fbpx
Wikipedia

Mainstream economics

Mainstream economics is the body of knowledge, theories, and models of economics, as taught by universities worldwide, that are generally accepted by economists as a basis for discussion. Also known as orthodox economics, it can be contrasted to heterodox economics, which encompasses various schools or approaches that are only accepted by a minority of economists.

The economics profession has traditionally been associated with neoclassical economics.[1] However, this association has been challenged by prominent historians of economic thought including David Colander.[2] They argue the current economic mainstream theories, such as game theory, behavioral economics, industrial organization, information economics, and the like, share very little common ground with the initial axioms of neoclassical economics.

History edit

Economics has always featured multiple schools of economic thought, with different schools having different prominence across countries and over time.[3]

Prior to the development and prevalence of classical economics, the dominant school in Europe was mercantilism, which was rather a loose set of related ideas than an institutionalized school. With the development of modern economics, conventionally given as the late 18th-century The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith, British economics developed and became dominated by what is now called the classical school. From The Wealth of Nations until the Great Depression, the dominant school within the English-speaking world was classical economics, and its successor, neoclassical economics.[a][citation needed] In continental Europe, the earlier work of the physiocrats in France formed a distinct tradition, as did the later work of the historical school of economics in Germany, and throughout the 19th century there were debates in British economics, notably the opposition underconsumptionist school.

During the Great Depression, the school of Keynesian economics gained attention as older models were neither able to explain the causes of the Depression nor provide solutions.[4] It built on the work of the underconsumptionist school, and gained prominence as part of the neoclassical synthesis, which was the post–World War II merger of Keynesian macroeconomics and neoclassical microeconomics that prevailed from the 1950s until the 1970s.[5]

In the 1970s, the consensus in macroeconomics collapsed as a result of the failure of the neoclassical synthesis to explain the phenomenon of stagflation:[6] subsequent to this, two schools of thought in the field emerged: New Keynesianism and New classical macroeconomics. Both sought to rebuild macroeconomics using microfoundations to explain macroeconomic phenomena using microeconomics.[7]

Over the course of the 1980s and the 1990s, macroeconomists coalesced around a paradigm known as the new neoclassical synthesis,[8] which combines elements of both New Keynesian and New classical macroeconomics, and forms the basis for the current consensus, which covers previously disputed areas of macroeconomics.[which?][9][10] The consensus built around this synthesis is characterised by an unprecedented agreement on methodological questions (such as the need to validate models econometrically); such agreement had, until the new synthesis, historically eluded macroeconomics, even during the neoclassical synthesis.[11]

The financial crisis of 2007–2010 and the ensuing global economic crisis exposed modelling failures in the field of short-term macroeconomics.[12] While most macroeconomists had predicted the burst of the housing bubble, according to The Economist "they did not expect the financial system to break."[13]

Term edit

The term "mainstream economics" came into use in the late 20th century. It appeared in 2001 edition of the textbook Economics by Samuelson and Nordhaus on the inside back cover in the "Family Tree of Economics", which depicts arrows into "Modern Mainstream Economics" from Keynes (1936) and neoclassical economics (1860–1910).[14] The term "neoclassical synthesis" itself also first appears in the 1955 edition of Samuelson's textbook.[15]

Scope edit

Mainstream economics can be defined, as distinct from other schools of economics, by various criteria, notably by its assumptions, its methods and its topics.

Assumptions edit

While being long rejected by many heterodox schools, several assumptions used to underpin many mainstream economic models. These include the neoclassical assumptions of rational choice theory, a representative agent, and, often, rational expectations. However, much of modern economic mainstream modeling consists of exploring the effects that complicating factors have on models, such as imperfect and asymmetric information, bounded rationality, incomplete markets, imperfect competition, heterogeneous agents[16] and transaction costs.[17]

Originally, the starting point of orthodox economic analysis was the individual. Individuals and firms were generally defined as units with a common goal: maximisation through rational behaviour. The only differences consisted of:

  • the specific objective of the maximisation (individuals tend to maximise utility and firms profit);[18]
  • and the constraints faced in the process of maximisation (individuals might be constrained by limited income or commodity prices and firms might be constrained by technology or availability of inputs).[18]

From this (descriptive) theoretical framework, neoclassical economists like Alfred Marshall often derived – although not systematically – the political prescription that political action should not be used to solve the problems of the economic system. Instead, the solution ought to derive from an intervention on the above-mentioned maximisation objectives and constraints. It is in this context that economic capitalism finds its justification.[19] Yet, mainstream economics now includes descriptive theories of market and government failure and private and public goods. These developments suggest a range of views on the desirability or otherwise of government intervention, from a more normative perspective.[citation needed]

Methods edit

Some economic fields include elements of both mainstream economics and heterodox economics: for example, institutional economics, neuroeconomics, and non-linear complexity theory.[20] They may use neoclassical economics as a point of departure. At least one institutionalist, John Davis, has argued that "neoclassical economics no longer dominates a mainstream economics."[21]

Topics edit

Economics has been initially shaped as a discipline concerned with a range of issues revolving around money and wealth. However, in the 1930s, mainstream economics began to mutate into a science of human decision. In 1931, Lionel Robbins famously wrote "Economics is the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses". This drew a line of demarcation between mainstream economics and other disciplines and schools studying the economy.[22]

The mainstream approach of economics as a science of decision-making contributed to enlarge the scope of the discipline. Economists like Gary Becker began to study seemingly distant fields including crime,[23] the family,[24] law,[25] politics,[25] and religion.[26] This expansion is sometimes referred to as economic imperialism.[27]

Notes edit

  1. ^ The precise distinction and relationship between classical economics and neoclassical economics is a debated point. Suffice to say that these are the ex post facto terms used to refer to successive chronological periods of an interrelated group of theories.

References edit

Footnotes edit

Works cited edit

  • Blanchard, Olivier Jean (11 November 2016) [Originally published in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (1987)]. "Neoclassical Synthesis". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK. pp. 1–5. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_1218-1. ISBN 978-1-349-95121-5. Retrieved 30 August 2023.
  • Boettke, Peter; Leeson, Peter (1 January 2003). "The Austrian School of Economics: 1950–2000" (PDF). In Samuels, Warren J.; Biddle, Jeff E.; Davis, John Bryan (eds.). A Companion to the History of Economic Thought. Malden, Massachusetts: Blackwell Publishing. doi:10.1002/9780470999059. ISBN 978-0-631-22573-7.
  • Clark, Barry Stewart (1998). Political economy: a comparative approach (2 ed.). Westport, Connecticut: Praeger. ISBN 978-0-275-96370-5.
  • Colander, David (2000a). Colander, David (ed.). Complexity and the history of economic thought. London: Routledge. ISBN 978-0-415-13356-2. OCLC 51977344.
  • Colander, David; Holt, Richard P. F.; Rosser, Barkley J. Jr. (November 2003). "The Changing Face of Mainstream Economics" (PDF). Review of Political Economy. 16 (4): 485–499. doi:10.1080/0953825042000256702. S2CID 35411709.
  • Colander, David (June 2000b). "The Death of Neoclassical Economics". Journal of the History of Economic Thought. 22 (2): 127–143. doi:10.1080/10427710050025330. ISSN 1053-8372. S2CID 154275191.
  • Davis, John B. (1 April 2006). "The turn in economics: neoclassical dominance to mainstream pluralism?". Journal of Institutional Economics. 2 (1): 1–20. doi:10.1017/S1744137405000263. ISSN 1744-1382. S2CID 37162943. from the original on 3 July 2023. Retrieved 1 September 2023.
  • Dequech, David (1 December 2007). "Neoclassical, Mainstream, Orthodox, and Heterodox Economics" (PDF). Journal of Post Keynesian Economics. 30 (2): 279–302. doi:10.2753/PKE0160-3477300207. ISSN 0160-3477. JSTOR 27746799. S2CID 153773877. (PDF) from the original on 12 August 2017.
  • Goodfriend, Marvin; King, Robert G (1997). "The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy". NBER Macroeconomics Annual. NBER Chapters. 12: 231–283. doi:10.1086/654336. JSTOR 3585232.
  • Himmelweit, Sue (17 March 1997). "Chapter 2: The individual as the basic unit of analysis". In Green, Francis; Nore, Peter (eds.). Economics: An Anti-text. London: MacMillan. doi:10.1007/978-1-349-15751-8. ISBN 9780765639233. Retrieved 30 August 2023.
  • Jahan, Sarwat; Mahmud, Ahmed Saber; Papageorgiou, Chris (September 2014). Hayden, Jeffrey; Primorac, Marina; et al. (eds.). "What Is Keynesian Economics?" (PDF). Finance & Development. Vol. 51, no. 3. International Monetary Fund. ISSN 0015-1947. Retrieved 9 September 2023.
  • Jelveh, Zubin; Kogut, Bruce; Naidu, Suresh (13 December 2022). "Political Language in Economics". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2535453. ISSN 1556-5068. S2CID 15818467. SSRN 2535453. Retrieved 1 September 2023.
  • Kaplan, Greg; Moll, Benjamin; Violante, Giovanni L. (1 March 2018). "Monetary Policy According to HANK". American Economic Review. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. 108 (3): 697–743. doi:10.1257/aer.20160042. ISSN 0002-8282. JSTOR 26527936. S2CID 31927674.
  • Kocherlakota, Narayana (4 May 2010). "Modern Macroeconomic Models as Tools for Economic Policy". Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. S2CID 154126343. Retrieved 26 November 2023.
  • Krugman, Paul (2 September 2009). "How did economists get it so wrong?". The New York Times Magazine. from the original on 24 May 2023. Retrieved 30 August 2023.
  • Lazear, Edward P. (July 1999). "Economic Imperialism" (PDF). The Quarterly Journal of Economics (published August 1999). 115 (1): 99–146. doi:10.1162/003355300554683. JSTOR 2586936. (PDF) from the original on 30 May 2023. Retrieved 1 September 2023.
  • Mankiw, N. Gregory (1 August 2006). "The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 20 (4): 29–46. doi:10.1257/jep.20.4.29. ISSN 0895-3309.
  • "The other-worldly philosophers". The Economist. 18 July 2009. ISSN 0013-0613.
  • Rotemberg, Julio J. (January 1987). "The New Keynesian Microfoundations". NBER Macroeconomics Annual. 2: 69–104. doi:10.1086/ma.2.4623707. hdl:1721.1/48619. ISSN 0889-3365. S2CID 154005964.
  • Samuelson, Paul A.; Nordhaus, William D. (2001). Economics (17 ed.). Richard D. Irwin, Inc. ISBN 9780072509144.
  • Schäfer, Georg N.; Schuster, Sören E. (7 June 2022). Mapping Mainstream Economics: Genealogical Foundations of Alternativity (1 ed.). London: Routledge. doi:10.4324/9781003287148. ISBN 978-1-003-28714-8. S2CID 249488205.
  • Snowdon, Brian; Vane, Howard R. (2006). Modern macroeconomics: its origins, development and current state (PDF) (Reprinted Paperback ed.). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing. ISBN 978-1-84542-208-0. (PDF) from the original on 30 April 2021. Retrieved 29 August 2023.
  • Woodford, Michael (January 2009). "Convergence in Macroeconomics: Elements of the New Synthesis" (PDF). American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics. 1 (1): 267–279. doi:10.1257/mac.1.1.267. ISSN 1945-7707. JSTOR 25760267. (PDF) from the original on 31 March 2023. Retrieved 30 August 2023.

mainstream, economics, body, knowledge, theories, models, economics, taught, universities, worldwide, that, generally, accepted, economists, basis, discussion, also, known, orthodox, economics, contrasted, heterodox, economics, which, encompasses, various, sch. Mainstream economics is the body of knowledge theories and models of economics as taught by universities worldwide that are generally accepted by economists as a basis for discussion Also known as orthodox economics it can be contrasted to heterodox economics which encompasses various schools or approaches that are only accepted by a minority of economists The economics profession has traditionally been associated with neoclassical economics 1 However this association has been challenged by prominent historians of economic thought including David Colander 2 They argue the current economic mainstream theories such as game theory behavioral economics industrial organization information economics and the like share very little common ground with the initial axioms of neoclassical economics Contents 1 History 1 1 Term 2 Scope 2 1 Assumptions 2 2 Methods 2 3 Topics 3 Notes 4 References 4 1 Footnotes 4 2 Works citedHistory editThis section is missing information about Microeconomics Please expand the section to include this information Further details may exist on the talk page June 2022 Economics has always featured multiple schools of economic thought with different schools having different prominence across countries and over time 3 Prior to the development and prevalence of classical economics the dominant school in Europe was mercantilism which was rather a loose set of related ideas than an institutionalized school With the development of modern economics conventionally given as the late 18th century The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith British economics developed and became dominated by what is now called the classical school From The Wealth of Nations until the Great Depression the dominant school within the English speaking world was classical economics and its successor neoclassical economics a citation needed In continental Europe the earlier work of the physiocrats in France formed a distinct tradition as did the later work of the historical school of economics in Germany and throughout the 19th century there were debates in British economics notably the opposition underconsumptionist school During the Great Depression the school of Keynesian economics gained attention as older models were neither able to explain the causes of the Depression nor provide solutions 4 It built on the work of the underconsumptionist school and gained prominence as part of the neoclassical synthesis which was the post World War II merger of Keynesian macroeconomics and neoclassical microeconomics that prevailed from the 1950s until the 1970s 5 In the 1970s the consensus in macroeconomics collapsed as a result of the failure of the neoclassical synthesis to explain the phenomenon of stagflation 6 subsequent to this two schools of thought in the field emerged New Keynesianism and New classical macroeconomics Both sought to rebuild macroeconomics using microfoundations to explain macroeconomic phenomena using microeconomics 7 Over the course of the 1980s and the 1990s macroeconomists coalesced around a paradigm known as the new neoclassical synthesis 8 which combines elements of both New Keynesian and New classical macroeconomics and forms the basis for the current consensus which covers previously disputed areas of macroeconomics which 9 10 The consensus built around this synthesis is characterised by an unprecedented agreement on methodological questions such as the need to validate models econometrically such agreement had until the new synthesis historically eluded macroeconomics even during the neoclassical synthesis 11 The financial crisis of 2007 2010 and the ensuing global economic crisis exposed modelling failures in the field of short term macroeconomics 12 While most macroeconomists had predicted the burst of the housing bubble according to The Economist they did not expect the financial system to break 13 Term edit The term mainstream economics came into use in the late 20th century It appeared in 2001 edition of the textbook Economics by Samuelson and Nordhaus on the inside back cover in the Family Tree of Economics which depicts arrows into Modern Mainstream Economics from Keynes 1936 and neoclassical economics 1860 1910 14 The term neoclassical synthesis itself also first appears in the 1955 edition of Samuelson s textbook 15 Scope editMainstream economics can be defined as distinct from other schools of economics by various criteria notably by its assumptions its methods and its topics Assumptions edit While being long rejected by many heterodox schools several assumptions used to underpin many mainstream economic models These include the neoclassical assumptions of rational choice theory a representative agent and often rational expectations However much of modern economic mainstream modeling consists of exploring the effects that complicating factors have on models such as imperfect and asymmetric information bounded rationality incomplete markets imperfect competition heterogeneous agents 16 and transaction costs 17 Originally the starting point of orthodox economic analysis was the individual Individuals and firms were generally defined as units with a common goal maximisation through rational behaviour The only differences consisted of the specific objective of the maximisation individuals tend to maximise utility and firms profit 18 and the constraints faced in the process of maximisation individuals might be constrained by limited income or commodity prices and firms might be constrained by technology or availability of inputs 18 From this descriptive theoretical framework neoclassical economists like Alfred Marshall often derived although not systematically the political prescription that political action should not be used to solve the problems of the economic system Instead the solution ought to derive from an intervention on the above mentioned maximisation objectives and constraints It is in this context that economic capitalism finds its justification 19 Yet mainstream economics now includes descriptive theories of market and government failure and private and public goods These developments suggest a range of views on the desirability or otherwise of government intervention from a more normative perspective citation needed Methods edit Some economic fields include elements of both mainstream economics and heterodox economics for example institutional economics neuroeconomics and non linear complexity theory 20 They may use neoclassical economics as a point of departure At least one institutionalist John Davis has argued that neoclassical economics no longer dominates a mainstream economics 21 Topics edit Economics has been initially shaped as a discipline concerned with a range of issues revolving around money and wealth However in the 1930s mainstream economics began to mutate into a science of human decision In 1931 Lionel Robbins famously wrote Economics is the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses This drew a line of demarcation between mainstream economics and other disciplines and schools studying the economy 22 The mainstream approach of economics as a science of decision making contributed to enlarge the scope of the discipline Economists like Gary Becker began to study seemingly distant fields including crime 23 the family 24 law 25 politics 25 and religion 26 This expansion is sometimes referred to as economic imperialism 27 Notes edit The precise distinction and relationship between classical economics and neoclassical economics is a debated point Suffice to say that these are the ex post facto terms used to refer to successive chronological periods of an interrelated group of theories References editFootnotes edit Colander 2000a p 35 Colander 2000b p 130 Dequech 2007 p 279 Jahan Mahmud amp Papageorgiou 2014 p 53 Blanchard 2016 p 4 Snowdon amp Vane 2006 p 23 Snowdon amp Vane 2006 p 72 Kocherlakota 2010 pp 11 12 Mankiw 2006 pp 38 39 Goodfriend amp King 1997 pp 231 232 Woodford 2009 pp 2 3 Krugman 2009 The Economist 2009 Samuelson amp Nordhaus 2001 Blanchard 2016 p 1 Kaplan Moll amp Violante 2018 p 699 Kaplan Moll amp Violante 2018 p 709 a b Himmelweit 1997 p 22 Himmelweit 1997 p 23 Colander Holt amp Rosser 2003 p 11 Davis 2006 pp 1 4 Schafer amp Schuster 2022 p 11f Lazear 1999 p 19 Lazear 1999 p 14 a b Lazear 1999 p 39 Lazear 1999 p 20 Lazear 1999 p 6 Works cited edit Blanchard Olivier Jean 11 November 2016 Originally published in The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics 1987 Neoclassical Synthesis The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics London Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 1 5 doi 10 1057 978 1 349 95121 5 1218 1 ISBN 978 1 349 95121 5 Retrieved 30 August 2023 Boettke Peter Leeson Peter 1 January 2003 The Austrian School of Economics 1950 2000 PDF In Samuels Warren J Biddle Jeff E Davis John Bryan eds A Companion to the History of Economic Thought Malden Massachusetts Blackwell Publishing doi 10 1002 9780470999059 ISBN 978 0 631 22573 7 Clark Barry Stewart 1998 Political economy a comparative approach 2 ed Westport Connecticut Praeger ISBN 978 0 275 96370 5 Colander David 2000a Colander David ed Complexity and the history of economic thought London Routledge ISBN 978 0 415 13356 2 OCLC 51977344 Colander David Holt Richard P F Rosser Barkley J Jr November 2003 The Changing Face of Mainstream Economics PDF Review of Political Economy 16 4 485 499 doi 10 1080 0953825042000256702 S2CID 35411709 Colander David June 2000b The Death of Neoclassical Economics Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22 2 127 143 doi 10 1080 10427710050025330 ISSN 1053 8372 S2CID 154275191 Davis John B 1 April 2006 The turn in economics neoclassical dominance to mainstream pluralism Journal of Institutional Economics 2 1 1 20 doi 10 1017 S1744137405000263 ISSN 1744 1382 S2CID 37162943 Archived from the original on 3 July 2023 Retrieved 1 September 2023 Dequech David 1 December 2007 Neoclassical Mainstream Orthodox and Heterodox Economics PDF Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 30 2 279 302 doi 10 2753 PKE0160 3477300207 ISSN 0160 3477 JSTOR 27746799 S2CID 153773877 Archived PDF from the original on 12 August 2017 Goodfriend Marvin King Robert G 1997 The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy NBER Macroeconomics Annual NBER Chapters 12 231 283 doi 10 1086 654336 JSTOR 3585232 Himmelweit Sue 17 March 1997 Chapter 2 The individual as the basic unit of analysis In Green Francis Nore Peter eds Economics An Anti text London MacMillan doi 10 1007 978 1 349 15751 8 ISBN 9780765639233 Retrieved 30 August 2023 Jahan Sarwat Mahmud Ahmed Saber Papageorgiou Chris September 2014 Hayden Jeffrey Primorac Marina et al eds What Is Keynesian Economics PDF Finance amp Development Vol 51 no 3 International Monetary Fund ISSN 0015 1947 Retrieved 9 September 2023 Jelveh Zubin Kogut Bruce Naidu Suresh 13 December 2022 Political Language in Economics SSRN Electronic Journal doi 10 2139 ssrn 2535453 ISSN 1556 5068 S2CID 15818467 SSRN 2535453 Retrieved 1 September 2023 Kaplan Greg Moll Benjamin Violante Giovanni L 1 March 2018 Monetary Policy According to HANK American Economic Review Cambridge MA National Bureau of Economic Research 108 3 697 743 doi 10 1257 aer 20160042 ISSN 0002 8282 JSTOR 26527936 S2CID 31927674 Kocherlakota Narayana 4 May 2010 Modern Macroeconomic Models as Tools for Economic Policy Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis S2CID 154126343 Retrieved 26 November 2023 Krugman Paul 2 September 2009 How did economists get it so wrong The New York Times Magazine Archived from the original on 24 May 2023 Retrieved 30 August 2023 Lazear Edward P July 1999 Economic Imperialism PDF The Quarterly Journal of Economics published August 1999 115 1 99 146 doi 10 1162 003355300554683 JSTOR 2586936 Archived PDF from the original on 30 May 2023 Retrieved 1 September 2023 Mankiw N Gregory 1 August 2006 The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer Journal of Economic Perspectives 20 4 29 46 doi 10 1257 jep 20 4 29 ISSN 0895 3309 The other worldly philosophers The Economist 18 July 2009 ISSN 0013 0613 Rotemberg Julio J January 1987 The New Keynesian Microfoundations NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2 69 104 doi 10 1086 ma 2 4623707 hdl 1721 1 48619 ISSN 0889 3365 S2CID 154005964 Samuelson Paul A Nordhaus William D 2001 Economics 17 ed Richard D Irwin Inc ISBN 9780072509144 Schafer Georg N Schuster Soren E 7 June 2022 Mapping Mainstream Economics Genealogical Foundations of Alternativity 1 ed London Routledge doi 10 4324 9781003287148 ISBN 978 1 003 28714 8 S2CID 249488205 Snowdon Brian Vane Howard R 2006 Modern macroeconomics its origins development and current state PDF Reprinted Paperback ed Cheltenham Edward Elgar Publishing ISBN 978 1 84542 208 0 Archived PDF from the original on 30 April 2021 Retrieved 29 August 2023 Woodford Michael January 2009 Convergence in Macroeconomics Elements of the New Synthesis PDF American Economic Journal Macroeconomics 1 1 267 279 doi 10 1257 mac 1 1 267 ISSN 1945 7707 JSTOR 25760267 Archived PDF from the original on 31 March 2023 Retrieved 30 August 2023 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Mainstream economics amp oldid 1189080903, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.