fbpx
Wikipedia

History of capitalism

The history of capitalism is diverse and the concept of capitalism has many debated roots. The history of the past 500 years is concerned with the development of capitalism in its various forms. Capital accumulated by a variety of methods, at a variety of scales, became associated with much variation in the concentration of wealth and economic power. Capitalism gradually became the dominant economic system throughout the world.[1][2][need quotation to verify][3][need quotation to verify]

Historiography

The processes by which capitalism emerged, evolved, and spread are the subject of extensive research and debate among historians. Debates sometimes focus on how to bring substantive historical data to bear on key questions.[4] Key parameters of debate include: the extent to which capitalism is a natural human behavior, versus the extent to which it arises from specific historical circumstances; whether its origins lie in towns and trade or in rural property relations; the role of class conflict; the role of the state; the extent to which capitalism is a distinctively European innovation; its relationship with European imperialism; whether technological change is a driver or merely a secondary byproduct of capitalism; and whether or not it is the most beneficial way to organize human societies.[5]

The historiography of capitalism can be divided into two broad schools.[citation needed] One is associated with economic liberalism, with the 18th-century economist Adam Smith as a foundational figure. The other is associated with Marxism, drawing particular inspiration from the 19th-century economist Karl Marx.

Liberals view capitalism as an expression of natural human behaviors that have been in evidence for millennia and the most beneficial way of promoting human well-being.[citation needed] They see capitalism as originating in trade and commerce, and freeing people to exercise their entrepreneurial natures.[citation needed]

Marxists view capitalism as a unique mode of production involving the bourgeoise and proletariat that emerged as a result of the fall of feudalism and the beginning of the Industrial Revolution. This rejects the notion that capitalism has existed for millennia and is a part of human nature.[citation needed]

Origins

The origins of capitalism have been much debated (and depend partly on how capitalism is defined). The traditional account, originating in classical 18th-century liberal economic thought and still often articulated, is the 'commercialisation model'. This sees capitalism originating in trade. In this reading, capitalism emerged from earlier trade once merchants had acquired sufficient wealth (referred to as 'primitive capital') to begin investing in increasingly productive technology. This account tends to see capitalism as a continuation of trade, arising when people's natural entrepreneurialism was freed from the constraints of feudalism, partly by urbanisation.[6] Thus it traces capitalism to early forms of merchant capitalism practiced in Western Europe during the Middle Ages.[7]

Other views

A competitor to the 'commercialisation model' is the 'agrarian model',[citation needed] which explains the rise of capitalism by unique circumstances in English agrarianism. The evidence it cites is that traditional mercantilism focused on moving goods from markets where they were cheap to markets where they were expensive rather than investing in production, and that many cultures (including the early modern Dutch Republic) saw urbanisation and the amassing of wealth by merchants without the emergence of capitalist production.[8][9]

The agrarian argument developed particularly through Karl Polanyi's The Great Transformation (1944), Maurice Dobb's Studies in the Development of Capitalism (1946), and Robert Brenner's research in the 1970s, the discussion of which is known as the Brenner Debate. In the wake of the Norman Conquest, the English state was unusually centralised. This gave aristocrats relatively limited powers to extract wealth directly from their feudal underlings through political means (not least the threat of violence). England's centralisation also meant that an unusual number of English farmers were not peasants (with their own land and thus direct access to subsistence) but tenants (renting their land). These circumstances produced a market in leases. Landlords, lacking other ways to extract wealth, were motivated to rent to tenants who could pay the most, while tenants, lacking security of tenure, were motivated to farm as productively as possible to win leases in a competitive market. This led to a cascade of effects whereby successful tenant farmers became agrarian capitalists; unsuccessful ones became wage-labourers, required to sell their labour in order to live; and landlords promoted the privatisation and renting out of common land, not least through the enclosures. In this reading, 'it was not merchants or manufacturers who drove the process that propelled the early development of capitalism. The transformation of social property relations was firmly rooted in the countryside, and the transformation of England's trade and industry was result more than cause of England's transition to capitalism'.[10]

21st-century scholarship

The 21st century has seen renewed interest in the history of capitalism, and "History of Capitalism" has become a field in its own right, with courses in history departments. In the 2000s, Harvard University founded the Program on the Study of U.S. Capitalism; Cornell University established the History of Capitalism Initiative;[11] and Columbia University Press launched a monograph series titled Studies in the History of U.S. Capitalism.[12] This field includes topics such as insurance, banking and regulation, the political dimension, and the impact on the middle classes, the poor and women and minorities.[13][14] These initiatives incorporate formerly neglected questions of race, gender, and sexuality into the history of capitalism. They have grown in the aftermath of the financial crisis of 2007–2008 and the associated Great Recession.

Some academic institutions which are managed in part by free-market think tanks, such as the Clemson Institute for the Study of Capitalism, reject the notion that race, gender, or sexuality have any significant relationship to capitalism at all and instead seek to show that laissez-faire capitalism, in particular, provides the moral foundations of a just society and the most numerous economic opportunities for all people. [15][16]

Agrarian capitalism

Crisis of the 14th century

 
Map of a medieval manor. Notice the large commons area and the division of land into small strips. The mustard-colored areas are part of the demesne, the hatched areas part of the glebe.
William R. Shepherd, Historical Atlas, 01923

According to some historians,[17] the modern capitalist system originated in the "crisis of the Late Middle Ages", a conflict between the land-owning aristocracy and the agricultural producers, or serfs. Manorial arrangements inhibited the development of capitalism in a number of ways. Serfs had obligations to produce for lords and therefore had no interest in technological innovation; they also had no interest in cooperating with one another because they produced to sustain their own families. The lords who owned the land[citation needed] relied on force to guarantee that they received sufficient food. Because lords were not producing to sell on the market, there was no competitive pressure for them to innovate. Finally, because lords expanded their power and wealth through military means, they spent their wealth on military equipment or on conspicuous consumption that helped foster alliances with other lords; they had no incentive to invest in developing new productive technologies.[18]

The demographic crisis of the 14th century upset this arrangement. This crisis had several causes: agricultural productivity reached its technological limitations and stopped growing, bad weather led to the Great Famine of 1315–1317, and the Black Death of 1348–1350 led to a population crash. These factors led to a decline in agricultural production. In response, feudal lords sought to expand agricultural production by extending their domains through warfare; therefore they demanded more tribute from their serfs to pay for military expenses. In England, many serfs rebelled. Some moved to towns, some bought land, and some entered into favorable contracts to rent lands from lords who needed to repopulate their estates.[19]

The collapse of the manorial system in England enlarged the class of tenant farmers with more freedom to market their goods and thus more incentive to invest in new technologies. Lords who did not want to rely on renters could buy out or evict tenant farmers, but then had to hire free labor to work their estates, giving them an incentive to invest in two kinds of commodity owners. One kind was those who had money, the means of production, and subsistence, who were eager to valorize the sum of value they had appropriated by buying the labor power of others.[citation needed] The other kind was free workers, who sold their own labor. The workers neither formed part of the means of production nor owned the means of production that transformed land and even money into what we now call "capital".[20] Marx labeled this period the "pre-history of capitalism".[21]

In effect, feudalism began to lay some of the foundations necessary for the development of mercantilism, a precursor of capitalism. Feudalism lasted from the medieval period through the 16th century. Feudal manors were almost entirely self-sufficient, and therefore limited the role of the market. This stifled any incipient tendency towards capitalism. However, the relatively sudden emergence of new technologies and discoveries, particularly in agriculture[22] and exploration, facilitated the growth of capitalism. The most important development at the end of feudalism[citation needed] was the emergence of what Robert Degan calls "the dichotomy between wage earners and capitalist merchants".[23] The competitive nature meant there are always winners and losers, and this became clear as feudalism evolved into mercantilism, an economic system characterized by the private or corporate ownership of capital goods, investments determined by private decisions, and by prices, production, and the distribution of goods determined mainly by competition in a free market.[citation needed]

Enclosure

 
Decaying hedges mark the lines of the straight field boundaries created by a Parliamentary Act of Enclosure.

England in the 16th century was already a centralized state, in which much of the feudal order of Medieval Europe had been swept away. This centralization was strengthened by a good system of roads and a disproportionately large capital city, London.[24] The capital acted as a central market for the entire country, creating a large internal market for goods, in contrast to the fragmented feudal holdings that prevailed in most parts of the Continent. The economic foundations of the agricultural system were also beginning to diverge substantially; the manorial system had broken down by this time, and land began to be concentrated in the hands of fewer landlords with increasingly large estates. The system put pressure on both the landlords and the tenants to increase agricultural productivity to create profit. The weakened coercive power of the aristocracy to extract peasant surpluses encouraged them to try out better methods. The tenants also had an incentive to improve their methods to succeed in an increasingly competitive labour market. Land rents had moved away from the previous stagnant system of custom and feudal obligation, and were becoming directly subject to economic market forces.

An important aspect of this process of change was the enclosure[25] of the common land previously held in the open field system where peasants had traditional rights, such as mowing meadows for hay and grazing livestock. Once enclosed, these uses of the land became restricted to the owner, and it ceased to be land for commons. The process of enclosure began to be a widespread feature of the English agricultural landscape during the 16th century. By the 19th century, unenclosed commons had become largely restricted to rough pasture in mountainous areas and to relatively small parts of the lowlands.

Marxist and neo-Marxist historians argue that rich landowners used their control of state processes to appropriate public land for their private benefit. This created a landless working class that provided the labour required in the new industries developing in the north of England. For example: "In agriculture the years between 1760 and 1820 are the years of wholesale enclosure in which, in village after village, common rights are lost".[26] "Enclosure (when all the sophistications are allowed for) was a plain enough case of class robbery".[27] Anthropologist Jason Hickel notes that this process of enclosure led to myriad peasant revolts, among them Kett's Rebellion and the Midland Revolt, which culminated in violent repression and executions.[28]

Other scholars[29] argue that the better-off members of the European peasantry encouraged and participated actively in enclosure, seeking to end the perpetual poverty of subsistence farming. "We should be careful not to ascribe to [enclosure] developments that were the consequence of a much broader and more complex process of historical change."[30] "[T]he impact of eighteenth and nineteenth century enclosure has been grossly exaggerated...."[31]

Merchant capitalism and mercantilism

Precedents

 
A painting of a French seaport from 1638, at the height of mercantilism.

While trade has existed since early in human history, it was not capitalism.[32] The earliest recorded activity of long-distance profit-seeking merchants can be traced to the Old Assyrian merchants active in Mesopotamia the 2nd millennium BCE.[33] The Roman Empire developed more advanced forms of commerce, and similarly widespread networks existed in Islamic nations. However, capitalism took shape in Europe in the late Middle Ages and Renaissance.

An early emergence of commerce occurred on monastic estates in Italy and France and in the independent city republics of Italy during the late Middle Ages. Innovations in banking, insurance, accountancy, and various production and commercial practices linked closely to a 'spirit' of frugality, reinvestment, and city life, promoted attitudes that sociologists have tended to associate only with northern Europe, Protestantism, and a much later age. The city republics maintained their political independence from Empire and Church, traded with North Africa, the Middle East and Asia, and introduced Eastern practices. They were also considerably different from the absolutist monarchies of Spain and France, and were strongly attached to civic liberty.[34][35][36]

Emergence

Modern capitalism only fully emerged in the early modern period between the 16th and 18th centuries, with the establishment of mercantilism or merchant capitalism.[37][38] Early evidence for mercantilistic practices appears in early modern Venice, Genoa, and Pisa over the Mediterranean trade in bullion. The region of mercantilism's real birth, however, was the Atlantic Ocean.[39]

 
Sir Josiah Child, an influential proponent of mercantilism. Painting attributed to John Riley.

England began a large-scale and integrative approach to mercantilism during the Elizabethan Era. An early statement on national balance of trade appeared in Discourse of the Common Weal of this Realm of England, 1549: "We must always take heed that we buy no more from strangers than we sell them, for so should we impoverish ourselves and enrich them."[40][full citation needed] The period featured various but often disjointed efforts by the court of Queen Elizabeth to develop a naval and merchant fleet capable of challenging the Spanish stranglehold on trade and of expanding the growth of bullion at home. Elizabeth promoted the Trade and Navigation Acts in Parliament and issued orders to her navy for the protection and promotion of English shipping.

These efforts organized national resources sufficiently in the defense of England against the far larger and more powerful Spanish Empire, and in turn paved the foundation for establishing a global empire in the 19th century.[citation needed] The authors noted most for establishing the English mercantilist system include Gerard de Malynes and Thomas Mun, who first articulated the Elizabethan System. The latter's England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, or the Balance of our Forraign Trade is The Rule of Our Treasure gave a systematic and coherent explanation of the concept of balance of trade. It was written in the 1620s and published in 1664.[41] Mercantile doctrines were further developed by Josiah Child. Numerous French authors helped to cement French policy around mercantilism in the 17th century. French mercantilism was best articulated by Jean-Baptiste Colbert (in office, 1665–1683), although his policies were greatly liberalised under Napoleon.

Doctrines

Under mercantilism, European merchants, backed by state controls, subsidies, and monopolies, made most of their profits from buying and selling goods. In the words of Francis Bacon, the purpose of mercantilism was "the opening and well-balancing of trade; the cherishing of manufacturers; the banishing of idleness; the repressing of waste and excess by sumptuary laws; the improvement and husbanding of the soil; the regulation of prices..."[42] Similar practices of economic regimentation had begun earlier in medieval towns. However, under mercantilism, given the contemporaneous rise of absolutism, the state superseded the local guilds as the regulator of the economy.

 
The Anglo-Dutch Wars were fought between the English and the Dutch for control over the seas and trade routes.

Among the major tenets of mercantilist theory was bullionism, a doctrine stressing the importance of accumulating precious metals. Mercantilists argued that a state should export more goods than it imported so that foreigners would have to pay the difference in precious metals. Mercantilists asserted that only raw materials that could not be extracted at home should be imported. They promoted the idea that government subsidies, such as granting monopolies and protective tariffs, were necessary to encourage home production of manufactured goods.

Proponents of mercantilism emphasized state power and overseas conquest as the principal aim of economic policy. If a state could not supply its own raw materials, according to the mercantilists, it should acquire colonies from which they could be extracted. Colonies constituted not only sources of raw materials but also markets for finished products. Because it was not in the interests of the state to allow competition, to help the mercantilists, colonies should be prevented from engaging in manufacturing and trading with foreign powers.

Mercantilism was a system of trade for profit, although commodities were still largely produced by non-capitalist production methods.[3] Noting the various pre-capitalist features of mercantilism, Karl Polanyi argued that "mercantilism, with all its tendency toward commercialization, never attacked the safeguards which protected [the] two basic elements of production – labor and land – from becoming the elements of commerce." Thus mercantilist regulation was more akin to feudalism than capitalism. According to Polanyi, "not until 1834 was a competitive labor market established in England, hence industrial capitalism as a social system cannot be said to have existed before that date."[43]

Chartered trading companies

 
British East India Company 1801

The Muscovy Company was the first major chartered joint stock English trading company. It was established in 1555 with a monopoly on trade between England and Muscovy. It was an offshoot of the earlier Company of Merchant Adventurers to New Lands, founded in 1551 by Richard Chancellor, Sebastian Cabot and Sir Hugh Willoughby to locate the Northeast Passage to China to allow trade. This was the precursor to a type of business that would soon flourish in England, the Dutch Republic and elsewhere.

The British East India Company (1600) and the Dutch East India Company (1602) launched an era of large state chartered trading companies.[7][44] These companies were characterized by their monopoly on trade, granted by letters patent provided by the state. Recognized as chartered joint-stock companies by the state, these companies enjoyed lawmaking, military, and treaty-making privileges.[45] Characterized by its colonial and expansionary powers by states, powerful nation-states sought to accumulate precious metals, and military conflicts arose.[7] During this era, merchants, who had previously traded on their own, invested capital in the East India Companies and other colonies, seeking a return on investment.

Industrial capitalism

 
Gustave Doré's 19th-century engraving depicted the dirty, overcrowded slums where the industrial workers of London lived.

Mercantilism declined in Great Britain in the mid-18th century, when a new group of economic theorists, led by Adam Smith, challenged fundamental mercantilist doctrines, such as that the world's wealth remained constant and that a state could only increase its wealth at the expense of another state. However, mercantilism continued in less developed economies, such as Prussia and Russia, with their much younger manufacturing bases.

The mid-18th century gave rise to industrial capitalism, made possible by (1) the accumulation of vast amounts of capital under the merchant phase of capitalism and its investment in machinery, and (2) the fact that the enclosures meant that Britain had a large population of people with no access to subsistence agriculture, who needed to buy basic commodities via the market, ensuring a mass consumer market.[46] Industrial capitalism, which Marx dated from the last third of the 18th century, marked the development of the factory system of manufacturing, characterized by a complex division of labor between and within work processes and the routinization of work tasks. Industrial capitalism finally established the global domination of the capitalist mode of production.[37]

During the resulting Industrial Revolution, the industrialist replaced the merchant as a dominant actor in the capitalist system, which led to the decline of the traditional handicraft skills of artisans, guilds, and journeymen. Also during this period, capitalism transformed relations between the British landowning gentry and peasants, giving rise to the production of cash crops for the market rather than for subsistence on a feudal manor. The surplus generated by the rise of commercial agriculture encouraged increased mechanization of agriculture.

Industrial Revolution

The productivity gains of capitalist production began a sustained and unprecedented increase at the turn of the 19th century, in a process commonly referred to as the Industrial Revolution. Starting in about 1760 in England, there was a steady transition to new manufacturing processes in a variety of industries, including going from hand production methods to machine production, new chemical manufacturing and iron production processes, improved efficiency of water power, the increasing use of steam power and the development of machine tools. It also included the change from wood and other bio-fuels to coal.

 
The Spinning mule, built by the inventor Samuel Crompton.

In textile manufacturing, mechanized cotton spinning powered by steam or water increased the output of a worker by a factor of about 1000, due to the application of James Hargreaves' spinning jenny, Richard Arkwright's water frame, Samuel Crompton's Spinning Mule and other inventions. The power loom increased the output of a worker by a factor of over 40.[47] The cotton gin increased the productivity of removing seed from cotton by a factor of 50. Large gains in productivity also occurred in spinning and weaving wool and linen, although they were not as great as in cotton.

Finance

 
The Rothschild family revolutionised international finance. The Frankfurt terminus of the Taunus Railway was financed by the Rothschilds and opened in 1840 as one of Germany's first railways.

The growth of Britain's industry stimulated a concomitant growth in its system of finance and credit. In the 18th century, services offered by banks increased. Clearing facilities, security investments, cheques and overdraft protections were introduced. Cheques had been invented in the 17th century in England, and banks settled payments by direct courier to the issuing bank. Around 1770, they began meeting in a central location, and by the 19th century a dedicated space was established, known as a bankers' clearing house. The London clearing house used a method where each bank paid cash to and then was paid cash by an inspector at the end of each day. The first overdraft facility was set up in 1728 by The Royal Bank of Scotland.

The end of the Napoleonic War and the subsequent rebound in trade led to an expansion in the bullion reserves held by the Bank of England, from a low of under 4 million pounds in 1821 to 14 million pounds by late 1824.

Older innovations became routine parts of financial life during the 19th century. The Bank of England first issued bank notes during the 17th century, but the notes were hand written and few in number. After 1725, they were partially printed, but cashiers still had to sign each note and make them payable to a named person. In 1844, parliament passed the Bank Charter Act tying these notes to gold reserves, effectively creating the institution of central banking and monetary policy. The notes became fully printed and widely available from 1855.[citation needed]

Growing international trade increased the number of banks, especially in London. These new "merchant banks" facilitated trade growth, profiting from England's emerging dominance in seaborne shipping. Two immigrant families, Rothschild and Baring, established merchant banking firms in London in the late 18th century and came to dominate world banking in the next century. The tremendous wealth amassed by these banking firms soon attracted much attention. The poet George Gordon Byron wrote in 1823: "Who makes politics run glibber all?/ The shade of Bonaparte's noble daring?/ Jew Rothschild and his fellow-Christian, Baring."

The operation of banks also shifted. At the beginning of the century, banking was still an elite preoccupation of a handful of very wealthy families. Within a few decades, however, a new sort of banking had emerged, owned by anonymous stockholders, run by professional managers, and the recipient of the deposits of a growing body of small middle-class savers. Although this breed of banks was newly prominent, it was not new – the Quaker family Barclays had been banking in this way since 1690.

Free trade and globalization

At the height of the First French Empire, Napoleon sought to introduce a "continental system" that would render Europe economically autonomous, thereby emasculating British trade and commerce. It involved such stratagems as the use of beet sugar in preference to the cane sugar that had to be imported from the tropics. Although this caused businessmen in England to agitate for peace, Britain persevered, in part because it was well into the industrial revolution. The war had the opposite effect – it stimulated the growth of certain industries, such as pig-iron production which increased from 68,000 tons in 1788 to 244,000 by 1806.[citation needed]

 
19th-century Great Britain become the first global economic superpower, because of superior manufacturing technology and improved global communications such as steamships and railroads.

In 1817, David Ricardo, James Mill and Robert Torrens, in the famous theory of comparative advantage, argued that free trade would benefit the industrially weak as well as the strong. In Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Ricardo advanced the doctrine still considered the most counterintuitive in economics:

When an inefficient producer sends the merchandise it produces best to a country able to produce it more efficiently, both countries benefit.

By the mid 19th century, Britain was firmly wedded to the notion of free trade, and the first era of globalization began.[37] In the 1840s, the Corn Laws and the Navigation Acts were repealed, ushering in a new age of free trade. In line with the teachings of the classical political economists, led by Adam Smith and David Ricardo, Britain embraced liberalism, encouraging competition and the development of a market economy.

Industrialization allowed cheap production of household items using economies of scale,[citation needed] while rapid population growth created sustained demand for commodities. Nineteenth-century imperialism decisively shaped globalization in this period. After the First and Second Opium Wars and the completion of the British conquest of India, vast populations of these regions became ready consumers of European exports. During this period, areas of sub-Saharan Africa and the Pacific islands were incorporated into the world system. Meanwhile, the European conquest of new parts of the globe, notably sub-Saharan Africa, yielded valuable natural resources such as rubber, diamonds and coal and helped fuel trade and investment between the European imperial powers, their colonies, and the United States.[48]

 
The gold standard formed the financial basis of the international economy from 1870 to 1914.

The inhabitant of London could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea, the various products of the whole earth, and reasonably expect their early delivery upon his doorstep. Militarism and imperialism of racial and cultural rivalries were little more than the amusements of his daily newspaper. What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man was that age which came to an end in August 1914.

The global financial system was mainly tied to the gold standard during this period. The United Kingdom first formally adopted this standard in 1821. Soon to follow was Canada in 1853, Newfoundland in 1865, and the United States and Germany (de jure) in 1873. New technologies, such as the telegraph, the transatlantic cable, the Radiotelephone, the steamship, and the railway allowed goods and information to move around the world at an unprecedented degree.[49]

The eruption of civil war in the United States in 1861 and the blockade of its ports to international commerce meant that the main supply of cotton for the Lancashire looms was cut off. The textile industries shifted to reliance upon cotton from Africa and Asia during the course of the U.S. civil war, and this created pressure for an Anglo-French controlled canal through the Suez peninsula. The Suez canal opened in 1869, the same year in which the Central Pacific Railroad that spanned the North American continent was completed. Capitalism and the engine of profit were making the globe a smaller place.

20th century

Several major challenges to capitalism appeared in the early part of the 20th century. The Russian revolution in 1917 established the first state with a ruling communist party in the world; a decade later, the Great Depression triggered increasing criticism of the existing capitalist system. One response to this crisis was a turn to fascism, an ideology that advocated state capitalism.[50] Another response was to reject capitalism altogether in favour of communist or democratic socialist ideologies.

Keynesianism and free markets

 
The New York stock exchange traders' floor (1963)

The economic recovery of the world's leading capitalist economies in the period following the end of the Great Depression and the Second World War—a period of unusually rapid growth by historical standards—eased discussion of capitalism's eventual decline or demise.[51] The state began to play an increasingly prominent role to moderate and regulate the capitalistic system throughout much of the world.

Keynesian economics became a widely accepted method of government regulation and countries such as the United Kingdom experimented with mixed economies in which the state owned and operated certain major industries.

The state also expanded in the US; in 1929, total government expenditures amounted to less than one-tenth of GNP; from the 1970s they amounted to around one-third.[38] Similar increases were seen in all industrialised capitalist economies, some of which, such as France, have reached even higher ratios of government expenditures to GNP than the United States.

A broad array of new analytical tools in the social sciences were developed to explain the social and economic trends of the period, including the concepts of post-industrial society and the welfare state.[37]

The long post-war boom ended in the 1970s, amid the economic crises experienced following the 1973 oil crisis.[52] The "stagflation" of the 1970s led many economic commentators and politicians to embrace market-oriented policy prescriptions inspired by the laissez-faire capitalism and classical liberalism of the nineteenth century, particularly under the influence of Friedrich Hayek and Milton Friedman. The theoretical alternative to Keynesianism was more compatible with laissez-faire and emphasised rapid expansion of the economy. Market-oriented solutions gained increasing support in the Western world, especially under the leadership of Ronald Reagan in the United States and Margaret Thatcher in the UK in the 1980s. Public and political interest began shifting away from the so-called collectivist concerns of Keynes's managed capitalism to a focus on individual choice, called "remarketized capitalism".[53]

The three booming decades that followed the Second World War, according to political economist Clara E. Mattei, were an anomaly in the history of contemporary capitalism. She writes that austerity did not originate with the emergence of the neoliberal era starting in the 1970s, but "has been the mainstay of capitalism."[54]

Globalization

Although overseas trade has been associated with the development of capitalism for over five hundred years, some thinkers argue that a number of trends associated with globalisation have acted to increase the mobility of people and capital since the last quarter of the twentieth century, combining to circumscribe the room to manoeuvre of states in choosing non-capitalist models of development. Today, these trends have bolstered the argument that capitalism should now be viewed as a truly world system (Burnham). However, other thinkers argue that globalisation, even in its quantitative degree, is no greater now than during earlier periods of capitalist trade.[55]

After the abandonment of the Bretton Woods system in 1971, and the strict state control of foreign exchange rates, the total value of transactions in foreign exchange was estimated to be at least twenty times greater than that of all foreign movements of goods and services (EB). The internationalisation of finance, which some see as beyond the reach of state control, combined with the growing ease with which large corporations have been able to relocate their operations to low-wage states, has posed the question of the 'eclipse' of state sovereignty, arising from the growing 'globalization' of capital.[56]

While economists generally agree about the size of global income inequality[citation needed], there is a general disagreement about the recent direction of change of it.[57] In cases such as China, where income inequality is clearly growing[58] it is also evident that overall economic growth has rapidly increased with capitalist reforms.[59] The book The Improving State of the World, published by the libertarian think tank Cato Institute, argues that economic growth since the Industrial Revolution has been very strong and that factors such as adequate nutrition, life expectancy, infant mortality, literacy, prevalence of child labor, education, and available free time have improved greatly.[60] Some scholars, including Stephen Hawking[61] and researchers for the International Monetary Fund,[62][63] contend that globalization and neoliberal economic policies are not ameliorating inequality and poverty but exacerbating it,[64][65][66] and are creating new forms of contemporary slavery.[67][68] Such policies are also expanding populations of the displaced, the unemployed and the imprisoned[69][70] along with accelerating the destruction of the environment[64] and species extinction.[71][72] In 2017, the IMF warned that inequality within nations, in spite of global inequality falling in recent decades, has risen so sharply that it threatens economic growth and could result in further political polarization.[73] Surging economic inequality following the economic crisis and the anger associated with it have resulted in a resurgence of socialist and nationalist ideas throughout the Western world, which has some economic elites from places including Silicon Valley, Davos and Harvard Business School concerned about the future of capitalism.[74]

21st century

By the beginning of the twenty-first century, mixed economies with capitalist elements had become the pervasive economic systems worldwide. The collapse of the Soviet bloc in 1991 significantly reduced the influence of socialism as an alternative economic system. Leftist movements continue to be influential in some parts of the world, most notably Latin-American Bolivarianism, with some having ties to more traditional anti-capitalist movements, such as Bolivarian Venezuela's ties to Cuba.

In many emerging markets, the influence of banking and financial capital have come to increasingly shape national developmental strategies, leading some to argue we are in a new phase of financial capitalism.[75]

State intervention in global capital markets following the financial crisis of 2007–2010 was perceived by some as signalling a crisis for free-market capitalism. Serious turmoil in the banking system and financial markets due in part to the subprime mortgage crisis reached a critical stage during September 2008, characterised by severely contracted liquidity in the global credit markets posed an existential threat to investment banks and other institutions.[76][77]

Future

According to some,[who?][78] the transition to the information society involves abandoning some parts of capitalism, as the "capital" required to produce and process information becomes available to the masses and difficult to control, and is closely related to the controversial issues of intellectual property. Some[78] even speculate that the development of mature nanotechnology, particularly of universal assemblers, may make capitalism obsolete, with capital ceasing to be an important factor in the economic life of humanity. Various thinkers have also explored what kind of economic system might replace capitalism, such as Bob Avakian, Jason Hickel, Paul Mason, Richard D. Wolff and contributors to the "Scientists' warning on affluence".[79]

Role of women

Women's historians have debated the impact of capitalism on the status of women.[80][81] Alice Clark argues that, when capitalism arrived in 17th-century England, it negatively impacted the status of women, who lost much of their economic importance. Clark argues that, in 16th-century England, women were engaged in many aspects of industry and agriculture. The home was a central unit of production, and women played a vital role in running farms and in some trades and landed estates. Their useful economic roles gave them a sort of equality with their husbands. However, Clark argues, as capitalism expanded in the 17th century, there was more and more division of labor, with the husband taking paid labor jobs outside the home, and the wife reduced to unpaid household work. Middle-class women were confined to an idle domestic existence, supervising servants; lower-class women were forced to take poorly paid jobs. Capitalism, therefore, had a negative effect on women.[82] By contrast, Ivy Pinchbeck argues that capitalism created the conditions for women's emancipation.[83] Tilly and Scott have emphasized the continuity and the status of women, finding three stages in European history. In the preindustrial era, production was mostly for home use, and women produced many household needs. The second stage was the "family wage economy" of early industrialization. During this stage, the entire family depended on the collective wages of its members, including husband, wife, and older children. The third, or modern, stage is the "family consumer economy", in which the family is the site of consumption, and women are employed in large numbers in retail and clerical jobs to support rising standards of consumption.[84]

See also

References

  1. ^ Compare: Rogers, Alisdair; Castree, Noel; Kitchin, Rob (2013). "capitalism". A Dictionary of Human Geography. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-959986-8. Retrieved 2019-08-11. Capitalism is the world's dominant economic system but was virtually non-existent three hundred years ago.
  2. ^ Calhoun, Craig (2002). "capitalism". Dictionary of the Social Sciences. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-512371-5. Retrieved 2019-08-11.
  3. ^ a b Scott, John; Marshall, Gordon (2005). "capitalism". Oxford Dictionary of Sociology (3rd ed.). Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-860986-5.
  4. ^ Richard Biernacki, review of Ellen Meiksins Wood (1999), The Origin of Capitalism (Monthly Review Press, 1999), in Contemporary Sociology, Vol. 29, No. 4 (Jul., 2000), pp. 638–39 JSTOR 2654574.
  5. ^ Ellen Meiksins Wood (2002), The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View (London: Verso, 2002).
  6. ^ Ellen Meiksins Wood (2002), The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View (London: Verso, 2002.), pp. 11–21.
  7. ^ a b c Jairus Banaji (2007), "Islam, the Mediterranean and the rise of capitalism", Journal Historical Materialism 15#1 pp. 47–74, Brill Publishers.
  8. ^ Ellen Meiksins Wood (2002), The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View (London: Verso, 2002), pp. 11–21.
  9. ^ Chris Harman, 'The Rise of Capitalism', International Socialism Journal, 102 (Spring 2004).
  10. ^ Ellen Meiksins Wood (2002), The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View (London: Verso, 2002), quoting p. 129.
  11. ^ Jennifer Schuessler, "In History Departments, It's Up with Capitalism", The New York Times, April 6, 2013
  12. ^ "Columbia Studies in the History of U.S. Capitalism – Columbia University Press". columbia.edu.
  13. ^ See Jennifer Schuessler "In History Departments, It's Up With Capitalism" The New York Times April 6, 2013
  14. ^ Lou Galambos, "Is This a Decisive Moment for the History of Business, Economic History, and the History of Capitalism? Essays in Economic & Business History (2014) v. 32 pp. 1–18 online
  15. ^ "About | Clemson Institute for the Study of Capitalism | Wilbur O. and Ann Powers College of Business | Clemson University, South Carolina". www.clemson.edu. Retrieved 2021-03-19.
  16. ^ Brutzman, Anna. "Gift to Clemson comes with strings". Independent Mail.
  17. ^ Hickel, Jason (2017). "3 – Where did poverty come from? A creation story". The divide : a brief guide to global inequality and its solutions. London. ISBN 9781785151125. OCLC 984907212.
  18. ^ Brenner, Robert, 1977, "The Origins of Capitalist Development: a Critique of Neo-Smithian Marxism", in New Left Review 104: 36–37, 46
  19. ^ Dobb, Maurice 1947 Studies in the Development of Capitalism. New York: International Publishers Co., Inc. 42–46, 48 ff.
  20. ^ Marx, Karl [1867] 1976 Capital: A Critique of Political Economy Volume One trans. Ben Fowkes. Harmondsworth and London: Penguin Books and New Left Review. 874
  21. ^ Marx, Karl [1867] 1976 Capital: A Critique of Political Economy Volume One trans. Ben Fowkes. Harmondsworth and London: Penguin Books and New Left Review. 875
  22. ^ James Fulcher, Capitalism (New York: Oxford University Press, 2004) 19
  23. ^ Degen, Robert A. (2011-12-31). The Triumph of Capitalism. New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Publishers (published 2011). p. 12. ISBN 9781412809856. Retrieved 2016-01-13. By the early 1400s, power came to be shared in an arrangement giving representation to various segments of the social order, but the dichotomy between wage earners and capitalist merchants remained.
  24. ^ Ellen Meikisins Wood, The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View, 2nd edn (London: Verso, 2002), p. 99.
  25. ^ "Enclosure" is the modern spelling, while "inclosure" is an older spelling still used in the United Kingdom in legal documents and place names.
  26. ^ Thompson, E. P. (1991). The Making of the English Working Class. Penguin. p. 217.
  27. ^ A comparison of the English historical enclosures with the (much later) German 19th century Landflucht. Engels, Friedrich (1882). "Die Mark". Die Entwicklung des Sozialismus von der Utopie zur Wissenschaft. Hottingen (Zurich). Marx, Karl; Engels, Friedrich. Werke (1973 reprint of 196t 1st ed.). Berlin: Karl Dietz.
  28. ^ Hickel, Jason (2018). The Divide: A Brief Guide to Global Inequality and its Solutions. Windmill Books. pp. 78–79. ISBN 978-1786090034.
  29. ^ W. A. Armstrong
  30. ^ Chambers, J. D.; Mingay, G. E. (1982). The Agricultural Revolution 1750–1850 (Reprinted ed.). Batsford. p. 104.
  31. ^ Armstrong, W A (1981). The Influence of Demographic Factors on the Position of the Agricultural Labourer in England and Wales, c.1750–1914". in "Agricultural History Review.". The Agricultural History Review. Vol. 29. British Agricultural History Society. p. 79.
  32. ^ Ellen Meiksins Wood (2002), The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View (London: Verso, 2002), pp. 73–94.
  33. ^ Warburton, David, Macroeconomics from the beginning: The General Theory, Ancient Markets, and the Rate of Interest. Paris: Recherches et Publications, 2003. p. 49
  34. ^ Stark, Rodney. Victory of Reason, (Random House New York, 2005)
  35. ^ Ferguson, Niall. The Ascent of Money, (Penguin,2008)
  36. ^ Skinner, Quentin, The Foundations of Modern Political Thought, vol I: The Renaissance; vol II: The Age of Reformation. Cambridge University Press, 1978)
  37. ^ a b c d Burnham, Peter Capitalism, the Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics, 2003 Oxford: Oxford University Press
  38. ^ a b Encyclopædia Britannica (2006)
  39. ^ John J. McCusker, Mercantilism and the Economic History of the Early Modern Atlantic World (Cambridge UP, 2001)
  40. ^ Now attributed to Sir Thomas Smith; quoted in Braudel (1979), p. 204.
  41. ^ David Onnekink; Gijs Rommelse (2011). Ideology and Foreign Policy in Early Modern Europe (1650–1750). Ashgate Publishing, Ltd. p. 257. ISBN 9781409419143.
  42. ^ Quoted in Sir George Clark, The Seventeenth Century (New York: Oxford University Press, 1961), p. 24.
  43. ^ Polanyi, Karl. The Great Transformation. Beacon Press, Boston. 1944. p. 87
  44. ^ Economic system :: Market systems. Encyclopædia Britannica. 2006.
  45. ^ . Archived from the original on 2009-01-09.
  46. ^ Ellen Meiksins Wood (2002), The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View (London: Verso, 2002), pp. 142–46.
  47. ^ Ayres, Robert (1989). (PDF). International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis. pp. 16–17. ISBN 3-7045-0092-5. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2012-03-01. Retrieved 2014-01-02.
  48. ^ "PBS.org". PBS.org. 1929-10-24. Retrieved 2010-07-31.
  49. ^ Michael D. Bordo, Barry Eichengreen, Douglas A. Irwin. "Is Globalization Today Really Different than Globalization a Hundred Years Ago?". NBER Working Paper No.7195. June 1999.
  50. ^ Reich, Wilhelm (1970). The Mass Psychology of Fascism. Macmillan. pp. 277–281. ISBN 978-0-374-20364-1.
  51. ^ Stanley Engerman; Seymour Drescher; Robert Paquette (2001). Slavery (Oxford Readers). Oxford University Press.
  52. ^ Barnes, Trevor J. (2004). Reading economic geography. Blackwell Publishing. p. 127. ISBN 0-631-23554-X.
  53. ^ Fulcher, James. Capitalism. 1st ed. New York: Oxford University Press, 2004.
  54. ^ Mattei, Clara E. (2022). The Capital Order: How Economists Invented Austerity and Paved the Way to Fascism. University of Chicago Press. p. 3. ISBN 978-0226818399. Austerity is not new, nor is it a product of the so-called Neoliberal Era that began in the 1970s. Outside, perhaps, of the less than three booming decades that followed World War II, austerity has been the mainstay of capitalism. It has been true throughout history that where capitalism exists, crisis follows. Where austerity has proven wildly effective is in insulating capitalist hierarchies from harm during these moments of would-be social change.
  55. ^ Doug Henwood is an economist who has argued that the heyday of globalisation was during the mid-nineteenth century. For example, he writes in What Is Globalization Anyway?:

    Not only is the novelty of "globalization" exaggerated, so is its extent. Capital flows were freer, and foreign holdings by British investors far larger, 100 years ago than anything we see today. Images of multinational corporations shuttling raw materials and parts around the world, as if the whole globe were an assembly line, are grossly overblown, accounting for only about a tenth of U.S. trade.

    (See also Henwood, Doug (October 1, 2003). After the New Economy. New Press. ISBN 1-56584-770-9.)

  56. ^ For an assessment of this question, see Peter Evans, "The Eclipse of the State? Reflections on Stateness in an Era of Globalization", World Politics, 50, 1 (October 1997): 62–87.
  57. ^ Milanovic, Branko (2006-08-01). Global Income Inequality: What It Is And Why It Matters? (Technical report). DESA Working Paper. Vol. 26. p. 9.
  58. ^ Brooks, David (2004-11-27). "Good News about Poverty". Retrieved 2008-02-26.
  59. ^ Fengbo Zhang: Speech at "Future China Global Forum 2010": China Rising with the Reform and Open Policy.
  60. ^ Dahl, Robert (2000). On Democracy. Yale University: Yale Nota Bene. pp. 168. ISBN 0-300-07627-4.
  61. ^ This is the most dangerous time for our planet. Stephen Hawking via The Guardian. 1 December 2016.
  62. ^ Neoliberalism: Oversold? – IMF Finance & Development June 2016 • Volume 53 • Number 2
  63. ^ IMF: The last generation of economic policies may have been a complete failure. Business Insider. May 2016.
  64. ^ a b Jones, Campbell, Martin Parker and Rene Ten Bos, For Business Ethics. (Routledge, 2005) ISBN 0415311357, p. 101
  65. ^ Stephen Haymes, Maria Vidal de Haymes and Reuben Miller (eds), The Routledge Handbook of Poverty in the United States, (London: Routledge, 2015) ISBN 0415673445, pp. 1–2.
  66. ^ Jason Hickel (February 13, 2019). An Open Letter to Steven Pinker (and Bill Gates). Jacobin. Retrieved February 14, 2019.
  67. ^ Bales, Kevin (2012). Disposable People: New Slavery in the Global Economy. University of California Press. ISBN 978-0520272910.
  68. ^ Žižek, Slavoj (2018). The Courage of Hopelessness: A Year of Acting Dangerously. Melville House. p. 29. ISBN 978-1612190037.
  69. ^ Saskia Sassen, Expulsions: Brutality and Complexity in the Global Economy. (Harvard University Press, 2014) ISBN 0674599225
  70. ^ Loïc Wacquant. Prisons of Poverty. University of Minnesota Press (2009). p. 55 ISBN 0816639019.
  71. ^ Dawson, Ashley (2016). Extinction: A Radical History. OR Books. p. 41. ISBN 978-1944869014.
  72. ^ Harvey, David (2005). A Brief History of Neoliberalism. Oxford University Press. p. 173. ISBN 0199283273.
  73. ^ Dunsmuir, Lindsay (October 11, 2017). "IMF calls for fiscal policies that tackle rising inequality". Reuters. Retrieved November 4, 2017.
  74. ^ Jaffe, Greg (April 20, 2019). "Capitalism in crisis: U.S. billionaires worry about the survival of the system that made them rich". The Washington Post. Retrieved April 24, 2019.
  75. ^ Marois, Thomas (2012) States, Banks and Crisis: Emerging Finance Capitalism in Mexico and Turkey. Cheltenham, Gloucestershire, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.
  76. ^ "President Bush Meets with Bicameral and Bipartisan Members of Congress to Discuss Economy", Whitehouse.gov, September 25, 2008.
  77. ^ "House votes down bail-out package". 29 September 2008 – via news.bbc.co.uk.
  78. ^ a b Kaku, Michio (1999). Visions: How Science Will Revolutionize the 21st Century and Beyond. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-288018-7
  79. ^ Wiedmann, Thomas; Lenzen, Manfred; Keyßer, Lorenz T.; Steinberger, Julia K. (2020). "Scientists' warning on affluence". Nature Communications. 11 (3107): 3107. Bibcode:2020NatCo..11.3107W. doi:10.1038/s41467-020-16941-y. PMC 7305220. PMID 32561753. The second, more radical, group disagrees and argues that the needed socio-ecological transformation will necessarily entail a shift beyond capitalism and/or current centralised states. Although comprising considerable heterogeneity, it can be divided into eco-socialist approaches, viewing the democratic state as an important means to achieve the socio-ecological transformation and eco-anarchist approaches, aiming instead at participatory democracy without a state, thus minimising hierarchies. Many degrowth approaches combine elements of the two, but often see a stronger role for state action than eco-anarchists.
  80. ^ Eleanor Amico, ed. Reader's guide to women's studies (1998) pp. 102–04.
  81. ^ Janet Thomas, "Women and capitalism: oppression or emancipation? A review article". Comparative studies in society and history 30#3 (1988): 534–49. JSTOR 178999.
  82. ^ Alice Clark, Working life of women in the seventeenth century (1919).
  83. ^ Ivy Pinchbeck, Women Workers in the Industrial Revolution (1930).
  84. ^ Louise Tilly and Joan Wallach Scott, Women, work, and family (1987).

Further reading

  • Appleby, Joyce. The Relentless Revolution: A History of Capitalism (2011)
  • Business History Review, Special issue on Italy and the Origins of Capitalism, Business History Review, Volume 94 - Issue 1 - Spring 2020.
  • Cheta, Omar Youssef. "The economy by other means: The historiography of capitalism in the modern Middle East", History Compass (April 2018) 16#4 doi:10.1111/hic3.12444
  • Comninel, George C. "English feudalism and the origins of capitalism" Journal of Peasant Studies, 27#4 (2000), pp. 1–53 doi:10.1080/03066150008438748
  • Maurice Dobb and Paul Sweezy's famous debate on transition from feudalism to capitalism. Hilton, Rodney H. 1976. ed. The Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism.
    • Leftspot.com
  • Duplessis, Robert S. Transitions to Capitalism in Early Modern Europe (1997).
  • Friedman, Walter A. "Recent trends in business history research: Capitalism, democracy, and innovation". Enterprise & Society 18.4 (2017): 748–771.
  • Giddens, Anthony. Capitalism and modern social theory: An analysis of the writings of Marx, Durkheim and Max Weber (1971).
  • Hilt, Eric. "Economic History, Historical Analysis, and the 'New History of Capitalism'". Journal of Economic History (June 2017) 77#2 pp 511–536.
  • Kocka, Jürgen. Capitalism: A Short History (2016) excerpt
  • McCarraher, Eugene. The Enchantments of Mammon: How Capitalism Became the Religion of Modernity (2022) excerpt
  • Marx, Karl (1867) Das Kapital
  • Morton, Adam David. "The Age of Absolutism: capitalism, the modern states-system and international relations" Review of International Studies (2005), 31 : 495–517 Cambridge University Press doi:10.1017/S0260210505006601
  • Neal, Larry, and Jeffrey G. Williamson, eds. The Cambridge History of Capitalism (2 Vol 2016)
  • Olmstead, Alan L., and Paul W. Rhode. "Cotton, slavery, and the new history of capitalism". Explorations in Economic History 67 (2018): 1–17. online
  • O'Sullivan, Mary. "The Intelligent Woman's Guide to Capitalism". Enterprise & Society 19.4 (2018): 751–802. online
  • Nolan, Peter (2009) Crossroads: The end of wild capitalism. Marshall Cavendish, ISBN 978-0-462-09968-2
  • Patriquin, Larry "The Agrarian Origins of the Industrial Revolution in England" Review of Radical Political Economics, Vol. 36, No. 2, 196–216 (2004) doi:10.1177/0486613404264190
  • Perelman, Michael (2000) The Invention of Capitalism: Classical Political Economy and the Secret History of Primitive Accumulation. Duke University Press. ISBN 0-8223-2491-1, ISBN 978-0-8223-2491-1
  • Prak, Maarten; Zanden, Jan Luiten van (2022). Pioneers of Capitalism: The Netherlands 1000–1800. Princeton University Press.
  • Schuessler, Jennifer. "In History Departments, It's Up With Capitalism" April 6, 2013 The New York Times
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. Can capitalism survive? (1978)
  • James Denham-Steuart [1767] An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Economy vol 1, vol2, vol 3
  • Weber, Max. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (2002).
  • Zmolek, Mike (2000). "The case for Agrarian capitalism: A response to albritton" Journal of Peasant Studies, Volume 27, Issue 4 July 2000, pp. 138–59
  • Zmolek M. (2001) DEBATE – Further Thoughts on Agrarian Capitalism: A Reply to Albritton The Journal of Peasant Studies, Volume 29, Number 1, October 2001, pp. 129–54 (26)
  • Debating Agrarian Capitalism: A Rejoinder to Albritton
  • World Socialist Movement. "What Is Capitalism?" World Socialism. 13, August 2007.
  • Thomas K. McCraw, "The Current Crisis and the Essence of Capitalism", The Montreal Review (August, 2011)
  • Zofia Łapniewska, , Museum des Kapitalismus, Berlin 2014.

history, capitalism, this, article, multiple, issues, please, help, improve, discuss, these, issues, talk, page, learn, when, remove, these, template, messages, this, article, contains, weasel, words, vague, phrasing, that, often, accompanies, biased, unverifi. This article has multiple issues Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page Learn how and when to remove these template messages This article contains weasel words vague phrasing that often accompanies biased or unverifiable information Such statements should be clarified or removed May 2020 This article s lead section may be too short to adequately summarize the key points Please consider expanding the lead to provide an accessible overview of all important aspects of the article July 2020 This article may lend undue weight to certain ideas incidents or controversies Please help improve it by rewriting it in a balanced fashion that contextualizes different points of view March 2022 Learn how and when to remove this template message Learn how and when to remove this template message The history of capitalism is diverse and the concept of capitalism has many debated roots The history of the past 500 years is concerned with the development of capitalism in its various forms Capital accumulated by a variety of methods at a variety of scales became associated with much variation in the concentration of wealth and economic power Capitalism gradually became the dominant economic system throughout the world 1 2 need quotation to verify 3 need quotation to verify Contents 1 Historiography 1 1 Origins 1 1 1 Other views 1 2 21st century scholarship 2 Agrarian capitalism 2 1 Crisis of the 14th century 2 2 Enclosure 3 Merchant capitalism and mercantilism 3 1 Precedents 3 2 Emergence 3 3 Doctrines 3 4 Chartered trading companies 4 Industrial capitalism 4 1 Industrial Revolution 4 2 Finance 4 3 Free trade and globalization 5 20th century 5 1 Keynesianism and free markets 5 2 Globalization 6 21st century 7 Future 8 Role of women 9 See also 10 References 11 Further readingHistoriography EditThe processes by which capitalism emerged evolved and spread are the subject of extensive research and debate among historians Debates sometimes focus on how to bring substantive historical data to bear on key questions 4 Key parameters of debate include the extent to which capitalism is a natural human behavior versus the extent to which it arises from specific historical circumstances whether its origins lie in towns and trade or in rural property relations the role of class conflict the role of the state the extent to which capitalism is a distinctively European innovation its relationship with European imperialism whether technological change is a driver or merely a secondary byproduct of capitalism and whether or not it is the most beneficial way to organize human societies 5 The historiography of capitalism can be divided into two broad schools citation needed One is associated with economic liberalism with the 18th century economist Adam Smith as a foundational figure The other is associated with Marxism drawing particular inspiration from the 19th century economist Karl Marx Liberals view capitalism as an expression of natural human behaviors that have been in evidence for millennia and the most beneficial way of promoting human well being citation needed They see capitalism as originating in trade and commerce and freeing people to exercise their entrepreneurial natures citation needed Marxists view capitalism as a unique mode of production involving the bourgeoise and proletariat that emerged as a result of the fall of feudalism and the beginning of the Industrial Revolution This rejects the notion that capitalism has existed for millennia and is a part of human nature citation needed Origins Edit The origins of capitalism have been much debated and depend partly on how capitalism is defined The traditional account originating in classical 18th century liberal economic thought and still often articulated is the commercialisation model This sees capitalism originating in trade In this reading capitalism emerged from earlier trade once merchants had acquired sufficient wealth referred to as primitive capital to begin investing in increasingly productive technology This account tends to see capitalism as a continuation of trade arising when people s natural entrepreneurialism was freed from the constraints of feudalism partly by urbanisation 6 Thus it traces capitalism to early forms of merchant capitalism practiced in Western Europe during the Middle Ages 7 Other views Edit A competitor to the commercialisation model is the agrarian model citation needed which explains the rise of capitalism by unique circumstances in English agrarianism The evidence it cites is that traditional mercantilism focused on moving goods from markets where they were cheap to markets where they were expensive rather than investing in production and that many cultures including the early modern Dutch Republic saw urbanisation and the amassing of wealth by merchants without the emergence of capitalist production 8 9 The agrarian argument developed particularly through Karl Polanyi s The Great Transformation 1944 Maurice Dobb s Studies in the Development of Capitalism 1946 and Robert Brenner s research in the 1970s the discussion of which is known as the Brenner Debate In the wake of the Norman Conquest the English state was unusually centralised This gave aristocrats relatively limited powers to extract wealth directly from their feudal underlings through political means not least the threat of violence England s centralisation also meant that an unusual number of English farmers were not peasants with their own land and thus direct access to subsistence but tenants renting their land These circumstances produced a market in leases Landlords lacking other ways to extract wealth were motivated to rent to tenants who could pay the most while tenants lacking security of tenure were motivated to farm as productively as possible to win leases in a competitive market This led to a cascade of effects whereby successful tenant farmers became agrarian capitalists unsuccessful ones became wage labourers required to sell their labour in order to live and landlords promoted the privatisation and renting out of common land not least through the enclosures In this reading it was not merchants or manufacturers who drove the process that propelled the early development of capitalism The transformation of social property relations was firmly rooted in the countryside and the transformation of England s trade and industry was result more than cause of England s transition to capitalism 10 21st century scholarship Edit The 21st century has seen renewed interest in the history of capitalism and History of Capitalism has become a field in its own right with courses in history departments In the 2000s Harvard University founded the Program on the Study of U S Capitalism Cornell University established the History of Capitalism Initiative 11 and Columbia University Press launched a monograph series titled Studies in the History of U S Capitalism 12 This field includes topics such as insurance banking and regulation the political dimension and the impact on the middle classes the poor and women and minorities 13 14 These initiatives incorporate formerly neglected questions of race gender and sexuality into the history of capitalism They have grown in the aftermath of the financial crisis of 2007 2008 and the associated Great Recession Some academic institutions which are managed in part by free market think tanks such as the Clemson Institute for the Study of Capitalism reject the notion that race gender or sexuality have any significant relationship to capitalism at all and instead seek to show that laissez faire capitalism in particular provides the moral foundations of a just society and the most numerous economic opportunities for all people 15 16 Agrarian capitalism EditCrisis of the 14th century Edit Map of a medieval manor Notice the large commons area and the division of land into small strips The mustard colored areas are part of the demesne the hatched areas part of the glebe William R Shepherd Historical Atlas 01923 According to some historians 17 the modern capitalist system originated in the crisis of the Late Middle Ages a conflict between the land owning aristocracy and the agricultural producers or serfs Manorial arrangements inhibited the development of capitalism in a number of ways Serfs had obligations to produce for lords and therefore had no interest in technological innovation they also had no interest in cooperating with one another because they produced to sustain their own families The lords who owned the land citation needed relied on force to guarantee that they received sufficient food Because lords were not producing to sell on the market there was no competitive pressure for them to innovate Finally because lords expanded their power and wealth through military means they spent their wealth on military equipment or on conspicuous consumption that helped foster alliances with other lords they had no incentive to invest in developing new productive technologies 18 The demographic crisis of the 14th century upset this arrangement This crisis had several causes agricultural productivity reached its technological limitations and stopped growing bad weather led to the Great Famine of 1315 1317 and the Black Death of 1348 1350 led to a population crash These factors led to a decline in agricultural production In response feudal lords sought to expand agricultural production by extending their domains through warfare therefore they demanded more tribute from their serfs to pay for military expenses In England many serfs rebelled Some moved to towns some bought land and some entered into favorable contracts to rent lands from lords who needed to repopulate their estates 19 The collapse of the manorial system in England enlarged the class of tenant farmers with more freedom to market their goods and thus more incentive to invest in new technologies Lords who did not want to rely on renters could buy out or evict tenant farmers but then had to hire free labor to work their estates giving them an incentive to invest in two kinds of commodity owners One kind was those who had money the means of production and subsistence who were eager to valorize the sum of value they had appropriated by buying the labor power of others citation needed The other kind was free workers who sold their own labor The workers neither formed part of the means of production nor owned the means of production that transformed land and even money into what we now call capital 20 Marx labeled this period the pre history of capitalism 21 In effect feudalism began to lay some of the foundations necessary for the development of mercantilism a precursor of capitalism Feudalism lasted from the medieval period through the 16th century Feudal manors were almost entirely self sufficient and therefore limited the role of the market This stifled any incipient tendency towards capitalism However the relatively sudden emergence of new technologies and discoveries particularly in agriculture 22 and exploration facilitated the growth of capitalism The most important development at the end of feudalism citation needed was the emergence of what Robert Degan calls the dichotomy between wage earners and capitalist merchants 23 The competitive nature meant there are always winners and losers and this became clear as feudalism evolved into mercantilism an economic system characterized by the private or corporate ownership of capital goods investments determined by private decisions and by prices production and the distribution of goods determined mainly by competition in a free market citation needed Enclosure Edit Main article Enclosure Decaying hedges mark the lines of the straight field boundaries created by a Parliamentary Act of Enclosure England in the 16th century was already a centralized state in which much of the feudal order of Medieval Europe had been swept away This centralization was strengthened by a good system of roads and a disproportionately large capital city London 24 The capital acted as a central market for the entire country creating a large internal market for goods in contrast to the fragmented feudal holdings that prevailed in most parts of the Continent The economic foundations of the agricultural system were also beginning to diverge substantially the manorial system had broken down by this time and land began to be concentrated in the hands of fewer landlords with increasingly large estates The system put pressure on both the landlords and the tenants to increase agricultural productivity to create profit The weakened coercive power of the aristocracy to extract peasant surpluses encouraged them to try out better methods The tenants also had an incentive to improve their methods to succeed in an increasingly competitive labour market Land rents had moved away from the previous stagnant system of custom and feudal obligation and were becoming directly subject to economic market forces An important aspect of this process of change was the enclosure 25 of the common land previously held in the open field system where peasants had traditional rights such as mowing meadows for hay and grazing livestock Once enclosed these uses of the land became restricted to the owner and it ceased to be land for commons The process of enclosure began to be a widespread feature of the English agricultural landscape during the 16th century By the 19th century unenclosed commons had become largely restricted to rough pasture in mountainous areas and to relatively small parts of the lowlands Marxist and neo Marxist historians argue that rich landowners used their control of state processes to appropriate public land for their private benefit This created a landless working class that provided the labour required in the new industries developing in the north of England For example In agriculture the years between 1760 and 1820 are the years of wholesale enclosure in which in village after village common rights are lost 26 Enclosure when all the sophistications are allowed for was a plain enough case of class robbery 27 Anthropologist Jason Hickel notes that this process of enclosure led to myriad peasant revolts among them Kett s Rebellion and the Midland Revolt which culminated in violent repression and executions 28 Other scholars 29 argue that the better off members of the European peasantry encouraged and participated actively in enclosure seeking to end the perpetual poverty of subsistence farming We should be careful not to ascribe to enclosure developments that were the consequence of a much broader and more complex process of historical change 30 T he impact of eighteenth and nineteenth century enclosure has been grossly exaggerated 31 Merchant capitalism and mercantilism EditMain articles Merchant capitalism and Mercantilism Precedents Edit A painting of a French seaport from 1638 at the height of mercantilism While trade has existed since early in human history it was not capitalism 32 The earliest recorded activity of long distance profit seeking merchants can be traced to the Old Assyrian merchants active in Mesopotamia the 2nd millennium BCE 33 The Roman Empire developed more advanced forms of commerce and similarly widespread networks existed in Islamic nations However capitalism took shape in Europe in the late Middle Ages and Renaissance An early emergence of commerce occurred on monastic estates in Italy and France and in the independent city republics of Italy during the late Middle Ages Innovations in banking insurance accountancy and various production and commercial practices linked closely to a spirit of frugality reinvestment and city life promoted attitudes that sociologists have tended to associate only with northern Europe Protestantism and a much later age The city republics maintained their political independence from Empire and Church traded with North Africa the Middle East and Asia and introduced Eastern practices They were also considerably different from the absolutist monarchies of Spain and France and were strongly attached to civic liberty 34 35 36 Emergence Edit Modern capitalism only fully emerged in the early modern period between the 16th and 18th centuries with the establishment of mercantilism or merchant capitalism 37 38 Early evidence for mercantilistic practices appears in early modern Venice Genoa and Pisa over the Mediterranean trade in bullion The region of mercantilism s real birth however was the Atlantic Ocean 39 Sir Josiah Child an influential proponent of mercantilism Painting attributed to John Riley England began a large scale and integrative approach to mercantilism during the Elizabethan Era An early statement on national balance of trade appeared in Discourse of the Common Weal of this Realm of England 1549 We must always take heed that we buy no more from strangers than we sell them for so should we impoverish ourselves and enrich them 40 full citation needed The period featured various but often disjointed efforts by the court of Queen Elizabeth to develop a naval and merchant fleet capable of challenging the Spanish stranglehold on trade and of expanding the growth of bullion at home Elizabeth promoted the Trade and Navigation Acts in Parliament and issued orders to her navy for the protection and promotion of English shipping These efforts organized national resources sufficiently in the defense of England against the far larger and more powerful Spanish Empire and in turn paved the foundation for establishing a global empire in the 19th century citation needed The authors noted most for establishing the English mercantilist system include Gerard de Malynes and Thomas Mun who first articulated the Elizabethan System The latter s England s Treasure by Forraign Trade or the Balance of our Forraign Trade is The Rule of Our Treasure gave a systematic and coherent explanation of the concept of balance of trade It was written in the 1620s and published in 1664 41 Mercantile doctrines were further developed by Josiah Child Numerous French authors helped to cement French policy around mercantilism in the 17th century French mercantilism was best articulated by Jean Baptiste Colbert in office 1665 1683 although his policies were greatly liberalised under Napoleon Doctrines Edit Under mercantilism European merchants backed by state controls subsidies and monopolies made most of their profits from buying and selling goods In the words of Francis Bacon the purpose of mercantilism was the opening and well balancing of trade the cherishing of manufacturers the banishing of idleness the repressing of waste and excess by sumptuary laws the improvement and husbanding of the soil the regulation of prices 42 Similar practices of economic regimentation had begun earlier in medieval towns However under mercantilism given the contemporaneous rise of absolutism the state superseded the local guilds as the regulator of the economy The Anglo Dutch Wars were fought between the English and the Dutch for control over the seas and trade routes Among the major tenets of mercantilist theory was bullionism a doctrine stressing the importance of accumulating precious metals Mercantilists argued that a state should export more goods than it imported so that foreigners would have to pay the difference in precious metals Mercantilists asserted that only raw materials that could not be extracted at home should be imported They promoted the idea that government subsidies such as granting monopolies and protective tariffs were necessary to encourage home production of manufactured goods Proponents of mercantilism emphasized state power and overseas conquest as the principal aim of economic policy If a state could not supply its own raw materials according to the mercantilists it should acquire colonies from which they could be extracted Colonies constituted not only sources of raw materials but also markets for finished products Because it was not in the interests of the state to allow competition to help the mercantilists colonies should be prevented from engaging in manufacturing and trading with foreign powers Mercantilism was a system of trade for profit although commodities were still largely produced by non capitalist production methods 3 Noting the various pre capitalist features of mercantilism Karl Polanyi argued that mercantilism with all its tendency toward commercialization never attacked the safeguards which protected the two basic elements of production labor and land from becoming the elements of commerce Thus mercantilist regulation was more akin to feudalism than capitalism According to Polanyi not until 1834 was a competitive labor market established in England hence industrial capitalism as a social system cannot be said to have existed before that date 43 Chartered trading companies Edit British East India Company 1801 The Muscovy Company was the first major chartered joint stock English trading company It was established in 1555 with a monopoly on trade between England and Muscovy It was an offshoot of the earlier Company of Merchant Adventurers to New Lands founded in 1551 by Richard Chancellor Sebastian Cabot and Sir Hugh Willoughby to locate the Northeast Passage to China to allow trade This was the precursor to a type of business that would soon flourish in England the Dutch Republic and elsewhere The British East India Company 1600 and the Dutch East India Company 1602 launched an era of large state chartered trading companies 7 44 These companies were characterized by their monopoly on trade granted by letters patent provided by the state Recognized as chartered joint stock companies by the state these companies enjoyed lawmaking military and treaty making privileges 45 Characterized by its colonial and expansionary powers by states powerful nation states sought to accumulate precious metals and military conflicts arose 7 During this era merchants who had previously traded on their own invested capital in the East India Companies and other colonies seeking a return on investment Industrial capitalism Edit Gustave Dore s 19th century engraving depicted the dirty overcrowded slums where the industrial workers of London lived Mercantilism declined in Great Britain in the mid 18th century when a new group of economic theorists led by Adam Smith challenged fundamental mercantilist doctrines such as that the world s wealth remained constant and that a state could only increase its wealth at the expense of another state However mercantilism continued in less developed economies such as Prussia and Russia with their much younger manufacturing bases The mid 18th century gave rise to industrial capitalism made possible by 1 the accumulation of vast amounts of capital under the merchant phase of capitalism and its investment in machinery and 2 the fact that the enclosures meant that Britain had a large population of people with no access to subsistence agriculture who needed to buy basic commodities via the market ensuring a mass consumer market 46 Industrial capitalism which Marx dated from the last third of the 18th century marked the development of the factory system of manufacturing characterized by a complex division of labor between and within work processes and the routinization of work tasks Industrial capitalism finally established the global domination of the capitalist mode of production 37 During the resulting Industrial Revolution the industrialist replaced the merchant as a dominant actor in the capitalist system which led to the decline of the traditional handicraft skills of artisans guilds and journeymen Also during this period capitalism transformed relations between the British landowning gentry and peasants giving rise to the production of cash crops for the market rather than for subsistence on a feudal manor The surplus generated by the rise of commercial agriculture encouraged increased mechanization of agriculture Industrial Revolution Edit Main article Industrial Revolution The productivity gains of capitalist production began a sustained and unprecedented increase at the turn of the 19th century in a process commonly referred to as the Industrial Revolution Starting in about 1760 in England there was a steady transition to new manufacturing processes in a variety of industries including going from hand production methods to machine production new chemical manufacturing and iron production processes improved efficiency of water power the increasing use of steam power and the development of machine tools It also included the change from wood and other bio fuels to coal The Spinning mule built by the inventor Samuel Crompton In textile manufacturing mechanized cotton spinning powered by steam or water increased the output of a worker by a factor of about 1000 due to the application of James Hargreaves spinning jenny Richard Arkwright s water frame Samuel Crompton s Spinning Mule and other inventions The power loom increased the output of a worker by a factor of over 40 47 The cotton gin increased the productivity of removing seed from cotton by a factor of 50 Large gains in productivity also occurred in spinning and weaving wool and linen although they were not as great as in cotton Finance Edit The Rothschild family revolutionised international finance The Frankfurt terminus of the Taunus Railway was financed by the Rothschilds and opened in 1840 as one of Germany s first railways The growth of Britain s industry stimulated a concomitant growth in its system of finance and credit In the 18th century services offered by banks increased Clearing facilities security investments cheques and overdraft protections were introduced Cheques had been invented in the 17th century in England and banks settled payments by direct courier to the issuing bank Around 1770 they began meeting in a central location and by the 19th century a dedicated space was established known as a bankers clearing house The London clearing house used a method where each bank paid cash to and then was paid cash by an inspector at the end of each day The first overdraft facility was set up in 1728 by The Royal Bank of Scotland The end of the Napoleonic War and the subsequent rebound in trade led to an expansion in the bullion reserves held by the Bank of England from a low of under 4 million pounds in 1821 to 14 million pounds by late 1824 Older innovations became routine parts of financial life during the 19th century The Bank of England first issued bank notes during the 17th century but the notes were hand written and few in number After 1725 they were partially printed but cashiers still had to sign each note and make them payable to a named person In 1844 parliament passed the Bank Charter Act tying these notes to gold reserves effectively creating the institution of central banking and monetary policy The notes became fully printed and widely available from 1855 citation needed Growing international trade increased the number of banks especially in London These new merchant banks facilitated trade growth profiting from England s emerging dominance in seaborne shipping Two immigrant families Rothschild and Baring established merchant banking firms in London in the late 18th century and came to dominate world banking in the next century The tremendous wealth amassed by these banking firms soon attracted much attention The poet George Gordon Byron wrote in 1823 Who makes politics run glibber all The shade of Bonaparte s noble daring Jew Rothschild and his fellow Christian Baring The operation of banks also shifted At the beginning of the century banking was still an elite preoccupation of a handful of very wealthy families Within a few decades however a new sort of banking had emerged owned by anonymous stockholders run by professional managers and the recipient of the deposits of a growing body of small middle class savers Although this breed of banks was newly prominent it was not new the Quaker family Barclays had been banking in this way since 1690 Free trade and globalization Edit At the height of the First French Empire Napoleon sought to introduce a continental system that would render Europe economically autonomous thereby emasculating British trade and commerce It involved such stratagems as the use of beet sugar in preference to the cane sugar that had to be imported from the tropics Although this caused businessmen in England to agitate for peace Britain persevered in part because it was well into the industrial revolution The war had the opposite effect it stimulated the growth of certain industries such as pig iron production which increased from 68 000 tons in 1788 to 244 000 by 1806 citation needed 19th century Great Britain become the first global economic superpower because of superior manufacturing technology and improved global communications such as steamships and railroads In 1817 David Ricardo James Mill and Robert Torrens in the famous theory of comparative advantage argued that free trade would benefit the industrially weak as well as the strong In Principles of Political Economy and Taxation Ricardo advanced the doctrine still considered the most counterintuitive in economics When an inefficient producer sends the merchandise it produces best to a country able to produce it more efficiently both countries benefit By the mid 19th century Britain was firmly wedded to the notion of free trade and the first era of globalization began 37 In the 1840s the Corn Laws and the Navigation Acts were repealed ushering in a new age of free trade In line with the teachings of the classical political economists led by Adam Smith and David Ricardo Britain embraced liberalism encouraging competition and the development of a market economy Industrialization allowed cheap production of household items using economies of scale citation needed while rapid population growth created sustained demand for commodities Nineteenth century imperialism decisively shaped globalization in this period After the First and Second Opium Wars and the completion of the British conquest of India vast populations of these regions became ready consumers of European exports During this period areas of sub Saharan Africa and the Pacific islands were incorporated into the world system Meanwhile the European conquest of new parts of the globe notably sub Saharan Africa yielded valuable natural resources such as rubber diamonds and coal and helped fuel trade and investment between the European imperial powers their colonies and the United States 48 The gold standard formed the financial basis of the international economy from 1870 to 1914 The inhabitant of London could order by telephone sipping his morning tea the various products of the whole earth and reasonably expect their early delivery upon his doorstep Militarism and imperialism of racial and cultural rivalries were little more than the amusements of his daily newspaper What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man was that age which came to an end in August 1914 The global financial system was mainly tied to the gold standard during this period The United Kingdom first formally adopted this standard in 1821 Soon to follow was Canada in 1853 Newfoundland in 1865 and the United States and Germany de jure in 1873 New technologies such as the telegraph the transatlantic cable the Radiotelephone the steamship and the railway allowed goods and information to move around the world at an unprecedented degree 49 The eruption of civil war in the United States in 1861 and the blockade of its ports to international commerce meant that the main supply of cotton for the Lancashire looms was cut off The textile industries shifted to reliance upon cotton from Africa and Asia during the course of the U S civil war and this created pressure for an Anglo French controlled canal through the Suez peninsula The Suez canal opened in 1869 the same year in which the Central Pacific Railroad that spanned the North American continent was completed Capitalism and the engine of profit were making the globe a smaller place 20th century EditSeveral major challenges to capitalism appeared in the early part of the 20th century The Russian revolution in 1917 established the first state with a ruling communist party in the world a decade later the Great Depression triggered increasing criticism of the existing capitalist system One response to this crisis was a turn to fascism an ideology that advocated state capitalism 50 Another response was to reject capitalism altogether in favour of communist or democratic socialist ideologies Keynesianism and free markets Edit Main articles Keynesian economics and Neoliberalism The New York stock exchange traders floor 1963 The economic recovery of the world s leading capitalist economies in the period following the end of the Great Depression and the Second World War a period of unusually rapid growth by historical standards eased discussion of capitalism s eventual decline or demise 51 The state began to play an increasingly prominent role to moderate and regulate the capitalistic system throughout much of the world Keynesian economics became a widely accepted method of government regulation and countries such as the United Kingdom experimented with mixed economies in which the state owned and operated certain major industries The state also expanded in the US in 1929 total government expenditures amounted to less than one tenth of GNP from the 1970s they amounted to around one third 38 Similar increases were seen in all industrialised capitalist economies some of which such as France have reached even higher ratios of government expenditures to GNP than the United States A broad array of new analytical tools in the social sciences were developed to explain the social and economic trends of the period including the concepts of post industrial society and the welfare state 37 The long post war boom ended in the 1970s amid the economic crises experienced following the 1973 oil crisis 52 The stagflation of the 1970s led many economic commentators and politicians to embrace market oriented policy prescriptions inspired by the laissez faire capitalism and classical liberalism of the nineteenth century particularly under the influence of Friedrich Hayek and Milton Friedman The theoretical alternative to Keynesianism was more compatible with laissez faire and emphasised rapid expansion of the economy Market oriented solutions gained increasing support in the Western world especially under the leadership of Ronald Reagan in the United States and Margaret Thatcher in the UK in the 1980s Public and political interest began shifting away from the so called collectivist concerns of Keynes s managed capitalism to a focus on individual choice called remarketized capitalism 53 The three booming decades that followed the Second World War according to political economist Clara E Mattei were an anomaly in the history of contemporary capitalism She writes that austerity did not originate with the emergence of the neoliberal era starting in the 1970s but has been the mainstay of capitalism 54 Globalization Edit The New York Stock Exchange Although overseas trade has been associated with the development of capitalism for over five hundred years some thinkers argue that a number of trends associated with globalisation have acted to increase the mobility of people and capital since the last quarter of the twentieth century combining to circumscribe the room to manoeuvre of states in choosing non capitalist models of development Today these trends have bolstered the argument that capitalism should now be viewed as a truly world system Burnham However other thinkers argue that globalisation even in its quantitative degree is no greater now than during earlier periods of capitalist trade 55 After the abandonment of the Bretton Woods system in 1971 and the strict state control of foreign exchange rates the total value of transactions in foreign exchange was estimated to be at least twenty times greater than that of all foreign movements of goods and services EB The internationalisation of finance which some see as beyond the reach of state control combined with the growing ease with which large corporations have been able to relocate their operations to low wage states has posed the question of the eclipse of state sovereignty arising from the growing globalization of capital 56 While economists generally agree about the size of global income inequality citation needed there is a general disagreement about the recent direction of change of it 57 In cases such as China where income inequality is clearly growing 58 it is also evident that overall economic growth has rapidly increased with capitalist reforms 59 The book The Improving State of the World published by the libertarian think tank Cato Institute argues that economic growth since the Industrial Revolution has been very strong and that factors such as adequate nutrition life expectancy infant mortality literacy prevalence of child labor education and available free time have improved greatly 60 Some scholars including Stephen Hawking 61 and researchers for the International Monetary Fund 62 63 contend that globalization and neoliberal economic policies are not ameliorating inequality and poverty but exacerbating it 64 65 66 and are creating new forms of contemporary slavery 67 68 Such policies are also expanding populations of the displaced the unemployed and the imprisoned 69 70 along with accelerating the destruction of the environment 64 and species extinction 71 72 In 2017 the IMF warned that inequality within nations in spite of global inequality falling in recent decades has risen so sharply that it threatens economic growth and could result in further political polarization 73 Surging economic inequality following the economic crisis and the anger associated with it have resulted in a resurgence of socialist and nationalist ideas throughout the Western world which has some economic elites from places including Silicon Valley Davos and Harvard Business School concerned about the future of capitalism 74 21st century EditBy the beginning of the twenty first century mixed economies with capitalist elements had become the pervasive economic systems worldwide The collapse of the Soviet bloc in 1991 significantly reduced the influence of socialism as an alternative economic system Leftist movements continue to be influential in some parts of the world most notably Latin American Bolivarianism with some having ties to more traditional anti capitalist movements such as Bolivarian Venezuela s ties to Cuba In many emerging markets the influence of banking and financial capital have come to increasingly shape national developmental strategies leading some to argue we are in a new phase of financial capitalism 75 State intervention in global capital markets following the financial crisis of 2007 2010 was perceived by some as signalling a crisis for free market capitalism Serious turmoil in the banking system and financial markets due in part to the subprime mortgage crisis reached a critical stage during September 2008 characterised by severely contracted liquidity in the global credit markets posed an existential threat to investment banks and other institutions 76 77 Future EditAccording to some who 78 the transition to the information society involves abandoning some parts of capitalism as the capital required to produce and process information becomes available to the masses and difficult to control and is closely related to the controversial issues of intellectual property Some 78 even speculate that the development of mature nanotechnology particularly of universal assemblers may make capitalism obsolete with capital ceasing to be an important factor in the economic life of humanity Various thinkers have also explored what kind of economic system might replace capitalism such as Bob Avakian Jason Hickel Paul Mason Richard D Wolff and contributors to the Scientists warning on affluence 79 Role of women EditWomen s historians have debated the impact of capitalism on the status of women 80 81 Alice Clark argues that when capitalism arrived in 17th century England it negatively impacted the status of women who lost much of their economic importance Clark argues that in 16th century England women were engaged in many aspects of industry and agriculture The home was a central unit of production and women played a vital role in running farms and in some trades and landed estates Their useful economic roles gave them a sort of equality with their husbands However Clark argues as capitalism expanded in the 17th century there was more and more division of labor with the husband taking paid labor jobs outside the home and the wife reduced to unpaid household work Middle class women were confined to an idle domestic existence supervising servants lower class women were forced to take poorly paid jobs Capitalism therefore had a negative effect on women 82 By contrast Ivy Pinchbeck argues that capitalism created the conditions for women s emancipation 83 Tilly and Scott have emphasized the continuity and the status of women finding three stages in European history In the preindustrial era production was mostly for home use and women produced many household needs The second stage was the family wage economy of early industrialization During this stage the entire family depended on the collective wages of its members including husband wife and older children The third or modern stage is the family consumer economy in which the family is the site of consumption and women are employed in large numbers in retail and clerical jobs to support rising standards of consumption 84 See also Edit Business and economics portalBrenner debate Capitalism and Islam Capitalist mode of production Enclosure and British Agricultural Revolution Fernand Braudel Financial crisis of 2007 2008 History of capitalist theory History of globalization History of private equity and venture capital Primitive accumulation of capital Protestant work ethic Simple commodity productionReferences Edit Compare Rogers Alisdair Castree Noel Kitchin Rob 2013 capitalism A Dictionary of Human Geography Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 959986 8 Retrieved 2019 08 11 Capitalism is the world s dominant economic system but was virtually non existent three hundred years ago Calhoun Craig 2002 capitalism Dictionary of the Social Sciences Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 512371 5 Retrieved 2019 08 11 a b Scott John Marshall Gordon 2005 capitalism Oxford Dictionary of Sociology 3rd ed Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 860986 5 Richard Biernacki review of Ellen Meiksins Wood 1999 The Origin of Capitalism Monthly Review Press 1999 in Contemporary Sociology Vol 29 No 4 Jul 2000 pp 638 39 JSTOR 2654574 Ellen Meiksins Wood 2002 The Origin of Capitalism A Longer View London Verso 2002 Ellen Meiksins Wood 2002 The Origin of Capitalism A Longer View London Verso 2002 pp 11 21 a b c Jairus Banaji 2007 Islam the Mediterranean and the rise of capitalism Journal Historical Materialism 15 1 pp 47 74 Brill Publishers Ellen Meiksins Wood 2002 The Origin of Capitalism A Longer View London Verso 2002 pp 11 21 Chris Harman The Rise of Capitalism International Socialism Journal 102 Spring 2004 Ellen Meiksins Wood 2002 The Origin of Capitalism A Longer View London Verso 2002 quoting p 129 Jennifer Schuessler In History Departments It s Up with Capitalism The New York Times April 6 2013 Columbia Studies in the History of U S Capitalism Columbia University Press columbia edu See Jennifer Schuessler In History Departments It s Up With Capitalism The New York Times April 6 2013 Lou Galambos Is This a Decisive Moment for the History of Business Economic History and the History of Capitalism Essays in Economic amp Business History 2014 v 32 pp 1 18 online About Clemson Institute for the Study of Capitalism Wilbur O and Ann Powers College of Business Clemson University South Carolina www clemson edu Retrieved 2021 03 19 Brutzman Anna Gift to Clemson comes with strings Independent Mail Hickel Jason 2017 3 Where did poverty come from A creation story The divide a brief guide to global inequality and its solutions London ISBN 9781785151125 OCLC 984907212 Brenner Robert 1977 The Origins of Capitalist Development a Critique of Neo Smithian Marxism in New Left Review 104 36 37 46 Dobb Maurice 1947 Studies in the Development of Capitalism New York International Publishers Co Inc 42 46 48 ff Marx Karl 1867 1976 Capital A Critique of Political Economy Volume One trans Ben Fowkes Harmondsworth and London Penguin Books and New Left Review 874 Marx Karl 1867 1976 Capital A Critique of Political Economy Volume One trans Ben Fowkes Harmondsworth and London Penguin Books and New Left Review 875 James Fulcher Capitalism New York Oxford University Press 2004 19 Degen Robert A 2011 12 31 The Triumph of Capitalism New Brunswick New Jersey Transaction Publishers published 2011 p 12 ISBN 9781412809856 Retrieved 2016 01 13 By the early 1400s power came to be shared in an arrangement giving representation to various segments of the social order but the dichotomy between wage earners and capitalist merchants remained Ellen Meikisins Wood The Origin of Capitalism A Longer View 2nd edn London Verso 2002 p 99 Enclosure is the modern spelling while inclosure is an older spelling still used in the United Kingdom in legal documents and place names Thompson E P 1991 The Making of the English Working Class Penguin p 217 A comparison of the English historical enclosures with the much later German 19th century Landflucht Engels Friedrich 1882 Die Mark Die Entwicklung des Sozialismus von der Utopie zur Wissenschaft Hottingen Zurich Marx Karl Engels Friedrich Werke 1973 reprint of 196t 1st ed Berlin Karl Dietz Hickel Jason 2018 The Divide A Brief Guide to Global Inequality and its Solutions Windmill Books pp 78 79 ISBN 978 1786090034 W A Armstrong Chambers J D Mingay G E 1982 The Agricultural Revolution 1750 1850 Reprinted ed Batsford p 104 Armstrong W A 1981 The Influence of Demographic Factors on the Position of the Agricultural Labourer in England and Wales c 1750 1914 in Agricultural History Review The Agricultural History Review Vol 29 British Agricultural History Society p 79 Ellen Meiksins Wood 2002 The Origin of Capitalism A Longer View London Verso 2002 pp 73 94 Warburton David Macroeconomics from the beginning The General Theory Ancient Markets and the Rate of Interest Paris Recherches et Publications 2003 p 49 Stark Rodney Victory of Reason Random House New York 2005 Ferguson Niall The Ascent of Money Penguin 2008 Skinner Quentin The Foundations of Modern Political Thought vol I The Renaissance vol II The Age of Reformation Cambridge University Press 1978 a b c d Burnham Peter Capitalism the Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics 2003 Oxford Oxford University Press a b Encyclopaedia Britannica 2006 John J McCusker Mercantilism and the Economic History of the Early Modern Atlantic World Cambridge UP 2001 Now attributed to Sir Thomas Smith quoted in Braudel 1979 harvtxt error no target CITEREFBraudel1979 help p 204 David Onnekink Gijs Rommelse 2011 Ideology and Foreign Policy in Early Modern Europe 1650 1750 Ashgate Publishing Ltd p 257 ISBN 9781409419143 Quoted in Sir George Clark The Seventeenth Century New York Oxford University Press 1961 p 24 Polanyi Karl The Great Transformation Beacon Press Boston 1944 p 87 Economic system Market systems Encyclopaedia Britannica 2006 chartered company Archived from the original on 2009 01 09 Ellen Meiksins Wood 2002 The Origin of Capitalism A Longer View London Verso 2002 pp 142 46 Ayres Robert 1989 Technological Transformations and Long Waves PDF International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis pp 16 17 ISBN 3 7045 0092 5 Archived from the original PDF on 2012 03 01 Retrieved 2014 01 02 PBS org PBS org 1929 10 24 Retrieved 2010 07 31 Michael D Bordo Barry Eichengreen Douglas A Irwin Is Globalization Today Really Different than Globalization a Hundred Years Ago NBER Working Paper No 7195 June 1999 Reich Wilhelm 1970 The Mass Psychology of Fascism Macmillan pp 277 281 ISBN 978 0 374 20364 1 Stanley Engerman Seymour Drescher Robert Paquette 2001 Slavery Oxford Readers Oxford University Press Barnes Trevor J 2004 Reading economic geography Blackwell Publishing p 127 ISBN 0 631 23554 X Fulcher James Capitalism 1st ed New York Oxford University Press 2004 Mattei Clara E 2022 The Capital Order How Economists Invented Austerity and Paved the Way to Fascism University of Chicago Press p 3 ISBN 978 0226818399 Austerity is not new nor is it a product of the so called Neoliberal Era that began in the 1970s Outside perhaps of the less than three booming decades that followed World War II austerity has been the mainstay of capitalism It has been true throughout history that where capitalism exists crisis follows Where austerity has proven wildly effective is in insulating capitalist hierarchies from harm during these moments of would be social change Doug Henwood is an economist who has argued that the heyday of globalisation was during the mid nineteenth century For example he writes in What Is Globalization Anyway Not only is the novelty of globalization exaggerated so is its extent Capital flows were freer and foreign holdings by British investors far larger 100 years ago than anything we see today Images of multinational corporations shuttling raw materials and parts around the world as if the whole globe were an assembly line are grossly overblown accounting for only about a tenth of U S trade 1 See also Henwood Doug October 1 2003 After the New Economy New Press ISBN 1 56584 770 9 For an assessment of this question see Peter Evans The Eclipse of the State Reflections on Stateness in an Era of Globalization World Politics 50 1 October 1997 62 87 Milanovic Branko 2006 08 01 Global Income Inequality What It Is And Why It Matters Technical report DESA Working Paper Vol 26 p 9 Brooks David 2004 11 27 Good News about Poverty Retrieved 2008 02 26 Fengbo Zhang Speech at Future China Global Forum 2010 China Rising with the Reform and Open Policy Dahl Robert 2000 On Democracy Yale University Yale Nota Bene pp 168 ISBN 0 300 07627 4 This is the most dangerous time for our planet Stephen Hawking via The Guardian 1 December 2016 Neoliberalism Oversold IMF Finance amp Development June 2016 Volume 53 Number 2 IMF The last generation of economic policies may have been a complete failure Business Insider May 2016 a b Jones Campbell Martin Parker and Rene Ten Bos For Business Ethics Routledge 2005 ISBN 0415311357 p 101 Stephen Haymes Maria Vidal de Haymes and Reuben Miller eds The Routledge Handbook of Poverty in the United States London Routledge 2015 ISBN 0415673445 pp 1 2 Jason Hickel February 13 2019 An Open Letter to Steven Pinker and Bill Gates Jacobin Retrieved February 14 2019 Bales Kevin 2012 Disposable People New Slavery in the Global Economy University of California Press ISBN 978 0520272910 Zizek Slavoj 2018 The Courage of Hopelessness A Year of Acting Dangerously Melville House p 29 ISBN 978 1612190037 Saskia Sassen Expulsions Brutality and Complexity in the Global Economy Harvard University Press 2014 ISBN 0674599225 Loic Wacquant Prisons of Poverty University of Minnesota Press 2009 p 55 ISBN 0816639019 Dawson Ashley 2016 Extinction A Radical History OR Books p 41 ISBN 978 1944869014 Harvey David 2005 A Brief History of Neoliberalism Oxford University Press p 173 ISBN 0199283273 Dunsmuir Lindsay October 11 2017 IMF calls for fiscal policies that tackle rising inequality Reuters Retrieved November 4 2017 Jaffe Greg April 20 2019 Capitalism in crisis U S billionaires worry about the survival of the system that made them rich The Washington Post Retrieved April 24 2019 Marois Thomas 2012 States Banks and Crisis Emerging Finance Capitalism in Mexico and Turkey Cheltenham Gloucestershire UK Edward Elgar Publishing President Bush Meets with Bicameral and Bipartisan Members of Congress to Discuss Economy Whitehouse gov September 25 2008 House votes down bail out package 29 September 2008 via news bbc co uk a b Kaku Michio 1999 Visions How Science Will Revolutionize the 21st Century and Beyond New York Oxford University Press ISBN 0 19 288018 7 Wiedmann Thomas Lenzen Manfred Keysser Lorenz T Steinberger Julia K 2020 Scientists warning on affluence Nature Communications 11 3107 3107 Bibcode 2020NatCo 11 3107W doi 10 1038 s41467 020 16941 y PMC 7305220 PMID 32561753 The second more radical group disagrees and argues that the needed socio ecological transformation will necessarily entail a shift beyond capitalism and or current centralised states Although comprising considerable heterogeneity it can be divided into eco socialist approaches viewing the democratic state as an important means to achieve the socio ecological transformation and eco anarchist approaches aiming instead at participatory democracy without a state thus minimising hierarchies Many degrowth approaches combine elements of the two but often see a stronger role for state action than eco anarchists Eleanor Amico ed Reader s guide to women s studies 1998 pp 102 04 Janet Thomas Women and capitalism oppression or emancipation A review article Comparative studies in society and history 30 3 1988 534 49 JSTOR 178999 Alice Clark Working life of women in the seventeenth century 1919 Ivy Pinchbeck Women Workers in the Industrial Revolution 1930 Louise Tilly and Joan Wallach Scott Women work and family 1987 Further reading EditAppleby Joyce The Relentless Revolution A History of Capitalism 2011 Business History Review Special issue on Italy and the Origins of Capitalism Business History Review Volume 94 Issue 1 Spring 2020 Cheta Omar Youssef The economy by other means The historiography of capitalism in the modern Middle East History Compass April 2018 16 4 doi 10 1111 hic3 12444 Comninel George C English feudalism and the origins of capitalism Journal of Peasant Studies 27 4 2000 pp 1 53 doi 10 1080 03066150008438748 Maurice Dobb and Paul Sweezy s famous debate on transition from feudalism to capitalism Hilton Rodney H 1976 ed The Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism blog on the Dobb Sweezy debate Leftspot com Duplessis Robert S Transitions to Capitalism in Early Modern Europe 1997 Friedman Walter A Recent trends in business history research Capitalism democracy and innovation Enterprise amp Society 18 4 2017 748 771 Giddens Anthony Capitalism and modern social theory An analysis of the writings of Marx Durkheim and Max Weber 1971 Hilt Eric Economic History Historical Analysis and the New History of Capitalism Journal of Economic History June 2017 77 2 pp 511 536 online Kocka Jurgen Capitalism A Short History 2016 excerpt McCarraher Eugene The Enchantments of Mammon How Capitalism Became the Religion of Modernity 2022 excerpt Marx Karl 1867 Das Kapital Morton Adam David The Age of Absolutism capitalism the modern states system and international relations Review of International Studies 2005 31 495 517 Cambridge University Press doi 10 1017 S0260210505006601 Neal Larry and Jeffrey G Williamson eds The Cambridge History of Capitalism 2 Vol 2016 Olmstead Alan L and Paul W Rhode Cotton slavery and the new history of capitalism Explorations in Economic History 67 2018 1 17 online O Sullivan Mary The Intelligent Woman s Guide to Capitalism Enterprise amp Society 19 4 2018 751 802 online Nolan Peter 2009 Crossroads The end of wild capitalism Marshall Cavendish ISBN 978 0 462 09968 2 Patriquin Larry The Agrarian Origins of the Industrial Revolution in England Review of Radical Political Economics Vol 36 No 2 196 216 2004 doi 10 1177 0486613404264190 Perelman Michael 2000 The Invention of Capitalism Classical Political Economy and the Secret History of Primitive Accumulation Duke University Press ISBN 0 8223 2491 1 ISBN 978 0 8223 2491 1 Prak Maarten Zanden Jan Luiten van 2022 Pioneers of Capitalism The Netherlands 1000 1800 Princeton University Press Schuessler Jennifer In History Departments It s Up With Capitalism April 6 2013 The New York Times Schumpeter Joseph A Can capitalism survive 1978 James Denham Steuart 1767 An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Economy vol 1 vol2 vol 3 Weber Max The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism 2002 Zmolek Mike 2000 The case for Agrarian capitalism A response to albritton Journal of Peasant Studies Volume 27 Issue 4 July 2000 pp 138 59 Zmolek M 2001 DEBATE Further Thoughts on Agrarian Capitalism A Reply to Albritton The Journal of Peasant Studies Volume 29 Number 1 October 2001 pp 129 54 26 Debating Agrarian Capitalism A Rejoinder to Albritton Research in Political Economy Volume 22 The Roots of Merchant Capitalism World Socialist Movement What Is Capitalism World Socialism 13 August 2007 Thomas K McCraw The Current Crisis and the Essence of Capitalism The Montreal Review August 2011 Zofia Lapniewska History of Capitalism Museum des Kapitalismus Berlin 2014 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title History of capitalism amp oldid 1131522403, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.