fbpx
Wikipedia

Property rights (economics)

Property rights are constructs in economics for determining how a resource or economic good is used and owned,[1] which have developed over ancient and modern history, from Abrahamic law to Article 17 of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights. Resources can be owned by (and hence be the property of) individuals, associations, collectives, or governments.[2]

Property rights can be viewed as an attribute of an economic good. This attribute has three broad components,[3][4][5] and is often referred to as a bundle of rights in the United States:[6]

  1. the right to use the good
  2. the right to earn income from the good
  3. the right to transfer the good to others, alter it, abandon it, or destroy it (the right to ownership cessation)

Conceptualizing property in economics vs. law

The fields of economics and law do not have a general consensus on conceptions of property rights.[7] Various property types are used in law but the terminology can be seen in economic reports. Sometimes in economics, property types are simply described as private or public/common in reference to private goods (excludable and rivalrous goods like a phone),[8] as well as public goods (non-excludable and non-rivalrous goods, like air),[9] respectively.[10] Below is a list of the several property types defined and their relation to the economic concepts of excludability (the ability to limit the consumption of the good) and rivalry (a person's consumption of the good reduces the ability of another to consume it).

Types of property regimes

  • Property rights can be categorized with excludability and rivalry. Excludability describes the characteristic regarding whether a good can be withheld from certain consumers. In terms of the same good, rivalry describes its accessibility to competing consumers. The combination of excludability and rivalry as parameters is reflected through various types of property rights.
  • Open-access property is owned by nobody (res nullius).[11] It is non-excludable, as excluding people is either impossible or prohibitively costly, and can be rivalrous or non-rivalrous. Open-access property is not managed by anyone, and access to it is not controlled. This is also known as a common property resource, impure public good or a common pool resource.[12] Examples of this can be air, water, sights, and sounds. Tragedy of the commons refers to this title. An example would be unregulated forests as there's limited resources available and therefore rivalrous, but anyone may access these resources. If non-rivalrous, it would be a public good (cannot be rivalrous, no matter how much it is used, for example, the ocean (outside of territorial borders)).[9]

Open-access property may exist because ownership has never been established, granted, by laws within a particular country, or because no effective controls are in place, or feasible, i.e., the cost of exclusivity outweighs the benefits.

— Encyclopedia of Law and Economics
  • Public property, also known as state property, is excludable and can be rivalrous or non-rivalrous.[13] This type of property is publicly owned, but its access and use are managed and controlled by a government agency or organization granted such authority.[14] For example, a government pavement is non-excludable as anyone may use it but rivalrous as, the more people using it, the more likely it will be too crowded for another to join. Public property is sometimes used interchangeably with public good,[15] usually impure public goods. They may also be a club good, which is excludable and non-rivalrous.[16] An example would be paying to go to an uncongested public bathroom, as the price excludes those who can't afford it but there is ample utilities for more people to use making it non-rivalrous.
  • Private property is both excludable and rivalrous. Private property access, use, exclusion and management are controlled by the private owner or a group of legal owners.[8] This is sometimes used interchangeably with private good.[15] An example would be a cellphone as it only one person may use it, making it rivalrous, and it has to be purchased, which makes it excludable.
  • Common property or collective property is excludable and rivalrous. Not to be confused with common property in reference to economics, this is in reference to law. It is property that is owned by a group of individuals where access, use, and exclusion are controlled by the joint owners.[17][11] Unlike private property, common property has multiple owners, which allows for a greater ability to manage conflicts through shared benefits and enforcement. This would still be related to private goods. An example of common property would be any private good that is jointly owned.

Property-rights theory

Introduction

Property rights theory is an exploration of how providing stakeholders with ownership of any factors of production or goods, not just land, will increase the efficiency of an economy as the gains from providing the rights exceed the costs.[18] A widely accepted explanation is that well-enforced property rights provide incentives for individuals to participate in economic activities, such as investment, innovation and trade, which lead to a more efficient market.[19] Implicit or explicit property rights can be created through government regulation in the market, either through prescriptive command and control approaches (e.g. limits on input/output/discharge quantities, specified processes/equipment, audits) or by market-based instruments (e.g. taxes, transferable permits or quotas),[17] and more recently through cooperative, self-regulatory, post-regulatory and reflexive law approaches.[20] In economics, depending on the level of transaction costs, various forms of property rights institutions will develop.[15] In economics, an institution is defined thusly:

"a complex of positions, roles, norms and values lodged in particular types of social structures and organising relatively stable patterns of human activity with respect to fundamental problems in producing life-sustaining resources, in reproducing individuals, and in sustaining viable societal structures within a given environment."

— Johnathon Turner, The Institutional Order

For specificity in the case of economic property rights, this is a system or structure that has value and stability. Transaction costs are the costs of defining, monitoring, and enforcing property rights.[21][22]

Exploration

Ronald Coase proposed that clearly defining and assigning property rights would resolve environmental problems by internalizing externalities and rely on incentives of private owners to conserve resources for the future.[23] He asserts transaction costs are ideally zero because they cause inefficiencies; due to those who would be allocatively efficient with the ownership being unable to afford or receiving less private benefit than they gain from it, as the transaction costs on top of the cost of purchasing and maintaining the property.[24] This is known as Coase theorem. Critics of this view argue that this assumes that it is possible to internalize all environmental benefits, that owners will have perfect information, that scale economies are manageable, transaction costs are bearable, and that legal frameworks operate efficiently.[17]

John Locke, Adam Smith, and Karl Marx are classical economists that generally recognize the importance of property rights in the process of economic development, and modern mainstream economics agree with such a recognition.[25] Locke supposed that one's labour was their own property and, consequently, property was any land maintained and sustained through one's own labour as long as there was sufficient and similar quality land to meet the needs of everyone's labour.[26][27] Using this ideology, property in a broader sense would be taken as any good a person produced or maintains with their own labour. This was later elaborated on by Smith, who believed that the amount of labour it takes to produce a good does not provide its value but instead the labour the good commands or the value of goods people will be willing to trade for the good.[28] He felt the division of labour to produce products for others was better for the whole of society.[29] This was later critiqued by Marx.[27]

Sanford Grossman, Oliver Hart, and John Hardman Moore developed the property rights approach to the theory of the firm based on the paradigm of incomplete contracts. These authors argue that in the real world, contracts are incomplete and hence it is impossible to contractually specify what decisions will have to be taken in any conceivable state of the world.[30][31] There will be renegotiations in the future, so parties have insufficient investment incentives (since they will only get a fraction of the investment's return in future negotiations); i.e., there is a hold-up problem.[30][31] Hence, they argue property rights matter because they determine who has control over future decisions if no agreement will be reached. In other words, property rights determine the parties' future bargaining positions (while their bargaining powers, i.e. their fractions of the renegotiation surplus, are independent of the property rights allocation).[32] The property rights approach to the theory of the firm can thus explain pros and cons of integration in the context of private firms. Yet, it has also been applied in various other frameworks such as public good provision and privatization.[33][34] The property rights approach has been extended in many directions. For instance, some authors have studied different bargaining solutions,[35][36] while other authors have studied the role of asymmetric information.[37]

Three important criteria for efficiency of property rights are

(1) universality—all scarce resources are owned by someone;

(2) exclusivity—property rights are exclusive rights;

(3) transferability—to ensure that resources can be allocated from low to high yield uses

— Joseph Mahoney, Economic Foundations of Strategy, pg 109

Benefits of implementing property rights

Opportunism is discouraged as it is harder to exploit a good protected by enforced property rights.[38] For example, a song can be easily pirated from purchased copies and, with no punishment, this form of the free-rider problem likely occurs. This causes the price mechanism to be less effective at finding the true market equilibrium and hurts the owners of the good who did not get it through opportunism.[39]

The moral hazard is less likely to influence the actions of consumers, meaning they will be less likely to exploit resources unsustainably or inefficiently as property is protected.[40] This will lead to a lower group cost overall as people will not be able to exploit these resources as easily, causing less inefficiency issues. For example, if a person's car doesn't have property rights, people will be more likely to mistreat it or steal it for a drive, as there is no real repercussions for doing so.

Property rights are also believed to lower transaction costs by providing an efficient resolution for conflicts over scarce resources.[41] Empirically, using historical data of former European colonies, Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson find substantial evidence that good economic institutions – those that provide secure property rights and equality of opportunity – lead to economic prosperity.[42]

Real-world interconnectivity

As a nation grows the necessity for a well-defined property rights grows as well.[43] This is due to the underlying assumption that within property rights other people must be present in order to have the rights over somebody else. Additionally, property rights are foundational for a capitalist system, allowing for growth and wealth creation.[44]

North, Wallis and Weingast argue that property rights originate to facilitate elites' rent-seeking activities.[45] Particularly, the legal and political systems that protect elites' claims on rent revenues form the basis of the so-called "limited access order", in which non-elites are denied access to political power and economic privileges. In a historical study of medieval England, for instance, North and Thomas find that the dramatic development of English land laws in the 13th century resulted from elites' interests in exploiting rent revenues from land ownership after a sudden rise in land price in the 12th century. In contrast, the modern "open access order", which consists of a democratic political system and a free- market economy, usually features widespread, secure and impersonal property rights.[46] Universal property rights, along with impersonal economic and political competition, downplay the role of rent-seeking and instead favor innovations and productive activities in a modern economy.

Further literature

In 2013, researchers produced an annotated bibliography on the property rights literature concerned with two principal outcomes: (a) reduction in investors risk and increase in incentives to invest, and (b) improvements in household welfare; the researchers explored the channels through which property rights affect growth and household welfare in developing countries. They found that better protection of property rights can affect several development outcomes, including better management of natural resources.[47]

Incomplete property rights allow agents with valuation lower than that of the original owners of economic value to inefficiently expropriate them distorting in this way their investment and effort exertion decisions. When instead, the state is entrusted the power to protect property, it might directly expropriate private parties if not sufficiently constrained by an efficient political process.[48] The necessity of strong protection of property for efficiency has been however criticized by a vast legal scholarship, originated from the seminal contribution by Guido Calabresi and Douglas Melamed.[49]

Calabresi and Melamed argue that in the face of transaction costs sufficiently sizeable to prevent consensual trade, legalized private expropriation in the form of, for instance, liability rules can be welfare-increasing. To elaborate, when property is fully protected, some agents with valuation higher than that of the original owners will be unable to legally acquire value because of sizable transaction costs. When the protection of property is weak instead, low-valuation potential buyers inefficiently expropriate original owners. Hence, a rise in the heterogeneity of the potential buyers' valuations makes inefficient expropriation by low-valuation potential buyers be more important from a social welfare point of view than inefficient exclusion from trade and so induces stronger property rights. Crucially, this prediction survives even after considering production and investment activities and it is consistent with a novel dataset on the rules on the acquisition of ownership through adverse possession and on the use of government takings to transfer real property from a private party to another private party prevailing in 126 jurisdictions. These data measure "horizontal property rights" and thus the extent of protection of property from "direct and indirect private takings", which are ubiquitous forms of expropriation that occur daily within the rule of law and are thus different from predation by the state and the elites, which is much less common but has been the focus of the economics literature.[49] To capture preference diversity, the author uses the contemporary genetic diversity, which is a primitive metric of the genealogical distance between populations with a common ancestor and so of the differences in characteristics transmitted across generations, such as preferences.[50] Regression analysis reveals that the protection of the original owners' property rights is the strongest where contemporary genetic diversity is the largest. Evidence from several different identification strategies suggests that this relationship is indeed causal.[50]

See also

References

  1. ^ Alchian, Armen A. "Property Rights". New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition (2008). A property right is a socially enforced right to select uses of an economic good.
  2. ^ Alchian, Armen A. (2008). . In David R. Henderson (ed.). Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (2nd ed.). Indianapolis: Library of Economics and Liberty. ISBN 978-0-86597-665-8. OCLC 237794267. Archived from the original on 2007-04-09.
  3. ^ "Economics Glossary". Retrieved 2007-01-28.
  4. ^ Thrainn Eggertsson (1990). Economic behavior and institutions. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-34891-1.
  5. ^ Dean Lueck (2008). "property law, economics and," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
  6. ^ Klein, Daniel B. and John Robinson. "Property: A Bundle of Rights? Prologue to the Symposium." Econ Journal Watch 8(3): 193–204, September 2011
  7. ^ Cole, Daniel H.; Grossman, Peter Z. (2002-08-01). "The Meaning of Property Rights: Law versus Economics?". Land Economics. 78 (3): 317–330. doi:10.2307/3146892. ISSN 0023-7639. JSTOR 3146892. S2CID 219193822.
  8. ^ a b Alchian, Armen A. (2018), "Property Rights", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 10892–10897, doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1814, ISBN 978-1-349-95189-5, retrieved 2021-04-26
  9. ^ a b Sandmo, Agnar (1989), Eatwell, John; Milgate, Murray; Newman, Peter (eds.), "Public Goods", Allocation, Information and Markets, The New Palgrave, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 254–266, doi:10.1007/978-1-349-20215-7_26, ISBN 978-1-349-20215-7, retrieved 2021-04-26
  10. ^ Ostrom, Elinor; Hess, Charlotte (2007-11-29). "Private and Common Property Rights". Rochester, NY. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1936062. hdl:10535/3985. S2CID 219365334. SSRN 1936062. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  11. ^ a b "Environmental and economy: property rights and public policy : Daniel W. Bromley, (Blackwell, Cambridge, MA and Oxford, U.K., 1991) pp. xi + 247". Journal of Development Economics. 42 (2): 417–419. 1993-12-01. doi:10.1016/0304-3878(93)90030-Q. ISSN 0304-3878.
  12. ^ Platteau, Jean-Philippe (2018), "Common Property Resources", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 1868–1871, doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2085, ISBN 978-1-349-95189-5, retrieved 2021-04-26
  13. ^ Snidal, Duncan (1979-12-01). "Public Goods, Property Rights, and Political Organizations". International Studies Quarterly. 23 (4): 532–566. doi:10.2307/2600328. ISSN 0020-8833. JSTOR 2600328.
  14. ^ Lueck, Dean (2018), "Property Law, Economics and", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 10883–10891, doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2225, ISBN 978-1-349-95189-5, retrieved 2021-04-26
  15. ^ a b c T., Mahoney, Joseph (2005). Economic foundations of strategy. Sage. ISBN 1-4129-0542-7. OCLC 492090732.
  16. ^ Buchanan, James M (1965). "An Economic Theory of Clubs". Economica. 32 (125): 1–14. doi:10.2307/2552442. JSTOR 2552442.
  17. ^ a b c Guerin, K. (2003). Property Rights and Environmental Policy: A New Zealand Perspective. Wellington, New Zealand: NZ Treasury
  18. ^ Demsetz, Harold (1967). ""Toward a Theory of Property Rights."" (PDF). The American Economic Review. 57: 347–359.
  19. ^ Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon; Robinson, James (2005). "Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth". Handbook of Economic Growth. 1: 397.
  20. ^ See literature on post-regulatory approaches and reflexive law, especially literature from Gunther Teubner. See also the example of the 'conservation property right'
  21. ^ Barzel, Yoram (April 1982). "Measurement Costs and the Organization of Markets". Journal of Law and Economics. 25 (1): 27–48. doi:10.1086/467005. ISSN 0022-2186. JSTOR 725223. S2CID 154409748.
  22. ^ Douglas Allen (1991). What are Transaction Costs? (Research in Law and Economics). Jai Pr. ISBN 978-0-7623-1115-6.
  23. ^ Coase, R. H. (1937). "The Nature of the Firm". Economica. 4 (16): 386–405. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0335.1937.tb00002.x. ISSN 1468-0335.
  24. ^ Coase, Ronald H. (2005), "The Institutional Structure of Production", Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag, pp. 31–39, doi:10.1007/0-387-25092-1_3, ISBN 1-4020-2687-0, retrieved 2021-04-28
  25. ^ Besley, Timothy; Maitreesh, Ghatak (2009). Rodrik, Dani; Rosenzweig, Mark R (eds.). "Property Rights and Economic Development". Handbook of Development Economics. V: 4526–28.
  26. ^ Locke, John (1690-01-01), Nidditch, Peter H (ed.), "An Essay concerning Human Understanding", The Clarendon Edition of the Works of John Locke: An Essay Concerning Human Understanding, Oxford University Press, p. 1, doi:10.1093/oseo/instance.00018020, ISBN 978-0-19-824386-1, retrieved 2021-04-28
  27. ^ a b "John Locke, Adam Smith and Karl Marx's Critique of Private Property", On the Formation of Marxism, BRILL, pp. 225–251, 2016-01-01, doi:10.1163/9789004306653_017, ISBN 978-90-04-30665-3
  28. ^ Smith, Adam. The wealth of nations. ISBN 979-12-80067-94-4. OCLC 1199365622.
  29. ^ "Material Wealth and Psychological Wealth of Nations", The Psychological Wealth of Nations, Oxford, UK: Wiley-Blackwell, pp. 145–158, 2012-04-11, doi:10.1002/9781444354447.ch10, ISBN 978-1-4443-5444-7, retrieved 2021-04-28
  30. ^ a b Grossman, Sanford J.; Hart, Oliver D. (1986). "The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration". Journal of Political Economy. 94 (4): 691–719. doi:10.1086/261404. hdl:1721.1/63378. ISSN 0022-3808.
  31. ^ a b Hart, Oliver; Moore, John (1990). "Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm". Journal of Political Economy. 98 (6): 1119–1158. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.472.9089. doi:10.1086/261729. ISSN 0022-3808. S2CID 15892859.
  32. ^ Schmitz, Patrick W. (2013). "Bargaining position, bargaining power, and the property rights approach" (PDF). Economics Letters. 119 (1): 28–31. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2013.01.011. S2CID 54953889.
  33. ^ Hart, Oliver; Shleifer, Andrei; Vishny, Robert W. (1997). "The Proper Scope of Government: Theory and an Application to Prisons". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 112 (4): 1127–1161. doi:10.1162/003355300555448. ISSN 0033-5533. S2CID 16270301.
  34. ^ Hoppe, Eva I.; Schmitz, Patrick W. (2010). "Public versus private ownership: Quantity contracts and the allocation of investment tasks". Journal of Public Economics. 94 (3–4): 258–268. doi:10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.11.009.
  35. ^ Meza, David de; Lockwood, Ben (1998). "Does Asset Ownership Always Motivate Managers? Outside Options and the Property Rights Theory of the Firm". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 113 (2): 361–386. doi:10.1162/003355398555621. ISSN 0033-5533.
  36. ^ Chiu, Y. Stephen (1998). "Noncooperative Bargaining, Hostages, and Optimal Asset Ownership". The American Economic Review. 88 (4): 882–901. JSTOR 117010.
  37. ^ Schmitz, Patrick W (2006). "Information Gathering, Transaction Costs, and the Property Rights Approach". American Economic Review. 96 (1): 422–434. doi:10.1257/000282806776157722. S2CID 154717219.
  38. ^ "Property rights | Economics Online | Economics Online". 2020-01-17. Retrieved 2021-04-26.
  39. ^ Yoram., Barzel (1997). Economic analysis of property rights. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 0-521-59275-5. OCLC 863296486.
  40. ^ Libecap, Gary D., ed. (1990), "Concluding remarks", Contracting for Property Rights, Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 115–121, doi:10.1017/cbo9780511664120.008, ISBN 978-0-521-44904-5, retrieved 2021-04-26
  41. ^ Alchian, Armen; Demsetz, Harold (1973). "The Property Right Paradigm". The Journal of Economic History. 33 (1): 16–27. doi:10.1017/S0022050700076403. S2CID 153392930.
  42. ^ Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon; Robinson, James (2005). "Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth". Handbook of Economic Growth. Vol. 1. pp. 385–472. ISBN 9780444520418.
  43. ^ Alchian, Armen A (1965). "Some Economics of Property Rights". II Politico. 30 (4): 816–829.
  44. ^ Demsetz, Harold (1967). "Toward a Theory of Property Rights". American Economic Association. 57: 347–359.
  45. ^ North, Douglass C; Wallis, John J; Weingast, Barry R (2006). "A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history". National Bureau of Economic Research. 12795: 32–33.
  46. ^ North, Douglass C; Wallis, John J; Weingast, Barry R (2009). "Violence and the Rise of Open-Access Orders". Journal of Democracy. 20 (1): 55–68. doi:10.1353/jod.0.0060. S2CID 153774943.
  47. ^ Mike Denison and Robyn Klingler-Vidra, October 2012, Annotated Bibliography for Rapid Review on Property Rights, Economics and Private Sector Professional Evidence and Applied Knowledge Services (EPS PEAKS)https://partnerplatform.org/?tcafmd80
  48. ^ Besley, Timothy, and Maitreesh Ghatak (2010). Handbook of Development Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier. pp. 4525–4595.
  49. ^ a b Calabresi, Guido, and Melamed, A. Douglas (1972). "Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral". Harvard Law Review. 85 (6): 1089–1128. doi:10.2307/1340059. JSTOR 1340059.
  50. ^ a b Menozzi, Paolo; Piazza, Alberto; Cavalli-Sforza, L. Luca (1994). The History and Geography of Human Genes. Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 9780691187266.

property, rights, economics, property, rights, constructs, economics, determining, resource, economic, good, used, owned, which, have, developed, over, ancient, modern, history, from, abrahamic, article, universal, declaration, human, rights, resources, owned,. Property rights are constructs in economics for determining how a resource or economic good is used and owned 1 which have developed over ancient and modern history from Abrahamic law to Article 17 of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights Resources can be owned by and hence be the property of individuals associations collectives or governments 2 Property rights can be viewed as an attribute of an economic good This attribute has three broad components 3 4 5 and is often referred to as a bundle of rights in the United States 6 the right to use the good the right to earn income from the good the right to transfer the good to others alter it abandon it or destroy it the right to ownership cessation Contents 1 Conceptualizing property in economics vs law 1 1 Types of property regimes 2 Property rights theory 2 1 Introduction 2 2 Exploration 2 3 Benefits of implementing property rights 2 4 Real world interconnectivity 3 Further literature 4 See also 5 ReferencesConceptualizing property in economics vs law EditThe fields of economics and law do not have a general consensus on conceptions of property rights 7 Various property types are used in law but the terminology can be seen in economic reports Sometimes in economics property types are simply described as private or public common in reference to private goods excludable and rivalrous goods like a phone 8 as well as public goods non excludable and non rivalrous goods like air 9 respectively 10 Below is a list of the several property types defined and their relation to the economic concepts of excludability the ability to limit the consumption of the good and rivalry a person s consumption of the good reduces the ability of another to consume it Types of property regimes Edit Property rights can be categorized with excludability and rivalry Excludability describes the characteristic regarding whether a good can be withheld from certain consumers In terms of the same good rivalry describes its accessibility to competing consumers The combination of excludability and rivalry as parameters is reflected through various types of property rights Open access property is owned by nobody res nullius 11 It is non excludable as excluding people is either impossible or prohibitively costly and can be rivalrous or non rivalrous Open access property is not managed by anyone and access to it is not controlled This is also known as a common property resource impure public good or a common pool resource 12 Examples of this can be air water sights and sounds Tragedy of the commons refers to this title An example would be unregulated forests as there s limited resources available and therefore rivalrous but anyone may access these resources If non rivalrous it would be a public good cannot be rivalrous no matter how much it is used for example the ocean outside of territorial borders 9 Open access property may exist because ownership has never been established granted by laws within a particular country or because no effective controls are in place or feasible i e the cost of exclusivity outweighs the benefits Encyclopedia of Law and Economics Public property also known as state property is excludable and can be rivalrous or non rivalrous 13 This type of property is publicly owned but its access and use are managed and controlled by a government agency or organization granted such authority 14 For example a government pavement is non excludable as anyone may use it but rivalrous as the more people using it the more likely it will be too crowded for another to join Public property is sometimes used interchangeably with public good 15 usually impure public goods They may also be a club good which is excludable and non rivalrous 16 An example would be paying to go to an uncongested public bathroom as the price excludes those who can t afford it but there is ample utilities for more people to use making it non rivalrous Private property is both excludable and rivalrous Private property access use exclusion and management are controlled by the private owner or a group of legal owners 8 This is sometimes used interchangeably with private good 15 An example would be a cellphone as it only one person may use it making it rivalrous and it has to be purchased which makes it excludable Common property or collective property is excludable and rivalrous Not to be confused with common property in reference to economics this is in reference to law It is property that is owned by a group of individuals where access use and exclusion are controlled by the joint owners 17 11 Unlike private property common property has multiple owners which allows for a greater ability to manage conflicts through shared benefits and enforcement This would still be related to private goods An example of common property would be any private good that is jointly owned Property rights theory EditIntroduction Edit Property rights theory is an exploration of how providing stakeholders with ownership of any factors of production or goods not just land will increase the efficiency of an economy as the gains from providing the rights exceed the costs 18 A widely accepted explanation is that well enforced property rights provide incentives for individuals to participate in economic activities such as investment innovation and trade which lead to a more efficient market 19 Implicit or explicit property rights can be created through government regulation in the market either through prescriptive command and control approaches e g limits on input output discharge quantities specified processes equipment audits or by market based instruments e g taxes transferable permits or quotas 17 and more recently through cooperative self regulatory post regulatory and reflexive law approaches 20 In economics depending on the level of transaction costs various forms of property rights institutions will develop 15 In economics an institution is defined thusly a complex of positions roles norms and values lodged in particular types of social structures and organising relatively stable patterns of human activity with respect to fundamental problems in producing life sustaining resources in reproducing individuals and in sustaining viable societal structures within a given environment Johnathon Turner The Institutional Order For specificity in the case of economic property rights this is a system or structure that has value and stability Transaction costs are the costs of defining monitoring and enforcing property rights 21 22 Exploration Edit Ronald Coase proposed that clearly defining and assigning property rights would resolve environmental problems by internalizing externalities and rely on incentives of private owners to conserve resources for the future 23 He asserts transaction costs are ideally zero because they cause inefficiencies due to those who would be allocatively efficient with the ownership being unable to afford or receiving less private benefit than they gain from it as the transaction costs on top of the cost of purchasing and maintaining the property 24 This is known as Coase theorem Critics of this view argue that this assumes that it is possible to internalize all environmental benefits that owners will have perfect information that scale economies are manageable transaction costs are bearable and that legal frameworks operate efficiently 17 John Locke Adam Smith and Karl Marx are classical economists that generally recognize the importance of property rights in the process of economic development and modern mainstream economics agree with such a recognition 25 Locke supposed that one s labour was their own property and consequently property was any land maintained and sustained through one s own labour as long as there was sufficient and similar quality land to meet the needs of everyone s labour 26 27 Using this ideology property in a broader sense would be taken as any good a person produced or maintains with their own labour This was later elaborated on by Smith who believed that the amount of labour it takes to produce a good does not provide its value but instead the labour the good commands or the value of goods people will be willing to trade for the good 28 He felt the division of labour to produce products for others was better for the whole of society 29 This was later critiqued by Marx 27 Sanford Grossman Oliver Hart and John Hardman Moore developed the property rights approach to the theory of the firm based on the paradigm of incomplete contracts These authors argue that in the real world contracts are incomplete and hence it is impossible to contractually specify what decisions will have to be taken in any conceivable state of the world 30 31 There will be renegotiations in the future so parties have insufficient investment incentives since they will only get a fraction of the investment s return in future negotiations i e there is a hold up problem 30 31 Hence they argue property rights matter because they determine who has control over future decisions if no agreement will be reached In other words property rights determine the parties future bargaining positions while their bargaining powers i e their fractions of the renegotiation surplus are independent of the property rights allocation 32 The property rights approach to the theory of the firm can thus explain pros and cons of integration in the context of private firms Yet it has also been applied in various other frameworks such as public good provision and privatization 33 34 The property rights approach has been extended in many directions For instance some authors have studied different bargaining solutions 35 36 while other authors have studied the role of asymmetric information 37 Three important criteria for efficiency of property rights are 1 universality all scarce resources are owned by someone 2 exclusivity property rights are exclusive rights 3 transferability to ensure that resources can be allocated from low to high yield uses Joseph Mahoney Economic Foundations of Strategy pg 109 Benefits of implementing property rights Edit Opportunism is discouraged as it is harder to exploit a good protected by enforced property rights 38 For example a song can be easily pirated from purchased copies and with no punishment this form of the free rider problem likely occurs This causes the price mechanism to be less effective at finding the true market equilibrium and hurts the owners of the good who did not get it through opportunism 39 The moral hazard is less likely to influence the actions of consumers meaning they will be less likely to exploit resources unsustainably or inefficiently as property is protected 40 This will lead to a lower group cost overall as people will not be able to exploit these resources as easily causing less inefficiency issues For example if a person s car doesn t have property rights people will be more likely to mistreat it or steal it for a drive as there is no real repercussions for doing so Property rights are also believed to lower transaction costs by providing an efficient resolution for conflicts over scarce resources 41 Empirically using historical data of former European colonies Acemoglu Johnson and Robinson find substantial evidence that good economic institutions those that provide secure property rights and equality of opportunity lead to economic prosperity 42 Real world interconnectivity Edit As a nation grows the necessity for a well defined property rights grows as well 43 This is due to the underlying assumption that within property rights other people must be present in order to have the rights over somebody else Additionally property rights are foundational for a capitalist system allowing for growth and wealth creation 44 North Wallis and Weingast argue that property rights originate to facilitate elites rent seeking activities 45 Particularly the legal and political systems that protect elites claims on rent revenues form the basis of the so called limited access order in which non elites are denied access to political power and economic privileges In a historical study of medieval England for instance North and Thomas find that the dramatic development of English land laws in the 13th century resulted from elites interests in exploiting rent revenues from land ownership after a sudden rise in land price in the 12th century In contrast the modern open access order which consists of a democratic political system and a free market economy usually features widespread secure and impersonal property rights 46 Universal property rights along with impersonal economic and political competition downplay the role of rent seeking and instead favor innovations and productive activities in a modern economy Further literature EditThis section may contain an excessive amount of intricate detail that may interest only a particular audience Please help by spinning off or relocating any relevant information and removing excessive detail that may be against Wikipedia s inclusion policy November 2021 Learn how and when to remove this template message In 2013 researchers produced an annotated bibliography on the property rights literature concerned with two principal outcomes a reduction in investors risk and increase in incentives to invest and b improvements in household welfare the researchers explored the channels through which property rights affect growth and household welfare in developing countries They found that better protection of property rights can affect several development outcomes including better management of natural resources 47 Incomplete property rights allow agents with valuation lower than that of the original owners of economic value to inefficiently expropriate them distorting in this way their investment and effort exertion decisions When instead the state is entrusted the power to protect property it might directly expropriate private parties if not sufficiently constrained by an efficient political process 48 The necessity of strong protection of property for efficiency has been however criticized by a vast legal scholarship originated from the seminal contribution by Guido Calabresi and Douglas Melamed 49 Calabresi and Melamed argue that in the face of transaction costs sufficiently sizeable to prevent consensual trade legalized private expropriation in the form of for instance liability rules can be welfare increasing To elaborate when property is fully protected some agents with valuation higher than that of the original owners will be unable to legally acquire value because of sizable transaction costs When the protection of property is weak instead low valuation potential buyers inefficiently expropriate original owners Hence a rise in the heterogeneity of the potential buyers valuations makes inefficient expropriation by low valuation potential buyers be more important from a social welfare point of view than inefficient exclusion from trade and so induces stronger property rights Crucially this prediction survives even after considering production and investment activities and it is consistent with a novel dataset on the rules on the acquisition of ownership through adverse possession and on the use of government takings to transfer real property from a private party to another private party prevailing in 126 jurisdictions These data measure horizontal property rights and thus the extent of protection of property from direct and indirect private takings which are ubiquitous forms of expropriation that occur daily within the rule of law and are thus different from predation by the state and the elites which is much less common but has been the focus of the economics literature 49 To capture preference diversity the author uses the contemporary genetic diversity which is a primitive metric of the genealogical distance between populations with a common ancestor and so of the differences in characteristics transmitted across generations such as preferences 50 Regression analysis reveals that the protection of the original owners property rights is the strongest where contemporary genetic diversity is the largest Evidence from several different identification strategies suggests that this relationship is indeed causal 50 See also EditAlienation property law Bundle of rights Common ownership Commons Economic system Intellectual property Land tenure Land titling Law and economics Means of production Natural and legal rights Open access Personal property Public property Private property Property income Right to property Social ownership State ownership Taxation as theftReferences Edit Alchian Armen A Property Rights New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Second Edition 2008 A property right is a socially enforced right to select uses of an economic good Alchian Armen A 2008 Property Rights In David R Henderson ed Concise Encyclopedia of Economics 2nd ed Indianapolis Library of Economics and Liberty ISBN 978 0 86597 665 8 OCLC 237794267 Archived from the original on 2007 04 09 Economics Glossary Retrieved 2007 01 28 Thrainn Eggertsson 1990 Economic behavior and institutions Cambridge UK Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 34891 1 Dean Lueck 2008 property law economics and The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Klein Daniel B and John Robinson Property A Bundle of Rights Prologue to the Symposium Econ Journal Watch 8 3 193 204 September 2011 Cole Daniel H Grossman Peter Z 2002 08 01 The Meaning of Property Rights Law versus Economics Land Economics 78 3 317 330 doi 10 2307 3146892 ISSN 0023 7639 JSTOR 3146892 S2CID 219193822 a b Alchian Armen A 2018 Property Rights The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics London Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 10892 10897 doi 10 1057 978 1 349 95189 5 1814 ISBN 978 1 349 95189 5 retrieved 2021 04 26 a b Sandmo Agnar 1989 Eatwell John Milgate Murray Newman Peter eds Public Goods Allocation Information and Markets The New Palgrave London Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 254 266 doi 10 1007 978 1 349 20215 7 26 ISBN 978 1 349 20215 7 retrieved 2021 04 26 Ostrom Elinor Hess Charlotte 2007 11 29 Private and Common Property Rights Rochester NY doi 10 2139 ssrn 1936062 hdl 10535 3985 S2CID 219365334 SSRN 1936062 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help a b Environmental and economy property rights and public policy Daniel W Bromley Blackwell Cambridge MA and Oxford U K 1991 pp xi 247 Journal of Development Economics 42 2 417 419 1993 12 01 doi 10 1016 0304 3878 93 90030 Q ISSN 0304 3878 Platteau Jean Philippe 2018 Common Property Resources The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics London Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 1868 1871 doi 10 1057 978 1 349 95189 5 2085 ISBN 978 1 349 95189 5 retrieved 2021 04 26 Snidal Duncan 1979 12 01 Public Goods Property Rights and Political Organizations International Studies Quarterly 23 4 532 566 doi 10 2307 2600328 ISSN 0020 8833 JSTOR 2600328 Lueck Dean 2018 Property Law Economics and The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics London Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 10883 10891 doi 10 1057 978 1 349 95189 5 2225 ISBN 978 1 349 95189 5 retrieved 2021 04 26 a b c T Mahoney Joseph 2005 Economic foundations of strategy Sage ISBN 1 4129 0542 7 OCLC 492090732 Buchanan James M 1965 An Economic Theory of Clubs Economica 32 125 1 14 doi 10 2307 2552442 JSTOR 2552442 a b c Guerin K 2003 Property Rights and Environmental Policy A New Zealand Perspective Wellington New Zealand NZ Treasury Demsetz Harold 1967 Toward a Theory of Property Rights PDF The American Economic Review 57 347 359 Acemoglu Daron Johnson Simon Robinson James 2005 Institutions as a fundamental cause of long run growth Handbook of Economic Growth 1 397 See literature on post regulatory approaches and reflexive law especially literature from Gunther Teubner See also the example of the conservation property right Barzel Yoram April 1982 Measurement Costs and the Organization of Markets Journal of Law and Economics 25 1 27 48 doi 10 1086 467005 ISSN 0022 2186 JSTOR 725223 S2CID 154409748 Douglas Allen 1991 What are Transaction Costs Research in Law and Economics Jai Pr ISBN 978 0 7623 1115 6 Coase R H 1937 The Nature of the Firm Economica 4 16 386 405 doi 10 1111 j 1468 0335 1937 tb00002 x ISSN 1468 0335 Coase Ronald H 2005 The Institutional Structure of Production Handbook of New Institutional Economics Berlin Heidelberg Springer Verlag pp 31 39 doi 10 1007 0 387 25092 1 3 ISBN 1 4020 2687 0 retrieved 2021 04 28 Besley Timothy Maitreesh Ghatak 2009 Rodrik Dani Rosenzweig Mark R eds Property Rights and Economic Development Handbook of Development Economics V 4526 28 Locke John 1690 01 01 Nidditch Peter H ed An Essay concerning Human Understanding The Clarendon Edition of the Works of John Locke An Essay Concerning Human Understanding Oxford University Press p 1 doi 10 1093 oseo instance 00018020 ISBN 978 0 19 824386 1 retrieved 2021 04 28 a b John Locke Adam Smith and Karl Marx s Critique of Private Property On the Formation of Marxism BRILL pp 225 251 2016 01 01 doi 10 1163 9789004306653 017 ISBN 978 90 04 30665 3 Smith Adam The wealth of nations ISBN 979 12 80067 94 4 OCLC 1199365622 Material Wealth and Psychological Wealth of Nations The Psychological Wealth of Nations Oxford UK Wiley Blackwell pp 145 158 2012 04 11 doi 10 1002 9781444354447 ch10 ISBN 978 1 4443 5444 7 retrieved 2021 04 28 a b Grossman Sanford J Hart Oliver D 1986 The Costs and Benefits of Ownership A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration Journal of Political Economy 94 4 691 719 doi 10 1086 261404 hdl 1721 1 63378 ISSN 0022 3808 a b Hart Oliver Moore John 1990 Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm Journal of Political Economy 98 6 1119 1158 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 472 9089 doi 10 1086 261729 ISSN 0022 3808 S2CID 15892859 Schmitz Patrick W 2013 Bargaining position bargaining power and the property rights approach PDF Economics Letters 119 1 28 31 doi 10 1016 j econlet 2013 01 011 S2CID 54953889 Hart Oliver Shleifer Andrei Vishny Robert W 1997 The Proper Scope of Government Theory and an Application to Prisons The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 4 1127 1161 doi 10 1162 003355300555448 ISSN 0033 5533 S2CID 16270301 Hoppe Eva I Schmitz Patrick W 2010 Public versus private ownership Quantity contracts and the allocation of investment tasks Journal of Public Economics 94 3 4 258 268 doi 10 1016 j jpubeco 2009 11 009 Meza David de Lockwood Ben 1998 Does Asset Ownership Always Motivate Managers Outside Options and the Property Rights Theory of the Firm The Quarterly Journal of Economics 113 2 361 386 doi 10 1162 003355398555621 ISSN 0033 5533 Chiu Y Stephen 1998 Noncooperative Bargaining Hostages and Optimal Asset Ownership The American Economic Review 88 4 882 901 JSTOR 117010 Schmitz Patrick W 2006 Information Gathering Transaction Costs and the Property Rights Approach American Economic Review 96 1 422 434 doi 10 1257 000282806776157722 S2CID 154717219 Property rights Economics Online Economics Online 2020 01 17 Retrieved 2021 04 26 Yoram Barzel 1997 Economic analysis of property rights Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 59275 5 OCLC 863296486 Libecap Gary D ed 1990 Concluding remarks Contracting for Property Rights Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions Cambridge Cambridge University Press pp 115 121 doi 10 1017 cbo9780511664120 008 ISBN 978 0 521 44904 5 retrieved 2021 04 26 Alchian Armen Demsetz Harold 1973 The Property Right Paradigm The Journal of Economic History 33 1 16 27 doi 10 1017 S0022050700076403 S2CID 153392930 Acemoglu Daron Johnson Simon Robinson James 2005 Institutions as a fundamental cause of long run growth Handbook of Economic Growth Vol 1 pp 385 472 ISBN 9780444520418 Alchian Armen A 1965 Some Economics of Property Rights II Politico 30 4 816 829 Demsetz Harold 1967 Toward a Theory of Property Rights American Economic Association 57 347 359 North Douglass C Wallis John J Weingast Barry R 2006 A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history National Bureau of Economic Research 12795 32 33 North Douglass C Wallis John J Weingast Barry R 2009 Violence and the Rise of Open Access Orders Journal of Democracy 20 1 55 68 doi 10 1353 jod 0 0060 S2CID 153774943 Mike Denison and Robyn Klingler Vidra October 2012 Annotated Bibliography for Rapid Review on Property Rights Economics and Private Sector Professional Evidence and Applied Knowledge Services EPS PEAKS https partnerplatform org tcafmd80 Besley Timothy and Maitreesh Ghatak 2010 Handbook of Development Economics Amsterdam Elsevier pp 4525 4595 a b Calabresi Guido and Melamed A Douglas 1972 Property Rules Liability Rules and Inalienability One View of the Cathedral Harvard Law Review 85 6 1089 1128 doi 10 2307 1340059 JSTOR 1340059 a b Menozzi Paolo Piazza Alberto Cavalli Sforza L Luca 1994 The History and Geography of Human Genes Princeton Princeton University Press ISBN 9780691187266 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Property rights economics amp oldid 1132488261, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.