fbpx
Wikipedia

Marshallian demand function

In microeconomics, a consumer's Marshallian demand function (named after Alfred Marshall) is the quantity they demand of a particular good as a function of its price, their income, and the prices of other goods, a more technical exposition of the standard demand function. It is a solution to the utility maximization problem of how the consumer can maximize their utility for given income and prices. A synonymous term is uncompensated demand function, because when the price rises the consumer is not compensated with higher nominal income for the fall in their real income, unlike in the Hicksian demand function. Thus the change in quantity demanded is a combination of a substitution effect and a wealth effect. Although Marshallian demand is in the context of partial equilibrium theory, it is sometimes called Walrasian demand as used in general equilibrium theory (named after Léon Walras).

According to the utility maximization problem, there are commodities with price vector and choosable quantity vector . The consumer has income , and hence a budget set of affordable packages

where is the dot product of the price and quantity vectors. The consumer has a utility function

The consumer's Marshallian demand correspondence is defined to be

Revealed preference Edit

Marshall's theory suggests that pursuit of utility is a motivational factor to a consumer which can be attained through the consumption of goods or service. The amount of consumer's utility is dependent on the level of consumption of a certain good, which is subject to the fundamental tendency of human nature and it is described as the law of diminishing marginal utility.

As utility maximum always exists, Marshallian demand correspondence must be nonempty at every value that corresponds with the standard budget set.

Uniqueness Edit

  is called a correspondence because in general it may be set-valued - there may be several different bundles that attain the same maximum utility. In some cases, there is a unique utility-maximizing bundle for each price and income situation; then,   is a function and it is called the Marshallian demand function.

If the consumer has strictly convex preferences and the prices of all goods are strictly positive, then there is a unique utility-maximizing bundle.[1]: 156  To prove this, suppose, by contradiction, that there are two different bundles,   and  , that maximize the utility. Then   and   are equally preferred. By definition of strict convexity, the mixed bundle   is strictly better than  . But this contradicts the optimality of  .

Continuity Edit

The maximum theorem implies that if:

  • The utility function   is continuous with respect to  ,
  • The correspondence   is non-empty, compact-valued, and continuous with respect to  ,

then   is an upper-semicontinuous correspondence. Moreover, if   is unique, then it is a continuous function of   and  .[1]: 156, 506 

Combining with the previous subsection, if the consumer has strictly convex preferences, then the Marshallian demand is unique and continuous. In contrast, if the preferences are not convex, then the Marshallian demand may be non-unique and non-continuous.

Homogeneity Edit

The optimal Marshallian demand correspondence of a continuous utility function is a homogeneous function with degree zero. This means that for every constant  

 

This is intuitively clear. Suppose   and   are measured in dollars. When  ,   and   are exactly the same quantities measured in cents. When prices and wealth go up by a factor a, the purchasing pattern of an economic agent remains constant. Obviously, expressing in different unit of measurement for prices and income should not affect the demand.

Demand curve Edit

Marshall's theory exploits that demand curve represents individual's diminishing marginal values of the good. The theory insists that the consumer's purchasing decision is dependent on the gainable utility of a goods or services compared to the price since the additional utility that the consumer gain must be at least as great as the price. The following suggestion proposes that the price demanded is equal to the maximum price that the consumer would pay for an extra unit of good or service. Hence, the utility is held constant along the demand curve. When the marginal utility of income is constant, or its value is the same across individuals within a market demand curve, generating net benefits of purchased units, or consumer surplus is possible through adding up of demand prices.

 
The intersection point of 'Price' and 'Marginal utility = Demand' shows the optimal level of individual's consumption.

Examples Edit

In the following examples, there are two commodities, 1 and 2.

1. The utility function has the Cobb–Douglas form:

 

The constrained optimization leads to the Marshallian demand function:

 

2. The utility function is a CES utility function:

 

Then  

In both cases, the preferences are strictly convex, the demand is unique and the demand function is continuous.

3. The utility function has the linear form:

 

The utility function is only weakly convex, and indeed the demand is not unique: when  , the consumer may divide his income in arbitrary ratios between product types 1 and 2 and get the same utility.

4. The utility function exhibits a non-diminishing marginal rate of substitution:

 

The utility function is not convex, and indeed the demand is not continuous: when  , the consumer demands only product 1, and when  , the consumer demands only product 2 (when   the demand correspondence contains two distinct bundles: either buy only product 1 or buy only product 2).

See also Edit

References Edit

  1. ^ a b Varian, Hal (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (Third ed.). New York: Norton. ISBN 0-393-95735-7.
  • Mas-Colell, Andreu; Whinston, Michael & Green, Jerry (1995). Microeconomic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-507340-1.
  • Nicholson, Walter (1978). Microeconomic Theory (Second ed.). Hinsdale: Dryden Press. pp. 90–93. ISBN 0-03-020831-9.
  • Silberberg, E. (2008). Hicksian and Marshallian Demands. London: Palgrave Macmillan, London. ISBN 978-1-349-95121-5.
  • Levin, Jonathan; Milgrom, Paul (October 2004). "Consumer Theory" (PDF). Retrieved 22 April 2021.
  • Wong, Stanley (2006). Foundations of Paul Samuelson's revealed preference theory (PDF) (Revised ed.). Routledge. ISBN 0-203-34983-0. Retrieved 19 April 2021.

marshallian, demand, function, microeconomics, consumer, named, after, alfred, marshall, quantity, they, demand, particular, good, function, price, their, income, prices, other, goods, more, technical, exposition, standard, demand, function, solution, utility,. In microeconomics a consumer s Marshallian demand function named after Alfred Marshall is the quantity they demand of a particular good as a function of its price their income and the prices of other goods a more technical exposition of the standard demand function It is a solution to the utility maximization problem of how the consumer can maximize their utility for given income and prices A synonymous term is uncompensated demand function because when the price rises the consumer is not compensated with higher nominal income for the fall in their real income unlike in the Hicksian demand function Thus the change in quantity demanded is a combination of a substitution effect and a wealth effect Although Marshallian demand is in the context of partial equilibrium theory it is sometimes called Walrasian demand as used in general equilibrium theory named after Leon Walras According to the utility maximization problem there are L displaystyle L commodities with price vector p displaystyle p and choosable quantity vector x displaystyle x The consumer has income I displaystyle I and hence a budget set of affordable packages B p I x p x I displaystyle B p I x p cdot x leq I where p x i L p i x i displaystyle p cdot x sum i L p i x i is the dot product of the price and quantity vectors The consumer has a utility function u R L R displaystyle u mathbb R L rightarrow mathbb R The consumer s Marshallian demand correspondence is defined to be x p I argmax x B p I u x displaystyle x p I operatorname argmax x in B p I u x Contents 1 Revealed preference 2 Uniqueness 3 Continuity 4 Homogeneity 5 Demand curve 6 Examples 7 See also 8 ReferencesRevealed preference EditMarshall s theory suggests that pursuit of utility is a motivational factor to a consumer which can be attained through the consumption of goods or service The amount of consumer s utility is dependent on the level of consumption of a certain good which is subject to the fundamental tendency of human nature and it is described as the law of diminishing marginal utility As utility maximum always exists Marshallian demand correspondence must be nonempty at every value that corresponds with the standard budget set Uniqueness Editx p I displaystyle x p I nbsp is called a correspondence because in general it may be set valued there may be several different bundles that attain the same maximum utility In some cases there is a unique utility maximizing bundle for each price and income situation then x p I displaystyle x p I nbsp is a function and it is called the Marshallian demand function If the consumer has strictly convex preferences and the prices of all goods are strictly positive then there is a unique utility maximizing bundle 1 156 To prove this suppose by contradiction that there are two different bundles x 1 displaystyle x 1 nbsp and x 2 displaystyle x 2 nbsp that maximize the utility Then x 1 displaystyle x 1 nbsp and x 2 displaystyle x 2 nbsp are equally preferred By definition of strict convexity the mixed bundle 0 5 x 1 0 5 x 2 displaystyle 0 5x 1 0 5x 2 nbsp is strictly better than x 1 x 2 displaystyle x 1 x 2 nbsp But this contradicts the optimality of x 1 x 2 displaystyle x 1 x 2 nbsp Continuity EditThe maximum theorem implies that if The utility function u x displaystyle u x nbsp is continuous with respect to x displaystyle x nbsp The correspondence B p I displaystyle B p I nbsp is non empty compact valued and continuous with respect to p I displaystyle p I nbsp then x p I displaystyle x p I nbsp is an upper semicontinuous correspondence Moreover if x p I displaystyle x p I nbsp is unique then it is a continuous function of p displaystyle p nbsp and I displaystyle I nbsp 1 156 506 Combining with the previous subsection if the consumer has strictly convex preferences then the Marshallian demand is unique and continuous In contrast if the preferences are not convex then the Marshallian demand may be non unique and non continuous Homogeneity EditThe optimal Marshallian demand correspondence of a continuous utility function is a homogeneous function with degree zero This means that for every constant a gt 0 displaystyle a gt 0 nbsp x a p a I x p I displaystyle x a cdot p a cdot I x p I nbsp This is intuitively clear Suppose p displaystyle p nbsp and I displaystyle I nbsp are measured in dollars When a 100 displaystyle a 100 nbsp a p displaystyle ap nbsp and a I displaystyle aI nbsp are exactly the same quantities measured in cents When prices and wealth go up by a factor a the purchasing pattern of an economic agent remains constant Obviously expressing in different unit of measurement for prices and income should not affect the demand Demand curve EditMarshall s theory exploits that demand curve represents individual s diminishing marginal values of the good The theory insists that the consumer s purchasing decision is dependent on the gainable utility of a goods or services compared to the price since the additional utility that the consumer gain must be at least as great as the price The following suggestion proposes that the price demanded is equal to the maximum price that the consumer would pay for an extra unit of good or service Hence the utility is held constant along the demand curve When the marginal utility of income is constant or its value is the same across individuals within a market demand curve generating net benefits of purchased units or consumer surplus is possible through adding up of demand prices nbsp The intersection point of Price and Marginal utility Demand shows the optimal level of individual s consumption Examples EditIn the following examples there are two commodities 1 and 2 1 The utility function has the Cobb Douglas form u x 1 x 2 x 1 a x 2 b displaystyle u x 1 x 2 x 1 alpha x 2 beta nbsp The constrained optimization leads to the Marshallian demand function x p 1 p 2 I a I a b p 1 b I a b p 2 displaystyle x p 1 p 2 I left frac alpha I alpha beta p 1 frac beta I alpha beta p 2 right nbsp 2 The utility function is a CES utility function u x 1 x 2 x 1 d d x 2 d d 1 d displaystyle u x 1 x 2 left frac x 1 delta delta frac x 2 delta delta right frac 1 delta nbsp Then x p 1 p 2 I I p 1 ϵ 1 p 1 ϵ p 2 ϵ I p 2 ϵ 1 p 1 ϵ p 2 ϵ with ϵ d d 1 displaystyle x p 1 p 2 I left frac Ip 1 epsilon 1 p 1 epsilon p 2 epsilon frac Ip 2 epsilon 1 p 1 epsilon p 2 epsilon right quad text with quad epsilon frac delta delta 1 nbsp In both cases the preferences are strictly convex the demand is unique and the demand function is continuous 3 The utility function has the linear form u x 1 x 2 x 1 x 2 displaystyle u x 1 x 2 x 1 x 2 nbsp The utility function is only weakly convex and indeed the demand is not unique when p 1 p 2 displaystyle p 1 p 2 nbsp the consumer may divide his income in arbitrary ratios between product types 1 and 2 and get the same utility 4 The utility function exhibits a non diminishing marginal rate of substitution u x 1 x 2 x 1 a x 2 a with a gt 1 displaystyle u x 1 x 2 x 1 alpha x 2 alpha quad text with quad alpha gt 1 nbsp The utility function is not convex and indeed the demand is not continuous when p 1 lt p 2 displaystyle p 1 lt p 2 nbsp the consumer demands only product 1 and when p 2 lt p 1 displaystyle p 2 lt p 1 nbsp the consumer demands only product 2 when p 1 p 2 displaystyle p 1 p 2 nbsp the demand correspondence contains two distinct bundles either buy only product 1 or buy only product 2 See also EditHicksian demand function Utility maximization problem Slutsky equationReferences Edit a b Varian Hal 1992 Microeconomic Analysis Third ed New York Norton ISBN 0 393 95735 7 Mas Colell Andreu Whinston Michael amp Green Jerry 1995 Microeconomic Theory Oxford Oxford University Press ISBN 0 19 507340 1 Nicholson Walter 1978 Microeconomic Theory Second ed Hinsdale Dryden Press pp 90 93 ISBN 0 03 020831 9 Silberberg E 2008 Hicksian and Marshallian Demands London Palgrave Macmillan London ISBN 978 1 349 95121 5 Levin Jonathan Milgrom Paul October 2004 Consumer Theory PDF Retrieved 22 April 2021 Wong Stanley 2006 Foundations of Paul Samuelson s revealed preference theory PDF Revised ed Routledge ISBN 0 203 34983 0 Retrieved 19 April 2021 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Marshallian demand function amp oldid 1147785827, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.