fbpx
Wikipedia

Léon Walras

Marie-Esprit-Léon Walras (French: [valʁas];[2] 16 December 1834 – 5 January 1910) was a French mathematical economist and Georgist.[3] He formulated the marginal theory of value (independently of William Stanley Jevons and Carl Menger) and pioneered the development of general equilibrium theory. Walras is best known for his book Éléments d'économie politique pure, a work that has contributed greatly to the mathematization of economics through the concept of general equilibrium. The definition of the role of the entrepreneur found in it was also taken up and amplified by Joseph Schumpeter.

Léon Walras
Born(1834-12-16)16 December 1834
Died5 January 1910(1910-01-05) (aged 75)
Clarens, now part of Montreux, Switzerland
FieldEconomics
Microeconomics
School or
tradition
Lausanne School
Marginalism
Alma materÉcole des Mines de Paris
Influences
ContributionsMarginal utility
General equilibrium
Walras's law
Walrasian auction

For Walras, exchanges only take place after a Walrasian tâtonnement (French for "trial and error"), guided by the auctioneer, has made it possible to reach market equilibrium. It was the general equilibrium obtained from a single hypothesis, rarity, that led Joseph Schumpeter to consider him "the greatest of all economists". The notion of general equilibrium was very quickly adopted by major economists such as Vilfredo Pareto, Knut Wicksell and Gustav Cassel. John Hicks and Paul Samuelson used the Walrasian contribution in the elaboration of the neoclassical synthesis. For their part, Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu, from the perspective of a logician and a mathematician, determined the conditions necessary for equilibrium.

Biography

Walras was the son of a French school administrator Auguste Walras. His father was not a professional economist, yet his economic thinking had a profound effect on his son. He found the value of goods by setting their scarcity relative to human wants.

Walras enrolled in the École des Mines de Paris, but grew tired of engineering. He worked as a bank manager, journalist, romantic novelist and railway clerk before turning to economics.[4] Walras received an appointment as the professor of political economy at the University of Lausanne.

Walras also inherited his father's interest in social reform. Much like the Fabians, Walras called for the nationalization of land, believing that land's productivity would always increase and that rents from that land would be sufficient to support the nation without taxes. He also asserts that all other taxes (i.e. on goods, labor, capital) eventually realize effects exactly identical to a consumption tax,[5] so they can hurt the economy (unlike a land tax).

Another of Walras's influences was Augustin Cournot, a former schoolmate of his father. Through Cournot, Walras came under the influence of rationalism and was introduced to the use of mathematics in economics.

As Professor of Political Economy at the University of Lausanne, Walras is credited with founding the Lausanne school of economics, along with his successor Vilfredo Pareto.[6]

Because most of Walras's publications were only available in French, many economists were unfamiliar with his work. This changed in 1954 with the publication of William Jaffé's English translation of Walras's Éléments d'économie politique pure.[7] Walras's work was also too mathematically complex for many contemporary readers of his time. On the other hand, it has a great insight into the market process under idealized conditions so it has been far more read in the modern era.

Although Walras came to be regarded as one of the three leaders of the marginalist revolution,[8] he was not familiar with the two other leading figures of marginalism, William Stanley Jevons and Carl Menger, and developed his theories independently. Elements has Walras disagreeing with Jevons on the applicability, while the findings adopted by Carl Menger, he says, are completely in alignment with the ideas present in the book (even though expressed non-mathematically).[9]

Main ideas

Walras's law

Walras's law implies that the sum of the values of excess demands across all markets must equal zero, whether or not the economy is in a general equilibrium. This implies that if positive excess demand exists in one market, negative excess demand must exist in some other market. Thus, if all markets but one are in equilibrium, then that last market must also be in equilibrium.

General equilibrium theory

In 1874 and 1877 Walras published the work that led him to be considered the father of the general equilibrium theory, Éléments d'économie politique pure [see next section for bibliographical details].

His main goal was to solve a problem presented by A. A. Cournot: Does a general equilibrium exist? Though it had been demonstrated that prices would equate supply and demand to clear individual markets ("partial equilibrium"), it was unclear that an equilibrium existed for all markets simultaneously ("general equilibrium").

While teaching at the Lausanne Academy, Walras began constructing a mathematical model that assumes a "regime of perfectly free competition", in which productive factors, products, and prices automatically adjust in equilibrium. Walras began with the theory of exchange in 1873 and proceeded to map out his theories of production, capitalization and money in his first edition.

His theory of exchange began with an expansion of Cournot's demand curve to include more than two commodities, also realizing the value of the quantity sold must equal the quantity purchased thus the ratio of prices must be equal to the inverse ratio of quantities. Walras then drew a supply curve from the demand curve and set equilibrium prices at the intersection. His model could now determine prices of commodities but only the relative price. In order to deduce the absolute price, Walras could choose one price to serve as the numeraire, such that all other prices are measured in units of this commodity. Using the numeraire, he determined that marginal utility [rareté] divided by the price must be equal for all commodities.

Then he argued that, because each individual consumer consumes as much value as the value of that individual's stock of goods, the value of total sales equals the value of total purchase. That is, Walras's law holds.

Walras then expanded the theory to include production with the assumption of an existence of fixed coefficients in said production making possible a generalization that the marginal productivity of the factors of production varied with the amount of input, making factor substitution possible.

Walras constructed his basic theory of general equilibrium by beginning with simple equations and then increasing the complexity in the next equations. He began with a two-person bartering system, then moved on to the derivation of downward-sloping consumer demands. Next he moved on to exchanges involving multiple parties, and finally ended with credit and money.

Walras wrote down four sets of equations:

  • the quantity of goods demanded;
  • relating the prices of goods to their costs of production;
  • the quantities of inputs supplied;
  • the quantities of inputs demanded.

There are four sets of variables to solve for:

  • the price of each good;
  • the quantity of each good sold;
  • the price of each factor of production;
  • the quantity of each of those factor bought by businesses.

To simplify matters, Walras added one further equation (the Walras's law equation), requiring that all the money received must be spent, one way or the other.

By Walras's law, any particular market must be in equilibrium if all other markets in an economy are also in equilibrium, because the excess market demands sum to zero. Thus, in an economy with n markets, it is sufficient to solve n-1 simultaneous equations for market clearing. Taking one good as the numéraire in terms of which prices are specified, the economy has n-1 unknown prices that can be determined by the n-1 simultaneous equations, he thus concluded that the general equilibrium exists.[10]

Though this argument works when all equations are linear, it does not hold when the equations are nonlinear. It is easy to construct a pairs of equations in two variables with no solutions. A more rigorous version of the argument was developed independently by Lionel McKenzie and the pair Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu in the 1950s.

Walrasian auction

The Walrasian auction is a type of simultaneous auction where each agent calculates its demand for the good at every possible price and submits this to an auctioneer. The price is then set so that the total demand across all agents equals the total amount of the good. Thus, a Walrasian auction perfectly matches the supply and the demand. Walras suggests that equilibrium will be achieved through a process of tâtonnement (French for "trial and error"), a form of incremental hill climbing.

Economic value definition of utility

Léon Walras provides a definition of economic utility based on economic value as opposed to an ethical theory of value:

I state that things are useful as soon as they may serve whatever usage, as soon as they match whatever need and allow its fulfillment. Thus, there is here no point to deal with 'nuances' by way of which one classes, in the language of everyday conversation, utility beside what is pleasant and between the necessary and the superfluous. Necessary, useful, pleasant and superfluous, all of this is, for us, more or less useful. There is here as well no need to take into account the morality or immorality of the need that the useful things matches and permits to fulfill. Whether a substance is searched for by a doctor to heal an ill person, or by an assassin to poison his family, this is an important question from other points of view, albeit totally indifferent from ours. The substance is useful, for us, in both cases, and may well be more useful in the second case than in the first one.[a]

In economic theories of value, the term "value" is unrelated to any notions of value used in ethics, they are homonyms.

Legacy

In 1941 George Stigler[11] wrote about Walras:

There is no general history of economic thought in English which devotes more than passing reference to his work. ... This sort of empty fame in English-speaking countries is of course attributable in large part to Walras's use of his mother tongue, French, and his depressing array of mathematical formulas.

What caused the re-appraisal of Walras's consideration in the US, was the influx of German-speaking scientists – the German version of the Éléments was published in 1881.[citation needed] According to Schumpeter:[12]

Walras is ... greatest of all economists. His system of economic equilibrium, uniting, as it does, the quality of 'revolutionary' creativeness with the quality of classic synthesis, is the only work by an economist that will stand comparison with the achievements of theoretical physics.

Major works

Éléments d'Économie Politique Pure

 
Éléments d’Économie Politique Pure

The Éléments of 1874/1877 are the work by which Léon Walras is best known. The full title is

  • Éléments d'Économie Politique Pure, ou Théorie de la richesse sociale.

The half title page uses only the title ('Éléments d'Économie Politique Pure') whereas inside the body (e.g. p. 1 and the contents page) the subtitle ('Théorie de la richesse sociale') is used as if it were the title.

Plan of work

The work was issued in two instalments (fascicules) in separate years. It was intended as the first of three parts of a systematic treatise as follows:

  • 1re partie:– Éléments d'Économie Politique Pure, ou Théorie de la richesse sociale.
    • Section I. Objet et divisions de l'économie politique et sociale.
    • Section II. Théorie mathématique de l'échange.
    • Section III. Du numéraire et de la monnaie.
    • Section IV. Théorie naturelle de la production et de la conommation de la richesse.
    • Section V. Conditions et conséquences du progrès économique.
    • Section VI. Effets naturels et nécessaires des divers modes d'organisation économique de la société.
  • 2e partie:– Éléments d'Économie Politique Appliquée, ou Théorie de la production agricole, industrielle et commerciale de la richesse.
  • 3e partie:– Éléments d'Économie Sociale, ou Théorie de la répartition de la richesse par la propriété et l'impôt.[13]

Works with titles echoing those proposed for Parts II and III were published in 1898 and 1896. They are included in the list of other works below.

Editions

  • First (1874/1877). Most readily available. Described by Walker and van Daal as a 'brilliant expression of pure originality, containing many theoretical innovations' which 'needed alteration and development in a variety of important respects'.[14]
  • Second (1889). Revised, corrected and enlarged.
  • Third (1896). A minor revision with new appendices. This is considered the best edition by Walker and van Daal.
  • Fourth (1900). Revised and extended. According to Walker and van Daal, 'these changes resulted in an incomplete, internally contradictory, and occasionally incoherent text'.
  • Fifth (1926). Posthumous; published by his daughter Aline. 'Édition définitive, revue et augmentée'.[15] Follows the fourth.

Derived work

The 'Théorie Mathématique de la Richesse Sociale' included in the list of other works (below) is described by the National Library of Australia as 'a series of lectures and articles that together summarize the mathematical elements of the author's Élements '.[16]

English Translations

  • William Jaffé (1954) of the fifth edition as Elements of Pure Economics.
  • Donald A. Walker and Jan van Daal (2014) of the third edition as Elements of Theoretical Economics.

Walker and van Daal describe Jaffé's translation of the word crieur as 'a momentous error that has misled generations of readers'.

Online and facsimile editions

  • Online: Walras, Léon (1874). Éléments D'économie Politique Pure, Ou, Théorie De La Richesse (in French). Retrieved 17 August 2018.
  • Facsimile: cheap photographic reprints are produced by facsimilepublisher.com.

Both of these are made from the first edition and are defective in respect of illustrations. The original figures were included as folding plates (presumably at the end of each fascicule). The online edition contains only Figs. 3, 4, 10, and 12 whereas the facsimile contains only Figs. 5 and 6.

Other works

  • Francis Saveur, 1858.
  • "De la propriété intellectuelle", 1859, Journal des économistes.
  • Walras, Léon (1860). L'économie Politique Et La Justice: Examen Critique Et Réfutation Des Doctrines Économiques De P.j. Proudhon, Précédés D'un Introduction À L'étude De La Question Sociale (in French). Paris: Guillaumin. Retrieved 17 August 2018.
  • "Paradoxes économiques I", 1860, Journal des économistes.
  • "Théorie critique de l'impôt", 1861.
  • De l'impôt dans le Canton de Vaud, 1861.
  • Walras, Léon (1865). Les associations populaires de consommation, de production et de crédit (in French). Paris: Dentu. Retrieved 17 August 2018.
  • "La bourse et le crédit", 1867, Paris Guide.
  • Walras (1868). Recherche de l'idéal social: leçons publiques faites à Paris (in French). Paris: Guillaumin. Retrieved 17 August 2018.
  • "Correspondance entre M. Jevons, professeur a Manchester, et M. Walras, professeur a Lausanne", 1874, Journal des économistes.
  • Walras, Léon (1882). De la fixité de valeur de l'étalon monétaire (in French). Paris. Retrieved 17 August 2018.
  • "Un nuovo ramo della matematica. Dell' applicazione delle matematiche all' economia politica", 1876, Giornale degli economisti.
  • Théorie mathématique de la richesse sociale, 1883.
  • "Notice autobiographique de Léon Walras", 1893.
  • Études d'économie sociale; Théorie de la répartition de la richesse sociale, 1896.
  • Études d'économie politique appliquée; Théorie de la production de la richesse sociale, 1898.
  • "Théorie du crédit", 1898, Revue d'économie politique.
  • "Sur les équations de la circulation", 1899, Giornale degli economisti
  • "Cournot et l'Économique Mathématique", 1905, Gazette de Lausanne.
  • "La Paix par la Justice Sociale et le Libre Échange", 1907, Questions Pratiques de Legislation Ouvrière.
  • L'état et le chemin de fer (1875).
  • "Leone Walras, Autobiografia", 1908, Giornale degli Economisti.
  • "Un initiateur en économie politique, A.A. Walras", 1908, La Revue du Mois.
  • "Économique et méchanique", 1909, Bulletin de la Société Vaudoise de Sciences Naturelles
  • Correspondence of Léon Walras and related papers (ed. by William Jaffé, 3 vols.), 1965.

See also

Note

  1. ^ « Je dis que les choses sont utiles dès qu'elles peuvent servir à un usage quelconque, dès qu'elles répondent à un besoin quelconque et en permettent la satisfaction. Ainsi, il n'y a pas à s'occuper ici des nuances par lesquelles on classe, dans le langage de la conversation courante, l'utilité à côté de l'agréable entre le nécessaire et le superflu. Nécessaire, utile, agréable et superflu, tout cela, pour nous, est plus ou moins utile. Il n'y a pas davantage à tenir compte ici de la moralité ou de l'immoralité du besoin auquel répond la chose utile et qu'elle permet de satisfaire. Qu'une substance soit recherchée par un médecin pour guérir un malade ou pour un assassin pour empoisonner sa famille, c'est une question très importante à d'autres points de vue, mais tout à fait indifférente au nôtre. La substance est utile, pour nous, dans les deux cas, et peut l'être plus dans le second que dans le premier. » Elements d'économie pure, ou théorie de la richesse sociale, 1874

References

  1. ^ Jaffé, William (1965). "128". Correspondence of Leon Walras and Related Papers. Vol. 1. Amsterdam: North Holland.
  2. ^ Singh, H. K. Manmohan (1958). "Marie Esprit Léon Walras". Indian Economic Review. 4 (1): 6–17. JSTOR 29793129.
  3. ^ Cirillo, Renato (Jan 1984). "Léon Walras and Social Justice". The American Journal of Economics and Sociology. 43 (1): 53–60. doi:10.1111/j.1536-7150.1984.tb02222.x. JSTOR 3486394.
  4. ^ Economyths (2010) by David Orrell, p. 54
  5. ^ Walras, Léon (1969). Elements of Pure Economics; or, The Theory of Social Wealth. Translated by William Jaffé. New York: A. M. Kelly. p. 457,458.
  6. ^ . The New School, The History of Economic Thought Website. Archived from the original on January 6, 2011. Retrieved 2010-12-30.
  7. ^ Walker, Donald A. (December 1981). "William Jaffé, Historian of Economic Thought, 1898–1980". The American Economic Review. 71 (5): 1012–19. JSTOR 1803482.
  8. ^ Sandmo, Agnar (2011). Economics Evolving: A History of Economic Thought, Princeton University Press: Princeton, p. 190
  9. ^ Walras, Léon (1969). Elements of Pure Economics; or, The Theory of Social Wealth. Translated by William Jaffé. New York: A. M. Kelly. p. 204.
  10. ^ Pressman, Steven. Fifty Major Economists. "Léon Walras (1834-1910)." 2nd ed., Routledge, 2006.
  11. ^ Stigler, George, 1994 [1941], Production and Distribution Theories, New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Publishers, p. 222.
  12. ^ Schumpeter, J. A., 1994 [1954], History of Economic Analysis, Oxford University Press, p. 795
  13. ^ Walras, 'Éléments', first ed., p. vi.
  14. ^ Donald A. Walker and Jan van Daal, translators' introduction to the 2014 translation. Available in part online as https://assets.cambridge.org/97811070/64133/frontmatter/9781107064133_frontmatter.pdf.
  15. ^ W.Hildenbrand and A. P. Kirman, 'Equilibrium Analysis' (1988).
  16. ^ Catalogue record at https://catalogue.nla.gov.au/Record/2018624.

Further reading

  • Jaffé, William, and Donald A. Walker (ed.) (1983). Essays on Walras. Cambridge University Press.
  • Morishima, Michio (1977). Walras' economics : a pure theory of capital and money. Cambridge University Press.
  • Medema S.G. & Samuels W.J. (2003). "The history of economic thought: a reader" Routledge, London and New York.

External links

léon, walras, marie, esprit, french, valʁas, december, 1834, january, 1910, french, mathematical, economist, georgist, formulated, marginal, theory, value, independently, william, stanley, jevons, carl, menger, pioneered, development, general, equilibrium, the. Marie Esprit Leon Walras French valʁas 2 16 December 1834 5 January 1910 was a French mathematical economist and Georgist 3 He formulated the marginal theory of value independently of William Stanley Jevons and Carl Menger and pioneered the development of general equilibrium theory Walras is best known for his book Elements d economie politique pure a work that has contributed greatly to the mathematization of economics through the concept of general equilibrium The definition of the role of the entrepreneur found in it was also taken up and amplified by Joseph Schumpeter Leon WalrasBorn 1834 12 16 16 December 1834Evreux Upper Normandy FranceDied5 January 1910 1910 01 05 aged 75 Clarens now part of Montreux SwitzerlandFieldEconomicsMicroeconomicsSchool ortraditionLausanne SchoolMarginalismAlma materEcole des Mines de ParisInfluencesAugustin CournotEtienne Vacherot 1 rationalismAdam SmithJean Baptiste SayContributionsMarginal utilityGeneral equilibriumWalras s lawWalrasian auctionFor Walras exchanges only take place after a Walrasian tatonnement French for trial and error guided by the auctioneer has made it possible to reach market equilibrium It was the general equilibrium obtained from a single hypothesis rarity that led Joseph Schumpeter to consider him the greatest of all economists The notion of general equilibrium was very quickly adopted by major economists such as Vilfredo Pareto Knut Wicksell and Gustav Cassel John Hicks and Paul Samuelson used the Walrasian contribution in the elaboration of the neoclassical synthesis For their part Kenneth Arrow and Gerard Debreu from the perspective of a logician and a mathematician determined the conditions necessary for equilibrium Contents 1 Biography 2 Main ideas 2 1 Walras s law 2 2 General equilibrium theory 2 3 Walrasian auction 2 4 Economic value definition of utility 3 Legacy 4 Major works 4 1 Elements d Economie Politique Pure 4 1 1 Plan of work 4 1 2 Editions 4 1 3 Derived work 4 1 4 English Translations 4 1 5 Online and facsimile editions 4 2 Other works 5 See also 6 Note 7 References 8 Further reading 9 External linksBiography EditWalras was the son of a French school administrator Auguste Walras His father was not a professional economist yet his economic thinking had a profound effect on his son He found the value of goods by setting their scarcity relative to human wants Walras enrolled in the Ecole des Mines de Paris but grew tired of engineering He worked as a bank manager journalist romantic novelist and railway clerk before turning to economics 4 Walras received an appointment as the professor of political economy at the University of Lausanne Walras also inherited his father s interest in social reform Much like the Fabians Walras called for the nationalization of land believing that land s productivity would always increase and that rents from that land would be sufficient to support the nation without taxes He also asserts that all other taxes i e on goods labor capital eventually realize effects exactly identical to a consumption tax 5 so they can hurt the economy unlike a land tax Another of Walras s influences was Augustin Cournot a former schoolmate of his father Through Cournot Walras came under the influence of rationalism and was introduced to the use of mathematics in economics As Professor of Political Economy at the University of Lausanne Walras is credited with founding the Lausanne school of economics along with his successor Vilfredo Pareto 6 Because most of Walras s publications were only available in French many economists were unfamiliar with his work This changed in 1954 with the publication of William Jaffe s English translation of Walras s Elements d economie politique pure 7 Walras s work was also too mathematically complex for many contemporary readers of his time On the other hand it has a great insight into the market process under idealized conditions so it has been far more read in the modern era Although Walras came to be regarded as one of the three leaders of the marginalist revolution 8 he was not familiar with the two other leading figures of marginalism William Stanley Jevons and Carl Menger and developed his theories independently Elements has Walras disagreeing with Jevons on the applicability while the findings adopted by Carl Menger he says are completely in alignment with the ideas present in the book even though expressed non mathematically 9 Main ideas EditSee also Walras s law General equilibrium theory and Walrasian auction Walras s law Edit Walras s law implies that the sum of the values of excess demands across all markets must equal zero whether or not the economy is in a general equilibrium This implies that if positive excess demand exists in one market negative excess demand must exist in some other market Thus if all markets but one are in equilibrium then that last market must also be in equilibrium General equilibrium theory Edit In 1874 and 1877 Walras published the work that led him to be considered the father of the general equilibrium theory Elements d economie politique pure see next section for bibliographical details His main goal was to solve a problem presented by A A Cournot Does a general equilibrium exist Though it had been demonstrated that prices would equate supply and demand to clear individual markets partial equilibrium it was unclear that an equilibrium existed for all markets simultaneously general equilibrium While teaching at the Lausanne Academy Walras began constructing a mathematical model that assumes a regime of perfectly free competition in which productive factors products and prices automatically adjust in equilibrium Walras began with the theory of exchange in 1873 and proceeded to map out his theories of production capitalization and money in his first edition His theory of exchange began with an expansion of Cournot s demand curve to include more than two commodities also realizing the value of the quantity sold must equal the quantity purchased thus the ratio of prices must be equal to the inverse ratio of quantities Walras then drew a supply curve from the demand curve and set equilibrium prices at the intersection His model could now determine prices of commodities but only the relative price In order to deduce the absolute price Walras could choose one price to serve as the numeraire such that all other prices are measured in units of this commodity Using the numeraire he determined that marginal utility rarete divided by the price must be equal for all commodities Then he argued that because each individual consumer consumes as much value as the value of that individual s stock of goods the value of total sales equals the value of total purchase That is Walras s law holds Walras then expanded the theory to include production with the assumption of an existence of fixed coefficients in said production making possible a generalization that the marginal productivity of the factors of production varied with the amount of input making factor substitution possible Walras constructed his basic theory of general equilibrium by beginning with simple equations and then increasing the complexity in the next equations He began with a two person bartering system then moved on to the derivation of downward sloping consumer demands Next he moved on to exchanges involving multiple parties and finally ended with credit and money Walras wrote down four sets of equations the quantity of goods demanded relating the prices of goods to their costs of production the quantities of inputs supplied the quantities of inputs demanded There are four sets of variables to solve for the price of each good the quantity of each good sold the price of each factor of production the quantity of each of those factor bought by businesses To simplify matters Walras added one further equation the Walras s law equation requiring that all the money received must be spent one way or the other By Walras s law any particular market must be in equilibrium if all other markets in an economy are also in equilibrium because the excess market demands sum to zero Thus in an economy with n markets it is sufficient to solve n 1 simultaneous equations for market clearing Taking one good as the numeraire in terms of which prices are specified the economy has n 1 unknown prices that can be determined by the n 1 simultaneous equations he thus concluded that the general equilibrium exists 10 Though this argument works when all equations are linear it does not hold when the equations are nonlinear It is easy to construct a pairs of equations in two variables with no solutions A more rigorous version of the argument was developed independently by Lionel McKenzie and the pair Kenneth Arrow and Gerard Debreu in the 1950s Walrasian auction Edit The Walrasian auction is a type of simultaneous auction where each agent calculates its demand for the good at every possible price and submits this to an auctioneer The price is then set so that the total demand across all agents equals the total amount of the good Thus a Walrasian auction perfectly matches the supply and the demand Walras suggests that equilibrium will be achieved through a process of tatonnement French for trial and error a form of incremental hill climbing Economic value definition of utility Edit Leon Walras provides a definition of economic utility based on economic value as opposed to an ethical theory of value I state that things are useful as soon as they may serve whatever usage as soon as they match whatever need and allow its fulfillment Thus there is here no point to deal with nuances by way of which one classes in the language of everyday conversation utility beside what is pleasant and between the necessary and the superfluous Necessary useful pleasant and superfluous all of this is for us more or less useful There is here as well no need to take into account the morality or immorality of the need that the useful things matches and permits to fulfill Whether a substance is searched for by a doctor to heal an ill person or by an assassin to poison his family this is an important question from other points of view albeit totally indifferent from ours The substance is useful for us in both cases and may well be more useful in the second case than in the first one a In economic theories of value the term value is unrelated to any notions of value used in ethics they are homonyms Legacy EditIn 1941 George Stigler 11 wrote about Walras There is no general history of economic thought in English which devotes more than passing reference to his work This sort of empty fame in English speaking countries is of course attributable in large part to Walras s use of his mother tongue French and his depressing array of mathematical formulas What caused the re appraisal of Walras s consideration in the US was the influx of German speaking scientists the German version of the Elements was published in 1881 citation needed According to Schumpeter 12 Walras is greatest of all economists His system of economic equilibrium uniting as it does the quality of revolutionary creativeness with the quality of classic synthesis is the only work by an economist that will stand comparison with the achievements of theoretical physics Major works EditElements d Economie Politique Pure Edit Elements d Economie Politique Pure The Elements of 1874 1877 are the work by which Leon Walras is best known The full title is Elements d Economie Politique Pure ou Theorie de la richesse sociale The half title page uses only the title Elements d Economie Politique Pure whereas inside the body e g p 1 and the contents page the subtitle Theorie de la richesse sociale is used as if it were the title Plan of work Edit The work was issued in two instalments fascicules in separate years It was intended as the first of three parts of a systematic treatise as follows 1re partie Elements d Economie Politique Pure ou Theorie de la richesse sociale Section I Objet et divisions de l economie politique et sociale Section II Theorie mathematique de l echange Section III Du numeraire et de la monnaie Section IV Theorie naturelle de la production et de la conommation de la richesse Section V Conditions et consequences du progres economique Section VI Effets naturels et necessaires des divers modes d organisation economique de la societe 2e partie Elements d Economie Politique Appliquee ou Theorie de la production agricole industrielle et commerciale de la richesse 3e partie Elements d Economie Sociale ou Theorie de la repartition de la richesse par la propriete et l impot 13 Works with titles echoing those proposed for Parts II and III were published in 1898 and 1896 They are included in the list of other works below Editions Edit First 1874 1877 Most readily available Described by Walker and van Daal as a brilliant expression of pure originality containing many theoretical innovations which needed alteration and development in a variety of important respects 14 Second 1889 Revised corrected and enlarged Third 1896 A minor revision with new appendices This is considered the best edition by Walker and van Daal Fourth 1900 Revised and extended According to Walker and van Daal these changes resulted in an incomplete internally contradictory and occasionally incoherent text Fifth 1926 Posthumous published by his daughter Aline Edition definitive revue et augmentee 15 Follows the fourth Derived work Edit The Theorie Mathematique de la Richesse Sociale included in the list of other works below is described by the National Library of Australia as a series of lectures and articles that together summarize the mathematical elements of the author s Elements 16 English Translations Edit William Jaffe 1954 of the fifth edition as Elements of Pure Economics Donald A Walker and Jan van Daal 2014 of the third edition as Elements of Theoretical Economics Walker and van Daal describe Jaffe s translation of the word crieur as a momentous error that has misled generations of readers Online and facsimile editions Edit Online Walras Leon 1874 Elements D economie Politique Pure Ou Theorie De La Richesse in French Retrieved 17 August 2018 Facsimile cheap photographic reprints are produced by facsimilepublisher com Both of these are made from the first edition and are defective in respect of illustrations The original figures were included as folding plates presumably at the end of each fascicule The online edition contains only Figs 3 4 10 and 12 whereas the facsimile contains only Figs 5 and 6 Other works Edit Francis Saveur 1858 De la propriete intellectuelle 1859 Journal des economistes Walras Leon 1860 L economie Politique Et La Justice Examen Critique Et Refutation Des Doctrines Economiques De P j Proudhon Precedes D un Introduction A L etude De La Question Sociale in French Paris Guillaumin Retrieved 17 August 2018 Paradoxes economiques I 1860 Journal des economistes Theorie critique de l impot 1861 De l impot dans le Canton de Vaud 1861 Walras Leon 1865 Les associations populaires de consommation de production et de credit in French Paris Dentu Retrieved 17 August 2018 La bourse et le credit 1867 Paris Guide Walras 1868 Recherche de l ideal social lecons publiques faites a Paris in French Paris Guillaumin Retrieved 17 August 2018 Correspondance entre M Jevons professeur a Manchester et M Walras professeur a Lausanne 1874 Journal des economistes Walras Leon 1882 De la fixite de valeur de l etalon monetaire in French Paris Retrieved 17 August 2018 Un nuovo ramo della matematica Dell applicazione delle matematiche all economia politica 1876 Giornale degli economisti Theorie mathematique de la richesse sociale 1883 Notice autobiographique de Leon Walras 1893 Etudes d economie sociale Theorie de la repartition de la richesse sociale 1896 Etudes d economie politique appliquee Theorie de la production de la richesse sociale 1898 Theorie du credit 1898 Revue d economie politique Sur les equations de la circulation 1899 Giornale degli economisti Cournot et l Economique Mathematique 1905 Gazette de Lausanne La Paix par la Justice Sociale et le Libre Echange 1907 Questions Pratiques de Legislation Ouvriere L etat et le chemin de fer 1875 Leone Walras Autobiografia 1908 Giornale degli Economisti Un initiateur en economie politique A A Walras 1908 La Revue du Mois Economique et mechanique 1909 Bulletin de la Societe Vaudoise de Sciences Naturelles Correspondence of Leon Walras and related papers ed by William Jaffe 3 vols 1965 See also EditLeon Walras at Wikipedia France Walras s law Walrasian auction General equilibrium Cost the limit of price Progressive theory of capitalNote Edit Je dis que les choses sont utiles des qu elles peuvent servir a un usage quelconque des qu elles repondent a un besoin quelconque et en permettent la satisfaction Ainsi il n y a pas a s occuper ici des nuances par lesquelles on classe dans le langage de la conversation courante l utilite a cote de l agreable entre le necessaire et le superflu Necessaire utile agreable et superflu tout cela pour nous est plus ou moins utile Il n y a pas davantage a tenir compte ici de la moralite ou de l immoralite du besoin auquel repond la chose utile et qu elle permet de satisfaire Qu une substance soit recherchee par un medecin pour guerir un malade ou pour un assassin pour empoisonner sa famille c est une question tres importante a d autres points de vue mais tout a fait indifferente au notre La substance est utile pour nous dans les deux cas et peut l etre plus dans le second que dans le premier Elements d economie pure ou theorie de la richesse sociale 1874References Edit Jaffe William 1965 128 Correspondence of Leon Walras and Related Papers Vol 1 Amsterdam North Holland Singh H K Manmohan 1958 Marie Esprit Leon Walras Indian Economic Review 4 1 6 17 JSTOR 29793129 Cirillo Renato Jan 1984 Leon Walras and Social Justice The American Journal of Economics and Sociology 43 1 53 60 doi 10 1111 j 1536 7150 1984 tb02222 x JSTOR 3486394 Economyths 2010 by David Orrell p 54 Walras Leon 1969 Elements of Pure Economics or The Theory of Social Wealth Translated by William Jaffe New York A M Kelly p 457 458 Marie Esprit Leon Walras 1834 1910 The New School The History of Economic Thought Website Archived from the original on January 6 2011 Retrieved 2010 12 30 Walker Donald A December 1981 William Jaffe Historian of Economic Thought 1898 1980 The American Economic Review 71 5 1012 19 JSTOR 1803482 Sandmo Agnar 2011 Economics Evolving A History of Economic Thought Princeton University Press Princeton p 190 Walras Leon 1969 Elements of Pure Economics or The Theory of Social Wealth Translated by William Jaffe New York A M Kelly p 204 Pressman Steven Fifty Major Economists Leon Walras 1834 1910 2nd ed Routledge 2006 Stigler George 1994 1941 Production and Distribution Theories New Brunswick N J Transaction Publishers p 222 Schumpeter J A 1994 1954 History of Economic Analysis Oxford University Press p 795 Walras Elements first ed p vi Donald A Walker and Jan van Daal translators introduction to the 2014 translation Available in part online as https assets cambridge org 97811070 64133 frontmatter 9781107064133 frontmatter pdf W Hildenbrand and A P Kirman Equilibrium Analysis 1988 Catalogue record at https catalogue nla gov au Record 2018624 Further reading EditJaffe William and Donald A Walker ed 1983 Essays on Walras Cambridge University Press Morishima Michio 1977 Walras economics a pure theory of capital and money Cambridge University Press Medema S G amp Samuels W J 2003 The history of economic thought a reader Routledge London and New York External links Edit Wikiquote has quotations related to Leon Walras Biography and major works Leon Walras 1834 1910 The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics Library of Economics and Liberty 2nd ed Liberty Fund 2008 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Leon Walras amp oldid 1149328644, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.