fbpx
Wikipedia

Surplus value

In Marxian economics, surplus value is the difference between the amount raised through a sale of a product and the amount it cost to manufacture it: i.e. the amount raised through sale of the product minus the cost of the materials, plant and labour power. The concept originated in Ricardian socialism, with the term "surplus value" itself being coined by William Thompson in 1824; however, it was not consistently distinguished from the related concepts of surplus labor and surplus product. The concept was subsequently developed and popularized by Karl Marx. Marx's formulation is the standard sense and the primary basis for further developments, though how much of Marx's concept is original and distinct from the Ricardian concept is disputed (see § Origin). Marx's term is the German word "Mehrwert", which simply means value added (sales revenue minus the cost of materials used up), and is cognate to English "more worth".

It is a major concept in Karl Marx's critique of political economy. Conventionally, value-added is equal to the sum of gross wage income and gross profit income. However, Marx uses the term Mehrwert to describe the yield, profit or return on production capital invested, i.e. the amount of the increase in the value of capital. Hence, Marx's use of Mehrwert has always been translated as "surplus value", distinguishing it from "value-added". According to Marx's theory, surplus value is equal to the new value created by workers in excess of their own labor-cost, which is appropriated by the capitalist as profit when products are sold.[1][2] Marx thought that the gigantic increase in wealth and population from the 19th century onwards was mainly due to the competitive striving to obtain maximum surplus-value from the employment of labor, resulting in an equally gigantic increase of productivity and capital resources. To the extent that increasingly the economic surplus is convertible into money and expressed in money, the amassment of wealth is possible on a larger and larger scale (see capital accumulation and surplus product). The concept is closely connected to producer surplus.

Origin Edit

By the Age of Enlightenment in the 18th century the French physiocrats were already writing on the surplus value that was being extracted from labor by "the employer, the owner, and all exploiters" although they used the term net product.[3] The concept of surplus value continued to be developed under Adam Smith who also used the term "net product" while his successors the Ricardian socialists, began using the term "surplus value" decades later after its coinage by William Thompson in 1824.

Two measures of the value of this use, here present themselves; the measure of the laborer, and the measure of the capitalist. The measure of the laborer consists in the contribution of such sums as would replace the waste and value of the capital by the time it would be consumed, with such added compensation to the owner and superintendent of it as would support him in equal comfort with the more actively employed productive laborers. The measure of the capitalist, on the contrary, would be the additional value produced by the same quantity of labor in consequence of the use of the machinery or other capital; the whole of such surplus value to be enjoyed by the capitalist for his superior intelligence and skill in accumulating and advancing to the laborers his capital or the use of it.

— William Thompson, An Inquiry into the Principles of the Distribution of Wealth (1824), p. 128 (2nd ed.), emphasis added

William Godwin and Charles Hall are also credited as earlier developers of the concept. Early authors also used the terms "surplus labor" and "surplus produce" (in Marx's language, surplus product), which have distinct meanings in Marxian economics: surplus labor produces surplus product, which has surplus value. Some authors consider Marx as completely borrowing from Thompson, notably Anton Menger:

... Marx is completely under the influence of the earlier English socialists, and more particularly of William Thompson. ... [T]he whole theory of surplus value, its conception, its name, and the estimates of its amounts are borrowed in all essentials from Thompson's writings.

...

Cf. Marx, Das Kapital, English trans. 1887, pp. 156, 194, 289, with Thompson, Distribution of Wealth, p. 163; 2nd ed. p. 125. ... The real discovers of the theory of surplus value are Godwin, Hall, and especially W. Thompson.

— Anton Menger, The Right to the Whole Produce of Labour (1886),[4] p. 101

This claim of priority has been vigorously contested, notably in an article by Friedrich Engels, completed by Karl Kautsky and published anonymously in 1887, reacting to and criticizing Menger in a review of his The Right to the Whole Produce of Labour, arguing that there is nothing in common but the term "surplus value" itself.[5]

An intermediate position acknowledges the early development by Ricardian socialists and others, but credits Marx with substantial development. For example:[6][a]

What is original in Marx is the explanation of the manner in which surplus value is produced.

— John Spargo, Socialism (1906)

Johann Karl Rodbertus developed a theory of surplus value in the 1830s and 1840s, notably in Zur Erkenntnis unserer staatswirthschaftlichen Zustände (Toward an appreciation of our economic circumstances, 1842), and claimed earlier priority to Marx, specifically to have "shown practically in the same way as Marx, only more briefly and clearly, the source of the surplus value of the capitalists". The debate, taking the side of Marx's priority, is detailed in the Preface to Capital, Volume II by Engels.

Marx first elaborated his doctrine of surplus value in 1857–58 manuscripts of A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy (1859), following earlier developments in his 1840s writings.[7] It forms the subject of his 1862–63 manuscript Theories of Surplus Value (which was subsequently published as Capital, Volume IV), and features in his Capital, Volume I (1867).

Theory Edit

The problem of explaining the source of surplus value is expressed by Friedrich Engels as follows:

"Whence comes this surplus-value? It cannot come either from the buyer buying the commodities under their value, or from the seller selling them above their value. For in both cases the gains and the losses of each individual cancel each other, as each individual is in turn buyer and seller. Nor can it come from cheating, for though cheating can enrich one person at the expense of another, it cannot increase the total sum possessed by both, and therefore cannot augment the sum of the values in circulation. (...) This problem must be solved, and it must be solved in a purely economic way, excluding all cheating and the intervention of any force — the problem being: how is it possible constantly to sell dearer than one has bought, even on the hypothesis that equal values are always exchanged for equal values?"[8]

Marx's solution was first to distinguish between labor-time worked and labor power, and secondly to distinguish between absolute surplus value and relative surplus value. A worker who is sufficiently productive can produce an output value greater than what it costs to hire him. Although his wage seems to be based on hours worked, in an economic sense this wage does not reflect the full value of what the worker produces. Effectively it is not labour which the worker sells, but his capacity to work.

Imagine a worker who is hired for an hour and paid $10 per hour. Once in the capitalist's employ, the capitalist can have him operate a boot-making machine with which the worker produces $10 worth of work every 15 minutes. Every hour, the capitalist receives $40 worth of work and only pays the worker $10, capturing the remaining $30 as gross revenue. Once the capitalist has deducted fixed and variable operating costs of (say) $20 (leather, depreciation of the machine, etc.), he is left with $10. Thus, for an outlay of capital of $30, the capitalist obtains a surplus value of $10; his capital has not only been replaced by the operation, but also has increased by $10.

This "simple" exploitation characterizes the realization of absolute surplus value, which is then claimed by the capitalist. The worker cannot capture this benefit directly because he has no claim to the means of production (e.g. the boot-making machine) or to its products, and his capacity to bargain over wages is restricted by laws and the supply/demand for wage labour. This form of exploitation was well understood by pre-Marxian Socialists and left-wing followers of Ricardo, such as Proudhon, and by early labor organizers, who sought to unite workers in unions capable of collective bargaining, in order to gain a share of profits and limit the length of the working day.[9]

Relative surplus value is not created in a single enterprise or site of production. It arises instead from the total relation between multiple enterprises and multiple branches of industry when the necessary labor-time of production is reduced, effecting a change in the value of labor-power. For example, when new technology or new business practices increase the productivity of labor a capitalist already employs, or when the commodities necessary for workers' subsistence fall in value, the amount of socially necessary labor-time is decreased, the value of labor-power is reduced, and a relative surplus value is realized as profit for the capitalist, increasing the overall general rate of surplus value in the total economy.

The surplus-value produced by prolongation of the working day, I call absolute surplus-value. On the other hand, the surplus-value arising from the curtailment of the necessary labour-time, and from the corresponding alteration in the respective lengths of the two components of the working day, I call relative surplus-value.

In order to effect a fall in the value of labour-power, the increase in the productiveness of labour must seize upon those branches of industry whose products determine the value of labour-power, and consequently either belong to the class of customary means of subsistence, or are capable of supplying the place of those means. But the value of a commodity is determined, not only by the quantity of labour which the labourer directly bestows upon that commodity, but also by the labour contained in the means of production. For instance, the value of a pair of boots depends not only on the cobbler’s labour, but also on the value of the leather, wax, thread, &c. Hence, a fall in the value of labour-power is also brought about by an increase in the productiveness of labour, and by a corresponding cheapening of commodities in those industries which supply the instruments of labour and the raw material, that form the material elements of the constant capital required for producing the necessaries of life.

— Marx, Capital Vol. 1, ch. 12, "The Concept of Relative Surplus-Value" [10]

Definition Edit

Total surplus-value in an economy (Marx refers to the mass or volume of surplus-value) is basically equal to the sum of net distributed and undistributed profit, net interest, net rents, net tax on production and various net receipts associated with royalties, licensing, leasing, certain honorariums etc. (see also value product). Of course, the way generic profit income is grossed and netted in social accounting may differ somewhat from the way an individual business does that (see also Operating surplus).

Marx's own discussion focuses mainly on profit, interest and rent, largely ignoring taxation and royalty-type fees which were proportionally very small components of the national income when he lived. Over the last 150 years, however, the role of the state in the economy has increased in almost every country in the world. Around 1850, the average share of government spending in GDP (See also Government spending) in the advanced capitalist economies was around 5%; in 1870, a bit above 8%; on the eve of World War I, just under 10%; just before the outbreak of World War II, around 20%; by 1950, nearly 30%; and today the average is around 35–40%. (see for example Alan Turner Peacock, "The growth of public expenditure", in Encyclopedia of Public Choice, Springer 2003, pp. 594–597).

Interpretations Edit

Surplus-value may be viewed in five ways:

  • As a component of the new value product, which Marx himself defines as equal to the sum of labor costs in respect of capitalistically productive labor (variable capital) and surplus-value. In production, he argues, the workers produce a value equal to their wages plus an additional value, the surplus-value. They also transfer part of the value of fixed assets and materials to the new product, equal to economic depreciation (consumption of fixed capital) and intermediate goods used up (constant capital inputs). Labor costs and surplus-value are the monetary valuations of what Marx calls the necessary product and the surplus product, or paid labour and unpaid labour.
  • Surplus-value can also be viewed as a flow of net income appropriated by the owners of capital in virtue of asset ownership, comprising both distributed personal income and undistributed business income. In the whole economy, this will include both income directly from production and property income.
  • Surplus-value can be viewed as the source of society's accumulation fund or investment fund; part of it is re-invested, but part is appropriated as personal income, and used for consumptive purposes by the owners of capital assets (see capital accumulation); in exceptional circumstances, part of it may also be hoarded in some way. In this context, surplus value can also be measured as the increase in the value of the stock of capital assets through an accounting period, prior to distribution.
  • Surplus-value can be viewed as a social relation of production, or as the monetary valuation of surplus-labour – a sort of "index" of the balance of power between social classes or nations in the process of the division of the social product.
  • Surplus-value can, in a developed capitalist economy, be viewed also as an indicator of the level of social productivity that has been reached by the working population, i.e. the net amount of value it can produce with its labour in excess of its own consumption requirements.

Equalization of rates Edit

Marx believed that the long-term historical tendency would be for differences in rates of surplus value between enterprises and economic sectors to level out, as Marx explains in two places in Capital Vol. 3:

"If capitals that set in motion unequal quantities of living labour produce unequal amounts of surplus-value, this assumes that the level of exploitation of labour, or the rate of surplus-value, is the same, at least to a certain extent, or that the distinctions that exist here are balanced out by real or imaginary (conventional) grounds of compensation. This assumes competition among workers, and an equalization that takes place by their constant migration between one sphere of production and another. Assume a general rate of surplus value of this kind, as a tendency, like all economic laws, as a theoretical simplification; but in any case this is in practice an actual presupposition of the capitalist mode of production, even if inhibited to a greater or lesser extent by practical frictions that produce more or less significant local differences, such as the settlement laws for agricultural labourers in England, for example. In theory, we assume that the laws of the capitalist mode of production develop in their pure form. In reality, this is only an approximation; but that approximation is all the more exact, the more the capitalist mode of production is developed and the less it is adulterated by survivals of earlier economic conditions with which it is amalgamated " – Capital Vol. 3, ch. 10, Pelican edition p. 275.[11]

Hence, he assumed a uniform rate of surplus value in his models of how surplus value would be shared out under competitive conditions.

Appropriation from production Edit

Both in Das Kapital and in preparatory manuscripts such as the Grundrisse and Results of the immediate process of production, Marx asserts that commerce by stages transforms a non-capitalist production process into a capitalist production process, integrating it fully into markets, so that all inputs and outputs become marketed goods or services. When that process is complete, according to Marx, the whole of production has become simultaneously a labor process creating use-values and a valorisation process creating new value, and more specifically a surplus-value appropriated as net income (see also capital accumulation).[citation needed]

Marx contends that the whole purpose of production in this situation becomes the growth of capital; i.e. that production of output becomes conditional on capital accumulation.[citation needed] If production becomes unprofitable, capital will be withdrawn from production sooner or later.

The implication is that the main driving force of capitalism becomes the quest to maximise the appropriation of surplus-value augmenting the stock of capital. The overriding motive behind efforts to economise resources and labor would thus be to obtain the maximum possible increase in income and capital assets ("business growth"), and provide a steady or growing return on investment.

Absolute vs. relative Edit

According to Marx, absolute surplus value is obtained by increasing the amount of time worked per worker in an accounting period.[12] Marx talks mainly about the length of the working day or week, but in modern times the concern is about the number of hours worked per year.

In many parts of the world, as productivity rose, the workweek decreased from 60 hours to 50, 40 or 35 hours.

Relative surplus value is obtained mainly by:

  • reducing wages[13] — this can only go to a certain point, because if wages fall below the ability of workers to purchase their means of subsistence, they will be unable to reproduce themselves and the capitalists will not be able to find sufficient labor power.
  • reducing the cost of wage-goods by various means, so that wage increases can be curbed.[14]
  • increasing the productivity and intensity[citation needed] of labour generally, through mechanisation and rationalisation, yielding a bigger output per hour worked.

The attempt to extract more and more surplus-value from labor on the one side, and on the other side the resistance to this exploitation, are according to Marx at the core of the conflict between social classes, which is sometimes muted or hidden, but at other times erupts in open class warfare and class struggle.

Production versus realisation Edit

Marx distinguished sharply between value and price, in part because of the sharp distinction he draws between the production of surplus-value and the realisation of profit income (see also value-form). Output may be produced containing surplus-value (valorisation), but selling that output (realisation) is not at all an automatic process.

Until payment from sales is received, it is uncertain how much of the surplus-value produced will actually be realised as profit from sales. So, the magnitude of profit realised in the form of money and the magnitude of surplus-value produced in the form of products may differ greatly, depending on what happens to market prices and the vagaries of supply and demand fluctuations. This insight forms the basis of Marx's theory of market value, prices of production and the tendency of the rate of profit of different enterprises to be levelled out by competition.

In his published and unpublished manuscripts, Marx went into great detail to examine many different factors which could affect the production and realisation of surplus-value. He regarded this as crucial for the purpose of understanding the dynamics and dimensions of capitalist competition, not just business competition but also competition between capitalists and workers and among workers themselves. But his analysis did not go much beyond specifying some of the overall outcomes of the process.

His main conclusion though is that employers will aim to maximise the productivity of labour and economise on the use of labour, to reduce their unit-costs and maximise their net returns from sales at current market prices; at a given ruling market price for an output, every reduction of costs and every increase in productivity and sales turnover will increase profit income for that output. The main method is mechanisation, which raises the fixed capital outlay in investment.

In turn, this causes the unit-values of commodities to decline over time, and a decline of the average rate of profit in the sphere of production occurs, culminating in a crisis of capital accumulation, in which a sharp reduction in productive investments combines with mass unemployment, followed by an intensive rationalisation process of take-overs, mergers, fusions, and restructuring aiming to restore profitability.

Relation to taxation Edit

 
S&P 500 dividends and buybacks vs. Federal and State tax collections
  State tax revenue
  Federal tax revenue
  S&P 500 Stock buyback
  S&P 500 Dividends

In general, business leaders and investors are hostile to any attempts to encroach on total profit volume, especially those of government taxation.[citation needed] The lower taxes are, other things being equal, the bigger the mass of profit that can be distributed as income to private investors. It was tax revolts that originally were a powerful stimulus motivating the bourgeoisie to wrest state power from the feudal aristocracy at the beginning of the capitalist era.[citation needed]

In reality, of course, a substantial portion of tax money is also redistributed to private enterprise in the form of government contracts and subsidies.[citation needed] Capitalists may therefore be in conflict among themselves about taxes, since what is a cost to some, is a source of profit to others.[citation needed] Marx never analysed all this in detail; but the concept of surplus value will apply mainly to taxes on gross income (personal and business income from production) and on the trade in products and services.[citation needed] Estate duty for example rarely contains a surplus value component, although profit could be earned in the transfer of the estate.[citation needed]

Generally, Marx seems to have regarded taxation imposts as a "form" which disguised real product values. Apparently following this view, Ernest Mandel in his 1960 treatise Marxist Economic Theory refers to (indirect) taxes as "arbitrary additions to commodity prices". But this is something of a misnomer, and disregards that taxes become part of the normal cost-structure of production. In his later treatise on late capitalism, Mandel astonishingly hardly mentions the significance of taxation at all, a very serious omission from the point of view of the real world of modern capitalism since taxes can reach a magnitude of a third, or even half of GDP (see E. Mandel, Late Capitalism. London: Verso, 1975).For example in the United Kingdom alone 75% of all taxation revenue comes from just three taxes Income tax, National insurance and VAT which in reality is 75% of the GDP of the country.

Relation to the circuits of capital Edit

Generally, Marx focused in Das Kapital on the new surplus-value generated by production, and the distribution of this surplus value. In this way, he aimed to reveal the "origin of the wealth of nations" given a capitalist mode of production. However, in any real economy, a distinction must be drawn between the primary circuit of capital, and the secondary circuits. To some extent, national accounts also do this.

The primary circuit refers to the incomes and products generated and distributed from productive activity (reflected by GDP). The secondary circuits refer to trade, transfers and transactions occurring outside that sphere, which can also generate incomes, and these incomes may also involve the realisation of a surplus-value or profit.

It is true that Marx argues no net additions to value can be created through acts of exchange, economic value being an attribute of labour-products (previous or newly created) only. Nevertheless, trading activity outside the sphere of production can obviously also yield a surplus-value which represents a transfer of value from one person, country or institution to another.

A very simple example would be if somebody sold a second-hand asset at a profit. This transaction is not recorded in gross product measures (after all, it isn't new production), nevertheless a surplus-value is obtained from it. Another example would be capital gains from property sales. Marx occasionally refers to this kind of profit as profit upon alienation, alienation being used here in the juridical, not sociological sense. By implication, if we just focused on surplus-value newly created in production, we would underestimate total surplus-values realised as income in a country. This becomes obvious if we compare census estimates of income & expenditure with GDP data.

This is another reason why surplus-value produced and surplus-value realised are two different things, although this point is largely ignored in the economics literature. But it becomes highly important when the real growth of production stagnates, and a growing portion of capital shifts out of the sphere of production in search of surplus-value from other deals.

Nowadays the volume of world trade grows significantly faster than GDP, suggesting to Marxian economists such as Samir Amin that surplus-value realised from commercial trade (representing to a large extent a transfer of value by intermediaries between producers and consumers) grows faster than surplus-value realised directly from production.

Thus, if we took the final price of a good (the cost to the final consumer) and analysed the cost structure of that good, we might find that, over a period of time, the direct producers get less income and intermediaries between producers and consumers (traders) get more income from it. That is, control over the access to a good, asset or resource as such may increasingly become a very important factor in realising a surplus-value. In the worst case, this amounts to parasitism or extortion. This analysis illustrates a key feature of surplus value which is that it accumulated by the owners of capital only within inefficient markets because only inefficient markets – i.e. those in which transparency and competition are low – have profit margins large enough to facilitate capital accumulation. Ironically, profitable – meaning inefficient – markets have difficulty meeting the definition a free market because a free market is to some extent defined as an efficient one: one in which goods or services are exchanged without coercion or fraud, or in other words with competition (to prevent monopolistic coercion) and transparency (to prevent fraud).

Measurement Edit

The first attempt to measure the rate of surplus-value in money-units was by Marx himself in chapter 9 of Das Kapital, using factory data of a spinning mill supplied by Friedrich Engels (though Marx credits "a Manchester spinner"). Both in published and unpublished manuscripts, Marx examines variables affecting the rate and mass of surplus-value in detail.

Some Marxian economists argue that Marx thought the possibility of measuring surplus value depends on the publicly available data. We can develop statistical indicators of trends, without mistakenly conflating data with the real thing they represent, or postulating "perfect measurements or perfect data" in the empiricist manner.

Since early studies by Marxian economists like Eugen Varga, Charles Bettelheim, Joseph Gillmann, Edward Wolff and Shane Mage, there have been numerous attempts by Marxian economists to measure the trend in surplus-value statistically using national accounts data. The most convincing modern attempt is probably that of Anwar Shaikh and Ahmet Tonak.[15]

Usually this type of research involves reworking the components of the official measures of gross output and capital outlays to approximate Marxian categories, in order to estimate empirically the trends in the ratios thought important in the Marxian explanation of capital accumulation and economic growth: the rate of surplus-value, the organic composition of capital, the rate of profit, the rate of increase in the capital stock, and the rate of reinvestment of realised surplus-value in production.

The Marxian mathematicians Emmanuel Farjoun and Moshé Machover argue that "even if the rate of surplus value has changed by 10–20% over a hundred years, the real problem [to explain] is why it has changed so little" (quoted from The Laws of Chaos: A Probabilistic Approach to Political Economy (1983), p. 192). The answer to that question must, in part, be sought in artifacts (statistical distortion effects) of data collection procedures. Mathematical extrapolations are ultimately based on the data available, but that data itself may be fragmentary and not the "complete picture".

Different conceptions Edit

In neo-Marxist thought, Paul A. Baran for example substitutes the concept of "economic surplus" for Marx's surplus value. In a joint work, Paul Baran and Paul Sweezy define the economic surplus as "the difference between what a society produces and the costs of producing it" (Monopoly Capitalism, New York 1966, p. 9). Much depends here on how the costs are valued, and which costs are taken into account. Piero Sraffa also refers to a "physical surplus" with a similar meaning, calculated according to the relationship between prices of physical inputs and outputs.

In these theories, surplus product and surplus value are equated, while value and price are identical, but the distribution of the surplus tends to be separated theoretically from its production; whereas Marx insists that the distribution of wealth is governed by the social conditions in which it is produced, especially by property relations giving entitlement to products, incomes and assets (see also relations of production).

In Kapital Vol. 3, Marx insists strongly that

"the specific economic form, in which unpaid surplus labour is pumped out of direct producers, determines the relationship of rulers and ruled, as it grows directly out of production itself and, in turn, reacts upon it as a determining element. Upon this, however, is founded the entire formation of the economic community which grows up out of the production relations themselves, thereby simultaneously its specific political form. It is always the direct relationship of the owners of the conditions of production to the direct producers – a relation always naturally corresponding to a definite stage of the methods of labour and thereby its social productivity – which reveals the innermost secret, the hidden basis of the entire social structure, and with it the political form of the relation of sovereignty and dependence, in short, the corresponding specific form of the state. This does not prevent the same economic basis – the same from the standpoint of its main conditions – due to innumerable different, empirical circumstances, natural environment, racial relations, external historical influence, etc. from showing infinite variations and gradations in appearance, which can be ascertained only by analysis of the empirically given circumstances."[16]

This is a substantive – if abstract – thesis about the basic social relations involved in giving and getting, taking and receiving in human society, and their consequences for the way work and wealth is shared out. It suggests a starting point for an inquiry into the problem of social order and social change. But obviously it is only a starting point, not the whole story, which would include all the "variations and gradations".

Morality and power Edit

A textbook-type example of an alternative interpretation to Marx's is provided by Lester Thurow. He argues:[17] "In a capitalistic society, profits – and losses – hold center stage." But what, he asks, explains profits?

There are five reasons for profit, according to Thurow:

  • capitalists are willing to delay their own personal gratification, and profit is their reward.
  • some profits are a return to those who take risks.
  • some profits are a return to organizational ability, enterprise, and entrepreneurial energy
  • some profits are economic rents – a firm that has a monopoly in producing some product or service can set a price higher than would be set in a competitive market and, thus, earn higher than normal returns.
  • some profits are due to market imperfections – they arise when goods are traded above their competitive equilibrium price.

The problem here is that Thurow doesn't really provide an objective explanation of profits so much as a moral justification for profits, i.e. as a legitimate entitlement or claim, in return for the supply of capital.

He adds that "Attempts have been made to organize productive societies without the profit motive (...) [but] since the industrial revolution... there have been essentially no successful economies that have not taken advantage of the profit motive." The problem here is again a moral judgement, dependent on what you mean by success. Some societies using the profit motive were ruined; profit is no guarantee of success, although you can say that it has powerfully stimulated economic growth.

Thurow goes on to note that "When it comes to actually measuring profits, some difficult accounting issues arise." Why? Because after deduction of costs from gross income, "It is hard to say exactly how much must be reinvested to maintain the size of the capital stock". Ultimately, Thurow implies, the tax department is the arbiter of the profit volume, because it determines depreciation allowances and other costs which capitalists may annually deduct in calculating taxable gross income.

This is obviously a theory very different from Marx's. In Thurow's theory, the aim of business is to maintain the capital stock. In Marx's theory, competition, desire and market fluctuations create the striving and pressure to increase the capital stock; the whole aim of capitalist production is capital accumulation, i.e. business growth maximising net income. Marx argues there is no evidence that the profit accruing to capitalist owners is quantitatively connected to the "productive contribution" of the capital they own. In practice, within the capitalist firm, no standard procedure exists for measuring such a "productive contribution" and for distributing the residual income accordingly.

In Thurow's theory, profit is mainly just "something that happens" when costs are deducted from sales, or else a justly deserved income. For Marx, increasing profits is, at least in the longer term, the "bottom line" of business behaviour: the quest for obtaining extra surplus-value, and the incomes obtained from it, are what guides capitalist development (in modern language, "creating maximum shareholder value").

That quest, Marx notes, always involves a power relationship between different social classes and nations, inasmuch as attempts are made to force other people to pay for costs as much as possible, while maximising one's own entitlement or claims to income from economic activity. The clash of economic interests that invariably results, implies that the battle for surplus value will always involve an irreducible moral dimension; the whole process rests on complex system of negotiations, dealing and bargaining in which reasons for claims to wealth are asserted, usually within a legal framework and sometimes through wars. Underneath it all, Marx argues, was an exploitative relationship.

That was the main reason why, Marx argues, the real sources of surplus-value were shrouded or obscured by ideology, and why Marx thought that political economy merited a critique. Quite simply, economics proved unable to theorise capitalism as a social system, at least not without moral biases intruding in the very definition of its conceptual distinctions. Hence, even the most simple economic concepts were often riddled with contradictions. But market trade could function fine, even if the theory of markets was false; all that was required was an agreed and legally enforceable accounting system. On this point, Marx probably would have agreed with Austrian School economics – no knowledge of "markets in general" is required to participate in markets.

See also Edit

Notes Edit

  1. ^ Spago incorrectly claims that "surplus value" appears in The Source and Remedy of the National Difficulties (1821), by Charles Wentworth Dilke, claiming that "the quantity of the surplus value appropriated by the capitalist" appears in that text. This is a misreading of the Preface to Capital, Volume II by Engels, who quotes from this pamphlet but uses the phrase himself (not in quotes); the pamphlet uses "surplus labour".
  1. ^ Marx, The Capital, Chapter 8
  2. ^ "...It was made clear that the wage worker has permission to work for his own subsistence—that is, to live, only insofar as he works for a certain time gratis for the capitalist (and hence also for the latter's co-consumers of surplus value)..." Karl Marx, Critique of the Gotha Programme. Sec.II
  3. ^ W. Tcherkesoff (1902). Pages of Socialist History: Teachings and Acts of Social Democracy. C.B. Cooper. p. 19.
  4. ^ Menger, Anton (1899) [1886]. Das Recht auf den vollen Arbeitsertrag in geschichtlicher Darstellung [The Right to the Whole Produce of Labour] (in German).
  5. ^ "Juristen-Sozialismus" [Juridical Socialism]. Die Neue Zeit (in German). 1887.
  6. ^ Spargo, John (1906). Socialism: A Summary and Interpretation of Socialist Principles. pp. 203–206.
  7. ^ Vygodsky, Vitaly. "Surplus Value".
  8. ^ Marxists Internet Archive
  9. ^ Karatani, Kōjin. Transcritique: on Kant and Marx. pp. 248–251.
  10. ^ "Economic Manuscripts: Capital Vol. I - Chapter Twelve".
  11. ^ Marxists Internet Archive
  12. ^ Karl Marx and Frederick The Collected Works of Karl Marx and Frederick Engels: Volume 34 (New York: International Publishers, 1994) p. 63.
  13. ^ Karl Marx and Frederick Engels, Collected Works of Karl Marx and Frederick Engels: Volume 34, pp. 75–76.
  14. ^ Karl Marx and Frederick Engels, Collected Works of Karl Marx and Frederick Engels: Volume 34, p. 77.
  15. ^ "Measuring the Wealth of Nations - Cambridge University Press".
  16. ^ Karl Marx, Economic Manuscripts: Capital, Vol.3, Chapter 47.
  17. ^ Thurow, Lester C. (2008). "Profits". Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Liberty Fund.

References Edit

  • Theories of Surplus-Value (1863)
  • Value, Price and Profit (1865)
  • Capital, Volume 1, Volume 2, Volume 3, Supplement B of Volume 3
  • Anwar Shaikh and Ahmet Tonak, Measuring the Wealth of Nations
  • Anwar Shaikh papers [1]
  • G. A. Cohen (1988), History, Labour and Freedom: Themes from Marx, Oxford University Press
  • Shane Mage, The Law of the Falling Tendency of the Rate of Profit; Its Place in the Marxian Theoretical System and Relevance to the US Economy. Phd Thesis, Columbia University, 1963.
  • Tatyana Volkova and Felix Volkov, What Is Surplus Value? (Moscow: Progress Publishers), 1987.
  • Fred Moseley papers
  • Steve Keen, Debunking Economics; The Naked Emperor of the Social Sciences. London: Zed Press, 2004.Economics: Debunking Economics Overview
  • Emmanuel Farjoun and Moshe Machover, Laws of Chaos; A Probabilistic Approach to Political Economy, London: Verso, 1983.
  • Ian Wright, iwright – Probabilistic Political Economy "Laws of Chaos" in the 21st Century.
  • Ernest Mandel, Marxist Economic Theory, Vol. 1 and Late Capitalism.
  • Harry W. Pearson, "The economy has no surplus" in "Trade and market in the early empires. Economies in history and theory", edited by Karl Polanyi, Conrad M. Arensberg and Harry W. Pearson (New York/London: The Free Press: Collier-Macmillan, 1957).
  • Paul A. Baran, The Political Economy of Growth.
  • Piero Sraffa, Production of Commodities by means of commodities.
  • Michał Kalecki, "The Determinants of Profits", in Selected Essays on the Dynamics of the Capitalist Economy 1933–1970.
  • John B. Davis (ed), The economic surplus in advanced economies. Aldershot, Hants, England/Brookfield, Vt.: Elgar, 1992.
  • Anders Danielson, The economic surplus : theory, measurement, applications. Westport, Connecticut: Praeger, 1994.
  • Helen Boss, Theories of surplus and transfer : parasites and producers in economic thought. Boston: Hyman, 1990.

External links Edit

    surplus, value, this, article, multiple, issues, please, help, improve, discuss, these, issues, talk, page, learn, when, remove, these, template, messages, this, article, section, possibly, contains, synthesis, material, which, does, verifiably, mention, relat. This article has multiple issues Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page Learn how and when to remove these template messages This article or section possibly contains synthesis of material which does not verifiably mention or relate to the main topic Relevant discussion may be found on the talk page January 2014 Learn how and when to remove this template message This article possibly contains original research Please improve it by verifying the claims made and adding inline citations Statements consisting only of original research should be removed January 2014 Learn how and when to remove this template message This article includes a list of general references but it lacks sufficient corresponding inline citations Please help to improve this article by introducing more precise citations January 2014 Learn how and when to remove this template message Learn how and when to remove this template message In Marxian economics surplus value is the difference between the amount raised through a sale of a product and the amount it cost to manufacture it i e the amount raised through sale of the product minus the cost of the materials plant and labour power The concept originated in Ricardian socialism with the term surplus value itself being coined by William Thompson in 1824 however it was not consistently distinguished from the related concepts of surplus labor and surplus product The concept was subsequently developed and popularized by Karl Marx Marx s formulation is the standard sense and the primary basis for further developments though how much of Marx s concept is original and distinct from the Ricardian concept is disputed see Origin Marx s term is the German word Mehrwert which simply means value added sales revenue minus the cost of materials used up and is cognate to English more worth It is a major concept in Karl Marx s critique of political economy Conventionally value added is equal to the sum of gross wage income and gross profit income However Marx uses the term Mehrwert to describe the yield profit or return on production capital invested i e the amount of the increase in the value of capital Hence Marx s use of Mehrwert has always been translated as surplus value distinguishing it from value added According to Marx s theory surplus value is equal to the new value created by workers in excess of their own labor cost which is appropriated by the capitalist as profit when products are sold 1 2 Marx thought that the gigantic increase in wealth and population from the 19th century onwards was mainly due to the competitive striving to obtain maximum surplus value from the employment of labor resulting in an equally gigantic increase of productivity and capital resources To the extent that increasingly the economic surplus is convertible into money and expressed in money the amassment of wealth is possible on a larger and larger scale see capital accumulation and surplus product The concept is closely connected to producer surplus Contents 1 Origin 2 Theory 3 Definition 4 Interpretations 5 Equalization of rates 6 Appropriation from production 7 Absolute vs relative 8 Production versus realisation 9 Relation to taxation 10 Relation to the circuits of capital 11 Measurement 12 Different conceptions 13 Morality and power 14 See also 15 Notes 16 References 17 External linksOrigin EditBy the Age of Enlightenment in the 18th century the French physiocrats were already writing on the surplus value that was being extracted from labor by the employer the owner and all exploiters although they used the term net product 3 The concept of surplus value continued to be developed under Adam Smith who also used the term net product while his successors the Ricardian socialists began using the term surplus value decades later after its coinage by William Thompson in 1824 Two measures of the value of this use here present themselves the measure of the laborer and the measure of the capitalist The measure of the laborer consists in the contribution of such sums as would replace the waste and value of the capital by the time it would be consumed with such added compensation to the owner and superintendent of it as would support him in equal comfort with the more actively employed productive laborers The measure of the capitalist on the contrary would be the additional value produced by the same quantity of labor in consequence of the use of the machinery or other capital the whole of such surplus value to be enjoyed by the capitalist for his superior intelligence and skill in accumulating and advancing to the laborers his capital or the use of it William Thompson An Inquiry into the Principles of the Distribution of Wealth 1824 p 128 2nd ed emphasis added William Godwin and Charles Hall are also credited as earlier developers of the concept Early authors also used the terms surplus labor and surplus produce in Marx s language surplus product which have distinct meanings in Marxian economics surplus labor produces surplus product which has surplus value Some authors consider Marx as completely borrowing from Thompson notably Anton Menger Marx is completely under the influence of the earlier English socialists and more particularly of William Thompson T he whole theory of surplus value its conception its name and the estimates of its amounts are borrowed in all essentials from Thompson s writings Cf Marx Das Kapital English trans 1887 pp 156 194 289 with Thompson Distribution of Wealth p 163 2nd ed p 125 The real discovers of the theory of surplus value are Godwin Hall and especially W Thompson Anton Menger The Right to the Whole Produce of Labour 1886 4 p 101 This claim of priority has been vigorously contested notably in an article by Friedrich Engels completed by Karl Kautsky and published anonymously in 1887 reacting to and criticizing Menger in a review of his The Right to the Whole Produce of Labour arguing that there is nothing in common but the term surplus value itself 5 An intermediate position acknowledges the early development by Ricardian socialists and others but credits Marx with substantial development For example 6 a What is original in Marx is the explanation of the manner in which surplus value is produced John Spargo Socialism 1906 Johann Karl Rodbertus developed a theory of surplus value in the 1830s and 1840s notably in Zur Erkenntnis unserer staatswirthschaftlichen Zustande Toward an appreciation of our economic circumstances 1842 and claimed earlier priority to Marx specifically to have shown practically in the same way as Marx only more briefly and clearly the source of the surplus value of the capitalists The debate taking the side of Marx s priority is detailed in the Preface to Capital Volume II by Engels Marx first elaborated his doctrine of surplus value in 1857 58 manuscripts of A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy 1859 following earlier developments in his 1840s writings 7 It forms the subject of his 1862 63 manuscript Theories of Surplus Value which was subsequently published as Capital Volume IV and features in his Capital Volume I 1867 Theory EditThe problem of explaining the source of surplus value is expressed by Friedrich Engels as follows Whence comes this surplus value It cannot come either from the buyer buying the commodities under their value or from the seller selling them above their value For in both cases the gains and the losses of each individual cancel each other as each individual is in turn buyer and seller Nor can it come from cheating for though cheating can enrich one person at the expense of another it cannot increase the total sum possessed by both and therefore cannot augment the sum of the values in circulation This problem must be solved and it must be solved in a purely economic way excluding all cheating and the intervention of any force the problem being how is it possible constantly to sell dearer than one has bought even on the hypothesis that equal values are always exchanged for equal values 8 Marx s solution was first to distinguish between labor time worked and labor power and secondly to distinguish between absolute surplus value and relative surplus value A worker who is sufficiently productive can produce an output value greater than what it costs to hire him Although his wage seems to be based on hours worked in an economic sense this wage does not reflect the full value of what the worker produces Effectively it is not labour which the worker sells but his capacity to work Imagine a worker who is hired for an hour and paid 10 per hour Once in the capitalist s employ the capitalist can have him operate a boot making machine with which the worker produces 10 worth of work every 15 minutes Every hour the capitalist receives 40 worth of work and only pays the worker 10 capturing the remaining 30 as gross revenue Once the capitalist has deducted fixed and variable operating costs of say 20 leather depreciation of the machine etc he is left with 10 Thus for an outlay of capital of 30 the capitalist obtains a surplus value of 10 his capital has not only been replaced by the operation but also has increased by 10 This simple exploitation characterizes the realization of absolute surplus value which is then claimed by the capitalist The worker cannot capture this benefit directly because he has no claim to the means of production e g the boot making machine or to its products and his capacity to bargain over wages is restricted by laws and the supply demand for wage labour This form of exploitation was well understood by pre Marxian Socialists and left wing followers of Ricardo such as Proudhon and by early labor organizers who sought to unite workers in unions capable of collective bargaining in order to gain a share of profits and limit the length of the working day 9 Relative surplus value is not created in a single enterprise or site of production It arises instead from the total relation between multiple enterprises and multiple branches of industry when the necessary labor time of production is reduced effecting a change in the value of labor power For example when new technology or new business practices increase the productivity of labor a capitalist already employs or when the commodities necessary for workers subsistence fall in value the amount of socially necessary labor time is decreased the value of labor power is reduced and a relative surplus value is realized as profit for the capitalist increasing the overall general rate of surplus value in the total economy The surplus value produced by prolongation of the working day I call absolute surplus value On the other hand the surplus value arising from the curtailment of the necessary labour time and from the corresponding alteration in the respective lengths of the two components of the working day I call relative surplus value In order to effect a fall in the value of labour power the increase in the productiveness of labour must seize upon those branches of industry whose products determine the value of labour power and consequently either belong to the class of customary means of subsistence or are capable of supplying the place of those means But the value of a commodity is determined not only by the quantity of labour which the labourer directly bestows upon that commodity but also by the labour contained in the means of production For instance the value of a pair of boots depends not only on the cobbler s labour but also on the value of the leather wax thread amp c Hence a fall in the value of labour power is also brought about by an increase in the productiveness of labour and by a corresponding cheapening of commodities in those industries which supply the instruments of labour and the raw material that form the material elements of the constant capital required for producing the necessaries of life Marx Capital Vol 1 ch 12 The Concept of Relative Surplus Value 10 Definition EditTotal surplus value in an economy Marx refers to the mass or volume of surplus value is basically equal to the sum of net distributed and undistributed profit net interest net rents net tax on production and various net receipts associated with royalties licensing leasing certain honorariums etc see also value product Of course the way generic profit income is grossed and netted in social accounting may differ somewhat from the way an individual business does that see also Operating surplus Marx s own discussion focuses mainly on profit interest and rent largely ignoring taxation and royalty type fees which were proportionally very small components of the national income when he lived Over the last 150 years however the role of the state in the economy has increased in almost every country in the world Around 1850 the average share of government spending in GDP See also Government spending in the advanced capitalist economies was around 5 in 1870 a bit above 8 on the eve of World War I just under 10 just before the outbreak of World War II around 20 by 1950 nearly 30 and today the average is around 35 40 see for example Alan Turner Peacock The growth of public expenditure in Encyclopedia of Public Choice Springer 2003 pp 594 597 Interpretations EditSurplus value may be viewed in five ways As a component of the new value product which Marx himself defines as equal to the sum of labor costs in respect of capitalistically productive labor variable capital and surplus value In production he argues the workers produce a value equal to their wages plus an additional value the surplus value They also transfer part of the value of fixed assets and materials to the new product equal to economic depreciation consumption of fixed capital and intermediate goods used up constant capital inputs Labor costs and surplus value are the monetary valuations of what Marx calls the necessary product and the surplus product or paid labour and unpaid labour Surplus value can also be viewed as a flow of net income appropriated by the owners of capital in virtue of asset ownership comprising both distributed personal income and undistributed business income In the whole economy this will include both income directly from production and property income Surplus value can be viewed as the source of society s accumulation fund or investment fund part of it is re invested but part is appropriated as personal income and used for consumptive purposes by the owners of capital assets see capital accumulation in exceptional circumstances part of it may also be hoarded in some way In this context surplus value can also be measured as the increase in the value of the stock of capital assets through an accounting period prior to distribution Surplus value can be viewed as a social relation of production or as the monetary valuation of surplus labour a sort of index of the balance of power between social classes or nations in the process of the division of the social product Surplus value can in a developed capitalist economy be viewed also as an indicator of the level of social productivity that has been reached by the working population i e the net amount of value it can produce with its labour in excess of its own consumption requirements Equalization of rates EditMarx believed that the long term historical tendency would be for differences in rates of surplus value between enterprises and economic sectors to level out as Marx explains in two places in Capital Vol 3 If capitals that set in motion unequal quantities of living labour produce unequal amounts of surplus value this assumes that the level of exploitation of labour or the rate of surplus value is the same at least to a certain extent or that the distinctions that exist here are balanced out by real or imaginary conventional grounds of compensation This assumes competition among workers and an equalization that takes place by their constant migration between one sphere of production and another Assume a general rate of surplus value of this kind as a tendency like all economic laws as a theoretical simplification but in any case this is in practice an actual presupposition of the capitalist mode of production even if inhibited to a greater or lesser extent by practical frictions that produce more or less significant local differences such as the settlement laws for agricultural labourers in England for example In theory we assume that the laws of the capitalist mode of production develop in their pure form In reality this is only an approximation but that approximation is all the more exact the more the capitalist mode of production is developed and the less it is adulterated by survivals of earlier economic conditions with which it is amalgamated Capital Vol 3 ch 10 Pelican edition p 275 11 Hence he assumed a uniform rate of surplus value in his models of how surplus value would be shared out under competitive conditions Appropriation from production EditBoth in Das Kapital and in preparatory manuscripts such as the Grundrisse and Results of the immediate process of production Marx asserts that commerce by stages transforms a non capitalist production process into a capitalist production process integrating it fully into markets so that all inputs and outputs become marketed goods or services When that process is complete according to Marx the whole of production has become simultaneously a labor process creating use values and a valorisation process creating new value and more specifically a surplus value appropriated as net income see also capital accumulation citation needed Marx contends that the whole purpose of production in this situation becomes the growth of capital i e that production of output becomes conditional on capital accumulation citation needed If production becomes unprofitable capital will be withdrawn from production sooner or later The implication is that the main driving force of capitalism becomes the quest to maximise the appropriation of surplus value augmenting the stock of capital The overriding motive behind efforts to economise resources and labor would thus be to obtain the maximum possible increase in income and capital assets business growth and provide a steady or growing return on investment Absolute vs relative EditAccording to Marx absolute surplus value is obtained by increasing the amount of time worked per worker in an accounting period 12 Marx talks mainly about the length of the working day or week but in modern times the concern is about the number of hours worked per year In many parts of the world as productivity rose the workweek decreased from 60 hours to 50 40 or 35 hours Relative surplus value is obtained mainly by reducing wages 13 this can only go to a certain point because if wages fall below the ability of workers to purchase their means of subsistence they will be unable to reproduce themselves and the capitalists will not be able to find sufficient labor power reducing the cost of wage goods by various means so that wage increases can be curbed 14 increasing the productivity and intensity citation needed of labour generally through mechanisation and rationalisation yielding a bigger output per hour worked The attempt to extract more and more surplus value from labor on the one side and on the other side the resistance to this exploitation are according to Marx at the core of the conflict between social classes which is sometimes muted or hidden but at other times erupts in open class warfare and class struggle Production versus realisation EditMarx distinguished sharply between value and price in part because of the sharp distinction he draws between the production of surplus value and the realisation of profit income see also value form Output may be produced containing surplus value valorisation but selling that output realisation is not at all an automatic process Until payment from sales is received it is uncertain how much of the surplus value produced will actually be realised as profit from sales So the magnitude of profit realised in the form of money and the magnitude of surplus value produced in the form of products may differ greatly depending on what happens to market prices and the vagaries of supply and demand fluctuations This insight forms the basis of Marx s theory of market value prices of production and the tendency of the rate of profit of different enterprises to be levelled out by competition In his published and unpublished manuscripts Marx went into great detail to examine many different factors which could affect the production and realisation of surplus value He regarded this as crucial for the purpose of understanding the dynamics and dimensions of capitalist competition not just business competition but also competition between capitalists and workers and among workers themselves But his analysis did not go much beyond specifying some of the overall outcomes of the process His main conclusion though is that employers will aim to maximise the productivity of labour and economise on the use of labour to reduce their unit costs and maximise their net returns from sales at current market prices at a given ruling market price for an output every reduction of costs and every increase in productivity and sales turnover will increase profit income for that output The main method is mechanisation which raises the fixed capital outlay in investment In turn this causes the unit values of commodities to decline over time and a decline of the average rate of profit in the sphere of production occurs culminating in a crisis of capital accumulation in which a sharp reduction in productive investments combines with mass unemployment followed by an intensive rationalisation process of take overs mergers fusions and restructuring aiming to restore profitability Relation to taxation Edit nbsp S amp P 500 dividends and buybacks vs Federal and State tax collections State tax revenue Federal tax revenue S amp P 500 Stock buyback S amp P 500 DividendsIn general business leaders and investors are hostile to any attempts to encroach on total profit volume especially those of government taxation citation needed The lower taxes are other things being equal the bigger the mass of profit that can be distributed as income to private investors It was tax revolts that originally were a powerful stimulus motivating the bourgeoisie to wrest state power from the feudal aristocracy at the beginning of the capitalist era citation needed In reality of course a substantial portion of tax money is also redistributed to private enterprise in the form of government contracts and subsidies citation needed Capitalists may therefore be in conflict among themselves about taxes since what is a cost to some is a source of profit to others citation needed Marx never analysed all this in detail but the concept of surplus value will apply mainly to taxes on gross income personal and business income from production and on the trade in products and services citation needed Estate duty for example rarely contains a surplus value component although profit could be earned in the transfer of the estate citation needed Generally Marx seems to have regarded taxation imposts as a form which disguised real product values Apparently following this view Ernest Mandel in his 1960 treatise Marxist Economic Theory refers to indirect taxes as arbitrary additions to commodity prices But this is something of a misnomer and disregards that taxes become part of the normal cost structure of production In his later treatise on late capitalism Mandel astonishingly hardly mentions the significance of taxation at all a very serious omission from the point of view of the real world of modern capitalism since taxes can reach a magnitude of a third or even half of GDP see E Mandel Late Capitalism London Verso 1975 For example in the United Kingdom alone 75 of all taxation revenue comes from just three taxes Income tax National insurance and VAT which in reality is 75 of the GDP of the country Relation to the circuits of capital EditGenerally Marx focused in Das Kapital on the new surplus value generated by production and the distribution of this surplus value In this way he aimed to reveal the origin of the wealth of nations given a capitalist mode of production However in any real economy a distinction must be drawn between the primary circuit of capital and the secondary circuits To some extent national accounts also do this The primary circuit refers to the incomes and products generated and distributed from productive activity reflected by GDP The secondary circuits refer to trade transfers and transactions occurring outside that sphere which can also generate incomes and these incomes may also involve the realisation of a surplus value or profit It is true that Marx argues no net additions to value can be created through acts of exchange economic value being an attribute of labour products previous or newly created only Nevertheless trading activity outside the sphere of production can obviously also yield a surplus value which represents a transfer of value from one person country or institution to another A very simple example would be if somebody sold a second hand asset at a profit This transaction is not recorded in gross product measures after all it isn t new production nevertheless a surplus value is obtained from it Another example would be capital gains from property sales Marx occasionally refers to this kind of profit as profit upon alienation alienation being used here in the juridical not sociological sense By implication if we just focused on surplus value newly created in production we would underestimate total surplus values realised as income in a country This becomes obvious if we compare census estimates of income amp expenditure with GDP data This is another reason why surplus value produced and surplus value realised are two different things although this point is largely ignored in the economics literature But it becomes highly important when the real growth of production stagnates and a growing portion of capital shifts out of the sphere of production in search of surplus value from other deals Nowadays the volume of world trade grows significantly faster than GDP suggesting to Marxian economists such as Samir Amin that surplus value realised from commercial trade representing to a large extent a transfer of value by intermediaries between producers and consumers grows faster than surplus value realised directly from production Thus if we took the final price of a good the cost to the final consumer and analysed the cost structure of that good we might find that over a period of time the direct producers get less income and intermediaries between producers and consumers traders get more income from it That is control over the access to a good asset or resource as such may increasingly become a very important factor in realising a surplus value In the worst case this amounts to parasitism or extortion This analysis illustrates a key feature of surplus value which is that it accumulated by the owners of capital only within inefficient markets because only inefficient markets i e those in which transparency and competition are low have profit margins large enough to facilitate capital accumulation Ironically profitable meaning inefficient markets have difficulty meeting the definition a free market because a free market is to some extent defined as an efficient one one in which goods or services are exchanged without coercion or fraud or in other words with competition to prevent monopolistic coercion and transparency to prevent fraud Measurement EditThe first attempt to measure the rate of surplus value in money units was by Marx himself in chapter 9 of Das Kapital using factory data of a spinning mill supplied by Friedrich Engels though Marx credits a Manchester spinner Both in published and unpublished manuscripts Marx examines variables affecting the rate and mass of surplus value in detail Some Marxian economists argue that Marx thought the possibility of measuring surplus value depends on the publicly available data We can develop statistical indicators of trends without mistakenly conflating data with the real thing they represent or postulating perfect measurements or perfect data in the empiricist manner Since early studies by Marxian economists like Eugen Varga Charles Bettelheim Joseph Gillmann Edward Wolff and Shane Mage there have been numerous attempts by Marxian economists to measure the trend in surplus value statistically using national accounts data The most convincing modern attempt is probably that of Anwar Shaikh and Ahmet Tonak 15 Usually this type of research involves reworking the components of the official measures of gross output and capital outlays to approximate Marxian categories in order to estimate empirically the trends in the ratios thought important in the Marxian explanation of capital accumulation and economic growth the rate of surplus value the organic composition of capital the rate of profit the rate of increase in the capital stock and the rate of reinvestment of realised surplus value in production The Marxian mathematicians Emmanuel Farjoun and Moshe Machover argue that even if the rate of surplus value has changed by 10 20 over a hundred years the real problem to explain is why it has changed so little quoted from The Laws of Chaos A Probabilistic Approach to Political Economy 1983 p 192 The answer to that question must in part be sought in artifacts statistical distortion effects of data collection procedures Mathematical extrapolations are ultimately based on the data available but that data itself may be fragmentary and not the complete picture Different conceptions EditIn neo Marxist thought Paul A Baran for example substitutes the concept of economic surplus for Marx s surplus value In a joint work Paul Baran and Paul Sweezy define the economic surplus as the difference between what a society produces and the costs of producing it Monopoly Capitalism New York 1966 p 9 Much depends here on how the costs are valued and which costs are taken into account Piero Sraffa also refers to a physical surplus with a similar meaning calculated according to the relationship between prices of physical inputs and outputs In these theories surplus product and surplus value are equated while value and price are identical but the distribution of the surplus tends to be separated theoretically from its production whereas Marx insists that the distribution of wealth is governed by the social conditions in which it is produced especially by property relations giving entitlement to products incomes and assets see also relations of production In Kapital Vol 3 Marx insists strongly that the specific economic form in which unpaid surplus labour is pumped out of direct producers determines the relationship of rulers and ruled as it grows directly out of production itself and in turn reacts upon it as a determining element Upon this however is founded the entire formation of the economic community which grows up out of the production relations themselves thereby simultaneously its specific political form It is always the direct relationship of the owners of the conditions of production to the direct producers a relation always naturally corresponding to a definite stage of the methods of labour and thereby its social productivity which reveals the innermost secret the hidden basis of the entire social structure and with it the political form of the relation of sovereignty and dependence in short the corresponding specific form of the state This does not prevent the same economic basis the same from the standpoint of its main conditions due to innumerable different empirical circumstances natural environment racial relations external historical influence etc from showing infinite variations and gradations in appearance which can be ascertained only by analysis of the empirically given circumstances 16 This is a substantive if abstract thesis about the basic social relations involved in giving and getting taking and receiving in human society and their consequences for the way work and wealth is shared out It suggests a starting point for an inquiry into the problem of social order and social change But obviously it is only a starting point not the whole story which would include all the variations and gradations Morality and power EditThis article has multiple issues Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page Learn how and when to remove these template messages This section reads like a review rather than an encyclopedic description of the subject Please help improve this article to make it neutral in tone and meet Wikipedia s quality standards September 2019 This section is written like a personal reflection personal essay or argumentative essay that states a Wikipedia editor s personal feelings or presents an original argument about a topic Please help improve it by rewriting it in an encyclopedic style September 2019 Learn how and when to remove this template message Learn how and when to remove this template message A textbook type example of an alternative interpretation to Marx s is provided by Lester Thurow He argues 17 In a capitalistic society profits and losses hold center stage But what he asks explains profits There are five reasons for profit according to Thurow capitalists are willing to delay their own personal gratification and profit is their reward some profits are a return to those who take risks some profits are a return to organizational ability enterprise and entrepreneurial energy some profits are economic rents a firm that has a monopoly in producing some product or service can set a price higher than would be set in a competitive market and thus earn higher than normal returns some profits are due to market imperfections they arise when goods are traded above their competitive equilibrium price The problem here is that Thurow doesn t really provide an objective explanation of profits so much as a moral justification for profits i e as a legitimate entitlement or claim in return for the supply of capital He adds that Attempts have been made to organize productive societies without the profit motive but since the industrial revolution there have been essentially no successful economies that have not taken advantage of the profit motive The problem here is again a moral judgement dependent on what you mean by success Some societies using the profit motive were ruined profit is no guarantee of success although you can say that it has powerfully stimulated economic growth Thurow goes on to note that When it comes to actually measuring profits some difficult accounting issues arise Why Because after deduction of costs from gross income It is hard to say exactly how much must be reinvested to maintain the size of the capital stock Ultimately Thurow implies the tax department is the arbiter of the profit volume because it determines depreciation allowances and other costs which capitalists may annually deduct in calculating taxable gross income This is obviously a theory very different from Marx s In Thurow s theory the aim of business is to maintain the capital stock In Marx s theory competition desire and market fluctuations create the striving and pressure to increase the capital stock the whole aim of capitalist production is capital accumulation i e business growth maximising net income Marx argues there is no evidence that the profit accruing to capitalist owners is quantitatively connected to the productive contribution of the capital they own In practice within the capitalist firm no standard procedure exists for measuring such a productive contribution and for distributing the residual income accordingly In Thurow s theory profit is mainly just something that happens when costs are deducted from sales or else a justly deserved income For Marx increasing profits is at least in the longer term the bottom line of business behaviour the quest for obtaining extra surplus value and the incomes obtained from it are what guides capitalist development in modern language creating maximum shareholder value That quest Marx notes always involves a power relationship between different social classes and nations inasmuch as attempts are made to force other people to pay for costs as much as possible while maximising one s own entitlement or claims to income from economic activity The clash of economic interests that invariably results implies that the battle for surplus value will always involve an irreducible moral dimension the whole process rests on complex system of negotiations dealing and bargaining in which reasons for claims to wealth are asserted usually within a legal framework and sometimes through wars Underneath it all Marx argues was an exploitative relationship That was the main reason why Marx argues the real sources of surplus value were shrouded or obscured by ideology and why Marx thought that political economy merited a critique Quite simply economics proved unable to theorise capitalism as a social system at least not without moral biases intruding in the very definition of its conceptual distinctions Hence even the most simple economic concepts were often riddled with contradictions But market trade could function fine even if the theory of markets was false all that was required was an agreed and legally enforceable accounting system On this point Marx probably would have agreed with Austrian School economics no knowledge of markets in general is required to participate in markets See also EditAnalytical Marxism Capital Volume I Character mask Commodity fetishism Compensation of employees Cost of capital Labor theory of value Law of value Primitive accumulation of capital Rate of exploitation Return on capital Superprofit Surplus economics Theories of Surplus ValueNotes Edit Spago incorrectly claims that surplus value appears in The Source and Remedy of the National Difficulties 1821 by Charles Wentworth Dilke claiming that the quantity of the surplus value appropriated by the capitalist appears in that text This is a misreading of the Preface to Capital Volume II by Engels who quotes from this pamphlet but uses the phrase himself not in quotes the pamphlet uses surplus labour Marx The Capital Chapter 8 It was made clear that the wage worker has permission to work for his own subsistence that is to live only insofar as he works for a certain time gratis for the capitalist and hence also for the latter s co consumers of surplus value Karl Marx Critique of the Gotha Programme Sec II W Tcherkesoff 1902 Pages of Socialist History Teachings and Acts of Social Democracy C B Cooper p 19 Menger Anton 1899 1886 Das Recht auf den vollen Arbeitsertrag in geschichtlicher Darstellung The Right to the Whole Produce of Labour in German Juristen Sozialismus Juridical Socialism Die Neue Zeit in German 1887 Spargo John 1906 Socialism A Summary and Interpretation of Socialist Principles pp 203 206 Vygodsky Vitaly Surplus Value Marxists Internet Archive Karatani Kōjin Transcritique on Kant and Marx pp 248 251 Economic Manuscripts Capital Vol I Chapter Twelve Marxists Internet Archive Karl Marx and Frederick The Collected Works of Karl Marx and Frederick Engels Volume 34 New York International Publishers 1994 p 63 Karl Marx and Frederick Engels Collected Works of Karl Marx and Frederick Engels Volume 34 pp 75 76 Karl Marx and Frederick Engels Collected Works of Karl Marx and Frederick Engels Volume 34 p 77 Measuring the Wealth of Nations Cambridge University Press Karl Marx Economic Manuscripts Capital Vol 3 Chapter 47 Thurow Lester C 2008 Profits Concise Encyclopedia of Economics Liberty Fund References EditTheories of Surplus Value 1863 Value Price and Profit 1865 Capital Volume 1 Volume 2 Volume 3 Supplement B of Volume 3 Anwar Shaikh and Ahmet Tonak Measuring the Wealth of Nations Anwar Shaikh papers 1 G A Cohen 1988 History Labour and Freedom Themes from Marx Oxford University Press Shane Mage The Law of the Falling Tendency of the Rate of Profit Its Place in the Marxian Theoretical System and Relevance to the US Economy Phd Thesis Columbia University 1963 Tatyana Volkova and Felix Volkov What Is Surplus Value Moscow Progress Publishers 1987 Fred Moseley papers Gerard Dumenil and Dominique Levy papers Steve Keen Debunking Economics The Naked Emperor of the Social Sciences London Zed Press 2004 Economics Debunking Economics Overview Emmanuel Farjoun and Moshe Machover Laws of Chaos A Probabilistic Approach to Political Economy London Verso 1983 Ian Wright iwright Probabilistic Political Economy Laws of Chaos in the 21st Century Ernest Mandel Marxist Economic Theory Vol 1 and Late Capitalism Harry W Pearson The economy has no surplus in Trade and market in the early empires Economies in history and theory edited by Karl Polanyi Conrad M Arensberg and Harry W Pearson New York London The Free Press Collier Macmillan 1957 Paul A Baran The Political Economy of Growth Piero Sraffa Production of Commodities by means of commodities Michal Kalecki The Determinants of Profits in Selected Essays on the Dynamics of the Capitalist Economy 1933 1970 John B Davis ed The economic surplus in advanced economies Aldershot Hants England Brookfield Vt Elgar 1992 Anders Danielson The economic surplus theory measurement applications Westport Connecticut Praeger 1994 Helen Boss Theories of surplus and transfer parasites and producers in economic thought Boston Hyman 1990 External links Edit The Concepts of Alienation and Surplus value a Brief Look Archive org Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Surplus value amp oldid 1165963022, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

    article

    , read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.