fbpx
Wikipedia

Planned economy

A planned economy is a type of economic system where the distribution of goods and services or the investment, production and the allocation of capital goods takes place according to economic plans that are either economy-wide or limited to a category of goods and services. A planned economy may use centralized, decentralized, participatory or Soviet-type forms of economic planning.[1][2] The level of centralization or decentralization in decision-making and participation depends on the specific type of planning mechanism employed.[3]

Socialist states based on the Soviet model have used central planning, although a minority such as the former Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia have adopted some degree of market socialism. Market abolitionist socialism replaces factor markets with direct calculation as the means to coordinate the activities of the various socially owned economic enterprises that make up the economy.[4][5][6] More recent approaches to socialist planning and allocation have come from some economists and computer scientists proposing planning mechanisms based on advances in computer science and information technology.[7]

Planned economies contrast with unplanned economies, specifically market economies, where autonomous firms operating in markets make decisions about production, distribution, pricing and investment. Market economies that use indicative planning are variously referred to as planned market economies, mixed economies and mixed market economies. A command economy follows an administrative-command system and uses Soviet-type economic planning which was characteristic of the former Soviet Union and Eastern Bloc before most of these countries converted to market economies. This highlights the central role of hierarchical administration and public ownership of production in guiding the allocation of resources in these economic systems.[8][9][10]

Overview edit

In the Hellenistic and post-Hellenistic world, "compulsory state planning was the most characteristic trade condition for the Egyptian countryside, for Hellenistic India, and to a lesser degree the more barbaric regions of the Seleucid, the Pergamenian, the southern Arabian, and the Parthian empires".[11] Scholars have argued that the Incan economy was a flexible type of command economy, centered around the movement and utilization of labor instead of goods.[12] One view of mercantilism sees it as involving planned economies.[13]

The Soviet-style planned economy in Soviet Russia evolved in the wake of a continuing existing World War I war-economy as well as other policies, known as war communism (1918–1921), shaped to the requirements of the Russian Civil War of 1917–1923. These policies began their formal consolidation under an official organ of government in 1921, when the Soviet government founded Gosplan. However, the period of the New Economic Policy (c. 1921 to c. 1928 intervened before the planned system of regular five-year plans started in 1928. Leon Trotsky was one of the earliest proponents of economic planning during the NEP period.[14][15][16] Trotsky argued that specialization, the concentration of production and the use of planning could "raise in the near future the coefficient of industrial growth not only two, but even three times higher than the pre-war rate of 6% and, perhaps, even higher".[17] According to historian Sheila Fitzpatrick, the scholarly consensus was that Stalin appropriated the position of the Left Opposition on such matters as industrialisation and collectivisation.[18]

After World War II (1939–1945) France and Great Britain practiced dirigisme – government direction of the economy through non-coercive means. The Swedish government planned public-housing models in a similar fashion as urban planning in a project called Million Programme, implemented from 1965 to 1974. Some decentralized participation in economic planning occurred across Revolutionary Spain, most notably in Catalonia, during the Spanish Revolution of 1936.[19][20]

Relationship with socialism edit

 
Albert Einstein advocated for a socialist planned economy with his 1949 article "Why Socialism?"

In the May 1949 issue of the Monthly Review titled "Why Socialism?", Albert Einstein wrote:[21]

I am convinced there is only one way to eliminate these grave evils, namely through the establishment of a socialist economy, accompanied by an educational system which would be oriented toward social goals. In such an economy, the means of production are owned by society itself and are utilized in a planned fashion. A planned economy, which adjusts production to the needs of the community, would distribute the work to be done among all those able to work and would guarantee a livelihood to every man, woman, and child. The education of the individual, in addition to promoting his own innate abilities, would attempt to develop in him a sense of responsibility for his fellow-men in place of the glorification of power and success in our present society.

While socialism is not equivalent to economic planning or to the concept of a planned economy, an influential conception of socialism involves the replacement of capital markets with some form of economic planning in order to achieve ex-ante coordination of the economy. The goal of such an economic system would be to achieve conscious control over the economy by the population, specifically so that the use of the surplus product is controlled by the producers.[22] The specific forms of planning proposed for socialism and their feasibility are subjects of the socialist calculation debate.

Computational economic planning edit

In 1959 Anatoly Kitov proposed a distributed computing system (Project "Red Book", Russian: Красная книга) with a focus on the management of the Soviet economy. Opposition from the Defence Ministry killed Kitov's plan.[23]

In 1971 the socialist Allende administration of Chile launched Project Cybersyn to install a telex machine in every corporation and organization in the economy for the communication of economic data between firms and the government. The data was also fed into a computer-simulated economy for forecasting. A control room was built for real-time observation and management of the overall economy. The prototype-stage of the project showed promise when it was used to redirect supplies around a trucker's strike,[24] but after CIA-backed Augusto Pinochet led a coup in 1973 that established a military dictatorship under his rule the program was abolished and Pinochet moved Chile towards a more liberalized market economy.

In their book Towards a New Socialism (1993), the computer scientist Paul Cockshott from the University of Glasgow and the economist Allin Cottrell from Wake Forest University claim to demonstrate how a democratically planned economy built on modern computer technology is possible and drives the thesis that it would be both economically more stable than the free-market economies and also morally desirable.[7]

Cybernetics edit

 
Project Cybersyn was an early form of computational economic planning.

The use of computers to coordinate production in an optimal fashion has been variously proposed for socialist economies. The Polish economist Oskar Lange (1904–1965) argued that the computer is more efficient than the market process at solving the multitude of simultaneous equations required for allocating economic inputs efficiently (either in terms of physical quantities or monetary prices).[25]

Salvador Allende's socialist government pioneered the 1970 Chilean distributed decision support system Project Cybersyn in an attempt to move towards a decentralized planned economy with the experimental viable system model of computed organisational structure of autonomous operative units through an algedonic feedback setting and bottom-up participative decision-making in the form of participative democracy by the Cyberfolk component.[26]

Fictional portrayals edit

The 1888 novel Looking Backward by Edward Bellamy depicts a fictional planned economy in a United States around the year 2000 which has become a socialist utopia.

The World State in Aldous Huxley's Brave New World (1932) and Airstrip One in George Orwell's Nineteen Eighty-Four (1949) provide fictional depictions of command economies, albeit with diametrically opposed aims. The former is a consumer economy designed to engender productivity while the latter is a shortage economy designed as an agent of totalitarian social control. Airstrip One is organized by the euphemistically named Ministry of Plenty.

Other literary portrayals of planned economies include Yevgeny Zamyatin's We (1924), which influenced Orwell's work. Like Nineteen Eighty-Four, Ayn Rand's dystopian 1938 story Anthem offered an artistic portrayal of a command economy that was influenced by We. The difference is that it was a primitivist planned economy as opposed to the advanced technology of We or Brave New World.

Central planning edit

Advantages edit

The government can harness land, labor, and capital to serve the economic objectives of the state. Consumer demand can be restrained in favor of greater capital investment for economic development in a desired pattern. In international comparisons, state-socialist nations have compared favorably with capitalist nations in health indicators such as infant mortality and life expectancy. However, according to Michael Ellman, the reality of this, at least regarding infant mortality, varies depending on whether official Soviet or WHO definitions are used.[27]

The state can begin building massive heavy industries at once in an underdeveloped economy without waiting years for capital to accumulate through the expansion of light industry and without reliance on external financing. This is what happened in the Soviet Union during the 1930s when the government forced the share of gross national income dedicated to private consumption down from 80% to 50%. As a result of this development, the Soviet Union experienced massive growth in heavy industry, with a concurrent massive contraction of its agricultural sector due to the labor shortage.[28]

Disadvantages edit

Economic instability edit

Studies of command economies of the Eastern Bloc in the 1950s and 1960s by both American and Eastern European economists found that contrary to the expectations of both groups they showed greater fluctuations in output than market economies during the same period.[29]

Inefficient resource distribution edit

Critics of planned economies argue that planners cannot detect consumer preferences, shortages and surpluses with sufficient accuracy and therefore cannot efficiently co-ordinate production (in a market economy, a free price system is intended to serve this purpose). This difficulty was notably written about by economists Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek, who referred to subtly distinct aspects of the problem as the economic calculation problem and local knowledge problem, respectively.[30][31] These distinct aspects were also present in the economic thought of Michael Polanyi.[32]

Whereas the former stressed the theoretical underpinnings of a market economy to subjective value theory while attacking the labor theory of value, the latter argued that the only way to satisfy individuals who have a constantly changing hierarchy of needs and are the only ones to possess their particular individual's circumstances is by allowing those with the most knowledge of their needs to have it in their power to use their resources in a competing marketplace to meet the needs of the most consumers most efficiently. This phenomenon is recognized as spontaneous order. Additionally, misallocation of resources would naturally ensue by redirecting capital away from individuals with direct knowledge and circumventing it into markets where a coercive monopoly influences behavior, ignoring market signals. According to Tibor Machan, "[w]ithout a market in which allocations can be made in obedience to the law of supply and demand, it is difficult or impossible to funnel resources with respect to actual human preferences and goals".[33]

Historian Robert Vincent Daniels regarded the Stalinist period to represent an abrupt break with Lenin's government in terms of economic planning in which an deliberated, scientific system of planning that featured former Menshevik economists at Gosplan had been replaced with a hasty version of planning with unrealistic targets, bureaucratic waste, bottlenecks and shortages. Stalin's formulations of national plans in terms of physical quantity of output was also attributed by Daniels as a source for the stagnant levels of efficiency and quality.[34]

Suppression of economic democracy and self-management edit

Economist Robin Hahnel, who supports participatory economics, a form of socialist decentralized planned economy, notes that even if central planning overcame its inherent inhibitions of incentives and innovation, it would nevertheless be unable to maximize economic democracy and self-management, which he believes are concepts that are more intellectually coherent, consistent and just than mainstream notions of economic freedom.[35] Furthermore, Hahnel states:

Combined with a more democratic political system, and redone to closer approximate a best case version, centrally planned economies no doubt would have performed better. But they could never have delivered economic self-management, they would always have been slow to innovate as apathy and frustration took their inevitable toll, and they would always have been susceptible to growing inequities and inefficiencies as the effects of differential economic power grew. Under central planning neither planners, managers, nor workers had incentives to promote the social economic interest. Nor did impeding markets for final goods to the planning system enfranchise consumers in meaningful ways. But central planning would have been incompatible with economic democracy even if it had overcome its information and incentive liabilities. And the truth is that it survived as long as it did only because it was propped up by unprecedented totalitarian political power.[35]

Command economy edit

Planned economies contrast with command economies in that a planned economy is "an economic system in which the government controls and regulates production, distribution, prices, etc."[36] whereas a command economy necessarily has substantial public ownership of industry while also having this type of regulation.[37] In command economies, important allocation decisions are made by government authorities and are imposed by law.[38]

This is contested by some Marxists.[5][39] Decentralized planning has been proposed as a basis for socialism and has been variously advocated by anarchists, council communists, libertarian Marxists and other democratic and libertarian socialists who advocate a non-market form of socialism, in total rejection of the type of planning adopted in the economy of the Soviet Union.[40]

Most of a command economy is organized in a top-down administrative model by a central authority, where decisions regarding investment and production output requirements are decided upon at the top in the chain of command, with little input from lower levels. Advocates of economic planning have sometimes been staunch critics of these command economies. Leon Trotsky believed that those at the top of the chain of command, regardless of their intellectual capacity, operated without the input and participation of the millions of people who participate in the economy and who understand/respond to local conditions and changes in the economy. Therefore, they would be unable to effectively coordinate all economic activity.[41]

Historians have associated planned economies with Marxist–Leninist states and the Soviet economic model. Since the 1980s, it has been contested that the Soviet economic model did not actually constitute a planned economy in that a comprehensive and binding plan did not guide production and investment.[42] The further distinction of an administrative-command system emerged as a new designation in some academic circles for the economic system that existed in the former Soviet Union and Eastern Bloc, highlighting the role of centralized hierarchical decision-making in the absence of popular control over the economy.[43] The possibility of a digital planned economy was explored in Chile between 1971 and 1973 with the development of Project Cybersyn and by Aleksandr Aleksandrovich Kharkevich, head of the Department of Technical Physics in Kiev in 1962.[44][45]

While both economic planning and a planned economy can be either authoritarian or democratic and participatory, democratic socialist critics argue that command economies are necessarily authoritarian or undemocratic in practice.[46][47] Indicative planning is a form of economic planning in market economies that directs the economy through incentive-based methods. Economic planning can be practiced in a decentralized manner through different government authorities. In some predominantly market-oriented and Western mixed economies, the state utilizes economic planning in strategic industries such as the aerospace industry. Mixed economies usually employ macroeconomic planning while micro-economic affairs are left to the market and price system.

Decentralized planning edit

A decentralized-planned economy, occasionally called horizontally planned economy due to its horizontalism, is a type of planned economy in which the investment and allocation of consumer and capital goods is explicated accordingly to an economy-wide plan built and operatively coordinated through a distributed network of disparate economic agents or even production units itself. Decentralized planning is usually held in contrast to centralized planning, in particular the Soviet-type economic planning of the Soviet Union's command economy, where economic information is aggregated and used to formulate a plan for production, investment and resource allocation by a single central authority. Decentralized planning can take shape both in the context of a mixed economy as well as in a post-capitalist economic system. This form of economic planning implies some process of democratic and participatory decision-making within the economy and within firms itself in the form of industrial democracy. Computer-based forms of democratic economic planning and coordination between economic enterprises have also been proposed by various computer scientists and radical economists.[25][7][24] Proponents present decentralized and participatory economic planning as an alternative to market socialism for a post-capitalist society.[48]

Decentralized planning has been a feature of anarchist and socialist economics. Variations of decentralized planning such as economic democracy, industrial democracy and participatory economics have been promoted by various political groups, most notably anarchists, democratic socialists, guild socialists, libertarian Marxists, libertarian socialists, revolutionary syndicalists and Trotskyists.[41] During the Spanish Revolution, some areas where anarchist and libertarian socialist influence through the CNT and UGT was extensive, particularly rural regions, were run on the basis of decentralized planning resembling the principles laid out by anarcho-syndicalist Diego Abad de Santillan in the book After the Revolution.[49]

Models edit

Negotiated coordination edit

Economist Pat Devine has created a model of decentralized economic planning called "negotiated coordination" which is based upon social ownership of the means of production by those affected by the use of the assets involved, with the allocation of consumer and capital goods made through a participatory form of decision-making by those at the most localized level of production.[50] Moreover, organizations that utilize modularity in their production processes may distribute problem solving and decision making.[51]

Participatory planning edit

The planning structure of a decentralized planned economy is generally based on a consumers council and producer council (or jointly, a distributive cooperative) which is sometimes called a consumers' cooperative. Producers and consumers, or their representatives, negotiate the quality and quantity of what is to be produced. This structure is central to guild socialism, participatory economics and the economic theories related to anarchism.

Practice edit

Kerala edit

Some decentralized participation in economic planning has been implemented in various regions and states in India, most notably in Kerala. Local level planning agencies assess the needs of people who are able to give their direct input through the Gram Sabhas (village-based institutions) and the planners subsequently seek to plan accordingly.[52]

Revolutionary Catalonia edit

Some decentralized participation in economic planning has been implemented across Revolutionary Spain, most notably in Catalonia, during the Spanish Revolution of 1936.[19][20]

Similar concepts in practice edit

Community participatory planning edit

The United Nations has developed local projects that promote participatory planning on a community level. Members of communities take decisions regarding community development directly.[citation needed]

See also edit

Case studies (Soviet-type economies)
Case studies (mixed-market economies)

References edit

  1. ^ Alec Nove (1987). "Planned Economy". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. vol. 3. p. 879.
  2. ^ Devine, Pat (2010). Democracy and Economic Planning. Polity. ISBN 978-0745634791.
  3. ^ Gregory, Paul R.; Stuart, Robert C. (2003). Comparing Economic Systems in the Twenty-First Century. Boston: Houghton Mifflin. pp. 23–24. ISBN 978-0-618-26181-9.
  4. ^ Prychito, David L. (2002). Markets, Planning, and Democracy: Essays After the Collapse of Communism. Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 72. ISBN 978-1840645194. Traditional socialism strives to plan all economic activities comprehensively, both within and between enterprises. As such, it seeks to integrate the economic activities of society (the coordination of socially owned property) into a single coherent plan, rather than to rely upon the spontaneous or anarchic ordering of the market system to coordinate plans.
  5. ^ a b Mandel, Ernest (1986). "In Defence of Socialist Planning" (PDF). New Left Review. 159: 5–37. (PDF) from the original on 2008-05-16. Planning is not equivalent to 'perfect' allocation of resources, nor 'scientific' allocation, nor even 'more humane' allocation. It simply means 'direct' allocation, ex ante. As such, it is the opposite of market allocation, which is ex post.
  6. ^ Ellman, Michael (1989). Socialist Planning. Cambridge University Press. p. 327. ISBN 978-0521358668. '[S]ocialist planning', in the original sense of a national economy which replaced market relationships by direct calculation and direct product exchange, has nowhere been established [...].
  7. ^ a b c Cottrell, Allin; Cockshott, W. Paul (1993). Towards a New Socialism 2018-06-27 at the Wayback Machine. (Nottingham, England: Spokesman. Retrieved 17 March 2012.
  8. ^ Zimbalist, Sherman and Brown, Andrew, Howard J. and Stuart (1988). Comparing Economic Systems: A Political-Economic Approach. Harcourt College Pub. p. 4. ISBN 978-0-15-512403-5. Almost all industry in the Soviet Union is government owned and all production is directed, in theory, by a central plan (though in practice much is left for local discretion and much happens that is unplanned or not under government control).{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  9. ^ Wilhelm, John Howard (1985). "The Soviet Union Has an Administered, Not a Planned, Economy". Soviet Studies. 37 (1): 118–130. doi:10.1080/09668138508411571.
  10. ^ Ellman, Michael (2007). "The Rise and Fall of Socialist Planning". In Estrin, Saul; Kołodko, Grzegorz W.; Uvalić, Milica (eds.). Transition and Beyond: Essays in Honour of Mario Nuti. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 22. ISBN 978-0-230-54697-4. In the USSR in the late 1980s the system was normally referred to as the 'administrative-command' economy. What was fundamental to this system was not the plan but the role of administrative hierarchies at all levels of decision making; the absence of control over decision making by the population [...].
  11. ^ Heichelheim, Friedrich Moritz (1949). "Commerce, Greek and Roman". In Hammond, Nicholas G. L.; Scullard, H. H. (eds.). The Oxford Classical Dictionary (2 ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press (published 1970). p. 274. ISBN 0198691173.
  12. ^ La Lone, Darrell E. (1982). "The Inca as a Nonmarket Economy: Supply on Command versus Supply and Demand". Contexts for Prehistoric Exchange: 292. from the original on 19 October 2020. Retrieved 17 December 2018.
  13. ^ Blaug, Mark, ed. (1991). The Early mercantilists: Thomas Mun (1571–1641), Edward Misselden (1608–1634), Gerard de Malynes (1586–1623). Pioneers in economics. E. Elgar Pub. Co. p. 136. ISBN 978-1852784669. Retrieved 7 September 2018. To this approach belongs at least in part an attempt to view mercantilism as economic dirigee, a planned economy with national economic objectives – 'wealth', 'plenty' or simply 'welfare' within the framework of the nation and at the expense of other nations.
  14. ^ Twiss, Thomas M. (2014). Trotsky and the Problem of Soviet Bureaucracy. Brill. pp. 88–113. ISBN 978-90-04-26953-8. from the original on 2023-07-26. Retrieved 2023-10-27.
  15. ^ Day, Richard B. (1973). Leon Trotsky and the Politics of Economic Isolation. Cambridge University Press. p. 109. ISBN 978-0-521-52436-0. from the original on 2023-07-26. Retrieved 2023-10-27.
  16. ^ Deutscher, Isaac (1965). The prophet unarmed: Trotsky, 1921–1929. New York, Vintage Books. p. 468. ISBN 978-0-394-70747-1.
  17. ^ Rogovin, Vadim Zakharovich (2021). Was There an Alternative? Trotskyism: a Look Back Through the Years. Mehring Books. pp. 404–405. ISBN 978-1-893638-97-6.
  18. ^ Fitzpatrick, Sheila (22 April 2010). "The Old Man". London Review of Books. 32 (8). ISSN 0260-9592. from the original on 3 February 2024. Retrieved 3 February 2024.
  19. ^ a b Wetzel, Tom. "Workers Power and the Spanish Revolution" 2020-11-07 at the Wayback Machine.
  20. ^ a b Dolgoff, Sam, ed. (1974). The Anarchist Collectives (1st ed.). Free Life Editions. p. 114. ISBN 978-0914156024.
  21. ^ Einstein, Albert (May 1949). "Why Socialism?" 2011-03-17 at the Wayback Machine, Monthly Review.
  22. ^ Feinstein, C. H. (1975). Socialism, Capitalism and Economic Growth: Essays Presented to Maurice Dobb. Cambridge University Press. p. 174. ISBN 0-521-29007-4. We have presented the view that planning and market mechanisms are instruments that can be used both in socialist and non-socialist societies. [...] It was important to explode the primitive identification of central planning and socialism and to stress the instrumental character of planning.
  23. ^ Kitov, Vladimir A.; Shilov, Valery V.; Silantiev, Sergey A. (5 October 2016). "Trente ans ou la Vie d'un scientifique". In Gadducci, Fabio; Tavosanis, Mirko (eds.). History and Philosophy of Computing: Third International Conference, HaPoC 2015, Pisa, Italy, October 8–11, 2015, Revised Selected Papers. Volume 487 of IFIP Advances in Information and Communication Technology. Cham, Switzerland: Springer (published 2016). p. 191. ISBN 978-3319472867. ISSN 1868-4238. Retrieved 12 September 2021. [...] "Measures to overcome the shortcomings in the development, production and introduction of computers in the Armed Forces and national economy". Today this project is known among the specialists as the 'Red Book' project. It was the first project in the USSR, which proposed to combine all the computers in the country into a unified network of compter centers. In peacetime this network must have fulfilled both national economic and defense tasks [...].
  24. ^ a b Eden Medina (2006). "Designing Freedom, Regulating a Nation: Socialist Cybernetics in Allende's Chile". J. Lat. Am. Stud. Cambridge University Press. 38 (38): 571–606. doi:10.1017/S0022216X06001179. S2CID 26484124.
  25. ^ a b Lange, Oskar (1979). "The Computer and the Market". Calculemus.org. from the original on 17 April 2021. Retrieved 12 September 2012.
  26. ^ "Cyberfolk". Project Cybersyn. 12 May 2011 at the Wayback Machine. Retrieved 6 August 2020.
  27. ^ Ellman, Michael (2014). Socialist Planning. Cambridge University Press. p. 372. ISBN 978-1107427327. from the original on 2024-02-07. Retrieved 2020-11-02. For the USSR, the official Soviet statistics of infant mortality give too favourable a picture. There are two reasons for this. First, the USSR used a definition of 'birth' different from the WHO one (Chapter 8, pp. 321–322). The percentage increase in the infant mortality rate caused by switching from the Soviet definition to the WHO one seems to have ranged from 13 per cent in Moldova to 40 per cent in Latvia. In Poland, which has a much larger population than the two previously mentioned countries, it was about 21 per cent. Secondly, there seems to have been significant under-registration of deaths, particularly in certain regions, such as Central Asia and Azerbaijan. Estimates of 'true' infant mortality in 1987–2000 show very high increases over the official figures in Central Asia, Azerbaijan, Albania, Romania, and Bulgaria. In Russia – which was supposed to have adopted the WHO definition of 'birth' by 1993 and where under-registration is much less than in Central Asia or Azerbaijan – in 1987–2000 the estimated increase of the official figures to measure 'true' infant mortality is 26.5 percent.
  28. ^ Kennedy, Paul (1987). The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers. New York: Random House. pp. 322–323. ISBN 0-394-54674-1.
  29. ^ Zielinski, J. G. (1973). Economic Reforms in Polish Industry. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-215323-4.
  30. ^ Von Mises, Ludwig (1990). (PDF). Ludwig von Mises Institute. Archived from the original (PDF) on 16 December 2014. Retrieved 8 September 2008.
  31. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. (1945). "The Use of Knowledge". American Economic Review. XXXV: 4. pp. 519–530.
  32. ^ Biro, Gabor (2022). "From Red Spirit to Underperforming Pyramids and Coercive Institutions: Michael Polanyi Against Economic Planning," History of European Ideas, 2022". History of European Ideas. 48 (6): 811–847. doi:10.1080/01916599.2021.2009359. S2CID 225260656. from the original on 2022-08-16. Retrieved 2022-08-16.
  33. ^ Machan, Tibor (2002). "Some Skeptical Reflections on Research and Development" (PDF). Liberty and Research and Development: Science Funding in a Free Society. Hoover Press. ISBN 0-8179-2942-8. (PDF) from the original on 2006-10-31.
  34. ^ Daniels, Robert V. (2002). The End of the Communist Revolution. Routledge. pp. 90–92. ISBN 978-1-134-92607-7. from the original on 2023-11-07. Retrieved 2023-10-30.
  35. ^ a b Hahnel, Robin (2002). The ABC's of Political Economy. London: Pluto Press. p. 262. ISBN 0-7453-1858-4.
  36. ^ "Planned economy" 2007-02-28 at the Wayback Machine. Dictionary.com. Unabridged (v. 1.1). Random House, Inc. Retrieved 11 May 2008).
  37. ^ "Command economy" 2007-01-24 at the Wayback Machine. Merriam-Webster Online Dictionary. Retrieved 11 May 2008.
  38. ^ Rosser, Mariana V.; Rosser, J. Barkley (2003). Comparative Economics in a Transforming World Economy. MIT Press. p. 7. ISBN 978-0-262-18234-8. In a command economy the most important allocation decisions are made by government authorities and are imposed by law.
  39. ^ Schweickart, David; Lawler, James; Ticktin, Hillel; Ollman, Bertell (1998). "Definitions of Market and Socialism". Market Socialism: The Debate Among Socialists. New York: Routledge. pp. 58–59. ISBN 978-0-415-91967-8. "For an Anti-Stalinist Marxist, socialism is defined by the degree to which the society is planned. Planning here is understood as the conscious regulation of society by the associated producers themselves. Put it differently, the control over the surplus product rests with the majority of the population through a resolutely democratic process. [...] The sale of labour power is abolished and labour necessarily becomes creative. Everyone participates in running their institutions and society as a whole. No one controls anyone else."
  40. ^ Schweickart, David (2007). "Democratic Socialism". In Anderson, Gary L.; Herr, Kathryn G., eds. Encyclopedia of Activism and Social Justice. Sage Publications. p. 448. ISBN 978-1452265650. 17 June 2012 at the Wayback Machine. Retrieved 6 August 2020. "Virtually all socialists have distanced themselves from the economic model long synonymous with socialism (i.e., the Soviet model of a nonmarket, centrally planned economy. [...] Some have endorsed the concept of market socialism, a postcapitalist economy that retains market competition but socializes the means of production and, in some versions, extends democracy to the workplace. Some hold out for a nonmarket, participatory economy. All democratic socialists agree on the need for a democratic alternative to capitalism".
  41. ^ a b Trotsky, Leon. Writings 1932–33. p. 96.
  42. ^ Wilhelm, John Howard (1985). "The Soviet Union Has an Administered, Not a Planned, Economy". Soviet Studies. 37 (1): 118–130. doi:10.1080/09668138508411571.
  43. ^ Ellman, Michael (2007). "The Rise and Fall of Socialist Planning". In Estrin, Saul; Kołodko, Grzegorz W.; Uvalić, Milica (eds.). Transition and Beyond: Essays in Honour of Mario Nuti. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 22. ISBN 978-0-230-54697-4. Realization of these facts led in the 1970s and 1980s to the development of new terms to describe what had previously been (and still were in United Nations publications) referred to as the 'centrally planned economies'. In the USSR in the late 1980s the system was normally referred to as the 'administrative-command' economy. What was fundamental to this system was not the plan but the role of administrative hierarchies at all levels of decision making; the absence of control over decision making by the population [...].
  44. ^ "Machine of communism. Why the USSR did not create the Internet" 2022-03-08 at the Wayback Machine.
  45. ^ Kharkevich, Aleksandr Aleksandrovich (1973). Theory of information. The identification of the images. Selected works in three volumes. Volume 3. Information and technology: Moscow: Publishing House "Nauka", 1973. – Academy of Sciences of the USSR. Institute of information transmission problems. p. 524.
  46. ^ Busky, Donald F. (2000). Democratic Socialism: A Global Survey. Praeger. pp. 7–8. ISBN 978-0275968861. "Sometimes simply called socialism, more often than not, the adjective democratic is added by democratic socialists to attempt to distinguish themselves from Communists who also call themselves socialists. All but communists, or more accurately, Marxist-Leninists, believe that modern-day communism is highly undemocratic and totalitarian in practice, and democratic socialists wish to emphasise by their name that they disagree strongly with the Marxist-Leninist brand of socialism."
  47. ^ Prychito, David L. (2002). Markets, Planning, and Democracy: Essays After the Collapse of Communism. Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 72. ISBN 978-1840645194. "It is perhaps less clearly understood that advocates of democratic socialism (who are committed to socialism in the above sense but opposed to Stalinist-style command planning) advocate a decentralized socialism, whereby the planning process itself (the integration of all productive units into one huge organisation) would follow the workers' self-management principle."
  48. ^ Kotz, David (2008). "What Economic Structure for Socialism?" (PDF). (PDF) from the original on 2011-01-02. Retrieved 12 September 2012.
  49. ^ . Membres.multimania.fr. 7 January 1936. Archived from the original on 29 August 2012. Retrieved 12 September 2012.
  50. ^ "Participatory Planning Through Negotiated Coordination" (PDF). 1 March 2002. (PDF) from the original on 2011-08-17. Retrieved 30 October 2011.
  51. ^ Kostakis, Vasilis (2019). "How to Reap the Benefits of the 'Digital Revolution'? Modularity and the Commons" 2023-06-19 at the Wayback Machine. Halduskultuur: The Estonian Journal of Administrative Culture and Digital Governance. 20 (1): 4–19.
  52. ^ Sivaramakrishnan, K.C. (2006). People's Participation in Urban Governance: A Comparative Study of the Working of Wards Committees in Karnataka, Kerala, Maharashtra and West Bengal. New Delhi: Concept Publishing Company. p. 140. ISBN 8180693260.
  53. ^ Crittenden, Ann (18 December 1977). "The Cuban Economy: How It Works". The New York Times. from the original on 29 June 2018. Retrieved 29 June 2018.

Further reading edit

  • Kaplan, Robert – see reference to his work on International Economics and Foreign Relations, where he addresses nature of "command economy", a Weberian term.
  • Cox, Robin (2005). "The Economic Calculation Controversy: Unravelling of a Myth". Common Voice (3).
  • Damier, Vadim (2012). "The Economy of Freedom".
  • Devine, Pat (2010). Democracy and Economic Planning. Polity. ISBN 978-0745634791.
  • Ellman, Michael (2014). Socialist Planning (3rd ed.). Cambridge University Press. ISBN 1107427320.
  • Grossman, Gregory (1987): "Command economy". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. 1. pp. 494–495.
  • Landauer, Carl (1947). Theory of National Economic Planning (2nd ed.). Berkeley and Los Angeles, California: University of California Press.
  • Mandel, Ernest (1986). In Defence of Socialist Planning. New Left Review (159).
  • Myant, Martin; Drahokoupil, Jan (2010), Transition Economies: Political Economy in Russia, Eastern Europe, and Central Asia, Wiley-Blackwell, ISBN 978-0-470-59619-7.
  • Nove, Alec (1987). "Planned economy". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. 3. pp. 879–885.

External links edit

  • "The Myth of the Permanent Arms Economy"
  • "The Stalin Model for the Control and Coordination of Enterprises in a Socialist Economy" 2021-01-26 at the Wayback Machine

planned, economy, planned, economy, type, economic, system, where, distribution, goods, services, investment, production, allocation, capital, goods, takes, place, according, economic, plans, that, either, economy, wide, limited, category, goods, services, pla. A planned economy is a type of economic system where the distribution of goods and services or the investment production and the allocation of capital goods takes place according to economic plans that are either economy wide or limited to a category of goods and services A planned economy may use centralized decentralized participatory or Soviet type forms of economic planning 1 2 The level of centralization or decentralization in decision making and participation depends on the specific type of planning mechanism employed 3 Socialist states based on the Soviet model have used central planning although a minority such as the former Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia have adopted some degree of market socialism Market abolitionist socialism replaces factor markets with direct calculation as the means to coordinate the activities of the various socially owned economic enterprises that make up the economy 4 5 6 More recent approaches to socialist planning and allocation have come from some economists and computer scientists proposing planning mechanisms based on advances in computer science and information technology 7 Planned economies contrast with unplanned economies specifically market economies where autonomous firms operating in markets make decisions about production distribution pricing and investment Market economies that use indicative planning are variously referred to as planned market economies mixed economies and mixed market economies A command economy follows an administrative command system and uses Soviet type economic planning which was characteristic of the former Soviet Union and Eastern Bloc before most of these countries converted to market economies This highlights the central role of hierarchical administration and public ownership of production in guiding the allocation of resources in these economic systems 8 9 10 Contents 1 Overview 1 1 Relationship with socialism 1 2 Computational economic planning 1 3 Cybernetics 1 4 Fictional portrayals 2 Central planning 2 1 Advantages 2 2 Disadvantages 2 2 1 Economic instability 2 2 2 Inefficient resource distribution 2 2 3 Suppression of economic democracy and self management 2 3 Command economy 3 Decentralized planning 3 1 Models 3 1 1 Negotiated coordination 3 1 2 Participatory planning 3 2 Practice 3 2 1 Kerala 3 2 2 Revolutionary Catalonia 3 2 3 Similar concepts in practice 3 2 3 1 Community participatory planning 4 See also 5 References 6 Further reading 7 External linksOverview editIn the Hellenistic and post Hellenistic world compulsory state planning was the most characteristic trade condition for the Egyptian countryside for Hellenistic India and to a lesser degree the more barbaric regions of the Seleucid the Pergamenian the southern Arabian and the Parthian empires 11 Scholars have argued that the Incan economy was a flexible type of command economy centered around the movement and utilization of labor instead of goods 12 One view of mercantilism sees it as involving planned economies 13 The Soviet style planned economy in Soviet Russia evolved in the wake of a continuing existing World War I war economy as well as other policies known as war communism 1918 1921 shaped to the requirements of the Russian Civil War of 1917 1923 These policies began their formal consolidation under an official organ of government in 1921 when the Soviet government founded Gosplan However the period of the New Economic Policy c 1921 to c 1928 intervened before the planned system of regular five year plans started in 1928 Leon Trotsky was one of the earliest proponents of economic planning during the NEP period 14 15 16 Trotsky argued that specialization the concentration of production and the use of planning could raise in the near future the coefficient of industrial growth not only two but even three times higher than the pre war rate of 6 and perhaps even higher 17 According to historian Sheila Fitzpatrick the scholarly consensus was that Stalin appropriated the position of the Left Opposition on such matters as industrialisation and collectivisation 18 After World War II 1939 1945 France and Great Britain practiced dirigisme government direction of the economy through non coercive means The Swedish government planned public housing models in a similar fashion as urban planning in a project called Million Programme implemented from 1965 to 1974 Some decentralized participation in economic planning occurred across Revolutionary Spain most notably in Catalonia during the Spanish Revolution of 1936 19 20 Relationship with socialism edit nbsp Albert Einstein advocated for a socialist planned economy with his 1949 article Why Socialism In the May 1949 issue of the Monthly Review titled Why Socialism Albert Einstein wrote 21 I am convinced there is only one way to eliminate these grave evils namely through the establishment of a socialist economy accompanied by an educational system which would be oriented toward social goals In such an economy the means of production are owned by society itself and are utilized in a planned fashion A planned economy which adjusts production to the needs of the community would distribute the work to be done among all those able to work and would guarantee a livelihood to every man woman and child The education of the individual in addition to promoting his own innate abilities would attempt to develop in him a sense of responsibility for his fellow men in place of the glorification of power and success in our present society While socialism is not equivalent to economic planning or to the concept of a planned economy an influential conception of socialism involves the replacement of capital markets with some form of economic planning in order to achieve ex ante coordination of the economy The goal of such an economic system would be to achieve conscious control over the economy by the population specifically so that the use of the surplus product is controlled by the producers 22 The specific forms of planning proposed for socialism and their feasibility are subjects of the socialist calculation debate Computational economic planning edit Further information Government by algorithm In 1959 Anatoly Kitov proposed a distributed computing system Project Red Book Russian Krasnaya kniga with a focus on the management of the Soviet economy Opposition from the Defence Ministry killed Kitov s plan 23 In 1971 the socialist Allende administration of Chile launched Project Cybersyn to install a telex machine in every corporation and organization in the economy for the communication of economic data between firms and the government The data was also fed into a computer simulated economy for forecasting A control room was built for real time observation and management of the overall economy The prototype stage of the project showed promise when it was used to redirect supplies around a trucker s strike 24 but after CIA backed Augusto Pinochet led a coup in 1973 that established a military dictatorship under his rule the program was abolished and Pinochet moved Chile towards a more liberalized market economy In their book Towards a New Socialism 1993 the computer scientist Paul Cockshott from the University of Glasgow and the economist Allin Cottrell from Wake Forest University claim to demonstrate how a democratically planned economy built on modern computer technology is possible and drives the thesis that it would be both economically more stable than the free market economies and also morally desirable 7 Cybernetics edit nbsp Project Cybersyn was an early form of computational economic planning The use of computers to coordinate production in an optimal fashion has been variously proposed for socialist economies The Polish economist Oskar Lange 1904 1965 argued that the computer is more efficient than the market process at solving the multitude of simultaneous equations required for allocating economic inputs efficiently either in terms of physical quantities or monetary prices 25 Salvador Allende s socialist government pioneered the 1970 Chilean distributed decision support system Project Cybersyn in an attempt to move towards a decentralized planned economy with the experimental viable system model of computed organisational structure of autonomous operative units through an algedonic feedback setting and bottom up participative decision making in the form of participative democracy by the Cyberfolk component 26 Fictional portrayals edit The 1888 novel Looking Backward by Edward Bellamy depicts a fictional planned economy in a United States around the year 2000 which has become a socialist utopia The World State in Aldous Huxley s Brave New World 1932 and Airstrip One in George Orwell s Nineteen Eighty Four 1949 provide fictional depictions of command economies albeit with diametrically opposed aims The former is a consumer economy designed to engender productivity while the latter is a shortage economy designed as an agent of totalitarian social control Airstrip One is organized by the euphemistically named Ministry of Plenty Other literary portrayals of planned economies include Yevgeny Zamyatin s We 1924 which influenced Orwell s work Like Nineteen Eighty Four Ayn Rand s dystopian 1938 story Anthem offered an artistic portrayal of a command economy that was influenced by We The difference is that it was a primitivist planned economy as opposed to the advanced technology of We or Brave New World Central planning editAdvantages edit The government can harness land labor and capital to serve the economic objectives of the state Consumer demand can be restrained in favor of greater capital investment for economic development in a desired pattern In international comparisons state socialist nations have compared favorably with capitalist nations in health indicators such as infant mortality and life expectancy However according to Michael Ellman the reality of this at least regarding infant mortality varies depending on whether official Soviet or WHO definitions are used 27 The state can begin building massive heavy industries at once in an underdeveloped economy without waiting years for capital to accumulate through the expansion of light industry and without reliance on external financing This is what happened in the Soviet Union during the 1930s when the government forced the share of gross national income dedicated to private consumption down from 80 to 50 As a result of this development the Soviet Union experienced massive growth in heavy industry with a concurrent massive contraction of its agricultural sector due to the labor shortage 28 Disadvantages edit Economic instability edit Studies of command economies of the Eastern Bloc in the 1950s and 1960s by both American and Eastern European economists found that contrary to the expectations of both groups they showed greater fluctuations in output than market economies during the same period 29 Inefficient resource distribution edit Critics of planned economies argue that planners cannot detect consumer preferences shortages and surpluses with sufficient accuracy and therefore cannot efficiently co ordinate production in a market economy a free price system is intended to serve this purpose This difficulty was notably written about by economists Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek who referred to subtly distinct aspects of the problem as the economic calculation problem and local knowledge problem respectively 30 31 These distinct aspects were also present in the economic thought of Michael Polanyi 32 Whereas the former stressed the theoretical underpinnings of a market economy to subjective value theory while attacking the labor theory of value the latter argued that the only way to satisfy individuals who have a constantly changing hierarchy of needs and are the only ones to possess their particular individual s circumstances is by allowing those with the most knowledge of their needs to have it in their power to use their resources in a competing marketplace to meet the needs of the most consumers most efficiently This phenomenon is recognized as spontaneous order Additionally misallocation of resources would naturally ensue by redirecting capital away from individuals with direct knowledge and circumventing it into markets where a coercive monopoly influences behavior ignoring market signals According to Tibor Machan w ithout a market in which allocations can be made in obedience to the law of supply and demand it is difficult or impossible to funnel resources with respect to actual human preferences and goals 33 Historian Robert Vincent Daniels regarded the Stalinist period to represent an abrupt break with Lenin s government in terms of economic planning in which an deliberated scientific system of planning that featured former Menshevik economists at Gosplan had been replaced with a hasty version of planning with unrealistic targets bureaucratic waste bottlenecks and shortages Stalin s formulations of national plans in terms of physical quantity of output was also attributed by Daniels as a source for the stagnant levels of efficiency and quality 34 Suppression of economic democracy and self management edit Main article Socialist democracy Economist Robin Hahnel who supports participatory economics a form of socialist decentralized planned economy notes that even if central planning overcame its inherent inhibitions of incentives and innovation it would nevertheless be unable to maximize economic democracy and self management which he believes are concepts that are more intellectually coherent consistent and just than mainstream notions of economic freedom 35 Furthermore Hahnel states Combined with a more democratic political system and redone to closer approximate a best case version centrally planned economies no doubt would have performed better But they could never have delivered economic self management they would always have been slow to innovate as apathy and frustration took their inevitable toll and they would always have been susceptible to growing inequities and inefficiencies as the effects of differential economic power grew Under central planning neither planners managers nor workers had incentives to promote the social economic interest Nor did impeding markets for final goods to the planning system enfranchise consumers in meaningful ways But central planning would have been incompatible with economic democracy even if it had overcome its information and incentive liabilities And the truth is that it survived as long as it did only because it was propped up by unprecedented totalitarian political power 35 Command economy edit Planned economies contrast with command economies in that a planned economy is an economic system in which the government controls and regulates production distribution prices etc 36 whereas a command economy necessarily has substantial public ownership of industry while also having this type of regulation 37 In command economies important allocation decisions are made by government authorities and are imposed by law 38 This is contested by some Marxists 5 39 Decentralized planning has been proposed as a basis for socialism and has been variously advocated by anarchists council communists libertarian Marxists and other democratic and libertarian socialists who advocate a non market form of socialism in total rejection of the type of planning adopted in the economy of the Soviet Union 40 Most of a command economy is organized in a top down administrative model by a central authority where decisions regarding investment and production output requirements are decided upon at the top in the chain of command with little input from lower levels Advocates of economic planning have sometimes been staunch critics of these command economies Leon Trotsky believed that those at the top of the chain of command regardless of their intellectual capacity operated without the input and participation of the millions of people who participate in the economy and who understand respond to local conditions and changes in the economy Therefore they would be unable to effectively coordinate all economic activity 41 Historians have associated planned economies with Marxist Leninist states and the Soviet economic model Since the 1980s it has been contested that the Soviet economic model did not actually constitute a planned economy in that a comprehensive and binding plan did not guide production and investment 42 The further distinction of an administrative command system emerged as a new designation in some academic circles for the economic system that existed in the former Soviet Union and Eastern Bloc highlighting the role of centralized hierarchical decision making in the absence of popular control over the economy 43 The possibility of a digital planned economy was explored in Chile between 1971 and 1973 with the development of Project Cybersyn and by Aleksandr Aleksandrovich Kharkevich head of the Department of Technical Physics in Kiev in 1962 44 45 While both economic planning and a planned economy can be either authoritarian or democratic and participatory democratic socialist critics argue that command economies are necessarily authoritarian or undemocratic in practice 46 47 Indicative planning is a form of economic planning in market economies that directs the economy through incentive based methods Economic planning can be practiced in a decentralized manner through different government authorities In some predominantly market oriented and Western mixed economies the state utilizes economic planning in strategic industries such as the aerospace industry Mixed economies usually employ macroeconomic planning while micro economic affairs are left to the market and price system Decentralized planning editA decentralized planned economy occasionally called horizontally planned economy due to its horizontalism is a type of planned economy in which the investment and allocation of consumer and capital goods is explicated accordingly to an economy wide plan built and operatively coordinated through a distributed network of disparate economic agents or even production units itself Decentralized planning is usually held in contrast to centralized planning in particular the Soviet type economic planning of the Soviet Union s command economy where economic information is aggregated and used to formulate a plan for production investment and resource allocation by a single central authority Decentralized planning can take shape both in the context of a mixed economy as well as in a post capitalist economic system This form of economic planning implies some process of democratic and participatory decision making within the economy and within firms itself in the form of industrial democracy Computer based forms of democratic economic planning and coordination between economic enterprises have also been proposed by various computer scientists and radical economists 25 7 24 Proponents present decentralized and participatory economic planning as an alternative to market socialism for a post capitalist society 48 Decentralized planning has been a feature of anarchist and socialist economics Variations of decentralized planning such as economic democracy industrial democracy and participatory economics have been promoted by various political groups most notably anarchists democratic socialists guild socialists libertarian Marxists libertarian socialists revolutionary syndicalists and Trotskyists 41 During the Spanish Revolution some areas where anarchist and libertarian socialist influence through the CNT and UGT was extensive particularly rural regions were run on the basis of decentralized planning resembling the principles laid out by anarcho syndicalist Diego Abad de Santillan in the book After the Revolution 49 Models edit Negotiated coordination edit Economist Pat Devine has created a model of decentralized economic planning called negotiated coordination which is based upon social ownership of the means of production by those affected by the use of the assets involved with the allocation of consumer and capital goods made through a participatory form of decision making by those at the most localized level of production 50 Moreover organizations that utilize modularity in their production processes may distribute problem solving and decision making 51 Participatory planning edit See also Participatory economics The planning structure of a decentralized planned economy is generally based on a consumers council and producer council or jointly a distributive cooperative which is sometimes called a consumers cooperative Producers and consumers or their representatives negotiate the quality and quantity of what is to be produced This structure is central to guild socialism participatory economics and the economic theories related to anarchism Practice edit Kerala edit Main article People s Planning in Kerala See also District planning in India Some decentralized participation in economic planning has been implemented in various regions and states in India most notably in Kerala Local level planning agencies assess the needs of people who are able to give their direct input through the Gram Sabhas village based institutions and the planners subsequently seek to plan accordingly 52 Revolutionary Catalonia edit Main article Collectivist anarchism See also Revolutionary Catalonia Some decentralized participation in economic planning has been implemented across Revolutionary Spain most notably in Catalonia during the Spanish Revolution of 1936 19 20 Similar concepts in practice edit Community participatory planning edit Main article Participatory planning The United Nations has developed local projects that promote participatory planning on a community level Members of communities take decisions regarding community development directly citation needed See also editAdhocracy Commanding heights of the economy Communist state Creative destruction Critique of political economy Distributed economy Economic equilibrium Economic interventionism Inclusive democracy Input output model Laissez faire Material balance planning Nationalization Peer to peer economy Production for use Public ownership Resource based economy Social peer to peer processes Steady state economy Technocracy Workers self management The Venus Project Why Socialism an article written by Albert Einstein which presented a critique of modern capitalism and advocated for a planned economy Case studies Soviet type economies Analysis of Soviet type economic planning Eastern Bloc economies Economy of Cuba 53 Economy of North Korea Five year plans of the Soviet Union OGAS a plan for creating a computer network to supervise the Soviet economy Project Cybersyn a project for a computer network controlling the economy of Chile under Salvador Allende Case studies mixed market economies Five year plans of China Dirigisme indicative planning in France Economy of India Economy of Singapore First Malaysia Plan Five year plans of Argentina Five year plans of South KoreaReferences edit Alec Nove 1987 Planned Economy The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics vol 3 p 879 Devine Pat 2010 Democracy and Economic Planning Polity ISBN 978 0745634791 Gregory Paul R Stuart Robert C 2003 Comparing Economic Systems in the Twenty First Century Boston Houghton Mifflin pp 23 24 ISBN 978 0 618 26181 9 Prychito David L 2002 Markets Planning and Democracy Essays After the Collapse of Communism Edward Elgar Publishing p 72 ISBN 978 1840645194 Traditional socialism strives to plan all economic activities comprehensively both within and between enterprises As such it seeks to integrate the economic activities of society the coordination of socially owned property into a single coherent plan rather than to rely upon the spontaneous or anarchic ordering of the market system to coordinate plans a b Mandel Ernest 1986 In Defence of Socialist Planning PDF New Left Review 159 5 37 Archived PDF from the original on 2008 05 16 Planning is not equivalent to perfect allocation of resources nor scientific allocation nor even more humane allocation It simply means direct allocation ex ante As such it is the opposite of market allocation which is ex post Ellman Michael 1989 Socialist Planning Cambridge University Press p 327 ISBN 978 0521358668 S ocialist planning in the original sense of a national economy which replaced market relationships by direct calculation and direct product exchange has nowhere been established a b c Cottrell Allin Cockshott W Paul 1993 Towards a New Socialism Archived 2018 06 27 at the Wayback Machine Nottingham England Spokesman Retrieved 17 March 2012 Zimbalist Sherman and Brown Andrew Howard J and Stuart 1988 Comparing Economic Systems A Political Economic Approach Harcourt College Pub p 4 ISBN 978 0 15 512403 5 Almost all industry in the Soviet Union is government owned and all production is directed in theory by a central plan though in practice much is left for local discretion and much happens that is unplanned or not under government control a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Wilhelm John Howard 1985 The Soviet Union Has an Administered Not a Planned Economy Soviet Studies 37 1 118 130 doi 10 1080 09668138508411571 Ellman Michael 2007 The Rise and Fall of Socialist Planning In Estrin Saul Kolodko Grzegorz W Uvalic Milica eds Transition and Beyond Essays in Honour of Mario Nuti New York Palgrave Macmillan p 22 ISBN 978 0 230 54697 4 In the USSR in the late 1980s the system was normally referred to as the administrative command economy What was fundamental to this system was not the plan but the role of administrative hierarchies at all levels of decision making the absence of control over decision making by the population Heichelheim Friedrich Moritz 1949 Commerce Greek and Roman In Hammond Nicholas G L Scullard H H eds The Oxford Classical Dictionary 2 ed Oxford Oxford University Press published 1970 p 274 ISBN 0198691173 La Lone Darrell E 1982 The Inca as a Nonmarket Economy Supply on Command versus Supply and Demand Contexts for Prehistoric Exchange 292 Archived from the original on 19 October 2020 Retrieved 17 December 2018 Blaug Mark ed 1991 The Early mercantilists Thomas Mun 1571 1641 Edward Misselden 1608 1634 Gerard de Malynes 1586 1623 Pioneers in economics E Elgar Pub Co p 136 ISBN 978 1852784669 Retrieved 7 September 2018 To this approach belongs at least in part an attempt to view mercantilism as economic dirigee a planned economy with national economic objectives wealth plenty or simply welfare within the framework of the nation and at the expense of other nations Twiss Thomas M 2014 Trotsky and the Problem of Soviet Bureaucracy Brill pp 88 113 ISBN 978 90 04 26953 8 Archived from the original on 2023 07 26 Retrieved 2023 10 27 Day Richard B 1973 Leon Trotsky and the Politics of Economic Isolation Cambridge University Press p 109 ISBN 978 0 521 52436 0 Archived from the original on 2023 07 26 Retrieved 2023 10 27 Deutscher Isaac 1965 The prophet unarmed Trotsky 1921 1929 New York Vintage Books p 468 ISBN 978 0 394 70747 1 Rogovin Vadim Zakharovich 2021 Was There an Alternative Trotskyism a Look Back Through the Years Mehring Books pp 404 405 ISBN 978 1 893638 97 6 Fitzpatrick Sheila 22 April 2010 The Old Man London Review of Books 32 8 ISSN 0260 9592 Archived from the original on 3 February 2024 Retrieved 3 February 2024 a b Wetzel Tom Workers Power and the Spanish Revolution Archived 2020 11 07 at the Wayback Machine a b Dolgoff Sam ed 1974 The Anarchist Collectives 1st ed Free Life Editions p 114 ISBN 978 0914156024 Einstein Albert May 1949 Why Socialism Archived 2011 03 17 at the Wayback Machine Monthly Review Feinstein C H 1975 Socialism Capitalism and Economic Growth Essays Presented to Maurice Dobb Cambridge University Press p 174 ISBN 0 521 29007 4 We have presented the view that planning and market mechanisms are instruments that can be used both in socialist and non socialist societies It was important to explode the primitive identification of central planning and socialism and to stress the instrumental character of planning Kitov Vladimir A Shilov Valery V Silantiev Sergey A 5 October 2016 Trente ans ou la Vie d un scientifique In Gadducci Fabio Tavosanis Mirko eds History and Philosophy of Computing Third International Conference HaPoC 2015 Pisa Italy October 8 11 2015 Revised Selected Papers Volume 487 of IFIP Advances in Information and Communication Technology Cham Switzerland Springer published 2016 p 191 ISBN 978 3319472867 ISSN 1868 4238 Retrieved 12 September 2021 Measures to overcome the shortcomings in the development production and introduction of computers in the Armed Forces and national economy Today this project is known among the specialists as the Red Book project It was the first project in the USSR which proposed to combine all the computers in the country into a unified network of compter centers In peacetime this network must have fulfilled both national economic and defense tasks a b Eden Medina 2006 Designing Freedom Regulating a Nation Socialist Cybernetics in Allende s Chile J Lat Am Stud Cambridge University Press 38 38 571 606 doi 10 1017 S0022216X06001179 S2CID 26484124 a b Lange Oskar 1979 The Computer and the Market Calculemus org Archived from the original on 17 April 2021 Retrieved 12 September 2012 Cyberfolk Project Cybersyn Archived 12 May 2011 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 6 August 2020 Ellman Michael 2014 Socialist Planning Cambridge University Press p 372 ISBN 978 1107427327 Archived from the original on 2024 02 07 Retrieved 2020 11 02 For the USSR the official Soviet statistics of infant mortality give too favourable a picture There are two reasons for this First the USSR used a definition of birth different from the WHO one Chapter 8 pp 321 322 The percentage increase in the infant mortality rate caused by switching from the Soviet definition to the WHO one seems to have ranged from 13 per cent in Moldova to 40 per cent in Latvia In Poland which has a much larger population than the two previously mentioned countries it was about 21 per cent Secondly there seems to have been significant under registration of deaths particularly in certain regions such as Central Asia and Azerbaijan Estimates of true infant mortality in 1987 2000 show very high increases over the official figures in Central Asia Azerbaijan Albania Romania and Bulgaria In Russia which was supposed to have adopted the WHO definition of birth by 1993 and where under registration is much less than in Central Asia or Azerbaijan in 1987 2000 the estimated increase of the official figures to measure true infant mortality is 26 5 percent Kennedy Paul 1987 The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers New York Random House pp 322 323 ISBN 0 394 54674 1 Zielinski J G 1973 Economic Reforms in Polish Industry New York Oxford University Press ISBN 0 19 215323 4 Von Mises Ludwig 1990 Economic calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth PDF Ludwig von Mises Institute Archived from the original PDF on 16 December 2014 Retrieved 8 September 2008 Hayek Friedrich A 1945 The Use of Knowledge American Economic Review XXXV 4 pp 519 530 Biro Gabor 2022 From Red Spirit to Underperforming Pyramids and Coercive Institutions Michael Polanyi Against Economic Planning History of European Ideas 2022 History of European Ideas 48 6 811 847 doi 10 1080 01916599 2021 2009359 S2CID 225260656 Archived from the original on 2022 08 16 Retrieved 2022 08 16 Machan Tibor 2002 Some Skeptical Reflections on Research and Development PDF Liberty and Research and Development Science Funding in a Free Society Hoover Press ISBN 0 8179 2942 8 Archived PDF from the original on 2006 10 31 Daniels Robert V 2002 The End of the Communist Revolution Routledge pp 90 92 ISBN 978 1 134 92607 7 Archived from the original on 2023 11 07 Retrieved 2023 10 30 a b Hahnel Robin 2002 The ABC s of Political Economy London Pluto Press p 262 ISBN 0 7453 1858 4 Planned economy Archived 2007 02 28 at the Wayback Machine Dictionary com Unabridged v 1 1 Random House Inc Retrieved 11 May 2008 Command economy Archived 2007 01 24 at the Wayback Machine Merriam Webster Online Dictionary Retrieved 11 May 2008 Rosser Mariana V Rosser J Barkley 2003 Comparative Economics in a Transforming World Economy MIT Press p 7 ISBN 978 0 262 18234 8 In a command economy the most important allocation decisions are made by government authorities and are imposed by law Schweickart David Lawler James Ticktin Hillel Ollman Bertell 1998 Definitions of Market and Socialism Market Socialism The Debate Among Socialists New York Routledge pp 58 59 ISBN 978 0 415 91967 8 For an Anti Stalinist Marxist socialism is defined by the degree to which the society is planned Planning here is understood as the conscious regulation of society by the associated producers themselves Put it differently the control over the surplus product rests with the majority of the population through a resolutely democratic process The sale of labour power is abolished and labour necessarily becomes creative Everyone participates in running their institutions and society as a whole No one controls anyone else Schweickart David 2007 Democratic Socialism In Anderson Gary L Herr Kathryn G eds Encyclopedia of Activism and Social Justice Sage Publications p 448 ISBN 978 1452265650 Archived 17 June 2012 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 6 August 2020 Virtually all socialists have distanced themselves from the economic model long synonymous with socialism i e the Soviet model of a nonmarket centrally planned economy Some have endorsed the concept of market socialism a postcapitalist economy that retains market competition but socializes the means of production and in some versions extends democracy to the workplace Some hold out for a nonmarket participatory economy All democratic socialists agree on the need for a democratic alternative to capitalism a b Trotsky Leon Writings 1932 33 p 96 Wilhelm John Howard 1985 The Soviet Union Has an Administered Not a Planned Economy Soviet Studies 37 1 118 130 doi 10 1080 09668138508411571 Ellman Michael 2007 The Rise and Fall of Socialist Planning In Estrin Saul Kolodko Grzegorz W Uvalic Milica eds Transition and Beyond Essays in Honour of Mario Nuti New York Palgrave Macmillan p 22 ISBN 978 0 230 54697 4 Realization of these facts led in the 1970s and 1980s to the development of new terms to describe what had previously been and still were in United Nations publications referred to as the centrally planned economies In the USSR in the late 1980s the system was normally referred to as the administrative command economy What was fundamental to this system was not the plan but the role of administrative hierarchies at all levels of decision making the absence of control over decision making by the population Machine of communism Why the USSR did not create the Internet Archived 2022 03 08 at the Wayback Machine Kharkevich Aleksandr Aleksandrovich 1973 Theory of information The identification of the images Selected works in three volumes Volume 3 Information and technology Moscow Publishing House Nauka 1973 Academy of Sciences of the USSR Institute of information transmission problems p 524 Busky Donald F 2000 Democratic Socialism A Global Survey Praeger pp 7 8 ISBN 978 0275968861 Sometimes simply called socialism more often than not the adjective democratic is added by democratic socialists to attempt to distinguish themselves from Communists who also call themselves socialists All but communists or more accurately Marxist Leninists believe that modern day communism is highly undemocratic and totalitarian in practice and democratic socialists wish to emphasise by their name that they disagree strongly with the Marxist Leninist brand of socialism Prychito David L 2002 Markets Planning and Democracy Essays After the Collapse of Communism Edward Elgar Publishing p 72 ISBN 978 1840645194 It is perhaps less clearly understood that advocates of democratic socialism who are committed to socialism in the above sense but opposed to Stalinist style command planning advocate a decentralized socialism whereby the planning process itself the integration of all productive units into one huge organisation would follow the workers self management principle Kotz David 2008 What Economic Structure for Socialism PDF Archived PDF from the original on 2011 01 02 Retrieved 12 September 2012 After the Revolution Membres multimania fr 7 January 1936 Archived from the original on 29 August 2012 Retrieved 12 September 2012 Participatory Planning Through Negotiated Coordination PDF 1 March 2002 Archived PDF from the original on 2011 08 17 Retrieved 30 October 2011 Kostakis Vasilis 2019 How to Reap the Benefits of the Digital Revolution Modularity and the Commons Archived 2023 06 19 at the Wayback Machine Halduskultuur The Estonian Journal of Administrative Culture and Digital Governance 20 1 4 19 Sivaramakrishnan K C 2006 People s Participation in Urban Governance A Comparative Study of the Working of Wards Committees in Karnataka Kerala Maharashtra and West Bengal New Delhi Concept Publishing Company p 140 ISBN 8180693260 Crittenden Ann 18 December 1977 The Cuban Economy How It Works The New York Times Archived from the original on 29 June 2018 Retrieved 29 June 2018 Further reading editKaplan Robert see reference to his work on International Economics and Foreign Relations where he addresses nature of command economy a Weberian term Cox Robin 2005 The Economic Calculation Controversy Unravelling of a Myth Common Voice 3 Damier Vadim 2012 The Economy of Freedom Devine Pat 2010 Democracy and Economic Planning Polity ISBN 978 0745634791 Ellman Michael 2014 Socialist Planning 3rd ed Cambridge University Press ISBN 1107427320 Grossman Gregory 1987 Command economy The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics 1 pp 494 495 Landauer Carl 1947 Theory of National Economic Planning 2nd ed Berkeley and Los Angeles California University of California Press Mandel Ernest 1986 In Defence of Socialist Planning New Left Review 159 Myant Martin Drahokoupil Jan 2010 Transition Economies Political Economy in Russia Eastern Europe and Central Asia Wiley Blackwell ISBN 978 0 470 59619 7 Nove Alec 1987 Planned economy The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics 3 pp 879 885 External links edit nbsp Wikiquote has quotations related to Planned Economy The Myth of the Permanent Arms Economy The Stalin Model for the Control and Coordination of Enterprises in a Socialist Economy Archived 2021 01 26 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Planned economy amp oldid 1204777595 Central planning, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.