fbpx
Wikipedia

Microeconomics

Microeconomics is a branch of mainstream economics that studies the behavior of individuals and firms in making decisions regarding the allocation of scarce resources and the interactions among these individuals and firms.[1][2][3] Microeconomics focuses on the study of individual markets, sectors, or industries as opposed to the national economy as whole, which is studied in macroeconomics.

Microeconomics analyzes the market mechanisms that enable buyers and sellers to establish relative prices among goods and services. Shown is a marketplace in Delhi.

One goal of microeconomics is to analyze the market mechanisms that establish relative prices among goods and services and allocate limited resources among alternative uses. Microeconomics shows conditions under which free markets lead to desirable allocations. It also analyzes market failure, where markets fail to produce efficient results.

While microeconomics focuses on firms and individuals, macroeconomics focuses on the sum total of economic activity, dealing with the issues of growth, inflation, and unemployment and with national policies relating to these issues.[2] Microeconomics also deals with the effects of economic policies (such as changing taxation levels) on microeconomic behavior and thus on the aforementioned aspects of the economy.[4] Particularly in the wake of the Lucas critique, much of modern macroeconomic theories has been built upon microfoundations—i.e. based upon basic assumptions about micro-level behavior.

Assumptions and definitions

The word microeconomics derives from the Greek word 'mikros'(small, minor). Microeconomic study historically has been performed according to general equilibrium theory, developed by Léon Walras in Elements of Pure Economics (1874) and partial equilibrium theory, introduced by Alfred Marshall in Principles of Economics (1890).

Microeconomic theory typically begins with the study of a single rational and utility maximizing individual. To economists, rationality means an individual possesses stable preferences that are both complete and transitive.

The technical assumption that preference relations are continuous is needed to ensure the existence of a utility function. Although microeconomic theory can continue without this assumption, it would make comparative statics impossible since there is no guarantee that the resulting utility function would be differentiable.

Microeconomic theory progresses by defining a competitive budget set which is a subset of the consumption set. It is at this point that economists make the technical assumption that preferences are locally non-satiated. Without the assumption of LNS (local non-satiation) there is no 100% guarantee but there would be a rational rise in individual utility. With the necessary tools and assumptions in place the utility maximization problem (UMP) is developed.

The utility maximization problem is the heart of consumer theory. The utility maximization problem attempts to explain the action axiom by imposing rationality axioms on consumer preferences and then mathematically modeling and analyzing the consequences. The utility maximization problem serves not only as the mathematical foundation of consumer theory but as a metaphysical explanation of it as well. That is, the utility maximization problem is used by economists to not only explain what or how individuals make choices but why individuals make choices as well.

The utility maximization problem is a constrained optimization problem in which an individual seeks to maximize utility subject to a budget constraint. Economists use the extreme value theorem to guarantee that a solution to the utility maximization problem exists. That is, since the budget constraint is both bounded and closed, a solution to the utility maximization problem exists. Economists call the solution to the utility maximization problem a Walrasian demand function or correspondence.

The utility maximization problem has so far been developed by taking consumer tastes (i.e. consumer utility) as the primitive. However, an alternative way to develop microeconomic theory is by taking consumer choice as the primitive. This model of microeconomic theory is referred to as revealed preference theory.

 
The supply and demand model describes how prices vary as a result of a balance between product availability at each price (supply) and the desires of those with purchasing power at each price (demand). The graph depicts a right-shift in demand from D1 to D2 along with the consequent increase in price and quantity required to reach a new market-clearing equilibrium point on the supply curve (S).

The theory of supply and demand usually assumes that markets are perfectly competitive. This implies that there are many buyers and sellers in the market and none of them have the capacity to significantly influence prices of goods and services. In many real-life transactions, the assumption fails because some individual buyers or sellers have the ability to influence prices. Quite often, a sophisticated analysis is required to understand the demand-supply equation of a good model. However, the theory works well in situations meeting these assumptions.

Mainstream economics does not assume a priori that markets are preferable to other forms of social organization. In fact, much analysis is devoted to cases where market failures lead to resource allocation that is suboptimal and creates deadweight loss. A classic example of suboptimal resource allocation is that of a public good. In such cases, economists may attempt to find policies that avoid waste, either directly by government control, indirectly by regulation that induces market participants to act in a manner consistent with optimal welfare, or by creating "missing markets" to enable efficient trading where none had previously existed.

This is studied in the field of collective action and public choice theory. "Optimal welfare" usually takes on a Paretian norm, which is a mathematical application of the Kaldor–Hicks method. This can diverge from the Utilitarian goal of maximizing utility because it does not consider the distribution of goods between people. Market failure in positive economics (microeconomics) is limited in implications without mixing the belief of the economist and their theory.

The demand for various commodities by individuals is generally thought of as the outcome of a utility-maximizing process, with each individual trying to maximize their own utility under a budget constraint and a given consumption set.

History

Economists commonly consider themselves microeconomists or macroeconomists. The difference between microeconomics and macroeconomics likely was introduced in 1933 by the Norwegian economist Ragnar Frisch, the co-recipient of the first Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1969.[5][6] However, Frisch did not actually use the word "microeconomics", instead drawing distinctions between "micro-dynamic" and "macro-dynamic" analysis in a way similar to how the words "microeconomics" and "macroeconomics" are used today.[5][7] The first known use of the term "microeconomics" in a published article was from Pieter de Wolff in 1941, who broadened the term "micro-dynamics" into "microeconomics".[6][8]

Microeconomic theory

Consumer demand theory

Consumer demand theory relates preferences for the consumption of both goods and services to the consumption expenditures; ultimately, this relationship between preferences and consumption expenditures is used to relate preferences to consumer demand curves. The link between personal preferences, consumption and the demand curve is one of the most closely studied relations in economics. It is a way of analyzing how consumers may achieve equilibrium between preferences and expenditures by maximizing utility subject to consumer budget constraints.

Production theory

Production theory is the study of production, or the economic process of converting inputs into outputs.[9] Production uses resources to create a good or service that is suitable for use, gift-giving in a gift economy, or exchange in a market economy. This can include manufacturing, storing, shipping, and packaging. Some economists define production broadly as all economic activity other than consumption. They see every commercial activity other than the final purchase as some form of production.

Cost-of-production theory of value

The cost-of-production theory of value states that the price of an object or condition is determined by the sum of the cost of the resources that went into making it. The cost can comprise any of the factors of production (including labor, capital, or land) and taxation. Technology can be viewed either as a form of fixed capital (e.g. an industrial plant) or circulating capital (e.g. intermediate goods).

In the mathematical model for the cost of production, the short-run total cost is equal to fixed cost plus total variable cost. The fixed cost refers to the cost that is incurred regardless of how much the firm produces. The variable cost is a function of the quantity of an object being produced. The cost function can be used to characterize production through the duality theory in economics, developed mainly by Ronald Shephard (1953, 1970) and other scholars (Sickles & Zelenyuk, 2019, ch.2).

Opportunity cost

Opportunity cost is closely related to the idea of time constraints. One can do only one thing at a time, which means that, inevitably, one is always giving up other things. The opportunity cost of any activity is the value of the next-best alternative thing one may have done instead. Opportunity cost depends only on the value of the next-best alternative. It doesn't matter whether one has five alternatives or 5,000.

Opportunity costs can tell when not to do something as well as when to do something. For example, one may like waffles, but like chocolate even more. If someone offers only waffles, one would take it. But if offered waffles or chocolate, one would take the chocolate. The opportunity cost of eating waffles is sacrificing the chance to eat chocolate. Because the cost of not eating the chocolate is higher than the benefits of eating the waffles, it makes no sense to choose waffles. Of course, if one chooses chocolate, they are still faced with the opportunity cost of giving up having waffles. But one is willing to do that because the waffle's opportunity cost is lower than the benefits of the chocolate. Opportunity costs are unavoidable constraints on behaviour because one has to decide what's best and give up the next-best alternative.

Price Theory

Price theory is a field of economics that uses the supply and demand framework to explain and predict human behavior. It is associated with the Chicago School of Economics. Price theory studies competitive equilibrium in markets to yield testable hypotheses that can be rejected.

Price theory is not the same as microeconomics. Strategic behavior, such as the interactions among sellers in a market where they are few, is a significant part of microeconomics but is not emphasized in price theory. Price theorists focus on competition believing it to be a reasonable description of most markets that leaves room to study additional aspects of tastes and technology. As a result, price theory tends to use less game theory than microeconomics does.

Price theory focuses on how agents respond to prices, but its framework can be applied to a wide variety of socioeconomic issues that might not seem to involve prices at first glance. Price theorists have influenced several other fields including developing public choice theory and law and economics. Price theory has been applied to issues previously thought of as outside the purview of economics such as criminal justice, marriage, and addiction.

Microeconomic models

Supply and demand

Supply and demand is an economic model of price determination in a perfectly competitive market. It concludes that in a perfectly competitive market with no externalities, per unit taxes, or price controls, the unit price for a particular good is the price at which the quantity demanded by consumers equals the quantity supplied by producers. This price results in a stable economic equilibrium.

 
The supply and demand model describes how prices vary as a result of a balance between product availability and demand. The graph depicts an increase (that is, right-shift) in demand from D1 to D2 along with the consequent increase in price and quantity required to reach a new equilibrium point on the supply curve (S).

Prices and quantities have been described as the most directly observable attributes of goods produced and exchanged in a market economy.[10] The theory of supply and demand is an organizing principle for explaining how prices coordinate the amounts produced and consumed. In microeconomics, it applies to price and output determination for a market with perfect competition, which includes the condition of no buyers or sellers large enough to have price-setting power.

For a given market of a commodity, demand is the relation of the quantity that all buyers would be prepared to purchase at each unit price of the good. Demand is often represented by a table or a graph showing price and quantity demanded (as in the figure). Demand theory describes individual consumers as rationally choosing the most preferred quantity of each good, given income, prices, tastes, etc. A term for this is "constrained utility maximization" (with income and wealth as the constraints on demand). Here, utility refers to the hypothesized relation of each individual consumer for ranking different commodity bundles as more or less preferred.

The law of demand states that, in general, price and quantity demanded in a given market are inversely related. That is, the higher the price of a product, the less of it people would be prepared to buy (other things unchanged). As the price of a commodity falls, consumers move toward it from relatively more expensive goods (the substitution effect). In addition, purchasing power from the price decline increases ability to buy (the income effect). Other factors can change demand; for example an increase in income will shift the demand curve for a normal good outward relative to the origin, as in the figure. All determinants are predominantly taken as constant factors of demand and supply.

Supply is the relation between the price of a good and the quantity available for sale at that price. It may be represented as a table or graph relating price and quantity supplied. Producers, for example business firms, are hypothesized to be profit maximizers, meaning that they attempt to produce and supply the amount of goods that will bring them the highest profit. Supply is typically represented as a function relating price and quantity, if other factors are unchanged.

That is, the higher the price at which the good can be sold, the more of it producers will supply, as in the figure. The higher price makes it profitable to increase production. Just as on the demand side, the position of the supply can shift, say from a change in the price of a productive input or a technical improvement. The "Law of Supply" states that, in general, a rise in price leads to an expansion in supply and a fall in price leads to a contraction in supply. Here as well, the determinants of supply, such as price of substitutes, cost of production, technology applied and various factors of inputs of production are all taken to be constant for a specific time period of evaluation of supply.

Market equilibrium occurs where quantity supplied equals quantity demanded, the intersection of the supply and demand curves in the figure above. At a price below equilibrium, there is a shortage of quantity supplied compared to quantity demanded. This is posited to bid the price up. At a price above equilibrium, there is a surplus of quantity supplied compared to quantity demanded. This pushes the price down. The model of supply and demand predicts that for given supply and demand curves, price and quantity will stabilize at the price that makes quantity supplied equal to quantity demanded. Similarly, demand-and-supply theory predicts a new price-quantity combination from a shift in demand (as to the figure), or in supply.

For a given quantity of a consumer good, the point on the demand curve indicates the value, or marginal utility, to consumers for that unit. It measures what the consumer would be prepared to pay for that unit.[11] The corresponding point on the supply curve measures marginal cost, the increase in total cost to the supplier for the corresponding unit of the good. The price in equilibrium is determined by supply and demand. In a perfectly competitive market, supply and demand equate marginal cost and marginal utility at equilibrium.[12]

On the supply side of the market, some factors of production are described as (relatively) variable in the short run, which affects the cost of changing output levels. Their usage rates can be changed easily, such as electrical power, raw-material inputs, and over-time and temp work. Other inputs are relatively fixed, such as plant and equipment and key personnel. In the long run, all inputs may be adjusted by management. These distinctions translate to differences in the elasticity (responsiveness) of the supply curve in the short and long runs and corresponding differences in the price-quantity change from a shift on the supply or demand side of the market.

Marginalist theory, such as above, describes the consumers as attempting to reach most-preferred positions, subject to income and wealth constraints while producers attempt to maximize profits subject to their own constraints, including demand for goods produced, technology, and the price of inputs. For the consumer, that point comes where marginal utility of a good, net of price, reaches zero, leaving no net gain from further consumption increases. Analogously, the producer compares marginal revenue (identical to price for the perfect competitor) against the marginal cost of a good, with marginal profit the difference. At the point where marginal profit reaches zero, further increases in production of the good stop. For movement to market equilibrium and for changes in equilibrium, price and quantity also change "at the margin": more-or-less of something, rather than necessarily all-or-nothing.

Other applications of demand and supply include the distribution of income among the factors of production, including labour and capital, through factor markets. In a competitive labour market for example the quantity of labour employed and the price of labour (the wage rate) depends on the demand for labour (from employers for production) and supply of labour (from potential workers). Labour economics examines the interaction of workers and employers through such markets to explain patterns and changes of wages and other labour income, labour mobility, and (un)employment, productivity through human capital, and related public-policy issues.[13]

Demand-and-supply analysis is used to explain the behaviour of perfectly competitive markets, but as a standard of comparison it can be extended to any type of market. It can also be generalized to explain variables across the economy, for example, total output (estimated as real GDP) and the general price level, as studied in macroeconomics.[14] Tracing the qualitative and quantitative effects of variables that change supply and demand, whether in the short or long run, is a standard exercise in applied economics. Economic theory may also specify conditions such that supply and demand through the market is an efficient mechanism for allocating resources.[15]

Market structure

Market structure refers to features of a market, including the number of firms in the market, the distribution of market shares between them, product uniformity across firms, how easy it is for firms to enter and exit the market, and forms of competition in the market.[16][17] A market structure can have several types of interacting market systems. Different forms of markets are a feature of capitalism and market socialism, with advocates of state socialism often criticizing markets and aiming to substitute or replace markets with varying degrees of government-directed economic planning.

Competition acts as a regulatory mechanism for market systems, with government providing regulations where the market cannot be expected to regulate itself. Regulations help to mitigate negative externalities of goods and services when the private equilibrium of the market does not match the social equilibrium. One example of this is with regards to building codes, which if absent in a purely competition regulated market system, might result in several horrific injuries or deaths to be required before companies would begin improving structural safety, as consumers may at first not be as concerned or aware of safety issues to begin putting pressure on companies to provide them, and companies would be motivated not to provide proper safety features due to how it would cut into their profits.

The concept of "market type" is different from the concept of "market structure". Nevertheless, it is worth noting here that there are a variety of types of markets.

The different market structures produce cost curves[18] based on the type of structure present. The different curves are developed based on the costs of production, specifically the graph contains marginal cost, average total cost, average variable cost, average fixed cost, and marginal revenue, which is sometimes equal to the demand, average revenue, and price in a price-taking firm.

Perfect competition

Perfect competition is a situation in which numerous small firms producing identical products compete against each other in a given industry. Perfect competition leads to firms producing the socially optimal output level at the minimum possible cost per unit. Firms in perfect competition are "price takers" (they do not have enough market power to profitably increase the price of their goods or services). A good example would be that of digital marketplaces, such as eBay, on which many different sellers sell similar products to many different buyers. Consumers in a perfect competitive market have perfect knowledge about the products that are being sold in this market.

Imperfect competition

Imperfect competition is a type of market structure showing some but not all features of competitive markets.

Monopolistic competition

Monopolistic competition is a situation in which many firms with slightly different products compete. Production costs are above what may be achieved by perfectly competitive firms, but society benefits from the product differentiation. Examples of industries with market structures similar to monopolistic competition include restaurants, cereal, clothing, shoes, and service industries in large cities.

Monopoly

A monopoly is a market structure in which a market or industry is dominated by a single supplier of a particular good or service. Because monopolies have no competition, they tend to sell goods and services at a higher price and produce below the socially optimal output level. However, not all monopolies are a bad thing, especially in industries where multiple firms would result in more costs than benefits (i.e. natural monopolies).[19][20]

  • Natural monopoly: A monopoly in an industry where one producer can produce output at a lower cost than many small producers.

Oligopoly

An oligopoly is a market structure in which a market or industry is dominated by a small number of firms (oligopolists). Oligopolies can create the incentive for firms to engage in collusion and form cartels that reduce competition leading to higher prices for consumers and less overall market output.[21] Alternatively, oligopolies can be fiercely competitive and engage in flamboyant advertising campaigns.[22]

  • Duopoly: A special case of an oligopoly, with only two firms. Game theory can elucidate behavior in duopolies and oligopolies.[23]

Monopsony

A monopsony is a market where there is only one buyer and many sellers.

Bilateral monopoly

A bilateral monopoly is a market consisting of both a monopoly (a single seller) and a monopsony (a single buyer).

Oligopsony

An oligopsony is a market where there are a few buyers and many sellers.

Game theory

Game theory is a major method used in mathematical economics and business for modeling competing behaviors of interacting agents. The term "game" here implies the study of any strategic interaction between people. Applications include a wide array of economic phenomena and approaches, such as auctions, bargaining, mergers & acquisitions pricing, fair division, duopolies, oligopolies, social network formation, agent-based computational economics, general equilibrium, mechanism design, and voting systems, and across such broad areas as experimental economics, behavioral economics, information economics, industrial organization, and political economy.

Information economics

Information economics is a branch of microeconomic theory that studies how information and information systems affect an economy and economic decisions. Information has special characteristics. It is easy to create but hard to trust. It is easy to spread but hard to control. It influences many decisions. These special characteristics (as compared with other types of goods) complicate many standard economic theories.[24] The economics of information has recently become of great interest to many - possibly due to the rise of information-based companies inside the technology industry.[6] From a game theory approach, the usual constraints that agents have complete information can be loosened to further examine the consequences of having incomplete information. This gives rise to many results which are applicable to real life situations. For example, if one does loosen this assumption, then it is possible to scrutinize the actions of agents in situations of uncertainty. It is also possible to more fully understand the impacts – both positive and negative – of agents seeking out or acquiring information.[6]

Applied

 
United States Capitol Building: meeting place of the United States Congress, where many tax laws are passed, which directly impact economic welfare. This is studied in the subject of public economics.

Applied microeconomics includes a range of specialized areas of study, many of which draw on methods from other fields.

  • Economic history examines the evolution of the economy and economic institutions, using methods and techniques from the fields of economics, history, geography, sociology, psychology, and political science.
  • Education economics examines the organization of education provision and its implication for efficiency and equity, including the effects of education on productivity.
  • Financial economics examines topics such as the structure of optimal portfolios, the rate of return to capital, econometric analysis of security returns, and corporate financial behavior.
  • Health economics examines the organization of health care systems, including the role of the health care workforce and health insurance programs.
  • Industrial organization examines topics such as the entry and exit of firms, innovation, and the role of trademarks.
  • Law and economics applies microeconomic principles to the selection and enforcement of competing legal regimes and their relative efficiencies.
  • Political economy examines the role of political institutions in determining policy outcomes.
  • Public economics examines the design of government tax and expenditure policies and economic effects of these policies (e.g., social insurance programs).
  • Urban economics, which examines the challenges faced by cities, such as sprawl, air and water pollution, traffic congestion, and poverty, draws on the fields of urban geography and sociology.
  • Labor economics examines primarily labor markets, but comprises a large range of public policy issues such as immigration, minimum wages, or inequality.

See also

References

  1. ^ Marchant, Mary A.; Snell, William M. "Macroeconomics and International Policy Terms" (PDF). University of Kentucky. (PDF) from the original on 2007-03-18. Retrieved 2007-05-04.
  2. ^ a b "Economics Glossary". Monroe County Women's Disability Network. from the original on 2008-02-04. Retrieved 2008-02-22.
  3. ^ . New Mexico Public Education Department. Archived from the original on 2007-08-08. Retrieved 2008-02-22.
  4. ^ "Glossary". ECON100. from the original on 2006-04-11. Retrieved 2008-02-22.
  5. ^ a b Frisch, R. 1933. Propagation problems and impulse problems in dynamic economics. In Economic essays in honour of Gustav Cassel, ed. R. Frisch. London: Allen & Unwin.
  6. ^ a b c d Varian H.R. (1987) Microeconomics. In: Palgrave Macmillan (eds) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, London.
  7. ^ Varian, Hal R. (1987). "Microeconomics". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. pp. 1–5. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_1212-1. ISBN 978-1-349-95121-5.
  8. ^ De Wolff, Pieter (April 1941). "Income Elasticity of Demand, a Micro-Economic and a Macro-Economic Interpretation". The Economic Journal. 51 (201): 140–145. doi:10.2307/2225666. JSTOR 2225666.
  9. ^ Sickles, R., & Zelenyuk, V. (2019). Measurement of Productivity and Efficiency: Theory and Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/9781139565981
  10. ^ Brody, A. (1987). "Prices and quantities". In Eatwell, John; Milgate, Murray; Newman, Peter (eds.). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (first ed.). pp. 1–7. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.3325. ISBN 9780333786765.
  11. ^ Baumol, William J. (28 April 2016). "Utility and Value". Encyclopædia Britannica.
  12. ^ Hicks, J.R. (2001) [1939]. Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory (second ed.). London: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-828269-3.
  13. ^ Freeman, Richard B. (1987). "Labour economics". In Eatwell, John; Milgate, Murray; Newman, Peter (eds.). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (first ed.). pp. 1–7. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.2907. ISBN 9780333786765.
       • Taber, Christopher; Weinberg, Bruce A. (2008). "Labour economics (new perspectives)". In Durlauf, Steven N.; Blume, Lawrence E. (eds.). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (second ed.). Palgrave Macmillan UK. pp. 787–791. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.0914. ISBN 978-0-333-78676-5.
       • Hicks, John R. (1963) [1932]. The Theory of Wages (second ed.). Macmillan.
  14. ^ Blanchard, Olivier (2006). "Chapter 7: Putting All Markets Together: The AS–AD Model". Macroeconomics (4th ed.). Prentice-Hall. ISBN 978-0-1318-6026-1.
  15. ^ Jordan, J.S. (October 1982). "The Competitive Allocation Process Is Informationally Efficient Uniquely". Journal of Economic Theory. 28 (1): 1–18. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(82)90088-6.
  16. ^ McEachern, William A. (2006). Economics: A Contemporary Introduction. Thomson South-Western. pp. 166. ISBN 978-0-324-28860-5.
  17. ^ Hashimzade, Nigar; Myles, Gareth; Black, John (2017). "market structure". A Dictionary of Economics. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-875943-0.
  18. ^ Emerson, Patrick M. (2019-10-28), "Module 8: Cost Curves", Intermediate Microeconomics, Oregon State University, retrieved 2021-05-13
  19. ^ "Monopoly - Economics Help". Economics Help. from the original on 2018-03-14. Retrieved 2018-03-14.
  20. ^ Krylovskiy, Nikolay (20 January 2020). "Natural monopolies". Economics Online. Retrieved 2020-09-03.
  21. ^ . ftstatus=live. 11 June 2013. Archived from the original on 4 December 2013.
  22. ^ Erickson, Gary M. (2009). "Gary M. Erickson (2009). "An Oligopoly Model of Dynamic Advertising Competition". European Journal of Operational Research 197 (2009): 374-388". European Journal of Operational Research. 197 (1): 374–388. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2008.06.023.
  23. ^ "Oligopoly/Duopoly and Game Theory". AP Microeconomics Review. 2017. from the original on 2016-06-25. Retrieved 2017-06-11. Game theory is the main way economists [sic] understands the behavior of firms within this market structure.
  24. ^ • Beth Allen, 1990. "Information as an Economic Commodity," American Economic Review, 80(2), pp. 268–273.
      • Kenneth J. Arrow, 1999. "Information and the Organization of Industry," ch. 1, in Graciela Chichilnisky Markets, Information, and Uncertainty. Cambridge University Press, pp. 20–21.
       • _____, 1996. "The Economics of Information: An Exposition," Empirica, 23(2), pp. 119–128.
       • _____, 1984. Collected Papers of Kenneth J. Arrow, v. 4, The Economics of Information. Description 2012-03-30 at the Wayback Machine and chapter-preview links.
       • Jean-Jacques Laffont, 1989. The Economics of Uncertainty and Information, MIT Press. Description 2012-01-25 at the Wayback Machine and chapter-preview links.

Further reading

* Bade, Robin; Michael Parkin (2001). Foundations of Microeconomics. Addison Wesley Paperback 1st Edition.
  • Editors, biography.com (August 17, 2016). "Adam Smith Biography.com". A&E Television Networks. {{cite news}}: |last= has generic name (help)
  • Bouman, John: Principles of Microeconomics – free fully comprehensive Principles of Microeconomics and Macroeconomics texts. Columbia, Maryland, 2011
  • Colander, David. Microeconomics. McGraw-Hill Paperback, 7th Edition: 2008.
  • Dunne, Timothy; J. Bradford Jensen; Mark J. Roberts (2009). Producer Dynamics: New Evidence from Micro Data. University of Chicago Press. ISBN 978-0-226-17256-9.
  • Eaton, B. Curtis; Eaton, Diane F.; and Douglas W. Allen. Microeconomics. Prentice Hall, 5th Edition: 2002.
  • Erickson, Gary M. (2009). “An Oligopoly Model of Dynamic Advertising Competition“. European Journal of Operational Research 197 (2009): 374-388. https://econpapers.repec.org/article/eeeejores/v_3a197_3ay_3a2009_3ai_3a1_3ap_3a374-388.htm
  • Frank, Robert H.; Microeconomics and Behavior. McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 6th Edition: 2006.
  • Friedman, Milton. Price Theory. Aldine Transaction: 1976
  • Hagendorf, Klaus: Labour Values and the Theory of the Firm. Part I: The Competitive Firm. Paris: EURODOS; 2009.
  • Harnerger, Arnold C. (2008). "Microeconomics". In David R. Henderson (ed.). Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (2nd ed.). Indianapolis: Library of Economics and Liberty. ISBN 978-0-86597-665-8. OCLC 237794267.
  • Hicks, John R. Value and Capital. Clarendon Press. [1939] 1946, 2nd ed.
  • Hirshleifer, Jack., Glazer, Amihai, and Hirshleifer, David, Price theory and applications: Decisions, markets, and information. Cambridge University Press, 7th Edition: 2005.
  • Jaffe, Sonia; Minton, Robert; Mulligan, Casey B.; and Murphy, Kevin M.: Chicago Price Theory. Princeton University Press, 2019
  • Jehle, Geoffrey A.; and Philip J. Reny. Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Addison Wesley Paperback, 2nd Edition: 2000.
  • Katz, Michael L.; and Harvey S. Rosen. Microeconomics. McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 3rd Edition: 1997.
  • Kreps, David M. A Course in Microeconomic Theory. Princeton University Press: 1990
  • Landsburg, Steven. Price Theory and Applications. South-Western College Pub, 5th Edition: 2001.
  • Mankiw, N. Gregory. Principles of Microeconomics. South-Western Pub, 2nd Edition: 2000.
  • Mas-Colell, Andreu; Whinston, Michael D.; and Jerry R. Green. Microeconomic Theory. Oxford University Press, US: 1995.
  • McGuigan, James R.; Moyer, R. Charles; and Frederick H. Harris. Managerial Economics: Applications, Strategy and Tactics. South-Western Educational Publishing, 9th Edition: 2001.
  • Nicholson, Walter. Microeconomic Theory: Basic Principles and Extensions. South-Western College Pub, 8th Edition: 2001.
  • Perloff, Jeffrey M. Microeconomics. Pearson – Addison Wesley, 4th Edition: 2007.
  • Perloff, Jeffrey M. Microeconomics: Theory and Applications with Calculus. Pearson – Addison Wesley, 1st Edition: 2007
  • Pindyck, Robert S.; and Daniel L. Rubinfeld. Microeconomics. Prentice Hall, 7th Edition: 2008.
  • Ruffin, Roy J.; and Paul R. Gregory. Principles of Microeconomics. Addison Wesley, 7th Edition: 2000.
  • Sickles, R., & Zelenyuk, V. (2019). Measurement of Productivity and Efficiency: Theory and Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. https://assets.cambridge.org/97811070/36161/frontmatter/9781107036161_frontmatter.pdf
  • Varian, Hal R. (1987). "microeconomics," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 3, pp. 461–63.
  • Varian, Hal R. Intermediate Microeconomics: A Modern Approach. W. W. Norton & Company, 8th Edition: 2009.
  • Varian, Hal R. Microeconomic Analysis. W. W. Norton & Company, 3rd Edition: 1992.

External links

microeconomics, further, information, history, microeconomics, branch, mainstream, economics, that, studies, behavior, individuals, firms, making, decisions, regarding, allocation, scarce, resources, interactions, among, these, individuals, firms, focuses, stu. Further information History of microeconomics Microeconomics is a branch of mainstream economics that studies the behavior of individuals and firms in making decisions regarding the allocation of scarce resources and the interactions among these individuals and firms 1 2 3 Microeconomics focuses on the study of individual markets sectors or industries as opposed to the national economy as whole which is studied in macroeconomics Microeconomics analyzes the market mechanisms that enable buyers and sellers to establish relative prices among goods and services Shown is a marketplace in Delhi One goal of microeconomics is to analyze the market mechanisms that establish relative prices among goods and services and allocate limited resources among alternative uses Microeconomics shows conditions under which free markets lead to desirable allocations It also analyzes market failure where markets fail to produce efficient results While microeconomics focuses on firms and individuals macroeconomics focuses on the sum total of economic activity dealing with the issues of growth inflation and unemployment and with national policies relating to these issues 2 Microeconomics also deals with the effects of economic policies such as changing taxation levels on microeconomic behavior and thus on the aforementioned aspects of the economy 4 Particularly in the wake of the Lucas critique much of modern macroeconomic theories has been built upon microfoundations i e based upon basic assumptions about micro level behavior Contents 1 Assumptions and definitions 2 History 3 Microeconomic theory 3 1 Consumer demand theory 3 2 Production theory 3 3 Cost of production theory of value 3 4 Opportunity cost 3 5 Price Theory 4 Microeconomic models 4 1 Supply and demand 5 Market structure 5 1 Perfect competition 5 2 Imperfect competition 5 3 Monopolistic competition 5 4 Monopoly 5 5 Oligopoly 5 6 Monopsony 5 7 Bilateral monopoly 5 8 Oligopsony 6 Game theory 7 Information economics 8 Applied 9 See also 10 References 11 Further reading 12 External linksAssumptions and definitions EditThe word microeconomics derives from the Greek word mikros small minor Microeconomic study historically has been performed according to general equilibrium theory developed by Leon Walras in Elements of Pure Economics 1874 and partial equilibrium theory introduced by Alfred Marshall in Principles of Economics 1890 Microeconomic theory typically begins with the study of a single rational and utility maximizing individual To economists rationality means an individual possesses stable preferences that are both complete and transitive The technical assumption that preference relations are continuous is needed to ensure the existence of a utility function Although microeconomic theory can continue without this assumption it would make comparative statics impossible since there is no guarantee that the resulting utility function would be differentiable Microeconomic theory progresses by defining a competitive budget set which is a subset of the consumption set It is at this point that economists make the technical assumption that preferences are locally non satiated Without the assumption of LNS local non satiation there is no 100 guarantee but there would be a rational rise in individual utility With the necessary tools and assumptions in place the utility maximization problem UMP is developed The utility maximization problem is the heart of consumer theory The utility maximization problem attempts to explain the action axiom by imposing rationality axioms on consumer preferences and then mathematically modeling and analyzing the consequences The utility maximization problem serves not only as the mathematical foundation of consumer theory but as a metaphysical explanation of it as well That is the utility maximization problem is used by economists to not only explain what or how individuals make choices but why individuals make choices as well The utility maximization problem is a constrained optimization problem in which an individual seeks to maximize utility subject to a budget constraint Economists use the extreme value theorem to guarantee that a solution to the utility maximization problem exists That is since the budget constraint is both bounded and closed a solution to the utility maximization problem exists Economists call the solution to the utility maximization problem a Walrasian demand function or correspondence The utility maximization problem has so far been developed by taking consumer tastes i e consumer utility as the primitive However an alternative way to develop microeconomic theory is by taking consumer choice as the primitive This model of microeconomic theory is referred to as revealed preference theory The supply and demand model describes how prices vary as a result of a balance between product availability at each price supply and the desires of those with purchasing power at each price demand The graph depicts a right shift in demand from D1 to D2 along with the consequent increase in price and quantity required to reach a new market clearing equilibrium point on the supply curve S The theory of supply and demand usually assumes that markets are perfectly competitive This implies that there are many buyers and sellers in the market and none of them have the capacity to significantly influence prices of goods and services In many real life transactions the assumption fails because some individual buyers or sellers have the ability to influence prices Quite often a sophisticated analysis is required to understand the demand supply equation of a good model However the theory works well in situations meeting these assumptions Mainstream economics does not assume a priori that markets are preferable to other forms of social organization In fact much analysis is devoted to cases where market failures lead to resource allocation that is suboptimal and creates deadweight loss A classic example of suboptimal resource allocation is that of a public good In such cases economists may attempt to find policies that avoid waste either directly by government control indirectly by regulation that induces market participants to act in a manner consistent with optimal welfare or by creating missing markets to enable efficient trading where none had previously existed This is studied in the field of collective action and public choice theory Optimal welfare usually takes on a Paretian norm which is a mathematical application of the Kaldor Hicks method This can diverge from the Utilitarian goal of maximizing utility because it does not consider the distribution of goods between people Market failure in positive economics microeconomics is limited in implications without mixing the belief of the economist and their theory The demand for various commodities by individuals is generally thought of as the outcome of a utility maximizing process with each individual trying to maximize their own utility under a budget constraint and a given consumption set History EditMain article History of microeconomics Economists commonly consider themselves microeconomists or macroeconomists The difference between microeconomics and macroeconomics likely was introduced in 1933 by the Norwegian economist Ragnar Frisch the co recipient of the first Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1969 5 6 However Frisch did not actually use the word microeconomics instead drawing distinctions between micro dynamic and macro dynamic analysis in a way similar to how the words microeconomics and macroeconomics are used today 5 7 The first known use of the term microeconomics in a published article was from Pieter de Wolff in 1941 who broadened the term micro dynamics into microeconomics 6 8 Microeconomic theory EditConsumer demand theory Edit Main article Consumer choice Consumer demand theory relates preferences for the consumption of both goods and services to the consumption expenditures ultimately this relationship between preferences and consumption expenditures is used to relate preferences to consumer demand curves The link between personal preferences consumption and the demand curve is one of the most closely studied relations in economics It is a way of analyzing how consumers may achieve equilibrium between preferences and expenditures by maximizing utility subject to consumer budget constraints Production theory Edit Main article Production theory Production theory is the study of production or the economic process of converting inputs into outputs 9 Production uses resources to create a good or service that is suitable for use gift giving in a gift economy or exchange in a market economy This can include manufacturing storing shipping and packaging Some economists define production broadly as all economic activity other than consumption They see every commercial activity other than the final purchase as some form of production Cost of production theory of value Edit Main article Cost of production theory of value The cost of production theory of value states that the price of an object or condition is determined by the sum of the cost of the resources that went into making it The cost can comprise any of the factors of production including labor capital or land and taxation Technology can be viewed either as a form of fixed capital e g an industrial plant or circulating capital e g intermediate goods In the mathematical model for the cost of production the short run total cost is equal to fixed cost plus total variable cost The fixed cost refers to the cost that is incurred regardless of how much the firm produces The variable cost is a function of the quantity of an object being produced The cost function can be used to characterize production through the duality theory in economics developed mainly by Ronald Shephard 1953 1970 and other scholars Sickles amp Zelenyuk 2019 ch 2 Opportunity cost Edit Main article Opportunity cost Opportunity cost is closely related to the idea of time constraints One can do only one thing at a time which means that inevitably one is always giving up other things The opportunity cost of any activity is the value of the next best alternative thing one may have done instead Opportunity cost depends only on the value of the next best alternative It doesn t matter whether one has five alternatives or 5 000 Opportunity costs can tell when not to do something as well as when to do something For example one may like waffles but like chocolate even more If someone offers only waffles one would take it But if offered waffles or chocolate one would take the chocolate The opportunity cost of eating waffles is sacrificing the chance to eat chocolate Because the cost of not eating the chocolate is higher than the benefits of eating the waffles it makes no sense to choose waffles Of course if one chooses chocolate they are still faced with the opportunity cost of giving up having waffles But one is willing to do that because the waffle s opportunity cost is lower than the benefits of the chocolate Opportunity costs are unavoidable constraints on behaviour because one has to decide what s best and give up the next best alternative Price Theory Edit Price theory is a field of economics that uses the supply and demand framework to explain and predict human behavior It is associated with the Chicago School of Economics Price theory studies competitive equilibrium in markets to yield testable hypotheses that can be rejected Price theory is not the same as microeconomics Strategic behavior such as the interactions among sellers in a market where they are few is a significant part of microeconomics but is not emphasized in price theory Price theorists focus on competition believing it to be a reasonable description of most markets that leaves room to study additional aspects of tastes and technology As a result price theory tends to use less game theory than microeconomics does Price theory focuses on how agents respond to prices but its framework can be applied to a wide variety of socioeconomic issues that might not seem to involve prices at first glance Price theorists have influenced several other fields including developing public choice theory and law and economics Price theory has been applied to issues previously thought of as outside the purview of economics such as criminal justice marriage and addiction Microeconomic models EditSupply and demand Edit Main article Supply and demand Supply and demand is an economic model of price determination in a perfectly competitive market It concludes that in a perfectly competitive market with no externalities per unit taxes or price controls the unit price for a particular good is the price at which the quantity demanded by consumers equals the quantity supplied by producers This price results in a stable economic equilibrium The supply and demand model describes how prices vary as a result of a balance between product availability and demand The graph depicts an increase that is right shift in demand from D1 to D2 along with the consequent increase in price and quantity required to reach a new equilibrium point on the supply curve S Prices and quantities have been described as the most directly observable attributes of goods produced and exchanged in a market economy 10 The theory of supply and demand is an organizing principle for explaining how prices coordinate the amounts produced and consumed In microeconomics it applies to price and output determination for a market with perfect competition which includes the condition of no buyers or sellers large enough to have price setting power For a given market of a commodity demand is the relation of the quantity that all buyers would be prepared to purchase at each unit price of the good Demand is often represented by a table or a graph showing price and quantity demanded as in the figure Demand theory describes individual consumers as rationally choosing the most preferred quantity of each good given income prices tastes etc A term for this is constrained utility maximization with income and wealth as the constraints on demand Here utility refers to the hypothesized relation of each individual consumer for ranking different commodity bundles as more or less preferred The law of demand states that in general price and quantity demanded in a given market are inversely related That is the higher the price of a product the less of it people would be prepared to buy other things unchanged As the price of a commodity falls consumers move toward it from relatively more expensive goods the substitution effect In addition purchasing power from the price decline increases ability to buy the income effect Other factors can change demand for example an increase in income will shift the demand curve for a normal good outward relative to the origin as in the figure All determinants are predominantly taken as constant factors of demand and supply Supply is the relation between the price of a good and the quantity available for sale at that price It may be represented as a table or graph relating price and quantity supplied Producers for example business firms are hypothesized to be profit maximizers meaning that they attempt to produce and supply the amount of goods that will bring them the highest profit Supply is typically represented as a function relating price and quantity if other factors are unchanged That is the higher the price at which the good can be sold the more of it producers will supply as in the figure The higher price makes it profitable to increase production Just as on the demand side the position of the supply can shift say from a change in the price of a productive input or a technical improvement The Law of Supply states that in general a rise in price leads to an expansion in supply and a fall in price leads to a contraction in supply Here as well the determinants of supply such as price of substitutes cost of production technology applied and various factors of inputs of production are all taken to be constant for a specific time period of evaluation of supply Market equilibrium occurs where quantity supplied equals quantity demanded the intersection of the supply and demand curves in the figure above At a price below equilibrium there is a shortage of quantity supplied compared to quantity demanded This is posited to bid the price up At a price above equilibrium there is a surplus of quantity supplied compared to quantity demanded This pushes the price down The model of supply and demand predicts that for given supply and demand curves price and quantity will stabilize at the price that makes quantity supplied equal to quantity demanded Similarly demand and supply theory predicts a new price quantity combination from a shift in demand as to the figure or in supply For a given quantity of a consumer good the point on the demand curve indicates the value or marginal utility to consumers for that unit It measures what the consumer would be prepared to pay for that unit 11 The corresponding point on the supply curve measures marginal cost the increase in total cost to the supplier for the corresponding unit of the good The price in equilibrium is determined by supply and demand In a perfectly competitive market supply and demand equate marginal cost and marginal utility at equilibrium 12 On the supply side of the market some factors of production are described as relatively variable in the short run which affects the cost of changing output levels Their usage rates can be changed easily such as electrical power raw material inputs and over time and temp work Other inputs are relatively fixed such as plant and equipment and key personnel In the long run all inputs may be adjusted by management These distinctions translate to differences in the elasticity responsiveness of the supply curve in the short and long runs and corresponding differences in the price quantity change from a shift on the supply or demand side of the market Marginalist theory such as above describes the consumers as attempting to reach most preferred positions subject to income and wealth constraints while producers attempt to maximize profits subject to their own constraints including demand for goods produced technology and the price of inputs For the consumer that point comes where marginal utility of a good net of price reaches zero leaving no net gain from further consumption increases Analogously the producer compares marginal revenue identical to price for the perfect competitor against the marginal cost of a good with marginal profit the difference At the point where marginal profit reaches zero further increases in production of the good stop For movement to market equilibrium and for changes in equilibrium price and quantity also change at the margin more or less of something rather than necessarily all or nothing Other applications of demand and supply include the distribution of income among the factors of production including labour and capital through factor markets In a competitive labour market for example the quantity of labour employed and the price of labour the wage rate depends on the demand for labour from employers for production and supply of labour from potential workers Labour economics examines the interaction of workers and employers through such markets to explain patterns and changes of wages and other labour income labour mobility and un employment productivity through human capital and related public policy issues 13 Demand and supply analysis is used to explain the behaviour of perfectly competitive markets but as a standard of comparison it can be extended to any type of market It can also be generalized to explain variables across the economy for example total output estimated as real GDP and the general price level as studied in macroeconomics 14 Tracing the qualitative and quantitative effects of variables that change supply and demand whether in the short or long run is a standard exercise in applied economics Economic theory may also specify conditions such that supply and demand through the market is an efficient mechanism for allocating resources 15 Market structure EditMain article Market structure This section does not cite any sources Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed October 2018 Learn how and when to remove this template message Market structure refers to features of a market including the number of firms in the market the distribution of market shares between them product uniformity across firms how easy it is for firms to enter and exit the market and forms of competition in the market 16 17 A market structure can have several types of interacting market systems Different forms of markets are a feature of capitalism and market socialism with advocates of state socialism often criticizing markets and aiming to substitute or replace markets with varying degrees of government directed economic planning Competition acts as a regulatory mechanism for market systems with government providing regulations where the market cannot be expected to regulate itself Regulations help to mitigate negative externalities of goods and services when the private equilibrium of the market does not match the social equilibrium One example of this is with regards to building codes which if absent in a purely competition regulated market system might result in several horrific injuries or deaths to be required before companies would begin improving structural safety as consumers may at first not be as concerned or aware of safety issues to begin putting pressure on companies to provide them and companies would be motivated not to provide proper safety features due to how it would cut into their profits The concept of market type is different from the concept of market structure Nevertheless it is worth noting here that there are a variety of types of markets The different market structures produce cost curves 18 based on the type of structure present The different curves are developed based on the costs of production specifically the graph contains marginal cost average total cost average variable cost average fixed cost and marginal revenue which is sometimes equal to the demand average revenue and price in a price taking firm Perfect competition Edit Main article Perfect competition Perfect competition is a situation in which numerous small firms producing identical products compete against each other in a given industry Perfect competition leads to firms producing the socially optimal output level at the minimum possible cost per unit Firms in perfect competition are price takers they do not have enough market power to profitably increase the price of their goods or services A good example would be that of digital marketplaces such as eBay on which many different sellers sell similar products to many different buyers Consumers in a perfect competitive market have perfect knowledge about the products that are being sold in this market Imperfect competition Edit Main article Imperfect competition Imperfect competition is a type of market structure showing some but not all features of competitive markets Monopolistic competition Edit Main article Monopolistic competition Monopolistic competition is a situation in which many firms with slightly different products compete Production costs are above what may be achieved by perfectly competitive firms but society benefits from the product differentiation Examples of industries with market structures similar to monopolistic competition include restaurants cereal clothing shoes and service industries in large cities Monopoly Edit Main article Monopoly A monopoly is a market structure in which a market or industry is dominated by a single supplier of a particular good or service Because monopolies have no competition they tend to sell goods and services at a higher price and produce below the socially optimal output level However not all monopolies are a bad thing especially in industries where multiple firms would result in more costs than benefits i e natural monopolies 19 20 Natural monopoly A monopoly in an industry where one producer can produce output at a lower cost than many small producers Oligopoly Edit Main article Oligopoly An oligopoly is a market structure in which a market or industry is dominated by a small number of firms oligopolists Oligopolies can create the incentive for firms to engage in collusion and form cartels that reduce competition leading to higher prices for consumers and less overall market output 21 Alternatively oligopolies can be fiercely competitive and engage in flamboyant advertising campaigns 22 Duopoly A special case of an oligopoly with only two firms Game theory can elucidate behavior in duopolies and oligopolies 23 Monopsony Edit Main article Monopsony A monopsony is a market where there is only one buyer and many sellers Bilateral monopoly Edit Main article Bilateral monopoly A bilateral monopoly is a market consisting of both a monopoly a single seller and a monopsony a single buyer Oligopsony Edit Main article Oligopsony An oligopsony is a market where there are a few buyers and many sellers Game theory EditMain article Game theory Game theory is a major method used in mathematical economics and business for modeling competing behaviors of interacting agents The term game here implies the study of any strategic interaction between people Applications include a wide array of economic phenomena and approaches such as auctions bargaining mergers amp acquisitions pricing fair division duopolies oligopolies social network formation agent based computational economics general equilibrium mechanism design and voting systems and across such broad areas as experimental economics behavioral economics information economics industrial organization and political economy Information economics EditMain article Information economics Information economics is a branch of microeconomic theory that studies how information and information systems affect an economy and economic decisions Information has special characteristics It is easy to create but hard to trust It is easy to spread but hard to control It influences many decisions These special characteristics as compared with other types of goods complicate many standard economic theories 24 The economics of information has recently become of great interest to many possibly due to the rise of information based companies inside the technology industry 6 From a game theory approach the usual constraints that agents have complete information can be loosened to further examine the consequences of having incomplete information This gives rise to many results which are applicable to real life situations For example if one does loosen this assumption then it is possible to scrutinize the actions of agents in situations of uncertainty It is also possible to more fully understand the impacts both positive and negative of agents seeking out or acquiring information 6 Applied Edit United States Capitol Building meeting place of the United States Congress where many tax laws are passed which directly impact economic welfare This is studied in the subject of public economics Applied microeconomics includes a range of specialized areas of study many of which draw on methods from other fields Economic history examines the evolution of the economy and economic institutions using methods and techniques from the fields of economics history geography sociology psychology and political science Education economics examines the organization of education provision and its implication for efficiency and equity including the effects of education on productivity Financial economics examines topics such as the structure of optimal portfolios the rate of return to capital econometric analysis of security returns and corporate financial behavior Health economics examines the organization of health care systems including the role of the health care workforce and health insurance programs Industrial organization examines topics such as the entry and exit of firms innovation and the role of trademarks Law and economics applies microeconomic principles to the selection and enforcement of competing legal regimes and their relative efficiencies Political economy examines the role of political institutions in determining policy outcomes Public economics examines the design of government tax and expenditure policies and economic effects of these policies e g social insurance programs Urban economics which examines the challenges faced by cities such as sprawl air and water pollution traffic congestion and poverty draws on the fields of urban geography and sociology Labor economics examines primarily labor markets but comprises a large range of public policy issues such as immigration minimum wages or inequality See also EditEconomics Macroeconomics Critique of political economyReferences Edit Marchant Mary A Snell William M Macroeconomics and International Policy Terms PDF University of Kentucky Archived PDF from the original on 2007 03 18 Retrieved 2007 05 04 a b Economics Glossary Monroe County Women s Disability Network Archived from the original on 2008 02 04 Retrieved 2008 02 22 Social Studies Standards Glossary New Mexico Public Education Department Archived from the original on 2007 08 08 Retrieved 2008 02 22 Glossary ECON100 Archived from the original on 2006 04 11 Retrieved 2008 02 22 a b Frisch R 1933 Propagation problems and impulse problems in dynamic economics In Economic essays in honour of Gustav Cassel ed R Frisch London Allen amp Unwin a b c d Varian H R 1987 Microeconomics In Palgrave Macmillan eds The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Palgrave Macmillan London Varian Hal R 1987 Microeconomics The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics pp 1 5 doi 10 1057 978 1 349 95121 5 1212 1 ISBN 978 1 349 95121 5 De Wolff Pieter April 1941 Income Elasticity of Demand a Micro Economic and a Macro Economic Interpretation The Economic Journal 51 201 140 145 doi 10 2307 2225666 JSTOR 2225666 Sickles R amp Zelenyuk V 2019 Measurement of Productivity and Efficiency Theory and Practice Cambridge Cambridge University Press doi 10 1017 9781139565981 Brody A 1987 Prices and quantities In Eatwell John Milgate Murray Newman Peter eds The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics first ed pp 1 7 doi 10 1057 9780230226203 3325 ISBN 9780333786765 Baumol William J 28 April 2016 Utility and Value Encyclopaedia Britannica Hicks J R 2001 1939 Value and Capital An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory second ed London Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 828269 3 Freeman Richard B 1987 Labour economics In Eatwell John Milgate Murray Newman Peter eds The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics first ed pp 1 7 doi 10 1057 9780230226203 2907 ISBN 9780333786765 Taber Christopher Weinberg Bruce A 2008 Labour economics new perspectives In Durlauf Steven N Blume Lawrence E eds The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics second ed Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 787 791 doi 10 1057 9780230226203 0914 ISBN 978 0 333 78676 5 Hicks John R 1963 1932 The Theory of Wages second ed Macmillan Blanchard Olivier 2006 Chapter 7 Putting All Markets Together The AS AD Model Macroeconomics 4th ed Prentice Hall ISBN 978 0 1318 6026 1 Jordan J S October 1982 The Competitive Allocation Process Is Informationally Efficient Uniquely Journal of Economic Theory 28 1 1 18 doi 10 1016 0022 0531 82 90088 6 McEachern William A 2006 Economics A Contemporary Introduction Thomson South Western pp 166 ISBN 978 0 324 28860 5 Hashimzade Nigar Myles Gareth Black John 2017 market structure A Dictionary of Economics Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 875943 0 Emerson Patrick M 2019 10 28 Module 8 Cost Curves Intermediate Microeconomics Oregon State University retrieved 2021 05 13 Monopoly Economics Help Economics Help Archived from the original on 2018 03 14 Retrieved 2018 03 14 Krylovskiy Nikolay 20 January 2020 Natural monopolies Economics Online Retrieved 2020 09 03 Competition Counts ftstatus live 11 June 2013 Archived from the original on 4 December 2013 Erickson Gary M 2009 Gary M Erickson 2009 An Oligopoly Model of Dynamic Advertising Competition European Journal of Operational Research 197 2009 374 388 European Journal of Operational Research 197 1 374 388 doi 10 1016 j ejor 2008 06 023 Oligopoly Duopoly and Game Theory AP Microeconomics Review 2017 Archived from the original on 2016 06 25 Retrieved 2017 06 11 Game theory is the main way economists sic understands the behavior of firms within this market structure Beth Allen 1990 Information as an Economic Commodity American Economic Review 80 2 pp 268 273 Kenneth J Arrow 1999 Information and the Organization of Industry ch 1 in Graciela Chichilnisky Markets Information and Uncertainty Cambridge University Press pp 20 21 1996 The Economics of Information An Exposition Empirica 23 2 pp 119 128 1984 Collected Papers of Kenneth J Arrow v 4 The Economics of Information Description Archived 2012 03 30 at the Wayback Machine and chapter preview links Jean Jacques Laffont 1989 The Economics of Uncertainty and Information MIT Press Description Archived 2012 01 25 at the Wayback Machine and chapter preview links Further reading Edit Bade Robin Michael Parkin 2001 Foundations of Microeconomics Addison Wesley Paperback 1st Edition Editors biography com August 17 2016 Adam Smith Biography com A amp E Television Networks a href Template Cite news html title Template Cite news cite news a last has generic name help Bouman John Principles of Microeconomics free fully comprehensive Principles of Microeconomics and Macroeconomics texts Columbia Maryland 2011 Colander David Microeconomics McGraw Hill Paperback 7th Edition 2008 Dunne Timothy J Bradford Jensen Mark J Roberts 2009 Producer Dynamics New Evidence from Micro Data University of Chicago Press ISBN 978 0 226 17256 9 Eaton B Curtis Eaton Diane F and Douglas W Allen Microeconomics Prentice Hall 5th Edition 2002 Erickson Gary M 2009 An Oligopoly Model of Dynamic Advertising Competition European Journal of Operational Research 197 2009 374 388 https econpapers repec org article eeeejores v 3a197 3ay 3a2009 3ai 3a1 3ap 3a374 388 htm Frank Robert H Microeconomics and Behavior McGraw Hill Irwin 6th Edition 2006 Friedman Milton Price Theory Aldine Transaction 1976 Hagendorf Klaus Labour Values and the Theory of the Firm Part I The Competitive Firm Paris EURODOS 2009 Harnerger Arnold C 2008 Microeconomics In David R Henderson ed Concise Encyclopedia of Economics 2nd ed Indianapolis Library of Economics and Liberty ISBN 978 0 86597 665 8 OCLC 237794267 Hicks John R Value and Capital Clarendon Press 1939 1946 2nd ed Hirshleifer Jack Glazer Amihai and Hirshleifer David Price theory and applications Decisions markets and information Cambridge University Press 7th Edition 2005 Jaffe Sonia Minton Robert Mulligan Casey B and Murphy Kevin M Chicago Price Theory Princeton University Press 2019 Jehle Geoffrey A and Philip J Reny Advanced Microeconomic Theory Addison Wesley Paperback 2nd Edition 2000 Katz Michael L and Harvey S Rosen Microeconomics McGraw Hill Irwin 3rd Edition 1997 Kreps David M A Course in Microeconomic Theory Princeton University Press 1990 Landsburg Steven Price Theory and Applications South Western College Pub 5th Edition 2001 Mankiw N Gregory Principles of Microeconomics South Western Pub 2nd Edition 2000 Mas Colell Andreu Whinston Michael D and Jerry R Green Microeconomic Theory Oxford University Press US 1995 McGuigan James R Moyer R Charles and Frederick H Harris Managerial Economics Applications Strategy and Tactics South Western Educational Publishing 9th Edition 2001 Nicholson Walter Microeconomic Theory Basic Principles and Extensions South Western College Pub 8th Edition 2001 Perloff Jeffrey M Microeconomics Pearson Addison Wesley 4th Edition 2007 Perloff Jeffrey M Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus Pearson Addison Wesley 1st Edition 2007 Pindyck Robert S and Daniel L Rubinfeld Microeconomics Prentice Hall 7th Edition 2008 Ruffin Roy J and Paul R Gregory Principles of Microeconomics Addison Wesley 7th Edition 2000 Sickles R amp Zelenyuk V 2019 Measurement of Productivity and Efficiency Theory and Practice Cambridge Cambridge University Press https assets cambridge org 97811070 36161 frontmatter 9781107036161 frontmatter pdf Varian Hal R 1987 microeconomics The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics v 3 pp 461 63 Varian Hal R Intermediate Microeconomics A Modern Approach W W Norton amp Company 8th Edition 2009 Varian Hal R Microeconomic Analysis W W Norton amp Company 3rd Edition 1992 External links Edit Wikibooks has a book on the topic of Microeconomics Wikiversity has learning resources about Microeconomics X Lab A Collaborative Micro Economics and Social Sciences Research Laboratory Simulations in Microeconomics http media lanecc edu users martinezp 201 MicroHistory html a brief history of microeconomics Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Microeconomics amp oldid 1140109790, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.