fbpx
Wikipedia

Law and economics

Law and economics, or economic analysis of law, is the application of microeconomic theory to the analysis of law, which emerged primarily from scholars of the Chicago school of economics. Economic concepts are used to explain the effects of laws, to assess which legal rules are economically efficient, and to predict which legal rules will be promulgated.[1] There are two major branches of law and economics;[2] one based on the application of the methods and theories of neoclassical economics to the positive and normative analysis of the law, and a second branch which focuses on an institutional analysis of law and legal institutions, with a broader focus on economic, political, and social outcomes, and overlapping with analyses of the institutions of politics and governance.

History

Origin

The historical antecedents of law and economics can be traced back to the classical economists, who are credited with the foundations of modern economic thought. As early as the 18th century, Adam Smith discussed the economic effects of mercantilist legislation; later, David Ricardo opposed the British Corn Laws on the grounds that they hindered agricultural productivity; and Frédéric Bastiat, in his influential book The Law, examined the unintended consequences of legislation. However, to apply economics to analyze the law regulating nonmarket activities is relatively new. A European law & economics movement around 1900 did not have any lasting influence.[3]

Harold Luhnow, the head of the Volker Fund, not only financed F. A. Hayek in the U.S. starting in 1946, but he shortly thereafter financed Aaron Director's coming to the University of Chicago in order to set up there a new center for scholars in law and economics. The University was headed by Robert Maynard Hutchins, a close collaborator of Luhnow's in setting up the Chicago School, as it became commonly known. The university faculty then included a strong base of libertarian scholars, including Frank Knight, George Stigler, Henry Simons, Ronald Coase and Jacob Viner.[4] Soon, it would also have not just Hayek himself, but Director's brother-in-law and Stigler's friend Milton Friedman, and also Robert Fogel, Robert Lucas, Eugene Fama, Richard Posner, and Gary Becker.

Historians Robert van Horn and Philip Mirowski described the development of modern economic concepts in "The Rise of the Chicago School of Economics", a chapter of The Road from Mont Pelerin (2009); and historian Bruce Caldwell (a great admirer of von Hayek) filled in more details of the account in his chapter, "The Chicago School, Hayek, and Neoliberalism", in Building Chicago Economics (2011). The field began with Gary Becker’s 1968 paper on crime (Becker also received a Nobel Prize). In 1972, Richard Posner, a law and economics scholar and the major advocate of the positive theory of efficiency, published the first edition of Economic Analysis of Law and founded The Journal of Legal Studies, both are regarded as important events. Gordon Tullock and Friedrich Hayek also wrote intensively in the area and influenced to spread of law and economics.

Founding

In 1958, Director founded The Journal of Law & Economics, which he co-edited with Nobel laureate Ronald Coase, and which helped to unite the fields of law and economics with far-reaching influence.[5] In 1960 and 1961, Ronald Coase and Guido Calabresi independently published two groundbreaking articles, "The Problem of Social Cost"[6] and "Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts".[7] This can be seen as the starting point for the modern school of law and economics.[8]

In 1962, Aaron Director helped to found the Committee on a Free Society. Director's appointment to the faculty of the University of Chicago Law School in 1946 began a half-century of intellectual productivity, although his reluctance about publishing left few writings behind.[9] He taught antitrust courses at the law school with Edward Levi, who eventually would serve as Dean of Chicago's Law School, President of the University of Chicago, and as U.S. Attorney General in the Ford administration. After retiring from the University of Chicago Law School in 1965, Director relocated to California and took a position at Stanford University's Hoover Institution. He died September 11, 2004, at his home in Los Altos Hills, California, ten days before his 103rd birthday.

Later development

In the early 1970s, Henry Manne (a former student of Coase) set out to build a center for law and economics at a major law school. He began at the University of Rochester, worked at the University of Miami, but was soon made unwelcome, moved to Emory University, and ended up at George Mason.[10] The last soon became a center for the education of judges—many long out of law school and never exposed to numbers and economics. Manne also attracted the support of the John M. Olin Foundation, whose support accelerated the movement. Today, Olin centers (or programs) for Law and Economics exist at many universities.

Chicago School notable figures

Modern forerunners of economic thought developed at the Chicago School include Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and Frédéric Bastiat.

Founders include:

Other notable individuals include:

Positive and normative law and economics

Economic analysis of law is usually divided into two subfields: positive and normative.

Positive law and economics

'Positive law and economics' uses economic analysis to predict the effects of various legal rules. So, for example, a positive economic analysis of tort law would predict the effects of a strict liability rule as opposed to the effects of a negligence rule. Positive law and economics has also at times purported to explain the development of legal rules, for example the common law of torts, in terms of their economic efficiency.

Normative law and economics

Normative law and economics goes one step further and makes policy recommendations based on the economic consequences of various policies. The key concept for normative economic analysis is efficiency, in particular, allocative efficiency.

A common concept of efficiency used by law and economics scholars is Pareto efficiency. A legal rule is Pareto efficient if it could not be changed so as to make one person better off without making another person worse off. A weaker conception of efficiency is Kaldor–Hicks efficiency. A legal rule is Kaldor–Hicks efficient if it could be made Pareto efficient by some parties compensating others as to offset their loss.

Nonetheless, the possibility of a clear distinction between positive and normative analysis has been questioned by Guido Calabresi who, in his book on "The future of Law and Economics" (2016: 21-22), believes that there is an "actual - and unavoidable - existence of value judgments underlying much economic analysis"[19]

Uri Weiss proposed this alternative: "It is common in law and economics to search for the law that will lead to the optimal outcome, providing the maximum size 'pie,' and to think about maximizing happiness instead of minimizing pain. We prefer another approach: We do not try to identify games that will lead to the optimal result but to prevent games in which it is in the best interests of the players to come to an unjust result".[20]

Criminal law

In 1968, Gary Becker, who would later win the Nobel prize for economics, published Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach.[21] This work relied on the economic concept of utility as the basic unit of analysis. In 1985, in An Economic Theory of the Criminal Law, Posner set out an alternative approach that relied instead on wealth as the basic unit of analysis.[22]

Relationship to other disciplines and approaches

As used by lawyers and legal scholars, the phrase "law and economics" refers to the application of microeconomic analysis to legal problems. Because of the overlap between legal systems and political systems, some of the issues in law and economics are also raised in political economy, constitutional economics and political science.

Approaches to the same issues from Marxist and critical theory/Frankfurt School perspectives usually do not identify themselves as "law and economics". For example, research by members of the critical legal studies movement and the sociology of law considers many of the same fundamental issues as does work labeled "law and economics", though from a vastly different perspective. The law and political economy movement also analyzes similar concepts using an entirely different approach.[23]

The one wing that represents a non-neoclassical approach to "law and economics" is the Continental (mainly German) tradition that sees the concept starting out of the governance and public policy (Staatswissenschaften) approach and the German Historical school of economics; this view is represented in the Elgar Companion to Law and Economics (2nd ed. 2005) and—though not exclusively—in the European Journal of Law and Economics. Here, consciously non-neoclassical approaches to economics are used for the analysis of legal (and administrative/governance) problems.

Law and economics is closely related to jurimetrics, the application of probability and statistics to legal questions.

Applications

Influence

The economic analysis of law has been influential in the United States as well as elsewhere. Judicial opinions use economic analysis and the theories of law and economics with some regularity, in the US but also, increasingly, in Commonwealth countries and in Europe. The influence of law and economics has also been felt in legal education, with graduate programs in the subject being offered in a number of countries. The influence of law and economics in civil law countries may be gauged from the availability of textbooks of law and economics, in English as well as in other European languages (Schäfer and Ott 2004; Mackaay 2013).

Many law schools in North America, Europe, and Asia have faculty members with a graduate degree in economics. In addition, many professional economists now study and write on the relationship between economics and legal doctrines. Anthony Kronman, former dean of Yale Law School, has written that "the intellectual movement that has had the greatest influence on American academic law in the past quarter-century [of the 20th Century]" is law and economics.[49]

Criticisms

Despite its influence, the law and economics movement has been criticized from a number of directions. This is especially true of normative law and economics. Because most law and economics scholarship operates within a neoclassical framework, fundamental criticisms of neoclassical economics have been drawn from other, competing frameworks, though there are numerous internal critiques as well.[50] Yet other schools of economic thought have emerged and have been applied to the work of law and economics in, for example, the work of Edgardo Buscaglia and Robert Cooter in the book "Law and Economics of Development".[51]

Rational choice theory

Critics of the economic analysis of legal questions have argued that normative economic analysis does not capture the importance of human rights and concerns for distributive justice. Some of the heaviest criticisms of law and economics come from the critical legal studies movement, in particular Duncan Kennedy[52] and Mark Kelman. Jon D. Hanson, of Harvard Law School, argues that our legal, economic, political, and social systems are unduly influenced by an individualistic model of behavior based on preferences, instead of a model that incorporates cognitive biases and social norms.[53]

Pareto efficiency

Additional criticism has been directed toward the assumed benefits of law and policy designed to increase allocative efficiency when such assumptions are modeled on "first-best" (Pareto optimal) general-equilibrium conditions. Under the theory of the second best, for example, if the fulfillment of a subset of optimal conditions cannot be met under any circumstances, it is incorrect to conclude that the fulfillment of any subset of optimal conditions will necessarily result in an increase in allocative efficiency.[54]

Consequently, any expression of public policy whose purported purpose is an unambiguous increase in allocative efficiency (for example, consolidation of research and development costs through increased mergers and acquisitions resulting from a systematic relaxation of antitrust laws) is, according to critics, fundamentally incorrect, as there is no general reason to conclude that an increase in allocative efficiency is more likely than a decrease.

Essentially, the "first-best" neoclassical analysis fails to properly account for various kinds of general-equilibrium feedback relationships that result from intrinsic Pareto imperfections.[54]

Another critique comes from the fact that there is no unique optimal result. Warren Samuels in his 2007 book, The Legal-Economic Nexus, argues, "efficiency in the Pareto sense cannot dispositively be applied to the definition and assignment of rights themselves, because efficiency requires an antecedent determination of the rights (23–4)".

Criminal methodology

Cullerne Bown has criticised Posner's approach on methodological grounds. He concludes that Posner’s approach to evaluating policies in the criminal process is methodologically invalid and that "these failings in turn make the entirety of his conclusions on the criminal process unreliable".[55]

Responses to criticism

Law and economics has adapted to some of these criticisms and been developed in a variety of directions. One important trend has been the application of game theory to legal problems.[56] Other developments have been the incorporation of behavioral economics into economic analysis of law,[57] and the increasing use of statistical and econometrics techniques.[58] Within the legal academy, the term socio-economics has been applied to economic approaches that are self-consciously broader than the neoclassical tradition.

Property rights, which are analyzed using economic analysis, are seen as fundamental human rights by defenders of law and economics.[59]

See also

References

  1. ^ David Friedman (1987). "law and economics," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 3, p. 144.
  2. ^ Ronald Coase (1996). "Law and Economics and A.W. Brian Simpson," The Journal of Legal Studies, v. 25, p. 103-104.
  3. ^ Kristoffel Grechenig & Martin Gelter, The Transatlantic Divergence in Legal Thought: American Law and Economics vs. German Doctrinalism, Hastings International and Comparative Law Review 2008, vol. 31, p. 295–360; Martin Gelter & Kristoffel Grechenig, History of Law and Economics, forthcoming in Encyclopedia on Law & Economics.
  4. ^ Hayek's journey: the mind of Friedrich Hayek by Alan Ebenstein, Palgrave Macmillan, 2003, pages 164–165. Retrieved November 10, 2022.
  5. ^ Kristoffel Grechenig & Martin Gelter, The Transatlantic Divergence in Legal Thought: American Law and Economics vs. German Doctrinalism, Hastings International and Comparative Law Review 2008, vol. 31, p. 295–360
  6. ^ Coase, Ronald (1960). "The Problem of Social Cost" (PDF). The Journal of Law and Economics. 3 (1): 1–44. doi:10.1086/466560. S2CID 222331226. This issue was actually published in 1961.
  7. ^ Calabresi, Guido (1961). "Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts". Yale Law Journal. 70 (4): 499–553. doi:10.2307/794261. JSTOR 794261.
  8. ^ Posner, Richard (1983). The Economics of Justice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. p. 4. ISBN 978-0-674-23525-0.
  9. ^ a b "Aaron Director, Founder of the field of Law and Economics". www-news.uchicago.edu. Retrieved 2019-09-04.
  10. ^ "Spotlight: Henry G. Manne ROBERT POOLE, Reason, May 1976. Retrieved October 7, 2022.
  11. ^ "Aaron Director". Mises Institute. 2014-06-20. Retrieved 2019-09-04.
  12. ^ "Ronald H. Coase". Econlib. Retrieved 2019-09-04.
  13. ^ "Swan Song of a Great Colossus: The Latest from Richard Posner". Law & Liberty. 2019-05-13. Retrieved 2019-09-25.
  14. ^ "Posner, Richard Allen". www.jewishvirtuallibrary.org. Retrieved 2019-09-25.
  15. ^ a b Gordon, Wendy J.; Marciano, Alain; Ramello, Giovanni B. (2019-08-01). "The future of law and economics and the legacy of Guido Calabresi". European Journal of Law and Economics. 48 (1): 1–8. doi:10.1007/s10657-019-09626-5. ISSN 1572-9990.
  16. ^ Stojanović, Aleksandar; Silvestri, Paolo (October 1, 2019). "The Road Not Taken – Reading Calabresi's "The Future of Law and Economics"". Global Jurist. 19 (3). doi:10.1515/gj-2019-0040. hdl:2318/1760860. S2CID 207894000 – via www.degruyter.com.
  17. ^ Litan, Robert (1988). Liability: Perspectives and Policy. Brookings Institution Press. ISBN 978-0-8157-5271-4.
  18. ^ "The Fourth Generation in Chicago". Economic Principals. 2014-11-16. Retrieved 2019-09-25.
  19. ^ Silvestri, Paolo (October 1, 2019). "On the (Methodological) Future of Law and Economics. The Uneasy Burden of Value Judgments and Normativity". Global Jurist. 19 (3). doi:10.1515/gj-2019-0026. hdl:2318/1760891. S2CID 207888412 – via www.degruyter.com.
  20. ^ "The Regressive Effect of Legal Uncertainty" Uri Weiss, Journal of Dispute Resolution, 2019, page 152. Retrieved October 23, 2022.
  21. ^ Becker, Gary (March 1, 1968), "Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach" (PDF), Journal of Political Economy, 76 (2): 169, doi:10.1086/259394
  22. ^ Posner, Richard (October 1985), "An Economic Theory of the Criminal Law", Columbia Law Review, 85 (6): 1193–1231, doi:10.2307/1122392, JSTOR 1122392
  23. ^ "Toward a Manifesto". LPE Project. Retrieved 2021-07-26.
  24. ^ Hart, Oliver (1995). "Corporate Governance: Some Theory and Implications". The Economic Journal. 105 (430): 678–689. doi:10.2307/2235027. ISSN 0013-0133. JSTOR 2235027.
  25. ^ La Porta, Rafael; Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio; Shleifer, Andrei; Vishny, Robert (2000-01-01). "Investor protection and corporate governance" (PDF). Journal of Financial Economics. Special Issue on International Corporate Governance. 58 (1): 3–27. doi:10.1016/S0304-405X(00)00065-9. ISSN 0304-405X.
  26. ^ Bebchuk, Lucian; Cohen, Alma; Ferrell, Allen (2009-02-01). "What Matters in Corporate Governance?". The Review of Financial Studies. 22 (2): 783–827. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhn099. ISSN 0893-9454.
  27. ^ Brown, Darryl K. (2004). "Cost-Benefit Analysis in Criminal Law". California Law Review. 92 (2): 323–372. doi:10.2307/3481427. ISSN 0008-1221. JSTOR 3481427.
  28. ^ Mueller, John; G, Stewart Mark (2014–2015). "Secret without Reason and Costly without Accomplishment: Questioning the National Security Agency's Metadata Program" (PDF). I/S: A Journal of Law and Policy for the Information Society. 10: 407.
  29. ^ Becker, Gary S. (1968). "Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach" (PDF). Journal of Political Economy. 76 (2): 169–217. doi:10.1086/259394. ISSN 0022-3808.
  30. ^ Levitt, Steven D (2004). "Understanding Why Crime Fell in the 1990s: Four Factors that Explain the Decline and Six that Do Not". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 18 (1): 163–190. doi:10.1257/089533004773563485. ISSN 0895-3309. S2CID 1403928.
  31. ^ Posner, Richard A. (1999). "An Economic Approach to the Law of Evidence". John M. Olin Law & Economics Working Paper No. 66. University of Chicago Law School.
  32. ^ Lempert, Richard (2001). "The Economic Analysis of Evidence Law: Common Sense on Stilts". Virginia Law Review. 87 (8): 1619–1712. doi:10.2307/1073903. ISSN 0042-6601. JSTOR 1073903.
  33. ^ Terrebonne, R. Peter (1981). "A Strictly Evolutionary Model of Common Law". The Journal of Legal Studies. 10 (2): 397–407. doi:10.1086/467688. ISSN 0047-2530. JSTOR 723986. S2CID 154112531.
  34. ^ Gennaioli, Nicola; Shleifer, Andrei (2007). "The Evolution of Common Law". Journal of Political Economy. 115 (1): 43–68. doi:10.1086/511996. ISSN 0022-3808. JSTOR 10.1086/511996. S2CID 38696030.
  35. ^ Friedman, Daniel (1998). "On economic applications of evolutionary game theory" (PDF). Journal of Evolutionary Economics. 8: 15–43. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.295.3014. doi:10.1007/s001910050054. S2CID 18758507.
  36. ^ Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-40599-7.
  37. ^ Demsetz, Harold (1967). "Toward a Theory of Property Rights". The American Economic Review. 57 (2): 347–359. ISSN 0002-8282. JSTOR 1821637.
  38. ^ Alchian, Armen A.; Demsetz, Harold (1973). "The Property Right Paradigm". The Journal of Economic History. 33 (1): 16–27. doi:10.1017/S0022050700076403. ISSN 0022-0507. JSTOR 2117138. S2CID 153392930.
  39. ^ Gostin, Lawrence (2006). "Public Health Strategies for Pandemic Influenza: Ethics and the Law". JAMA. 295 (14): 1700–1704. doi:10.1001/jama.295.14.1700. PMID 16609092.
  40. ^ Fidler, David P.; Gostin, Lawrence O.; Markel, Howard (2007). "Through the Quarantine Looking Glass: Drug‐Resistant Tuberculosis and Public Health Governance, Law, and Ethics". The Journal of Law, Medicine & Ethics. 35 (4): 616–628. doi:10.1111/j.1748-720X.2007.00185.x. PMID 18076513. S2CID 25081245.
  41. ^ "Modern Portfolio Theory". LII / Legal Information Institute. Cornell Law School. Retrieved 2019-12-23.
  42. ^ Glaeser, Edward L.; Luttmer, Erzo F. P. (2003). "The Misallocation of Housing Under Rent Control" (PDF). American Economic Review. 93 (4): 1027–1046. doi:10.1257/000282803769206188. ISSN 0002-8282. S2CID 153883166.
  43. ^ Diamond, Rebecca; McQuade, Tim; Qian, Franklin (2019). "The Effects of Rent Control Expansion on Tenants, Landlords, and Inequality: Evidence from San Francisco". American Economic Review. 109 (9): 3365–3394. doi:10.1257/aer.20181289. ISSN 0002-8282.
  44. ^ Krueger, Anne O. (1974). "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society". The American Economic Review. 64 (3): 291–303. ISSN 0002-8282. JSTOR 1808883.
  45. ^ Viscusi, W. Kip (1993). "The Value of Risks to Life and Health". Journal of Economic Literature. 31 (4): 1912–1946. ISSN 0022-0515. JSTOR 2728331.
  46. ^ Viscusi, W. Kip; Aldy, Joseph E. (2003-08-01). "The Value of a Statistical Life: A Critical Review of Market Estimates Throughout the World". Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 27 (1): 5–76. doi:10.1023/A:1025598106257. ISSN 1573-0476. S2CID 189928888.
  47. ^ Burness, H. Stuart; Quirk, James P. (1980). "Water Law, Water Transfers, and Economic Efficiency: The Colorado River" (PDF). The Journal of Law and Economics. 23 (1): 111–134. doi:10.1086/466954. ISSN 0022-2186. S2CID 153474147.
  48. ^ Johnson, Ronald N.; Gisser, Micha; Werner, Michael (1981). "The Definition of a Surface Water Right and Transferability". The Journal of Law and Economics. 24 (2): 273–288. doi:10.1086/466984. ISSN 0022-2186. S2CID 153338557.
  49. ^ Anthony T. Kronman, The Lost Lawyer 166 (1993).
  50. ^ Schlag, Pierre (2013-09-17). "Coase Minus the Coase Theorem – Some Problems with Chicago Transaction Cost Analysis". Rochester, NY: Social Science Research Network. SSRN 2320068. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  51. ^ The law and economics of development - Edgardo Buscaglia, William Ratliff and Robert Cooter Libraries, JAI Press, 1997, ISBN 0762301074
  52. ^ "Essays on Law and Economics". www.duncankennedy.net.
  53. ^ Hanson, Jon D. (2012). Hanson, Jon (ed.). Ideology, Psychology, and Law. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199737512.001.0001. ISBN 9780199918638.
  54. ^ a b Markovits, Richard (1998). Second-Best Theory and Law & Economics: An Introduction. Vol. 73. Chicago-Kent Law Review.
  55. ^ Cullerne Bown, William. (2022-12-23). "An epistemic theory of the criminal process, Part II: Packer, Posner and epistemic pressure". Law, Probability and Risk.
  56. ^ Baird, Douglas G.; Gertner, Robert H.; Picker, Randal C. (1998). Game Theory and the Law. Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674341111.
  57. ^ Jolls, Christine; Sunstein, Cass R.; Thaler, Richard (1997–1998). "A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics". Stanford Law Review. 50 (5): 1471. doi:10.2307/1229304. JSTOR 1229304.
  58. ^ Martin Gelter & Kristoffel Grechenig, History of Law and Economics, forthcoming in Encyclopedia on Law & Economics.
  59. ^ Alvarez, José E. (2018). "The Human Right of Property". University of Miami Law Review. 72: 580. SSRN 3150903.

Further reading

  • Kai Purnhagen Never the Twain Shall Meet? – A Critical Perspective on Cultural Limits Between Internal Continental Dogmatism and Consequential US-Style Law and Economics Theory in Klaus Mathis Law and Economics in Europe (Springer Science), pp. 3–21, available at [1]
  • Bouckaert, Boudewijn, and Gerrit De Geest, eds. (2000). Encyclopedia of Law and Economics (Edward Elgar, Online version.
  • Coase, Ronald (1990). The Firm, The Market, and the Law (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, reprint ed.) ISBN 0-226-11101-6.
  • Cooter, Robert and Thomas Ulen (2012). Law and Economics (Addison Wesley Longman, 6th edition). ISBN 0-321-33634-8
  • Friedman, David (1987). "law and economics," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 3, pp. 144–48.
  • _____ (2000). Law's Order. (Princeton University Press). Chapter links. links.
  • _____ (2001). Law's Order: What Economics Has to Do with Law and Why It Matters. ISBN 978-0691090092 .
  • Martin Gelter & Kristoffel Grechenig, History of Law and Economics, forthcoming in Encyclopedia on Law & Economics.
  • Georgakopoulos, Nicholas L. (2005). Principles and Methods of Law and Economics: Basic Tools for Normative Reasoning (Cambridge University Press, ISBN 0-521-82681-0).
  • Kristoffel Grechenig & Martin Gelter, The Transatlantic Divergence in Legal Thought: American Law and Economics vs. German Doctrinalism, Hastings International and Comparative Law Review 2008, vol. 31, pp. 295–360
  • Kennedy, Duncan (1998). "Law-and-Economics from the Perspective of Critical Legal Studies" (from The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law PDF
  • Kornhauser, Lewis (2006). "The Economic Analysis of Law," Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy.
  • Mestmäcker, Ernst-Joachim (2007). A Legal Theory without Law: Posner v. Hayek on Economic Analysis of Law. Tübingen: Mohr. ISBN 978-3-16-149276-1.
  • Mackaay, Ejan (2013), Law and Economics for Civil Law Systems, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, ISBN 978-1848443099; softcover forthcoming 2014 [2]
  • Mas-Colell, Andreu; Whinston, Michael D.; Green, Jerry R. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
  • Polinsky, A. Mitchell, and Steven Shavell (2008). "law, economic analysis of," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract and pre-publication copy.
  • Posner, Richard A. (2011). Economic Analysis of Law (New York, Wolters Kluwer Law & Business, 8th edition). ISBN 978-0735594425.
  • _____ (2006). "A Review of Steven Shavell's Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law," Journal of Economic Literature, 44(2), pp. 405–14[permanent dead link] (press +).
  • Schäfer, Hans-Bernd and Claus Ott (2004), “Economic Analysis of Civil Law”, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar Publishing; ISBN 1843762773
  • Shavell, Steven (2004). Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law. Harvard University Press. Description and scroll to chapter-preview links.
  • The Legal Structure of the Firm, Accounting, Economics, and Law: Vol. 1 : Iss. 1, Article 5, 2011. Jean-Philippe Robé
  • Viscusi, W. Kip; Vernon, John M.; Harrington Jr., Joseph E. (2005). Economics of Regulation and Antitrust. MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-28732-6.
  • Stojanovich A., Silvestri P. (Eds.), "Special Issue: On 'The Future of Law and Economics' by Guido Calabresi: An Interdisciplinary Dialogue", Global Jurist, 19(2019), 3.

External links

economics, economic, analysis, application, microeconomic, theory, analysis, which, emerged, primarily, from, scholars, chicago, school, economics, economic, concepts, used, explain, effects, laws, assess, which, legal, rules, economically, efficient, predict,. Law and economics or economic analysis of law is the application of microeconomic theory to the analysis of law which emerged primarily from scholars of the Chicago school of economics Economic concepts are used to explain the effects of laws to assess which legal rules are economically efficient and to predict which legal rules will be promulgated 1 There are two major branches of law and economics 2 one based on the application of the methods and theories of neoclassical economics to the positive and normative analysis of the law and a second branch which focuses on an institutional analysis of law and legal institutions with a broader focus on economic political and social outcomes and overlapping with analyses of the institutions of politics and governance Contents 1 History 1 1 Origin 1 2 Founding 1 3 Later development 2 Chicago School notable figures 3 Positive and normative law and economics 3 1 Positive law and economics 3 2 Normative law and economics 4 Criminal law 5 Relationship to other disciplines and approaches 6 Applications 7 Influence 8 Criticisms 8 1 Rational choice theory 8 2 Pareto efficiency 8 3 Criminal methodology 8 4 Responses to criticism 9 See also 10 References 11 Further reading 12 External linksHistory EditThis section needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Law and economics news newspapers books scholar JSTOR September 2022 Learn how and when to remove this template message Origin Edit The historical antecedents of law and economics can be traced back to the classical economists who are credited with the foundations of modern economic thought As early as the 18th century Adam Smith discussed the economic effects of mercantilist legislation later David Ricardo opposed the British Corn Laws on the grounds that they hindered agricultural productivity and Frederic Bastiat in his influential book The Law examined the unintended consequences of legislation However to apply economics to analyze the law regulating nonmarket activities is relatively new A European law amp economics movement around 1900 did not have any lasting influence 3 Harold Luhnow the head of the Volker Fund not only financed F A Hayek in the U S starting in 1946 but he shortly thereafter financed Aaron Director s coming to the University of Chicago in order to set up there a new center for scholars in law and economics The University was headed by Robert Maynard Hutchins a close collaborator of Luhnow s in setting up the Chicago School as it became commonly known The university faculty then included a strong base of libertarian scholars including Frank Knight George Stigler Henry Simons Ronald Coase and Jacob Viner 4 Soon it would also have not just Hayek himself but Director s brother in law and Stigler s friend Milton Friedman and also Robert Fogel Robert Lucas Eugene Fama Richard Posner and Gary Becker Historians Robert van Horn and Philip Mirowski described the development of modern economic concepts in The Rise of the Chicago School of Economics a chapter of The Road from Mont Pelerin 2009 and historian Bruce Caldwell a great admirer of von Hayek filled in more details of the account in his chapter The Chicago School Hayek and Neoliberalism in Building Chicago Economics 2011 The field began with Gary Becker s 1968 paper on crime Becker also received a Nobel Prize In 1972 Richard Posner a law and economics scholar and the major advocate of the positive theory of efficiency published the first edition of Economic Analysis of Law and founded The Journal of Legal Studies both are regarded as important events Gordon Tullock and Friedrich Hayek also wrote intensively in the area and influenced to spread of law and economics Founding Edit In 1958 Director founded The Journal of Law amp Economics which he co edited with Nobel laureate Ronald Coase and which helped to unite the fields of law and economics with far reaching influence 5 In 1960 and 1961 Ronald Coase and Guido Calabresi independently published two groundbreaking articles The Problem of Social Cost 6 and Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts 7 This can be seen as the starting point for the modern school of law and economics 8 In 1962 Aaron Director helped to found the Committee on a Free Society Director s appointment to the faculty of the University of Chicago Law School in 1946 began a half century of intellectual productivity although his reluctance about publishing left few writings behind 9 He taught antitrust courses at the law school with Edward Levi who eventually would serve as Dean of Chicago s Law School President of the University of Chicago and as U S Attorney General in the Ford administration After retiring from the University of Chicago Law School in 1965 Director relocated to California and took a position at Stanford University s Hoover Institution He died September 11 2004 at his home in Los Altos Hills California ten days before his 103rd birthday Later development Edit In the early 1970s Henry Manne a former student of Coase set out to build a center for law and economics at a major law school He began at the University of Rochester worked at the University of Miami but was soon made unwelcome moved to Emory University and ended up at George Mason 10 The last soon became a center for the education of judges many long out of law school and never exposed to numbers and economics Manne also attracted the support of the John M Olin Foundation whose support accelerated the movement Today Olin centers or programs for Law and Economics exist at many universities Chicago School notable figures EditModern forerunners of economic thought developed at the Chicago School include Adam Smith David Ricardo and Frederic Bastiat Founders include Aaron Director University of Chicago 9 11 Ronald Coase University of Chicago 1991 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences 12 Richard Posner University of Chicago 13 14 Guido Calabresi Yale University 15 16 Calabresi judge for the U S Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit wrote in depth on this subject his book The Costs of Accidents A Legal and Economic Analysis 1970 has been cited as influential in its extensive treatment of the proper incentives and compensation required in accident situations 17 Calabresi took a different approach in Ideals Beliefs Attitudes and the Law 1985 where he argued who is the cheapest avoider of a cost depends on the valuations put on acts activities and beliefs by the whole of our law and not on some objective or scientific notion 69 Henry Manne George Mason University 15 Other notable individuals include Gary Becker Nobel Memorial Prize winning economist and a leader of the Chicago School of Economics 18 Frank Easterbrook U S Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit judge Andrei Shleifer Robert Cooter Harold Demsetz Hans Bernd Schafer William Landes W Kip Viscusi A Mitchell Polinsky Michael TrebilcockPositive and normative law and economics EditEconomic analysis of law is usually divided into two subfields positive and normative Positive law and economics Edit Positive law and economics uses economic analysis to predict the effects of various legal rules So for example a positive economic analysis of tort law would predict the effects of a strict liability rule as opposed to the effects of a negligence rule Positive law and economics has also at times purported to explain the development of legal rules for example the common law of torts in terms of their economic efficiency Normative law and economics Edit Normative law and economics goes one step further and makes policy recommendations based on the economic consequences of various policies The key concept for normative economic analysis is efficiency in particular allocative efficiency A common concept of efficiency used by law and economics scholars is Pareto efficiency A legal rule is Pareto efficient if it could not be changed so as to make one person better off without making another person worse off A weaker conception of efficiency is Kaldor Hicks efficiency A legal rule is Kaldor Hicks efficient if it could be made Pareto efficient by some parties compensating others as to offset their loss Nonetheless the possibility of a clear distinction between positive and normative analysis has been questioned by Guido Calabresi who in his book on The future of Law and Economics 2016 21 22 believes that there is an actual and unavoidable existence of value judgments underlying much economic analysis 19 Uri Weiss proposed this alternative It is common in law and economics to search for the law that will lead to the optimal outcome providing the maximum size pie and to think about maximizing happiness instead of minimizing pain We prefer another approach We do not try to identify games that will lead to the optimal result but to prevent games in which it is in the best interests of the players to come to an unjust result 20 Criminal law EditIn 1968 Gary Becker who would later win the Nobel prize for economics published Crime and Punishment An Economic Approach 21 This work relied on the economic concept of utility as the basic unit of analysis In 1985 in An Economic Theory of the Criminal Law Posner set out an alternative approach that relied instead on wealth as the basic unit of analysis 22 Relationship to other disciplines and approaches EditAs used by lawyers and legal scholars the phrase law and economics refers to the application of microeconomic analysis to legal problems Because of the overlap between legal systems and political systems some of the issues in law and economics are also raised in political economy constitutional economics and political science Approaches to the same issues from Marxist and critical theory Frankfurt School perspectives usually do not identify themselves as law and economics For example research by members of the critical legal studies movement and the sociology of law considers many of the same fundamental issues as does work labeled law and economics though from a vastly different perspective The law and political economy movement also analyzes similar concepts using an entirely different approach 23 The one wing that represents a non neoclassical approach to law and economics is the Continental mainly German tradition that sees the concept starting out of the governance and public policy Staatswissenschaften approach and the German Historical school of economics this view is represented in the Elgar Companion to Law and Economics 2nd ed 2005 and though not exclusively in the European Journal of Law and Economics Here consciously non neoclassical approaches to economics are used for the analysis of legal and administrative governance problems Law and economics is closely related to jurimetrics the application of probability and statistics to legal questions Applications EditAffirmative action Coate Loury model Antitrust law Herfindahl Hirschman Index Calculus of negligence Congestion pricing Corporate governance 24 25 26 Cost benefit analysis Criminal law 27 Mass surveillance in the United States 28 Surveillance Crime enforcement 29 30 Deregulation Airlines communications energy surface freight Design of contracts Contract theory Efficient breach Discrimination Statistical discrimination economics Drug policy Iron law of prohibition Evidence 31 32 Evolution of the common law 33 34 Evolutionary game theory 35 Financial regulation Efficient market hypothesis Fraud on the market theory Governance of the commons 36 Tragedy of the commons Institutional origins The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development An Empirical Investigation Constitutional economics Legal origins theory Property rights 37 38 Intellectual property Economics and patents Natural monopoly regulation Averch Johnson effect Peltzman effect Principal agent problem Adverse selection Moral hazard Quarantine measures for public health 39 40 Prudent investor rule 41 Modern portfolio theory Rent control 42 43 Rent seeking 44 Transaction costs Coase theorem Value of a statistical life 45 46 Voting systems Social choice theory Water law 47 48 Influence EditThe economic analysis of law has been influential in the United States as well as elsewhere Judicial opinions use economic analysis and the theories of law and economics with some regularity in the US but also increasingly in Commonwealth countries and in Europe The influence of law and economics has also been felt in legal education with graduate programs in the subject being offered in a number of countries The influence of law and economics in civil law countries may be gauged from the availability of textbooks of law and economics in English as well as in other European languages Schafer and Ott 2004 Mackaay 2013 Many law schools in North America Europe and Asia have faculty members with a graduate degree in economics In addition many professional economists now study and write on the relationship between economics and legal doctrines Anthony Kronman former dean of Yale Law School has written that the intellectual movement that has had the greatest influence on American academic law in the past quarter century of the 20th Century is law and economics 49 Criticisms EditDespite its influence the law and economics movement has been criticized from a number of directions This is especially true of normative law and economics Because most law and economics scholarship operates within a neoclassical framework fundamental criticisms of neoclassical economics have been drawn from other competing frameworks though there are numerous internal critiques as well 50 Yet other schools of economic thought have emerged and have been applied to the work of law and economics in for example the work of Edgardo Buscaglia and Robert Cooter in the book Law and Economics of Development 51 Rational choice theory Edit Critics of the economic analysis of legal questions have argued that normative economic analysis does not capture the importance of human rights and concerns for distributive justice Some of the heaviest criticisms of law and economics come from the critical legal studies movement in particular Duncan Kennedy 52 and Mark Kelman Jon D Hanson of Harvard Law School argues that our legal economic political and social systems are unduly influenced by an individualistic model of behavior based on preferences instead of a model that incorporates cognitive biases and social norms 53 Pareto efficiency Edit Additional criticism has been directed toward the assumed benefits of law and policy designed to increase allocative efficiency when such assumptions are modeled on first best Pareto optimal general equilibrium conditions Under the theory of the second best for example if the fulfillment of a subset of optimal conditions cannot be met under any circumstances it is incorrect to conclude that the fulfillment of any subset of optimal conditions will necessarily result in an increase in allocative efficiency 54 Consequently any expression of public policy whose purported purpose is an unambiguous increase in allocative efficiency for example consolidation of research and development costs through increased mergers and acquisitions resulting from a systematic relaxation of antitrust laws is according to critics fundamentally incorrect as there is no general reason to conclude that an increase in allocative efficiency is more likely than a decrease Essentially the first best neoclassical analysis fails to properly account for various kinds of general equilibrium feedback relationships that result from intrinsic Pareto imperfections 54 Another critique comes from the fact that there is no unique optimal result Warren Samuels in his 2007 book The Legal Economic Nexus argues efficiency in the Pareto sense cannot dispositively be applied to the definition and assignment of rights themselves because efficiency requires an antecedent determination of the rights 23 4 Criminal methodology Edit Cullerne Bown has criticised Posner s approach on methodological grounds He concludes that Posner s approach to evaluating policies in the criminal process is methodologically invalid and that these failings in turn make the entirety of his conclusions on the criminal process unreliable 55 Responses to criticism Edit Law and economics has adapted to some of these criticisms and been developed in a variety of directions One important trend has been the application of game theory to legal problems 56 Other developments have been the incorporation of behavioral economics into economic analysis of law 57 and the increasing use of statistical and econometrics techniques 58 Within the legal academy the term socio economics has been applied to economic approaches that are self consciously broader than the neoclassical tradition Property rights which are analyzed using economic analysis are seen as fundamental human rights by defenders of law and economics 59 See also EditCompetition policy Contract theory Constitutionalism Constitutional economics Cost benefit analysis Economic imperialism economics Economics Iron law of prohibition Islamic economical jurisprudence Jurimetrics Legal origins theory Legal theory Microeconomics New institutional economics Occupational licensing Political economy Property rights economics Public choice theoryReferences Edit David Friedman 1987 law and economics The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics v 3 p 144 Ronald Coase 1996 Law and Economics and A W Brian Simpson The Journal of Legal Studies v 25 p 103 104 Kristoffel Grechenig amp Martin Gelter The Transatlantic Divergence in Legal Thought American Law and Economics vs German Doctrinalism Hastings International and Comparative Law Review 2008 vol 31 p 295 360 Martin Gelter amp Kristoffel Grechenig History of Law and Economics forthcoming in Encyclopedia on Law amp Economics Hayek s journey the mind of Friedrich Hayek by Alan Ebenstein Palgrave Macmillan 2003 pages 164 165 Retrieved November 10 2022 Kristoffel Grechenig amp Martin Gelter The Transatlantic Divergence in Legal Thought American Law and Economics vs German Doctrinalism Hastings International and Comparative Law Review 2008 vol 31 p 295 360 Coase Ronald 1960 The Problem of Social Cost PDF The Journal of Law and Economics 3 1 1 44 doi 10 1086 466560 S2CID 222331226 This issue was actually published in 1961 Calabresi Guido 1961 Some Thoughts on Risk Distribution and the Law of Torts Yale Law Journal 70 4 499 553 doi 10 2307 794261 JSTOR 794261 Posner Richard 1983 The Economics of Justice Cambridge Harvard University Press p 4 ISBN 978 0 674 23525 0 a b Aaron Director Founder of the field of Law and Economics www news uchicago edu Retrieved 2019 09 04 Spotlight Henry G Manne ROBERT POOLE Reason May 1976 Retrieved October 7 2022 Aaron Director Mises Institute 2014 06 20 Retrieved 2019 09 04 Ronald H Coase Econlib Retrieved 2019 09 04 Swan Song of a Great Colossus The Latest from Richard Posner Law amp Liberty 2019 05 13 Retrieved 2019 09 25 Posner Richard Allen www jewishvirtuallibrary org Retrieved 2019 09 25 a b Gordon Wendy J Marciano Alain Ramello Giovanni B 2019 08 01 The future of law and economics and the legacy of Guido Calabresi European Journal of Law and Economics 48 1 1 8 doi 10 1007 s10657 019 09626 5 ISSN 1572 9990 Stojanovic Aleksandar Silvestri Paolo October 1 2019 The Road Not Taken Reading Calabresi s The Future of Law and Economics Global Jurist 19 3 doi 10 1515 gj 2019 0040 hdl 2318 1760860 S2CID 207894000 via www degruyter com Litan Robert 1988 Liability Perspectives and Policy Brookings Institution Press ISBN 978 0 8157 5271 4 The Fourth Generation in Chicago Economic Principals 2014 11 16 Retrieved 2019 09 25 Silvestri Paolo October 1 2019 On the Methodological Future of Law and Economics The Uneasy Burden of Value Judgments and Normativity Global Jurist 19 3 doi 10 1515 gj 2019 0026 hdl 2318 1760891 S2CID 207888412 via www degruyter com The Regressive Effect of Legal Uncertainty Uri Weiss Journal of Dispute Resolution 2019 page 152 Retrieved October 23 2022 Becker Gary March 1 1968 Crime and Punishment An Economic Approach PDF Journal of Political Economy 76 2 169 doi 10 1086 259394 Posner Richard October 1985 An Economic Theory of the Criminal Law Columbia Law Review 85 6 1193 1231 doi 10 2307 1122392 JSTOR 1122392 Toward a Manifesto LPE Project Retrieved 2021 07 26 Hart Oliver 1995 Corporate Governance Some Theory and Implications The Economic Journal 105 430 678 689 doi 10 2307 2235027 ISSN 0013 0133 JSTOR 2235027 La Porta Rafael Lopez de Silanes Florencio Shleifer Andrei Vishny Robert 2000 01 01 Investor protection and corporate governance PDF Journal of Financial Economics Special Issue on International Corporate Governance 58 1 3 27 doi 10 1016 S0304 405X 00 00065 9 ISSN 0304 405X Bebchuk Lucian Cohen Alma Ferrell Allen 2009 02 01 What Matters in Corporate Governance The Review of Financial Studies 22 2 783 827 doi 10 1093 rfs hhn099 ISSN 0893 9454 Brown Darryl K 2004 Cost Benefit Analysis in Criminal Law California Law Review 92 2 323 372 doi 10 2307 3481427 ISSN 0008 1221 JSTOR 3481427 Mueller John G Stewart Mark 2014 2015 Secret without Reason and Costly without Accomplishment Questioning the National Security Agency s Metadata Program PDF I S A Journal of Law and Policy for the Information Society 10 407 Becker Gary S 1968 Crime and Punishment An Economic Approach PDF Journal of Political Economy 76 2 169 217 doi 10 1086 259394 ISSN 0022 3808 Levitt Steven D 2004 Understanding Why Crime Fell in the 1990s Four Factors that Explain the Decline and Six that Do Not Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 1 163 190 doi 10 1257 089533004773563485 ISSN 0895 3309 S2CID 1403928 Posner Richard A 1999 An Economic Approach to the Law of Evidence John M Olin Law amp Economics Working Paper No 66 University of Chicago Law School Lempert Richard 2001 The Economic Analysis of Evidence Law Common Sense on Stilts Virginia Law Review 87 8 1619 1712 doi 10 2307 1073903 ISSN 0042 6601 JSTOR 1073903 Terrebonne R Peter 1981 A Strictly Evolutionary Model of Common Law The Journal of Legal Studies 10 2 397 407 doi 10 1086 467688 ISSN 0047 2530 JSTOR 723986 S2CID 154112531 Gennaioli Nicola Shleifer Andrei 2007 The Evolution of Common Law Journal of Political Economy 115 1 43 68 doi 10 1086 511996 ISSN 0022 3808 JSTOR 10 1086 511996 S2CID 38696030 Friedman Daniel 1998 On economic applications of evolutionary game theory PDF Journal of Evolutionary Economics 8 15 43 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 295 3014 doi 10 1007 s001910050054 S2CID 18758507 Ostrom Elinor 1990 Governing the Commons The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action Cambridge UK Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 40599 7 Demsetz Harold 1967 Toward a Theory of Property Rights The American Economic Review 57 2 347 359 ISSN 0002 8282 JSTOR 1821637 Alchian Armen A Demsetz Harold 1973 The Property Right Paradigm The Journal of Economic History 33 1 16 27 doi 10 1017 S0022050700076403 ISSN 0022 0507 JSTOR 2117138 S2CID 153392930 Gostin Lawrence 2006 Public Health Strategies for Pandemic Influenza Ethics and the Law JAMA 295 14 1700 1704 doi 10 1001 jama 295 14 1700 PMID 16609092 Fidler David P Gostin Lawrence O Markel Howard 2007 Through the Quarantine Looking Glass Drug Resistant Tuberculosis and Public Health Governance Law and Ethics The Journal of Law Medicine amp Ethics 35 4 616 628 doi 10 1111 j 1748 720X 2007 00185 x PMID 18076513 S2CID 25081245 Modern Portfolio Theory LII Legal Information Institute Cornell Law School Retrieved 2019 12 23 Glaeser Edward L Luttmer Erzo F P 2003 The Misallocation of Housing Under Rent Control PDF American Economic Review 93 4 1027 1046 doi 10 1257 000282803769206188 ISSN 0002 8282 S2CID 153883166 Diamond Rebecca McQuade Tim Qian Franklin 2019 The Effects of Rent Control Expansion on Tenants Landlords and Inequality Evidence from San Francisco American Economic Review 109 9 3365 3394 doi 10 1257 aer 20181289 ISSN 0002 8282 Krueger Anne O 1974 The Political Economy of the Rent Seeking Society The American Economic Review 64 3 291 303 ISSN 0002 8282 JSTOR 1808883 Viscusi W Kip 1993 The Value of Risks to Life and Health Journal of Economic Literature 31 4 1912 1946 ISSN 0022 0515 JSTOR 2728331 Viscusi W Kip Aldy Joseph E 2003 08 01 The Value of a Statistical Life A Critical Review of Market Estimates Throughout the World Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 27 1 5 76 doi 10 1023 A 1025598106257 ISSN 1573 0476 S2CID 189928888 Burness H Stuart Quirk James P 1980 Water Law Water Transfers and Economic Efficiency The Colorado River PDF The Journal of Law and Economics 23 1 111 134 doi 10 1086 466954 ISSN 0022 2186 S2CID 153474147 Johnson Ronald N Gisser Micha Werner Michael 1981 The Definition of a Surface Water Right and Transferability The Journal of Law and Economics 24 2 273 288 doi 10 1086 466984 ISSN 0022 2186 S2CID 153338557 Anthony T Kronman The Lost Lawyer 166 1993 Schlag Pierre 2013 09 17 Coase Minus the Coase Theorem Some Problems with Chicago Transaction Cost Analysis Rochester NY Social Science Research Network SSRN 2320068 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help The law and economics of development Edgardo Buscaglia William Ratliff and Robert Cooter Libraries JAI Press 1997 ISBN 0762301074 Essays on Law and Economics www duncankennedy net Hanson Jon D 2012 Hanson Jon ed Ideology Psychology and Law Oxford UK Oxford University Press doi 10 1093 acprof oso 9780199737512 001 0001 ISBN 9780199918638 a b Markovits Richard 1998 Second Best Theory and Law amp Economics An Introduction Vol 73 Chicago Kent Law Review Cullerne Bown William 2022 12 23 An epistemic theory of the criminal process Part II Packer Posner and epistemic pressure Law Probability and Risk Baird Douglas G Gertner Robert H Picker Randal C 1998 Game Theory and the Law Harvard University Press ISBN 9780674341111 Jolls Christine Sunstein Cass R Thaler Richard 1997 1998 A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics Stanford Law Review 50 5 1471 doi 10 2307 1229304 JSTOR 1229304 Martin Gelter amp Kristoffel Grechenig History of Law and Economics forthcoming in Encyclopedia on Law amp Economics Alvarez Jose E 2018 The Human Right of Property University of Miami Law Review 72 580 SSRN 3150903 Further reading EditKai Purnhagen Never the Twain Shall Meet A Critical Perspective on Cultural Limits Between Internal Continental Dogmatism and Consequential US Style Law and Economics Theory in Klaus Mathis Law and Economics in Europe Springer Science pp 3 21 available at 1 Bouckaert Boudewijn and Gerrit De Geest eds 2000 Encyclopedia of Law and Economics Edward Elgar Online version Coase Ronald 1990 The Firm The Market and the Law Chicago University of Chicago Press reprint ed ISBN 0 226 11101 6 Cooter Robert and Thomas Ulen 2012 Law and Economics Addison Wesley Longman 6th edition ISBN 0 321 33634 8 Friedman David 1987 law and economics The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics v 3 pp 144 48 2000 Law s Order Princeton University Press Chapter links links 2001 Law s Order What Economics Has to Do with Law and Why It Matters ISBN 978 0691090092 Martin Gelter amp Kristoffel Grechenig History of Law and Economics forthcoming in Encyclopedia on Law amp Economics Georgakopoulos Nicholas L 2005 Principles and Methods of Law and Economics Basic Tools for Normative Reasoning Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 82681 0 Kristoffel Grechenig amp Martin Gelter The Transatlantic Divergence in Legal Thought American Law and Economics vs German Doctrinalism Hastings International and Comparative Law Review 2008 vol 31 pp 295 360 Kennedy Duncan 1998 Law and Economics from the Perspective of Critical Legal Studies from The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law PDF Kornhauser Lewis 2006 The Economic Analysis of Law Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy Mestmacker Ernst Joachim 2007 A Legal Theory without Law Posner v Hayek on Economic Analysis of Law Tubingen Mohr ISBN 978 3 16 149276 1 Mackaay Ejan 2013 Law and Economics for Civil Law Systems Cheltenham Edward Elgar ISBN 978 1848443099 softcover forthcoming 2014 2 Mas Colell Andreu Whinston Michael D Green Jerry R 1995 Microeconomic Theory New York NY Oxford University Press Polinsky A Mitchell and Steven Shavell 2008 law economic analysis of The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract and pre publication copy Posner Richard A 2011 Economic Analysis of Law New York Wolters Kluwer Law amp Business 8th edition ISBN 978 0735594425 2006 A Review of Steven Shavell s Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law Journal of Economic Literature 44 2 pp 405 14 permanent dead link press Schafer Hans Bernd and Claus Ott 2004 Economic Analysis of Civil Law Cheltenham Edward Elgar Publishing ISBN 1843762773 Shavell Steven 2004 Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law Harvard University Press Description and scroll to chapter preview links Robe Jean Philippe The Legal Structure of the Firm Accounting Economics and Law Vol 1 Iss 1 Article 5 2011 Jean Philippe Robe Viscusi W Kip Vernon John M Harrington Jr Joseph E 2005 Economics of Regulation and Antitrust MIT Press ISBN 978 0 262 28732 6 Stojanovich A Silvestri P Eds Special Issue On The Future of Law and Economics by Guido Calabresi An Interdisciplinary Dialogue Global Jurist 19 2019 3 External links Edit Law and Economics article in the Internet Encyclopedia of Philosophy Law amp Economics LAB Paper describing the effects of law and economics on inequality Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Law and economics amp oldid 1149087137, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.