fbpx
Wikipedia

Time preference

In economics, time preference (or time discounting,[1] delay discounting, temporal discounting,[2] long-term orientation[3]) is the current relative valuation placed on receiving a good or some cash at an earlier date compared with receiving it at a later date.[1]

Time preferences are captured mathematically in the discount function. The higher the time preference, the higher the discount placed on returns receivable or costs payable in the future.

One of the factors that may determine an individual's time preference is how long that individual has lived. An older individual may have a lower time preference (relative to what they had earlier in life) due to a higher income and to the fact that they have had more time to acquire durable commodities (such as a college education or a house).[4]. As future is inherently uncertain, risk preferences also affect time preferences.[5]

Example edit

A practical example: Jim and Bob go out for a drink but Jim has no money so Bob lends Jim $10. The next day Jim visits Bob and says, "Bob, you can have $10 now, or I will give you $15 when I get paid at the end of the month." Bob's time preference will change depending on his trust in Jim, whether he needs the money now, or if he thinks he can wait; or if he'd prefer to have $15 at the end of the month rather than $10 now. Present and expected needs, present and expected income affect one's time preference.

Neoclassical views edit

In the neoclassical theory of interest due to Irving Fisher, the rate of time preference is usually taken as a parameter in an individual's utility function which captures the trade off between consumption today and consumption in the future, and is thus exogenous and subjective. It is also the underlying determinant of the real rate of interest. The rate of return on investment is generally seen as return on capital, with the real rate of interest equal to the marginal product of capital at any point in time. Arbitrage, in turn, implies that the return on capital is equalized with the interest rate on financial assets (adjusting for factors such as inflation and risk). Consumers, who are facing a choice between consumption and saving, respond to the difference between the market interest rate and their own subjective rate of time preference ("impatience") and increase or decrease their current consumption according to this difference. This changes the amount of funds available for investment and capital accumulation, as in for example the Ramsey growth model.

In the long run steady state, consumption's share in a person's income is constant which pins down the rate of interest as equal to the rate of time preference, with the marginal product of capital adjusting to ensure this equality holds. It is important to note that in this view, it is not that people discount the future because they can receive positive interest rates on their savings. Rather, the causality goes in the opposite direction; interest rates must be positive in order to induce impatient individuals to forgo current consumptions in favor of future.

Austrian economics edit

Time preference is a key component of the Austrian School of economics,[6][7] it is used to understand the relationship between saving, investment and interest rates.[8] According to the Misesian branch of the school: In acting, an actor invariably aims to substitute a more satisfactory for a less satisfactory state of affairs and thus demonstrates a preference for more rather than fewer goods. Moreover, he invariably considers when in the future his goals will be reached, i.e., the time necessary to accomplish them, as well as a good's duration of serviceability. Thus, he also demonstrates a universal preference for earlier over later goods, and for more over less durable ones. This is the phenomenon of time preference. Every actor requires some amount of time to attain his goal, and since man must always consume something and cannot entirely stop consuming while he is alive, time is always scarce. Thus, ceteris paribus, present or earlier goods are, and must invariably be, valued more highly than future or later ones. In fact, if man were not constrained by time preference and if the only constraint operating on him were that of preferring more over less, he would invariably choose those production processes which yielded the largest output per input, regardless of the length of time needed for these methods to bear fruit.[9]

Temporal discounting edit

Temporal discounting (also known as delay discounting, time discounting)[10] is the tendency of people to discount rewards as they approach a temporal horizon in the future or the past (i.e., become so distant in time that they cease to be valuable or to have additive effects). To put it another way, it is a tendency to give greater value to rewards as they move away from their temporal horizons and towards the "now". For instance, a nicotine deprived smoker may highly value a cigarette available any time in the next 6 hours but assign little or no value to a cigarette available in 6 months.[11]

Regarding terminology, from Frederick et al. (2002):

We distinguish time discounting from time preference. We use the term time discounting broadly to encompass any reason for caring less about a future consequence, including factors that diminish the expected utility generated by a future consequence, such as uncertainty or changing tastes. We use the term time preference to refer, more specifically, to the preference for immediate utility over delayed utility.

This term is used in intertemporal economics, intertemporal choice, neurobiology of reward and decision making, microeconomics and recently neuroeconomics.[12] Traditional models of economics assumed that the discounting function is exponential in time leading to a monotonic decrease in preference with increased time delay; however, more recent neuroeconomic models suggest a hyperbolic discount function which can address the phenomenon of preference reversal.[13] Temporal discounting is also a theory particularly relevant to the political decisions of individuals, as people often put their short term political interests before the longer term policies.[14] This can be applied to the way individuals vote in elections but can also apply to how they contribute to societal issues like climate change, that is primarily a long term threat and therefore not prioritised.[15]

Assessing temporal discounting edit

Offered a choice of $100 today and $100 in one month, individuals will most likely choose the $100 now. However, should the question change to having $100 today, or $1,000 in one month, individuals will most likely choose the $1,000 in one month. The $100 can be conceptualized as a Smaller Sooner Reward (SSR), and the $1,000 can be conceptualized as a Larger Later Reward (LLR). Researchers who study temporal discounting are interested in the point in time in which an individual changes their preference for the SSR to the LLR, or vice versa. For example, although an individual may prefer $1,000 in one month over $100 now, they may switch their preference to the $100 if the delay to the $1,000 is increased to 60 months (5 years). This means that this person values $1,000, after a delay of 60 months, less than $100 now. The key is to find the point in time in which the individual values the LLR and the SSR as being equivalent. That is known as the indifference point.[16] Preferences can be measured by asking people to make a series of choices between immediate and delayed payoffs, where the delay period and the payoff amounts are varied.

Origin of differences in time preference across countries edit

Differences of time preferences across countries have been found in several large-scale studies, in particular the INTRA study[17] and the GPS study.[18]

Oded Galor and Omer Ozak explore the roots of observed differences in time preference across nations.[19] They establish that pre-industrial agricultural characteristics that were favorable to higher return to agricultural investment triggered a process of selection, adaptation, and learning that brought about a higher prevalence of long-term orientation. These agricultural characteristics are associated with contemporary economic and human behavior such as technological adoption, education, saving, and smoking.

The most comprehensive data set of time preferences encompasses 117 countries and is calculated by merging several previous datasets, including the aforementioned INTRA- and GPS-data, but also, e.g., survey questions from the World Value Survey.[20]

Historical understanding of time preference theory in relation to interest rates edit

[21]

The Catholic scholastic philosophers firstly brought up sophisticated explanations and justifications of return on capital, including risk and the opportunity cost of profit forgone, associated with the discount factor. However, they failed to interpret the interest on a riskless loan and hence denounced the time preference discounter as sinful and usurious.

Later, Conrad Summenhart, a theologian at the University of Tübingen, used time preference to explain the discount loans, where the lenders won't profit usuriously from the loans as the borrowers would accept the price the lenders ask. A half-century later, Martin de Azpilcueta Navarrus, a Dominican canon lawyer and monetary theorist at the University of Salamanca, held the view that present goods, such as money, will naturally be worth more on the market than future goods (money). At about the same time, Gian Francesco Lottini da Volterra, an Italian humanist and politician, discovered time preference and contemplated time preference as an overestimation of "a present" that can be grasped immediately by the senses. Two centuries later, Ferdinando Galiani, a Neapolitan abbot, used an analogy to point out that just similar to the exchange rate, the interest rate links and equates the present value to the future value, and under people's subjective mind, these two physically non-identical items should be equal.

These scattered thoughts and progression of theories inspired Anne Robert Jacques Turgot, a French statesman, to generate a full-scale time preference theory: what must be compared in a loan transaction is not the value of money lent with the value repaid, but rather the 'value of the promise of a sum of money compared to the value of money available now;[22] in addition, he analyzed the relation between money supply and interest rates: If money supply increases and people with insensitive time preference receive the money, then these people tend to hoard money for savings instead of going for consumptions, which will cause interest rates to fall while prices to rise.

See also edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ a b Frederick, Shane; Loewenstein, George; O'donoghue, Ted (2002). (PDF). Journal of Economic Literature. 40 (2): 351–401. doi:10.1257/jel.40.2.351. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2017-03-11. Retrieved 2014-11-02.
  2. ^ Doyle, John R. (2013). "Survey of time preference, delay discounting models" (PDF). Judgment and Decision Making. 8 (2): 116–135. doi:10.1017/S1930297500005052.
  3. ^ Hofstede, Geert (2001). Culture's consequences: Comparing values, behaviors, institutions and organizations across nations. Sage publications.
  4. ^ Bayer, Y. M.; Osher, Y. (2018). "Time preference, executive functions, and ego-depletion: An exploratory study". Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics. 11 (3): 127–134. doi:10.1037/npe0000092. S2CID 149582921.
  5. ^ Somasundaram, Jeeva; Eli, Vincent (2022). "Risk and time preferences interaction: An experimental measurement". Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 65 (2): 215–234. doi:10.1007/s11166-022-09394-9. S2CID 219346855.
  6. ^ Judy (2018-12-14). "A Brief Defense of Mises's Conception of Time Preference and His Pure Time Preference Theory of Interest". Mises Institute. Retrieved 2023-10-06.
  7. ^ Clay (2017-04-10). "11. Time and Time Preference". Mises Institute. Retrieved 2023-10-06.
  8. ^ "Time preference | economics | Britannica". www.britannica.com. Retrieved 2023-10-06.
  9. ^ Hoppe, Hans-Hermann (2018-02-06). Democracy: The God That Failed. doi:10.4324/9780203793572. ISBN 978-0-203-79357-2.
  10. ^ Doyle, John R. (2013). "Survey of time preference, delay discounting models" (PDF). Judgment and Decision Making. 8 (2): 116–135. doi:10.1017/S1930297500005052. ISSN 1930-2975.
  11. ^ Bickel, W. K.; Odum, A. L.; Madden, G. J. (1999). "Impulsivity and cigarette smoking: delay discounting in current, never, and ex-smokers". Psychopharmacology. 146 (4): 447–454. doi:10.1007/PL00005490. ISSN 0033-3158. PMID 10550495. S2CID 24789357.
  12. ^ Takahashi T.; Hadzibeganovic T.; Cannas S. A.; Makino T.; Fukui H.; Kitayama S. (2009). "Cultural neuroeconomics of intertemporal choice". Neuro Endocrinol. Lett. 30 (2): 185–91. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.232.7650. PMID 19675524.
  13. ^ Green, Leonard; Myerson, Joel (2004). "A Discounting Framework for Choice With Delayed and Probabilistic Rewards". Psychological Bulletin. 130 (5): 769–792. doi:10.1037/0033-2909.130.5.769. ISSN 0033-2909. PMC 1382186. PMID 15367080.
  14. ^ Schafer2016
  15. ^ Baum2010
  16. ^ Odum, Amy L. (2011). "Delay Discounting: I'm a k, You're a k". Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior. 96 (3): 427–439. doi:10.1901/jeab.2011.96-423. ISSN 0022-5002. PMC 3213005. PMID 22084499.
  17. ^ Wang, Mei; Rieger, Marc Oliver; Hens, Thorsten (2016). "How time preference differ: evidence from 53 countries" (PDF). Journal of Economic Psychology. 52: 115–135. doi:10.1016/j.joep.2015.12.001.
  18. ^ Falk, Armin; Becker, Anke; Dohmen, Thomas; et al. (2018). "Global evidence on economic preferences". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 133 (4): 1645–92. doi:10.1093/qje/qjy013.
  19. ^ Galor, Oded; Özak, Ömer (2016). "The Agricultural Origins of Time Preference". American Economic Review. 106 (10): 3064–3103. doi:10.1257/aer.20150020. PMC 5541952. PMID 28781375.
  20. ^ Rieger, Marc; Wang, Mei; Hens, Thorsten (2021). "Universal Time Preference". PLOS ONE. 16 (2): e0245692. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0245692. PMC 7888607. PMID 33596234.
  21. ^ The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd edition, 2008. Edited by Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume
  22. ^ Turgot, A.R.J. 1977. In The Economics of A.R.J. Turgot, ed. P.D. Groenewegen. The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff.

time, preference, this, article, about, time, preference, economics, time, preference, psychology, delayed, gratification, economics, time, preference, time, discounting, delay, discounting, temporal, discounting, long, term, orientation, current, relative, va. This article is about time preference in economics For time preference in psychology see Delayed gratification In economics time preference or time discounting 1 delay discounting temporal discounting 2 long term orientation 3 is the current relative valuation placed on receiving a good or some cash at an earlier date compared with receiving it at a later date 1 Time preferences are captured mathematically in the discount function The higher the time preference the higher the discount placed on returns receivable or costs payable in the future One of the factors that may determine an individual s time preference is how long that individual has lived An older individual may have a lower time preference relative to what they had earlier in life due to a higher income and to the fact that they have had more time to acquire durable commodities such as a college education or a house 4 As future is inherently uncertain risk preferences also affect time preferences 5 Contents 1 Example 2 Neoclassical views 3 Austrian economics 4 Temporal discounting 4 1 Assessing temporal discounting 5 Origin of differences in time preference across countries 6 Historical understanding of time preference theory in relation to interest rates 7 See also 8 NotesExample editA practical example Jim and Bob go out for a drink but Jim has no money so Bob lends Jim 10 The next day Jim visits Bob and says Bob you can have 10 now or I will give you 15 when I get paid at the end of the month Bob s time preference will change depending on his trust in Jim whether he needs the money now or if he thinks he can wait or if he d prefer to have 15 at the end of the month rather than 10 now Present and expected needs present and expected income affect one s time preference Neoclassical views editIn the neoclassical theory of interest due to Irving Fisher the rate of time preference is usually taken as a parameter in an individual s utility function which captures the trade off between consumption today and consumption in the future and is thus exogenous and subjective It is also the underlying determinant of the real rate of interest The rate of return on investment is generally seen as return on capital with the real rate of interest equal to the marginal product of capital at any point in time Arbitrage in turn implies that the return on capital is equalized with the interest rate on financial assets adjusting for factors such as inflation and risk Consumers who are facing a choice between consumption and saving respond to the difference between the market interest rate and their own subjective rate of time preference impatience and increase or decrease their current consumption according to this difference This changes the amount of funds available for investment and capital accumulation as in for example the Ramsey growth model In the long run steady state consumption s share in a person s income is constant which pins down the rate of interest as equal to the rate of time preference with the marginal product of capital adjusting to ensure this equality holds It is important to note that in this view it is not that people discount the future because they can receive positive interest rates on their savings Rather the causality goes in the opposite direction interest rates must be positive in order to induce impatient individuals to forgo current consumptions in favor of future Austrian economics editTime preference is a key component of the Austrian School of economics 6 7 it is used to understand the relationship between saving investment and interest rates 8 According to the Misesian branch of the school In acting an actor invariably aims to substitute a more satisfactory for a less satisfactory state of affairs and thus demonstrates a preference for more rather than fewer goods Moreover he invariably considers when in the future his goals will be reached i e the time necessary to accomplish them as well as a good s duration of serviceability Thus he also demonstrates a universal preference for earlier over later goods and for more over less durable ones This is the phenomenon of time preference Every actor requires some amount of time to attain his goal and since man must always consume something and cannot entirely stop consuming while he is alive time is always scarce Thus ceteris paribus present or earlier goods are and must invariably be valued more highly than future or later ones In fact if man were not constrained by time preference and if the only constraint operating on him were that of preferring more over less he would invariably choose those production processes which yielded the largest output per input regardless of the length of time needed for these methods to bear fruit 9 Temporal discounting editTemporal discounting also known as delay discounting time discounting 10 is the tendency of people to discount rewards as they approach a temporal horizon in the future or the past i e become so distant in time that they cease to be valuable or to have additive effects To put it another way it is a tendency to give greater value to rewards as they move away from their temporal horizons and towards the now For instance a nicotine deprived smoker may highly value a cigarette available any time in the next 6 hours but assign little or no value to a cigarette available in 6 months 11 Regarding terminology from Frederick et al 2002 We distinguish time discounting from time preference We use the term time discounting broadly to encompass any reason for caring less about a future consequence including factors that diminish the expected utility generated by a future consequence such as uncertainty or changing tastes We use the term time preference to refer more specifically to the preference for immediate utility over delayed utility This term is used in intertemporal economics intertemporal choice neurobiology of reward and decision making microeconomics and recently neuroeconomics 12 Traditional models of economics assumed that the discounting function is exponential in time leading to a monotonic decrease in preference with increased time delay however more recent neuroeconomic models suggest a hyperbolic discount function which can address the phenomenon of preference reversal 13 Temporal discounting is also a theory particularly relevant to the political decisions of individuals as people often put their short term political interests before the longer term policies 14 This can be applied to the way individuals vote in elections but can also apply to how they contribute to societal issues like climate change that is primarily a long term threat and therefore not prioritised 15 Assessing temporal discounting edit Offered a choice of 100 today and 100 in one month individuals will most likely choose the 100 now However should the question change to having 100 today or 1 000 in one month individuals will most likely choose the 1 000 in one month The 100 can be conceptualized as a Smaller Sooner Reward SSR and the 1 000 can be conceptualized as a Larger Later Reward LLR Researchers who study temporal discounting are interested in the point in time in which an individual changes their preference for the SSR to the LLR or vice versa For example although an individual may prefer 1 000 in one month over 100 now they may switch their preference to the 100 if the delay to the 1 000 is increased to 60 months 5 years This means that this person values 1 000 after a delay of 60 months less than 100 now The key is to find the point in time in which the individual values the LLR and the SSR as being equivalent That is known as the indifference point 16 Preferences can be measured by asking people to make a series of choices between immediate and delayed payoffs where the delay period and the payoff amounts are varied Origin of differences in time preference across countries editDifferences of time preferences across countries have been found in several large scale studies in particular the INTRA study 17 and the GPS study 18 Oded Galor and Omer Ozak explore the roots of observed differences in time preference across nations 19 They establish that pre industrial agricultural characteristics that were favorable to higher return to agricultural investment triggered a process of selection adaptation and learning that brought about a higher prevalence of long term orientation These agricultural characteristics are associated with contemporary economic and human behavior such as technological adoption education saving and smoking The most comprehensive data set of time preferences encompasses 117 countries and is calculated by merging several previous datasets including the aforementioned INTRA and GPS data but also e g survey questions from the World Value Survey 20 Historical understanding of time preference theory in relation to interest rates edit 21 The Catholic scholastic philosophers firstly brought up sophisticated explanations and justifications of return on capital including risk and the opportunity cost of profit forgone associated with the discount factor However they failed to interpret the interest on a riskless loan and hence denounced the time preference discounter as sinful and usurious Later Conrad Summenhart a theologian at the University of Tubingen used time preference to explain the discount loans where the lenders won t profit usuriously from the loans as the borrowers would accept the price the lenders ask A half century later Martin de Azpilcueta Navarrus a Dominican canon lawyer and monetary theorist at the University of Salamanca held the view that present goods such as money will naturally be worth more on the market than future goods money At about the same time Gian Francesco Lottini da Volterra an Italian humanist and politician discovered time preference and contemplated time preference as an overestimation of a present that can be grasped immediately by the senses Two centuries later Ferdinando Galiani a Neapolitan abbot used an analogy to point out that just similar to the exchange rate the interest rate links and equates the present value to the future value and under people s subjective mind these two physically non identical items should be equal These scattered thoughts and progression of theories inspired Anne Robert Jacques Turgot a French statesman to generate a full scale time preference theory what must be compared in a loan transaction is not the value of money lent with the value repaid but rather the value of the promise of a sum of money compared to the value of money available now 22 in addition he analyzed the relation between money supply and interest rates If money supply increases and people with insensitive time preference receive the money then these people tend to hoard money for savings instead of going for consumptions which will cause interest rates to fall while prices to rise See also editDecision theory Delayed gratification Discount function Discounted utility Discounting Dynamic inconsistency Hofstede s cultural dimensions theory A theory of cultural differences in time preference Hyperbolic discounting A model of typical time preferences Intertemporal choice Net present value Time value of money Treasury test discount rate PatienceNotes edit a b Frederick Shane Loewenstein George O donoghue Ted 2002 Time Discounting and Time Preference A Critical Review PDF Journal of Economic Literature 40 2 351 401 doi 10 1257 jel 40 2 351 Archived from the original PDF on 2017 03 11 Retrieved 2014 11 02 Doyle John R 2013 Survey of time preference delay discounting models PDF Judgment and Decision Making 8 2 116 135 doi 10 1017 S1930297500005052 Hofstede Geert 2001 Culture s consequences Comparing values behaviors institutions and organizations across nations Sage publications Bayer Y M Osher Y 2018 Time preference executive functions and ego depletion An exploratory study Journal of Neuroscience Psychology and Economics 11 3 127 134 doi 10 1037 npe0000092 S2CID 149582921 Somasundaram Jeeva Eli Vincent 2022 Risk and time preferences interaction An experimental measurement Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 65 2 215 234 doi 10 1007 s11166 022 09394 9 S2CID 219346855 Judy 2018 12 14 A Brief Defense of Mises s Conception of Time Preference and His Pure Time Preference Theory of Interest Mises Institute Retrieved 2023 10 06 Clay 2017 04 10 11 Time and Time Preference Mises Institute Retrieved 2023 10 06 Time preference economics Britannica www britannica com Retrieved 2023 10 06 Hoppe Hans Hermann 2018 02 06 Democracy The God That Failed doi 10 4324 9780203793572 ISBN 978 0 203 79357 2 Doyle John R 2013 Survey of time preference delay discounting models PDF Judgment and Decision Making 8 2 116 135 doi 10 1017 S1930297500005052 ISSN 1930 2975 Bickel W K Odum A L Madden G J 1999 Impulsivity and cigarette smoking delay discounting in current never and ex smokers Psychopharmacology 146 4 447 454 doi 10 1007 PL00005490 ISSN 0033 3158 PMID 10550495 S2CID 24789357 Takahashi T Hadzibeganovic T Cannas S A Makino T Fukui H Kitayama S 2009 Cultural neuroeconomics of intertemporal choice Neuro Endocrinol Lett 30 2 185 91 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 232 7650 PMID 19675524 Green Leonard Myerson Joel 2004 A Discounting Framework for Choice With Delayed and Probabilistic Rewards Psychological Bulletin 130 5 769 792 doi 10 1037 0033 2909 130 5 769 ISSN 0033 2909 PMC 1382186 PMID 15367080 Schafer2016 Baum2010 Odum Amy L 2011 Delay Discounting I m a k You re a k Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 96 3 427 439 doi 10 1901 jeab 2011 96 423 ISSN 0022 5002 PMC 3213005 PMID 22084499 Wang Mei Rieger Marc Oliver Hens Thorsten 2016 How time preference differ evidence from 53 countries PDF Journal of Economic Psychology 52 115 135 doi 10 1016 j joep 2015 12 001 Falk Armin Becker Anke Dohmen Thomas et al 2018 Global evidence on economic preferences The Quarterly Journal of Economics 133 4 1645 92 doi 10 1093 qje qjy013 Galor Oded Ozak Omer 2016 The Agricultural Origins of Time Preference American Economic Review 106 10 3064 3103 doi 10 1257 aer 20150020 PMC 5541952 PMID 28781375 Rieger Marc Wang Mei Hens Thorsten 2021 Universal Time Preference PLOS ONE 16 2 e0245692 doi 10 1371 journal pone 0245692 PMC 7888607 PMID 33596234 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd edition 2008 Edited by Steven N Durlauf and Lawrence E Blume Turgot A R J 1977 In The Economics of A R J Turgot ed P D Groenewegen The Hague Martinus Nijhoff Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Time preference amp oldid 1187307449, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.