fbpx
Wikipedia

Collective action

Collective action refers to action taken together by a group of people whose goal is to enhance their condition and achieve a common objective.[1] It is a term that has formulations and theories in many areas of the social sciences including psychology, sociology, anthropology, political science and economics.

The social identity model edit

Researchers Martijn van Zomeren, Tom Postmes, and Russell Spears conducted a meta-analysis of over 180 studies of collective action, in an attempt to integrate three dominant socio-psychological perspectives explaining antecedent conditions to this phenomenon – injustice, efficacy, and identity.[2] In their resultant 2008 review article, an integrative Social Identity Model of Collective Action (SIMCA) was proposed which accounts for interrelationships among the three predictors as well as their predictive capacities for collective action.[2] An important assumption of this approach is that people tend to respond to subjective states of disadvantage, which may or may not flow from objective physical and social reality.

Perceived injustice edit

Examining collective action through perceived injustice was initially guided by relative deprivation theory (RDT). RDT focuses on a subjective state of unjust disadvantage, proposing that engaging in fraternal (group-based) social comparisons with others may result in feelings of relative deprivation that foster collective action. Group-based emotions resulting from perceived injustice, such as anger, are thought to motivate collective action in an attempt to rectify the state of unfair deprivation.[2] The extent to which individuals respond to this deprivation involves several different factors and varies from extremely high to extremely low across different settings.[3] Meta-analysis results confirm that effects of injustice causally predict collective action, highlighting the theoretical importance of this variable.[2]

Perceived efficacy edit

Moving beyond RDT, scholars suggested that in addition to a sense of injustice, people must also have the objective, structural resources necessary to mobilize change through social protest. An important psychological development saw this research instead directed towards subjective expectations and beliefs that unified effort (collective action) is a viable option for achieving group-based goals – this is referred to as perceived collective efficacy. Empirically, collective efficacy is shown to causally affect collective action among a number of populations across varied contexts.[2]

Social identity edit

Social identity theory (SIT) suggests that people strive to achieve and maintain positive social identities associated with their group memberships.[4] Where a group membership is disadvantaged (for example, low status), SIT implicates three variables in the evocation of collective action to improve conditions for the group – permeability of group boundaries,[5] legitimacy of the intergroup structures, and the stability of these relationships. For example, when disadvantaged groups perceive intergroup status relationships as illegitimate and unstable, collective action is predicted to occur, in an attempt to change status structures for the betterment of the disadvantaged group.

Meta-analysis results also confirm that social identity causally predicts collective action across a number of diverse contexts. Additionally, the integrated SIMCA affords another important role to social identity – that of a psychological bridge forming the collective base from which both collective efficacy and group injustice may be conceived.[citation needed]

Model refinement edit

While there is sound empirical support for the causal importance of SIMCA's key theoretical variables on collective action,[2] more recent literature has addressed the issue of reverse causation, finding support for a related, yet distinct, encapsulation model of social identity in collective action (EMSICA).[6] This model suggests that perceived group efficacy and perceived injustice provide the basis from which social identity emerges, highlighting an alternative causal pathway to collective action. Recent research has sought to integrate SIMCA with intergroup contact theory (see Cakal, Hewstone, Schwär, & Heath[7]) and others have extended SIMCA through bridging morality research with the collective action literature (see van Zomeren, Postmes, & Spears[8] for a review).

Public good edit

The economic theory of collective action is concerned with the provision of public goods (and other collective consumption) through the collaboration of two or more individuals, and the impact of externalities on group behavior. It is more commonly referred to as Public Choice. Mancur Olson's 1965 book The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, is an important early analysis of the problems of public good cost.

Besides economics, the theory has found many applications in political science, sociology, communication, anthropology and environmentalism.

Collective action problem edit

The term collective action problem describes the situation in which multiple individuals would all benefit from a certain action, but has an associated cost making it implausible that any individual can or will undertake and solve it alone. The ideal solution is then to undertake this as a collective action, the cost of which is shared. Situations like this include the prisoner's dilemma, a collective action problem in which no communication is allowed, the free rider problem, and the tragedy of the commons, also known as the problem with open access.[9] An allegorical metaphor often used to describe the problem is "belling the cat".[10]

Solutions to collective action problems include mutually binding agreements, government regulation, privatisation, and assurance contracts, also known as crowdacting.[11]

Exploitation of the great by the small edit

Mancur Olson made the claim that individual rational choice leads to situations where individuals with more resources will carry a higher burden in the provision of the public good than poorer ones.[12] Poorer individuals will usually have little choice but to opt for the free rider strategy, i.e., they will attempt to benefit from the public good without contributing to its provision. This may also encourage the under-production (inefficient production) of the public good.

Institutional design edit

While public goods are often provided by governments, this is not always the case. Various institutional designs have been studied with the aim of reducing the collaborative failure. The best design for a given situation depends on the production costs, the utility function, and the collaborative effects, amongst other things. Here are only some examples:

Joint products edit

A joint-product model analyzes the collaborative effect of joining a private good to a public good. For example, a tax deduction (private good) can be tied to a donation to a charity (public good).

It can be shown that the provision of the public good increases when tied to the private good, as long as the private good is provided by a monopoly (otherwise the private good would be provided by competitors without the link to the public good).

Clubs edit

Some institutional design, e.g., intellectual property rights, can introduce an exclusion mechanism and turn a pure public good into an impure public good artificially.

If the costs of the exclusion mechanism are not higher than the gain from the collaboration, clubs can emerge. James M. Buchanan showed in his seminal paper that clubs can be an efficient alternative to government interventions.[13]

A nation can be seen as a club whose members are its citizens. Government would then be the manager of this club.

Federated structure edit

In some cases, theory shows that collaboration emerges spontaneously in smaller groups rather than in large ones (see e.g. Dunbar's number). This explains why labor unions or charities often have a federated structure.

In philosophy edit

Since the late 20th century, analytic philosophers have been exploring the nature of collective action in the sense of acting together, as when people paint a house together, go for a walk together, or together execute a pass play. These particular examples have been central for three of the philosophers who have made well known contributions to this literature: Michael Bratman, Margaret Gilbert, and John Searle, respectively.

In (Gilbert 1989) and subsequent articles and book chapters including Gilbert (2006, chapter 7), whom argues for an account of collective action according to which this rests on a special kind of interpersonal commitment, what Gilbert calls a "joint commitment". A joint commitment in Gilbert's sense is not a matter of a set of personal commitments independently created by each of the participants, as when each makes a personal decision to do something. Rather, it is a single commitment to whose creation each participant makes a contribution. Thus suppose that one person says "Shall we go for a walk?" and the other says "Yes, let's". Gilbert proposes that as a result of this exchange the parties are jointly committed to go for a walk, and thereby obligated to one another to act as if they were parts of a single person taking a walk. Joint commitments can be created less explicitly and through processes that are more extended in time. One merit of a joint commitment account of collective action, in Gilbert's view, is that it explains the fact that those who are out on a walk together, for instance, understand that each of them is in a position to demand corrective action of the other if he or she acts in ways that affect negatively the completion of their walk. In (Gilbert 2006a) she discusses the pertinence of joint commitment to collective actions in the sense of the theory of rational choice.

In Searle (1990) Searle argues that what lies at the heart of a collective action is the presence in the mind of each participant of a "we-intention". Searle does not give an account of we-intentions or, as he also puts it, "collective intentionality", but insists that they are distinct from the "I-intentions" that animate the actions of persons acting alone.

In Bratman (1993) Bratman proposed that, roughly, two people "share an intention" to paint a house together when each intends that the house is painted by virtue of the activity of each, and also intends that it is so painted by virtue of the intention of each that it is so painted. That these conditions obtain must also be "common knowledge" between the participants.

Discussion in this area continues to expand, and has influenced discussions in other disciplines including anthropology, developmental psychology, and economics. One general question is whether it is necessary to think in terms that go beyond the personal intentions of individual human beings properly to characterize what it is to act together. Bratman's account does not go beyond such personal intentions. Gilbert's account, with its invocation of joint commitment, does go beyond them. Searle's account does also, with its invocation of collective intentionality. The question of whether and how one must account for the existence of mutual obligations when there is a collective intention is another of the issues in this area of inquiry.

Spontaneous consensus edit

In addition to the psychological mechanisms of collective action as explained by the social identity model, researchers have developed sociological models of why collective action exists and have studied under what conditions collective action emerges.[14] Along this social dimension, a special case of the general collective action problem is one of collective agreement: how does a group of agents (humans, animals, robots, etc.) reach consensus about a decision or belief in the absence of central organization? Common examples can be found from domains as diverse as biology (flocking, shoaling and schooling, and general collective animal behavior), economics (stock market bubbles), and sociology (social conventions and norms) among others.

Consensus is distinct from the collective action problem in that there often is not an explicit goal, benefit, or cost of action but rather it concerns itself with a social equilibrium of the individuals involved (and their beliefs). And it can be considered spontaneous when it emerges without the presence of a centralized institution among self-interested individuals.[15]

Dimensions edit

Spontaneous consensus can be considered along 4 dimensions involving the social structure of the individuals participating (local versus global) in the consensus as well as the processes (competitive vs cooperative) involved in reaching consensus:[14]

  • Competitive
  • Cooperative
  • Local
  • Global

Competitive versus cooperative edit

The underlying processes of spontaneous consensus can be viewed either as cooperation among individuals trying to coordinate themselves through their interactions or as competition between the alternatives or choices to be decided upon.[14] Depending on the dynamics of the individuals involved as well as the context of the alternatives considered for consensus, the process can be wholly cooperative, wholly competitive, or a mix of the two.

Local versus global edit

The distinction between local and global consensus can be viewed in terms of the social structure underlying the network of individuals participating in the consensus making process. Local consensus occurs when there is agreement between groups of neighboring nodes while global consensus refers to the state in which most of the population has reached an agreement.[14] How and why consensus is reached is dependent on both the structure of the social network of individuals as well as the presence (or lack) of centralized institutions.

Equilibrium mechanisms edit

There are many mechanisms (social and psychological) that have been identified to underlie the consensus making process.[14] They have been used to both explain the emergence of spontaneous consensus and understand how to facilitate an equilibrium between individuals and can be grouped according to their role in the process.

  • Facilitation of Equilibrium
  • Selection of Alternatives
    • Logical Reflection[20]
    • Psychological and shared biases[18]
    • Chance (when all alternatives are equivalent)[21]

Methods and techniques edit

Due to the interdisciplinary nature of both the mechanisms as well as the applications of spontaneous consensus, a variety of techniques have been developed to study the emergence and evolution of spontaneous cooperation. Two of the most widely used are game theory and social network analysis.

Game theory edit

Traditionally game theory has been used to study zero-sum games but has been extended to many different types of games. Relevant to the study of spontaneous consensus are cooperative and non-cooperative games. Since a consensus must be reached without the presence of any external authoritative institution for it to be considered spontaneous, non-cooperative games and Nash equilibrium have been the dominant paradigm for which to study its emergence.

In the context of non-cooperative games, a consensus is a formal Nash equilibrium that all players tend towards through self-enforcing alliances or agreements.

An important case study of the underlying mathematical dynamics is the coordination game. Even when coordination is desired, it can be difficult to achieve due to incomplete information and constrained time horizons.

Social network analysis edit

An alternative approach to studying the emergence of spontaneous consensus—that avoids many of the unnatural or overly constrained assumptions of game theoretic models—is the use of network based methods and social network analysis (SNA). These SNA models are theoretically grounded in the communication mechanism[16] of facilitating consensus and describe its emergence through the information propagation processes of the network (behavioral contagion). Through the spread of influence (and ideas) between agents participating in the consensus, local and global consensus can emerge if the agents in the network achieve a shared equilibrium state. Leveraging this model of consensus, researchers have shown that local peer influence can be used to reach a global consensus and cooperation across the entire network.[22] While this model of consensus and cooperation has been shown to be successful in certain contexts, research suggest that communication and social influence cannot be fully captured by simple contagion models[23] and as such a pure contagion based model of consensus may have limits.

Confucian approach edit

The teachings of Confucius have led to a kind of collective action that's based on the principal of "saving face" and other behavioral norms found taught in the Analects.[24] One of the largest instances of Confucian-style collective action took place 1867 in the construction of the Transcontinental Railroad, where Chinese workers protested peacefully and negotiated for an outcome in a way that clearly demonstrated a kind of spontaneous consensus that's based on Confucian face-saving behavior.[24]

See also edit

Footnotes edit

  1. ^ "collective action problem - collective action". Encyclopædia Britannica.
  2. ^ a b c d e f van Zomeren, M.; Postmes, T.; Spears, R. (2008). "Toward an integrative social identity model of collective action: A quantitative research synthesis of three socio-psychological perspectives". Psychological Bulletin. 134 (4): 504–535. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.576.5638. doi:10.1037/0033-2909.134.4.504. PMID 18605818. S2CID 18741272.
  3. ^ Ostrom, Elinor (2000). "Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms" (PDF). The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 14 (3): 137–158. doi:10.1257/jep.14.3.137. hdl:10535/5683.
  4. ^ Tajfel, H.; Turner, J.C. (1979). "An integrative theory of inter-group conflict. In W.G. Austin & S. Worchel (Eds.)". The Social Psychology of Inter-group Relations: 33–47.
  5. ^ Stephen C. Wright; Donald M. Taylor; Fathali M. Moghaddam (June 1990). "Responding to Membership in a Disadvantaged Group: From Acceptance to Collective Protest". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 58 (6): 994–1003. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.58.6.994.
  6. ^ Thomas, E.F.; Mavor, K.I.; McGarty, C. (2011). "Social identities facilitate and encapsulate action-relevant constructs: A test of the social identity model of collective action". Group Processes and Intergroup Relations. 15 (1): 75–88. doi:10.1177/1368430211413619. hdl:1885/66105. S2CID 53577195.
  7. ^ Cakal, H.; Hewstone, M.; Schwär, G.; Heath, A. (2011). "An investigation of the social identity model of collective action and the 'sedative' effect of intergroup contact among Black and White students in South Africa". British Journal of Social Psychology. 50 (4): 606–627. doi:10.1111/j.2044-8309.2011.02075.x. PMID 22122025.
  8. ^ van Zomeren, M.; Postmes, T.; Spears, R. (2012). "On conviction's collective consequences: Integrating moral conviction with the social identity model of collective action" (PDF). British Journal of Social Psychology. 51 (1): 52–71. doi:10.1111/j.2044-8309.2010.02000.x. PMID 22435846. S2CID 44659756.
  9. ^ Archived at Ghostarchive and the : Agar, Jesse. "Tragedy of the Commons │ The Problem with Open Access". Youtube. This Place (youtube channel). Retrieved Jun 9, 2015.
  10. ^ Dowding, Keith (1996). Power. University of Minnesota Press. pp. 31 ff. ISBN 978-0-8166-2941-1.
  11. ^ Archived at Ghostarchive and the : van den Akker, Ron. "Crowdacting". YouTube. Bord&Stift. Retrieved Sep 7, 2016.
  12. ^ Olson, Mancur (1965). "logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups" (Document). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  13. ^ Buchanan, James M. (1965). "An Economic Theory of Clubs". Economica. 32 (125): 1–14. doi:10.2307/2552442. JSTOR 2552442.
  14. ^ a b c d e Baronchelli, Andrea (2018). "The Emergence of Consensus". Royal Society Open Science. 5 (2): 172189. arXiv:1704.07767. Bibcode:2018RSOS....572189B. doi:10.1098/rsos.172189. PMC 5830794. PMID 29515905.
  15. ^ Sugden, Robert (1989). "Spontaneous order". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 3 (4): 85–97. doi:10.1257/jep.3.4.85.
  16. ^ a b Garrod, Simon; Doherty, Gwyneth (1994). "Conversation, co-ordination and convention: An empirical investigation of how groups establish linguistic conventions". Cognition. 53 (3): 181–215. doi:10.1016/0010-0277(94)90048-5. PMID 7842633. S2CID 26766644.
  17. ^ Boyd, Robert; Richerson, Peter (1992). "Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups". Ethology and Sociobiology. 13 (3): 171–195. doi:10.1016/0162-3095(92)90032-Y.
  18. ^ a b Schelling, Thomas (1960). The strategy of conflict. Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674840317.
  19. ^ Asch, Solomon (1955). "Opinions and social pressure". In Aronson, Elliot (ed.). Readings about the social animal. Macmillan. pp. 17–26. ISBN 9780716759669.
  20. ^ Harsanyi, John; Selten, Reinhard (1988). A general theory of equilibrium selection in games. MIT Press Books. p. 1. ISBN 9780262582384.
  21. ^ Young, H Peyton (1996). "The economics of convention". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 10 (2): 105–122. doi:10.1257/jep.10.2.105. JSTOR 2138484. S2CID 155064244.
  22. ^ Mani, Ankur; Rahwan, Iyad; Pentland, Alex (2013). "Inducing Peer Pressure to Promote Cooperation". Scientific Reports. 3 (1735): 1735. Bibcode:2013NatSR...3E1735M. doi:10.1038/srep01735. PMC 3636514. PMID 23619166.
  23. ^ Alshamsi, Aamena; Pianesi, Fabio; Lepri, Bruno; Pentland, Alex; Rahwan, Iyad (2015). "Beyond Contagion: Reality Mining Reveals Complex Patterns of Social Influence". PLOS ONE. 10 (8): e0135740. arXiv:1507.04192. Bibcode:2015PLoSO..1035740A. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0135740. PMC 4551670. PMID 26313449.
  24. ^ a b Ryan, Patrick Spaulding. "Saving Face Without Words: A Confucian Perspective on The Strike of 1867". International Journal of Humanities, Art and Social Studies. forthcoming. doi:10.2139/ssrn.4067005. S2CID 248036295.

Bibliography edit

  • Bratman, Michael (October 1993). "Shared intention". Ethics. 104 (1): 97–113. doi:10.1086/293577. JSTOR 2381695. S2CID 222814811.
  • Dolata, Ulrich; Schrape, Jan-Felix (2015). "Masses, Crowds, Communities, Movements: Collective Action in the Internet Age". Social Movement Studies. 15: 1–18. doi:10.1080/14742837.2015.1055722. S2CID 141985609.
  • Dolata, Ulrich; Schrape, Jan-Felix (2018). Collectivity and Power on the Internet. A Sociological Perspective. London Cham: Springer. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-78414-4. ISBN 9783319784137.
  • Gilbert, Margaret (1989). On social facts. London New York: Routledge. ISBN 9780415024440.
  • Gilbert, Margaret (2006a). "Rationality in Collective Action". Philosophy of the Social Sciences. 36 (1): 3–17. doi:10.1177/0048393105284167. S2CID 144590512.
  • Gilbert, Margaret (2006). A theory of political obligation : membership, commitment, and the bonds of society. Oxford Oxford New York: Clarendon Press Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780199274956.
  • Hardin, Russell (1982). Collective action. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. ISBN 9780801828195.
  • Meinzen-Dick, Ruth Suseela; di Gregorio, Monica, eds. (2004). Collective action and property rights for sustainable development. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute. 2020 Focus No. 11. Pdf.
  • Olson, Mancur (1965). The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674537514.
  • Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521405997.
  • Searle, John R. (2002), "Collective intentions and actions", in Searle, John R. (ed.), Consciousness and language, New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 90–105, ISBN 9780521597449.
  • van Winden, Frans (December 2015). "Political economy with affect: on the role of emotions and relationships in political economics". European Journal of Political Economy. 40 (B): 298–311. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2015.05.005.

External links edit

collective, action, refers, action, taken, together, group, people, whose, goal, enhance, their, condition, achieve, common, objective, term, that, formulations, theories, many, areas, social, sciences, including, psychology, sociology, anthropology, political. Collective action refers to action taken together by a group of people whose goal is to enhance their condition and achieve a common objective 1 It is a term that has formulations and theories in many areas of the social sciences including psychology sociology anthropology political science and economics Contents 1 The social identity model 1 1 Perceived injustice 1 2 Perceived efficacy 1 3 Social identity 1 4 Model refinement 2 Public good 2 1 Collective action problem 2 2 Exploitation of the great by the small 2 3 Institutional design 2 3 1 Joint products 2 3 2 Clubs 2 3 3 Federated structure 3 In philosophy 4 Spontaneous consensus 4 1 Dimensions 4 1 1 Competitive versus cooperative 4 1 2 Local versus global 4 2 Equilibrium mechanisms 4 3 Methods and techniques 4 3 1 Game theory 4 3 2 Social network analysis 4 3 3 Confucian approach 5 See also 6 Footnotes 7 Bibliography 8 External linksThe social identity model editResearchers Martijn van Zomeren Tom Postmes and Russell Spears conducted a meta analysis of over 180 studies of collective action in an attempt to integrate three dominant socio psychological perspectives explaining antecedent conditions to this phenomenon injustice efficacy and identity 2 In their resultant 2008 review article an integrative Social Identity Model of Collective Action SIMCA was proposed which accounts for interrelationships among the three predictors as well as their predictive capacities for collective action 2 An important assumption of this approach is that people tend to respond to subjective states of disadvantage which may or may not flow from objective physical and social reality Perceived injustice edit Examining collective action through perceived injustice was initially guided by relative deprivation theory RDT RDT focuses on a subjective state of unjust disadvantage proposing that engaging in fraternal group based social comparisons with others may result in feelings of relative deprivation that foster collective action Group based emotions resulting from perceived injustice such as anger are thought to motivate collective action in an attempt to rectify the state of unfair deprivation 2 The extent to which individuals respond to this deprivation involves several different factors and varies from extremely high to extremely low across different settings 3 Meta analysis results confirm that effects of injustice causally predict collective action highlighting the theoretical importance of this variable 2 Perceived efficacy edit Moving beyond RDT scholars suggested that in addition to a sense of injustice people must also have the objective structural resources necessary to mobilize change through social protest An important psychological development saw this research instead directed towards subjective expectations and beliefs that unified effort collective action is a viable option for achieving group based goals this is referred to as perceived collective efficacy Empirically collective efficacy is shown to causally affect collective action among a number of populations across varied contexts 2 Social identity edit Social identity theory SIT suggests that people strive to achieve and maintain positive social identities associated with their group memberships 4 Where a group membership is disadvantaged for example low status SIT implicates three variables in the evocation of collective action to improve conditions for the group permeability of group boundaries 5 legitimacy of the intergroup structures and the stability of these relationships For example when disadvantaged groups perceive intergroup status relationships as illegitimate and unstable collective action is predicted to occur in an attempt to change status structures for the betterment of the disadvantaged group Meta analysis results also confirm that social identity causally predicts collective action across a number of diverse contexts Additionally the integrated SIMCA affords another important role to social identity that of a psychological bridge forming the collective base from which both collective efficacy and group injustice may be conceived citation needed Model refinement edit While there is sound empirical support for the causal importance of SIMCA s key theoretical variables on collective action 2 more recent literature has addressed the issue of reverse causation finding support for a related yet distinct encapsulation model of social identity in collective action EMSICA 6 This model suggests that perceived group efficacy and perceived injustice provide the basis from which social identity emerges highlighting an alternative causal pathway to collective action Recent research has sought to integrate SIMCA with intergroup contact theory see Cakal Hewstone Schwar amp Heath 7 and others have extended SIMCA through bridging morality research with the collective action literature see van Zomeren Postmes amp Spears 8 for a review Public good editThe economic theory of collective action is concerned with the provision of public goods and other collective consumption through the collaboration of two or more individuals and the impact of externalities on group behavior It is more commonly referred to as Public Choice Mancur Olson s 1965 book The Logic of Collective Action Public Goods and the Theory of Groups is an important early analysis of the problems of public good cost Besides economics the theory has found many applications in political science sociology communication anthropology and environmentalism Collective action problem edit Main article Collective action problem The term collective action problem describes the situation in which multiple individuals would all benefit from a certain action but has an associated cost making it implausible that any individual can or will undertake and solve it alone The ideal solution is then to undertake this as a collective action the cost of which is shared Situations like this include the prisoner s dilemma a collective action problem in which no communication is allowed the free rider problem and the tragedy of the commons also known as the problem with open access 9 An allegorical metaphor often used to describe the problem is belling the cat 10 Solutions to collective action problems include mutually binding agreements government regulation privatisation and assurance contracts also known as crowdacting 11 Exploitation of the great by the small edit Mancur Olson made the claim that individual rational choice leads to situations where individuals with more resources will carry a higher burden in the provision of the public good than poorer ones 12 Poorer individuals will usually have little choice but to opt for the free rider strategy i e they will attempt to benefit from the public good without contributing to its provision This may also encourage the under production inefficient production of the public good Institutional design edit While public goods are often provided by governments this is not always the case Various institutional designs have been studied with the aim of reducing the collaborative failure The best design for a given situation depends on the production costs the utility function and the collaborative effects amongst other things Here are only some examples Joint products edit A joint product model analyzes the collaborative effect of joining a private good to a public good For example a tax deduction private good can be tied to a donation to a charity public good It can be shown that the provision of the public good increases when tied to the private good as long as the private good is provided by a monopoly otherwise the private good would be provided by competitors without the link to the public good Clubs edit Some institutional design e g intellectual property rights can introduce an exclusion mechanism and turn a pure public good into an impure public good artificially If the costs of the exclusion mechanism are not higher than the gain from the collaboration clubs can emerge James M Buchanan showed in his seminal paper that clubs can be an efficient alternative to government interventions 13 A nation can be seen as a club whose members are its citizens Government would then be the manager of this club Federated structure edit In some cases theory shows that collaboration emerges spontaneously in smaller groups rather than in large ones see e g Dunbar s number This explains why labor unions or charities often have a federated structure In philosophy editSince the late 20th century analytic philosophers have been exploring the nature of collective action in the sense of acting together as when people paint a house together go for a walk together or together execute a pass play These particular examples have been central for three of the philosophers who have made well known contributions to this literature Michael Bratman Margaret Gilbert and John Searle respectively In Gilbert 1989 and subsequent articles and book chapters including Gilbert 2006 chapter 7 whom argues for an account of collective action according to which this rests on a special kind of interpersonal commitment what Gilbert calls a joint commitment A joint commitment in Gilbert s sense is not a matter of a set of personal commitments independently created by each of the participants as when each makes a personal decision to do something Rather it is a single commitment to whose creation each participant makes a contribution Thus suppose that one person says Shall we go for a walk and the other says Yes let s Gilbert proposes that as a result of this exchange the parties are jointly committed to go for a walk and thereby obligated to one another to act as if they were parts of a single person taking a walk Joint commitments can be created less explicitly and through processes that are more extended in time One merit of a joint commitment account of collective action in Gilbert s view is that it explains the fact that those who are out on a walk together for instance understand that each of them is in a position to demand corrective action of the other if he or she acts in ways that affect negatively the completion of their walk In Gilbert 2006a she discusses the pertinence of joint commitment to collective actions in the sense of the theory of rational choice In Searle 1990 Searle argues that what lies at the heart of a collective action is the presence in the mind of each participant of a we intention Searle does not give an account of we intentions or as he also puts it collective intentionality but insists that they are distinct from the I intentions that animate the actions of persons acting alone In Bratman 1993 Bratman proposed that roughly two people share an intention to paint a house together when each intends that the house is painted by virtue of the activity of each and also intends that it is so painted by virtue of the intention of each that it is so painted That these conditions obtain must also be common knowledge between the participants Discussion in this area continues to expand and has influenced discussions in other disciplines including anthropology developmental psychology and economics One general question is whether it is necessary to think in terms that go beyond the personal intentions of individual human beings properly to characterize what it is to act together Bratman s account does not go beyond such personal intentions Gilbert s account with its invocation of joint commitment does go beyond them Searle s account does also with its invocation of collective intentionality The question of whether and how one must account for the existence of mutual obligations when there is a collective intention is another of the issues in this area of inquiry Spontaneous consensus editIn addition to the psychological mechanisms of collective action as explained by the social identity model researchers have developed sociological models of why collective action exists and have studied under what conditions collective action emerges 14 Along this social dimension a special case of the general collective action problem is one of collective agreement how does a group of agents humans animals robots etc reach consensus about a decision or belief in the absence of central organization Common examples can be found from domains as diverse as biology flocking shoaling and schooling and general collective animal behavior economics stock market bubbles and sociology social conventions and norms among others Consensus is distinct from the collective action problem in that there often is not an explicit goal benefit or cost of action but rather it concerns itself with a social equilibrium of the individuals involved and their beliefs And it can be considered spontaneous when it emerges without the presence of a centralized institution among self interested individuals 15 Dimensions edit Spontaneous consensus can be considered along 4 dimensions involving the social structure of the individuals participating local versus global in the consensus as well as the processes competitive vs cooperative involved in reaching consensus 14 Competitive Cooperative Local GlobalCompetitive versus cooperative edit The underlying processes of spontaneous consensus can be viewed either as cooperation among individuals trying to coordinate themselves through their interactions or as competition between the alternatives or choices to be decided upon 14 Depending on the dynamics of the individuals involved as well as the context of the alternatives considered for consensus the process can be wholly cooperative wholly competitive or a mix of the two Local versus global edit The distinction between local and global consensus can be viewed in terms of the social structure underlying the network of individuals participating in the consensus making process Local consensus occurs when there is agreement between groups of neighboring nodes while global consensus refers to the state in which most of the population has reached an agreement 14 How and why consensus is reached is dependent on both the structure of the social network of individuals as well as the presence or lack of centralized institutions Equilibrium mechanisms edit There are many mechanisms social and psychological that have been identified to underlie the consensus making process 14 They have been used to both explain the emergence of spontaneous consensus and understand how to facilitate an equilibrium between individuals and can be grouped according to their role in the process Facilitation of Equilibrium Communication 16 Punishment of Deviants 17 Positive Payoffs 18 Conformity Bias 19 Selection of Alternatives Logical Reflection 20 Psychological and shared biases 18 Chance when all alternatives are equivalent 21 Methods and techniques edit Due to the interdisciplinary nature of both the mechanisms as well as the applications of spontaneous consensus a variety of techniques have been developed to study the emergence and evolution of spontaneous cooperation Two of the most widely used are game theory and social network analysis Game theory edit Traditionally game theory has been used to study zero sum games but has been extended to many different types of games Relevant to the study of spontaneous consensus are cooperative and non cooperative games Since a consensus must be reached without the presence of any external authoritative institution for it to be considered spontaneous non cooperative games and Nash equilibrium have been the dominant paradigm for which to study its emergence In the context of non cooperative games a consensus is a formal Nash equilibrium that all players tend towards through self enforcing alliances or agreements An important case study of the underlying mathematical dynamics is the coordination game Even when coordination is desired it can be difficult to achieve due to incomplete information and constrained time horizons Social network analysis edit An alternative approach to studying the emergence of spontaneous consensus that avoids many of the unnatural or overly constrained assumptions of game theoretic models is the use of network based methods and social network analysis SNA These SNA models are theoretically grounded in the communication mechanism 16 of facilitating consensus and describe its emergence through the information propagation processes of the network behavioral contagion Through the spread of influence and ideas between agents participating in the consensus local and global consensus can emerge if the agents in the network achieve a shared equilibrium state Leveraging this model of consensus researchers have shown that local peer influence can be used to reach a global consensus and cooperation across the entire network 22 While this model of consensus and cooperation has been shown to be successful in certain contexts research suggest that communication and social influence cannot be fully captured by simple contagion models 23 and as such a pure contagion based model of consensus may have limits Confucian approach edit The teachings of Confucius have led to a kind of collective action that s based on the principal of saving face and other behavioral norms found taught in the Analects 24 One of the largest instances of Confucian style collective action took place 1867 in the construction of the Transcontinental Railroad where Chinese workers protested peacefully and negotiated for an outcome in a way that clearly demonstrated a kind of spontaneous consensus that s based on Confucian face saving behavior 24 See also editAnti corruption collective action Collaborative innovation network Collective intelligence Collective intentionality Common property resource Constitutional economics Coordination good Free rider problem Group action sociology Mass collaboration Nash equilibrium Outline of organizational theory Pareto efficiency Polytely Prisoner s dilemma Private collective model of innovation Public good Social fact Tragedy of the commons Tragedy of the anticommonsFootnotes edit collective action problem collective action Encyclopaedia Britannica a b c d e f van Zomeren M Postmes T Spears R 2008 Toward an integrative social identity model of collective action A quantitative research synthesis of three socio psychological perspectives Psychological Bulletin 134 4 504 535 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 576 5638 doi 10 1037 0033 2909 134 4 504 PMID 18605818 S2CID 18741272 Ostrom Elinor 2000 Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms PDF The Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 3 137 158 doi 10 1257 jep 14 3 137 hdl 10535 5683 Tajfel H Turner J C 1979 An integrative theory of inter group conflict In W G Austin amp S Worchel Eds The Social Psychology of Inter group Relations 33 47 Stephen C Wright Donald M Taylor Fathali M Moghaddam June 1990 Responding to Membership in a Disadvantaged Group From Acceptance to Collective Protest Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 58 6 994 1003 doi 10 1037 0022 3514 58 6 994 Thomas E F Mavor K I McGarty C 2011 Social identities facilitate and encapsulate action relevant constructs A test of the social identity model of collective action Group Processes and Intergroup Relations 15 1 75 88 doi 10 1177 1368430211413619 hdl 1885 66105 S2CID 53577195 Cakal H Hewstone M Schwar G Heath A 2011 An investigation of the social identity model of collective action and the sedative effect of intergroup contact among Black and White students in South Africa British Journal of Social Psychology 50 4 606 627 doi 10 1111 j 2044 8309 2011 02075 x PMID 22122025 van Zomeren M Postmes T Spears R 2012 On conviction s collective consequences Integrating moral conviction with the social identity model of collective action PDF British Journal of Social Psychology 51 1 52 71 doi 10 1111 j 2044 8309 2010 02000 x PMID 22435846 S2CID 44659756 Archived at Ghostarchive and the Wayback Machine Agar Jesse Tragedy of the Commons The Problem with Open Access Youtube This Place youtube channel Retrieved Jun 9 2015 Dowding Keith 1996 Power University of Minnesota Press pp 31 ff ISBN 978 0 8166 2941 1 Archived at Ghostarchive and the Wayback Machine van den Akker Ron Crowdacting YouTube Bord amp Stift Retrieved Sep 7 2016 Olson Mancur 1965 logic of collective action Public goods and the theory of groups Document Cambridge MA Harvard University Press Buchanan James M 1965 An Economic Theory of Clubs Economica 32 125 1 14 doi 10 2307 2552442 JSTOR 2552442 a b c d e Baronchelli Andrea 2018 The Emergence of Consensus Royal Society Open Science 5 2 172189 arXiv 1704 07767 Bibcode 2018RSOS 572189B doi 10 1098 rsos 172189 PMC 5830794 PMID 29515905 Sugden Robert 1989 Spontaneous order The Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 4 85 97 doi 10 1257 jep 3 4 85 a b Garrod Simon Doherty Gwyneth 1994 Conversation co ordination and convention An empirical investigation of how groups establish linguistic conventions Cognition 53 3 181 215 doi 10 1016 0010 0277 94 90048 5 PMID 7842633 S2CID 26766644 Boyd Robert Richerson Peter 1992 Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation or anything else in sizable groups Ethology and Sociobiology 13 3 171 195 doi 10 1016 0162 3095 92 90032 Y a b Schelling Thomas 1960 The strategy of conflict Harvard University Press ISBN 9780674840317 Asch Solomon 1955 Opinions and social pressure In Aronson Elliot ed Readings about the social animal Macmillan pp 17 26 ISBN 9780716759669 Harsanyi John Selten Reinhard 1988 A general theory of equilibrium selection in games MIT Press Books p 1 ISBN 9780262582384 Young H Peyton 1996 The economics of convention The Journal of Economic Perspectives 10 2 105 122 doi 10 1257 jep 10 2 105 JSTOR 2138484 S2CID 155064244 Mani Ankur Rahwan Iyad Pentland Alex 2013 Inducing Peer Pressure to Promote Cooperation Scientific Reports 3 1735 1735 Bibcode 2013NatSR 3E1735M doi 10 1038 srep01735 PMC 3636514 PMID 23619166 Alshamsi Aamena Pianesi Fabio Lepri Bruno Pentland Alex Rahwan Iyad 2015 Beyond Contagion Reality Mining Reveals Complex Patterns of Social Influence PLOS ONE 10 8 e0135740 arXiv 1507 04192 Bibcode 2015PLoSO 1035740A doi 10 1371 journal pone 0135740 PMC 4551670 PMID 26313449 a b Ryan Patrick Spaulding Saving Face Without Words A Confucian Perspective on The Strike of 1867 International Journal of Humanities Art and Social Studies forthcoming doi 10 2139 ssrn 4067005 S2CID 248036295 Bibliography editBratman Michael October 1993 Shared intention Ethics 104 1 97 113 doi 10 1086 293577 JSTOR 2381695 S2CID 222814811 Dolata Ulrich Schrape Jan Felix 2015 Masses Crowds Communities Movements Collective Action in the Internet Age Social Movement Studies 15 1 18 doi 10 1080 14742837 2015 1055722 S2CID 141985609 Dolata Ulrich Schrape Jan Felix 2018 Collectivity and Power on the Internet A Sociological Perspective London Cham Springer doi 10 1007 978 3 319 78414 4 ISBN 9783319784137 Gilbert Margaret 1989 On social facts London New York Routledge ISBN 9780415024440 Gilbert Margaret 2006a Rationality in Collective Action Philosophy of the Social Sciences 36 1 3 17 doi 10 1177 0048393105284167 S2CID 144590512 Gilbert Margaret 2006 A theory of political obligation membership commitment and the bonds of society Oxford Oxford New York Clarendon Press Oxford University Press ISBN 9780199274956 Hardin Russell 1982 Collective action Baltimore Johns Hopkins University Press ISBN 9780801828195 Meinzen Dick Ruth Suseela di Gregorio Monica eds 2004 Collective action and property rights for sustainable development Washington DC International Food Policy Research Institute 2020 Focus No 11 Pdf Olson Mancur 1965 The logic of collective action public goods and the theory of groups Cambridge Massachusetts Harvard University Press ISBN 9780674537514 Ostrom Elinor 1990 Governing the commons the evolution of institutions for collective action Cambridge New York Cambridge University Press ISBN 9780521405997 Searle John R 2002 Collective intentions and actions in Searle John R ed Consciousness and language New York Cambridge University Press pp 90 105 ISBN 9780521597449 van Winden Frans December 2015 Political economy with affect on the role of emotions and relationships in political economics European Journal of Political Economy 40 B 298 311 doi 10 1016 j ejpoleco 2015 05 005 External links edit nbsp Scholia has a topic profile for Collective action Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Collective action amp oldid 1168463761, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.