fbpx
Wikipedia

Subsidy

A subsidy or government incentive is a type of government expenditure targeted towards individuals and households, as well as businesses with the aim of stabilising the economy. It ensures that individuals and households are viable by having access to essential goods and services while giving businesses the opportunity to stay afloat and/or competitive. Subsidies not only promote long term economic stability but also help governments to respond to economic shocks during a recession or in response to unforeseen shocks such as COVID-19.[1]

Subsidies take various forms such as direct government expenditures, tax incentives, soft loans, price support, and government provision of goods and services.[2] For instance, the government may distribute direct payment subsidies to individuals and households during an economic downturn in order to help its citizens pay their bills and to stimulate economic activity. Here, subsidies act as an effective financial aid issued when the economy experiences economic hardship.[3] They can also be a good policy tool to revise market imperfections when rational and competitive firms fail to produce an optimal market outcome. For example, in an imperfect market condition, governments can inject subsidies to encourage firms to invest in R&D (research and development). This will not only benefit the firms but also produce some positive externalities such that it benefits the industry in which the firms belong, and most importantly, the society at large.[4]

Although commonly extended from the government, the term subsidy can relate to any type of support – for example from NGOs or as implicit subsidies.

Subsidies come in various forms including: direct (cash grants, interest-free loans) and indirect (tax breaks, insurance, low-interest loans, accelerated depreciation, rent rebates).[5][6] Furthermore, they can be broad or narrow, legal or illegal, ethical or unethical. The most common forms of subsidies are those to the producer or the consumer. Producer/production subsidies ensure producers are better off by either supplying market price support, direct support, or payments to factors of production. [6] Consumer/consumption subsidies commonly reduce the price of goods and services to the consumer. For example, in the US at one time it was cheaper to buy gasoline than bottled water.[7]

All countries use subsidies via national and sub-national entities through different forms such as tax incentives and direct grants. Likewise, subsidies have an economic influence on both a domestic and international level. On a domestic level, subsidies affect the allocation decision of domestic resources, income distribution, and expenditure productivity. On an international level, subsidies may increase or decrease international interaction and integration through trade.[8] For this reason, having a thorough subsidy policy is essential as its inadequacy can potentially lead to financial hardship and problems for not only the poor or low income individuals but the aggregate economy as a whole.[9]

At large, subsidies take up a substantial portion of the government and economy. Amongst OECD countries in 2020, the median of subsidies and other transfers such as social benefits and non-repayable transfers to private and public enterprises was 56.3 percent of total government expenses which was 34.9 percent (weighted average) of GDP in the same year.[10] Yet, the number of subsidy measures in force have been rapidly increasing since 2008.[11]

Types

Production subsidy

A production subsidy encourages suppliers to increase the output of a particular product by partially offsetting the production costs or losses.[12] The objective of production subsidies is to expand production of a particular product more so that the market would promote but without raising the final price to consumers. This type of subsidy is predominantly found in developed markets.[6] Other examples of production subsidies include the assistance in the creation of a new firm (Enterprise Investment Scheme), industry (industrial policy) and even the development of certain areas (regional policy). Production subsidies are critically discussed in the literature as they can cause many problems including the additional cost of storing the extra produced products, depressing world market prices, and incentivizing producers to over-produce, for example, a farmer overproducing in terms of his land's carrying capacity.

Consumer/consumption subsidy

A consumption subsidy is one that subsidizes the behavior of consumers. This type of subsidies are most common in developing countries where governments subsidise such things as food, water, electricity and education on the basis that no matter how impoverished, all should be allowed those most basic requirements.[6] For example, some governments offer 'lifeline' rates for electricity, that is, the first increment of electricity each month is subsidized.[6] Evidence from recent studies suggests that government expenditures on subsidies remain high in many countries, often amounting to several percentage points of GDP. Subsidization on such a scale implies substantial opportunity costs. There are at least three compelling reasons for studying government subsidy behavior. First, subsidies are a major instrument of government expenditure policy. Second, on a domestic level, subsidies affect domestic resource allocation decisions, income distribution, and expenditure productivity. A consumer subsidy is a shift in demand as the subsidy is given directly to consumers.

Export subsidy

An export subsidy is a support from the government for products that are exported, as a means of assisting the country's balance of payments.[12] Usha Haley and George Haley identified the subsidies to manufacturing industry provided by the Chinese government and how they have altered trade patterns.[5] Traditionally, economists have argued that subsidies benefit consumers but hurt the subsidizing countries. Haley and Haley provided data to show that over the decade after China joined the World Trade Organization industrial subsidies have helped give China an advantage in industries in which they previously enjoyed no comparative advantage such as the steel, glass, paper, auto parts, and solar industries.[5] China's shores have also collapsed from overfishing and industrialization, which is why the Chinese government heavily subsidizes its fishermen, who sail the world in search of new grounds.[13]

Export subsidy is known for being abused. For example, some exporters substantially over declare the value of their goods so as to benefit more from the export subsidy. Another method is to export a batch of goods to a foreign country but the same goods will be re-imported by the same trader via a circuitous route and changing the product description so as to obscure their origin. Thus the trader benefits from the export subsidy without creating real trade value to the economy. Export subsidy as such can become a self-defeating and disruptive policy.

Adam Smith observed that special government subsidies enabled exporters to sell abroad at substantial ongoing losses. He did not regard that as a sound and sustainable policy. That was because "… under normal industrial-commercial conditions their own interests soon oblige loss-making businesses to deploy their capital in other ways – or to move into markets where the sales prices do cover the supply costs and yield ordinary profits. Like other mercantilist schemes and devices, export bounties are a means of trying to force business capital into channels it would not naturally enter. The schemes are invariably costly and damaging in various ways."[14]

Import subsidy

An import subsidy is support from the government for products that are imported. Rarer than an export subsidy, an import subsidy further reduces the price to consumers for imported goods. Import subsidies have various effects depending on the subject. For example, consumers in the importing country are better off and experience an increase in consumer welfare due to the decrease in price of the imported goods, as well as the decrease in price of the domestic substitute goods. Conversely, the consumers in the exporting country experience a decrease in consumer welfare due to an increase in the price of their domestic goods. Furthermore, producers of the importing country experience a loss of welfare due to a decrease of the price for the good in their market, while on the other side, the exporters of the producing country experience an increase in well being due to the increase in demand. Ultimately, the import subsidy is rarely used due to an overall loss of welfare for the country due to a decrease in domestic production and a reduction in production throughout the world. However, that can result in a redistribution of income.[15]

Employment subsidy

Employment or wage subsidies keep the employment relationship ongoing even during financial crisis. It is particularly beneficial for enterprises to recover quickly after a temporary suspension following a crisis. Workers are prevented from losing their jobs and other associated employment benefits such as annual leave entitlements and retirement pensions.[16]

Employment subsidies allow individual beneficiaries a minimum standard of living at the very least. However, less than half of active jobseekers in around 50% of OECD countries receive unemployment support.[17] The effect of employment subsidies may not be evident immediately. When employers received grants to subside a substantial part of the wages for retaining their employees or to create new jobs during severe recessions such as the 2008 GFC (Global Financial Crisis), there were minor impacts on employment during the first year. However, the subsidy began to yield positive effects on employment, particularly a decrease in the unemployment rate, in the second year as employers began to properly utilise the subsidy.[18]

Tax subsidy

Tax subsidies, also known as tax breaks or tax expenditures, are a way for governments to achieve certain outcomes without directly providing cash payments. By offering tax breaks, the government can incentivize behavior that is beneficial to the economy or society as a whole. However, tax subsidies can also have negative consequences.

One type of tax subsidy is a health tax deduction, which allows individuals or businesses to deduct their health expenses from their taxable income. This can be seen as a way to incentivize people to prioritize their health and well-being. However, it can also create distortions in the economy by encouraging people to spend more on health care than they otherwise would.

Another type of tax subsidy is related to Intellectual Property. Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) is a particular form of tax subsidy that involves companies shifting their profits to low-tax jurisdictions in order to reduce their overall tax burden. The Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting is a treaty signed by half the nations of the world aimed at preventing this type of tax avoidance.

While tax subsidies can be effective in achieving certain outcomes, they are also less transparent than direct cash payments and can be difficult to undo. Additionally, some argue that tax breaks disproportionately benefit the wealthy and large corporations, further exacerbating income inequality. Therefore, it is important for governments to carefully consider the potential consequences of offering tax subsidies and ensure that they are targeted towards achieving the greatest public good.

Furthermore, tax subsidies can have unintended consequences, such as creating market distortions that favor certain industries or companies over others. For example, if a government offers tax breaks to incentivize investment in renewable energy, it may lead to a glut of renewable energy projects and an oversupply of energy in the market. This, in turn, can lead to lower prices for energy and financial losses for investors.

In addition, tax subsidies can be difficult to monitor and enforce, which can lead to abuse and fraud. Companies may claim tax breaks for activities that do not qualify, or may use complex legal structures to shift profits to lower tax jurisdictions. This can result in lost revenue for governments and a lack of fairness in the tax system.

Despite these concerns, tax subsidies remain a popular tool for governments to promote various policy objectives, such as economic growth, job creation, and environmental sustainability. The use of tax subsidies is often debated in political circles, with some arguing that they are necessary to support certain industries or to incentivize certain behaviors, while others argue that they create inefficiencies and distortions in the economy.

In conclusion, tax subsidies are a powerful tool for governments to achieve policy goals, but they come with their own set of challenges and limitations. It is important for policymakers to carefully consider the potential unintended consequences of tax subsidies and to design them in a way that maximizes their benefits while minimizing their costs. Additionally, strong monitoring and enforcement mechanisms are needed to ensure that tax subsidies are used appropriately and do not result in abuse or fraud.

Transport subsidies

Some governments subsidise transport, especially rail and bus transport, which decrease congestion and pollution compared to cars. In the EU, rail subsidies are around €73 billion, and Chinese subsidies reach $130 billion.[19][20]

Publicly owned airports can be an indirect subsidy if they lose money. The European Union, for instance, criticizes Germany for its high number of money-losing airports that are used primarily by low cost carriers, characterizing the arrangement as an illegal subsidy.[citation needed]

In many countries, roads and highways are paid for through general revenue, rather than tolls or other dedicated sources that are paid only by road users, creating an indirect subsidy for road transportation. The fact that long-distance buses in Germany do not pay tolls has been called an indirect subsidy by critics, who point to track access charges for railways.

Energy subsidies

Energy subsidies are measures that keep prices for customers below market levels, or for suppliers above market levels, or reduce costs for customers and suppliers.[21][22] Energy subsidies may be direct cash transfers to suppliers, customers, or related bodies, as well as indirect support mechanisms, such as tax exemptions and rebates, price controls, trade restrictions, and limits on market access.

The International Renewable Energy Agency tracked some $634 billion in energy-sector subsidies in 2020, and found that around 70% were fossil fuel subsidies. About 20% went to renewable power generation, 6% to biofuels and just over 3% to nuclear.[23]

Fossil fuels

 
Fossil-fuel subsidies per capita, 2019. Fossil-fuel pre-tax subsidies per capita are measured in constant US dollars.
 
Fossil-fuel subsidies as a share of GDP, 2019. Fossil-fuel pre-tax subsidies are given as a share of total gross domestic product.

Fossil fuel subsidies are energy subsidies on fossil fuels. They may be tax breaks on consumption, such as a lower sales tax on natural gas for residential heating; or subsidies on production, such as tax breaks on exploration for oil. Or they may be free or cheap negative externalities; such as air pollution or climate change due to burning gasoline, diesel and jet fuel. Some fossil fuel subsidies are via electricity generation, such as subsidies for coal-fired power stations.

Eliminating fossil fuel subsidies would reduce the health risks of air pollution,[24] and would greatly reduce global carbon emissions thus helping to limit climate change.[25] As of 2021, policy researchers estimate that substantially more money is spent on fossil fuel subsidies than on environmentally harmful agricultural subsidies or environmentally harmful water subsidies.[26]

The International Energy Agency says that "High fossil fuel prices hit the poor hardest, but subsidies are rarely well-targeted to protect vulnerable groups and tend to benefit better-off segments of the population."[27]

Despite the G20 countries having pledged to phase-out inefficient fossil fuel subsidies,[28] as of 2023 they continue because of voter demand[29][30] or for energy security.[31] Global fossil fuel consumption subsidies in 2022 have been estimated at one trillion dollars;[27] although they vary each year depending on oil prices they are consistently hundreds of billions of dollars.[32]

Housing subsidies

Housing subsidies are designed to promote the construction industry and homeownership. As of 2018, U.S housing subsidies total around $15 billion per year. Housing subsidies can come in two types; assistance with down payment and interest rate subsidies. The deduction of mortgage interest from the federal income tax accounts for the largest interest rate subsidy. Additionally, the federal government will help low-income families with the down payment, coming to $10.9 million in 2008.[33]

As a housing policy tool, housing subsidies also help low income individuals gain and maintain liveable residency by easing the cost burdens of housing for low income individuals and households. However, some policy makers and experts believe they are costly to implement and may even reduce incentives for beneficiaries to participate in the labour market. In the contrary, certain literatures have found that subsidy cuts do not encourage employment or participation among beneficiaries. For example, research by Daniel Borbely found that reducing housing subsidies did not increase employment and labour force participation. Though, he also added that claimants relocated to other areas of the rental market to maintain their benefits.[34]

Nonetheless, the most common method for providing housing subsidies is via direct payments to renters by covering a part of their rent on the private rent market. This method of direct transfer of housing subsidies is often referred to as 'housing vouchers'. In the United States, the so-called Section 8 is a direct payment program subsidising the largest amount of money to renters for rental assistance.[35]

Environmental externalities

While conventional subsidies require financial support, many economists have described implicit subsidies in the form of untaxed environmental externalities.[7] These externalities include things such as pollution from vehicle emissions, pesticides, or other sources.

A 2015 report studied the implicit subsidies accruing to 20 fossil fuel companies. It estimated that the societal costs from downstream emissions and pollution attributable to these companies were substantial.[36][37] The report spans the period 2008–2012 and notes that: "for all companies and all years, the economic cost to society of their CO2 emissions was greater than their after‐tax profit, with the single exception of ExxonMobil in 2008."[36]: 4  Pure coal companies fare even worse: "the economic cost to society exceeds total revenue (employment, taxes, supply purchases, and indirect employment) in all years, with this cost varying between nearly $2 and nearly $9 per $1 of revenue."[36]: 4–5 

Categorising subsidies

Direct and Indirect

The first important classification of subsidies are direct and indirect subsidies. Subsidies are categorised as direct when it involves actual cash outlays targeted towards a specified individual or household. Popular examples include is cash grants and interest-free loans. Subsidies can also be classified as indirect when they do not involve actual payments. An example would be an increase in disposable income arising from a decrease in price of an essential good or service that the government has enforced in a form of monetary support. In contrast, a decrease in the price of a good or service may lead to an increase in revenue for producers earned from the heightened demand by consumers.[38]

The use of indirect subsidies such as price controls is widespread among developing economies and emerging markets as a necessary tool for social policy. It has proven to be effective in many cases but price controls have a potential to dampen investment activity and growth, cause heavy fiscal burdens for the government, and may even complicate the optimal performance of monetary policy. To prevent the undesirable negative effects, price control regimes may be replaced by creating social safety nets and proposing sound reforms to encourage competition and growth.[39]

Production and Consumption

Another important classification of subsidies are producer/production subsidies and consumer/consumption subsidies. Production subsidies are designed to ensure producers are advantaged by creating fluid market activity through other market control mechanisms or by providing cash payments for factors of production. Consumption subsidies benefit consumers typically through a reduction in the market price of goods and services. They are commonly used by governments of many developing countries in an attempt to secure the most basic needs for its population.[40]

Broad and Narrow

These various subsidies can be divided into broad and narrow. Narrow subsidies are those monetary transfers that are easily identifiable and have a clear intent. They are commonly characterised by a monetary transfer between governments and institutions or businesses and individuals. A classic example is a government payment to a farmer.[41]

Monetary and Non-monetary

Conversely broad subsidies include both monetary and non-monetary subsidies and is often difficult to identify.[41] A broad subsidy is less attributable and less transparent. Environmental externalities are the most common type of broad subsidy.

Economic effects

 

Competitive equilibrium is a state of balance between buyers and suppliers, in which the quantity demanded of a good is the quantity supplied at a specified price. When the price falls the quantity demand exceeds the equilibrium quantity, conversely, a reduction in the supply of a good beyond equilibrium quantity implies an increase in the price. The effect of a subsidy is to shift the supply or demand curve to the right (i.e. increases the supply or demand) by the amount of the subsidy. If a consumer is receiving the subsidy, a lower price of a good resulting from the marginal subsidy on consumption increases demand, shifting the demand curve to the right. If a supplier is receiving the subsidy, an increase in the price (revenue) resulting from the marginal subsidy on production results increases supply, shifting the supply curve to the right.

 

Assuming the market is in a perfectly competitive equilibrium, a subsidy increases the supply of the good beyond the equilibrium competitive quantity. The imbalance creates deadweight loss. Deadweight loss from a subsidy is the amount by which the cost of the subsidy exceeds the gains of the subsidy.[42] The magnitude of the deadweight loss is dependent on the size of the subsidy. This is considered a market failure, or inefficiency.[42]

Subsidies targeted at goods in one country, by lowering the price of those goods, make them more competitive against foreign goods, thereby reducing foreign competition.[43] As a result, many developing countries cannot engage in foreign trade, and receive lower prices for their products in the global market. This is considered protectionism: a government policy to erect trade barriers in order to protect domestic industries.[44] The problem with protectionism arises when industries are selected for nationalistic reasons (infant-industry), rather than to gain a comparative advantage. The market distortion, and reduction in social welfare, is the logic behind the World Bank policy for the removal of subsidies in developing countries.[45]

Subsidies create spillover effects in other economic sectors and industries. A subsidized product sold in the world market lowers the price of the good in other countries. Since subsidies result in lower revenues for producers of foreign countries, they are a source of tension between the United States, Europe and poorer developing countries.[46] While subsidies may provide immediate benefits to an industry, in the long-run they may prove to have unethical, negative effects. Subsidies are intended to support public interest, however, they can violate ethical or legal principles if they lead to higher consumer prices or discriminate against some producers to benefit others.[43] For example, domestic subsidies granted by individual US states may be unconstitutional if they discriminate against out-of-state producers, violating the Privileges and Immunities Clause or the Dormant Commerce Clause of the United States Constitution.[43] Depending on their nature, subsidies are discouraged by international trade agreements such as the World Trade Organization (WTO). This trend, however, may change in the future, as needs of sustainable development and environmental protection could suggest different interpretations regarding energy and renewable energy subsidies.[47] In its July 2019 report, "Going for Growth 2019: The time for reform is now", the OECD suggests that countries make better use of environmental taxation, phase out agricultural subsidies and environmentally harmful tax breaks.[48][49]

Preventing fraud

In the Netherlands, audits are performed to verify whether the funds that have been received has indeed been spent legally (and all requirements of the subsidy provider have been attained), for the purpose intended.[50] It hence prevents fraud.

Perverse subsidies

Definitions

Although subsidies can be important, many are "perverse", in the sense of having adverse unintended consequences. To be "perverse", subsidies must exert effects that are demonstrably and significantly adverse both economically and environmentally.[6] A subsidy rarely, if ever, starts perverse, but over time a legitimate efficacious subsidy can become perverse or illegitimate if it is not withdrawn after meeting its goal or as political goals change. Perverse subsidies are now so widespread that as of 2007 they amounted $2 trillion per year in the six most subsidised sectors alone (agriculture, fossil fuels, road transportation, water, fisheries and forestry).[51]

Effects

The detrimental effects of perverse subsidies are diverse in nature and reach. Case-studies from differing sectors are highlighted below but can be summarised as follows.

Directly, they are expensive to governments by directing resources away from other legitimate should priorities (such as environmental conservation, education, health, or infrastructure),[52][41][53][54] ultimately reducing the fiscal health of the government.[55]

Indirectly, they cause environmental degradation (exploitation of resources, pollution, loss of landscape, misuse and overuse of supplies) which, as well as its fundamental damage, acts as a further brake on economies; tend to benefit the few at the expense of the many, and the rich at the expense of the poor; lead to further polarization of development between the Northern and Southern hemispheres; lower global market prices; and undermine investment decisions reducing the pressure on businesses to become more efficient.[7][54][56] Over time the latter effect means support becomes enshrined in human behaviour and business decisions to the point where people become reliant on, even addicted to, subsidies, 'locking' them into society.[57]

Consumer attitudes do not change and become out-of-date, off-target and inefficient;[7] furthermore, over time people feel a sense of historical right to them.[56]

Implementation

Perverse subsidies are not tackled as robustly as they should be. Principally, this is because they become 'locked' into society, causing bureaucratic roadblocks and institutional inertia.[58][59] When cuts are suggested many argue (most fervently by those 'entitled', special interest groups and political lobbyists) that it will disrupt and harm the lives of people who receive them, distort domestic competitiveness curbing trade opportunities, and increase unemployment.[56][60] Individual governments recognise this as a 'prisoner's dilemma' – insofar as that even if they wanted to adopt subsidy reform, by acting unilaterally they fear only negative effects will ensue if others do not follow.[57] Furthermore, cutting subsidies, however perverse they may be, is considered a vote-losing policy.[58]

Reform of perverse subsidies is at a propitious time. The current economic conditions mean governments are forced into fiscal constraints and are looking for ways to reduce activist roles in their economies.[59] There are two main reform paths: unilateral and multilateral. Unilateral agreements (one country) are less likely to be undertaken for the reasons outlined above, although New Zealand,[61] Russia, Bangladesh and others represent successful examples.[7] Multilateral actions by several countries are more likely to succeed as this reduces competitiveness concerns, but are more complex to implement requiring greater international collaboration through a body such as the WTO.[54] Irrespective of the path, the aim of policymakers should be to: create alternative policies that target the same issue as the original subsidies but better; develop subsidy removal strategies allowing market-discipline to return; introduce 'sunset' provisions that require remaining subsidies to be re-justified periodically; and make perverse subsidies more transparent to taxpayers to alleviate the 'vote-loser' concern.[7]

Examples

Agricultural subsidies

Support for agriculture dates back to the 19th century. It was developed extensively in the EU and USA across the two World Wars and the Great Depression to protect domestic food production, but remains important across the world today.[54][58] In 2005, US farmers received $14 billion and EU farmers $47 billion in agricultural subsidies.[43] Today, agricultural subsidies are defended on the grounds of helping farmers to maintain their livelihoods. The majority of payments are based on outputs and inputs and thus favour the larger producing agribusinesses over the small-scale farmers.[6][62] In the USA nearly 30% of payments go to the top 2% of farmers.[54][63][64]

By subsidising inputs and outputs through such schemes as 'yield based subsidisation', farmers are encouraged to over-produce using intensive methods, including using more fertilizers and pesticides; grow high-yielding monocultures; reduce crop rotation; shorten fallow periods; and promote exploitative land use change from forests, rainforests and wetlands to agricultural land.[54] These all lead to severe environmental degradation, including adverse effects on soil quality and productivity including erosion, nutrient supply and salinity which in turn affects carbon storage and cycling, water retention and drought resistance; water quality including pollution, nutrient deposition and eutrophication of waterways, and lowering of water tables; diversity of flora and fauna including indigenous species both directly and indirectly through the destruction of habitats, resulting in a genetic wipe-out.[6][54][65][66]

Cotton growers in the US reportedly receive half their income from the government under the Farm Bill of 2002. The subsidy payments stimulated overproduction and resulted in a record cotton harvest in 2002, much of which had to be sold at very reduced prices in the global market.[43] For foreign producers, the depressed cotton price lowered their prices far below the break-even price. In fact, African farmers received 35 to 40 cents per pound for cotton, while US cotton growers, backed by government agricultural payments, received 75 cents per pound. Developing countries and trade organizations argue that poorer countries should be able to export their principal commodities to survive, but protectionist laws and payments in the United States and Europe prevent these countries from engaging in international trade opportunities.

Fisheries

Today, much of the world's major fisheries are overexploited; in 2002, the WWF estimate this at approximately 75%. Fishing subsidies include "direct assistant to fishers; loan support programs; tax preferences and insurance support; capital and infrastructure programs; marketing and price support programs; and fisheries management, research, and conservation programs."[67] They promote the expansion of fishing fleets, the supply of larger and longer nets, larger yields and indiscriminate catch, as well as mitigating risks which encourages further investment into large-scale operations to the disfavour of the already struggling small-scale industry.[54][68] Collectively, these result in the continued overcapitalization and overfishing of marine fisheries.

There are four categories of fisheries subsidies. First are direct financial transfers, second are indirect financial transfers and services. Third, certain forms of intervention and fourth, not intervening. The first category regards direct payments from the government received by the fisheries industry. These typically affect profits of the industry in the short term and can be negative or positive. Category two pertains to government intervention, not involving those under the first category. These subsidies also affect the profits in the short term but typically are not negative. Category three includes intervention that results in a negative short-term economic impact, but economic benefits in the long term. These benefits are usually more general societal benefits such as the environment. The final category pertains to inaction by the government, allowing producers to impose certain production costs on others. These subsidies tend to lead to positive benefits in the short term but negative in the long term.[69]

Manufacturing subsidies

A survey of manufacturing in Britain found government subsidies had had various unintended dysfunctional consequences. The subsidies had usually been selective or discriminatory – benefiting some companies at the expense of others. Government money in the form of grants and awards of production and R&D contracts had gone to advanced and viable firms as well as old uneconomic enterprises. However, the main recipients had been larger, established companies – while most of the firms pioneering radical technical-product developments with long-term economic growth potential had been new small enterprises. The study concluded that instead of providing subsidies, governments wanting to benefit industrial-technological development and performance should lower standard rates of business taxation, raise tax allowances for investments in new plant, equipment and products, and remove obstacles to market competition and customer choice.[70]

Others

The US National Football League's (NFL) profits have topped records at $11 billion, the highest of all sports. The NFL had tax-exempt status until voluntarily relinquishing it in 2015, and new stadiums have been built with public subsidies.[71][72]

The Commitment to Development Index (CDI), published by the Center for Global Development, measures the effect that subsidies and trade barriers actually have on the undeveloped world. It uses trade, along with six other components such as aid or investment, to rank and evaluate developed countries on policies that affect the undeveloped world. It finds that the richest countries spend $106 billion per year subsidizing their own farmers – almost exactly as much as they spend on foreign aid.[73]

Short list of subsidies

See also

References

  1. ^ Ayanna, Julien (2022). Subsidy. Salem Press Encyclopedia. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  2. ^ OECD. "Subsidies, Competition and Trade, OECD Competition Policy Roundtable Background Note" (PDF). OECD. (PDF) from the original on 27 November 2022. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  3. ^ "What is a Subsidy?". Real Vision. from the original on 28 April 2023. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  4. ^ Clements, Benedict; Parry, Ian. "What Are Subsidies?". International Monetary Fund. International Monetary Fund. from the original on 28 April 2023. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  5. ^ a b c Haley, U.; G. Haley (2013). "Subsidies to Chinese Industry". The Economist. London: Oxford University Press. from the original on 2017-06-16. Retrieved 2017-09-15.
  6. ^ a b c d e f g h Myers, N.; Kent, J. (2001). Perverse subsidies: how tax dollars can undercut the environment and the economy. Washington, DC: Island Press. ISBN 978-1-55963-835-7.
  7. ^ a b c d e f Myers, N. (1998). "Lifting the veil on perverse subsidies". Nature. 392 (6674): 327–328. Bibcode:1998Natur.392..327M. doi:10.1038/32761. S2CID 4426064.
  8. ^ Schwartz, Gerd; Clements, Benedict (1999). "Government Subsidies". Journal of Economic Surveys. 13 (2): 119. doi:10.1111/1467-6419.00079. from the original on 28 April 2023. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  9. ^ Johan Kruger Afcap Consulting. "Subsidies" (PDF). World Bank Group. (PDF) from the original on 7 May 2023. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  10. ^ "Subsidies and other transfers (% of expense) - OECD members". The World Bank. from the original on 28 April 2023. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  11. ^ OECD. "Subsidies, Competition and Trade, OECD Competition Policy Roundtable Background Note" (PDF). (PDF) from the original on 27 November 2022. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  12. ^ a b "Collins Dictionary of Economics". from the original on 2013-09-27. Retrieved 2013-09-05.
  13. ^ Urbina, Ian (11 August 2020). "The deadly secret of China's invisible armada". NBC News. from the original on 19 February 2021. Retrieved 19 February 2021.
  14. ^ Smith, Adam. The Wealth of Nations: A Translation into Modern English. ISR/Google Books, 2019, page 300. ISBN 9780906321706
  15. ^ Suranovic, Steven. "Welfare Effects of a VIE/Import Subsidy: Large Country". International Trade Theory and Policy. from the original on 16 March 2018. Retrieved 16 March 2018.
  16. ^ "Temporary Wage Subsidies" (PDF). International Labour Organisation. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  17. ^ "Basic income as a policy option: Can it add up?" (PDF). OECD. (PDF) from the original on 28 April 2023. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  18. ^ Kim, Hyejin; Lee, Jungmin (2019). "Can employment subsidies save jobs? Evidence from a shipbuilding city in South Korea". Labour Economics. 61: 101763. doi:10.1016/j.labeco.2019.101763. S2CID 204435231.
  19. ^ "EU Technical Report 2007". from the original on 2021-02-06. Retrieved 2016-03-23.
  20. ^ "China to Invest $128 Billion in Rail, Push for Global Share". Bloomberg News. 5 March 2015. from the original on 2017-03-24. Retrieved 2017-03-11.
  21. ^ Timperley, Jocelyn (20 October 2021). "Why fossil fuel subsidies are so hard to kill". Nature. Retrieved 26 October 2021. "Fossil-fuel subsidies generally take two forms. Production subsidies...[and]...Consumption subsidies...
  22. ^ OECD, 1998
  23. ^ Timperley, Jocelyn (20 October 2021). "Why fossil fuel subsidies are so hard to kill". Nature. Retrieved 26 October 2021.
  24. ^ "Local Environmental Externalities due to Energy Price Subsidies: A Focus on Air Pollution and Health" (PDF). World Bank.
  25. ^ "Fossil fuel subsidies: If we want to reduce greenhouse gas emissions we should not pay people to burn fossil-fuels". Our World in Data. Retrieved 2021-11-04.
  26. ^ "Protecting Nature by Reforming Environmentally Harmful Subsidies: The Role of Business | Earth Track". www.earthtrack.net. Retrieved 2022-03-07.
  27. ^ a b "Fossil Fuels Consumption Subsidies 2022 – Analysis". IEA. Retrieved 2023-02-16.
  28. ^ "Update on recent progress in reform of inefficient fossil-fuel subsidies that encourage wasteful consumption" (PDF). 2021.
  29. ^ George, Johannes Urpelainen and Elisha (2021-07-14). "Reforming global fossil fuel subsidies: How the United States can restart international cooperation". Brookings. Retrieved 2022-02-26.
  30. ^ Martinez-Alvarez, Cesar B.; Hazlett, Chad; Mahdavi, Paasha; Ross, Michael L. (2022-11-22). "Political leadership has limited impact on fossil fuel taxes and subsidies". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 119 (47). doi:10.1073/pnas.2208024119. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 9704748. PMID 36375060.
  31. ^ Brower, Derek; Wilson, Tom; Giles, Chris (2022-02-25). "The new energy shock: Putin, Ukraine and the global economy". Financial Times. Retrieved 2022-02-26.
  32. ^ "Fossil Fuel Subsidies & Finance". Oil Change International. Retrieved 2022-06-02.
  33. ^ Amadeo, Kimberly. "Government Subsidies (Farm, Oil, Export, etc.)". The Balance. from the original on 16 March 2018. Retrieved 16 March 2018.
  34. ^ Borbely, Daniel (2022). "The impact of housing subsidy cuts on the labour market outcomes of claimants: Evidence from England". Journal of Housing Economics. 57: 101859. doi:10.1016/j.jhe.2022.101859.
  35. ^ "What Are Housing Subsidies?". Planetizen. from the original on 28 April 2023. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  36. ^ a b c Hope, Chris; Gilding, Paul; Alvarez, Jimena (2015). (PDF). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Judge Business School, University of Cambridge. Archived from the original (PDF) on 28 March 2016. Retrieved 27 June 2016.
  37. ^ "Measuring fossil fuel 'hidden' costs". University of Cambridge Judge Business School. 23 July 2015. from the original on 26 June 2016. Retrieved 27 June 2016.
  38. ^ "Subsidy". ClearTax. from the original on 28 April 2023. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  39. ^ Guenette, Justin-Damien. "Price Controls, Good Intentions, Bad Outcomes" (PDF). World Bank Group. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  40. ^ "Subsidy". ClearTax. from the original on 28 April 2023. Retrieved 27 April 2023.
  41. ^ a b c Myers, N. (2008). "Perverse Priorities" (PDF). IUCN Opinion Piece: 6–7. (PDF) from the original on 2016-03-04. Retrieved 2013-09-08.
  42. ^ a b Watkins, Thayer. "The Impact of an Excise Tax or Subsidy on Price". San José State University Department of Economics. from the original on 2016-06-23. Retrieved 2016-06-28.
  43. ^ a b c d e Kolb, R.W. (2008). "Subsidies". Encyclopedia of business ethics and society. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications. ISBN 9781412916523.
  44. ^ Protectionism. (2006). Collins Dictionary
  45. ^ Amegashie, J. A. (2006). The Economics of Subsidies. Crossroads , 6 (2), 7-15.
  46. ^ Parkin, M.; Powell, M.; Matthews, K. (2007). Economics (7th ed.). Harlow: Addison-Wesley. ISBN 978-0132041225.
  47. ^ Farah, Paolo Davide; Cima, Elena (2015). "World Trade Organization, Renewable Energy Subsidies and the Case of Feed-In Tariffs: Time for Reform Toward Sustainable Development?". Georgetown International Environmental Law Review (GIELR). 27 (1). SSRN 2704398. and Farah, Paolo Davide; Cima, Elena (15 December 2015). "WTO and Renewable Energy: Lessons from the Case Law". 49 JOURNAL OF WORLD TRADE 6, Kluwer Law International. SSRN 2704453.
  48. ^ "Going for Growth 2019: The time for reform is now - OECD". www.oecd.org. from the original on 2019-10-08. Retrieved 2019-10-01.
  49. ^ "Uncertain global economy should prompt governments to embark on reforms that boost sustainable growth, raise incomes and increase opportunities for all - OECD". www.oecd.org. from the original on 2019-10-01. Retrieved 2019-10-01.
  50. ^ "Audit of the subsidy statements". from the original on 2021-04-18. Retrieved 2021-04-18.
  51. ^ Myers, N. (1997). "Perverse subsidies". In Costanza, R.; Norgaard, R.; Daly, H.; Goodland, R.; Cumberland, J. (eds.). An introduction to ecological economics. Boca Raton, Fla.: St. Lucie Press. ISBN 978-1884015724. Retrieved 2013-08-03.
  52. ^ Is That a Good State/Local Economic Development Deal? A Checklist 2014-06-05 at the Wayback Machine (2014-06-03), Naked Capitalism
  53. ^ James, A.N.; Gaston, K.J.; Balmford, A. (1999). "Balancing the Earth's accounts". Nature. 401 (6751): 323–324. Bibcode:1999Natur.401..323J. doi:10.1038/43774. PMID 16862091. S2CID 4410695.
  54. ^ a b c d e f g h Robin, S.; Wolcott, R.; Quintela, C.E. (2003). (PDF). Durban, South Africa: Vth World Parks Congress: Sustainable Finance Stream. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2013-12-03.
  55. ^ McDonald, B.D.; Decker, J.W.; Johnson, B.A.M. (2020). "You don't always get what you want: The effect of financial incentives on state fiscal health". Public Administration Review. 81 (3): 365–374. doi:10.1111/puar.13163.
  56. ^ a b c van Beers, Cees; van den Bergh, Jeroen CJM (2009). "Environmental Harm of Hidden Subsidies: Global Warming and Acidification" (PDF). Ambio: A Journal of the Human Environment. 38 (6): 339–341. doi:10.1579/08-A-616.1. PMID 19860158. (PDF) from the original on 2011-09-03. Retrieved 2019-09-18.
  57. ^ a b van Beers, C.; de Moor, A. (1998). . Planejamento e Políticas Públicas. 18: 49–69. Archived from the original on 2016-03-04. Retrieved 2013-09-08.
  58. ^ a b c Myers, N. (1996). "Perverse Subsidies" (PDF). Sixth Ordinary Meeting of the Conference of the Parties to the Convention on Biological Diversity: 268–278. (PDF) from the original on 2012-05-12. Retrieved 2013-09-08.
  59. ^ a b Myers, N. (1998). "Consumption and sustainable development: the role of perverse subsidies" (PDF). Background Paper for the 1998 Human Development Report: 1–31. (PDF) from the original on 2019-12-09. Retrieved 2013-09-08.
  60. ^ Bellmann, C.; Hepburn, J.; Sugathan, M.; Monkelbaan, J. (2012). (PDF). International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development: Information Note June 2012. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2020-08-08. Retrieved 2013-09-08.
  61. ^ Myers, N.; Kent, J. (2001). Perverse subsidies: how tax dollars can undercut the environment and the economy. Washington, DC: Island Press. pp. box 3.2. ISBN 978-1-55963-835-7.
  62. ^ Steenblik, R. (1998). "Previous Multilateral Efforts to Discipline Subsidies to Natural Resource Based Industries" (PDF). Workshop on the Impact of Government Financial Transfers on Fisheries Management, Resource Sustainability, and International Trade. (PDF) from the original on 2012-10-22. Retrieved 2013-08-05.
  63. ^ "How Farm Subsidies Harm Taxpayers, Consumers, and Farmers, Too". from the original on 2018-04-23. Retrieved 2018-04-23.
  64. ^ "Who Benefits from Farm Subsidies?". from the original on 2018-04-23. Retrieved 2018-04-23.
  65. ^ Portugal, L. (2002). "OECD Work on Defining and Measuring Subsidies in Agriculture". The OECD Workshop on Environmentally Harmful Subsidies, Paris, 7–8 November 2002.
  66. ^ OECD (2003). "Perverse incentives in biodiversity loss" (PDF). Working Party on Global and Structural Policies Working Group on Economic Aspects of Biodiversity. (PDF) from the original on 2013-12-03. Retrieved 2013-08-05.
  67. ^ Robin, S.; Wolcott, R.; Quintela, C.E. (2003). (PDF). Durban, South Africa: Vth World Parks Congress: Sustainable Finance Stream. p. 4. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2013-12-03.
  68. ^ Porter, G. (1998). "Natural Resource Subsidies, Trade and Environment: The Cases of Forest and Fisheries" (PDF). Center for Environmental Law. (PDF) from the original on 2012-09-15. Retrieved 2013-08-05.
  69. ^ "Report of the Expert Consultation on Identifying, Assessing and Reporting on Subsidies in the Fishing Industry - Rome, 3-6 December 2002". Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Food and Agriculture Organization. from the original on 16 March 2018. Retrieved 16 March 2018.
  70. ^ Manufacturing in Britain: A Survey of Factors Affecting Growth and Performance, ISR/Google Books, 2019, pages 37-38. ISBN 9780906321614
  71. ^ Clegg, Jonathan (28 April 2015). "NFL to End Tax-Exempt Status." 2017-11-12 at the Wayback Machine The Wall Street Journal. Retrieved 17 December 2019.
  72. ^ Cohen, R. (2008). "Playing by the NFL's Tax Exempt Rulesh". NonProfit Quarterly. from the original on 2013-08-20. Retrieved 2013-04-15.
  73. ^ Fowler, P.; Fokker, R. (2004). A Sweeter Future? The potential for EU sugar reform to contribute to poverty reduction in Southern Africa. Oxford: Oxfam International. ISBN 9781848141940. from the original on 2014-02-09. Retrieved 2013-09-08.

Further reading

External links

subsidy, subsidy, government, incentive, type, government, expenditure, targeted, towards, individuals, households, well, businesses, with, stabilising, economy, ensures, that, individuals, households, viable, having, access, essential, goods, services, while,. A subsidy or government incentive is a type of government expenditure targeted towards individuals and households as well as businesses with the aim of stabilising the economy It ensures that individuals and households are viable by having access to essential goods and services while giving businesses the opportunity to stay afloat and or competitive Subsidies not only promote long term economic stability but also help governments to respond to economic shocks during a recession or in response to unforeseen shocks such as COVID 19 1 Subsidies take various forms such as direct government expenditures tax incentives soft loans price support and government provision of goods and services 2 For instance the government may distribute direct payment subsidies to individuals and households during an economic downturn in order to help its citizens pay their bills and to stimulate economic activity Here subsidies act as an effective financial aid issued when the economy experiences economic hardship 3 They can also be a good policy tool to revise market imperfections when rational and competitive firms fail to produce an optimal market outcome For example in an imperfect market condition governments can inject subsidies to encourage firms to invest in R amp D research and development This will not only benefit the firms but also produce some positive externalities such that it benefits the industry in which the firms belong and most importantly the society at large 4 Although commonly extended from the government the term subsidy can relate to any type of support for example from NGOs or as implicit subsidies Subsidies come in various forms including direct cash grants interest free loans and indirect tax breaks insurance low interest loans accelerated depreciation rent rebates 5 6 Furthermore they can be broad or narrow legal or illegal ethical or unethical The most common forms of subsidies are those to the producer or the consumer Producer production subsidies ensure producers are better off by either supplying market price support direct support or payments to factors of production 6 Consumer consumption subsidies commonly reduce the price of goods and services to the consumer For example in the US at one time it was cheaper to buy gasoline than bottled water 7 All countries use subsidies via national and sub national entities through different forms such as tax incentives and direct grants Likewise subsidies have an economic influence on both a domestic and international level On a domestic level subsidies affect the allocation decision of domestic resources income distribution and expenditure productivity On an international level subsidies may increase or decrease international interaction and integration through trade 8 For this reason having a thorough subsidy policy is essential as its inadequacy can potentially lead to financial hardship and problems for not only the poor or low income individuals but the aggregate economy as a whole 9 At large subsidies take up a substantial portion of the government and economy Amongst OECD countries in 2020 the median of subsidies and other transfers such as social benefits and non repayable transfers to private and public enterprises was 56 3 percent of total government expenses which was 34 9 percent weighted average of GDP in the same year 10 Yet the number of subsidy measures in force have been rapidly increasing since 2008 11 Contents 1 Types 1 1 Production subsidy 1 2 Consumer consumption subsidy 1 3 Export subsidy 1 4 Import subsidy 1 5 Employment subsidy 1 6 Tax subsidy 1 7 Transport subsidies 1 8 Energy subsidies 1 8 1 Fossil fuels 1 9 Housing subsidies 1 10 Environmental externalities 2 Categorising subsidies 2 1 Direct and Indirect 2 2 Production and Consumption 2 3 Broad and Narrow 2 4 Monetary and Non monetary 3 Economic effects 4 Preventing fraud 5 Perverse subsidies 5 1 Definitions 5 2 Effects 5 3 Implementation 5 4 Examples 5 4 1 Agricultural subsidies 5 4 2 Fisheries 5 4 3 Manufacturing subsidies 5 4 4 Others 6 Short list of subsidies 7 See also 8 References 9 Further reading 10 External linksTypes EditProduction subsidy Edit A production subsidy encourages suppliers to increase the output of a particular product by partially offsetting the production costs or losses 12 The objective of production subsidies is to expand production of a particular product more so that the market would promote but without raising the final price to consumers This type of subsidy is predominantly found in developed markets 6 Other examples of production subsidies include the assistance in the creation of a new firm Enterprise Investment Scheme industry industrial policy and even the development of certain areas regional policy Production subsidies are critically discussed in the literature as they can cause many problems including the additional cost of storing the extra produced products depressing world market prices and incentivizing producers to over produce for example a farmer overproducing in terms of his land s carrying capacity Consumer consumption subsidy Edit A consumption subsidy is one that subsidizes the behavior of consumers This type of subsidies are most common in developing countries where governments subsidise such things as food water electricity and education on the basis that no matter how impoverished all should be allowed those most basic requirements 6 For example some governments offer lifeline rates for electricity that is the first increment of electricity each month is subsidized 6 Evidence from recent studies suggests that government expenditures on subsidies remain high in many countries often amounting to several percentage points of GDP Subsidization on such a scale implies substantial opportunity costs There are at least three compelling reasons for studying government subsidy behavior First subsidies are a major instrument of government expenditure policy Second on a domestic level subsidies affect domestic resource allocation decisions income distribution and expenditure productivity A consumer subsidy is a shift in demand as the subsidy is given directly to consumers Export subsidy Edit An export subsidy is a support from the government for products that are exported as a means of assisting the country s balance of payments 12 Usha Haley and George Haley identified the subsidies to manufacturing industry provided by the Chinese government and how they have altered trade patterns 5 Traditionally economists have argued that subsidies benefit consumers but hurt the subsidizing countries Haley and Haley provided data to show that over the decade after China joined the World Trade Organization industrial subsidies have helped give China an advantage in industries in which they previously enjoyed no comparative advantage such as the steel glass paper auto parts and solar industries 5 China s shores have also collapsed from overfishing and industrialization which is why the Chinese government heavily subsidizes its fishermen who sail the world in search of new grounds 13 Export subsidy is known for being abused For example some exporters substantially over declare the value of their goods so as to benefit more from the export subsidy Another method is to export a batch of goods to a foreign country but the same goods will be re imported by the same trader via a circuitous route and changing the product description so as to obscure their origin Thus the trader benefits from the export subsidy without creating real trade value to the economy Export subsidy as such can become a self defeating and disruptive policy Adam Smith observed that special government subsidies enabled exporters to sell abroad at substantial ongoing losses He did not regard that as a sound and sustainable policy That was because under normal industrial commercial conditions their own interests soon oblige loss making businesses to deploy their capital in other ways or to move into markets where the sales prices do cover the supply costs and yield ordinary profits Like other mercantilist schemes and devices export bounties are a means of trying to force business capital into channels it would not naturally enter The schemes are invariably costly and damaging in various ways 14 Import subsidy Edit An import subsidy is support from the government for products that are imported Rarer than an export subsidy an import subsidy further reduces the price to consumers for imported goods Import subsidies have various effects depending on the subject For example consumers in the importing country are better off and experience an increase in consumer welfare due to the decrease in price of the imported goods as well as the decrease in price of the domestic substitute goods Conversely the consumers in the exporting country experience a decrease in consumer welfare due to an increase in the price of their domestic goods Furthermore producers of the importing country experience a loss of welfare due to a decrease of the price for the good in their market while on the other side the exporters of the producing country experience an increase in well being due to the increase in demand Ultimately the import subsidy is rarely used due to an overall loss of welfare for the country due to a decrease in domestic production and a reduction in production throughout the world However that can result in a redistribution of income 15 Employment subsidy Edit Employment or wage subsidies keep the employment relationship ongoing even during financial crisis It is particularly beneficial for enterprises to recover quickly after a temporary suspension following a crisis Workers are prevented from losing their jobs and other associated employment benefits such as annual leave entitlements and retirement pensions 16 Employment subsidies allow individual beneficiaries a minimum standard of living at the very least However less than half of active jobseekers in around 50 of OECD countries receive unemployment support 17 The effect of employment subsidies may not be evident immediately When employers received grants to subside a substantial part of the wages for retaining their employees or to create new jobs during severe recessions such as the 2008 GFC Global Financial Crisis there were minor impacts on employment during the first year However the subsidy began to yield positive effects on employment particularly a decrease in the unemployment rate in the second year as employers began to properly utilise the subsidy 18 Tax subsidy Edit Tax subsidies also known as tax breaks or tax expenditures are a way for governments to achieve certain outcomes without directly providing cash payments By offering tax breaks the government can incentivize behavior that is beneficial to the economy or society as a whole However tax subsidies can also have negative consequences One type of tax subsidy is a health tax deduction which allows individuals or businesses to deduct their health expenses from their taxable income This can be seen as a way to incentivize people to prioritize their health and well being However it can also create distortions in the economy by encouraging people to spend more on health care than they otherwise would Another type of tax subsidy is related to Intellectual Property Base Erosion and Profit Shifting BEPS is a particular form of tax subsidy that involves companies shifting their profits to low tax jurisdictions in order to reduce their overall tax burden The Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting is a treaty signed by half the nations of the world aimed at preventing this type of tax avoidance While tax subsidies can be effective in achieving certain outcomes they are also less transparent than direct cash payments and can be difficult to undo Additionally some argue that tax breaks disproportionately benefit the wealthy and large corporations further exacerbating income inequality Therefore it is important for governments to carefully consider the potential consequences of offering tax subsidies and ensure that they are targeted towards achieving the greatest public good Furthermore tax subsidies can have unintended consequences such as creating market distortions that favor certain industries or companies over others For example if a government offers tax breaks to incentivize investment in renewable energy it may lead to a glut of renewable energy projects and an oversupply of energy in the market This in turn can lead to lower prices for energy and financial losses for investors In addition tax subsidies can be difficult to monitor and enforce which can lead to abuse and fraud Companies may claim tax breaks for activities that do not qualify or may use complex legal structures to shift profits to lower tax jurisdictions This can result in lost revenue for governments and a lack of fairness in the tax system Despite these concerns tax subsidies remain a popular tool for governments to promote various policy objectives such as economic growth job creation and environmental sustainability The use of tax subsidies is often debated in political circles with some arguing that they are necessary to support certain industries or to incentivize certain behaviors while others argue that they create inefficiencies and distortions in the economy In conclusion tax subsidies are a powerful tool for governments to achieve policy goals but they come with their own set of challenges and limitations It is important for policymakers to carefully consider the potential unintended consequences of tax subsidies and to design them in a way that maximizes their benefits while minimizing their costs Additionally strong monitoring and enforcement mechanisms are needed to ensure that tax subsidies are used appropriately and do not result in abuse or fraud Transport subsidies Edit Some governments subsidise transport especially rail and bus transport which decrease congestion and pollution compared to cars In the EU rail subsidies are around 73 billion and Chinese subsidies reach 130 billion 19 20 Publicly owned airports can be an indirect subsidy if they lose money The European Union for instance criticizes Germany for its high number of money losing airports that are used primarily by low cost carriers characterizing the arrangement as an illegal subsidy citation needed In many countries roads and highways are paid for through general revenue rather than tolls or other dedicated sources that are paid only by road users creating an indirect subsidy for road transportation The fact that long distance buses in Germany do not pay tolls has been called an indirect subsidy by critics who point to track access charges for railways Energy subsidies Edit This section is an excerpt from Energy subsidy edit Energy subsidies are measures that keep prices for customers below market levels or for suppliers above market levels or reduce costs for customers and suppliers 21 22 Energy subsidies may be direct cash transfers to suppliers customers or related bodies as well as indirect support mechanisms such as tax exemptions and rebates price controls trade restrictions and limits on market access The International Renewable Energy Agency tracked some 634 billion in energy sector subsidies in 2020 and found that around 70 were fossil fuel subsidies About 20 went to renewable power generation 6 to biofuels and just over 3 to nuclear 23 Fossil fuels Edit This section is an excerpt from Fossil fuel subsidies edit Fossil fuel subsidies per capita 2019 Fossil fuel pre tax subsidies per capita are measured in constant US dollars Fossil fuel subsidies as a share of GDP 2019 Fossil fuel pre tax subsidies are given as a share of total gross domestic product Fossil fuel subsidies are energy subsidies on fossil fuels They may be tax breaks on consumption such as a lower sales tax on natural gas for residential heating or subsidies on production such as tax breaks on exploration for oil Or they may be free or cheap negative externalities such as air pollution or climate change due to burning gasoline diesel and jet fuel Some fossil fuel subsidies are via electricity generation such as subsidies for coal fired power stations Eliminating fossil fuel subsidies would reduce the health risks of air pollution 24 and would greatly reduce global carbon emissions thus helping to limit climate change 25 As of 2021 update policy researchers estimate that substantially more money is spent on fossil fuel subsidies than on environmentally harmful agricultural subsidies or environmentally harmful water subsidies 26 The International Energy Agency says that High fossil fuel prices hit the poor hardest but subsidies are rarely well targeted to protect vulnerable groups and tend to benefit better off segments of the population 27 Despite the G20 countries having pledged to phase out inefficient fossil fuel subsidies 28 as of 2023 update they continue because of voter demand 29 30 or for energy security 31 Global fossil fuel consumption subsidies in 2022 have been estimated at one trillion dollars 27 although they vary each year depending on oil prices they are consistently hundreds of billions of dollars 32 Housing subsidies Edit Housing subsidies are designed to promote the construction industry and homeownership As of 2018 U S housing subsidies total around 15 billion per year Housing subsidies can come in two types assistance with down payment and interest rate subsidies The deduction of mortgage interest from the federal income tax accounts for the largest interest rate subsidy Additionally the federal government will help low income families with the down payment coming to 10 9 million in 2008 33 As a housing policy tool housing subsidies also help low income individuals gain and maintain liveable residency by easing the cost burdens of housing for low income individuals and households However some policy makers and experts believe they are costly to implement and may even reduce incentives for beneficiaries to participate in the labour market In the contrary certain literatures have found that subsidy cuts do not encourage employment or participation among beneficiaries For example research by Daniel Borbely found that reducing housing subsidies did not increase employment and labour force participation Though he also added that claimants relocated to other areas of the rental market to maintain their benefits 34 Nonetheless the most common method for providing housing subsidies is via direct payments to renters by covering a part of their rent on the private rent market This method of direct transfer of housing subsidies is often referred to as housing vouchers In the United States the so called Section 8 is a direct payment program subsidising the largest amount of money to renters for rental assistance 35 Environmental externalities Edit See also Climate change mitigation Environmental economics and Environmental protection While conventional subsidies require financial support many economists have described implicit subsidies in the form of untaxed environmental externalities 7 These externalities include things such as pollution from vehicle emissions pesticides or other sources A 2015 report studied the implicit subsidies accruing to 20 fossil fuel companies It estimated that the societal costs from downstream emissions and pollution attributable to these companies were substantial 36 37 The report spans the period 2008 2012 and notes that for all companies and all years the economic cost to society of their CO2 emissions was greater than their after tax profit with the single exception of ExxonMobil in 2008 36 4 Pure coal companies fare even worse the economic cost to society exceeds total revenue employment taxes supply purchases and indirect employment in all years with this cost varying between nearly 2 and nearly 9 per 1 of revenue 36 4 5 Categorising subsidies EditDirect and Indirect Edit The first important classification of subsidies are direct and indirect subsidies Subsidies are categorised as direct when it involves actual cash outlays targeted towards a specified individual or household Popular examples include is cash grants and interest free loans Subsidies can also be classified as indirect when they do not involve actual payments An example would be an increase in disposable income arising from a decrease in price of an essential good or service that the government has enforced in a form of monetary support In contrast a decrease in the price of a good or service may lead to an increase in revenue for producers earned from the heightened demand by consumers 38 The use of indirect subsidies such as price controls is widespread among developing economies and emerging markets as a necessary tool for social policy It has proven to be effective in many cases but price controls have a potential to dampen investment activity and growth cause heavy fiscal burdens for the government and may even complicate the optimal performance of monetary policy To prevent the undesirable negative effects price control regimes may be replaced by creating social safety nets and proposing sound reforms to encourage competition and growth 39 Production and Consumption Edit Another important classification of subsidies are producer production subsidies and consumer consumption subsidies Production subsidies are designed to ensure producers are advantaged by creating fluid market activity through other market control mechanisms or by providing cash payments for factors of production Consumption subsidies benefit consumers typically through a reduction in the market price of goods and services They are commonly used by governments of many developing countries in an attempt to secure the most basic needs for its population 40 Broad and Narrow Edit These various subsidies can be divided into broad and narrow Narrow subsidies are those monetary transfers that are easily identifiable and have a clear intent They are commonly characterised by a monetary transfer between governments and institutions or businesses and individuals A classic example is a government payment to a farmer 41 Monetary and Non monetary Edit Conversely broad subsidies include both monetary and non monetary subsidies and is often difficult to identify 41 A broad subsidy is less attributable and less transparent Environmental externalities are the most common type of broad subsidy Economic effects Edit Competitive equilibrium is a state of balance between buyers and suppliers in which the quantity demanded of a good is the quantity supplied at a specified price When the price falls the quantity demand exceeds the equilibrium quantity conversely a reduction in the supply of a good beyond equilibrium quantity implies an increase in the price The effect of a subsidy is to shift the supply or demand curve to the right i e increases the supply or demand by the amount of the subsidy If a consumer is receiving the subsidy a lower price of a good resulting from the marginal subsidy on consumption increases demand shifting the demand curve to the right If a supplier is receiving the subsidy an increase in the price revenue resulting from the marginal subsidy on production results increases supply shifting the supply curve to the right Assuming the market is in a perfectly competitive equilibrium a subsidy increases the supply of the good beyond the equilibrium competitive quantity The imbalance creates deadweight loss Deadweight loss from a subsidy is the amount by which the cost of the subsidy exceeds the gains of the subsidy 42 The magnitude of the deadweight loss is dependent on the size of the subsidy This is considered a market failure or inefficiency 42 Subsidies targeted at goods in one country by lowering the price of those goods make them more competitive against foreign goods thereby reducing foreign competition 43 As a result many developing countries cannot engage in foreign trade and receive lower prices for their products in the global market This is considered protectionism a government policy to erect trade barriers in order to protect domestic industries 44 The problem with protectionism arises when industries are selected for nationalistic reasons infant industry rather than to gain a comparative advantage The market distortion and reduction in social welfare is the logic behind the World Bank policy for the removal of subsidies in developing countries 45 Subsidies create spillover effects in other economic sectors and industries A subsidized product sold in the world market lowers the price of the good in other countries Since subsidies result in lower revenues for producers of foreign countries they are a source of tension between the United States Europe and poorer developing countries 46 While subsidies may provide immediate benefits to an industry in the long run they may prove to have unethical negative effects Subsidies are intended to support public interest however they can violate ethical or legal principles if they lead to higher consumer prices or discriminate against some producers to benefit others 43 For example domestic subsidies granted by individual US states may be unconstitutional if they discriminate against out of state producers violating the Privileges and Immunities Clause or the Dormant Commerce Clause of the United States Constitution 43 Depending on their nature subsidies are discouraged by international trade agreements such as the World Trade Organization WTO This trend however may change in the future as needs of sustainable development and environmental protection could suggest different interpretations regarding energy and renewable energy subsidies 47 In its July 2019 report Going for Growth 2019 The time for reform is now the OECD suggests that countries make better use of environmental taxation phase out agricultural subsidies and environmentally harmful tax breaks 48 49 Preventing fraud EditIn the Netherlands audits are performed to verify whether the funds that have been received has indeed been spent legally and all requirements of the subsidy provider have been attained for the purpose intended 50 It hence prevents fraud Perverse subsidies EditThe neutrality of this section is disputed Relevant discussion may be found on the talk page Please do not remove this message until conditions to do so are met September 2019 Learn how and when to remove this template message Definitions Edit Although subsidies can be important many are perverse in the sense of having adverse unintended consequences To be perverse subsidies must exert effects that are demonstrably and significantly adverse both economically and environmentally 6 A subsidy rarely if ever starts perverse but over time a legitimate efficacious subsidy can become perverse or illegitimate if it is not withdrawn after meeting its goal or as political goals change Perverse subsidies are now so widespread that as of 2007 they amounted 2 trillion per year in the six most subsidised sectors alone agriculture fossil fuels road transportation water fisheries and forestry 51 Effects Edit The detrimental effects of perverse subsidies are diverse in nature and reach Case studies from differing sectors are highlighted below but can be summarised as follows Directly they are expensive to governments by directing resources away from other legitimate should priorities such as environmental conservation education health or infrastructure 52 41 53 54 ultimately reducing the fiscal health of the government 55 Indirectly they cause environmental degradation exploitation of resources pollution loss of landscape misuse and overuse of supplies which as well as its fundamental damage acts as a further brake on economies tend to benefit the few at the expense of the many and the rich at the expense of the poor lead to further polarization of development between the Northern and Southern hemispheres lower global market prices and undermine investment decisions reducing the pressure on businesses to become more efficient 7 54 56 Over time the latter effect means support becomes enshrined in human behaviour and business decisions to the point where people become reliant on even addicted to subsidies locking them into society 57 Consumer attitudes do not change and become out of date off target and inefficient 7 furthermore over time people feel a sense of historical right to them 56 Implementation Edit Perverse subsidies are not tackled as robustly as they should be Principally this is because they become locked into society causing bureaucratic roadblocks and institutional inertia 58 59 When cuts are suggested many argue most fervently by those entitled special interest groups and political lobbyists that it will disrupt and harm the lives of people who receive them distort domestic competitiveness curbing trade opportunities and increase unemployment 56 60 Individual governments recognise this as a prisoner s dilemma insofar as that even if they wanted to adopt subsidy reform by acting unilaterally they fear only negative effects will ensue if others do not follow 57 Furthermore cutting subsidies however perverse they may be is considered a vote losing policy 58 Reform of perverse subsidies is at a propitious time The current economic conditions mean governments are forced into fiscal constraints and are looking for ways to reduce activist roles in their economies 59 There are two main reform paths unilateral and multilateral Unilateral agreements one country are less likely to be undertaken for the reasons outlined above although New Zealand 61 Russia Bangladesh and others represent successful examples 7 Multilateral actions by several countries are more likely to succeed as this reduces competitiveness concerns but are more complex to implement requiring greater international collaboration through a body such as the WTO 54 Irrespective of the path the aim of policymakers should be to create alternative policies that target the same issue as the original subsidies but better develop subsidy removal strategies allowing market discipline to return introduce sunset provisions that require remaining subsidies to be re justified periodically and make perverse subsidies more transparent to taxpayers to alleviate the vote loser concern 7 Examples Edit Agricultural subsidies Edit Support for agriculture dates back to the 19th century It was developed extensively in the EU and USA across the two World Wars and the Great Depression to protect domestic food production but remains important across the world today 54 58 In 2005 US farmers received 14 billion and EU farmers 47 billion in agricultural subsidies 43 Today agricultural subsidies are defended on the grounds of helping farmers to maintain their livelihoods The majority of payments are based on outputs and inputs and thus favour the larger producing agribusinesses over the small scale farmers 6 62 In the USA nearly 30 of payments go to the top 2 of farmers 54 63 64 By subsidising inputs and outputs through such schemes as yield based subsidisation farmers are encouraged to over produce using intensive methods including using more fertilizers and pesticides grow high yielding monocultures reduce crop rotation shorten fallow periods and promote exploitative land use change from forests rainforests and wetlands to agricultural land 54 These all lead to severe environmental degradation including adverse effects on soil quality and productivity including erosion nutrient supply and salinity which in turn affects carbon storage and cycling water retention and drought resistance water quality including pollution nutrient deposition and eutrophication of waterways and lowering of water tables diversity of flora and fauna including indigenous species both directly and indirectly through the destruction of habitats resulting in a genetic wipe out 6 54 65 66 Cotton growers in the US reportedly receive half their income from the government under the Farm Bill of 2002 The subsidy payments stimulated overproduction and resulted in a record cotton harvest in 2002 much of which had to be sold at very reduced prices in the global market 43 For foreign producers the depressed cotton price lowered their prices far below the break even price In fact African farmers received 35 to 40 cents per pound for cotton while US cotton growers backed by government agricultural payments received 75 cents per pound Developing countries and trade organizations argue that poorer countries should be able to export their principal commodities to survive but protectionist laws and payments in the United States and Europe prevent these countries from engaging in international trade opportunities Fisheries Edit Today much of the world s major fisheries are overexploited in 2002 the WWF estimate this at approximately 75 Fishing subsidies include direct assistant to fishers loan support programs tax preferences and insurance support capital and infrastructure programs marketing and price support programs and fisheries management research and conservation programs 67 They promote the expansion of fishing fleets the supply of larger and longer nets larger yields and indiscriminate catch as well as mitigating risks which encourages further investment into large scale operations to the disfavour of the already struggling small scale industry 54 68 Collectively these result in the continued overcapitalization and overfishing of marine fisheries There are four categories of fisheries subsidies First are direct financial transfers second are indirect financial transfers and services Third certain forms of intervention and fourth not intervening The first category regards direct payments from the government received by the fisheries industry These typically affect profits of the industry in the short term and can be negative or positive Category two pertains to government intervention not involving those under the first category These subsidies also affect the profits in the short term but typically are not negative Category three includes intervention that results in a negative short term economic impact but economic benefits in the long term These benefits are usually more general societal benefits such as the environment The final category pertains to inaction by the government allowing producers to impose certain production costs on others These subsidies tend to lead to positive benefits in the short term but negative in the long term 69 Manufacturing subsidies Edit A survey of manufacturing in Britain found government subsidies had had various unintended dysfunctional consequences The subsidies had usually been selective or discriminatory benefiting some companies at the expense of others Government money in the form of grants and awards of production and R amp D contracts had gone to advanced and viable firms as well as old uneconomic enterprises However the main recipients had been larger established companies while most of the firms pioneering radical technical product developments with long term economic growth potential had been new small enterprises The study concluded that instead of providing subsidies governments wanting to benefit industrial technological development and performance should lower standard rates of business taxation raise tax allowances for investments in new plant equipment and products and remove obstacles to market competition and customer choice 70 Others Edit The US National Football League s NFL profits have topped records at 11 billion the highest of all sports The NFL had tax exempt status until voluntarily relinquishing it in 2015 and new stadiums have been built with public subsidies 71 72 The Commitment to Development Index CDI published by the Center for Global Development measures the effect that subsidies and trade barriers actually have on the undeveloped world It uses trade along with six other components such as aid or investment to rank and evaluate developed countries on policies that affect the undeveloped world It finds that the richest countries spend 106 billion per year subsidizing their own farmers almost exactly as much as they spend on foreign aid 73 Short list of subsidies EditAgricultural subsidy Fisheries subsidy Export subsidy Energy subsidy Fossil fuel subsidies oil subsidies coal subsidies gas subsidies Photovoltaics subsidy Party subsidies Wage subsidy Artist subsidy Netherlands See also EditAgricultural subsidy Cross subsidization Cultural subsidy Energy subsidy Subsidization of company cars Federal government Audit software in governmental procurement Municipal services Perverse incentive Rail subsidies Stadium subsidy Tax exemption Wage subsidyReferences Edit Ayanna Julien 2022 Subsidy Salem Press Encyclopedia Retrieved 27 April 2023 OECD Subsidies Competition and Trade OECD Competition Policy Roundtable Background Note PDF OECD Archived PDF from the original on 27 November 2022 Retrieved 27 April 2023 What is a Subsidy Real Vision Archived from the original on 28 April 2023 Retrieved 27 April 2023 Clements Benedict Parry Ian What Are Subsidies International Monetary Fund International Monetary Fund Archived from the original on 28 April 2023 Retrieved 27 April 2023 a b c Haley U G Haley 2013 Subsidies to Chinese Industry The Economist London Oxford University Press Archived from the original on 2017 06 16 Retrieved 2017 09 15 a b c d e f g h Myers N Kent J 2001 Perverse subsidies how tax dollars can undercut the environment and the economy Washington DC Island Press ISBN 978 1 55963 835 7 a b c d e f Myers N 1998 Lifting the veil on perverse subsidies Nature 392 6674 327 328 Bibcode 1998Natur 392 327M doi 10 1038 32761 S2CID 4426064 Schwartz Gerd Clements Benedict 1999 Government Subsidies Journal of Economic Surveys 13 2 119 doi 10 1111 1467 6419 00079 Archived from the original on 28 April 2023 Retrieved 27 April 2023 Johan Kruger Afcap Consulting Subsidies PDF World Bank Group Archived PDF from the original on 7 May 2023 Retrieved 27 April 2023 Subsidies and other transfers of expense OECD members The World Bank Archived from the original on 28 April 2023 Retrieved 27 April 2023 OECD Subsidies Competition and Trade OECD Competition Policy Roundtable Background Note PDF Archived PDF from the original on 27 November 2022 Retrieved 27 April 2023 a b Collins Dictionary of Economics Archived from the original on 2013 09 27 Retrieved 2013 09 05 Urbina Ian 11 August 2020 The deadly secret of China s invisible armada NBC News Archived from the original on 19 February 2021 Retrieved 19 February 2021 Smith Adam The Wealth of Nations A Translation into Modern English ISR Google Books 2019 page 300 ISBN 9780906321706 Suranovic Steven Welfare Effects of a VIE Import Subsidy Large Country International Trade Theory and Policy Archived from the original on 16 March 2018 Retrieved 16 March 2018 Temporary Wage Subsidies PDF International Labour Organisation Retrieved 27 April 2023 Basic income as a policy option Can it add up PDF OECD Archived PDF from the original on 28 April 2023 Retrieved 27 April 2023 Kim Hyejin Lee Jungmin 2019 Can employment subsidies save jobs Evidence from a shipbuilding city in South Korea Labour Economics 61 101763 doi 10 1016 j labeco 2019 101763 S2CID 204435231 EU Technical Report 2007 Archived from the original on 2021 02 06 Retrieved 2016 03 23 China to Invest 128 Billion in Rail Push for Global Share Bloomberg News 5 March 2015 Archived from the original on 2017 03 24 Retrieved 2017 03 11 Timperley Jocelyn 20 October 2021 Why fossil fuel subsidies are so hard to kill Nature Retrieved 26 October 2021 Fossil fuel subsidies generally take two forms Production subsidies and Consumption subsidies OECD 1998 Timperley Jocelyn 20 October 2021 Why fossil fuel subsidies are so hard to kill Nature Retrieved 26 October 2021 Local Environmental Externalities due to Energy Price Subsidies A Focus on Air Pollution and Health PDF World Bank Fossil fuel subsidies If we want to reduce greenhouse gas emissions we should not pay people to burn fossil fuels Our World in Data Retrieved 2021 11 04 Protecting Nature by Reforming Environmentally Harmful Subsidies The Role of Business Earth Track www earthtrack net Retrieved 2022 03 07 a b Fossil Fuels Consumption Subsidies 2022 Analysis IEA Retrieved 2023 02 16 Update on recent progress in reform of inefficient fossil fuel subsidies that encourage wasteful consumption PDF 2021 George Johannes Urpelainen and Elisha 2021 07 14 Reforming global fossil fuel subsidies How the United States can restart international cooperation Brookings Retrieved 2022 02 26 Martinez Alvarez Cesar B Hazlett Chad Mahdavi Paasha Ross Michael L 2022 11 22 Political leadership has limited impact on fossil fuel taxes and subsidies Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 119 47 doi 10 1073 pnas 2208024119 ISSN 0027 8424 PMC 9704748 PMID 36375060 Brower Derek Wilson Tom Giles Chris 2022 02 25 The new energy shock Putin Ukraine and the global economy Financial Times Retrieved 2022 02 26 Fossil Fuel Subsidies amp Finance Oil Change International Retrieved 2022 06 02 Amadeo Kimberly Government Subsidies Farm Oil Export etc The Balance Archived from the original on 16 March 2018 Retrieved 16 March 2018 Borbely Daniel 2022 The impact of housing subsidy cuts on the labour market outcomes of claimants Evidence from England Journal of Housing Economics 57 101859 doi 10 1016 j jhe 2022 101859 What Are Housing Subsidies Planetizen Archived from the original on 28 April 2023 Retrieved 27 April 2023 a b c Hope Chris Gilding Paul Alvarez Jimena 2015 Quantifying the implicit climate subsidy received by leading fossil fuel companies Working Paper No 02 2015 PDF Cambridge UK Cambridge Judge Business School University of Cambridge Archived from the original PDF on 28 March 2016 Retrieved 27 June 2016 Measuring fossil fuel hidden costs University of Cambridge Judge Business School 23 July 2015 Archived from the original on 26 June 2016 Retrieved 27 June 2016 Subsidy ClearTax Archived from the original on 28 April 2023 Retrieved 27 April 2023 Guenette Justin Damien Price Controls Good Intentions Bad Outcomes PDF World Bank Group Retrieved 27 April 2023 Subsidy ClearTax Archived from the original on 28 April 2023 Retrieved 27 April 2023 a b c Myers N 2008 Perverse Priorities PDF IUCN Opinion Piece 6 7 Archived PDF from the original on 2016 03 04 Retrieved 2013 09 08 a b Watkins Thayer The Impact of an Excise Tax or Subsidy on Price San Jose State University Department of Economics Archived from the original on 2016 06 23 Retrieved 2016 06 28 a b c d e Kolb R W 2008 Subsidies Encyclopedia of business ethics and society Thousand Oaks Sage Publications ISBN 9781412916523 Protectionism 2006 Collins Dictionary Amegashie J A 2006 The Economics of Subsidies Crossroads 6 2 7 15 Parkin M Powell M Matthews K 2007 Economics 7th ed Harlow Addison Wesley ISBN 978 0132041225 Farah Paolo Davide Cima Elena 2015 World Trade Organization Renewable Energy Subsidies and the Case of Feed In Tariffs Time for Reform Toward Sustainable Development Georgetown International Environmental Law Review GIELR 27 1 SSRN 2704398 and Farah Paolo Davide Cima Elena 15 December 2015 WTO and Renewable Energy Lessons from the Case Law 49 JOURNAL OF WORLD TRADE 6 Kluwer Law International SSRN 2704453 Going for Growth 2019 The time for reform is now OECD www oecd org Archived from the original on 2019 10 08 Retrieved 2019 10 01 Uncertain global economy should prompt governments to embark on reforms that boost sustainable growth raise incomes and increase opportunities for all OECD www oecd org Archived from the original on 2019 10 01 Retrieved 2019 10 01 Audit of the subsidy statements Archived from the original on 2021 04 18 Retrieved 2021 04 18 Myers N 1997 Perverse subsidies In Costanza R Norgaard R Daly H Goodland R Cumberland J eds An introduction to ecological economics Boca Raton Fla St Lucie Press ISBN 978 1884015724 Retrieved 2013 08 03 Is That a Good State Local Economic Development Deal A Checklist Archived 2014 06 05 at the Wayback Machine 2014 06 03 Naked Capitalism James A N Gaston K J Balmford A 1999 Balancing the Earth s accounts Nature 401 6751 323 324 Bibcode 1999Natur 401 323J doi 10 1038 43774 PMID 16862091 S2CID 4410695 a b c d e f g h Robin S Wolcott R Quintela C E 2003 Perverse Subsidies and the Implications for Biodiversity A review of recent findings and the status of policy reforms PDF Durban South Africa Vth World Parks Congress Sustainable Finance Stream Archived from the original PDF on 2013 12 03 McDonald B D Decker J W Johnson B A M 2020 You don t always get what you want The effect of financial incentives on state fiscal health Public Administration Review 81 3 365 374 doi 10 1111 puar 13163 a b c van Beers Cees van den Bergh Jeroen CJM 2009 Environmental Harm of Hidden Subsidies Global Warming and Acidification PDF Ambio A Journal of the Human Environment 38 6 339 341 doi 10 1579 08 A 616 1 PMID 19860158 Archived PDF from the original on 2011 09 03 Retrieved 2019 09 18 a b van Beers C de Moor A 1998 Perverse subsidies international trade and the environment Planejamento e Politicas Publicas 18 49 69 Archived from the original on 2016 03 04 Retrieved 2013 09 08 a b c Myers N 1996 Perverse Subsidies PDF Sixth Ordinary Meeting of the Conference of the Parties to the Convention on Biological Diversity 268 278 Archived PDF from the original on 2012 05 12 Retrieved 2013 09 08 a b Myers N 1998 Consumption and sustainable development the role of perverse subsidies PDF Background Paper for the 1998 Human Development Report 1 31 Archived PDF from the original on 2019 12 09 Retrieved 2013 09 08 Bellmann C Hepburn J Sugathan M Monkelbaan J 2012 Tackling Perverse Subsidies in Agriculture Fisheries and Energy PDF International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development Information Note June 2012 Archived from the original PDF on 2020 08 08 Retrieved 2013 09 08 Myers N Kent J 2001 Perverse subsidies how tax dollars can undercut the environment and the economy Washington DC Island Press pp box 3 2 ISBN 978 1 55963 835 7 Steenblik R 1998 Previous Multilateral Efforts to Discipline Subsidies to Natural Resource Based Industries PDF Workshop on the Impact of Government Financial Transfers on Fisheries Management Resource Sustainability and International Trade Archived PDF from the original on 2012 10 22 Retrieved 2013 08 05 How Farm Subsidies Harm Taxpayers Consumers and Farmers Too Archived from the original on 2018 04 23 Retrieved 2018 04 23 Who Benefits from Farm Subsidies Archived from the original on 2018 04 23 Retrieved 2018 04 23 Portugal L 2002 OECD Work on Defining and Measuring Subsidies in Agriculture The OECD Workshop on Environmentally Harmful Subsidies Paris 7 8 November 2002 OECD 2003 Perverse incentives in biodiversity loss PDF Working Party on Global and Structural Policies Working Group on Economic Aspects of Biodiversity Archived PDF from the original on 2013 12 03 Retrieved 2013 08 05 Robin S Wolcott R Quintela C E 2003 Perverse Subsidies and the Implications for Biodiversity A review of recent findings and the status of policy reforms PDF Durban South Africa Vth World Parks Congress Sustainable Finance Stream p 4 Archived from the original PDF on 2013 12 03 Porter G 1998 Natural Resource Subsidies Trade and Environment The Cases of Forest and Fisheries PDF Center for Environmental Law Archived PDF from the original on 2012 09 15 Retrieved 2013 08 05 Report of the Expert Consultation on Identifying Assessing and Reporting on Subsidies in the Fishing Industry Rome 3 6 December 2002 Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization Archived from the original on 16 March 2018 Retrieved 16 March 2018 Manufacturing in Britain A Survey of Factors Affecting Growth and Performance ISR Google Books 2019 pages 37 38 ISBN 9780906321614 Clegg Jonathan 28 April 2015 NFL to End Tax Exempt Status Archived 2017 11 12 at the Wayback Machine The Wall Street Journal Retrieved 17 December 2019 Cohen R 2008 Playing by the NFL s Tax Exempt Rulesh NonProfit Quarterly Archived from the original on 2013 08 20 Retrieved 2013 04 15 Fowler P Fokker R 2004 A Sweeter Future The potential for EU sugar reform to contribute to poverty reduction in Southern Africa Oxford Oxfam International ISBN 9781848141940 Archived from the original on 2014 02 09 Retrieved 2013 09 08 Further reading EditOECD 2001 Environmentally Harmful Subsidies Policy Issues and Challenges France OECD Productions http www inecc gob mx descargas dgipea harmful subsidies pdfExternal links EditAnother Day Another Bad Incentive Deal 2014 06 06 Naked Capitalism Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Subsidy amp oldid 1170994654, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.