fbpx
Wikipedia

Commodity fetishism

In Marxist philosophy, the term commodity fetishism describes the economic relationships of production and exchange as being social relationships that exist among things (money and merchandise) and not as relationships that exist among people. As a form of reification, commodity fetishism presents economic value as inherent to the commodities, and not as arising from the workforce, from the human relations that produced the commodity, the goods and the services.[1][2]

Commodity fetishism: In the economics of the marketplace, the producers and the consumers of goods and services perceive each other as the money and merchandise they exchange.

Concept edit

In the first chapter of Capital: A Critique of Political Economy (1867), commodity fetishism is used to explain how the social organization of labour manifests in the buying and selling of commodities (goods and services). In the marketplace, social relations among people—who makes what, who works for whom, the production-time for a commodity, etc.—are represented as social relations among objects.[3]

In the process of commercial exchange, commodities appear in a depersonalized form, obscuring the social relations inherent to their production.[4] Marx explained the sociology of commodity fetishism:

As against this, the commodity-form, and the value-relation of the products of labour, within which it appears, have absolutely no connection with the physical nature of the commodity and the material relations arising out of this. It is nothing but the definite social relation, between men, themselves, which assumes here, for them, the fantastic form of a relation between things. In order, therefore, to find an analogy, we must take flight into the misty realm of religion. There the products of the human brain appear as autonomous figures endowed with a life of their own, which enter into relations, both with each other and with the human race. So it is in the world of commodities with the products of men's hands. I call this the fetishism which attaches itself to the products of labour as soon as they are produced as commodities, and is, therefore, inseparable from the production of commodities.[5]

According to Marx, the operation of commodity fetishism requires the owners of capital to actively ignore or maintain an indifference to the relational whole that produces a commodity.[6]: 132 

Development edit

 
A South African fetish figurine whose supernatural powers protect the owner and kin in the natural world (c. 1900)
 
A political poster shows gold coin as the basis of prosperity (c. 1896)

The theory of commodity fetishism (German: Warenfetischismus) originated from Karl Marx's references to fetishes and fetishism in his analyses of religious superstition, and in the criticism of the beliefs of political economists.[7] Marx borrowed the concept of "fetishism" from The Cult of Fetish Gods (1760) by Charles de Brosses, which proposed a materialist theory of the origin of religion.[8][9] Moreover, in the 1840s, the philosophic discussion of fetishism by Auguste Comte, and Ludwig Feuerbach's psychological interpretation of religion also influenced Marx's development of commodity fetishism.[10][11]

Marx's first mention of fetishism appeared in 1842, in his response to a newspaper article by Karl Heinrich Hermes, which defended Germany on religious grounds.[12] Hermes agreed with the German philosopher Hegel in regarding fetishism as the crudest form of religion. Marx dismissed that argument and Hermes's definition of religion as that which elevates man "above sensuous appetites". Instead, Marx said that fetishism is "the religion of sensuous appetites", and that the fantasy of the appetites tricks the fetish worshipper into believing that an inanimate object will yield its natural character to gratify the desires of the worshipper. Therefore, the crude appetite of the fetish worshipper smashes the fetish when it ceases to be of service.[13][14][15]

The next mention of fetishism was in the 1842 Rheinische Zeitung newspaper articles about the "Debates on the Law on Thefts of Wood", wherein Marx spoke of the Spanish fetishism of gold and the German fetishism of wood as commodities:[16]

The savages of Cuba regarded gold as a fetish of the Spaniards. They celebrated a feast in its honour, sang in a circle around it, and then threw it into the sea. If the Cuban savages had been present at the sitting of the Rhine Province Assembly, would they not have regarded wood as the Rhinelanders' fetish? But a subsequent sitting would have taught them that the worship of animals is connected with this fetishism, and they would have thrown the hares into the sea in order to save the human beings.

In the Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844, Marx spoke of the European fetish of precious-metal money:

The nations which are still dazzled by the sensuous glitter of precious metals, and are, therefore, still fetish-worshippers of metal money, are not yet fully developed money-nations. [Note the] contrast of France and England. The extent to which the solution of theoretical riddles is the task of practice, and is effected through practice, the extent to which true practice is the condition of a real and positive theory, is shown, for example, in fetishism. The sensuous consciousness of the fetish-worshipper is different from that of the Greek, because his sensuous existence is different. The abstract enmity between sense and spirit is necessary so long as the human feeling for nature, the human sense of nature, and, therefore, also the natural sense of man, are not yet produced by man's own labour.[17]

In the ethnological notebooks, he commented upon the archaeological reportage of The Origin of Civilization and the Primitive Condition of Man: Mental and Social conditions of Savages (1870), by John Lubbock.[18] In the Outlines of the Critique of Political Economy (Grundrisse, 1859), he criticized the liberal arguments of the French economist Frédéric Bastiat; and about fetishes and fetishism Marx said:

In real history, wage labour arises out of the dissolution of slavery and serfdom—or of the decay of communal property, as with Oriental and Slavonic peoples—and, in its adequate, epoch-making form, the form which takes possession of the entire social being of labour, out of the decline and fall of the guild economy, of the system of Estates, of labour and income in kind, of industry carried on as rural subsidiary occupation, of small-scale feudal agriculture, etc. In all these real historic transitions, wage labour appears as the dissolution, the annihilation of relations in which labour was fixed on all sides, in its income, its content, its location, its scope, etc. Hence, as negation of the stability of labour and of its remuneration. The direct transition from the African's fetish to Voltaire's "Supreme Being", or from the hunting gear of a North American savage to the capital of the Bank of England, is not so absurdly contrary to history, as is the transition from Bastiat's fisherman to the wage labourer.[19]

In A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy (1859), Marx referred to A Discourse on the Rise, Progress, Peculiar Objects, and Importance of Political Economy (1825), by John Ramsay McCulloch, who said that "In its natural state, matter ... is always destitute of value", with which Marx concurred, saying that "this shows how high even a McCulloch stands above the fetishism of German 'thinkers' who assert that 'material', and half a dozen similar irrelevancies are elements of value".

Furthermore, in the manuscript of "Results of the Immediate Process of Production" (c. 1864), an appendix to Capital: Critique of Political Economy, Volume 1 (1867), Marx said that:

... we find in the capitalist process of production [an] indissoluble fusion of use-values in which capital subsists [as] means of production and objects defined as capital, when what we are really faced with is a definite social relationship of production. In consequence, the product embedded in this mode of production is equated with the commodity, by those who have to deal with it. It is this that forms the foundation for the fetishism of the political economists.[20]

Hence did Karl Marx apply the concepts of fetish and fetishism, derived from economic and ethnologic studies, to the development of the theory of commodity fetishism, wherein an economic abstraction (value) is psychologically transformed (reified) into an object, which people choose to believe has an intrinsic value, in and of itself.[21]

Critique edit

In the critique of political economy edit

Marx proposed that in a society where independent, private producers trade their products with each other, of their own volition and initiative, and without much coordination of market exchange, the volumes of production and commercial activities are adjusted in accordance with the fluctuating values of the products (goods and services) as they are bought and sold, and in accordance with the fluctuations of supply and demand. Because their social coexistence, and its meaning, is expressed through market exchange (trade and transaction), people have no other relations with each other. Therefore, social relations are continually mediated and expressed with objects (commodities and money). How the traded commodities relate will depend upon the costs of production, which are reducible to quantities of human labour, although the worker has no control over what happens to the commodities that they produce. (See: Entfremdung, Marx's theory of alienation)

Domination of things edit

The concept of the intrinsic value of commodities (goods and services) determines and dominates the economic (business) relationships among people, to the extent that buyers and sellers continually adjust their beliefs (financial expectations) about the value of things—either consciously or unconsciously—to the proportionate price changes (market-value) of the commodities over which buyers and sellers believe they have no true control. That psychologic perception transforms the trading-value of a commodity into an independent entity (an object), to the degree that the social value of the goods and services appears to be a natural property of the commodity itself. Thence objectified, the market appears as if self-regulated (by fluctuating supply and demand) because, in pursuit of profit, the consumers of the products ceased to perceive the human co-operation among capitalists that is the true engine of the market where commodities are bought and sold; such is the domination of things in the market.

Objectified value edit

The value of a commodity originates from the human being's intellectual and perceptual capacity to consciously (subjectively) ascribe a relative value (importance) to a commodity, the goods and services manufactured by the labour of a worker. Therefore, in the course of the economic transactions (buying and selling) that constitute market exchange, people ascribe subjective values to the commodities (goods and services), which the buyers and the sellers then perceive as objective values, the market-exchange prices that people will pay for the commodities.

Naturalization of market behaviour edit

In a capitalist society, the human perception that "the market" is an independent, sentient entity, is how buyers, sellers, and producers naturalize market exchange (the human choices and decisions that constitute commerce) as a series of "natural phenomena ... that ... happen of their own accord". Such were the political-economy arguments of the economists whom Karl Marx criticized when they spoke of the "natural equilibria" of markets, as if the price (value) of a commodity were independent of the volition and initiative of the capitalist producers, buyers, and sellers of commodities.

In the 18th century, the Scottish social philosopher and political economist Adam Smith, in The Wealth of Nations (1776) proposed that the "truck, barter, and exchange" activities of the market were corresponding economic representations of human nature, that is, the buying and selling of commodities were activities intrinsic to the market, and thus are the "natural behaviour" of the market. Hence, Smith proposed that a market economy was a self-regulating entity that "naturally" tended towards economic equilibrium, wherein the relative prices (the value) of a commodity ensured that the buyers and sellers obtained what they wanted for and from their goods and services.[22]

In the 19th century, Karl Marx contradicted the artifice of Adam Smith's "naturalisation of the market's behaviour" as a politico-ideologic apology—by and for the capitalists—which allowed human economic choices and decisions to be misrepresented as fixed "facts of life", rather than as the human actions that resulted from the will of the producers, the buyers, and the sellers of the commodities traded at market. Such "immutable economic laws" are what Capital: Critique of Political Economy (1867) revealed about the functioning of the capitalist mode of production, how goods and services (commodities) are circulated among a society; and thus explain the psychological phenomenon of commodity fetishism, which ascribes an independent, objective value and reality to a thing that has no inherent value—other than the value given to it by the producer, the seller, and the buyer of the commodity.

Masking edit

In a capitalist economy, a character mask (Charaktermaske) is the functional role with which a person relates and is related to in a society composed of stratified social classes, especially in relationships and market-exchange transactions; thus, in the course of buying and selling, the commodities (goods and services) usually appear other than they are, because they are masked (obscured) by the role-playing of the buyer and the seller. Moreover, because the capitalist economy of a class society is an intrinsically contradictory system, the masking of the true socio-economic character of the transaction is an integral feature of its function and operation as market exchange. In the course of business competition among themselves, buyers, sellers, and producers cannot do business (compete) without obscurity—confidentiality and secrecy—thus the necessity of the character masks that obscure true economic motive.

Central to the Marxist critique of political economy is the obscurantism of the juridical labour contract, between the worker and the capitalist, that masks the true, exploitive nature of their economic relationship—that the worker does not sell his and her labour, but that the worker sells individual labour power, the human capacity to perform work and manufacture commodities (goods and services) that yield a profit to the producer. The work contract is the mask that obscures the economic exploitation of the difference between the wages paid for the labour of the worker, and the new value created by the labour of the worker.

Marx thus established that in a capitalist society the creation of wealth is based upon "the paid and unpaid portions of labour [that] are inseparably mixed up with each other, and the nature of the whole transaction is completely masked by the intervention of a contract, and the pay received at the end of the week"; and that:[23][24][25]

Vulgar economics actually does nothing more than to interpret, to systematize and turn into apologetics—in a doctrinaire way—the ideas of the agents who are trapped within bourgeois relations of production. So it should not surprise us that, precisely within the estranged form of appearance of economic relations in which these prima facie absurd and complete contradictions occur—and all science would be superfluous if the form of appearance of things directly coincided with their essence—that precisely here vulgar economics feels completely at home, and that these relationships appear all the more self-evident to it, the more their inner interconnection remains hidden to it, even though these relationships are comprehensible to the popular mind.

Opacity of economic relations edit

The primary valuation of the trading-value of goods and services (commodities) is expressed as money-prices. The buyers and the sellers determine and establish the economic and financial relationships; and afterwards compare the prices in and the price trends of the market. Moreover, because of the masking of true economic motive, neither the buyer, nor the seller, nor the producer perceive and understand every human labour-activity required to deliver the commodities (goods and services), nor do they perceive the workers whose labour facilitated the purchase of commodities. The economic results of such collective human labour are expressed as the values and the prices of the commodities; the value-relations between the amount of human labour and the value of the supplied commodity.

Capitalism as religion edit

In the essay "Capitalism as Religion" (1921), Walter Benjamin said that whether or not people treat capitalism as a religion was a moot subject, because "One can behold in capitalism a religion, that is to say, capitalism essentially serves to satisfy the same worries, anguish, and disquiet formerly answered by so-called religion." That the religion of capitalism is manifest in four tenets:

(i) "Capitalism is a purely cultic religion, perhaps the most extreme that ever existed"
(ii) "The permanence of the cult"
(iii) "Capitalism is probably the first instance of a cult that creates guilt, not atonement"
(iv) "God must be hidden from it, and may be addressed only when guilt is at its zenith".[27][28]

Applications edit

Cultural theory edit

 
The Hungarian philosopher György Lukács developed Karl Marx's theory of commodity fetishism to develop reification theory.
 
Thorstein Veblen proposed the conspicuous consumption of commodities as the pursuit of social prestige.

Since the 19th century, when Karl Marx presented the theory of commodity fetishism, in Section 4, "The Fetishism of Commodities and the Secret thereof", of the first chapter of Capital: Critique of Political Economy (1867), the constituent concepts of the theory, and their sociologic and economic explanations, have proved intellectually fertile propositions that permit the application of the theory (interpretation, development, adaptation) to the study, examination, and analysis of other cultural aspects of the political economy of capitalism, such as:

Sublimated sexuality edit

The theory of sexual fetishism, which Alfred Binet presented in the essay Le fétichisme dans l'amour: la vie psychique des micro-organismes, l'intensité des images mentales, etc. (Fetishism in Love: the Psychic Life of Micro-organisms, the Intensity of Mental Images, etc., 1887), was applied to interpret commodity fetishism as types of sexually-charged economic relationships, between a person and a commodity (goods and services), as in the case of advertising, which is a commercial enterprise that ascribes human qualities (values) to a commodity, to persuade the buyer to purchase the advertised goods and services.[29] However, Marx focused on the exchange value of the commodity -- its price -- when considering commodity fetishism and its hiding of the complex social relationships involved in producing and exchanging a product under capitalism. He was not discussing the symbolic meanings of the commodity for the consumer, or what he called its "use value." Hence, sexual fetishism and commodity fetishism are largely unconnected concepts.[citation needed]

Social prestige edit

In the 19th and in the 21st centuries, Thorstein Veblen (The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study of Institutions, 1899) and Alain de Botton (Status Anxiety, 2004) respectively developed the social status (prestige) relationship between the producer of consumer goods and the aspirations to prestige of the consumer. To avoid the status anxiety of not being of or belonging to "the right social class", the consumer establishes a personal identity (social, economic, cultural) that is defined and expressed by the commodities (goods and services) that they buy, own, and use; the domination of things that communicate the "correct signals" of social prestige, of belonging. (See: Conspicuous consumption.)

Reification edit

In History and Class Consciousness (1923), György Lukács started from the theory of commodity fetishism for his development of reification (the psychological transformation of an abstraction into a concrete object) as the principal obstacle to class consciousness. About which Lukács said: "Just as the capitalist system continuously produces and reproduces itself economically on higher levels, the structure of reification progressively sinks more deeply, more fatefully, and more definitively into the consciousness of Man"—hence, commodification pervaded every conscious human activity, as the growth of capitalism commodified every sphere of human activity into a product that can be bought and sold in the market.[30] (See: Verdinglichung, Marx's theory of reification.)

Industrialized culture edit

Commodity fetishism is theoretically central to the Frankfurt School philosophy, especially in the work of the sociologist Theodor W. Adorno, which describes how the forms of commerce invade the human psyche; how commerce casts a person into a role not of his or her making; and how commercial forces affect the development of the psyche. In the book Dialectic of Enlightenment (1944), Adorno and Max Horkheimer presented the Theory of the Culture Industry to describe how the human imagination (artistic, spiritual, intellectual activity) becomes commodified when subordinated to the "natural commercial laws" of the market.

To the consumer, the cultural goods and services sold in the market appear to offer the promise of a richly developed and creative individuality, yet the inherent commodification severely restricts and stunts the human psyche, so that the man and the woman consumer has little "time for myself", because of the continual personification of cultural roles over which he and she exercise little control. In personifying such cultural identities, the person is a passive consumer, not the active creator, of his or her life; the promised life of individualistic creativity is incompatible with the collectivist, commercial norms of bourgeois culture.

Commodity narcissism edit

In the study From Commodity Fetishism to Commodity Narcissism (2012) the investigators applied the Marxist theory of commodity fetishism to psychologically analyse the economic behaviour (buying and selling) of the contemporary consumer. With the concept of commodity narcissism, the psychologists Stephen Dunne and Robert Cluley proposed that consumers who claim to be ethically concerned about the manufacturing origin of commodities, nonetheless behaved as if ignorant of the exploitative labour conditions under which the workers produced the goods and services, bought by the "concerned consumer"; that, within the culture of consumerism, narcissistic men and women have established shopping (economic consumption) as a socially acceptable way to express aggression.[31] Researchers find no evidence that a greater manufacturing base can spur economic growth, while improving government effectiveness and regulation quality are more promising for facilitating economic growth.[32]

Ethical Consumption edit

Environmentally “conscious” consumers want their purchased products to be environmentally ethical. According to James G. Carrier,[33] on a personal level their purchases can make them feel more positively moral and second they can help put pressure on firms in a competitive market to change the way they do things. Marx’s 1867 notion of commodity fetishism which concerns the idea that ethical consumption is going beyond the two reasons first noted by Carrier.[according to whom?] Certain commodities are perceived in a particular way that the consumer ignores or denies the labor time entailed in the process of production or for that matter any detailed background people and process that is viable in creating an ethical product. Capitalists have the intention of selling to an audience with commercial gain - the use of nature as a strategy is vital in urging people to buy their product. Ethical consumption is mostly concerned with the social, political and environmental context of objects - and consumers want a product that meets their moral criteria, something non-exploitative. These baseline concepts need to be visible and eye-catching with recognizable verifications. This is very common in ecotourism who produce eco-friendliness as a reason to buy and visit. Advertising protection and conservation attracts visitors and media attention. These capitalists make no point to vary in their images and photographs or captions - the repetition of nature is always colorful and vibrant, gentle and reserved. They are "fetishizing" nature as a marketing technique. Portraying themselves as a business that protects nature satisfies their clientele so that the consumer cannot see the objects and mechanisms used to actually produce it. Carrier describes how the environment itself is fetishized as a consumable product through parks and other areas of land being used as bodies or images attached to promises of natural experiences or protection efforts in return for money. Carrier also offers the example of fair-trade coffee as a way that commodity fetishism is seen in ethical consumption. If fair-trade coffee promises that it is direct, cooperative supply chain between growers and consumers through images of coffee growers and messaging on the bag of coffee, this becomes more relevant to consumer decision making than the reality that many other “middle-men” were needing in the roasting, packaging, marketing, and transportation of that commodity. [34]

Ethical consumption is believed by advocates of the theory., to allow people to lead more moral lives as well as affect the world by placing economic pressure on firms to change their production processes and products to become more ethical to remain competitive within the greater market. The fetishization of nature and natural resources often leads through its commodification as a product to be advertised. Conceptual categories need to be “legible, be visible and recognizable”[35] in order to be effective as ethical standards. The advertising on items listed and named as fair trade often misrepresents the actual production process, especially in products requiring extensive and hard labor to produce, such as coffee. It also often becomes exploitative as it uses the images of ethnic small holders rather than the ethnic migrants and wage laborers who do the majority of the work. The use of images not only fetishizes the product, but defines ethicality as a whole.[36] A common narrative now is whether or not ethical consumption is at all possible in a globalized world of highly interconnected capitalism and trade. It relies on ideas of greenwashing in which producers use environmentalism and fair trade ideals to advertise their products without living up to the ideals. The false image of environmentalism disguises the unsustainable practices being utilized. Another critique is the overall effectiveness of individual consumer choices without large-scale systemic change through government regulation. Accessibility is another issue, as ethical products are often more expensive and less accessible to low-income activists.

Social alienation edit

In The Society of the Spectacle (1967), Guy Debord presented the theory of "le spectacle"—the systematic conflation of advanced capitalism, the mass communications media, and a government amenable to exploiting those factors. The spectacle transforms human relations into objectified relations among images, and vice versa; the exemplar spectacle is television, the communications medium wherein people passively allow (cultural) representations of themselves to become the active agents of their beliefs. The spectacle is the form that society assumes when the Arts, the instruments of cultural production, have been commodified as commercial activities that render an aesthetic value into a commercial value (a commodity). Whereby artistic expression then is shaped by the person's ability to sell it as a commodity, that is, as artistic goods and services.

Capitalism reorganizes personal consumption to conform to the commercial principles of market exchange; commodity fetishism transforms a cultural commodity into a product with an economic "life of its own" that is independent of the volition and initiative of the artist, the producer of the commodity. What Karl Marx critically anticipated in the 19th century, with "The Fetishism of Commodities and the Secret thereof", Guy Debord interpreted and developed for the 20th century—that in modern society, the psychologic intimacies of intersubjectivity and personal self-relation are commodified into discrete "experiences" that can be bought and sold. The Society of the Spectacle is the ultimate form of social alienation that occurs when a person views his or her being (self) as a commodity that can be bought and sold, because they regard every human relation as a (potential) business transaction. (See: Entfremdung, Marx's theory of alienation)

Semiotic sign edit

Jean Baudrillard applied commodity fetishism to explain the subjective feelings of men and women towards consumer goods in the "realm of circulation"; that is, the cultural mystique (mystification) that advertising ascribed to the commodities (goods and services) in order to encourage the buyer to purchase the goods and services as aids to the construction of his and her cultural identity. In the book For a Critique of the Political Economy of the Sign (1972), Baudrillard developed the semiotic theory of "the Sign" (sign value) as a development of Marx's theory of commodity fetishism and of the exchange value vs. use value dichotomy of capitalism.

Intellectual property edit

In the 21st century, the political economy of capitalism reified the abstract objects that are information and knowledge into the tangible commodities of intellectual property, which are produced by and derived from the labours of the intellectual and the white collar workers.

Philosophic base edit

The economist Michael Perelman critically examined the belief systems from which arose intellectual property rights, the field of law that commodified knowledge and information. Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis critically reviewed the belief systems of the theory of human capital.[37] Knowledge, as the philosophic means to a better life, is contrasted with capitalist knowledge (as commodity and capital), produced to generate income and profit. Such commodification detaches knowledge and information from the (user) person, because, as intellectual property, they are independent, economic entities.

Knowledge: authentic and counterfeit edit

In Postmodernism, or, the Cultural Logic of Late Capitalism (1991), the Marxist theorist Fredric Jameson linked the reification of information and knowledge to the post-modern distinction between authentic knowledge (experience) and counterfeit knowledge (vicarious experience), which usually is acquired through the mass communications media. In Critique of Commodity Aesthetics: Appearance, Sexuality and Advertising in Capitalist Society (1986), the philosopher Wolfgang Fritz Haug presents a "critique of commodity aesthetics" that examines how human needs and desires are manipulated and reshaped for commercial gain.[38]

Financial risk management edit

The sociologists Frank Furedi and Ulrich Beck studied the development of commodified types of knowledge in the business culture of "risk prevention" in the management of money. The Post–World War II economic expansion (c. 1945–1973) created very much money (capital and savings), while the dominant bourgeois ideology of money favoured the risk-management philosophy of the managers of investment funds and financial assets. From such administration of investment money, manipulated to create new capital, arose the preoccupation with risk calculations, which subsequently was followed by the "economic science" of risk prevention management.[39][40] In light of which, the commodification of money as "financial investment funds" allows an ordinary person to pose as a rich person, as an economic risk-taker able to risk losing money invested to the market. Hence, the fetishization of financial risk as "a sum of money" is a reification that distorts the social perception of the true nature of financial risk, as experienced by ordinary people.[41] Moreover, the valuation of financial risk is susceptible to ideological bias; that contemporary fortunes are achieved from the insight of experts in financial management, who study the relationship between "known" and "unknown" economic factors, by which human fears about money can be manipulated and exploited.

Commodified art edit

The cultural critics Georg Simmel and Walter Benjamin examined and described the fetishes and fetishism of Art, by means of which "artistic" commodities are produced for sale in the market, and how commodification determines and establishes the value of the artistic commodities (goods and services) derived from legitimate Art; for example, the selling of an artist's personal effects as "artistic fetishes".

Legal traducement edit

In the field of law, the scholar Evgeny Pashukanis (The General Theory of Law and Marxism, 1924), the Austrian politician Karl Renner, the German political scientist Franz Leopold Neumann, the British socialist writer China Miéville, the labour-law attorney Marc Linder, and the American legal philosopher Duncan Kennedy (The Role of Law in Economic Theory: Essays on the Fetishism of Commodities, 1985) have respectively explored the applications of commodity fetishism in their contemporary legal systems, and reported that the reification of legal forms misrepresents social relations.[42][43]

Criticism edit

 
The Tribuna of the Uffizi (1772–1778) by Johann Zoffany depicts the commodity-fetishism metamorphosis of oil paintings into culture-industry products.

In Portrait of a Marxist as a Young Nun (1988), Professor Helena Sheehan said that the analogy between religious faith and commodity fetishism is a mistaken interpretation, because people do not worship commodities (money and merchandise) by attributing supernatural powers to inanimate objects, to a fetish. That the belief that value-relationships inherent to a commodity described is not religious belief, because value-relations do not possess the psychological characteristics of spiritual beliefs. That interpretation is proved by the possibility of a person's possessing religious faith, whilst being aware of the psychology of commodity fetishism, and thus being critical of the fetishization of money and merchandise, thus, a person's disbelief in the Golden Calf is integral to the person's iconoclasm against the idolatry of money.[44]

See also edit

Pre-Marxist theories
Marxist theories pertinent to the theory of commodity fetishism
Post-Marxist theories derived from the theory of commodity fetishism

References edit

  1. ^ Marx, Karl (1887). Capital Volume One. Moscow: Progress Publishers. from the original on 7 June 2019. Retrieved 11 January 2020. A commodity is therefore a mysterious thing, simply because in it the social character of men's labour appears to them as an objective character stamped upon the product of that labour; because the relation of the producers to the sum total of their own labour is presented to them as a social relation, existing not between themselves, but between the products of their labour.
  2. ^ Isaak Illich Rubin said that "The theory of fetishism is, per se, the basis of Marx's entire economic system, and, in particular, of his theory of value." — Essays on Marx's Theory of Value. Montreal: Black Rose Books, 1990, p. 5.
  3. ^ Roubine, Isaak I. (2009). Essais sur la théorie de la valeur de Marx. Paris: Syllepse. p. 55. ISBN 978-2-84950-218-1.
  4. ^ Rubin, Isaak Illich (1972). Essays on Marx's Theory of Value. Detroit: Black and Red. from the original on 31 May 2020. Retrieved 10 January 2020.
  5. ^ Marx, Karl (1990). Capital. London: Penguin Classics. p. 165.
  6. ^ Driscoll, Mark W. (2020). The Whites are Enemies of Heaven: Climate Caucasianism and Asian Ecological Protection. Durham: Duke University Press. ISBN 978-1-4780-1121-7.
  7. ^ The various references in the 'Wood Theft' articles to idols, animal masks, workship of animals, and fetishes, reflect Marx's systematic study (1841–42) of primitive religion. The notebooks indicate that Marx was especially interested in the concept of fetishism — its nature, its origins, and the difference between ancient and modern forms of fetishism. (MEGA, Vol . 1, Part 2 p. 115ff) — Sherover, Erica (1979). "The Virtue of Poverty: Marx's Transformation of Hegel's Concept of the Poor" (PDF). Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory. 3 (1): 53–66. (PDF) from the original on 13 October 2011. Retrieved 1 October 2011.
  8. ^ Du culte des dieux fétiches ou Parallèle de l'ancienne religion de l'Égypte avec la religion actuelle de Nigritie ([Reprod.]) (in French). 15 October 2007. from the original on 6 December 2016. Retrieved 3 January 2017 – via Gallica.bnf.fr.
  9. ^ The German translation was Uber den Dienst der fetischengotter oder Vergleichung der alten religion Egyptians mit den heutigen Religion Nigritiens. Ubersetzt von Christian Brandanus Hermann Pistorius. Berlin, Stralsund: Gottlieb August Lange, 1785. For a study of the conceptual origin of fetishism, see: William Pietz, "The problem of the fetish, I", Res 9 (Spring 1985), pp. 5–17; "The problem of the fetish, II: The origin of the fetish", Res 13 (Spring 1987), pp. 23–45; "The problem of the fetish, III: Bosman's Guinea and the enlightenment theory of fetishism", Res 16 (Autumn 1988), pp. 105–123.
  10. ^ "Philosophy3.p65" (PDF). Socserv.mcmaster.ca. (PDF) from the original on 7 July 2012. Retrieved 3 January 2017.
  11. ^ Feuerbach, Ludwig (2008). (PDF). Translated by Eliot, George. MSAC Philosophy Group. ISBN 978-1-56543-102-7. Archived from the original (PDF) on 14 June 2012.
  12. ^ . Archived from the original on 9 March 2001.
  13. ^ Karl Marx and Frederick Engels, On religion. Atlanta: Scholars, 1982, p. 22.
  14. ^ "Commodity fetishism - Fredy Perlman". 2006. from the original on 25 December 2007.
  15. ^ "The fetishism of commodities". 2016. from the original on 28 June 2019.
  16. ^ . Archived from the original on 9 March 2001.
  17. ^ Karl Marx (1975). ""Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844", in Marx-Engels Collected Works". Moscow: Progress. p. 312. from the original on 22 September 2023. Retrieved 8 June 2010.
  18. ^ Lawrence Krader (ed.), The Ethnological Notebooks of Karl Marx: Studies of Morgan, Phear, Maine, Lubbock. Assen: Van Gorcum, 1972, p. 342f.
  19. ^ "Grundrisse 17". Marxists.org. from the original on 21 February 2012. Retrieved 3 January 2017.
  20. ^ Karl Marx,Results of the Immediate Process of Production, appendix in Capital Volume 1. Penguin edition, 1976, p. 983.
  21. ^ For more details, see Boer, Roland (2010). "That Hideous Pagan Idol: Marx, Fetishism and Graven Images". Critique: Journal of Socialist Theory. 38 (1): 93–116. doi:10.1080/03017600903454413. S2CID 143420404.
  22. ^ Smith, Adam. "An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations". Geolib.com. from the original on 27 January 2017. Retrieved 3 January 2017.
  23. ^ Karl Marx. "Value, Price and Profit, part 9". Marxists.org. from the original on 21 December 2016. Retrieved 3 January 2017. ... the paid and unpaid portions of labour are inseparably mixed up with each other, and the nature of the whole transaction is completely masked by the intervention of a contract and the pay received at the end of the week
  24. ^ Karl Marx (1875). "Critique of the Gotha Programme". Marxists.org. p. part 2 (emphases added). from the original on 16 July 2018. Retrieved 3 January 2017. "Since Lassalle's death, there has asserted itself in our party the scientific understanding that wages are not what they appear to be—namely, the value, or price, of labor—but only a masked form for the value, or price, of labor power".
  25. ^ cf. the Resultate manuscript in Capital, Volume I, Penguin edition, p. 1064, where Marx uses the word "vertuscht" (covered up).
  26. ^ Marx, Capital, Volume III, Penguin edition, p. 956 (translation corrected to the German edition).
  27. ^ "Capitalism as Religion", by Walter Benjamin, in Walter Benjamin: Selected Writings, Vol. 1 1913–1926. Michael W. Jennings (ed.), Cambridge, Massachusetts Harvard University Press, 2004 p. 259.
  28. ^ "No Useless Leniency: Notes on 'Capitalism as Religion'". Leniency.blogspot.com. 17 December 2008. from the original on 4 January 2017. Retrieved 3 January 2017.
  29. ^ . Archived from the original on 4 March 2016.
  30. ^ "Just as the capitalist system continuously produces and reproduces itself economically on higher levels, the structure of reification progressively sinks more deeply, more fatefully, and more definitively into the consciousness of Man." György Lukács, History and Class-Consciousness London: Merlin Press, 1971, p. 93.
  31. ^ Cluley, R. and Dunne, S. (2012) From Commodity Fetishism to Commodity Narcissism, Marketing Theory, 12(3)
  32. ^ Alecia, Waite Cassidy; Edward, Tower; Xiaolu, Wang, Lucy (1 September 2016). "Manufacturing Fetishism: The Neo-Mercantilist Preoccupation with Protecting Manufacturing". SSRN 2833529.{{cite news}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  33. ^ "James G. Carrier". The Social Solidarity Economy resource website. from the original on 18 April 2016. Retrieved 2 November 2021.
  34. ^ Carrier, James (2012). Ethical Consumption. Social Value and Economic Practice. Berghahn Books. pp. 672–689.
  35. ^ Carrier, James G. (21 May 2010). "Protecting the Environment the Natural Way: Ethical Consumption and Commodity Fetishism". Antipode. 42 (3): 672–689. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8330.2010.00768.x. ISSN 0066-4812. from the original on 6 July 2023. Retrieved 9 November 2023.
  36. ^ Carrier, James G. (21 May 2010). "Protecting the Environment the Natural Way: Ethical Consumption and Commodity Fetishism". Antipode. 42 (3): 672–689. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8330.2010.00768.x. ISSN 0066-4812. from the original on 6 July 2023. Retrieved 9 November 2023.
  37. ^ . Tuvalu.santafe.edu. Archived from the original on 17 December 2016. Retrieved 3 January 2017.
  38. ^ Wolfgang Fritz Haug, Critique of Commodity Aesthetics: Appearance, Sexuality and Advertising in Capitalist Society. Introduced by Stuart Hall. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1986.
  39. ^ "Paying for Pensions: Affording Old Age" 24 June 2021 at the Wayback Machine, BBC News, 13 September 2010
  40. ^ Charles Roxburgh; Susan Lund; Charles Atkins; Stanislas Belot; Wayne W. Hu; Moira S. Pierce (September 2009), Global capital markets: entering a new era, McKinsey Global Institute, p. 9, from the original on 7 March 2016, retrieved 3 March 2016
  41. ^ Toporowski, Jan (4 September 2010). "The Wisdom of Property and the Politics of the Middle Classes by Jan Toporowski". Monthly Review. from the original on 9 January 2011. Retrieved 3 January 2017.
  42. ^ Marc Linder, Reification and the consciousness of the critics of political economy. Copenhagen: Rhodos, 1975 and subsequent works.
  43. ^ Duncan Kennedy (1985). "The Role of Law in Economic Theory: Essays on the Fetishism of Commodities" (PDF). The American University Law Review. 34: 939–1001. (PDF) from the original on 24 December 2010. Retrieved 29 June 2010.
  44. ^ Dr Helena Sheehan. "Portrait of a Marxist as a Young Nun". Webpages.dcu.ie. from the original on 22 December 2016. Retrieved 3 January 2017.

Further reading edit

  • Sandel, Michael (2012). What money can't buy : the moral limits of markets. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux. ISBN 9780374203030.
  • Bottomore, Tom (1991). A Dictionary of Marxist thought. Oxford, UK Cambridge, Mass: Blackwell Reference. ISBN 9780631180821.
  • Debord, Guy (2009). The Society of the Spectacle. Eastbourne: Soul Bay Press. ISBN 9780955955334.
  • Fine, Ben (2010). Marx's Capital. London & New York: Pluto Press. ISBN 978-0745330167.
  • Harvey, David (2010). A companion to Marx's Capital. London New York: Verso. ISBN 978-1844673599.
  • Lukács, György (1971). History and Class Consciousness : studies in Marxist dialectics. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press. ISBN 9780262620208.
  • Marx, Karl (1981). Capital :Volume 1: A critique of political economy. London New York, N.Y: Penguin Books in association with New Left Review. ISBN 9780140445688.
  • Douglas, Mary (1996). The world of goods : towards an anthropology of consumption : with a new introduction. London New York: Routledge. ISBN 9780415130479.

External links edit

  • Capital, Chapter 1, Section 4 – The Fetishism of Commodities and the Secret Thereof
  • All of Chapter One – Marx's logical presentation
  • Isaac Rubin's commentary on Marx
  • David Harvey, Reading Marx's Capital, Reading Marx's Capital – Class 2, Chapters 1–2, The Commodity (video lecture)
  • Biene Baumeister,Die Marxsche Kritik des Fetischismus (outline in German)
  • Understanding Capitalism Part IV: Capitalism, Culture and Society

commodity, fetishism, other, uses, fetishism, disambiguation, marxist, philosophy, term, commodity, fetishism, describes, economic, relationships, production, exchange, being, social, relationships, that, exist, among, things, money, merchandise, relationships. For other uses see Fetishism disambiguation In Marxist philosophy the term commodity fetishism describes the economic relationships of production and exchange as being social relationships that exist among things money and merchandise and not as relationships that exist among people As a form of reification commodity fetishism presents economic value as inherent to the commodities and not as arising from the workforce from the human relations that produced the commodity the goods and the services 1 2 Commodity fetishism In the economics of the marketplace the producers and the consumers of goods and services perceive each other as the money and merchandise they exchange Contents 1 Concept 2 Development 3 Critique 3 1 In the critique of political economy 3 2 Domination of things 3 3 Objectified value 3 4 Naturalization of market behaviour 3 5 Masking 3 6 Opacity of economic relations 3 7 Capitalism as religion 4 Applications 4 1 Cultural theory 4 1 1 Sublimated sexuality 4 1 2 Social prestige 4 1 3 Reification 4 1 4 Industrialized culture 4 1 5 Commodity narcissism 4 1 6 Ethical Consumption 4 1 7 Social alienation 4 1 8 Semiotic sign 4 2 Intellectual property 4 2 1 Philosophic base 4 2 2 Knowledge authentic and counterfeit 4 2 3 Financial risk management 4 2 4 Commodified art 4 2 5 Legal traducement 5 Criticism 6 See also 7 References 8 Further reading 9 External linksConcept editIn the first chapter of Capital A Critique of Political Economy 1867 commodity fetishism is used to explain how the social organization of labour manifests in the buying and selling of commodities goods and services In the marketplace social relations among people who makes what who works for whom the production time for a commodity etc are represented as social relations among objects 3 In the process of commercial exchange commodities appear in a depersonalized form obscuring the social relations inherent to their production 4 Marx explained the sociology of commodity fetishism As against this the commodity form and the value relation of the products of labour within which it appears have absolutely no connection with the physical nature of the commodity and the material relations arising out of this It is nothing but the definite social relation between men themselves which assumes here for them the fantastic form of a relation between things In order therefore to find an analogy we must take flight into the misty realm of religion There the products of the human brain appear as autonomous figures endowed with a life of their own which enter into relations both with each other and with the human race So it is in the world of commodities with the products of men s hands I call this the fetishism which attaches itself to the products of labour as soon as they are produced as commodities and is therefore inseparable from the production of commodities 5 According to Marx the operation of commodity fetishism requires the owners of capital to actively ignore or maintain an indifference to the relational whole that produces a commodity 6 132 Development edit nbsp A South African fetish figurine whose supernatural powers protect the owner and kin in the natural world c 1900 nbsp A political poster shows gold coin as the basis of prosperity c 1896 The theory of commodity fetishism German Warenfetischismus originated from Karl Marx s references to fetishes and fetishism in his analyses of religious superstition and in the criticism of the beliefs of political economists 7 Marx borrowed the concept of fetishism from The Cult of Fetish Gods 1760 by Charles de Brosses which proposed a materialist theory of the origin of religion 8 9 Moreover in the 1840s the philosophic discussion of fetishism by Auguste Comte and Ludwig Feuerbach s psychological interpretation of religion also influenced Marx s development of commodity fetishism 10 11 Marx s first mention of fetishism appeared in 1842 in his response to a newspaper article by Karl Heinrich Hermes which defended Germany on religious grounds 12 Hermes agreed with the German philosopher Hegel in regarding fetishism as the crudest form of religion Marx dismissed that argument and Hermes s definition of religion as that which elevates man above sensuous appetites Instead Marx said that fetishism is the religion of sensuous appetites and that the fantasy of the appetites tricks the fetish worshipper into believing that an inanimate object will yield its natural character to gratify the desires of the worshipper Therefore the crude appetite of the fetish worshipper smashes the fetish when it ceases to be of service 13 14 15 The next mention of fetishism was in the 1842 Rheinische Zeitung newspaper articles about the Debates on the Law on Thefts of Wood wherein Marx spoke of the Spanish fetishism of gold and the German fetishism of wood as commodities 16 The savages of Cuba regarded gold as a fetish of the Spaniards They celebrated a feast in its honour sang in a circle around it and then threw it into the sea If the Cuban savages had been present at the sitting of the Rhine Province Assembly would they not have regarded wood as the Rhinelanders fetish But a subsequent sitting would have taught them that the worship of animals is connected with this fetishism and they would have thrown the hares into the sea in order to save the human beings In the Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844 Marx spoke of the European fetish of precious metal money The nations which are still dazzled by the sensuous glitter of precious metals and are therefore still fetish worshippers of metal money are not yet fully developed money nations Note the contrast of France and England The extent to which the solution of theoretical riddles is the task of practice and is effected through practice the extent to which true practice is the condition of a real and positive theory is shown for example in fetishism The sensuous consciousness of the fetish worshipper is different from that of the Greek because his sensuous existence is different The abstract enmity between sense and spirit is necessary so long as the human feeling for nature the human sense of nature and therefore also the natural sense of man are not yet produced by man s own labour 17 In the ethnological notebooks he commented upon the archaeological reportage of The Origin of Civilization and the Primitive Condition of Man Mental and Social conditions of Savages 1870 by John Lubbock 18 In the Outlines of the Critique of Political Economy Grundrisse 1859 he criticized the liberal arguments of the French economist Frederic Bastiat and about fetishes and fetishism Marx said In real history wage labour arises out of the dissolution of slavery and serfdom or of the decay of communal property as with Oriental and Slavonic peoples and in its adequate epoch making form the form which takes possession of the entire social being of labour out of the decline and fall of the guild economy of the system of Estates of labour and income in kind of industry carried on as rural subsidiary occupation of small scale feudal agriculture etc In all these real historic transitions wage labour appears as the dissolution the annihilation of relations in which labour was fixed on all sides in its income its content its location its scope etc Hence as negation of the stability of labour and of its remuneration The direct transition from the African s fetish to Voltaire s Supreme Being or from the hunting gear of a North American savage to the capital of the Bank of England is not so absurdly contrary to history as is the transition from Bastiat s fisherman to the wage labourer 19 In A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy 1859 Marx referred to A Discourse on the Rise Progress Peculiar Objects and Importance of Political Economy 1825 by John Ramsay McCulloch who said that In its natural state matter is always destitute of value with which Marx concurred saying that this shows how high even a McCulloch stands above the fetishism of German thinkers who assert that material and half a dozen similar irrelevancies are elements of value Furthermore in the manuscript of Results of the Immediate Process of Production c 1864 an appendix to Capital Critique of Political Economy Volume 1 1867 Marx said that we find in the capitalist process of production an indissoluble fusion of use values in which capital subsists as means of production and objects defined as capital when what we are really faced with is a definite social relationship of production In consequence the product embedded in this mode of production is equated with the commodity by those who have to deal with it It is this that forms the foundation for the fetishism of the political economists 20 Hence did Karl Marx apply the concepts of fetish and fetishism derived from economic and ethnologic studies to the development of the theory of commodity fetishism wherein an economic abstraction value is psychologically transformed reified into an object which people choose to believe has an intrinsic value in and of itself 21 Critique editIn the critique of political economy edit Marx proposed that in a society where independent private producers trade their products with each other of their own volition and initiative and without much coordination of market exchange the volumes of production and commercial activities are adjusted in accordance with the fluctuating values of the products goods and services as they are bought and sold and in accordance with the fluctuations of supply and demand Because their social coexistence and its meaning is expressed through market exchange trade and transaction people have no other relations with each other Therefore social relations are continually mediated and expressed with objects commodities and money How the traded commodities relate will depend upon the costs of production which are reducible to quantities of human labour although the worker has no control over what happens to the commodities that they produce See Entfremdung Marx s theory of alienation Domination of things edit The concept of the intrinsic value of commodities goods and services determines and dominates the economic business relationships among people to the extent that buyers and sellers continually adjust their beliefs financial expectations about the value of things either consciously or unconsciously to the proportionate price changes market value of the commodities over which buyers and sellers believe they have no true control That psychologic perception transforms the trading value of a commodity into an independent entity an object to the degree that the social value of the goods and services appears to be a natural property of the commodity itself Thence objectified the market appears as if self regulated by fluctuating supply and demand because in pursuit of profit the consumers of the products ceased to perceive the human co operation among capitalists that is the true engine of the market where commodities are bought and sold such is the domination of things in the market Objectified value edit The value of a commodity originates from the human being s intellectual and perceptual capacity to consciously subjectively ascribe a relative value importance to a commodity the goods and services manufactured by the labour of a worker Therefore in the course of the economic transactions buying and selling that constitute market exchange people ascribe subjective values to the commodities goods and services which the buyers and the sellers then perceive as objective values the market exchange prices that people will pay for the commodities Naturalization of market behaviour edit In a capitalist society the human perception that the market is an independent sentient entity is how buyers sellers and producers naturalize market exchange the human choices and decisions that constitute commerce as a series of natural phenomena that happen of their own accord Such were the political economy arguments of the economists whom Karl Marx criticized when they spoke of the natural equilibria of markets as if the price value of a commodity were independent of the volition and initiative of the capitalist producers buyers and sellers of commodities In the 18th century the Scottish social philosopher and political economist Adam Smith in The Wealth of Nations 1776 proposed that the truck barter and exchange activities of the market were corresponding economic representations of human nature that is the buying and selling of commodities were activities intrinsic to the market and thus are the natural behaviour of the market Hence Smith proposed that a market economy was a self regulating entity that naturally tended towards economic equilibrium wherein the relative prices the value of a commodity ensured that the buyers and sellers obtained what they wanted for and from their goods and services 22 In the 19th century Karl Marx contradicted the artifice of Adam Smith s naturalisation of the market s behaviour as a politico ideologic apology by and for the capitalists which allowed human economic choices and decisions to be misrepresented as fixed facts of life rather than as the human actions that resulted from the will of the producers the buyers and the sellers of the commodities traded at market Such immutable economic laws are what Capital Critique of Political Economy 1867 revealed about the functioning of the capitalist mode of production how goods and services commodities are circulated among a society and thus explain the psychological phenomenon of commodity fetishism which ascribes an independent objective value and reality to a thing that has no inherent value other than the value given to it by the producer the seller and the buyer of the commodity Masking edit In a capitalist economy a character mask Charaktermaske is the functional role with which a person relates and is related to in a society composed of stratified social classes especially in relationships and market exchange transactions thus in the course of buying and selling the commodities goods and services usually appear other than they are because they are masked obscured by the role playing of the buyer and the seller Moreover because the capitalist economy of a class society is an intrinsically contradictory system the masking of the true socio economic character of the transaction is an integral feature of its function and operation as market exchange In the course of business competition among themselves buyers sellers and producers cannot do business compete without obscurity confidentiality and secrecy thus the necessity of the character masks that obscure true economic motive Central to the Marxist critique of political economy is the obscurantism of the juridical labour contract between the worker and the capitalist that masks the true exploitive nature of their economic relationship that the worker does not sell his and her labour but that the worker sells individual labour power the human capacity to perform work and manufacture commodities goods and services that yield a profit to the producer The work contract is the mask that obscures the economic exploitation of the difference between the wages paid for the labour of the worker and the new value created by the labour of the worker Marx thus established that in a capitalist society the creation of wealth is based upon the paid and unpaid portions of labour that are inseparably mixed up with each other and the nature of the whole transaction is completely masked by the intervention of a contract and the pay received at the end of the week and that 23 24 25 Vulgar economics actually does nothing more than to interpret to systematize and turn into apologetics in a doctrinaire way the ideas of the agents who are trapped within bourgeois relations of production So it should not surprise us that precisely within the estranged form of appearance of economic relations in which these prima facie absurd and complete contradictions occur and all science would be superfluous if the form of appearance of things directly coincided with their essence that precisely here vulgar economics feels completely at home and that these relationships appear all the more self evident to it the more their inner interconnection remains hidden to it even though these relationships are comprehensible to the popular mind Capital Volume III 26 Opacity of economic relations edit The primary valuation of the trading value of goods and services commodities is expressed as money prices The buyers and the sellers determine and establish the economic and financial relationships and afterwards compare the prices in and the price trends of the market Moreover because of the masking of true economic motive neither the buyer nor the seller nor the producer perceive and understand every human labour activity required to deliver the commodities goods and services nor do they perceive the workers whose labour facilitated the purchase of commodities The economic results of such collective human labour are expressed as the values and the prices of the commodities the value relations between the amount of human labour and the value of the supplied commodity Capitalism as religion edit In the essay Capitalism as Religion 1921 Walter Benjamin said that whether or not people treat capitalism as a religion was a moot subject because One can behold in capitalism a religion that is to say capitalism essentially serves to satisfy the same worries anguish and disquiet formerly answered by so called religion That the religion of capitalism is manifest in four tenets i Capitalism is a purely cultic religion perhaps the most extreme that ever existed ii The permanence of the cult iii Capitalism is probably the first instance of a cult that creates guilt not atonement iv God must be hidden from it and may be addressed only when guilt is at its zenith 27 28 Applications editCultural theory edit nbsp The Hungarian philosopher Gyorgy Lukacs developed Karl Marx s theory of commodity fetishism to develop reification theory nbsp Thorstein Veblen proposed the conspicuous consumption of commodities as the pursuit of social prestige Since the 19th century when Karl Marx presented the theory of commodity fetishism in Section 4 The Fetishism of Commodities and the Secret thereof of the first chapter of Capital Critique of Political Economy 1867 the constituent concepts of the theory and their sociologic and economic explanations have proved intellectually fertile propositions that permit the application of the theory interpretation development adaptation to the study examination and analysis of other cultural aspects of the political economy of capitalism such as Sublimated sexuality edit The theory of sexual fetishism which Alfred Binet presented in the essay Le fetichisme dans l amour la vie psychique des micro organismes l intensite des images mentales etc Fetishism in Love the Psychic Life of Micro organisms the Intensity of Mental Images etc 1887 was applied to interpret commodity fetishism as types of sexually charged economic relationships between a person and a commodity goods and services as in the case of advertising which is a commercial enterprise that ascribes human qualities values to a commodity to persuade the buyer to purchase the advertised goods and services 29 However Marx focused on the exchange value of the commodity its price when considering commodity fetishism and its hiding of the complex social relationships involved in producing and exchanging a product under capitalism He was not discussing the symbolic meanings of the commodity for the consumer or what he called its use value Hence sexual fetishism and commodity fetishism are largely unconnected concepts citation needed Social prestige edit In the 19th and in the 21st centuries Thorstein Veblen The Theory of the Leisure Class An Economic Study of Institutions 1899 and Alain de Botton Status Anxiety 2004 respectively developed the social status prestige relationship between the producer of consumer goods and the aspirations to prestige of the consumer To avoid the status anxiety of not being of or belonging to the right social class the consumer establishes a personal identity social economic cultural that is defined and expressed by the commodities goods and services that they buy own and use the domination of things that communicate the correct signals of social prestige of belonging See Conspicuous consumption Reification edit In History and Class Consciousness 1923 Gyorgy Lukacs started from the theory of commodity fetishism for his development of reification the psychological transformation of an abstraction into a concrete object as the principal obstacle to class consciousness About which Lukacs said Just as the capitalist system continuously produces and reproduces itself economically on higher levels the structure of reification progressively sinks more deeply more fatefully and more definitively into the consciousness of Man hence commodification pervaded every conscious human activity as the growth of capitalism commodified every sphere of human activity into a product that can be bought and sold in the market 30 See Verdinglichung Marx s theory of reification Industrialized culture edit Commodity fetishism is theoretically central to the Frankfurt School philosophy especially in the work of the sociologist Theodor W Adorno which describes how the forms of commerce invade the human psyche how commerce casts a person into a role not of his or her making and how commercial forces affect the development of the psyche In the book Dialectic of Enlightenment 1944 Adorno and Max Horkheimer presented the Theory of the Culture Industry to describe how the human imagination artistic spiritual intellectual activity becomes commodified when subordinated to the natural commercial laws of the market To the consumer the cultural goods and services sold in the market appear to offer the promise of a richly developed and creative individuality yet the inherent commodification severely restricts and stunts the human psyche so that the man and the woman consumer has little time for myself because of the continual personification of cultural roles over which he and she exercise little control In personifying such cultural identities the person is a passive consumer not the active creator of his or her life the promised life of individualistic creativity is incompatible with the collectivist commercial norms of bourgeois culture Commodity narcissism edit In the study From Commodity Fetishism to Commodity Narcissism 2012 the investigators applied the Marxist theory of commodity fetishism to psychologically analyse the economic behaviour buying and selling of the contemporary consumer With the concept of commodity narcissism the psychologists Stephen Dunne and Robert Cluley proposed that consumers who claim to be ethically concerned about the manufacturing origin of commodities nonetheless behaved as if ignorant of the exploitative labour conditions under which the workers produced the goods and services bought by the concerned consumer that within the culture of consumerism narcissistic men and women have established shopping economic consumption as a socially acceptable way to express aggression 31 Researchers find no evidence that a greater manufacturing base can spur economic growth while improving government effectiveness and regulation quality are more promising for facilitating economic growth 32 Ethical Consumption edit Environmentally conscious consumers want their purchased products to be environmentally ethical According to James G Carrier 33 on a personal level their purchases can make them feel more positively moral and second they can help put pressure on firms in a competitive market to change the way they do things Marx s 1867 notion of commodity fetishism which concerns the idea that ethical consumption is going beyond the two reasons first noted by Carrier according to whom Certain commodities are perceived in a particular way that the consumer ignores or denies the labor time entailed in the process of production or for that matter any detailed background people and process that is viable in creating an ethical product Capitalists have the intention of selling to an audience with commercial gain the use of nature as a strategy is vital in urging people to buy their product Ethical consumption is mostly concerned with the social political and environmental context of objects and consumers want a product that meets their moral criteria something non exploitative These baseline concepts need to be visible and eye catching with recognizable verifications This is very common in ecotourism who produce eco friendliness as a reason to buy and visit Advertising protection and conservation attracts visitors and media attention These capitalists make no point to vary in their images and photographs or captions the repetition of nature is always colorful and vibrant gentle and reserved They are fetishizing nature as a marketing technique Portraying themselves as a business that protects nature satisfies their clientele so that the consumer cannot see the objects and mechanisms used to actually produce it Carrier describes how the environment itself is fetishized as a consumable product through parks and other areas of land being used as bodies or images attached to promises of natural experiences or protection efforts in return for money Carrier also offers the example of fair trade coffee as a way that commodity fetishism is seen in ethical consumption If fair trade coffee promises that it is direct cooperative supply chain between growers and consumers through images of coffee growers and messaging on the bag of coffee this becomes more relevant to consumer decision making than the reality that many other middle men were needing in the roasting packaging marketing and transportation of that commodity 34 Ethical consumption is believed by advocates of the theory to allow people to lead more moral lives as well as affect the world by placing economic pressure on firms to change their production processes and products to become more ethical to remain competitive within the greater market The fetishization of nature and natural resources often leads through its commodification as a product to be advertised Conceptual categories need to be legible be visible and recognizable 35 in order to be effective as ethical standards The advertising on items listed and named as fair trade often misrepresents the actual production process especially in products requiring extensive and hard labor to produce such as coffee It also often becomes exploitative as it uses the images of ethnic small holders rather than the ethnic migrants and wage laborers who do the majority of the work The use of images not only fetishizes the product but defines ethicality as a whole 36 A common narrative now is whether or not ethical consumption is at all possible in a globalized world of highly interconnected capitalism and trade It relies on ideas of greenwashing in which producers use environmentalism and fair trade ideals to advertise their products without living up to the ideals The false image of environmentalism disguises the unsustainable practices being utilized Another critique is the overall effectiveness of individual consumer choices without large scale systemic change through government regulation Accessibility is another issue as ethical products are often more expensive and less accessible to low income activists Social alienation edit In The Society of the Spectacle 1967 Guy Debord presented the theory of le spectacle the systematic conflation of advanced capitalism the mass communications media and a government amenable to exploiting those factors The spectacle transforms human relations into objectified relations among images and vice versa the exemplar spectacle is television the communications medium wherein people passively allow cultural representations of themselves to become the active agents of their beliefs The spectacle is the form that society assumes when the Arts the instruments of cultural production have been commodified as commercial activities that render an aesthetic value into a commercial value a commodity Whereby artistic expression then is shaped by the person s ability to sell it as a commodity that is as artistic goods and services Capitalism reorganizes personal consumption to conform to the commercial principles of market exchange commodity fetishism transforms a cultural commodity into a product with an economic life of its own that is independent of the volition and initiative of the artist the producer of the commodity What Karl Marx critically anticipated in the 19th century with The Fetishism of Commodities and the Secret thereof Guy Debord interpreted and developed for the 20th century that in modern society the psychologic intimacies of intersubjectivity and personal self relation are commodified into discrete experiences that can be bought and sold The Society of the Spectacle is the ultimate form of social alienation that occurs when a person views his or her being self as a commodity that can be bought and sold because they regard every human relation as a potential business transaction See Entfremdung Marx s theory of alienation Semiotic sign edit Jean Baudrillard applied commodity fetishism to explain the subjective feelings of men and women towards consumer goods in the realm of circulation that is the cultural mystique mystification that advertising ascribed to the commodities goods and services in order to encourage the buyer to purchase the goods and services as aids to the construction of his and her cultural identity In the book For a Critique of the Political Economy of the Sign 1972 Baudrillard developed the semiotic theory of the Sign sign value as a development of Marx s theory of commodity fetishism and of the exchange value vs use value dichotomy of capitalism Intellectual property edit In the 21st century the political economy of capitalism reified the abstract objects that are information and knowledge into the tangible commodities of intellectual property which are produced by and derived from the labours of the intellectual and the white collar workers Philosophic base edit The economist Michael Perelman critically examined the belief systems from which arose intellectual property rights the field of law that commodified knowledge and information Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis critically reviewed the belief systems of the theory of human capital 37 Knowledge as the philosophic means to a better life is contrasted with capitalist knowledge as commodity and capital produced to generate income and profit Such commodification detaches knowledge and information from the user person because as intellectual property they are independent economic entities Knowledge authentic and counterfeit edit In Postmodernism or the Cultural Logic of Late Capitalism 1991 the Marxist theorist Fredric Jameson linked the reification of information and knowledge to the post modern distinction between authentic knowledge experience and counterfeit knowledge vicarious experience which usually is acquired through the mass communications media In Critique of Commodity Aesthetics Appearance Sexuality and Advertising in Capitalist Society 1986 the philosopher Wolfgang Fritz Haug presents a critique of commodity aesthetics that examines how human needs and desires are manipulated and reshaped for commercial gain 38 Financial risk management edit The sociologists Frank Furedi and Ulrich Beck studied the development of commodified types of knowledge in the business culture of risk prevention in the management of money The Post World War II economic expansion c 1945 1973 created very much money capital and savings while the dominant bourgeois ideology of money favoured the risk management philosophy of the managers of investment funds and financial assets From such administration of investment money manipulated to create new capital arose the preoccupation with risk calculations which subsequently was followed by the economic science of risk prevention management 39 40 In light of which the commodification of money as financial investment funds allows an ordinary person to pose as a rich person as an economic risk taker able to risk losing money invested to the market Hence the fetishization of financial risk as a sum of money is a reification that distorts the social perception of the true nature of financial risk as experienced by ordinary people 41 Moreover the valuation of financial risk is susceptible to ideological bias that contemporary fortunes are achieved from the insight of experts in financial management who study the relationship between known and unknown economic factors by which human fears about money can be manipulated and exploited Commodified art edit The cultural critics Georg Simmel and Walter Benjamin examined and described the fetishes and fetishism of Art by means of which artistic commodities are produced for sale in the market and how commodification determines and establishes the value of the artistic commodities goods and services derived from legitimate Art for example the selling of an artist s personal effects as artistic fetishes Legal traducement edit In the field of law the scholar Evgeny Pashukanis The General Theory of Law and Marxism 1924 the Austrian politician Karl Renner the German political scientist Franz Leopold Neumann the British socialist writer China Mieville the labour law attorney Marc Linder and the American legal philosopher Duncan Kennedy The Role of Law in Economic Theory Essays on the Fetishism of Commodities 1985 have respectively explored the applications of commodity fetishism in their contemporary legal systems and reported that the reification of legal forms misrepresents social relations 42 43 Criticism edit nbsp The Tribuna of the Uffizi 1772 1778 by Johann Zoffany depicts the commodity fetishism metamorphosis of oil paintings into culture industry products In Portrait of a Marxist as a Young Nun 1988 Professor Helena Sheehan said that the analogy between religious faith and commodity fetishism is a mistaken interpretation because people do not worship commodities money and merchandise by attributing supernatural powers to inanimate objects to a fetish That the belief that value relationships inherent to a commodity described is not religious belief because value relations do not possess the psychological characteristics of spiritual beliefs That interpretation is proved by the possibility of a person s possessing religious faith whilst being aware of the psychology of commodity fetishism and thus being critical of the fetishization of money and merchandise thus a person s disbelief in the Golden Calf is integral to the person s iconoclasm against the idolatry of money 44 See also editPre Marxist theoriesSimple livingMarxist theories pertinent to the theory of commodity fetishismCharacter mask Commodity Marxism Critique of political economy Exchange value False consciousness Fetishism Labor theory of value Law of value Real prices and ideal prices Reification Marxism Relations of production Use value Value formPost Marxist theories derived from the theory of commodity fetishismEssays of Marx s Theory of Value by Isaak Illich Rubin History and Class Consciousness Reification and the Consciousness of the Proletariat theories of class consciousness and of reification by Georg Lukacs The Society of the Spectacle by Guy Debord full text The System of Objects by Jean Baudrillard Neomaterialism by Joshua Simon Time Labor and Social Domination by Moishe Postone Value criticism in German Wertkritik References edit Marx Karl 1887 Capital Volume One Moscow Progress Publishers Archived from the original on 7 June 2019 Retrieved 11 January 2020 A commodity is therefore a mysterious thing simply because in it the social character of men s labour appears to them as an objective character stamped upon the product of that labour because the relation of the producers to the sum total of their own labour is presented to them as a social relation existing not between themselves but between the products of their labour Isaak Illich Rubin said that The theory of fetishism is per se the basis of Marx s entire economic system and in particular of his theory of value Essays on Marx s Theory of Value Montreal Black Rose Books 1990 p 5 Roubine Isaak I 2009 Essais sur la theorie de la valeur de Marx Paris Syllepse p 55 ISBN 978 2 84950 218 1 Rubin Isaak Illich 1972 Essays on Marx s Theory of Value Detroit Black and Red Archived from the original on 31 May 2020 Retrieved 10 January 2020 Marx Karl 1990 Capital London Penguin Classics p 165 Driscoll Mark W 2020 The Whites are Enemies of Heaven Climate Caucasianism and Asian Ecological Protection Durham Duke University Press ISBN 978 1 4780 1121 7 The various references in the Wood Theft articles to idols animal masks workship of animals and fetishes reflect Marx s systematic study 1841 42 of primitive religion The notebooks indicate that Marx was especially interested in the concept of fetishism its nature its origins and the difference between ancient and modern forms of fetishism MEGA Vol 1 Part 2 p 115ff Sherover Erica 1979 The Virtue of Poverty Marx s Transformation of Hegel s Concept of the Poor PDF Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory 3 1 53 66 Archived PDF from the original on 13 October 2011 Retrieved 1 October 2011 Du culte des dieux fetiches ou Parallele de l ancienne religion de l Egypte avec la religion actuelle de Nigritie Reprod in French 15 October 2007 Archived from the original on 6 December 2016 Retrieved 3 January 2017 via Gallica bnf fr The German translation was Uber den Dienst der fetischengotter oder Vergleichung der alten religion Egyptians mit den heutigen Religion Nigritiens Ubersetzt von Christian Brandanus Hermann Pistorius Berlin Stralsund Gottlieb August Lange 1785 For a study of the conceptual origin of fetishism see William Pietz The problem of the fetish I Res 9 Spring 1985 pp 5 17 The problem of the fetish II The origin of the fetish Res 13 Spring 1987 pp 23 45 The problem of the fetish III Bosman s Guinea and the enlightenment theory of fetishism Res 16 Autumn 1988 pp 105 123 Philosophy3 p65 PDF Socserv mcmaster ca Archived PDF from the original on 7 July 2012 Retrieved 3 January 2017 Feuerbach Ludwig 2008 The Essence of Christianity PDF Translated by Eliot George MSAC Philosophy Group ISBN 978 1 56543 102 7 Archived from the original PDF on 14 June 2012 Leading Article in No 179 of the Kolnische Zeitung Archived from the original on 9 March 2001 Karl Marx and Frederick Engels On religion Atlanta Scholars 1982 p 22 Commodity fetishism Fredy Perlman 2006 Archived from the original on 25 December 2007 The fetishism of commodities 2016 Archived from the original on 28 June 2019 1842 Debates on the Law on Thefts of Wood Archived from the original on 9 March 2001 Karl Marx 1975 Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844 in Marx Engels Collected Works Moscow Progress p 312 Archived from the original on 22 September 2023 Retrieved 8 June 2010 Lawrence Krader ed The Ethnological Notebooks of Karl Marx Studies of Morgan Phear Maine Lubbock Assen Van Gorcum 1972 p 342f Grundrisse 17 Marxists org Archived from the original on 21 February 2012 Retrieved 3 January 2017 Karl Marx Results of the Immediate Process of Production appendix in Capital Volume 1 Penguin edition 1976 p 983 For more details see Boer Roland 2010 That Hideous Pagan Idol Marx Fetishism and Graven Images Critique Journal of Socialist Theory 38 1 93 116 doi 10 1080 03017600903454413 S2CID 143420404 Smith Adam An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations Geolib com Archived from the original on 27 January 2017 Retrieved 3 January 2017 Karl Marx Value Price and Profit part 9 Marxists org Archived from the original on 21 December 2016 Retrieved 3 January 2017 the paid and unpaid portions of labour are inseparably mixed up with each other and the nature of the whole transaction is completely masked by the intervention of a contract and the pay received at the end of the week Karl Marx 1875 Critique of the Gotha Programme Marxists org p part 2 emphases added Archived from the original on 16 July 2018 Retrieved 3 January 2017 Since Lassalle s death there has asserted itself in our party the scientific understanding that wages are not what they appear to be namely the value or price of labor but only a masked form for the value or price of labor power cf the Resultate manuscript in Capital Volume I Penguin edition p 1064 where Marx uses the word vertuscht covered up Marx Capital Volume III Penguin edition p 956 translation corrected to the German edition Capitalism as Religion by Walter Benjamin in Walter Benjamin Selected Writings Vol 1 1913 1926 Michael W Jennings ed Cambridge Massachusetts Harvard University Press 2004 p 259 No Useless Leniency Notes on Capitalism as Religion Leniency blogspot com 17 December 2008 Archived from the original on 4 January 2017 Retrieved 3 January 2017 Le fetichisme dans l amour the Art and Popular Culture Encyclopedia Archived from the original on 4 March 2016 Just as the capitalist system continuously produces and reproduces itself economically on higher levels the structure of reification progressively sinks more deeply more fatefully and more definitively into the consciousness of Man Gyorgy Lukacs History and Class Consciousness London Merlin Press 1971 p 93 Cluley R and Dunne S 2012 From Commodity Fetishism to Commodity Narcissism Marketing Theory 12 3 Alecia Waite Cassidy Edward Tower Xiaolu Wang Lucy 1 September 2016 Manufacturing Fetishism The Neo Mercantilist Preoccupation with Protecting Manufacturing SSRN 2833529 a href Template Cite news html title Template Cite news cite news a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link James G Carrier The Social Solidarity Economy resource website Archived from the original on 18 April 2016 Retrieved 2 November 2021 Carrier James 2012 Ethical Consumption Social Value and Economic Practice Berghahn Books pp 672 689 Carrier James G 21 May 2010 Protecting the Environment the Natural Way Ethical Consumption and Commodity Fetishism Antipode 42 3 672 689 doi 10 1111 j 1467 8330 2010 00768 x ISSN 0066 4812 Archived from the original on 6 July 2023 Retrieved 9 November 2023 Carrier James G 21 May 2010 Protecting the Environment the Natural Way Ethical Consumption and Commodity Fetishism Antipode 42 3 672 689 doi 10 1111 j 1467 8330 2010 00768 x ISSN 0066 4812 Archived from the original on 6 July 2023 Retrieved 9 November 2023 Samuel Bowles Tuvalu santafe edu Archived from the original on 17 December 2016 Retrieved 3 January 2017 Wolfgang Fritz Haug Critique of Commodity Aesthetics Appearance Sexuality and Advertising in Capitalist Society Introduced by Stuart Hall Minneapolis University of Minnesota Press 1986 Paying for Pensions Affording Old Age Archived 24 June 2021 at the Wayback Machine BBC News 13 September 2010 Charles Roxburgh Susan Lund Charles Atkins Stanislas Belot Wayne W Hu Moira S Pierce September 2009 Global capital markets entering a new era McKinsey Global Institute p 9 archived from the original on 7 March 2016 retrieved 3 March 2016 Toporowski Jan 4 September 2010 The Wisdom of Property and the Politics of the Middle Classes by Jan Toporowski Monthly Review Archived from the original on 9 January 2011 Retrieved 3 January 2017 Marc Linder Reification and the consciousness of the critics of political economy Copenhagen Rhodos 1975 and subsequent works Duncan Kennedy 1985 The Role of Law in Economic Theory Essays on the Fetishism of Commodities PDF The American University Law Review 34 939 1001 Archived PDF from the original on 24 December 2010 Retrieved 29 June 2010 Dr Helena Sheehan Portrait of a Marxist as a Young Nun Webpages dcu ie Archived from the original on 22 December 2016 Retrieved 3 January 2017 Further reading editSandel Michael 2012 What money can t buy the moral limits of markets New York Farrar Straus and Giroux ISBN 9780374203030 Bottomore Tom 1991 A Dictionary of Marxist thought Oxford UK Cambridge Mass Blackwell Reference ISBN 9780631180821 Debord Guy 2009 The Society of the Spectacle Eastbourne Soul Bay Press ISBN 9780955955334 Fine Ben 2010 Marx s Capital London amp New York Pluto Press ISBN 978 0745330167 Harvey David 2010 A companion to Marx s Capital London New York Verso ISBN 978 1844673599 Lukacs Gyorgy 1971 History and Class Consciousness studies in Marxist dialectics Cambridge Mass MIT Press ISBN 9780262620208 Marx Karl 1981 Capital Volume 1 A critique of political economy London New York N Y Penguin Books in association with New Left Review ISBN 9780140445688 Douglas Mary 1996 The world of goods towards an anthropology of consumption with a new introduction London New York Routledge ISBN 9780415130479 External links edit nbsp Wikiquote has quotations related to Commodity fetishism Capital Chapter 1 Section 4 The Fetishism of Commodities and the Secret Thereof All of Chapter One Marx s logical presentation Isaac Rubin s commentary on Marx The Reality behind Commodity Fetishism David Harvey Reading Marx s Capital Reading Marx s Capital Class 2 Chapters 1 2 The Commodity video lecture Biene Baumeister Die Marxsche Kritik des Fetischismus outline in German Understanding Capitalism Part IV Capitalism Culture and Society Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Commodity fetishism amp oldid 1189897314, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.