fbpx
Wikipedia

Balance of trade

Balance of trade can be measured in terms of commercial balance, or net exports. Balance of trade is the difference between the monetary value of a nation's exports and imports over a certain time period.[1] Sometimes a distinction is made between a balance of trade for goods versus one for services. The balance of trade measures a flow variable of exports and imports over a given period of time. The notion of the balance of trade does not mean that exports and imports are "in balance" with each other.

Cumulative current account balance 1980–2008 based on International Monetary Fund data
Cumulative current account balance per capita 1980–2008 based on International Monetary Fund data

If a country exports a greater value than it imports, it has a trade surplus or positive trade balance, and conversely, if a country imports a greater value than it exports, it has a trade deficit or negative trade balance. As of 2016, about 60 out of 200 countries have a trade surplus. The notion that bilateral trade deficits are bad in and of themselves is overwhelmingly rejected by trade experts and economists.[2][3][4][5]

Explanation edit

 
Balance of trade in goods and services (Eurozone countries)
 
US trade balance from 1960
 
U.S. trade balance and trade policy (1895–2015)
 
U.K. balance of trade in goods (since 1870)

The balance of trade forms part of the current account, which includes other transactions such as income from the net international investment position as well as international aid. If the current account is in surplus, the country's net international asset position increases correspondingly. Equally, a deficit decreases the net international asset position.

The trade balance is identical to the difference between a country's output and its domestic demand (the difference between what goods a country produces and how many goods it buys from abroad; this does not include money re-spent on foreign stock, nor does it factor in the concept of importing goods to produce for the domestic market).

Measuring the balance of trade can be problematic because of problems with recording and collecting data. As an illustration of this problem, when official data for all the world's countries are added up, exports exceed imports by almost 1%; it appears the world is running a positive balance of trade with itself. This cannot be true, because all transactions involve an equal credit or debit in the account of each nation. The discrepancy is widely believed to be explained by transactions intended to launder money or evade taxes, smuggling and other visibility problems. While the accuracy of developing countries' statistics would be suspicious, most of the discrepancy actually occurs between developed countries of trusted statistics.[6][7][8]

Factors that can affect the balance of trade include:

  • The cost of production (land, labor, capital, taxes, incentives, etc.) in the exporting economy vis-à-vis those in the importing economy;
  • The cost and availability of raw materials, intermediate goods and other inputs;
  • Currency exchange rate movements;
  • Multilateral, bilateral and unilateral taxes or restrictions on trade;
  • Non-tariff barriers such as environmental, health or safety standards;
  • The availability of adequate foreign exchange with which to pay for imports; and
  • Prices of goods manufactured at home (influenced by the responsiveness of supply)

In addition, the trade balance is likely to differ across the business cycle. In export-led growth (such as oil and early industrial goods), the balance of trade will shift towards exports during an economic expansion.[citation needed] However, with domestic demand-led growth (as in the United States and Australia) the trade balance will shift towards imports at the same stage in the business cycle.

The monetary balance of trade is different from the physical balance of trade[9] (which is expressed in amount of raw materials, known also as Total Material Consumption). Developed countries usually import a substantial amount of raw materials from developing countries. Typically, these imported materials are transformed into finished products and might be exported after adding value. Financial trade balance statistics conceal material flow. Most developed countries have a large physical trade deficit because they consume more raw materials than they produce.

Examples edit

Historical example edit

Many countries in early modern Europe adopted a policy of mercantilism, which theorized that a trade surplus was beneficial to a country. Mercantilist ideas also influenced how European nations regulated trade policies with their colonies, promoting the idea that natural resources and cash crops should be exported to Europe, with processed goods being exported back to the colonies in return. Ideas such as bullionism spurred the popularity of mercantilism in European governments.[10]

 
Merchandise exports (1870–1992)
 
Trade policy, exports and growth in selected European countries

An early statement concerning the balance of trade appeared in Discourse of the Common Wealth of this Realm of England, 1549: "We must always take heed that we buy no more from strangers than we sell them, for so should we impoverish ourselves and enrich them."[11] Similarly, a systematic and coherent explanation of balance of trade was made public through Thomas Mun's 1630 "England's treasure by foreign trade, or, The balance of our foreign trade is the rule of our treasure".[12]

Since the mid-1980s, the United States has had a growing deficit in tradeable goods, especially with Asian nations (China and Japan) which now hold large sums of U.S debt that has in part funded the consumption.[13][14][15] The U.S. has a trade surplus with nations such as Australia. The issue of trade deficits can be complex. Trade deficits generated in tradeable goods such as manufactured goods or software may impact domestic employment to different degrees than do trade deficits in raw materials.[14]

Economies that have savings surpluses, such as Japan and Germany, typically run trade surpluses. China, a high-growth economy, has tended to run trade surpluses. A higher savings rate generally corresponds to a trade surplus. Correspondingly, the U.S. with its lower savings rate has tended to run high trade deficits, especially with Asian nations.[14]

Some have said that China pursues a mercantilist economic policy.[16][17][18] Russia pursues a policy based on protectionism, according to which international trade is not a "win-win" game but a zero-sum game: surplus countries get richer at the expense of deficit countries.[19][20][21][22]

Views on economic impact edit

The notion that bilateral trade deficits are bad in and of themselves is overwhelmingly rejected by trade experts and economists.[23][2][3][4][5] According to the IMF trade deficits can cause a balance of payments problem, which can affect foreign exchange shortages and hurt countries.[24] On the other hand, Joseph Stiglitz points out that countries running surpluses exert a "negative externality" on trading partners, and pose a threat to global prosperity, far more than those in deficit.[25][26][27] Ben Bernanke argues that "persistent imbalances within the euro zone are... unhealthy, as they lead to financial imbalances as well as to unbalanced growth. The fact that Germany is selling so much more than it is buying redirects demand from its neighbors (as well as from other countries around the world), reducing output and employment outside Germany."[28] According to Carla Norrlöf, there are three main benefits to trade deficits for the United States:[29]

  1. Greater consumption than production: the US enjoys the better side of the bargain by being able to consume more than it produces
  2. Usage of efficiently produced foreign-made intermediate goods is productivity-enhancing for US firms: the US makes the most effective use of the global division of labor
  3. A large market that other countries are reliant on for exports enhances American bargaining power in trade negotiations

A 2018 National Bureau of Economic Research paper by economists at the International Monetary Fund and University of California, Berkeley, found in a study of 151 countries over 1963-2014 that the imposition of tariffs had little effect on the trade balance.[30]

Classical theory edit

Adam Smith on the balance of trade edit

In the foregoing part of this chapter I have endeavoured to show, even upon the principles of the commercial system, how unnecessary it is to lay extraordinary restraints upon the importation of goods from those countries with which the balance of trade is supposed to be disadvantageous. Nothing, however, can be more absurd than this whole doctrine of the balance of trade, upon which, not only these restraints, but almost all the other regulations of commerce are founded. When two places trade with one another, this [absurd] doctrine supposes that, if the balance be even, neither of them either loses or gains; but if it leans in any degree to one side, that one of them loses and the other gains in proportion to its declension from the exact equilibrium.

— Smith, 1776, book IV, ch. iii, part ii[31]

Keynesian theory edit

In the last few years of his life, John Maynard Keynes was much preoccupied with the question of balance in international trade. He was the leader of the British delegation to the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference in 1944 that established the Bretton Woods system of international currency management. He was the principal author of a proposal – the so-called Keynes Plan – for an International Clearing Union. The two governing principles of the plan were that the problem of settling outstanding balances should be solved by 'creating' additional 'international money', and that debtor and creditor should be treated almost alike as disturbers of equilibrium. In the event, though, the plans were rejected, in part because "American opinion was naturally reluctant to accept the principle of equality of treatment so novel in debtor-creditor relationships".[32]

The new system is not founded on free-trade (liberalisation[33] of foreign trade[34]) but rather on the regulation of international trade, in order to eliminate trade imbalances: the nations with a surplus would have a powerful incentive to get rid of it, and in doing so they would automatically clear other nations' deficits.[35] He proposed a global bank that would issue its own currency – the bancor – which was exchangeable with national currencies at fixed rates of exchange and would become the unit of account between nations, which means it would be used to measure a country's trade deficit or trade surplus. Every country would have an overdraft facility in its bancor account at the International Clearing Union. He pointed out that surpluses lead to weak global aggregate demand – countries running surpluses exert a "negative externality" on trading partners, and posed far more than those in deficit, a threat to global prosperity.[36] In "National Self-Sufficiency" The Yale Review, Vol. 22, no. 4 (June 1933),[37][38] he already highlighted the problems created by free trade.

His view, supported by many economists and commentators at the time, was that creditor nations may be just as responsible as debtor nations for disequilibrium in exchanges and that both should be under an obligation to bring trade back into a state of balance. Failure for them to do so could have serious consequences. In the words of Geoffrey Crowther, then editor of The Economist, "If the economic relationships between nations are not, by one means or another, brought fairly close to balance, then there is no set of financial arrangements that can rescue the world from the impoverishing results of chaos."[39]

These ideas were informed by events prior to the Great Depression when – in the opinion of Keynes and others – international lending, primarily by the U.S., exceeded the capacity of sound investment and so got diverted into non-productive and speculative uses, which in turn invited default and a sudden stop to the process of lending.[40]

Influenced by Keynes, economics texts in the immediate post-war period put a significant emphasis on balance in trade. For example, the second edition of the popular introductory textbook, An Outline of Money,[41] devoted the last three of its ten chapters to questions of foreign exchange management and in particular the 'problem of balance'. However, in more recent years, since the end of the Bretton Woods system in 1971, with the increasing influence of monetarist schools of thought in the 1980s, and particularly in the face of large sustained trade imbalances, these concerns – and particularly concerns about the destabilising effects of large trade surpluses – have largely disappeared from mainstream economics discourse[42] and Keynes' insights have slipped from view.[43] They are receiving some attention again in the wake of the financial crisis of 2007–08.[44]

Monetarist theory edit

Prior to 20th-century monetarist theory, the 19th-century economist and philosopher Frédéric Bastiat expressed the idea that trade deficits actually were a manifestation of profit, rather than a loss. He proposed as an example to suppose that he, a Frenchman, exported French wine and imported British coal, turning a profit. He supposed he was in France and sent a cask of wine which was worth 50 francs to England. The customhouse would record an export of 50 francs. If in England, the wine sold for 70 francs (or the pound equivalent), which he then used to buy coal, which he imported into France (the customhouse would record an import of 70 francs), and was found to be worth 90 francs in France, he would have made a profit of 40 francs. But the customhouse would say that the value of imports exceeded that of exports and was trade deficit of 20 against the ledger of France.This is not true for the current account that would be in surplus.

By reductio ad absurdum, Bastiat argued that the national trade deficit was an indicator of a successful economy, rather than a failing one. Bastiat predicted that a successful, growing economy would result in greater trade deficits, and an unsuccessful, shrinking economy would result in lower trade deficits. This was later, in the 20th century, echoed by economist Milton Friedman.

In the 1980s, Friedman, a Nobel Memorial Prize-winning economist and a proponent of monetarism, contended that some of the concerns of trade deficits are unfair criticisms in an attempt to push macroeconomic policies favorable to exporting industries.

Friedman argued that trade deficits are not necessarily important, as high exports raise the value of the currency, reducing aforementioned exports, and vice versa for imports, thus naturally removing trade deficits not due to investment. Since 1971, when the Nixon administration decided to abolish fixed exchange rates, America's Current Account accumulated trade deficits have totaled $7.75 trillion as of 2010. This deficit exists as it is matched by investment coming into the United States – purely by the definition of the balance of payments, any current account deficit that exists is matched by an inflow of foreign investment.

In the late 1970s and early 1980s, the U.S. had experienced high inflation and Friedman's policy positions tended to defend the stronger dollar at that time. He stated his belief that these trade deficits were not necessarily harmful to the economy at the time since the currency comes back to the country (country A sells to country B, country B sells to country C who buys from country A, but the trade deficit only includes A and B). However, it may be in one form or another including the possible tradeoff of foreign control of assets. In his view, the "worst-case scenario" of the currency never returning to the country of origin was actually the best possible outcome: the country actually purchased its goods by exchanging them for pieces of cheaply made paper. As Friedman put it, this would be the same result as if the exporting country burned the dollars it earned, never returning it to market circulation.[45]

This position is a more refined version of the theorem first discovered by David Hume.[46] Hume argued that England could not permanently gain from exports, because hoarding gold (i.e., currency) would make gold more plentiful in England; therefore, the prices of English goods would rise, making them less attractive exports and making foreign goods more attractive imports. In this way, countries' trade balances would balance out.

Friedman presented his analysis of the balance of trade in Free to Choose, widely considered his most significant popular work.

Trade balance’s effects upon a nation's GDP edit

Exports directly increase and imports directly reduce a nation's balance of trade (i.e. net exports). A trade surplus is a positive net balance of trade, and a trade deficit is a negative net balance of trade. Due to the balance of trade being explicitly added to the calculation of the nation's gross domestic product using the expenditure method of calculating gross domestic product (i.e. GDP), trade surpluses are contributions and trade deficits are "drags" upon their nation's GDP; however, foreign made goods sold (e.g., retail) contribute to total GDP.[47][48][49]

Balance of trade vs. balance of payments edit

Balance of trade Balance of payments
Includes only visible imports and exports, i.e. imports and exports of merchandise. The difference between exports and imports is called the balance of trade. If imports are greater than exports, it is sometimes called an unfavourable balance of trade. If exports exceed imports, it is sometimes called a favourable balance of trade. Includes all those visible and invisible items exported from and imported into the country in addition to exports and imports of merchandise.
Includes revenues received or paid on account of imports and exports of merchandise. It shows only revenue items. Includes all revenue and capital items whether visible or non-visible. The balance of trade thus forms a part of the balance of payments.

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ O'Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Pearson Prentice Hall. p. 462. ISBN 0130630853.
  2. ^ a b "Analysis: Trump rails against trade deficit, but economists say there's no easy way for him to make it go away". Washington Post. Retrieved 12 March 2017.
  3. ^ a b "Trump warns of trade deficits. Economists say, who cares?". Public Radio International. Retrieved 17 October 2017.
  4. ^ a b "Trade Balances". www.igmchicago.org. Retrieved 27 October 2017.
  5. ^ a b "What Is the Trade Deficit?". The New York Times. 9 June 2018. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 10 June 2018.
  6. ^ Romei, Valentina; Cocco, Federica (24 September 2017). "UK and US report trade surplus with each other". Financial Times. Retrieved 15 August 2023.
  7. ^ "Trump vs. Trudeau: Both Right, Both Wrong". NPR.org.
  8. ^ "The Daily — Comparing Canadian and US bilateral trade in goods data, 2014, 2015 and 2016". www150.statcan.gc.ca. 6 February 2018. Retrieved 15 August 2023.
  9. ^ "Physical Trade Balance, OECD Glossary of Statistical Terms". Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  10. ^ Ames, Glenn J. (1996), Colbert, Mercantilism and the French Quest for the Asian Trade
  11. ^ Now attributed to Sir Thomas Smith; quoted in José Rizal, The Wheels of Commerce, vol. II of Civilization and Capitalism 15th–18th Century, 1979:204.
  12. ^ Thomas Mun, Oxford National Dictionary of Biography
  13. ^ Bivens, L. Josh (14 December 2004). Debt and the dollar 17 December 2004 at the Wayback Machine Economic Policy Institute. Retrieved on 8 July 2007.
  14. ^ a b c Phillips, Kevin (2007). Bad Money: Reckless Finance, Failed Politics, and the Global Crisis of American Capitalism. Penguin. ISBN 978-0-14-314328-4.
  15. ^ Major foreign holders of Treasury securities. United States Treasury.
  16. ^ "Macroeconomic effects of Chinese mercantilism". 31 December 2009. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  17. ^ "China's Economic Mercantilism". 24 July 2013. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  18. ^ "U.S. tech group urges global action against Chinese". Reuters. 16 March 2017. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  19. ^ "Protectionism". Investopedia. 25 November 2003. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  20. ^ "Russia was most protectionist nation in 2013: study". Reuters. 30 December 2013. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  21. ^ "Study: Russia Insulated From Further Sanctions by Import Substitution Success". 26 July 2017. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  22. ^ Samofalova, Olga (10 February 2017). "Food import substitution turns out to be extremely profitable". Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  23. ^ Gramer, Robbie (6 March 2017). "Economists Take Aim at Trump Trade Theory – Again". Foreign Policy (magazine). Retrieved 12 March 2017.
  24. ^ "The IMF in Action: How can the IMF help in a crisis? Getting a member country's economy back on track". www.imf.org. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  25. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph (5 May 2010). "Reform the euro or bin it by Joseph Stiglitz". www.theguardian.com.
  26. ^ Lowenstein, Roger (16 August 2016). "Nobel Laureate Joseph Stiglitz Says the Euro Needs Big Reform". The New York Times. Archived from the original on 1 January 2022. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  27. ^ Bounader, Lahcen (31 December 2016). "Lahcen Bounader's weblog: A Critical Issue Addressed to Joseph Stiglitz".
  28. ^ Bernanke, Ben S. "Germany's trade surplus is a problem". Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  29. ^ Norrlof, Carla (2010). America's Global Advantage: US Hegemony and International Cooperation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. p. 89. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511676406. ISBN 978-0-521-76543-5.
  30. ^ Furceri, Davide; Hannan, Swarnali A; Ostry, Jonathan D; Rose, Andrew K (2018). "Macroeconomic Consequences of Tariffs". Working Paper Series. doi:10.3386/w25402. S2CID 198728925. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  31. ^ Smith, Adam. (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1981, 2 vols., (1776) (reprint of the Clarendon Press edition, Oxford 1976, with Edward Cannan's original index from 1922)
  32. ^ Crowther, Geoffrey (1948). An Outline of Money. Second Edition. Thomas Nelson and Sons. pp. 326–29.
  33. ^ "Deregulation". Investopedia. 25 November 2003. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  34. ^ "Trade Liberalization". Investopedia. 3 April 2010. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  35. ^ Costabile, Lilia (2007). "Current Global Imbalances and the Keynes Plan". scholarworks.umass.edu. Retrieved 21 August 2019.
  36. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph (5 May 2010). "Reform the euro or bin it - Joseph Stiglitz". The Guardian. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  37. ^ "Inicio". Grupo de Economía Política Alternativa.
  38. ^ "601 David Singh Grewal, What Keynes warned about globalization". www.india-seminar.com. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  39. ^ Crowther, Geoffrey (1948). An Outline of Money. Second Edition. Thomas Nelson and Sons. p. 336.
  40. ^ Crowther, Geoffrey (1948). An Outline of Money. Second Edition. Thomas Nelson and Sons. pp. 368–72.
  41. ^ Crowther, Geoffrey (1948). An Outline of Money. Second Edition. Thomas Nelson and Sons.
  42. ^ See for example, Krugman, P and Wells, R (2006). "Economics", Worth Publishers
  43. ^ although see Duncan, R (2005). "The Dollar Crisis: Causes, Consequences, Cures", Wiley
  44. ^ See for example,"Clearing Up This Mess". 18 November 2008. from the original on 23 January 2009.
  45. ^ . www.ideachannel.tv. Archived from the original on 10 December 2006. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  46. ^ Hume, David (1904). Essays, Moral, Political, and Literary.
  47. ^ "Expenditure Method". Investopedia. 11 May 2010. Retrieved 15 March 2018.
  48. ^ Analysis, US Department of Commerce, BEA, Bureau of Economic. "Bureau of Economic Analysis". www.bea.gov. Retrieved 15 March 2018.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  49. ^ "gross domestic product - Definition & Formula". Retrieved 15 March 2018.

balance, trade, confused, with, balance, payments, measured, terms, commercial, balance, exports, difference, between, monetary, value, nation, exports, imports, over, certain, time, period, sometimes, distinction, made, between, balance, trade, goods, versus,. Not to be confused with Balance of payments Balance of trade can be measured in terms of commercial balance or net exports Balance of trade is the difference between the monetary value of a nation s exports and imports over a certain time period 1 Sometimes a distinction is made between a balance of trade for goods versus one for services The balance of trade measures a flow variable of exports and imports over a given period of time The notion of the balance of trade does not mean that exports and imports are in balance with each other Cumulative current account balance 1980 2008 based on International Monetary Fund dataCumulative current account balance per capita 1980 2008 based on International Monetary Fund dataIf a country exports a greater value than it imports it has a trade surplus or positive trade balance and conversely if a country imports a greater value than it exports it has a trade deficit or negative trade balance As of 2016 about 60 out of 200 countries have a trade surplus The notion that bilateral trade deficits are bad in and of themselves is overwhelmingly rejected by trade experts and economists 2 3 4 5 Contents 1 Explanation 2 Examples 2 1 Historical example 3 Views on economic impact 3 1 Classical theory 3 1 1 Adam Smith on the balance of trade 3 2 Keynesian theory 3 3 Monetarist theory 3 4 Trade balance s effects upon a nation s GDP 4 Balance of trade vs balance of payments 5 See also 6 ReferencesExplanation edit nbsp Balance of trade in goods and services Eurozone countries nbsp US trade balance from 1960 nbsp U S trade balance and trade policy 1895 2015 nbsp U K balance of trade in goods since 1870 The balance of trade forms part of the current account which includes other transactions such as income from the net international investment position as well as international aid If the current account is in surplus the country s net international asset position increases correspondingly Equally a deficit decreases the net international asset position The trade balance is identical to the difference between a country s output and its domestic demand the difference between what goods a country produces and how many goods it buys from abroad this does not include money re spent on foreign stock nor does it factor in the concept of importing goods to produce for the domestic market Measuring the balance of trade can be problematic because of problems with recording and collecting data As an illustration of this problem when official data for all the world s countries are added up exports exceed imports by almost 1 it appears the world is running a positive balance of trade with itself This cannot be true because all transactions involve an equal credit or debit in the account of each nation The discrepancy is widely believed to be explained by transactions intended to launder money or evade taxes smuggling and other visibility problems While the accuracy of developing countries statistics would be suspicious most of the discrepancy actually occurs between developed countries of trusted statistics 6 7 8 Factors that can affect the balance of trade include The cost of production land labor capital taxes incentives etc in the exporting economy vis a vis those in the importing economy The cost and availability of raw materials intermediate goods and other inputs Currency exchange rate movements Multilateral bilateral and unilateral taxes or restrictions on trade Non tariff barriers such as environmental health or safety standards The availability of adequate foreign exchange with which to pay for imports and Prices of goods manufactured at home influenced by the responsiveness of supply In addition the trade balance is likely to differ across the business cycle In export led growth such as oil and early industrial goods the balance of trade will shift towards exports during an economic expansion citation needed However with domestic demand led growth as in the United States and Australia the trade balance will shift towards imports at the same stage in the business cycle The monetary balance of trade is different from the physical balance of trade 9 which is expressed in amount of raw materials known also as Total Material Consumption Developed countries usually import a substantial amount of raw materials from developing countries Typically these imported materials are transformed into finished products and might be exported after adding value Financial trade balance statistics conceal material flow Most developed countries have a large physical trade deficit because they consume more raw materials than they produce Examples editSee also Foreign trade of the United States Historical example edit Many countries in early modern Europe adopted a policy of mercantilism which theorized that a trade surplus was beneficial to a country Mercantilist ideas also influenced how European nations regulated trade policies with their colonies promoting the idea that natural resources and cash crops should be exported to Europe with processed goods being exported back to the colonies in return Ideas such as bullionism spurred the popularity of mercantilism in European governments 10 nbsp Merchandise exports 1870 1992 nbsp Trade policy exports and growth in selected European countriesAn early statement concerning the balance of trade appeared in Discourse of the Common Wealth of this Realm of England 1549 We must always take heed that we buy no more from strangers than we sell them for so should we impoverish ourselves and enrich them 11 Similarly a systematic and coherent explanation of balance of trade was made public through Thomas Mun s 1630 England s treasure by foreign trade or The balance of our foreign trade is the rule of our treasure 12 Since the mid 1980s the United States has had a growing deficit in tradeable goods especially with Asian nations China and Japan which now hold large sums of U S debt that has in part funded the consumption 13 14 15 The U S has a trade surplus with nations such as Australia The issue of trade deficits can be complex Trade deficits generated in tradeable goods such as manufactured goods or software may impact domestic employment to different degrees than do trade deficits in raw materials 14 Economies that have savings surpluses such as Japan and Germany typically run trade surpluses China a high growth economy has tended to run trade surpluses A higher savings rate generally corresponds to a trade surplus Correspondingly the U S with its lower savings rate has tended to run high trade deficits especially with Asian nations 14 Some have said that China pursues a mercantilist economic policy 16 17 18 Russia pursues a policy based on protectionism according to which international trade is not a win win game but a zero sum game surplus countries get richer at the expense of deficit countries 19 20 21 22 Views on economic impact editThe notion that bilateral trade deficits are bad in and of themselves is overwhelmingly rejected by trade experts and economists 23 2 3 4 5 According to the IMF trade deficits can cause a balance of payments problem which can affect foreign exchange shortages and hurt countries 24 On the other hand Joseph Stiglitz points out that countries running surpluses exert a negative externality on trading partners and pose a threat to global prosperity far more than those in deficit 25 26 27 Ben Bernanke argues that persistent imbalances within the euro zone are unhealthy as they lead to financial imbalances as well as to unbalanced growth The fact that Germany is selling so much more than it is buying redirects demand from its neighbors as well as from other countries around the world reducing output and employment outside Germany 28 According to Carla Norrlof there are three main benefits to trade deficits for the United States 29 Greater consumption than production the US enjoys the better side of the bargain by being able to consume more than it produces Usage of efficiently produced foreign made intermediate goods is productivity enhancing for US firms the US makes the most effective use of the global division of labor A large market that other countries are reliant on for exports enhances American bargaining power in trade negotiationsA 2018 National Bureau of Economic Research paper by economists at the International Monetary Fund and University of California Berkeley found in a study of 151 countries over 1963 2014 that the imposition of tariffs had little effect on the trade balance 30 Classical theory edit Adam Smith on the balance of trade edit See also Friedrich List In the foregoing part of this chapter I have endeavoured to show even upon the principles of the commercial system how unnecessary it is to lay extraordinary restraints upon the importation of goods from those countries with which the balance of trade is supposed to be disadvantageous Nothing however can be more absurd than this whole doctrine of the balance of trade upon which not only these restraints but almost all the other regulations of commerce are founded When two places trade with one another this absurd doctrine supposes that if the balance be even neither of them either loses or gains but if it leans in any degree to one side that one of them loses and the other gains in proportion to its declension from the exact equilibrium Smith 1776 book IV ch iii part ii 31 Keynesian theory edit In the last few years of his life John Maynard Keynes was much preoccupied with the question of balance in international trade He was the leader of the British delegation to the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference in 1944 that established the Bretton Woods system of international currency management He was the principal author of a proposal the so called Keynes Plan for an International Clearing Union The two governing principles of the plan were that the problem of settling outstanding balances should be solved by creating additional international money and that debtor and creditor should be treated almost alike as disturbers of equilibrium In the event though the plans were rejected in part because American opinion was naturally reluctant to accept the principle of equality of treatment so novel in debtor creditor relationships 32 The new system is not founded on free trade liberalisation 33 of foreign trade 34 but rather on the regulation of international trade in order to eliminate trade imbalances the nations with a surplus would have a powerful incentive to get rid of it and in doing so they would automatically clear other nations deficits 35 He proposed a global bank that would issue its own currency the bancor which was exchangeable with national currencies at fixed rates of exchange and would become the unit of account between nations which means it would be used to measure a country s trade deficit or trade surplus Every country would have an overdraft facility in its bancor account at the International Clearing Union He pointed out that surpluses lead to weak global aggregate demand countries running surpluses exert a negative externality on trading partners and posed far more than those in deficit a threat to global prosperity 36 In National Self Sufficiency The Yale Review Vol 22 no 4 June 1933 37 38 he already highlighted the problems created by free trade His view supported by many economists and commentators at the time was that creditor nations may be just as responsible as debtor nations for disequilibrium in exchanges and that both should be under an obligation to bring trade back into a state of balance Failure for them to do so could have serious consequences In the words of Geoffrey Crowther then editor of The Economist If the economic relationships between nations are not by one means or another brought fairly close to balance then there is no set of financial arrangements that can rescue the world from the impoverishing results of chaos 39 These ideas were informed by events prior to the Great Depression when in the opinion of Keynes and others international lending primarily by the U S exceeded the capacity of sound investment and so got diverted into non productive and speculative uses which in turn invited default and a sudden stop to the process of lending 40 Influenced by Keynes economics texts in the immediate post war period put a significant emphasis on balance in trade For example the second edition of the popular introductory textbook An Outline of Money 41 devoted the last three of its ten chapters to questions of foreign exchange management and in particular the problem of balance However in more recent years since the end of the Bretton Woods system in 1971 with the increasing influence of monetarist schools of thought in the 1980s and particularly in the face of large sustained trade imbalances these concerns and particularly concerns about the destabilising effects of large trade surpluses have largely disappeared from mainstream economics discourse 42 and Keynes insights have slipped from view 43 They are receiving some attention again in the wake of the financial crisis of 2007 08 44 Monetarist theory edit Prior to 20th century monetarist theory the 19th century economist and philosopher Frederic Bastiat expressed the idea that trade deficits actually were a manifestation of profit rather than a loss He proposed as an example to suppose that he a Frenchman exported French wine and imported British coal turning a profit He supposed he was in France and sent a cask of wine which was worth 50 francs to England The customhouse would record an export of 50 francs If in England the wine sold for 70 francs or the pound equivalent which he then used to buy coal which he imported into France the customhouse would record an import of 70 francs and was found to be worth 90 francs in France he would have made a profit of 40 francs But the customhouse would say that the value of imports exceeded that of exports and was trade deficit of 20 against the ledger of France This is not true for the current account that would be in surplus By reductio ad absurdum Bastiat argued that the national trade deficit was an indicator of a successful economy rather than a failing one Bastiat predicted that a successful growing economy would result in greater trade deficits and an unsuccessful shrinking economy would result in lower trade deficits This was later in the 20th century echoed by economist Milton Friedman In the 1980s Friedman a Nobel Memorial Prize winning economist and a proponent of monetarism contended that some of the concerns of trade deficits are unfair criticisms in an attempt to push macroeconomic policies favorable to exporting industries Friedman argued that trade deficits are not necessarily important as high exports raise the value of the currency reducing aforementioned exports and vice versa for imports thus naturally removing trade deficits not due to investment Since 1971 when the Nixon administration decided to abolish fixed exchange rates America s Current Account accumulated trade deficits have totaled 7 75 trillion as of 2010 This deficit exists as it is matched by investment coming into the United States purely by the definition of the balance of payments any current account deficit that exists is matched by an inflow of foreign investment In the late 1970s and early 1980s the U S had experienced high inflation and Friedman s policy positions tended to defend the stronger dollar at that time He stated his belief that these trade deficits were not necessarily harmful to the economy at the time since the currency comes back to the country country A sells to country B country B sells to country C who buys from country A but the trade deficit only includes A and B However it may be in one form or another including the possible tradeoff of foreign control of assets In his view the worst case scenario of the currency never returning to the country of origin was actually the best possible outcome the country actually purchased its goods by exchanging them for pieces of cheaply made paper As Friedman put it this would be the same result as if the exporting country burned the dollars it earned never returning it to market circulation 45 This position is a more refined version of the theorem first discovered by David Hume 46 Hume argued that England could not permanently gain from exports because hoarding gold i e currency would make gold more plentiful in England therefore the prices of English goods would rise making them less attractive exports and making foreign goods more attractive imports In this way countries trade balances would balance out Friedman presented his analysis of the balance of trade in Free to Choose widely considered his most significant popular work Trade balance s effects upon a nation s GDP edit Exports directly increase and imports directly reduce a nation s balance of trade i e net exports A trade surplus is a positive net balance of trade and a trade deficit is a negative net balance of trade Due to the balance of trade being explicitly added to the calculation of the nation s gross domestic product using the expenditure method of calculating gross domestic product i e GDP trade surpluses are contributions and trade deficits are drags upon their nation s GDP however foreign made goods sold e g retail contribute to total GDP 47 48 49 Balance of trade vs balance of payments editThis section is in list format but may read better as prose You can help by converting this section if appropriate Editing help is available April 2016 Balance of trade Balance of paymentsIncludes only visible imports and exports i e imports and exports of merchandise The difference between exports and imports is called the balance of trade If imports are greater than exports it is sometimes called an unfavourable balance of trade If exports exceed imports it is sometimes called a favourable balance of trade Includes all those visible and invisible items exported from and imported into the country in addition to exports and imports of merchandise Includes revenues received or paid on account of imports and exports of merchandise It shows only revenue items Includes all revenue and capital items whether visible or non visible The balance of trade thus forms a part of the balance of payments See also editList of countries by net exports Dutch disease Transfer problemReferences edit O Sullivan Arthur Sheffrin Steven M 2003 Economics Principles in Action Upper Saddle River New Jersey Pearson Prentice Hall p 462 ISBN 0130630853 a b Analysis Trump rails against trade deficit but economists say there s no easy way for him to make it go away Washington Post Retrieved 12 March 2017 a b Trump warns of trade deficits Economists say who cares Public Radio International Retrieved 17 October 2017 a b Trade Balances www igmchicago org Retrieved 27 October 2017 a b What Is the Trade Deficit The New York Times 9 June 2018 ISSN 0362 4331 Retrieved 10 June 2018 Romei Valentina Cocco Federica 24 September 2017 UK and US report trade surplus with each other Financial Times Retrieved 15 August 2023 Trump vs Trudeau Both Right Both Wrong NPR org The Daily Comparing Canadian and US bilateral trade in goods data 2014 2015 and 2016 www150 statcan gc ca 6 February 2018 Retrieved 15 August 2023 Physical Trade Balance OECD Glossary of Statistical Terms Retrieved 15 March 2018 Ames Glenn J 1996 Colbert Mercantilism and the French Quest for the Asian Trade Now attributed to Sir Thomas Smith quoted in Jose Rizal The Wheels of Commerce vol II of Civilization and Capitalism 15th 18th Century 1979 204 Thomas Mun Oxford National Dictionary of Biography Bivens L Josh 14 December 2004 Debt and the dollar Archived 17 December 2004 at the Wayback Machine Economic Policy Institute Retrieved on 8 July 2007 a b c Phillips Kevin 2007 Bad Money Reckless Finance Failed Politics and the Global Crisis of American Capitalism Penguin ISBN 978 0 14 314328 4 Major foreign holders of Treasury securities United States Treasury Macroeconomic effects of Chinese mercantilism 31 December 2009 Retrieved 15 March 2018 China s Economic Mercantilism 24 July 2013 Retrieved 15 March 2018 U S tech group urges global action against Chinese Reuters 16 March 2017 Retrieved 15 March 2018 Protectionism Investopedia 25 November 2003 Retrieved 15 March 2018 Russia was most protectionist nation in 2013 study Reuters 30 December 2013 Retrieved 15 March 2018 Study Russia Insulated From Further Sanctions by Import Substitution Success 26 July 2017 Retrieved 15 March 2018 Samofalova Olga 10 February 2017 Food import substitution turns out to be extremely profitable Retrieved 15 March 2018 Gramer Robbie 6 March 2017 Economists Take Aim at Trump Trade Theory Again Foreign Policy magazine Retrieved 12 March 2017 The IMF in Action How can the IMF help in a crisis Getting a member country s economy back on track www imf org Retrieved 15 March 2018 Stiglitz Joseph 5 May 2010 Reform the euro or bin it by Joseph Stiglitz www theguardian com Lowenstein Roger 16 August 2016 Nobel Laureate Joseph Stiglitz Says the Euro Needs Big Reform The New York Times Archived from the original on 1 January 2022 Retrieved 15 March 2018 Bounader Lahcen 31 December 2016 Lahcen Bounader s weblog A Critical Issue Addressed to Joseph Stiglitz Bernanke Ben S Germany s trade surplus is a problem Retrieved 15 March 2018 Norrlof Carla 2010 America s Global Advantage US Hegemony and International Cooperation Cambridge Cambridge University Press p 89 doi 10 1017 cbo9780511676406 ISBN 978 0 521 76543 5 Furceri Davide Hannan Swarnali A Ostry Jonathan D Rose Andrew K 2018 Macroeconomic Consequences of Tariffs Working Paper Series doi 10 3386 w25402 S2CID 198728925 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Smith Adam 1776 An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations Indianapolis Liberty Fund 1981 2 vols 1776 reprint of the Clarendon Press edition Oxford 1976 with Edward Cannan s original index from 1922 Crowther Geoffrey 1948 An Outline of Money Second Edition Thomas Nelson and Sons pp 326 29 Deregulation Investopedia 25 November 2003 Retrieved 15 March 2018 Trade Liberalization Investopedia 3 April 2010 Retrieved 15 March 2018 Costabile Lilia 2007 Current Global Imbalances and the Keynes Plan scholarworks umass edu Retrieved 21 August 2019 Stiglitz Joseph 5 May 2010 Reform the euro or bin it Joseph Stiglitz The Guardian Retrieved 15 March 2018 Inicio Grupo de Economia Politica Alternativa 601 David Singh Grewal What Keynes warned about globalization www india seminar com Retrieved 15 March 2018 Crowther Geoffrey 1948 An Outline of Money Second Edition Thomas Nelson and Sons p 336 Crowther Geoffrey 1948 An Outline of Money Second Edition Thomas Nelson and Sons pp 368 72 Crowther Geoffrey 1948 An Outline of Money Second Edition Thomas Nelson and Sons See for example Krugman P and Wells R 2006 Economics Worth Publishers although see Duncan R 2005 The Dollar Crisis Causes Consequences Cures Wiley See for example Clearing Up This Mess 18 November 2008 Archived from the original on 23 January 2009 TheIdeaChannel tv www ideachannel tv Archived from the original on 10 December 2006 Retrieved 15 March 2018 Hume David 1904 Essays Moral Political and Literary Expenditure Method Investopedia 11 May 2010 Retrieved 15 March 2018 Analysis US Department of Commerce BEA Bureau of Economic Bureau of Economic Analysis www bea gov Retrieved 15 March 2018 a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link gross domestic product Definition amp Formula Retrieved 15 March 2018 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Balance of trade amp oldid 1189003584, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.