fbpx
Wikipedia

Modern portfolio theory

Modern portfolio theory (MPT), or mean-variance analysis, is a mathematical framework for assembling a portfolio of assets such that the expected return is maximized for a given level of risk. It is a formalization and extension of diversification in investing, the idea that owning different kinds of financial assets is less risky than owning only one type. Its key insight is that an asset's risk and return should not be assessed by itself, but by how it contributes to a portfolio's overall risk and return. The variance of return (or its transformation, the standard deviation) is used as a measure of risk, because it is tractable when assets are combined into portfolios.[1] Often, the historical variance and covariance of returns is used as a proxy for the forward-looking versions of these quantities,[2] but other, more sophisticated methods are available.[3]

Economist Harry Markowitz introduced MPT in a 1952 essay,[1] for which he was later awarded a Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences; see Markowitz model.

In 1940, Bruno de Finetti published[4] the mean-variance analysis method, in the context of proportional reinsurance, under a stronger assumption. The paper was obscure and only became known to economists of the English-speaking world in 2006.[5]

Mathematical model edit

Risk and expected return edit

MPT assumes that investors are risk averse, meaning that given two portfolios that offer the same expected return, investors will prefer the less risky one. Thus, an investor will take on increased risk only if compensated by higher expected returns. Conversely, an investor who wants higher expected returns must accept more risk. The exact trade-off will not be the same for all investors. Different investors will evaluate the trade-off differently based on individual risk aversion characteristics. The implication is that a rational investor will not invest in a portfolio if a second portfolio exists with a more favorable risk vs expected return profile — i.e., if for that level of risk an alternative portfolio exists that has better expected returns.

Under the model:

  • Portfolio return is the proportion-weighted combination of the constituent assets' returns.
  • Portfolio return volatility   is a function of the correlations ρij of the component assets, for all asset pairs (i, j). The volatility gives insight into the risk which is associated with the investment. The higher the volatility, the higher the risk.

In general:

  • Expected return:
 
where   is the return on the portfolio,   is the return on asset i and   is the weighting of component asset   (that is, the proportion of asset "i" in the portfolio, so that  ).
  • Portfolio return variance:
 ,
where   is the (sample) standard deviation of the periodic returns on an asset i, and   is the correlation coefficient between the returns on assets i and j. Alternatively the expression can be written as:
 ,
where   for   , or
 ,
where   is the (sample) covariance of the periodic returns on the two assets, or alternatively denoted as  ,   or  .
  • Portfolio return volatility (standard deviation):
 

For a two-asset portfolio:

  • Portfolio expected return:  
  • Portfolio variance:  

For a three-asset portfolio:

  • Portfolio expected return:  
  • Portfolio variance:  

The algebra can be much simplified by expressing the quantities involved in matrix notation.[6] Arrange the returns of N risky assets in an   vector  , where the first element is the return of the first asset, the second element of the second asset, and so on. Arrange their expected returns in a column vector  , and their variances and covariances in a covariance matrix  . Consider a portfolio of risky assets whose weights in each of the N risky assets is given by the corresponding element of the weight vector  . Then:

  • Portfolio expected return:  

and

  • Portfolio variance:  

For the case where there is investment in a riskfree asset with return  , the weights of the weight vector do not sum to 1, and the portfolio expected return becomes  . The expression for the portfolio variance is unchanged.

Diversification edit

An investor can reduce portfolio risk (especially  ) simply by holding combinations of instruments that are not perfectly positively correlated (correlation coefficient  ). In other words, investors can reduce their exposure to individual asset risk by holding a diversified portfolio of assets. Diversification may allow for the same portfolio expected return with reduced risk. The mean-variance framework for constructing optimal investment portfolios was first posited by Markowitz and has since been reinforced and improved by other economists and mathematicians who went on to account for the limitations of the framework.

If all the asset pairs have correlations of 0—they are perfectly uncorrelated—the portfolio's return variance is the sum over all assets of the square of the fraction held in the asset times the asset's return variance (and the portfolio standard deviation is the square root of this sum).

If all the asset pairs have correlations of 1—they are perfectly positively correlated—then the portfolio return's standard deviation is the sum of the asset returns' standard deviations weighted by the fractions held in the portfolio. For given portfolio weights and given standard deviations of asset returns, the case of all correlations being 1 gives the highest possible standard deviation of portfolio return.

Efficient frontier with no risk-free asset edit

 
Efficient Frontier. The hyperbola is sometimes referred to as the 'Markowitz Bullet', and is the efficient frontier if no risk-free asset is available. With a risk-free asset, the straight line is the efficient frontier.

The MPT is a mean-variance theory, and it compares the expected (mean) return of a portfolio with the standard deviation of the same portfolio. The image shows expected return on the vertical axis, and the standard deviation on the horizontal axis (volatility). Volatility is described by standard deviation and it serves as a measure of risk.[7] The return - standard deviation space is sometimes called the space of 'expected return vs risk'. Every possible combination of risky assets, can be plotted in this risk-expected return space, and the collection of all such possible portfolios defines a region in this space. The left boundary of this region is hyperbolic,[8] and the upper part of the hyperbolic boundary is the efficient frontier in the absence of a risk-free asset (sometimes called "the Markowitz bullet"). Combinations along this upper edge represent portfolios (including no holdings of the risk-free asset) for which there is lowest risk for a given level of expected return. Equivalently, a portfolio lying on the efficient frontier represents the combination offering the best possible expected return for given risk level. The tangent to the upper part of the hyperbolic boundary is the capital allocation line (CAL).

Matrices are preferred for calculations of the efficient frontier.

In matrix form, for a given "risk tolerance"  , the efficient frontier is found by minimizing the following expression:

 

where

  •   is a vector of portfolio weights and   (The weights can be negative);
  •   is the covariance matrix for the returns on the assets in the portfolio;
  •   is a "risk tolerance" factor, where 0 results in the portfolio with minimal risk and   results in the portfolio infinitely far out on the frontier with both expected return and risk unbounded; and
  •   is a vector of expected returns.
  •   is the variance of portfolio return.
  •   is the expected return on the portfolio.

The above optimization finds the point on the frontier at which the inverse of the slope of the frontier would be q if portfolio return variance instead of standard deviation were plotted horizontally. The frontier in its entirety is parametric on q.

Harry Markowitz developed a specific procedure for solving the above problem, called the critical line algorithm,[9] that can handle additional linear constraints, upper and lower bounds on assets, and which is proved to work with a semi-positive definite covariance matrix. Examples of implementation of the critical line algorithm exist in Visual Basic for Applications,[10] in JavaScript[11] and in a few other languages.

Also, many software packages, including MATLAB, Microsoft Excel, Mathematica and R, provide generic optimization routines so that using these for solving the above problem is possible, with potential caveats (poor numerical accuracy, requirement of positive definiteness of the covariance matrix...).

An alternative approach to specifying the efficient frontier is to do so parametrically on the expected portfolio return   This version of the problem requires that we minimize

 

subject to

 

for parameter  . This problem is easily solved using a Lagrange multiplier which leads to the following linear system of equations:

 

Two mutual fund theorem edit

One key result of the above analysis is the two mutual fund theorem.[12][13] This theorem states that any portfolio on the efficient frontier can be generated by holding a combination of any two given portfolios on the frontier; the latter two given portfolios are the "mutual funds" in the theorem's name. So in the absence of a risk-free asset, an investor can achieve any desired efficient portfolio even if all that is accessible is a pair of efficient mutual funds. If the location of the desired portfolio on the frontier is between the locations of the two mutual funds, both mutual funds will be held in positive quantities. If the desired portfolio is outside the range spanned by the two mutual funds, then one of the mutual funds must be sold short (held in negative quantity) while the size of the investment in the other mutual fund must be greater than the amount available for investment (the excess being funded by the borrowing from the other fund).

Risk-free asset and the capital allocation line edit

The risk-free asset is the (hypothetical) asset that pays a risk-free rate. In practice, short-term government securities (such as US treasury bills) are used as a risk-free asset, because they pay a fixed rate of interest and have exceptionally low default risk. The risk-free asset has zero variance in returns (hence is risk-free); it is also uncorrelated with any other asset (by definition, since its variance is zero). As a result, when it is combined with any other asset or portfolio of assets, the change in return is linearly related to the change in risk as the proportions in the combination vary.

When a risk-free asset is introduced, the half-line shown in the figure is the new efficient frontier. It is tangent to the hyperbola at the pure risky portfolio with the highest Sharpe ratio. Its vertical intercept represents a portfolio with 100% of holdings in the risk-free asset; the tangency with the hyperbola represents a portfolio with no risk-free holdings and 100% of assets held in the portfolio occurring at the tangency point; points between those points are portfolios containing positive amounts of both the risky tangency portfolio and the risk-free asset; and points on the half-line beyond the tangency point are portfolios involving negative holdings of the risk-free asset and an amount invested in the tangency portfolio equal to more than 100% of the investor's initial capital. This efficient half-line is called the capital allocation line (CAL), and its formula can be shown to be

 

In this formula P is the sub-portfolio of risky assets at the tangency with the Markowitz bullet, F is the risk-free asset, and C is a combination of portfolios P and F.

By the diagram, the introduction of the risk-free asset as a possible component of the portfolio has improved the range of risk-expected return combinations available, because everywhere except at the tangency portfolio the half-line gives a higher expected return than the hyperbola does at every possible risk level. The fact that all points on the linear efficient locus can be achieved by a combination of holdings of the risk-free asset and the tangency portfolio is known as the one mutual fund theorem,[12] where the mutual fund referred to is the tangency portfolio.

Geometric intuition edit

The efficient frontier can be pictured as a problem in quadratic curves.[12] On the market, we have the assets  . We have some funds, and a portfolio is a way to divide our funds into the assets. Each portfolio can be represented as a vector  , such that  , and we hold the assets according to  .

Markowitz bullet edit

 
The ellipsoid is the contour of constant variance. The   plane is the space of possible portfolios. The other plane is the contour of constant expected return. The ellipsoid intersects the plane to give an ellipse of portfolios of constant variance. On this ellipse, the point of maximal (or minimal) expected return is the point where it is tangent to the contour of constant expected return. All these portfolios fall on one line.

Since we wish to maximize expected return while minimizing the standard deviation of the return, we are to solve a quadratic optimization problem:

 
Portfolios are points in the Euclidean space  . The third equation states that the portfolio should fall on a plane defined by  . The first equation states that the portfolio should fall on a plane defined by  . The second condition states that the portfolio should fall on the contour surface for   that is as close to the origin as possible. Since the equation is quadratic, each such contour surface is an ellipsoid (assuming that the covariance matrix   is invertible). Therefore, we can solve the quadratic optimization graphically by drawing ellipsoidal contours on the plane  , then intersect the contours with the plane  . As the ellipsoidal contours shrink, eventually one of them would become exactly tangent to the plane, before the contours become completely disjoint from the plane. The tangent point is the optimal portfolio at this level of expected return.

As we vary  , the tangent point varies as well, but always falling on a single line (this is the two mutual funds theorem).

Let the line be parameterized as  . We find that along the line,

 
giving a hyperbola in the   plane. The hyperbola has two branches, symmetric with respect to the   axis. However, only the branch with   is meaningful. By symmetry, the two asymptotes of the hyperbola intersect at a point   on the   axis. The point   is the height of the leftmost point of the hyperbola, and can be interpreted as the expected return of the global minimum-variance portfolio (global MVP).

Tangency portfolio edit

 
Illustration of the effect of changing the risk-free asset return rate. As the risk-free return rate approaches the return rate of the global minimum-variance portfolio, the tangency portfolio escapes to infinity. Animated at source [2].

The tangency portfolio exists if and only if  .

In particular, if the risk-free return is greater or equal to  , then the tangent portfolio does not exist. The capital market line (CML) becomes parallel to the upper asymptote line of the hyperbola. Points on the CML become impossible to achieve, though they can be approached from below.

It is usually assumed that the risk-free return is less than the return of the global MVP, in order that the tangency portfolio exists. However, even in this case, as   approaches   from below, the tangency portfolio diverges to a portfolio with infinite return and variance. Since there are only finitely many assets in the market, such a portfolio must be shorting some assets heavily while longing some other assets heavily. In practice, such a tangency portfolio would be impossible to achieve, because one cannot short an asset too much due to short sale constraints, and also because of price impact, that is, longing a large amount of an asset would push up its price, breaking the assumption that the asset prices do not depend on the portfolio.

Non-invertible covariance matrix edit

If the covariance matrix is not invertible, then there exists some nonzero vector  , such that   is a random variable with zero variance—that is, it is not random at all.

Suppose   and  , then that means one of the assets can be exactly replicated using the other assets at the same price and the same return. Therefore, there is never a reason to buy that asset, and we can remove it from the market.

Suppose   and  , then that means there is free money, breaking the no arbitrage assumption.

Suppose  , then we can scale the vector to  . This means that we have constructed a risk-free asset with return  . We can remove each such asset from the market, constructing one risk-free asset for each such asset removed. By the no arbitrage assumption, all their return rates are equal. For the assets that still remain in the market, their covariance matrix is invertible.

Asset pricing edit

The above analysis describes optimal behavior of an individual investor. Asset pricing theory builds on this analysis, allowing MPT to derive the required expected return for a correctly priced asset in this context.

Intuitively (in a perfect market with rational investors), if a security was expensive relative to others - i.e. too much risk for the price - demand would fall and its price would drop correspondingly; if cheap, demand and price would increase likewise. This would continue until all such adjustments had ceased - a state of "market equilibrium". In this equilibrium, relative supplies will equal relative demands: given the relationship of price with supply and demand, since risk-to-reward is "identical" across all securities, proportions of each security in any fully-diversified portfolio would correspondingly be the same.

More formally, then, since everyone holds the risky assets in identical proportions to each other — namely in the proportions given by the tangency portfolio — in market equilibrium the risky assets' prices, and therefore their expected returns, will adjust so that the ratios in the tangency portfolio are the same as the ratios in which the risky assets are supplied to the market.[14] The result for expected return then follows, as below.

Systematic risk and specific risk edit

Specific risk is the risk associated with individual assets - within a portfolio these risks can be reduced through diversification (specific risks "cancel out"). Specific risk is also called diversifiable, unique, unsystematic, or idiosyncratic risk. Systematic risk (a.k.a. portfolio risk or market risk) refers to the risk common to all securities—except for selling short as noted below, systematic risk cannot be diversified away (within one market). Within the market portfolio, asset specific risk will be diversified away to the extent possible. Systematic risk is therefore equated with the risk (standard deviation) of the market portfolio.

Since a security will be purchased only if it improves the risk-expected return characteristics of the market portfolio, the relevant measure of the risk of a security is the risk it adds to the market portfolio, and not its risk in isolation. In this context, the volatility of the asset, and its correlation with the market portfolio, are historically observed and are therefore given. (There are several approaches to asset pricing that attempt to price assets by modelling the stochastic properties of the moments of assets' returns - these are broadly referred to as conditional asset pricing models.)

Systematic risks within one market can be managed through a strategy of using both long and short positions within one portfolio, creating a "market neutral" portfolio. Market neutral portfolios, therefore, will be uncorrelated with broader market indices.

Capital asset pricing model edit

The asset return depends on the amount paid for the asset today. The price paid must ensure that the market portfolio's risk / return characteristics improve when the asset is added to it. The CAPM is a model that derives the theoretical required expected return (i.e., discount rate) for an asset in a market, given the risk-free rate available to investors and the risk of the market as a whole. The CAPM is usually expressed:

 
  • β, Beta, is the measure of asset sensitivity to a movement in the overall market; Beta is usually found via regression on historical data. Betas exceeding one signify more than average "riskiness" in the sense of the asset's contribution to overall portfolio risk; betas below one indicate a lower than average risk contribution.
  •   is the market premium, the expected excess return of the market portfolio's expected return over the risk-free rate.

A derivation [14] is as follows:

(1) The incremental impact on risk and expected return when an additional risky asset, a, is added to the market portfolio, m, follows from the formulae for a two-asset portfolio. These results are used to derive the asset-appropriate discount rate.

  • Updated portfolio risk =  
Hence, risk added to portfolio =  
but since the weight of the asset will be very low re. the overall market,  
i.e. additional risk =  
  • Updated expected return =  
Hence additional expected return =  

(2) If an asset, a, is correctly priced, the improvement for an investor in her risk-to-expected return ratio achieved by adding it to the market portfolio, m, will at least (in equilibrium, exactly) match the gains of spending that money on an increased stake in the market portfolio. The assumption is that the investor will purchase the asset with funds borrowed at the risk-free rate,  ; this is rational if  .

Thus:  
i.e.:  
i.e.:   (since  )
  is the "beta",   return mentioned — the covariance between the asset's return and the market's return divided by the variance of the market return — i.e. the sensitivity of the asset price to movement in the market portfolio's value (see also Beta (finance) § Adding an asset to the market portfolio).

This equation can be estimated statistically using the following regression equation:

 

where αi is called the asset's alpha, βi is the asset's beta coefficient and SCL is the security characteristic line.

Once an asset's expected return,  , is calculated using CAPM, the future cash flows of the asset can be discounted to their present value using this rate to establish the correct price for the asset. A riskier stock will have a higher beta and will be discounted at a higher rate; less sensitive stocks will have lower betas and be discounted at a lower rate. In theory, an asset is correctly priced when its observed price is the same as its value calculated using the CAPM derived discount rate. If the observed price is higher than the valuation, then the asset is overvalued; it is undervalued for a too low price.

Criticisms edit

Despite its theoretical importance, critics of MPT question whether it is an ideal investment tool, because its model of financial markets does not match the real world in many ways.[15][2]

The risk, return, and correlation measures used by MPT are based on expected values, which means that they are statistical statements about the future (the expected value of returns is explicit in the above equations, and implicit in the definitions of variance and covariance). Such measures often cannot capture the true statistical features of the risk and return which often follow highly skewed distributions (e.g. the log-normal distribution) and can give rise to, besides reduced volatility, also inflated growth of return.[16] In practice, investors must substitute predictions based on historical measurements of asset return and volatility for these values in the equations. Very often such expected values fail to take account of new circumstances that did not exist when the historical data were generated.[17] An optimal approach to capturing trends, which differs from Markowitz optimization by utilizing invariance properties, is also derived from physics. Instead of transforming the normalized expectations using the inverse of the correlation matrix, the invariant portfolio employs the inverse of the square root of the correlation matrix.[18] The optimization problem is solved under the assumption that expected values are uncertain and correlated.[19] The Markowitz solution corresponds only to the case where the correlation between expected returns is similar to the correlation between returns.

More fundamentally, investors are stuck with estimating key parameters from past market data because MPT attempts to model risk in terms of the likelihood of losses, but says nothing about why those losses might occur. The risk measurements used are probabilistic in nature, not structural. This is a major difference as compared to many engineering approaches to risk management.

Options theory and MPT have at least one important conceptual difference from the probabilistic risk assessment done by nuclear power [plants]. A PRA is what economists would call a structural model. The components of a system and their relationships are modeled in Monte Carlo simulations. If valve X fails, it causes a loss of back pressure on pump Y, causing a drop in flow to vessel Z, and so on.

But in the Black–Scholes equation and MPT, there is no attempt to explain an underlying structure to price changes. Various outcomes are simply given probabilities. And, unlike the PRA, if there is no history of a particular system-level event like a liquidity crisis, there is no way to compute the odds of it. If nuclear engineers ran risk management this way, they would never be able to compute the odds of a meltdown at a particular plant until several similar events occurred in the same reactor design.

— Douglas W. Hubbard, The Failure of Risk Management, p. 67, John Wiley & Sons, 2009. ISBN 978-0-470-38795-5

Mathematical risk measurements are also useful only to the degree that they reflect investors' true concerns—there is no point minimizing a variable that nobody cares about in practice. In particular, variance is a symmetric measure that counts abnormally high returns as just as risky as abnormally low returns. The psychological phenomenon of loss aversion is the idea that investors are more concerned about losses than gains, meaning that our intuitive concept of risk is fundamentally asymmetric in nature. There many other risk measures (like coherent risk measures) might better reflect investors' true preferences.

Modern portfolio theory has also been criticized because it assumes that returns follow a Gaussian distribution. Already in the 1960s, Benoit Mandelbrot and Eugene Fama showed the inadequacy of this assumption and proposed the use of more general stable distributions instead. Stefan Mittnik and Svetlozar Rachev presented strategies for deriving optimal portfolios in such settings.[20][21][22] More recently, Nassim Nicholas Taleb has also criticized modern portfolio theory on this ground, writing:

After the stock market crash (in 1987), they rewarded two theoreticians, Harry Markowitz and William Sharpe, who built beautifully Platonic models on a Gaussian base, contributing to what is called Modern Portfolio Theory. Simply, if you remove their Gaussian assumptions and treat prices as scalable, you are left with hot air. The Nobel Committee could have tested the Sharpe and Markowitz models—they work like quack remedies sold on the Internet—but nobody in Stockholm seems to have thought about it.

— Nassim N. Taleb, The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable, p. 277, Random House, 2007. ISBN 978-1-4000-6351-2

Contrarian investors and value investors typically do not subscribe to Modern Portfolio Theory.[23] One objection is that the MPT relies on the efficient-market hypothesis and uses fluctuations in share price as a substitute for risk. Sir John Templeton believed in diversification as a concept, but also felt the theoretical foundations of MPT were questionable, and concluded (as described by a biographer): "the notion that building portfolios on the basis of unreliable and irrelevant statistical inputs, such as historical volatility, was doomed to failure."[24]

A few studies have argued that "naive diversification", splitting capital equally among available investment options, might have advantages over MPT in some situations.[25]

When applied to certain universes of assets, the Markowitz model has been identified by academics to be inadequate due to its susceptibility to model instability which may arise, for example, among a universe of highly correlated assets.[26]

Extensions edit

Since MPT's introduction in 1952, many attempts have been made to improve the model, especially by using more realistic assumptions.

Post-modern portfolio theory extends MPT by adopting non-normally distributed, asymmetric, and fat-tailed measures of risk.[27] This helps with some of these problems, but not others.

Black–Litterman model optimization is an extension of unconstrained Markowitz optimization that incorporates relative and absolute 'views' on inputs of risk and returns from.

The model is also extended by assuming that expected returns are uncertain, and the correlation matrix in this case can differ from the correlation matrix between returns.[18][19]

Connection with rational choice theory edit

Modern portfolio theory is inconsistent with main axioms of rational choice theory, most notably with monotonicity axiom, stating that, if investing into portfolio X will, with probability one, return more money than investing into portfolio Y, then a rational investor should prefer X to Y. In contrast, modern portfolio theory is based on a different axiom, called variance aversion,[28] and may recommend to invest into Y on the basis that it has lower variance. Maccheroni et al.[29] described choice theory which is the closest possible to the modern portfolio theory, while satisfying monotonicity axiom. Alternatively, mean-deviation analysis[30] is a rational choice theory resulting from replacing variance by an appropriate deviation risk measure.

Other applications edit

In the 1970s, concepts from MPT found their way into the field of regional science. In a series of seminal works, Michael Conroy[citation needed] modeled the labor force in the economy using portfolio-theoretic methods to examine growth and variability in the labor force. This was followed by a long literature on the relationship between economic growth and volatility.[31]

More recently, modern portfolio theory has been used to model the self-concept in social psychology. When the self attributes comprising the self-concept constitute a well-diversified portfolio, then psychological outcomes at the level of the individual such as mood and self-esteem should be more stable than when the self-concept is undiversified. This prediction has been confirmed in studies involving human subjects.[32]

Recently, modern portfolio theory has been applied to modelling the uncertainty and correlation between documents in information retrieval. Given a query, the aim is to maximize the overall relevance of a ranked list of documents and at the same time minimize the overall uncertainty of the ranked list.[33]

Project portfolios and other "non-financial" assets edit

Some experts apply MPT to portfolios of projects and other assets besides financial instruments.[34][35] When MPT is applied outside of traditional financial portfolios, some distinctions between the different types of portfolios must be considered.

  1. The assets in financial portfolios are, for practical purposes, continuously divisible while portfolios of projects are "lumpy". For example, while we can compute that the optimal portfolio position for 3 stocks is, say, 44%, 35%, 21%, the optimal position for a project portfolio may not allow us to simply change the amount spent on a project. Projects might be all or nothing or, at least, have logical units that cannot be separated. A portfolio optimization method would have to take the discrete nature of projects into account.
  2. The assets of financial portfolios are liquid; they can be assessed or re-assessed at any point in time. But opportunities for launching new projects may be limited and may occur in limited windows of time. Projects that have already been initiated cannot be abandoned without the loss of the sunk costs (i.e., there is little or no recovery/salvage value of a half-complete project).

Neither of these necessarily eliminate the possibility of using MPT and such portfolios. They simply indicate the need to run the optimization with an additional set of mathematically expressed constraints that would not normally apply to financial portfolios.

Furthermore, some of the simplest elements of Modern Portfolio Theory are applicable to virtually any kind of portfolio. The concept of capturing the risk tolerance of an investor by documenting how much risk is acceptable for a given return may be applied to a variety of decision analysis problems. MPT uses historical variance as a measure of risk, but portfolios of assets like major projects do not have a well-defined "historical variance". In this case, the MPT investment boundary can be expressed in more general terms like "chance of an ROI less than cost of capital" or "chance of losing more than half of the investment". When risk is put in terms of uncertainty about forecasts and possible losses then the concept is transferable to various types of investment.[34]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ a b Markowitz, H.M. (March 1952). "Portfolio Selection". The Journal of Finance. 7 (1): 77–91. doi:10.2307/2975974. JSTOR 2975974.
  2. ^ a b Wigglesworth, Robin (11 April 2018). "How a volatility virus infected Wall Street". The Financial Times.
  3. ^ Luc Bauwens, Sébastien Laurent, Jeroen V. K. Rombouts (February 2006). "Multivariate GARCH models: a survey". Journal of Applied Econometrics. 21 (1).{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  4. ^ de Finetti, B. (1940): Il problema dei “Pieni”. Giornale dell’ Istituto Italiano degli Attuari 11, 1–88; translation (Barone, L. (2006)): The problem of full-risk insurances. Chapter I. The risk within a single accounting period. Journal of Investment Management 4(3), 19–43
  5. ^ Pressacco, Flavio; Serafini, Paolo (May 2007). "The origins of the mean-variance approach in finance: revisiting de Finetti 65 years later". Decisions in Economics and Finance. 30 (1): 19–49. doi:10.1007/s10203-007-0067-7. ISSN 1593-8883.
  6. ^ David Lando and Rolf Poulsen's lecture notes, Chapter 9, "Portfolio theory" [1]
  7. ^ Portfolio Selection, Harry Markowitz - The Journal of Finance, Vol. 7, No. 1. (Mar., 1952), pp. 77-91
  8. ^ see bottom of slide 6 here
  9. ^ Markowitz, H.M. (March 1956). "The Optimization of a Quadratic Function Subject to Linear Constraints". Naval Research Logistics Quarterly. 3 (1–2): 111–133. doi:10.1002/nav.3800030110.
  10. ^ Markowitz, Harry (February 2000). Mean-Variance Analysis in Portfolio Choice and Capital Markets. Wiley. ISBN 978-1-883-24975-5.
  11. ^ "PortfolioAllocation JavaScript library". github.com/lequant40. Retrieved 2018-06-13.
  12. ^ a b c Merton, Robert C. (September 1972). (PDF). The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis. 7 (4): 1851. doi:10.2307/2329621. hdl:1721.1/46832. ISSN 0022-1090. Archived from the original on 21 Mar 2022.
  13. ^ Karatzas, Ioannis; Lehoczky, John P.; Sethi, Suresh P.; Shreve, Steven E. (1986). "Explicit Solution of a General Consumption/Investment Problem". Mathematics of Operations Research. 11 (2): 261–294. doi:10.1287/moor.11.2.261. JSTOR 3689808. S2CID 22489650. SSRN 1086184.
  14. ^ a b See, e.g., Tim Bollerslev (2019). "Risk and Return in Equilibrium: The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)"
  15. ^ Mahdavi Damghani B. (2013). "The Non-Misleading Value of Inferred Correlation: An Introduction to the Cointelation Model". Wilmott Magazine. 2013 (67): 50–61. doi:10.1002/wilm.10252.
  16. ^ Hui, C.; Fox, G.A.; Gurevitch, J. (2017). "Scale-dependent portfolio effects explain growth inflation and volatility reduction in landscape demography". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA. 114 (47): 12507–12511. Bibcode:2017PNAS..11412507H. doi:10.1073/pnas.1704213114. PMC 5703273. PMID 29109261.
  17. ^ Low, R.K.Y.; Faff, R.; Aas, K. (2016). "Enhancing mean–variance portfolio selection by modeling distributional asymmetries" (PDF). Journal of Economics and Business. 85: 49–72. doi:10.1016/j.jeconbus.2016.01.003.
  18. ^ a b Benichou, R.; Lemperiere, Y.; Serie, E.; Kockelkoren, J.; Seager, P.; Bouchaud, J.-P.; Potters, M. (2017). "Agnostic Risk Parity: Taming Known and Unknown-Unknowns". Journal of Investment Strategies. 6.
  19. ^ a b Valeyre, S. (2024). "Optimal trend-following portfolios". Journal of Investment Strategies. 12.
  20. ^ Rachev, Svetlozar T. and Stefan Mittnik (2000), Stable Paretian Models in Finance, Wiley, ISBN 978-0-471-95314-2.
  21. ^ Risk Manager Journal (2006), "New Approaches for Portfolio Optimization: Parting with the Bell Curve — Interview with Prof. Svetlozar Rachev and Prof.Stefan Mittnik" (PDF).
  22. ^ Doganoglu, Toker; Hartz, Christoph; Mittnik, Stefan (2007). "Portfolio Optimization When Risk Factors Are Conditionally Varying and Heavy Tailed" (PDF). Computational Economics. 29 (3–4): 333–354. doi:10.1007/s10614-006-9071-1. S2CID 8280640.
  23. ^ Seth Klarman (1991). Margin of Safety: Risk-averse Value Investing Strategies for the Thoughtful Investor. HarperCollins, ISBN 978-0887305108, pp. 97-102
  24. ^ Alasdair Nairn (2005). "Templeton's Way With Money: Strategies and Philosophy of a Legendary Investor." Wiley, ISBN 1118149610, p. 262
  25. ^ Duchin, Ran; Levy, Haim (2009). "Markowitz Versus the Talmudic Portfolio Diversification Strategies". The Journal of Portfolio Management. 35 (2): 71–74. doi:10.3905/JPM.2009.35.2.071. S2CID 154865200.
  26. ^ Henide, Karim (2023). "Sherman ratio optimization: constructing alternative ultrashort sovereign bond portfolios". Journal of Investment Strategies. doi:10.21314/JOIS.2023.001.
  27. ^ Stoyanov, Stoyan; Rachev, Svetlozar; Racheva-Yotova, Boryana; Fabozzi, Frank (2011). "Fat-Tailed Models for Risk Estimation" (PDF). The Journal of Portfolio Management. 37 (2): 107–117. doi:10.3905/jpm.2011.37.2.107. S2CID 154172853.
  28. ^ Loffler, A. (1996). Variance Aversion Implies μ-σ2-Criterion. Journal of economic theory, 69(2), 532-539.
  29. ^ MacCheroni, Fabio; Marinacci, Massimo; Rustichini, Aldo; Taboga, Marco (2009). "Portfolio Selection with Monotone Mean-Variance Preferences" (PDF). Mathematical Finance. 19 (3): 487–521. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9965.2009.00376.x. S2CID 154536043.
  30. ^ Grechuk, Bogdan; Molyboha, Anton; Zabarankin, Michael (2012). "Mean-Deviation Analysis in the Theory of Choice". Risk Analysis. 32 (8): 1277–1292. doi:10.1111/j.1539-6924.2011.01611.x. PMID 21477097. S2CID 12133839.
  31. ^ Chandra, Siddharth (2003). "Regional Economy Size and the Growth-Instability Frontier: Evidence from Europe". Journal of Regional Science. 43 (1): 95–122. doi:10.1111/1467-9787.00291. S2CID 154477444.
  32. ^ Chandra, Siddharth; Shadel, William G. (2007). "Crossing disciplinary boundaries: Applying financial portfolio theory to model the organization of the self-concept". Journal of Research in Personality. 41 (2): 346–373. doi:10.1016/j.jrp.2006.04.007.
  33. ^ Portfolio Theory of Information Retrieval July 11th, 2009 (2009-07-11). "Portfolio Theory of Information Retrieval | Dr. Jun Wang's Home Page". Web4.cs.ucl.ac.uk. Retrieved 2012-09-05.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  34. ^ a b Hubbard, Douglas (2007). How to Measure Anything: Finding the Value of Intangibles in Business. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons. ISBN 978-0-470-11012-6.
  35. ^ Sabbadini, Tony (2010). "Manufacturing Portfolio Theory" (PDF). International Institute for Advanced Studies in Systems Research and Cybernetics.

Further reading edit

  • Lintner, John (1965). "The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 47 (1): 13–39. doi:10.2307/1924119. JSTOR 1924119.
  • Sharpe, William F. (1964). "Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk". Journal of Finance. 19 (3): 425–442. doi:10.2307/2977928. hdl:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1964.tb02865.x. JSTOR 2977928.
  • Tobin, James (1958). "Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk" (PDF). The Review of Economic Studies. 25 (2): 65–86. doi:10.2307/2296205. JSTOR 2296205.

External links edit

  • Macro-Investment Analysis, Prof. William F. Sharpe, Stanford University
  • Portfolio Optimization, Prof. Stephen P. Boyd, Stanford University
  • "New Approaches for Portfolio Optimization: Parting with the Bell Curve" — Interview with Prof. Svetlozar Rachev and Prof. Stefan Mittnik
  • "Bruno de Finetti and Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection Article by Mark Rubinstein on Bruno de Finetti's discovery and comments by Markowitz.

modern, portfolio, theory, portfolio, analysis, redirects, here, text, book, portfolio, analysis, theorems, about, mean, variance, efficient, frontier, mutual, fund, separation, theorem, mean, variance, portfolio, analysis, marginal, conditional, stochastic, d. Portfolio analysis redirects here For the text book see Portfolio Analysis For theorems about the mean variance efficient frontier see Mutual fund separation theorem For non mean variance portfolio analysis see Marginal conditional stochastic dominance Modern portfolio theory MPT or mean variance analysis is a mathematical framework for assembling a portfolio of assets such that the expected return is maximized for a given level of risk It is a formalization and extension of diversification in investing the idea that owning different kinds of financial assets is less risky than owning only one type Its key insight is that an asset s risk and return should not be assessed by itself but by how it contributes to a portfolio s overall risk and return The variance of return or its transformation the standard deviation is used as a measure of risk because it is tractable when assets are combined into portfolios 1 Often the historical variance and covariance of returns is used as a proxy for the forward looking versions of these quantities 2 but other more sophisticated methods are available 3 Economist Harry Markowitz introduced MPT in a 1952 essay 1 for which he was later awarded a Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences see Markowitz model In 1940 Bruno de Finetti published 4 the mean variance analysis method in the context of proportional reinsurance under a stronger assumption The paper was obscure and only became known to economists of the English speaking world in 2006 5 Contents 1 Mathematical model 1 1 Risk and expected return 1 2 Diversification 1 3 Efficient frontier with no risk free asset 1 4 Two mutual fund theorem 1 5 Risk free asset and the capital allocation line 1 6 Geometric intuition 1 6 1 Markowitz bullet 1 6 2 Tangency portfolio 1 6 3 Non invertible covariance matrix 2 Asset pricing 2 1 Systematic risk and specific risk 2 2 Capital asset pricing model 3 Criticisms 4 Extensions 5 Connection with rational choice theory 6 Other applications 6 1 Project portfolios and other non financial assets 7 See also 8 References 9 Further reading 10 External linksMathematical model editRisk and expected return edit This section does not cite any sources Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed April 2021 Learn how and when to remove this template message MPT assumes that investors are risk averse meaning that given two portfolios that offer the same expected return investors will prefer the less risky one Thus an investor will take on increased risk only if compensated by higher expected returns Conversely an investor who wants higher expected returns must accept more risk The exact trade off will not be the same for all investors Different investors will evaluate the trade off differently based on individual risk aversion characteristics The implication is that a rational investor will not invest in a portfolio if a second portfolio exists with a more favorable risk vs expected return profile i e if for that level of risk an alternative portfolio exists that has better expected returns Under the model Portfolio return is the proportion weighted combination of the constituent assets returns Portfolio return volatility s p displaystyle sigma p nbsp is a function of the correlations rij of the component assets for all asset pairs i j The volatility gives insight into the risk which is associated with the investment The higher the volatility the higher the risk In general Expected return E R p i w i E R i displaystyle operatorname E R p sum i w i operatorname E R i quad nbsp where R p displaystyle R p nbsp is the return on the portfolio R i displaystyle R i nbsp is the return on asset i and w i displaystyle w i nbsp is the weighting of component asset i displaystyle i nbsp that is the proportion of asset i in the portfolio so that i w i 1 displaystyle sum i w i 1 nbsp Portfolio return variance s p 2 i w i 2 s i 2 i j i w i w j s i s j r i j displaystyle sigma p 2 sum i w i 2 sigma i 2 sum i sum j neq i w i w j sigma i sigma j rho ij nbsp where s i displaystyle sigma i nbsp is the sample standard deviation of the periodic returns on an asset i and r i j displaystyle rho ij nbsp is the correlation coefficient between the returns on assets i and j Alternatively the expression can be written as s p 2 i j w i w j s i s j r i j displaystyle sigma p 2 sum i sum j w i w j sigma i sigma j rho ij nbsp where r i j 1 displaystyle rho ij 1 nbsp for i j displaystyle i j nbsp ors p 2 i j w i w j s i j displaystyle sigma p 2 sum i sum j w i w j sigma ij nbsp where s i j s i s j r i j displaystyle sigma ij sigma i sigma j rho ij nbsp is the sample covariance of the periodic returns on the two assets or alternatively denoted as s i j displaystyle sigma i j nbsp cov i j displaystyle text cov ij nbsp or cov i j displaystyle text cov i j nbsp Portfolio return volatility standard deviation s p s p 2 displaystyle sigma p sqrt sigma p 2 nbsp For a two asset portfolio Portfolio expected return E R p w A E R A w B E R B w A E R A 1 w A E R B displaystyle operatorname E R p w A operatorname E R A w B operatorname E R B w A operatorname E R A 1 w A operatorname E R B nbsp Portfolio variance s p 2 w A 2 s A 2 w B 2 s B 2 2 w A w B s A s B r A B displaystyle sigma p 2 w A 2 sigma A 2 w B 2 sigma B 2 2w A w B sigma A sigma B rho AB nbsp For a three asset portfolio Portfolio expected return E R p w A E R A w B E R B w C E R C displaystyle operatorname E R p w A operatorname E R A w B operatorname E R B w C operatorname E R C nbsp Portfolio variance s p 2 w A 2 s A 2 w B 2 s B 2 w C 2 s C 2 2 w A w B s A s B r A B 2 w A w C s A s C r A C 2 w B w C s B s C r B C displaystyle sigma p 2 w A 2 sigma A 2 w B 2 sigma B 2 w C 2 sigma C 2 2w A w B sigma A sigma B rho AB 2w A w C sigma A sigma C rho AC 2w B w C sigma B sigma C rho BC nbsp The algebra can be much simplified by expressing the quantities involved in matrix notation 6 Arrange the returns of N risky assets in an N 1 displaystyle N times 1 nbsp vector R displaystyle R nbsp where the first element is the return of the first asset the second element of the second asset and so on Arrange their expected returns in a column vector m displaystyle mu nbsp and their variances and covariances in a covariance matrix S displaystyle Sigma nbsp Consider a portfolio of risky assets whose weights in each of the N risky assets is given by the corresponding element of the weight vector w displaystyle w nbsp Then Portfolio expected return w m displaystyle w mu nbsp and Portfolio variance w S w displaystyle w Sigma w nbsp For the case where there is investment in a riskfree asset with return R f displaystyle Rf nbsp the weights of the weight vector do not sum to 1 and the portfolio expected return becomes w m 1 w 1 R f displaystyle w mu 1 w 1 Rf nbsp The expression for the portfolio variance is unchanged Diversification edit This section does not cite any sources Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed April 2021 Learn how and when to remove this template message An investor can reduce portfolio risk especially s p displaystyle sigma p nbsp simply by holding combinations of instruments that are not perfectly positively correlated correlation coefficient 1 r i j lt 1 displaystyle 1 leq rho ij lt 1 nbsp In other words investors can reduce their exposure to individual asset risk by holding a diversified portfolio of assets Diversification may allow for the same portfolio expected return with reduced risk The mean variance framework for constructing optimal investment portfolios was first posited by Markowitz and has since been reinforced and improved by other economists and mathematicians who went on to account for the limitations of the framework If all the asset pairs have correlations of 0 they are perfectly uncorrelated the portfolio s return variance is the sum over all assets of the square of the fraction held in the asset times the asset s return variance and the portfolio standard deviation is the square root of this sum If all the asset pairs have correlations of 1 they are perfectly positively correlated then the portfolio return s standard deviation is the sum of the asset returns standard deviations weighted by the fractions held in the portfolio For given portfolio weights and given standard deviations of asset returns the case of all correlations being 1 gives the highest possible standard deviation of portfolio return Efficient frontier with no risk free asset edit Main article Efficient frontier See also Portfolio optimization nbsp Efficient Frontier The hyperbola is sometimes referred to as the Markowitz Bullet and is the efficient frontier if no risk free asset is available With a risk free asset the straight line is the efficient frontier The MPT is a mean variance theory and it compares the expected mean return of a portfolio with the standard deviation of the same portfolio The image shows expected return on the vertical axis and the standard deviation on the horizontal axis volatility Volatility is described by standard deviation and it serves as a measure of risk 7 The return standard deviation space is sometimes called the space of expected return vs risk Every possible combination of risky assets can be plotted in this risk expected return space and the collection of all such possible portfolios defines a region in this space The left boundary of this region is hyperbolic 8 and the upper part of the hyperbolic boundary is the efficient frontier in the absence of a risk free asset sometimes called the Markowitz bullet Combinations along this upper edge represent portfolios including no holdings of the risk free asset for which there is lowest risk for a given level of expected return Equivalently a portfolio lying on the efficient frontier represents the combination offering the best possible expected return for given risk level The tangent to the upper part of the hyperbolic boundary is the capital allocation line CAL Matrices are preferred for calculations of the efficient frontier In matrix form for a given risk tolerance q 0 displaystyle q in 0 infty nbsp the efficient frontier is found by minimizing the following expression w T S w q R T w displaystyle w T Sigma w q times R T w nbsp where w displaystyle w nbsp is a vector of portfolio weights and i w i 1 displaystyle sum i w i 1 nbsp The weights can be negative S displaystyle Sigma nbsp is the covariance matrix for the returns on the assets in the portfolio q 0 displaystyle q geq 0 nbsp is a risk tolerance factor where 0 results in the portfolio with minimal risk and displaystyle infty nbsp results in the portfolio infinitely far out on the frontier with both expected return and risk unbounded and R displaystyle R nbsp is a vector of expected returns w T S w displaystyle w T Sigma w nbsp is the variance of portfolio return R T w displaystyle R T w nbsp is the expected return on the portfolio The above optimization finds the point on the frontier at which the inverse of the slope of the frontier would be q if portfolio return variance instead of standard deviation were plotted horizontally The frontier in its entirety is parametric on q Harry Markowitz developed a specific procedure for solving the above problem called the critical line algorithm 9 that can handle additional linear constraints upper and lower bounds on assets and which is proved to work with a semi positive definite covariance matrix Examples of implementation of the critical line algorithm exist in Visual Basic for Applications 10 in JavaScript 11 and in a few other languages Also many software packages including MATLAB Microsoft Excel Mathematica and R provide generic optimization routines so that using these for solving the above problem is possible with potential caveats poor numerical accuracy requirement of positive definiteness of the covariance matrix An alternative approach to specifying the efficient frontier is to do so parametrically on the expected portfolio return R T w displaystyle R T w nbsp This version of the problem requires that we minimize w T S w displaystyle w T Sigma w nbsp subject to R T w m displaystyle R T w mu nbsp for parameter m displaystyle mu nbsp This problem is easily solved using a Lagrange multiplier which leads to the following linear system of equations 2 S R 1 R T 0 0 1 T 0 0 w l 1 l 2 0 m 1 displaystyle begin bmatrix 2 Sigma amp R amp bf 1 R T amp 0 amp 0 bf 1 T amp 0 amp 0 end bmatrix begin bmatrix w lambda 1 lambda 2 end bmatrix begin bmatrix 0 mu 1 end bmatrix nbsp Two mutual fund theorem edit One key result of the above analysis is the two mutual fund theorem 12 13 This theorem states that any portfolio on the efficient frontier can be generated by holding a combination of any two given portfolios on the frontier the latter two given portfolios are the mutual funds in the theorem s name So in the absence of a risk free asset an investor can achieve any desired efficient portfolio even if all that is accessible is a pair of efficient mutual funds If the location of the desired portfolio on the frontier is between the locations of the two mutual funds both mutual funds will be held in positive quantities If the desired portfolio is outside the range spanned by the two mutual funds then one of the mutual funds must be sold short held in negative quantity while the size of the investment in the other mutual fund must be greater than the amount available for investment the excess being funded by the borrowing from the other fund Risk free asset and the capital allocation line edit Main article Capital allocation line The risk free asset is the hypothetical asset that pays a risk free rate In practice short term government securities such as US treasury bills are used as a risk free asset because they pay a fixed rate of interest and have exceptionally low default risk The risk free asset has zero variance in returns hence is risk free it is also uncorrelated with any other asset by definition since its variance is zero As a result when it is combined with any other asset or portfolio of assets the change in return is linearly related to the change in risk as the proportions in the combination vary When a risk free asset is introduced the half line shown in the figure is the new efficient frontier It is tangent to the hyperbola at the pure risky portfolio with the highest Sharpe ratio Its vertical intercept represents a portfolio with 100 of holdings in the risk free asset the tangency with the hyperbola represents a portfolio with no risk free holdings and 100 of assets held in the portfolio occurring at the tangency point points between those points are portfolios containing positive amounts of both the risky tangency portfolio and the risk free asset and points on the half line beyond the tangency point are portfolios involving negative holdings of the risk free asset and an amount invested in the tangency portfolio equal to more than 100 of the investor s initial capital This efficient half line is called the capital allocation line CAL and its formula can be shown to be E R C R F s C E R P R F s P displaystyle E R C R F sigma C frac E R P R F sigma P nbsp In this formula P is the sub portfolio of risky assets at the tangency with the Markowitz bullet F is the risk free asset and C is a combination of portfolios P and F By the diagram the introduction of the risk free asset as a possible component of the portfolio has improved the range of risk expected return combinations available because everywhere except at the tangency portfolio the half line gives a higher expected return than the hyperbola does at every possible risk level The fact that all points on the linear efficient locus can be achieved by a combination of holdings of the risk free asset and the tangency portfolio is known as the one mutual fund theorem 12 where the mutual fund referred to is the tangency portfolio Geometric intuition edit The efficient frontier can be pictured as a problem in quadratic curves 12 On the market we have the assets R 1 R 2 R n displaystyle R 1 R 2 dots R n nbsp We have some funds and a portfolio is a way to divide our funds into the assets Each portfolio can be represented as a vector w 1 w 2 w n displaystyle w 1 w 2 dots w n nbsp such that i w i 1 displaystyle sum i w i 1 nbsp and we hold the assets according to w T R i w i R i displaystyle w T R sum i w i R i nbsp Markowitz bullet edit nbsp The ellipsoid is the contour of constant variance The x y z 1 displaystyle x y z 1 nbsp plane is the space of possible portfolios The other plane is the contour of constant expected return The ellipsoid intersects the plane to give an ellipse of portfolios of constant variance On this ellipse the point of maximal or minimal expected return is the point where it is tangent to the contour of constant expected return All these portfolios fall on one line Since we wish to maximize expected return while minimizing the standard deviation of the return we are to solve a quadratic optimization problem E w T R m min s 2 V a r w T R i w i 1 displaystyle begin cases E w T R mu min sigma 2 Var w T R sum i w i 1 end cases nbsp Portfolios are points in the Euclidean space R n displaystyle mathbb R n nbsp The third equation states that the portfolio should fall on a plane defined by i w i 1 displaystyle sum i w i 1 nbsp The first equation states that the portfolio should fall on a plane defined by w T E R m displaystyle w T E R mu nbsp The second condition states that the portfolio should fall on the contour surface for i j w i r i j w j displaystyle sum ij w i rho ij w j nbsp that is as close to the origin as possible Since the equation is quadratic each such contour surface is an ellipsoid assuming that the covariance matrix r i j displaystyle rho ij nbsp is invertible Therefore we can solve the quadratic optimization graphically by drawing ellipsoidal contours on the plane i w i 1 displaystyle sum i w i 1 nbsp then intersect the contours with the plane w w T E R m and i w i 1 displaystyle w w T E R mu text and sum i w i 1 nbsp As the ellipsoidal contours shrink eventually one of them would become exactly tangent to the plane before the contours become completely disjoint from the plane The tangent point is the optimal portfolio at this level of expected return As we vary m displaystyle mu nbsp the tangent point varies as well but always falling on a single line this is the two mutual funds theorem Let the line be parameterized as w w t t R displaystyle w w t t in mathbb R nbsp We find that along the line m w T E R t w T E R s 2 w T r w t 2 2 w T r w t w T r w displaystyle begin cases mu amp w T E R t w T E R sigma 2 amp w T rho w t 2 2 w T rho w t w T rho w end cases nbsp giving a hyperbola in the s m displaystyle sigma mu nbsp plane The hyperbola has two branches symmetric with respect to the m displaystyle mu nbsp axis However only the branch with s gt 0 displaystyle sigma gt 0 nbsp is meaningful By symmetry the two asymptotes of the hyperbola intersect at a point m M V P displaystyle mu MVP nbsp on the m displaystyle mu nbsp axis The point m m i d displaystyle mu mid nbsp is the height of the leftmost point of the hyperbola and can be interpreted as the expected return of the global minimum variance portfolio global MVP Tangency portfolio edit nbsp Illustration of the effect of changing the risk free asset return rate As the risk free return rate approaches the return rate of the global minimum variance portfolio the tangency portfolio escapes to infinity Animated at source 2 The tangency portfolio exists if and only if m R F lt m M V P displaystyle mu RF lt mu MVP nbsp In particular if the risk free return is greater or equal to m M V P displaystyle mu MVP nbsp then the tangent portfolio does not exist The capital market line CML becomes parallel to the upper asymptote line of the hyperbola Points on the CML become impossible to achieve though they can be approached from below It is usually assumed that the risk free return is less than the return of the global MVP in order that the tangency portfolio exists However even in this case as m R F displaystyle mu RF nbsp approaches m M V P displaystyle mu MVP nbsp from below the tangency portfolio diverges to a portfolio with infinite return and variance Since there are only finitely many assets in the market such a portfolio must be shorting some assets heavily while longing some other assets heavily In practice such a tangency portfolio would be impossible to achieve because one cannot short an asset too much due to short sale constraints and also because of price impact that is longing a large amount of an asset would push up its price breaking the assumption that the asset prices do not depend on the portfolio Non invertible covariance matrix edit If the covariance matrix is not invertible then there exists some nonzero vector v displaystyle v nbsp such that v T R displaystyle v T R nbsp is a random variable with zero variance that is it is not random at all Suppose i v i 0 displaystyle sum i v i 0 nbsp and v T R 0 displaystyle v T R 0 nbsp then that means one of the assets can be exactly replicated using the other assets at the same price and the same return Therefore there is never a reason to buy that asset and we can remove it from the market Suppose i v i 0 displaystyle sum i v i 0 nbsp and v T R 0 displaystyle v T R neq 0 nbsp then that means there is free money breaking the no arbitrage assumption Suppose i v i 0 displaystyle sum i v i neq 0 nbsp then we can scale the vector to i v i 1 displaystyle sum i v i 1 nbsp This means that we have constructed a risk free asset with return v T R displaystyle v T R nbsp We can remove each such asset from the market constructing one risk free asset for each such asset removed By the no arbitrage assumption all their return rates are equal For the assets that still remain in the market their covariance matrix is invertible Asset pricing editThe above analysis describes optimal behavior of an individual investor Asset pricing theory builds on this analysis allowing MPT to derive the required expected return for a correctly priced asset in this context Intuitively in a perfect market with rational investors if a security was expensive relative to others i e too much risk for the price demand would fall and its price would drop correspondingly if cheap demand and price would increase likewise This would continue until all such adjustments had ceased a state of market equilibrium In this equilibrium relative supplies will equal relative demands given the relationship of price with supply and demand since risk to reward is identical across all securities proportions of each security in any fully diversified portfolio would correspondingly be the same More formally then since everyone holds the risky assets in identical proportions to each other namely in the proportions given by the tangency portfolio in market equilibrium the risky assets prices and therefore their expected returns will adjust so that the ratios in the tangency portfolio are the same as the ratios in which the risky assets are supplied to the market 14 The result for expected return then follows as below Systematic risk and specific risk edit This section does not cite any sources Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed April 2021 Learn how and when to remove this template message Specific risk is the risk associated with individual assets within a portfolio these risks can be reduced through diversification specific risks cancel out Specific risk is also called diversifiable unique unsystematic or idiosyncratic risk Systematic risk a k a portfolio risk or market risk refers to the risk common to all securities except for selling short as noted below systematic risk cannot be diversified away within one market Within the market portfolio asset specific risk will be diversified away to the extent possible Systematic risk is therefore equated with the risk standard deviation of the market portfolio Since a security will be purchased only if it improves the risk expected return characteristics of the market portfolio the relevant measure of the risk of a security is the risk it adds to the market portfolio and not its risk in isolation In this context the volatility of the asset and its correlation with the market portfolio are historically observed and are therefore given There are several approaches to asset pricing that attempt to price assets by modelling the stochastic properties of the moments of assets returns these are broadly referred to as conditional asset pricing models Systematic risks within one market can be managed through a strategy of using both long and short positions within one portfolio creating a market neutral portfolio Market neutral portfolios therefore will be uncorrelated with broader market indices Capital asset pricing model edit Main article Capital asset pricing model The asset return depends on the amount paid for the asset today The price paid must ensure that the market portfolio s risk return characteristics improve when the asset is added to it The CAPM is a model that derives the theoretical required expected return i e discount rate for an asset in a market given the risk free rate available to investors and the risk of the market as a whole The CAPM is usually expressed E R i R f b i E R m R f displaystyle operatorname E R i R f beta i operatorname E R m R f nbsp b Beta is the measure of asset sensitivity to a movement in the overall market Beta is usually found via regression on historical data Betas exceeding one signify more than average riskiness in the sense of the asset s contribution to overall portfolio risk betas below one indicate a lower than average risk contribution E R m R f displaystyle operatorname E R m R f nbsp is the market premium the expected excess return of the market portfolio s expected return over the risk free rate A derivation 14 is as follows 1 The incremental impact on risk and expected return when an additional risky asset a is added to the market portfolio m follows from the formulae for a two asset portfolio These results are used to derive the asset appropriate discount rate Updated portfolio risk w m 2 s m 2 w a 2 s a 2 2 w m w a r a m s a s m displaystyle w m 2 sigma m 2 w a 2 sigma a 2 2w m w a rho am sigma a sigma m nbsp Hence risk added to portfolio w a 2 s a 2 2 w m w a r a m s a s m displaystyle w a 2 sigma a 2 2w m w a rho am sigma a sigma m nbsp but since the weight of the asset will be very low re the overall market w a 2 0 displaystyle w a 2 approx 0 nbsp i e additional risk 2 w m w a r a m s a s m displaystyle 2w m w a rho am sigma a sigma m quad nbsp dd Updated expected return w m E R m w a E R a displaystyle w m operatorname E R m w a operatorname E R a nbsp Hence additional expected return w a E R a displaystyle w a operatorname E R a nbsp dd 2 If an asset a is correctly priced the improvement for an investor in her risk to expected return ratio achieved by adding it to the market portfolio m will at least in equilibrium exactly match the gains of spending that money on an increased stake in the market portfolio The assumption is that the investor will purchase the asset with funds borrowed at the risk free rate R f displaystyle R f nbsp this is rational if E R a gt R f displaystyle operatorname E R a gt R f nbsp Thus w a E R a R f 2 w m w a r a m s a s m w a E R m R f 2 w m w a s m s m displaystyle w a operatorname E R a R f 2w m w a rho am sigma a sigma m w a operatorname E R m R f 2w m w a sigma m sigma m nbsp i e E R a R f E R m R f r a m s a s m s m s m displaystyle operatorname E R a R f operatorname E R m R f rho am sigma a sigma m sigma m sigma m nbsp i e E R a R f E R m R f s a m s m m displaystyle operatorname E R a R f operatorname E R m R f sigma am sigma mm nbsp since r X Y s X Y s X s Y displaystyle rho XY sigma XY sigma X sigma Y nbsp s a m s m m displaystyle sigma am sigma mm quad nbsp is the beta b displaystyle beta nbsp return mentioned the covariance between the asset s return and the market s return divided by the variance of the market return i e the sensitivity of the asset price to movement in the market portfolio s value see also Beta finance Adding an asset to the market portfolio This equation can be estimated statistically using the following regression equation S C L R i t R f a i b i R M t R f ϵ i t displaystyle mathrm SCL R i t R f alpha i beta i R M t R f epsilon i t frac nbsp where ai is called the asset s alpha bi is the asset s beta coefficient and SCL is the security characteristic line Once an asset s expected return E R i displaystyle E R i nbsp is calculated using CAPM the future cash flows of the asset can be discounted to their present value using this rate to establish the correct price for the asset A riskier stock will have a higher beta and will be discounted at a higher rate less sensitive stocks will have lower betas and be discounted at a lower rate In theory an asset is correctly priced when its observed price is the same as its value calculated using the CAPM derived discount rate If the observed price is higher than the valuation then the asset is overvalued it is undervalued for a too low price Criticisms editDespite its theoretical importance critics of MPT question whether it is an ideal investment tool because its model of financial markets does not match the real world in many ways 15 2 The risk return and correlation measures used by MPT are based on expected values which means that they are statistical statements about the future the expected value of returns is explicit in the above equations and implicit in the definitions of variance and covariance Such measures often cannot capture the true statistical features of the risk and return which often follow highly skewed distributions e g the log normal distribution and can give rise to besides reduced volatility also inflated growth of return 16 In practice investors must substitute predictions based on historical measurements of asset return and volatility for these values in the equations Very often such expected values fail to take account of new circumstances that did not exist when the historical data were generated 17 An optimal approach to capturing trends which differs from Markowitz optimization by utilizing invariance properties is also derived from physics Instead of transforming the normalized expectations using the inverse of the correlation matrix the invariant portfolio employs the inverse of the square root of the correlation matrix 18 The optimization problem is solved under the assumption that expected values are uncertain and correlated 19 The Markowitz solution corresponds only to the case where the correlation between expected returns is similar to the correlation between returns More fundamentally investors are stuck with estimating key parameters from past market data because MPT attempts to model risk in terms of the likelihood of losses but says nothing about why those losses might occur The risk measurements used are probabilistic in nature not structural This is a major difference as compared to many engineering approaches to risk management Options theory and MPT have at least one important conceptual difference from the probabilistic risk assessment done by nuclear power plants A PRA is what economists would call a structural model The components of a system and their relationships are modeled in Monte Carlo simulations If valve X fails it causes a loss of back pressure on pump Y causing a drop in flow to vessel Z and so on But in the Black Scholes equation and MPT there is no attempt to explain an underlying structure to price changes Various outcomes are simply given probabilities And unlike the PRA if there is no history of a particular system level event like a liquidity crisis there is no way to compute the odds of it If nuclear engineers ran risk management this way they would never be able to compute the odds of a meltdown at a particular plant until several similar events occurred in the same reactor design Douglas W Hubbard The Failure of Risk Management p 67 John Wiley amp Sons 2009 ISBN 978 0 470 38795 5 Mathematical risk measurements are also useful only to the degree that they reflect investors true concerns there is no point minimizing a variable that nobody cares about in practice In particular variance is a symmetric measure that counts abnormally high returns as just as risky as abnormally low returns The psychological phenomenon of loss aversion is the idea that investors are more concerned about losses than gains meaning that our intuitive concept of risk is fundamentally asymmetric in nature There many other risk measures like coherent risk measures might better reflect investors true preferences Modern portfolio theory has also been criticized because it assumes that returns follow a Gaussian distribution Already in the 1960s Benoit Mandelbrot and Eugene Fama showed the inadequacy of this assumption and proposed the use of more general stable distributions instead Stefan Mittnik and Svetlozar Rachev presented strategies for deriving optimal portfolios in such settings 20 21 22 More recently Nassim Nicholas Taleb has also criticized modern portfolio theory on this ground writing After the stock market crash in 1987 they rewarded two theoreticians Harry Markowitz and William Sharpe who built beautifully Platonic models on a Gaussian base contributing to what is called Modern Portfolio Theory Simply if you remove their Gaussian assumptions and treat prices as scalable you are left with hot air The Nobel Committee could have tested the Sharpe and Markowitz models they work like quack remedies sold on the Internet but nobody in Stockholm seems to have thought about it Nassim N Taleb The Black Swan The Impact of the Highly Improbable p 277 Random House 2007 ISBN 978 1 4000 6351 2 Contrarian investors and value investors typically do not subscribe to Modern Portfolio Theory 23 One objection is that the MPT relies on the efficient market hypothesis and uses fluctuations in share price as a substitute for risk Sir John Templeton believed in diversification as a concept but also felt the theoretical foundations of MPT were questionable and concluded as described by a biographer the notion that building portfolios on the basis of unreliable and irrelevant statistical inputs such as historical volatility was doomed to failure 24 A few studies have argued that naive diversification splitting capital equally among available investment options might have advantages over MPT in some situations 25 When applied to certain universes of assets the Markowitz model has been identified by academics to be inadequate due to its susceptibility to model instability which may arise for example among a universe of highly correlated assets 26 Extensions editSince MPT s introduction in 1952 many attempts have been made to improve the model especially by using more realistic assumptions Post modern portfolio theory extends MPT by adopting non normally distributed asymmetric and fat tailed measures of risk 27 This helps with some of these problems but not others Black Litterman model optimization is an extension of unconstrained Markowitz optimization that incorporates relative and absolute views on inputs of risk and returns from The model is also extended by assuming that expected returns are uncertain and the correlation matrix in this case can differ from the correlation matrix between returns 18 19 Connection with rational choice theory editModern portfolio theory is inconsistent with main axioms of rational choice theory most notably with monotonicity axiom stating that if investing into portfolio X will with probability one return more money than investing into portfolio Y then a rational investor should prefer X to Y In contrast modern portfolio theory is based on a different axiom called variance aversion 28 and may recommend to invest into Y on the basis that it has lower variance Maccheroni et al 29 described choice theory which is the closest possible to the modern portfolio theory while satisfying monotonicity axiom Alternatively mean deviation analysis 30 is a rational choice theory resulting from replacing variance by an appropriate deviation risk measure Other applications editIn the 1970s concepts from MPT found their way into the field of regional science In a series of seminal works Michael Conroy citation needed modeled the labor force in the economy using portfolio theoretic methods to examine growth and variability in the labor force This was followed by a long literature on the relationship between economic growth and volatility 31 More recently modern portfolio theory has been used to model the self concept in social psychology When the self attributes comprising the self concept constitute a well diversified portfolio then psychological outcomes at the level of the individual such as mood and self esteem should be more stable than when the self concept is undiversified This prediction has been confirmed in studies involving human subjects 32 Recently modern portfolio theory has been applied to modelling the uncertainty and correlation between documents in information retrieval Given a query the aim is to maximize the overall relevance of a ranked list of documents and at the same time minimize the overall uncertainty of the ranked list 33 Project portfolios and other non financial assets edit Some experts apply MPT to portfolios of projects and other assets besides financial instruments 34 35 When MPT is applied outside of traditional financial portfolios some distinctions between the different types of portfolios must be considered The assets in financial portfolios are for practical purposes continuously divisible while portfolios of projects are lumpy For example while we can compute that the optimal portfolio position for 3 stocks is say 44 35 21 the optimal position for a project portfolio may not allow us to simply change the amount spent on a project Projects might be all or nothing or at least have logical units that cannot be separated A portfolio optimization method would have to take the discrete nature of projects into account The assets of financial portfolios are liquid they can be assessed or re assessed at any point in time But opportunities for launching new projects may be limited and may occur in limited windows of time Projects that have already been initiated cannot be abandoned without the loss of the sunk costs i e there is little or no recovery salvage value of a half complete project Neither of these necessarily eliminate the possibility of using MPT and such portfolios They simply indicate the need to run the optimization with an additional set of mathematically expressed constraints that would not normally apply to financial portfolios Furthermore some of the simplest elements of Modern Portfolio Theory are applicable to virtually any kind of portfolio The concept of capturing the risk tolerance of an investor by documenting how much risk is acceptable for a given return may be applied to a variety of decision analysis problems MPT uses historical variance as a measure of risk but portfolios of assets like major projects do not have a well defined historical variance In this case the MPT investment boundary can be expressed in more general terms like chance of an ROI less than cost of capital or chance of losing more than half of the investment When risk is put in terms of uncertainty about forecasts and possible losses then the concept is transferable to various types of investment 34 See also editOutline of finance Portfolio theory Beta finance Bias ratio finance Black Litterman model Financial risk management Investment management Intertemporal portfolio choice Investment theory Kelly criterion Marginal conditional stochastic dominance Markowitz model Mutual fund separation theorem Omega ratio Post modern portfolio theory Sortino ratio Treynor ratio Two moment decision models Universal portfolio algorithmReferences edit a b Markowitz H M March 1952 Portfolio Selection The Journal of Finance 7 1 77 91 doi 10 2307 2975974 JSTOR 2975974 a b Wigglesworth Robin 11 April 2018 How a volatility virus infected Wall Street The Financial Times Luc Bauwens Sebastien Laurent Jeroen V K Rombouts February 2006 Multivariate GARCH models a survey Journal of Applied Econometrics 21 1 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link de Finetti B 1940 Il problema dei Pieni Giornale dell Istituto Italiano degli Attuari 11 1 88 translation Barone L 2006 The problem of full risk insurances Chapter I The risk within a single accounting period Journal of Investment Management 4 3 19 43 Pressacco Flavio Serafini Paolo May 2007 The origins of the mean variance approach in finance revisiting de Finetti 65 years later Decisions in Economics and Finance 30 1 19 49 doi 10 1007 s10203 007 0067 7 ISSN 1593 8883 David Lando and Rolf Poulsen s lecture notes Chapter 9 Portfolio theory 1 Portfolio Selection Harry Markowitz The Journal of Finance Vol 7 No 1 Mar 1952 pp 77 91 see bottom of slide 6 here Markowitz H M March 1956 The Optimization of a Quadratic Function Subject to Linear Constraints Naval Research Logistics Quarterly 3 1 2 111 133 doi 10 1002 nav 3800030110 Markowitz Harry February 2000 Mean Variance Analysis in Portfolio Choice and Capital Markets Wiley ISBN 978 1 883 24975 5 PortfolioAllocation JavaScript library github com lequant40 Retrieved 2018 06 13 a b c Merton Robert C September 1972 An Analytic Derivation of the Efficient Portfolio Frontier PDF The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 7 4 1851 doi 10 2307 2329621 hdl 1721 1 46832 ISSN 0022 1090 Archived from the original on 21 Mar 2022 Karatzas Ioannis Lehoczky John P Sethi Suresh P Shreve Steven E 1986 Explicit Solution of a General Consumption Investment Problem Mathematics of Operations Research 11 2 261 294 doi 10 1287 moor 11 2 261 JSTOR 3689808 S2CID 22489650 SSRN 1086184 a b See e g Tim Bollerslev 2019 Risk and Return in Equilibrium The Capital Asset Pricing Model CAPM Mahdavi Damghani B 2013 The Non Misleading Value of Inferred Correlation An Introduction to the Cointelation Model Wilmott Magazine 2013 67 50 61 doi 10 1002 wilm 10252 Hui C Fox G A Gurevitch J 2017 Scale dependent portfolio effects explain growth inflation and volatility reduction in landscape demography Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the USA 114 47 12507 12511 Bibcode 2017PNAS 11412507H doi 10 1073 pnas 1704213114 PMC 5703273 PMID 29109261 Low R K Y Faff R Aas K 2016 Enhancing mean variance portfolio selection by modeling distributional asymmetries PDF Journal of Economics and Business 85 49 72 doi 10 1016 j jeconbus 2016 01 003 a b Benichou R Lemperiere Y Serie E Kockelkoren J Seager P Bouchaud J P Potters M 2017 Agnostic Risk Parity Taming Known and Unknown Unknowns Journal of Investment Strategies 6 a b Valeyre S 2024 Optimal trend following portfolios Journal of Investment Strategies 12 Rachev Svetlozar T and Stefan Mittnik 2000 Stable Paretian Models in Finance Wiley ISBN 978 0 471 95314 2 Risk Manager Journal 2006 New Approaches for Portfolio Optimization Parting with the Bell Curve Interview with Prof Svetlozar Rachev and Prof Stefan Mittnik PDF Doganoglu Toker Hartz Christoph Mittnik Stefan 2007 Portfolio Optimization When Risk Factors Are Conditionally Varying and Heavy Tailed PDF Computational Economics 29 3 4 333 354 doi 10 1007 s10614 006 9071 1 S2CID 8280640 Seth Klarman 1991 Margin of Safety Risk averse Value Investing Strategies for the Thoughtful Investor HarperCollins ISBN 978 0887305108 pp 97 102 Alasdair Nairn 2005 Templeton s Way With Money Strategies and Philosophy of a Legendary Investor Wiley ISBN 1118149610 p 262 Duchin Ran Levy Haim 2009 Markowitz Versus the Talmudic Portfolio Diversification Strategies The Journal of Portfolio Management 35 2 71 74 doi 10 3905 JPM 2009 35 2 071 S2CID 154865200 Henide Karim 2023 Sherman ratio optimization constructing alternative ultrashort sovereign bond portfolios Journal of Investment Strategies doi 10 21314 JOIS 2023 001 Stoyanov Stoyan Rachev Svetlozar Racheva Yotova Boryana Fabozzi Frank 2011 Fat Tailed Models for Risk Estimation PDF The Journal of Portfolio Management 37 2 107 117 doi 10 3905 jpm 2011 37 2 107 S2CID 154172853 Loffler A 1996 Variance Aversion Implies m s2 Criterion Journal of economic theory 69 2 532 539 MacCheroni Fabio Marinacci Massimo Rustichini Aldo Taboga Marco 2009 Portfolio Selection with Monotone Mean Variance Preferences PDF Mathematical Finance 19 3 487 521 doi 10 1111 j 1467 9965 2009 00376 x S2CID 154536043 Grechuk Bogdan Molyboha Anton Zabarankin Michael 2012 Mean Deviation Analysis in the Theory of Choice Risk Analysis 32 8 1277 1292 doi 10 1111 j 1539 6924 2011 01611 x PMID 21477097 S2CID 12133839 Chandra Siddharth 2003 Regional Economy Size and the Growth Instability Frontier Evidence from Europe Journal of Regional Science 43 1 95 122 doi 10 1111 1467 9787 00291 S2CID 154477444 Chandra Siddharth Shadel William G 2007 Crossing disciplinary boundaries Applying financial portfolio theory to model the organization of the self concept Journal of Research in Personality 41 2 346 373 doi 10 1016 j jrp 2006 04 007 Portfolio Theory of Information Retrieval July 11th 2009 2009 07 11 Portfolio Theory of Information Retrieval Dr Jun Wang s Home Page Web4 cs ucl ac uk Retrieved 2012 09 05 a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a CS1 maint numeric names authors list link a b Hubbard Douglas 2007 How to Measure Anything Finding the Value of Intangibles in Business Hoboken NJ John Wiley amp Sons ISBN 978 0 470 11012 6 Sabbadini Tony 2010 Manufacturing Portfolio Theory PDF International Institute for Advanced Studies in Systems Research and Cybernetics Further reading editLintner John 1965 The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets The Review of Economics and Statistics 47 1 13 39 doi 10 2307 1924119 JSTOR 1924119 Sharpe William F 1964 Capital asset prices A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk Journal of Finance 19 3 425 442 doi 10 2307 2977928 hdl 10 1111 j 1540 6261 1964 tb02865 x JSTOR 2977928 Tobin James 1958 Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk PDF The Review of Economic Studies 25 2 65 86 doi 10 2307 2296205 JSTOR 2296205 External links edit nbsp Wikimedia Commons has media related to Portfolio theory Macro Investment Analysis Prof William F Sharpe Stanford University Portfolio Optimization Prof Stephen P Boyd Stanford University New Approaches for Portfolio Optimization Parting with the Bell Curve Interview with Prof Svetlozar Rachev and Prof Stefan Mittnik Bruno de Finetti and Mean Variance Portfolio Selection Article by Mark Rubinstein on Bruno de Finetti s discovery and comments by Markowitz Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Modern portfolio theory amp oldid 1203583419, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.