear optimization problem Minimize f x displaystyle f x subject to g i x 0 displaystyle g i x leq 0 and h j x 0 displaystyle h j x 0 where f displaystyle f cdot is the function to be minimized g i displaystyle g i cdot are the functions of the m displaystyle m inequality constraints where i 1 m displaystyle i 1 dots m h j displaystyle h j cdot are the functions of the l displaystyle l equality constraints where j 1 l displaystyle j 1 dots l In allowing inequality constraints the Kuhn Tucker approach generalized the classic method of Lagrange multipliers which until then had allowed only equality constraints 68 The Kuhn Tucker approach inspired further research on Lagrangian duality including the treatment of inequality constraints 69 70 The duality theory of nonlinear programming is particularly satisfactory when applied to convex minimization problems which enjoy the convex analytic duality theory of Fenchel and Rockafellar this convex duality is particularly strong for polyhedral convex functions such as those arising in linear programming Lagrangian duality and convex analysis are used daily in operations research in the scheduling of power plants the planning of production schedules for factories and the routing of airlines routes flights planes crews 70 Variational calculus and optimal control Edit See also Calculus of variations Optimal control and Dynamic programming Economic dynamics allows for changes in economic variables over time including in dynamic systems The problem of finding optimal functions for such changes is studied in variational calculus and in optimal control theory Before the Second World War Frank Ramsey and Harold Hotelling used the calculus of variations to that end Following Richard Bellman s work on dynamic programming and the 1962 English translation of L Pontryagin et al s earlier work 71 optimal control theory was used more extensively in economics in addressing dynamic problems especially as to economic growth equilibrium and stability of economic systems 72 of which a textbook example is optimal consumption and saving 73 A crucial distinction is between deterministic and stochastic control models 74 Other applications of optimal control theory include those in finance inventories and production for example 75 Functional analysis Edit See also Functional analysis Convex set Supporting hyperplane Hahn Banach theorem Fixed point theorem and Dual space It was in the course of proving of the existence of an optimal equilibrium in his 1937 model of economic growth that John von Neumann introduced functional analytic methods to include topology in economic theory in particular fixed point theory through his generalization of Brouwer s fixed point theorem 8 44 76 Following von Neumann s program Kenneth Arrow and Gerard Debreu formulated abstract models of economic equilibria using convex sets and fixed point theory In introducing the Arrow Debreu model in 1954 they proved the existence but not the uniqueness of an equilibrium and also proved that every Walras equilibrium is Pareto efficient in general equilibria need not be unique 77 In their models the primal vector space represented quantities while the dual vector space represented prices 78 In Russia the mathematician Leonid Kantorovich developed economic models in partially ordered vector spaces that emphasized the duality between quantities and prices 79 Kantorovich renamed prices as objectively determined valuations which were abbreviated in Russian as o o o alluding to the difficulty of discussing prices in the Soviet Union 78 80 81 Even in finite dimensions the concepts of functional analysis have illuminated economic theory particularly in clarifying the role of prices as normal vectors to a hyperplane supporting a convex set representing production or consumption possibilities However problems of describing optimization over time or under uncertainty require the use of infinite dimensional function spaces because agents are choosing among functions or stochastic processes 78 82 83 84 Differential decline and rise Edit See also Global analysis Baire category and Sard s lemma John von Neumann s work on functional analysis and topology broke new ground in mathematics and economic theory 44 85 It also left advanced mathematical economics with fewer applications of differential calculus In particular general equilibrium theorists used general topology convex geometry and optimization theory more than differential calculus because the approach of differential calculus had failed to establish the existence of an equilibrium However the decline of differential calculus should not be exaggerated because differential calculus has always been used in graduate training and in applications Moreover differential calculus has returned to the highest levels of mathematical economics general equilibrium theory GET as practiced by the GET set the humorous designation due to Jacques H Dreze In the 1960s and 1970s however Gerard Debreu and Stephen Smale led a revival of the use of differential calculus in mathematical economics In particular they were able to prove the existence of a general equilibrium where earlier writers had failed because of their novel mathematics Baire category from general topology and Sard s lemma from differential topology Other economists associated with the use of differential analysis include Egbert Dierker Andreu Mas Colell and Yves Balasko 86 87 These advances have changed the traditional narrative of the history of mathematical economics following von Neumann which celebrated the abandonment of differential calculus Game theory Edit Main article Game Theory See also Cooperative game theory Non cooperative game theory John von Neumann Theory of Games and Economic Behavior and John Forbes Nash Jr John von Neumann working with Oskar Morgenstern on the theory of games broke new mathematical ground in 1944 by extending functional analytic methods related to convex sets and topological fixed point theory to economic analysis 8 85 Their work thereby avoided the traditional differential calculus for which the maximum operator did not apply to non differentiable functions Continuing von Neumann s work in cooperative game theory game theorists Lloyd S Shapley Martin Shubik Herve Moulin Nimrod Megiddo Bezalel Peleg influenced economic research in politics and economics For example research on the fair prices in cooperative games and fair values for voting games led to changed rules for voting in legislatures and for accounting for the costs in public works projects For example cooperative game theory was used in designing the water distribution system of Southern Sweden and for setting rates for dedicated telephone lines in the USA Earlier neoclassical theory had bounded only the range of bargaining outcomes and in special cases for example bilateral monopoly or along the contract curve of the Edgeworth box 88 Von Neumann and Morgenstern s results were similarly weak Following von Neumann s program however John Nash used fixed point theory to prove conditions under which the bargaining problem and noncooperative games can generate a unique equilibrium solution 89 Noncooperative game theory has been adopted as a fundamental aspect of experimental economics 90 behavioral economics 91 information economics 92 industrial organization 93 and political economy 94 It has also given rise to the subject of mechanism design sometimes called reverse game theory which has private and public policy applications as to ways of improving economic efficiency through incentives for information sharing 95 In 1994 Nash John Harsanyi and Reinhard Selten received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences their work on non cooperative games Harsanyi and Selten were awarded for their work on repeated games Later work extended their results to computational methods of modeling 96 Agent based computational economics Edit Main article Agent based computational economics Agent based computational economics ACE as a named field is relatively recent dating from about the 1990s as to published work It studies economic processes including whole economies as dynamic systems of interacting agents over time As such it falls in the paradigm of complex adaptive systems 97 In corresponding agent based models agents are not real people but computational objects modeled as interacting according to rules whose micro level interactions create emergent patterns in space and time 98 The rules are formulated to predict behavior and social interactions based on incentives and information The theoretical assumption of mathematical optimization by agents markets is replaced by the less restrictive postulate of agents with bounded rationality adapting to market forces 99 ACE models apply numerical methods of analysis to computer based simulations of complex dynamic problems for which more conventional methods such as theorem formulation may not find ready use 100 Starting from specified initial conditions the computational economic system is modeled as evolving over time as its constituent agents repeatedly interact with each other In these respects ACE has been characterized as a bottom up culture dish approach to the study of the economy 101 In contrast to other standard modeling methods ACE events are driven solely by initial conditions whether or not equilibria exist or are computationally tractable ACE modeling however includes agent adaptation autonomy and learning 102 It has a similarity to and overlap with game theory as an agent based method for modeling social interactions 96 Other dimensions of the approach include such standard economic subjects as competition and collaboration 103 market structure and industrial organization 104 transaction costs 105 welfare economics 106 and mechanism design 95 information and uncertainty 107 and macroeconomics 108 109 The method is said to benefit from continuing improvements in modeling techniques of computer science and increased computer capabilities Issues include those common to experimental economics in general 110 and by comparison 111 and to development of a common framework for empirical validation and resolving open questions in agent based modeling 112 The ultimate scientific objective of the method has been described as test ing theoretical findings against real world data in ways that permit empirically supported theories to cumulate over time with each researcher s work building appropriately on the work that has gone before 113 Mathematicization of economics Edit The surface of the Volatility smile is a 3 D surface whereby the current market implied volatility Z axis for all options on the underlier is plotted against strike price and time to maturity X amp Y axes 114 Over the course of the 20th century articles in core journals 115 in economics have been almost exclusively written by economists in academia As a result much of the material transmitted in those journals relates to economic theory and economic theory itself has been continuously more abstract and mathematical 116 A subjective assessment of mathematical techniques 117 employed in these core journals showed a decrease in articles that use neither geometric representations nor mathematical notation from 95 in 1892 to 5 3 in 1990 118 A 2007 survey of ten of the top economic journals finds that only 5 8 of the articles published in 2003 and 2004 both lacked statistical analysis of data and lacked displayed mathematical expressions that were indexed with numbers at the margin of the page 119 Econometrics EditMain article Econometrics Between the world wars advances in mathematical statistics and a cadre of mathematically trained economists led to econometrics which was the name proposed for the discipline of advancing economics by using mathematics and statistics Within economics econometrics has often been used for statistical methods in economics rather than mathematical economics Statistical econometrics features the application of linear regression and time series analysis to economic data Ragnar Frisch coined the word econometrics and helped to found both the Econometric Society in 1930 and the journal Econometrica in 1933 120 121 A student of Frisch s Trygve Haavelmo published The Probability Approach in Econometrics in 1944 where he asserted that precise statistical analysis could be used as a tool to validate mathematical theories about economic actors with data from complex sources 122 This linking of statistical analysis of systems to economic theory was also promulgated by the Cowles Commission now the Cowles Foundation throughout the 1930s and 1940s 123 The roots of modern econometrics can be traced to the American economist Henry L Moore Moore studied agricultural productivity and attempted to fit changing values of productivity for plots of corn and other crops to a curve using different values of elasticity Moore made several errors in his work some from his choice of models and some from limitations in his use of mathematics The accuracy of Moore s models also was limited by the poor data for national accounts in the United States at the time While his first models of production were static in 1925 he published a dynamic moving equilibrium model designed to explain business cycles this periodic variation from over correction in supply and demand curves is now known as the cobweb model A more formal derivation of this model was made later by Nicholas Kaldor who is largely credited for its exposition 124 Application Edit The IS LM model is a Keynesian macroeconomic model designed to make predictions about the intersection of real economic activity e g spending income savings rates and decisions made in the financial markets Money supply and Liquidity preference The model is no longer widely taught at the graduate level but is common in undergraduate macroeconomics courses 125 Much of classical economics can be presented in simple geometric terms or elementary mathematical notation Mathematical economics however conventionally makes use of calculus and matrix algebra in economic analysis in order to make powerful claims that would be more difficult without such mathematical tools These tools are prerequisites for formal study not only in mathematical economics but in contemporary economic theory in general Economic problems often involve so many variables that mathematics is the only practical way of attacking and solving them Alfred Marshall argued that every economic problem which can be quantified analytically expressed and solved should be treated by means of mathematical work 126 Economics has become increasingly dependent upon mathematical methods and the mathematical tools it employs have become more sophisticated As a result mathematics has become considerably more important to professionals in economics and finance Graduate programs in both economics and finance require strong undergraduate preparation in mathematics for admission and for this reason attract an increasingly high number of mathematicians Applied mathematicians apply mathematical principles to practical problems such as economic analysis and other economics related issues and many economic problems are often defined as integrated into the scope of applied mathematics 18 This integration results from the formulation of economic problems as stylized models with clear assumptions and falsifiable predictions This modeling may be informal or prosaic as it was in Adam Smith s The Wealth of Nations or it may be formal rigorous and mathematical Broadly speaking formal economic models may be classified as stochastic or deterministic and as discrete or continuous At a practical level quantitative modeling is applied to many areas of economics and several methodologies have evolved more or less independently of each other 127 Stochastic models are formulated using stochastic processes They model economically observable values over time Most of econometrics is based on statistics to formulate and test hypotheses about these processes or estimate parameters for them Between the World Wars Herman Wold developed a representation of stationary stochastic processes in terms of autoregressive models and a determinist trend Wold and Jan Tinbergen applied time series analysis to economic data Contemporary research on time series statistics consider additional formulations of stationary processes such as autoregressive moving average models More general models include autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity ARCH models and generalized ARCH GARCH models Non stochastic mathematical models may be purely qualitative for example models involved in some aspect of social choice theory or quantitative involving rationalization of financial variables for example with hyperbolic coordinates and or specific forms of functional relationships between variables In some cases economic predictions of a model merely assert the direction of movement of economic variables and so the functional relationships are used only in a qualitative sense for example if the price of an item increases then the demand for that item will decrease For such models economists often use two dimensional graphs instead of functions Qualitative models are occasionally used One example is qualitative scenario planning in which possible future events are played out Another example is non numerical decision tree analysis Qualitative models often suffer from lack of precision Example The effect of a corporate tax cut on wages EditThe great appeal of mathematical economics is that it brings a degree of rigor to economic thinking particularly around charged political topics For example during the discussion of the efficacy of a corporate tax cut for increasing the wages of workers a simple mathematical model proved beneficial to understanding the issues at hand As an intellectual exercise the following problem was posed by Prof Greg Mankiw of Harvard University 128 An open economy has the production function y f k textstyle y f k where y textstyle y is output per worker and k textstyle k is capital per worker The capital stock adjusts so that the after tax marginal product of capital equals the exogenously given world interest rate r textstyle r How much will the tax cut increase wages To answer this question we follow John H Cochrane of the Hoover Institution 129 Suppose an open economy has the production function Y F K L f k L k K L displaystyle Y F K L f k L quad k K L Where the variables in this equation are Y textstyle Y is the total output F K L textstyle F K L is the production function K textstyle K is the total capital stock L textstyle L is the total labor stockThe standard choice for the production function is the Cobb Douglas production function Y A K a L 1 a A k a L a 0 1 displaystyle Y AK alpha L 1 alpha Ak alpha L quad alpha in 0 1 where A textstyle A is the factor of productivity assumed to be a constant A corporate tax cut in this model is equivalent to a tax on capital With taxes firms look to maximize J max K L 1 t F K L w L r K max K L 1 t f k w L r K displaystyle J max K L 1 tau left F K L wL right rK equiv max K L 1 tau left f k w right L rK where t textstyle tau is the capital tax rate w textstyle w is wages per worker and r textstyle r is the exogenous interest rate Then the first order optimality conditions become J K 1 t f k r J L 1 t f k f k k w displaystyle begin aligned frac partial J partial K amp 1 tau f k r frac partial J partial L amp 1 tau left f k f k k w right end aligned Therefore the optimality conditions imply that r 1 t f k w f k f k k displaystyle r 1 tau f k quad w f k f k k Define total taxes X t F K L w L textstyle X tau F K L wL This implies that taxes per worker x textstyle x are x t f k w t f k k displaystyle x tau f k w tau f k k Then the change in taxes per worker given the tax rate is d x d t f k k Static t f k f k k d k d t Dynamic displaystyle dx over d tau underbrace f k k text Static underbrace tau left f k f k k right dk over d tau text Dynamic To find the change in wages we differentiate the second optimality condition for the per worker wages to obtain d w d t f k f k f k k d k d t f k k d k d t displaystyle frac dw d tau left f k f k f k k right frac dk d tau f k k frac dk d tau Assuming that the interest rate is fixed at r textstyle r so that d r d t 0 textstyle dr d tau 0 we may differentiate the first optimality condition for the interest rate to find d k d t f k 1 t f k displaystyle dk over d tau f k over 1 tau f k For the moment let s focus only on the static effect of a capital tax cut so that d x d t f k k textstyle dx d tau f k k If we substitute this equation into equation for wage changes with respect to the tax rate then we find that d w d t f k k 1 t 1 1 t d x d t displaystyle dw over d tau frac f k k 1 tau 1 over 1 tau frac dx d tau Therefore the static effect of a capital tax cut on wages is d w d x 1 1 t displaystyle dw over dx 1 over 1 tau Based on the model it seems possible that we may achieve a rise in the wage of a worker greater than the amount of the tax cut But that only considers the static effect and we know that the dynamic effect must be accounted for In the dynamic model we may rewrite the equation for changes in taxes per worker with respect to the tax rate as d x d t f k k t f k f k k d k d t f k k t 1 t f k 2 f k f k k f k t 1 t f k 2 f k 1 1 t f k k f k 1 t t f k f k k displaystyle begin aligned dx over d tau amp f k k tau left f k f k k right dk over d tau amp f k k tau over 1 tau f k 2 f k f k k over f k amp tau over 1 tau f k 2 over f k 1 over 1 tau f k k amp f k over 1 tau left tau f k over f k k right end aligned Recalling that d w d t f k k 1 t textstyle dw d tau f k k 1 tau we have that d w d x f k k 1 t f k 1 t t f k f k k 1 t f k k f k 1 displaystyle frac dw dx frac f k k 1 tau over frac f k 1 tau left tau frac f k f k k right frac 1 tau frac f k kf k 1 Using the Cobb Douglas production function we have that f k k f k 1 1 a displaystyle f k over kf k 1 over 1 alpha Therefore the dynamic effect of a capital tax cut on wages is d w d x 1 a 1 t a displaystyle dw over dx 1 alpha over 1 tau alpha If we take a t 1 3 textstyle alpha tau 1 3 then the dynamic effect of lowering capital taxes on wages will be even larger than the static effect Moreover if there are positive externalities to capital accumulation the effect of the tax cut on wages would be larger than in the model we just derived It is important to note that the result is a combination of The standard result that in a small open economy labor bears 100 of a small capital income tax The fact that starting at a positive tax rate the burden of a tax increase exceeds revenue collection due to the first order deadweight lossThis result showing that under certain assumptions a corporate tax cut can boost the wages of workers by more than the lost revenue does not imply that the magnitude is correct Rather it suggests a basis for policy analysis that is not grounded in handwaving If the assumptions are reasonable then the model is an acceptable approximation of reality if they are not then better models should be developed CES production function Edit Now let s assume that instead of the Cobb Douglas production function we have a more general constant elasticity of substitution CES production function f k A a k r 1 a 1 r displaystyle f k A left alpha k rho 1 alpha right 1 rho where r 1 s 1 textstyle rho 1 sigma 1 s textstyle sigma is the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor The relevant quantity we want to calculate is f k f textstyle f kf which may be derived as f k f 1 1 r a 1 r a 1 a k r displaystyle f over kf 1 over 1 rho alpha 1 rho over alpha 1 alpha k rho Therefore we may use this to find that 1 t f k f 1 t a 1 a k r 1 r a 1 a k r a 1 r 1 r t a 1 a k r a 1 r 1 r a 1 a k r a 1 r displaystyle begin aligned 1 tau f over kf amp 1 tau alpha 1 alpha k rho over 1 rho alpha 1 alpha k rho alpha 1 rho 6pt amp 1 rho tau alpha 1 alpha k rho alpha 1 rho over 1 rho alpha 1 alpha k rho alpha 1 rho end aligned Therefore under a general CES model the dynamic effect of a capital tax cut on wages is d w d x 1 r a 1 a k r a 1 r 1 r t a 1 a k r a 1 r displaystyle dw over dx 1 rho alpha 1 alpha k rho alpha 1 rho over 1 rho tau alpha 1 alpha k rho alpha 1 rho We recover the Cobb Douglas solution when r 0 textstyle rho 0 When r 1 textstyle rho 1 which is the case when perfect substitutes exist we find that d w d x 0 textstyle dw dx 0 there is no effect of changes in capital taxes on wages And when r textstyle rho infty which is the case when perfect complements exist we find that d w d x 1 textstyle dw dx 1 a cut in capital taxes increases wages by exactly one dollar Criticisms and defences EditAdequacy of mathematics for qualitative and complicated economics Edit The Austrian school while making many of the same normative economic arguments as mainstream economists from marginalist traditions such as the Chicago school differs methodologically from mainstream neoclassical schools of economics in particular in their sharp critiques of the mathematization of economics 130 Friedrich Hayek contended that the use of formal techniques projects a scientific exactness that does not appropriately account for informational limitations faced by real economic agents 131 In an interview in 1999 the economic historian Robert Heilbroner stated 132 I guess the scientific approach began to penetrate and soon dominate the profession in the past twenty to thirty years This came about in part because of the invention of mathematical analysis of various kinds and indeed considerable improvements in it This is the age in which we have not only more data but more sophisticated use of data So there is a strong feeling that this is a data laden science and a data laden undertaking which by virtue of the sheer numerics the sheer equations and the sheer look of a journal page bears a certain resemblance to science That one central activity looks scientific I understand that I think that is genuine It approaches being a universal law But resembling a science is different from being a science Heilbroner stated that some much of economics is not naturally quantitative and therefore does not lend itself to mathematical exposition 133 Testing predictions of mathematical economics Edit Philosopher Karl Popper discussed the scientific standing of economics in the 1940s and 1950s He argued that mathematical economics suffered from being tautological In other words insofar as economics became a mathematical theory mathematical economics ceased to rely on empirical refutation but rather relied on mathematical proofs and disproof 134 According to Popper falsifiable assumptions can be tested by experiment and observation while unfalsifiable assumptions can be explored mathematically for their consequences and for their consistency with other assumptions 135 Sharing Popper s concerns about assumptions in economics generally and not just mathematical economics Milton Friedman declared that all assumptions are unrealistic Friedman proposed judging economic models by their predictive performance rather than by the match between their assumptions and reality 136 Mathematical economics as a form of pure mathematics Edit See also Pure mathematics Applied mathematics and Engineering Considering mathematical economics J M Keynes wrote in The General Theory 137 It is a great fault of symbolic pseudo mathematical methods of formalising a system of economic analysis that they expressly assume strict independence between the factors involved and lose their cogency and authority if this hypothesis is disallowed whereas in ordinary discourse where we are not blindly manipulating and know all the time what we are doing and what the words mean we can keep at the back of our heads the necessary reserves and qualifications and the adjustments which we shall have to make later on in a way in which we cannot keep complicated partial differentials at the back of several pages of algebra which assume they all vanish Too large a proportion of recent mathematical economics are merely concoctions as imprecise as the initial assumptions they rest on which allow the author to lose sight of the complexities and interdependencies of the real world in a maze of pretentious and unhelpful symbols Defense of mathematical economics Edit In response to these criticisms Paul Samuelson argued that mathematics is a language repeating a thesis of Josiah Willard Gibbs In economics the language of mathematics is sometimes necessary for representing substantive problems Moreover mathematical economics has led to conceptual advances in economics 138 In particular Samuelson gave the example of microeconomics writing that few people are ingenious enough to grasp its more complex parts without resorting to the language of mathematics while most ordinary individuals can do so fairly easily with the aid of mathematics 139 Some economists state that mathematical economics deserves support just like other forms of mathematics particularly its neighbors in mathematical optimization and mathematical statistics and increasingly in theoretical computer science Mathematical economics and other mathematical sciences have a history in which theoretical advances have regularly contributed to the reform of the more applied branches of economics In particular following the program of John von Neumann game theory now provides the foundations for describing much of applied economics from statistical decision theory as games against nature and econometrics to general equilibrium theory and industrial organization In the last decade with the rise of the internet mathematical economists and optimization experts and computer scientists have worked on problems of pricing for on line services their contributions using mathematics from cooperative game theory nondifferentiable optimization and combinatorial games Robert M Solow concluded that mathematical economics was the core infrastructure of contemporary economics Economics is no longer a fit conversation piece for ladies and gentlemen It has become a technical subject Like any technical subject it attracts some people who are more interested in the technique than the subject That is too bad but it may be inevitable In any case do not kid yourself the technical core of economics is indispensable infrastructure for the political economy That is why if you consult a reference in contemporary economics looking for enlightenment about the world today you will be led to technical economics or history or nothing at all 140 Mathematical economists EditProminent mathematical economists include the following 19th century Edit Enrico Barone Antoine Augustin Cournot Francis Ysidro Edgeworth Irving Fisher William Stanley Jevons Vilfredo Pareto Leon Walras 20th century Edit Charalambos D Aliprantis R G D Allen Maurice Allais Kenneth J Arrow Robert J Aumann Yves Balasko David Blackwell Lawrence E Blume Graciela Chichilnisky George B Dantzig Gerard Debreu Mario Draghi Jacques H Dreze David Gale Nicholas Georgescu Roegen Roger Guesnerie Frank Hahn John C Harsanyi John R Hicks Werner Hildenbrand Harold Hotelling Leonid Hurwicz Leonid Kantorovich Tjalling Koopmans David M Kreps Harold W Kuhn Edmond Malinvaud Andreu Mas Colell Eric Maskin Nimrod Megiddo Jean Francois Mertens James Mirrlees Roger Myerson John Forbes Nash Jr John von Neumann Edward C Prescott Roy Radner Frank Ramsey Donald John Roberts Paul Samuelson Yuliy Sannikov Thomas Sargent Leonard J Savage Herbert Scarf Reinhard Selten Amartya Sen Lloyd S Shapley Stephen Smale Robert Solow Hugo F Sonnenschein Nancy L Stokey Albert W Tucker Hirofumi Uzawa Robert B Wilson Abraham Wald Hermann Wold Nicholas C YannelisSee also Edit Business and economics portal Mathematics portalEconophysics Mathematical financeReferences Edit Elaborated at the JEL classification codes Mathematical and quantitative methods JEL C Subcategories a b Chiang Alpha C Kevin Wainwright 2005 Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics McGraw Hill Irwin pp 3 4 ISBN 978 0 07 010910 0 TOC Archived 2012 03 08 at the Wayback Machine Debreu Gerard 1987 2008 mathematical economics section II The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2013 05 16 at the Wayback Machine Republished with revisions from 1986 Theoretic Models Mathematical Form and Economic Content Econometrica 54 6 pp 1259 Archived 2017 08 05 at the Wayback Machine 1270 Varian Hal 1997 What Use Is Economic Theory in A D Autume and J Cartelier ed Is Economics Becoming a Hard Science Edward Elgar Pre publication PDF Archived 2006 06 25 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 2008 04 01 As in Handbook of Mathematical Economics 1st page chapter links Arrow Kenneth J and Michael D Intriligator ed 1981 v 1 1982 v 2 1986 v 3 Hildenbrand Werner and Hugo Sonnenschein ed 1991 v 4 Archived 2013 04 15 at the Wayback Machine Debreu Gerard 1983 Mathematical Economics Twenty Papers of Gerard Debreu Contents Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Glaister Stephen 1984 Mathematical Methods for Economists 3rd ed Blackwell Contents Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Takayama Akira 1985 Mathematical Economics 2nd ed Cambridge Description Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine and Contents Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Michael Carter 2001 Foundations of Mathematical Economics MIT Press Description and Contents Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Chiang Alpha C 1992 Elements of Dynamic Optimization Waveland TOC amp Amazon com link Archived 2016 03 03 at the Wayback Machine to inside first pp a b c d Samuelson Paul 1947 1983 Foundations of Economic Analysis Harvard University Press ISBN 978 0 674 31301 9 a b c d Debreu Gerard 1987 2008 mathematical economics The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2013 05 16 at the Wayback Machine Republished with revisions from 1986 Theoretic Models Mathematical Form and Economic Content Econometrica 54 6 pp 1259 Archived 2017 08 05 at the Wayback Machine 1270 von Neumann John and Oskar Morgenstern 1944 Theory of Games and Economic Behavior Princeton University Press Schumpeter J A 1954 Elizabeth B Schumpeter ed History of Economic Analysis New York Oxford University Press pp 209 212 ISBN 978 0 04 330086 2 OCLC 13498913 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2020 05 28 Schumpeter 1954 p 212 215 Schnieder Erich 1934 Johann Heinrich von Thunen Econometrica 2 1 1 12 doi 10 2307 1907947 ISSN 0012 9682 JSTOR 1907947 OCLC 35705710 Schumpeter 1954 p 465 468 Philip Mirowski 1991 The When the How and the Why of Mathematical Expression in the History of Economics Analysis Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 1 pp 145 157 permanent dead link Weintraub E Roy 2008 mathematics and economics The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2013 05 16 at the Wayback Machine Jevons W S 1866 Brief Account of a General Mathematical Theory of Political Economy Journal of the Royal Statistical Society XXIX June pp 282 87 Read in Section F of the British Association 1862 PDF Jevons W Stanley 1871 The Principles of Political Economy pp 4 25 Macmillan The Theory of Political Economy jevons 1871 See the preface Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine to Irving Fisher s 1897 work A brief introduction to the infinitesimal calculus designed especially to aid in reading mathematical economics and statistics a b Sheila C Dow 1999 05 21 The Use of Mathematics in Economics ESRC Public Understanding of Mathematics Seminar Birmingham Economic and Social Research Council Retrieved 2008 07 06 While the concept of cardinality has fallen out of favor in neoclassical economics the differences between cardinal utility and ordinal utility are minor for most applications a b Nicola PierCarlo 2000 Mainstream Mathermatical Economics in the 20th Century Springer p 4 ISBN 978 3 540 67084 1 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2008 08 21 Augustin Cournot 1838 tr 1897 Researches into the Mathematical Principles of Wealth Links to description Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine and chapters Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine a b Hotelling Harold 1990 Stability in Competition In Darnell Adrian C ed The Collected Economics Articles of Harold Hotelling Springer pp 51 52 ISBN 978 3 540 97011 8 OCLC 20217006 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2008 08 21 Antoine Augustin Cournot 1801 1877 The History of Economic Thought Website The New School for Social Research Archived from the original on 2000 07 09 Retrieved 2008 08 21 Gibbons Robert 1992 Game Theory for Applied Economists Princeton New Jersey Princeton University Press pp 14 15 ISBN 978 0 691 00395 5 permanent dead link Nicola p 9 12 Edgeworth Francis Ysidro September 5 1889 The Mathematical Theory of Political Economy Review of Leon Walras Elements d economie politique pure PDF Nature 40 1036 434 436 doi 10 1038 040434a0 ISSN 0028 0836 S2CID 21004543 Archived from the original PDF on April 11 2003 Retrieved 2008 08 21 Nicholson Walter Snyder Christopher p 350 353 Dixon Robert Walras Law and Macroeconomics Walras Law Guide Department of Economics University of Melbourne Archived from the original on April 17 2008 Retrieved 2008 09 28 Dixon Robert A Formal Proof of Walras Law Walras Law Guide Department of Economics University of Melbourne Archived from the original on April 30 2008 Retrieved 2008 09 28 Rima Ingrid H 1977 Neoclassicism and Dissent 1890 1930 In Weintraub Sidney ed Modern Economic Thought University of Pennsylvania Press pp 10 11 ISBN 978 0 8122 7712 8 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2021 05 31 Heilbroner Robert L 1999 1953 The Worldly Philosophers Seventh ed New York Simon and Schuster pp 172 175 313 ISBN 978 0 684 86214 9 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2020 05 28 Edgeworth Francis Ysidro 1961 1881 Mathematical Psychics London Kegan Paul A M Kelley pp 15 19 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2020 05 28 Nicola p 14 15 258 261 Bowley Arthur Lyon 1960 1924 The Mathematical Groundwork of Economics an Introductory Treatise Oxford Clarendon Press Kelly Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2020 05 28 Gillies D B 1969 Solutions to general non zero sum games In Tucker A W Luce R D eds Contributions to the Theory of Games Annals of Mathematics Vol 40 Princeton New Jersey Princeton University Press pp 47 85 ISBN 978 0 691 07937 0 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2020 05 28 Moss Lawrence S 2003 The Seligman Edgeworth Debate about the Analysis of Tax Incidence The Advent of Mathematical Economics 1892 1910 History of Political Economy 35 2 207 212 219 234 237 doi 10 1215 00182702 35 2 205 ISSN 0018 2702 Hotelling Harold 1990 Note on Edgeworth s Taxation Phenomenon and Professor Garver s Additional Condition on Demand Functions In Darnell Adrian C ed The Collected Economics Articles of Harold Hotelling Springer pp 94 122 ISBN 978 3 540 97011 8 OCLC 20217006 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2008 08 26 Herstein I N October 1953 Some Mathematical Methods and Techniques in Economics Quarterly of Applied Mathematics 11 3 249 262 doi 10 1090 qam 60205 ISSN 1552 4485 Pp 249 62 Weintraub E Roy 2008 mathematics and economics The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2013 05 16 at the Wayback Machine 2002 How Economics Became a Mathematical Science Duke University Press Description and preview Archived 2023 06 04 at the Wayback Machine Nicholson Walter Snyder Christopher 2007 General Equilibrium and Welfare Intermediate Microeconomics and Its Applications 10th ed Thompson pp 364 365 ISBN 978 0 324 31968 2 Jolink Albert 2006 What Went Wrong with Walras In Backhaus Juergen G Maks J A Hans eds From Walras to Pareto The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences Vol IV Springer pp 69 80 doi 10 1007 978 0 387 33757 9 6 ISBN 978 0 387 33756 2 Blaug Mark 2007 The Fundamental Theorems of Modern Welfare Economics Historically Contemplated History of Political Economy 39 2 186 188 doi 10 1215 00182702 2007 001 ISSN 0018 2702 S2CID 154074343 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2020 01 27 Blaug 2007 p 185 187 Metzler Lloyd 1948 Review of Foundations of Economic Analysis American Economic Review 38 5 905 910 ISSN 0002 8282 JSTOR 1811704 a b c Neumann J von 1937 Uber ein okonomisches Gleichungssystem und ein Verallgemeinerung des Brouwerschen Fixpunktsatzes Ergebnisse eines Mathematischen Kolloquiums 8 pp 73 83 translated and published in 1945 46 as A Model of General Equilibrium Review of Economic Studies 13 pp 1 9 For this problem to have a unique solution it suffices that the nonnegative matrices A and B satisfy an irreducibility condition generalizing that of the Perron Frobenius theorem of nonnegative matrices which considers the simplified eigenvalue problem A l I q 0 where the nonnegative matrix A must be square and where the diagonal matrix I is the identity matrix Von Neumann s irreducibility condition was called the whales and wranglers hypothesis by David Champernowne who provided a verbal and economic commentary on the English translation of von Neumann s article Von Neumann s hypothesis implied that every economic process used a positive amount of every economic good Weaker irreducibility conditions were given by David Gale and by John Kemeny Oskar Morgenstern and Gerald L Thompson in the 1950s and then by Stephen M Robinson in the 1970s David Gale The theory of linear economic models McGraw Hill New York 1960 Morgenstern Oskar Thompson Gerald L 1976 Mathematical theory of expanding and contracting economies Lexington Books Lexington Massachusetts D C Heath and Company pp xviii 277 Alexander Schrijver Theory of Linear and Integer Programming John Wiley amp sons 1998 ISBN 0 471 98232 6 Rockafellar R Tyrrell 1967 Monotone processes of convex and concave type Memoirs of the American Mathematical Society Providence R I American Mathematical Society pp i 74 Rockafellar R T 1974 Convex algebra and duality in dynamic models of production In Josef Loz Maria Loz eds Mathematical models in economics Proc Sympos and Conf von Neumann Models Warsaw 1972 Amsterdam North Holland and Polish Academy of Sciences PAN pp 351 378 Rockafellar R T 1997 1970 Convex analysis Princeton New Jersey Princeton University Press Kenneth Arrow Paul Samuelson John Harsanyi Sidney Afriat Gerald L Thompson and Nicholas Kaldor 1989 Mohammed Dore Sukhamoy Chakravarty Richard Goodwin eds John Von Neumann and modern economics Oxford Clarendon p 261 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Chapter 9 1 The von Neumann growth model pages 277 299 Yinyu Ye Interior point algorithms Theory and analysis Wiley 1997 Screpanti Ernesto Zamagni Stefano 1993 An Outline of the History of Economic Thought New York Oxford University Press pp 288 290 ISBN 978 0 19 828370 6 OCLC 57281275 David Gale The theory of linear economic models McGraw Hill New York 1960 Morgenstern Oskar Thompson Gerald L 1976 Mathematical theory of expanding and contracting economies Lexington Books Lexington Massachusetts D C Heath and Company pp xviii 277 The Nature of Mathematical Programming Mathematical Programming Glossary INFORMS Computing Society a b Schmedders Karl 2008 numerical optimization methods in economics The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition v 6 pp 138 57 Abstract Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Robbins Lionel 1935 2nd ed An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science Macmillan p 16 Blume Lawrence E 2008 duality The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2017 02 02 at the Wayback Machine a b Dixit A K 1976 1990 Optimization in Economic Theory 2nd ed Oxford Description Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine and contents preview Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Samuelson Paul A 1998 How Foundations Came to Be Journal of Economic Literature 36 3 pp 1375 1386 1970 Maximum Principles in Analytical Economics Archived 2012 10 11 at the Wayback Machine Nobel Prize lecture Allan M Feldman 3008 welfare economics The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Mas Colell Andreu Michael D Whinston and Jerry R Green 1995 Microeconomic Theory Chapter 16 Oxford University Press ISBN 0 19 510268 1 Description Archived 2012 01 26 at the Wayback Machine and contents Archived 2012 01 26 at the Wayback Machine Geanakoplos John 1987 2008 Arrow Debreu model of general equilibrium The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Arrow Kenneth J and Gerard Debreu 1954 Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy Econometrica 22 3 pp 265 290 Scarf Herbert E 2008 computation of general equilibria The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2009 05 23 at the Wayback Machine Kubler Felix 2008 computation of general equilibria new developments The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Nicola p 133 Dorfman Robert Paul A Samuelson and Robert M Solow 1958 Linear Programming and Economic Analysis McGraw Hill Chapter preview links Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine M Padberg Linear Optimization and Extensions Second Edition Springer Verlag 1999 Dantzig George B 1987 2008 linear programming The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Intriligator Michael D 2008 nonlinear programming The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition TOC Archived 2016 03 04 at the Wayback Machine Blume Lawrence E 2008 convex programming The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2017 10 18 at the Wayback Machine Kuhn H W Tucker A W 1951 Nonlinear programming Proceedings of 2nd Berkeley Symposium Berkeley University of California Press pp 481 492 Bertsekas Dimitri P 1999 Nonlinear Programming Second ed Cambridge Massachusetts Athena Scientific ISBN 978 1 886529 00 7 Vapnyarskii I B 2001 1994 Lagrange multipliers Encyclopedia of Mathematics EMS Press Lasdon Leon S 1970 Optimization theory for large systems Macmillan series in operations research New York The Macmillan Company pp xi 523 MR 0337317 Lasdon Leon S 2002 Optimization theory for large systems reprint of the 1970 Macmillan ed Mineola New York Dover Publications Inc pp xiii 523 MR 1888251 Hiriart Urruty Jean Baptiste Lemarechal Claude 1993 XII Abstract duality for practitioners Convex analysis and minimization algorithms Volume II Advanced theory and bundle methods Grundlehren der Mathematischen Wissenschaften Fundamental Principles of Mathematical Sciences Vol 306 Berlin Springer Verlag pp 136 193 and Bibliographical comments on pp 334 335 ISBN 978 3 540 56852 0 MR 1295240 a b Lemarechal Claude 2001 Lagrangian relaxation In Michael Junger Denis Naddef eds Computational combinatorial optimization Papers from the Spring School held in Schloss Dagstuhl May 15 19 2000 Lecture Notes in Computer Science Vol 2241 Berlin Springer Verlag pp 112 156 doi 10 1007 3 540 45586 8 4 ISBN 978 3 540 42877 0 MR 1900016 S2CID 9048698 Pontryagin L S Boltyanski V G Gamkrelidze R V Mischenko E F 1962 The Mathematical Theory of Optimal Processes New York Wiley ISBN 9782881240775 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2015 06 27 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Zelikin M I 1987 2008 Pontryagin s principle of optimality The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Preview link Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Martos Bela 1987 control and coordination of economic activity The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics Description link Archived 2016 03 06 at the Wayback Machine Brock W A 1987 optimal control and economic dynamics The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics Outline Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Shell K ed 1967 Essays on the Theory of Optimal Economic Growth Cambridge Massachusetts The MIT Press ISBN 978 0 262 19036 7 Stokey Nancy L and Robert E Lucas with Edward Prescott 1989 Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics Harvard University Press chapter 5 Desecription Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine and chapter preview links Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Malliaris A G 2008 stochastic optimal control The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2017 10 18 at the Wayback Machine Arrow K J Kurz M 1970 Public Investment the Rate of Return and Optimal Fiscal Policy Baltimore Maryland The Johns Hopkins Press ISBN 978 0 8018 1124 1 Abstract Archived 2013 03 09 at the Wayback Machine Sethi S P Thompson G L 2000 Optimal Control Theory Applications to Management Science and Economics Second Edition New York Springer ISBN 978 0 7923 8608 7 Scroll to chapter preview links Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Andrew McLennan 2008 fixed point theorems The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2016 03 06 at the Wayback Machine Weintraub E Roy 1977 General Equilibrium Theory In Weintraub Sidney ed Modern Economic Thought University of Pennsylvania Press pp 107 109 ISBN 978 0 8122 7712 8 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2020 05 28 Arrow Kenneth J Debreu Gerard 1954 Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy Econometrica 22 3 265 290 doi 10 2307 1907353 ISSN 0012 9682 JSTOR 1907353 a b c Kantorovich Leonid and Victor Polterovich 2008 Functional analysis in S Durlauf and L Blume ed The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2016 03 03 at the Wayback Machine ed Palgrave Macmillan Kantorovich L V 1990 My journey in science supposed report to the Moscow Mathematical Society expanding Russian Math Surveys 42 1987 no 2 pp 233 270 In Lev J Leifman ed Functional analysis optimization and mathematical economics A collection of papers dedicated to the memory of Leonid Vitalʹevich Kantorovich New York The Clarendon Press Oxford University Press pp 8 45 ISBN 978 0 19 505729 4 MR 0898626 Page 406 Polyak B T 2002 History of mathematical programming in the USSR Analyzing the phenomenon Chapter 3 The pioneer L V Kantorovich 1912 1986 pp 405 407 Mathematical Programming Series B 91 ISMP 2000 Part 1 Atlanta GA number 3 401 416 doi 10 1007 s101070100258 MR 1888984 S2CID 13089965 Leonid Vitaliyevich Kantorovich Prize Lecture Mathematics in economics Achievements difficulties perspectives Nobelprize org Archived from the original on 14 December 2010 Retrieved 12 Dec 2010 Aliprantis Charalambos D Brown Donald J Burkinshaw Owen 1990 Existence and optimality of competitive equilibria Berlin Springer Verlag pp xii 284 ISBN 978 3 540 52866 1 MR 1075992 Rockafellar R Tyrrell Conjugate duality and optimization Lectures given at the Johns Hopkins University Baltimore Maryland June 1973 Conference Board of the Mathematical Sciences Regional Conference Series in Applied Mathematics No 16 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics Philadelphia Pa 1974 vi 74 pp Lester G Telser and Robert L Graves Functional Analysis in Mathematical Economics Optimization Over Infinite Horizons 1972 University of Chicago Press 1972 ISBN 978 0 226 79190 6 a b Neumann John von and Oskar Morgenstern 1944 Theory of Games and Economic Behavior Princeton Mas Colell Andreu 1985 The Theory of general economic equilibrium Adifferentiableapproach Econometric Society monographs Cambridge UP ISBN 978 0 521 26514 0 MR 1113262 Yves Balasko Foundations of the Theory of General Equilibrium 1988 ISBN 0 12 076975 1 Creedy John 2008 Francis Ysidro 1845 1926 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Nash John F Jr 1950 The Bargaining Problem Econometrica 18 2 pp 155 162 Archived 2016 03 04 at the Wayback Machine Serrano Roberto 2008 bargaining The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Smith Vernon L 1992 Game Theory and Experimental Economics Beginnings and Early Influences in E R Weintraub ed Towards a History of Game Theory pp 241 Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine 282 2001 Experimental Economics International Encyclopedia of the Social amp Behavioral Sciences pp 5100 5108 Abstract Archived 2018 10 14 at the Wayback Machine per sect 1 1 amp 2 1 Plott Charles R and Vernon L Smith ed 2008 Handbook of Experimental Economics Results v 1 Elsevier Part 4 Games ch 45 66 preview links Shubik Martin 2002 Game Theory and Experimental Gaming in R Aumann and S Hart ed Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications Elsevier v 3 pp 2327 2351 Abstract Archived 2018 11 07 at the Wayback Machine From The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2008 2nd Edition Gul Faruk behavioural economics and game theory Abstract Archived 2017 08 07 at the Wayback Machine Camerer Colin F behavioral game theory Abstract Archived 2011 11 23 at the Wayback Machine Rasmusen Eric 2007 Games and Information 4th ed Description Archived 2017 06 24 at the Wayback Machine and chapter preview links Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Aumann R and S Hart ed 1992 2002 Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications v 1 links at ch 3 6 Archived 2017 08 16 at the Wayback Machine and v 3 ch 43 Archived 2018 10 14 at the Wayback Machine Tirole Jean 1988 The Theory of Industrial Organization MIT Press Description and chapter preview links pp vii ix General Organization pp 5 6 and Non Cooperative Game Theory A User s Guide Manual ch 11 pp 423 59 Bagwell Kyle and Asher Wolinsky 2002 Game theory and Industrial Organization ch 49 Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications v 3 pp 1851 Archived 2016 01 02 at the Wayback Machine 1895 Shubik Martin 1981 Game Theory Models and Methods in Political Economy in Handbook of Mathematical Economics v 1 pp 285 dead link 330 a b The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2008 2nd Edition Myerson Roger B mechanism design Abstract Archived 2011 11 23 at the Wayback Machine revelation principle Abstract Archived 2013 05 16 at the Wayback Machine Sandholm Tuomas computing in mechanism design Abstract Archived 2011 11 23 at the Wayback Machine Nisan Noam and Amir Ronen 2001 Algorithmic Mechanism Design Games and Economic Behavior 35 1 2 pp 166 196 Archived 2018 10 14 at the Wayback Machine Nisan Noam et al ed 2007 Algorithmic Game Theory Cambridge University Press Description Archived 2012 05 05 at the Wayback Machine a b Halpern Joseph Y 2008 computer science and game theory The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2017 11 05 at the Wayback Machine Shoham Yoav 2008 Computer Science and Game Theory Communications of the ACM 51 8 pp 75 79 Archived 2012 04 26 at the Wayback Machine Roth Alvin E 2002 The Economist as Engineer Game Theory Experimentation and Computation as Tools for Design Economics Econometrica 70 4 pp 1341 1378 Kirman Alan 2008 economy as a complex system The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Tesfatsion Leigh 2003 Agent based Computational Economics Modeling Economies as Complex Adaptive Systems Information Sciences 149 4 pp 262 268 Scott E Page 2008 agent based models The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2018 02 10 at the Wayback Machine Holland John H and John H Miller 1991 Artificial Adaptive Agents in Economic Theory American Economic Review 81 2 pp 365 370 Archived 2011 01 05 at the Wayback Machine p 366 Arthur W Brian 1994 Inductive Reasoning and Bounded Rationality American Economic Review 84 2 pp 406 411 Schelling Thomas C 1978 2006 Micromotives and Macrobehavior Norton Description Archived 2017 11 02 at the Wayback Machine preview Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Sargent Thomas J 1994 Bounded Rationality in Macroeconomics Oxford Description and chapter preview 1st page links Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Judd Kenneth L 2006 Computationally Intensive Analyses in Economics Handbook of Computational Economics v 2 ch 17 Introduction p 883 Pp 881 893 Pre pub PDF Archived 2022 01 21 at the Wayback Machine 1998 Numerical Methods in Economics MIT Press Links to description and chapter previews Tesfatsion Leigh 2002 Agent Based Computational Economics Growing Economies from the Bottom Up Artificial Life 8 1 pp 55 82 Abstract Archived 2020 03 06 at the Wayback Machine and pre pub PDF 1997 How Economists Can Get Alife in W B Arthur S Durlauf and D Lane eds The Economy as an Evolving Complex System II pp 533 564 Addison Wesley Pre pub PDF Archived 2012 04 15 at the Wayback Machine Tesfatsion Leigh 2006 Agent Based Computational Economics A Constructive Approach to Economic Theory ch 16 Handbook of Computational Economics v 2 part 2 ACE study of economic system Abstract Archived 2018 08 09 at the Wayback Machine and pre pub PDF Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Axelrod Robert 1997 The Complexity of Cooperation Agent Based Models of Competition and Collaboration Princeton Description Archived 2018 01 02 at the Wayback Machine contents Archived 2018 01 02 at the Wayback Machine and preview Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Leombruni Roberto and Matteo Richiardi ed 2004 Industry and Labor Dynamics The Agent Based Computational Economics Approach World Scientific Publishing ISBN 981 256 100 5 Description Archived 2010 07 27 at the Wayback Machine and chapter preview links Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Epstein Joshua M 2006 Growing Adaptive Organizations An Agent Based Computational Approach in Generative Social Science Studies in Agent Based Computational Modeling pp 309 1 Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine 344 Description Archived 2012 01 26 at the Wayback Machine and abstract Archived 2016 10 19 at the Wayback Machine Klosa Tomas B and Bart Nooteboom 2001 Agent based Computational Transaction Cost Economics Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 25 3 4 pp 503 52 Abstract Archived 2020 06 22 at the Wayback Machine Axtell Robert 2005 The Complexity of Exchange Economic Journal 115 504 Features pp F193 F210 Archived 2017 08 08 at the Wayback Machine Sandholm Tuomas W and Victor R Lesser 2001 Leveled Commitment Contracts and Strategic Breach Games and Economic Behavior 35 1 2 pp 212 270 Archived 2020 12 04 at the Wayback Machine Colander David Peter Howitt Alan Kirman Axel Leijonhufvud and Perry Mehrling 2008 Beyond DSGE Models Toward an Empirically Based Macroeconomics American Economic Review 98 2 pp 236 240 Pre pub PDF Sargent Thomas J 1994 Bounded Rationality in Macroeconomics Oxford Description and chapter preview 1st page links Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Tesfatsion Leigh 2006 Agent Based Computational Economics A Constructive Approach to Economic Theory ch 16 Handbook of Computational Economics v 2 pp 832 865 Abstract Archived 2018 08 09 at the Wayback Machine and pre pub PDF Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Smith Vernon L 2008 experimental economics The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Archived 2012 01 19 at the Wayback Machine Duffy John 2006 Agent Based Models and Human Subject Experiments ch 19 Handbook of Computational Economics v 2 pp 949 101 Abstract Archived 2015 09 24 at the Wayback Machine Namatame Akira and Takao Terano 2002 The Hare and the Tortoise Cumulative Progress in Agent based Simulation in Agent based Approaches in Economic and Social Complex Systems pp 3 14 IOS Press Description Archived 2012 04 05 at the Wayback Machine Fagiolo Giorgio Alessio Moneta and Paul Windrum 2007 A Critical Guide to Empirical Validation of Agent Based Models in Economics Methodologies Procedures and Open Problems Computational Economics 30 pp 195 Archived 2023 07 01 at the Wayback Machine 226 Tesfatsion Leigh 2006 Agent Based Computational Economics A Constructive Approach to Economic Theory ch 16 Handbook of Computational Economics v 2 pp 831 880 sect 5 Abstract Archived 2018 08 09 at the Wayback Machine and pre pub PDF Archived 2017 08 11 at the Wayback Machine Judd Kenneth L 2006 Computationally Intensive Analyses in Economics Handbook of Computational Economics v 2 ch 17 pp 881 893 Pre pub PDF Archived 2022 01 21 at the Wayback Machine Tesfatsion Leigh and Kenneth L Judd ed 2006 Handbook of Computational Economics v 2 Description Archived 2012 03 06 at the Wayback Machine amp and chapter previewlinks Brockhaus Oliver Farkas Michael Ferraris Andrew Long Douglas Overhaus Marcus 2000 Equity Derivatives and Market Risk Models Risk Books pp 13 17 ISBN 978 1 899332 87 8 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2008 08 17 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Liner Gaines H 2002 Core Journals in Economics Economic Inquiry 40 1 140 doi 10 1093 ei 40 1 138 Stigler George J Stigler Steven J Friedland Claire April 1995 The Journals of Economics The Journal of Political Economy 103 2 331 359 doi 10 1086 261986 ISSN 0022 3808 JSTOR 2138643 S2CID 154780520 Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2020 01 27 Stigler et al reviewed journal articles in core economic journals as defined by the authors but meaning generally non specialist journals throughout the 20th century Journal articles which at any point used geometric representation or mathematical notation were noted as using that level of mathematics as its highest level of mathematical technique The authors refer to verbal techniques as those which conveyed the subject of the piece without notation from geometry algebra or calculus Stigler et al p 342 Sutter Daniel and Rex Pjesky Where Would Adam Smith Publish Today The Near Absence of Math free Research in Top Journals May 2007 2 Archived 2017 10 10 at the Wayback Machine Arrow Kenneth J April 1960 The Work of Ragnar Frisch Econometrician Econometrica 28 2 175 192 doi 10 2307 1907716 ISSN 0012 9682 JSTOR 1907716 Bjerkholt Olav July 1995 Ragnar Frisch Editor of Econometrica 1933 1954 Econometrica 63 4 755 765 doi 10 2307 2171799 ISSN 0012 9682 JSTOR 1906940 Lange Oskar 1945 The Scope and Method of Economics Review of Economic Studies 13 1 19 32 doi 10 2307 2296113 ISSN 0034 6527 JSTOR 2296113 S2CID 4140287 Aldrich John January 1989 Autonomy Oxford Economic Papers 41 1 History and Methodology of Econometrics 15 34 doi 10 1093 oxfordjournals oep a041889 ISSN 0030 7653 JSTOR 2663180 Epstein Roy J 1987 A History of Econometrics Contributions to Economic Analysis North Holland pp 13 19 ISBN 978 0 444 70267 8 OCLC 230844893 Colander David C 2004 The Strange Persistence of the IS LM Model History of Political Economy 36 Annual Supplement 305 322 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 692 6446 doi 10 1215 00182702 36 Suppl 1 305 ISSN 0018 2702 S2CID 6705939 Brems Hans October 1975 Marshall on Mathematics Journal of Law and Economics 18 2 583 585 doi 10 1086 466825 ISSN 0022 2186 JSTOR 725308 S2CID 154881432 Frigg R Hartman S February 27 2006 Edward N Zalta ed Models in Science Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy Stanford California The Metaphysics Research Lab ISSN 1095 5054 Archived from the original on 2007 06 09 Retrieved 2008 08 16 Greg Mankiw s Blog An Exercise for My Readers Archived from the original on 2019 08 07 Retrieved 2019 08 07 Cochrane John H 2017 10 21 The Grumpy Economist Greg s algebra The Grumpy Economist Archived from the original on 2023 07 01 Retrieved 2019 08 07 Ekelund Robert Hebert Robert 2014 A History of Economic Theory amp Method 6th ed Long Grove IL Waveland Press pp 574 575 Hayek Friedrich September 1945 The Use of Knowledge in Society American Economic Review 35 4 519 530 JSTOR 1809376 Heilbroner Robert May June 1999 The end of the Dismal Science Challenge Magazine Archived from the original on 2008 12 10 Beed amp Owen 584 Boland L A 2007 Seven Decades of Economic Methodology In I C Jarvie K Milford D W Miller eds Karl Popper A Centenary Assessment London Ashgate Publishing p 219 ISBN 978 0 7546 5375 2 Retrieved 2008 06 10 Beed Clive Kane Owen 1991 What Is the Critique of the Mathematization of Economics Kyklos 44 4 581 612 doi 10 1111 j 1467 6435 1991 tb01798 x Friedman Milton 1953 Essays in Positive Economics Chicago University of Chicago Press pp 30 33 41 ISBN 978 0 226 26403 5 Keynes John Maynard 1936 The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money Cambridge Macmillan p 297 ISBN 978 0 333 10729 4 Archived from the original on 2019 05 28 Retrieved 2009 04 30 Paul A Samuelson 1952 Economic Theory and Mathematics An Appraisal American Economic Review 42 2 pp 56 64 65 press D W Bushaw and R W Clower 1957 Introduction to Mathematical Economics p vii Archived 2022 03 18 at the Wayback Machine Solow Robert M 20 March 1988 The Wide Wide World Of Wealth The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics Edited by John Eatwell Murray Milgate and Peter Newman Four volumes 4 103 pp New York Stockton Press 650 New York Times Archived from the original on 1 August 2017 Retrieved 11 February 2017 Further reading EditAlpha C Chiang and Kevin Wainwright 1967 2005 Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics McGraw Hill Irwin Contents E Roy Weintraub 1982 Mathematics for Economists Cambridge Contents Stephen Glaister 1984 Mathematical Methods for Economists 3rd ed Blackwell Contents Akira Takayama 1985 Mathematical Economics 2nd ed Cambridge Contents Nancy L Stokey and Robert E Lucas with Edward Prescott 1989 Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics Harvard University Press Desecription and chapter preview links A K Dixit 1976 1990 Optimization in Economic Theory 2nd ed Oxford Description and contents preview Kenneth L Judd 1998 Numerical Methods in Economics MIT Press Description and chapter preview links Michael Carter 2001 Foundations of Mathematical Economics MIT Press Contents Ferenc Szidarovszky and Sandor Molnar 2002 Introduction to Matrix Theory With Applications to Business and Economics World Scientific Publishing Description and preview D Wade Hands 2004 Introductory Mathematical Economics 2nd ed Oxford Contents Giancarlo Gandolfo 1997 2009 Economic Dynamics 4th ed Springer Description and preview John Stachurski 2009 Economic Dynamics Theory and Computation MIT Press Description and preview External links Edit Wikiquote has quotations related to Mathematical economics Look up mathematical economics in Wiktionary the free dictionary Journal of Mathematical Economics Aims amp Scope Mathematical Economics and Financial Mathematics at Curlie Erasmus Mundus Master QEM Models and Methods of Quantitative Economics The Models and Methods of Quantitative Economics QEM Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Mathematical economics amp oldid 1168776057, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.