fbpx
Wikipedia

The Problem of Social Cost

The Problem of Social Cost (1960) is a law review article by Ronald Coase, then a faculty member at the University of Virginia, dealing with the economic problem of externalities. It draws from a number of English legal cases and statutes to illustrate Coase's belief that legal rules are only justified by reference to a cost–benefit analysis, and that nuisances that are often regarded as being the fault of one party are more symmetric conflicts between the interests of the two parties. If there are sufficiently low costs of doing a transaction, legal rules would be irrelevant to the maximization of production. Because in the real world there are costs of bargaining and information gathering, legal rules are justified to the extent of their ability to allocate rights to the most efficient right-bearer.

Along with an earlier article, “The Nature of the Firm”, "The Problem of Social Cost" was cited by the Nobel committee when Coase was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1991. The article is foundational to the field of law and economics, and has become the most frequently cited work in all of legal scholarship.[1]

Summary edit

Coase argued that if we lived in a world without transaction costs, people would bargain with one another to produce the most efficient distribution of resources, regardless of the initial allocation. This is superior to allocation through litigation.[2] Coase used the example of a nuisance case named Sturges v Bridgman, where a noisy sweetmaker and a quiet doctor were neighbours and went to court to see who should have to move.[3] Coase said that regardless of whether the judge ruled that the sweetmaker had to stop using his machinery, or that the doctor had to put up with it, they could strike a mutually beneficial bargain about who moves that reaches the same outcome of productive activity.

However, many welfare-maximizing reallocations are often forgone because of the transaction costs involved in bargaining.[4] For instance, the sweetmaker may have many neighbors who claim "nuisance" — some legitimate and some not, that the firm would have to sort through, and some of those neighbors who do claim nuisance may try to hold out for excessive compensation. In these cases, the transaction costs eat away, and ultimately eclipse, the price signals that would have led to the most efficient distribution of resources.[citation needed]

In cases like these with potentially high transaction costs, the law ought to produce an outcome similar to what would result if the transaction costs were eliminated. However, there is no cost-effective method of determining precisely what that outcome would be, by definition. So Coase argues that the courts should only intervene in cases that cause an unreasonable amount of nuisance after a wide analysis with regard to the total effect of such interventions.[2]

Additionally, Coase highlights reciprocity of harms present in externalities as a central question for distributing rights. Damage is shared between parties in a dispute, such that both parties consider the present costs in their optimization question. Coase uses the ruling of "Bryant v. Lefever" to explore the reciprocal nature of externality. Bryant v. Lefever concerns a conflict between neighbors, in which one neighbor constructed a wall such that the other neighbor’s chimney would smoke. Originally, the court determined the wall was the cause of the chimneys smoking and awarded the plaintiff financial compensation. However, in the Court of Appeals, this judgment was reversed. Coase argues that this judgment provides context for framing blame. According to Coase, “The smoke nuisance was caused both by the man who built the wall and by the man who lit the fires”.[5] Under this framework, the wall-builder is not legally liable for the nuisance suffered by his neighbor alone. In this example, Coase seeks to illuminate the conditions for optimizing the allocation of rights, the case in which both parties consider harmful. Here, Coase is referencing Pareto efficiency allowed by the prevailing “pricing system”.

Coase used the example of pollution (raised by George Stigler in The Theory of Price, 1952) several times: he argued that arbitrage between actors in a market with low transaction costs could lead to an efficient market solution.[6]

Coase extends this framework throughout his development of a functional theorem concerning externalities. Coase argues that these rights are integrated into an actor's decision-making process through their unique cost function. These costs are not isolated in nature, according to Coase, who concluded “The cost of exercising a right (of using a factor of production) is always the loss which is suffered elsewhere”[7]

The ultimate thesis is that law and regulation are not as important or effective at helping people as lawyers and government planners believe.[8] Coase and others like him wanted a change of approach, to put the burden of proof for positive effects on a government that was intervening in the market, by analysing the costs of the action.[9]


The argument forms the basis of the Coase Theorem as labeled by George Stigler.[citation needed]

Theoretical challenges edit

Guido Calabresi in his book The Costs of Accidents (1970)[10] argues that it is still efficient to hold companies liable that produce greater wealth.[11]

In the real world, where people cannot negotiate costlessly, there may be collective action problems of those who caused a nuisance, for instance by smoke emissions from a factory to many neighbouring farms, and so getting together to negotiate effectively can be difficult against a single polluter because of coordination problems. If it is efficient for the farmers to pay the factory to reduce its emissions, some of those farmers may hold off paying their fair share, hoping to get a free ride. The factory may be in a better position to know what measures to take to reduce harm, and can be the cheapest avoider, illustrating Coase's argument.

Cases and statutes edit

Coase uses three main examples in his article to attempt to illustrate his points. The first is a fictional cattle herder and a farmer, but the second is the case Sturges v Bridgman[12] and the third is the Railway (Fires) Act 1905.[13] Apart from these main examples, the following cases are referred to.

  • Fontainebleu Hotel Corp. v. Forty-Five Twenty-Five, Inc., 114 So. 2d 357 (1959)
  • Cooke v Forbes (1867–1868) LR 5 Eq 166[14]
  • Bryant v Lefever (1878–1879) 4 CPD 172, Bramwell LJ and Cotton LJ[15]
  • Bass v Gregory (1890) 25 QBD 481[16]
  • Attorney General v Doughty (1752) 28 ER 290[17]
  • Versailles Borough v. McKeesport Coal & Coke Co. (1935) 83 Pitts. Leg. J 379, 385
  • Webb v Bird (1863) 143 ER 332
  • Rushmer v Polsue and Alfieri, Ltd (1906) 1 Ch 234
  • Adams v Ursell (1913) 1 Ch 269, regarding fish and chips
  • Andreae v Selfridge and Company Ltd (1938) 1 Ch 1
  • Delta Air Corporation v. Kersey (1942) 193 Ga. 862
  • Thrasher v. City of Atlanta (1934) 178 Ga. 514
  • Georgia Railroad and Banking Co. v. Maddox (1902) 116 Ga. 64
  • Smith v. New England Aircraft Co. (1930) 270 Mass. 511
  • Vaughan v Taff Vale Railway Co. (1858) 3 H and N 743
  • Boulston v Hardy (1597) 77 ER 216
  • Stearn v Prentice Bros Ltd (1919) 1 KB 395
  • Bland v Yates (1913–1914) 58 Sol J 612

See also edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ Merrill & Smith (2017), p. 32.
  2. ^ a b (Coase 1960) page 44
  3. ^ Sturges v Bridgman (1879) 11 Ch D 852
  4. ^ (Coase 1960, p. IV, 7)
  5. ^ (Coase 1960, p. V, 11)
  6. ^ (Coase 1960) page 17
  7. ^ (Coase 1960, p. X, 44)
  8. ^ (Coase 1960, p. V, 9)
  9. ^ (Coase 1960, p. VIII, 23)
  10. ^ The Cost of Accidents (1970), 135–403
  11. ^ See also Calabresi, Guido (1968). "Transaction Costs, Resource Allocation and Liability Rules—A Comment". Journal of Law and Economics. 11 (1): 67–73 [p. 71–73]. doi:10.1086/466644. S2CID 3455654.
  12. ^ (1960) 3 JLE 1, 8-11, 20–21
  13. ^ (1960) 3 JLE 1, 30–34
  14. ^ (1960) 3 JLE 1, 10–11
  15. ^ (1960) 3 JLE 1, 11–12
  16. ^ (1960) 3 JLE 1, 14
  17. ^ (1960) 3 JLE 1, 20

References edit

  • Coase, Ronald (1960), "The Problem of Social Cost" (PDF), Journal of Law and Economics, 3 (Oct., 1960), The University of Chicago Press: 1–44, doi:10.1086/466560, S2CID 222331226.
  • RH Coase, 'The Nature of the Firm' (1937) 16(4) Economica 386–405.
  • Sir Alfred Denning, Freedom Under the Law (1949) 71.
  • E McGaughey, 'Behavioural Economics and Labour Law' (2014), LSE Legal Studies Working Paper No. 20/2014.
  • Merrill, Thomas W.; Smith, Henry E. (2017). Property: Principles and Policies. University Casebook Series (3rd ed.). St. Paul: Foundation Press. ISBN 978-1-62810-102-7.
  • AC Pigou, The Economics of Welfare (4th ed 1932).
  • Pierre Schlag, Coase Minus the Coase Theorem – Some Problems with Chicago Transaction Cost Analysis, 99 Iowa Law Review 175 (2013).
  • AWB Simpson, '"Coase v. Pigou" Reexamined' (1996). 25(1) The Journal of Legal Studies 53

External links edit

  • Nobel prize in Economics 1991 – Press release
  • His Autobiography
  • His page at the University of Chicago

problem, social, cost, 1960, review, article, ronald, coase, then, faculty, member, university, virginia, dealing, with, economic, problem, externalities, draws, from, number, english, legal, cases, statutes, illustrate, coase, belief, that, legal, rules, only. The Problem of Social Cost 1960 is a law review article by Ronald Coase then a faculty member at the University of Virginia dealing with the economic problem of externalities It draws from a number of English legal cases and statutes to illustrate Coase s belief that legal rules are only justified by reference to a cost benefit analysis and that nuisances that are often regarded as being the fault of one party are more symmetric conflicts between the interests of the two parties If there are sufficiently low costs of doing a transaction legal rules would be irrelevant to the maximization of production Because in the real world there are costs of bargaining and information gathering legal rules are justified to the extent of their ability to allocate rights to the most efficient right bearer Along with an earlier article The Nature of the Firm The Problem of Social Cost was cited by the Nobel committee when Coase was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1991 The article is foundational to the field of law and economics and has become the most frequently cited work in all of legal scholarship 1 Contents 1 Summary 2 Theoretical challenges 3 Cases and statutes 4 See also 5 Notes 6 References 7 External linksSummary editCoase argued that if we lived in a world without transaction costs people would bargain with one another to produce the most efficient distribution of resources regardless of the initial allocation This is superior to allocation through litigation 2 Coase used the example of a nuisance case named Sturges v Bridgman where a noisy sweetmaker and a quiet doctor were neighbours and went to court to see who should have to move 3 Coase said that regardless of whether the judge ruled that the sweetmaker had to stop using his machinery or that the doctor had to put up with it they could strike a mutually beneficial bargain about who moves that reaches the same outcome of productive activity However many welfare maximizing reallocations are often forgone because of the transaction costs involved in bargaining 4 For instance the sweetmaker may have many neighbors who claim nuisance some legitimate and some not that the firm would have to sort through and some of those neighbors who do claim nuisance may try to hold out for excessive compensation In these cases the transaction costs eat away and ultimately eclipse the price signals that would have led to the most efficient distribution of resources citation needed In cases like these with potentially high transaction costs the law ought to produce an outcome similar to what would result if the transaction costs were eliminated However there is no cost effective method of determining precisely what that outcome would be by definition So Coase argues that the courts should only intervene in cases that cause an unreasonable amount of nuisance after a wide analysis with regard to the total effect of such interventions 2 Additionally Coase highlights reciprocity of harms present in externalities as a central question for distributing rights Damage is shared between parties in a dispute such that both parties consider the present costs in their optimization question Coase uses the ruling of Bryant v Lefever to explore the reciprocal nature of externality Bryant v Lefever concerns a conflict between neighbors in which one neighbor constructed a wall such that the other neighbor s chimney would smoke Originally the court determined the wall was the cause of the chimneys smoking and awarded the plaintiff financial compensation However in the Court of Appeals this judgment was reversed Coase argues that this judgment provides context for framing blame According to Coase The smoke nuisance was caused both by the man who built the wall and by the man who lit the fires 5 Under this framework the wall builder is not legally liable for the nuisance suffered by his neighbor alone In this example Coase seeks to illuminate the conditions for optimizing the allocation of rights the case in which both parties consider harmful Here Coase is referencing Pareto efficiency allowed by the prevailing pricing system Coase used the example of pollution raised by George Stigler in The Theory of Price 1952 several times he argued that arbitrage between actors in a market with low transaction costs could lead to an efficient market solution 6 Coase extends this framework throughout his development of a functional theorem concerning externalities Coase argues that these rights are integrated into an actor s decision making process through their unique cost function These costs are not isolated in nature according to Coase who concluded The cost of exercising a right of using a factor of production is always the loss which is suffered elsewhere 7 The ultimate thesis is that law and regulation are not as important or effective at helping people as lawyers and government planners believe 8 Coase and others like him wanted a change of approach to put the burden of proof for positive effects on a government that was intervening in the market by analysing the costs of the action 9 The argument forms the basis of the Coase Theorem as labeled by George Stigler citation needed Theoretical challenges editGuido Calabresi in his book The Costs of Accidents 1970 10 argues that it is still efficient to hold companies liable that produce greater wealth 11 In the real world where people cannot negotiate costlessly there may be collective action problems of those who caused a nuisance for instance by smoke emissions from a factory to many neighbouring farms and so getting together to negotiate effectively can be difficult against a single polluter because of coordination problems If it is efficient for the farmers to pay the factory to reduce its emissions some of those farmers may hold off paying their fair share hoping to get a free ride The factory may be in a better position to know what measures to take to reduce harm and can be the cheapest avoider illustrating Coase s argument Cases and statutes editCoase uses three main examples in his article to attempt to illustrate his points The first is a fictional cattle herder and a farmer but the second is the case Sturges v Bridgman 12 and the third is the Railway Fires Act 1905 13 Apart from these main examples the following cases are referred to Fontainebleu Hotel Corp v Forty Five Twenty Five Inc 114 So 2d 357 1959 Cooke v Forbes 1867 1868 LR 5 Eq 166 14 Bryant v Lefever 1878 1879 4 CPD 172 Bramwell LJ and Cotton LJ 15 Bass v Gregory 1890 25 QBD 481 16 Attorney General v Doughty 1752 28 ER 290 17 Versailles Borough v McKeesport Coal amp Coke Co 1935 83 Pitts Leg J 379 385 Webb v Bird 1863 143 ER 332 Rushmer v Polsue and Alfieri Ltd 1906 1 Ch 234 Adams v Ursell 1913 1 Ch 269 regarding fish and chips Andreae v Selfridge and Company Ltd 1938 1 Ch 1 Delta Air Corporation v Kersey 1942 193 Ga 862 Thrasher v City of Atlanta 1934 178 Ga 514 Georgia Railroad and Banking Co v Maddox 1902 116 Ga 64 Smith v New England Aircraft Co 1930 270 Mass 511 Vaughan v Taff Vale Railway Co 1858 3 H and N 743 Boulston v Hardy 1597 77 ER 216 Stearn v Prentice Bros Ltd 1919 1 KB 395 Bland v Yates 1913 1914 58 Sol J 612See also editTheory of the firmNotes edit Merrill amp Smith 2017 p 32 a b Coase 1960 page 44 Sturges v Bridgman 1879 11 Ch D 852 Coase 1960 p IV 7 Coase 1960 p V 11 Coase 1960 page 17 Coase 1960 p X 44 Coase 1960 p V 9 Coase 1960 p VIII 23 The Cost of Accidents 1970 135 403 See also Calabresi Guido 1968 Transaction Costs Resource Allocation and Liability Rules A Comment Journal of Law and Economics 11 1 67 73 p 71 73 doi 10 1086 466644 S2CID 3455654 1960 3 JLE 1 8 11 20 21 1960 3 JLE 1 30 34 1960 3 JLE 1 10 11 1960 3 JLE 1 11 12 1960 3 JLE 1 14 1960 3 JLE 1 20References editCoase Ronald 1960 The Problem of Social Cost PDF Journal of Law and Economics 3 Oct 1960 The University of Chicago Press 1 44 doi 10 1086 466560 S2CID 222331226 RH Coase The Nature of the Firm 1937 16 4 Economica 386 405 Sir Alfred Denning Freedom Under the Law 1949 71 E McGaughey Behavioural Economics and Labour Law 2014 LSE Legal Studies Working Paper No 20 2014 Merrill Thomas W Smith Henry E 2017 Property Principles and Policies University Casebook Series 3rd ed St Paul Foundation Press ISBN 978 1 62810 102 7 AC Pigou The Economics of Welfare 4th ed 1932 Pierre Schlag Coase Minus the Coase Theorem Some Problems with Chicago Transaction Cost Analysis 99 Iowa Law Review 175 2013 AWB Simpson Coase v Pigou Reexamined 1996 25 1 The Journal of Legal Studies 53External links editNobel prize in Economics 1991 Press release His Autobiography His page at the University of Chicago Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title The Problem of Social Cost amp oldid 1203320634, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.