fbpx
Wikipedia

Recession

In economics, a recession is a business cycle contraction that occurs when there is a general decline in economic activity.[1][2] Recessions generally occur when there is a widespread drop in spending (an adverse demand shock). This may be triggered by various events, such as a financial crisis, an external trade shock, an adverse supply shock, the bursting of an economic bubble, or a large-scale anthropogenic or natural disaster (e.g. a pandemic).

In the United States, a recession is defined as "a significant decline in economic activity spread across the market, lasting more than a few months, normally visible in real GDP, real income, employment, industrial production, and wholesale-retail sales."[3] The European Union has adopted a similar definition.[4][5] In the United Kingdom, a recession is defined as negative economic growth for two consecutive quarters.[6][7]

Governments usually respond to recessions by adopting expansionary macroeconomic policies, such as increasing money supply and decreasing interest rates or increasing government spending and decreasing taxation.

Definitions edit

In a 1974 article by The New York Times, Commissioner of the Bureau of Labor Statistics Julius Shiskin suggested that a rough translation of the bureau's qualitative definition of a recession into a quantitative one that almost anyone can use might run like this:

  • In terms of duration – Declines in real gross national product (GNP) for two consecutive quarters; a decline in industrial production over a six-month period.
  • In terms of depth – A 1.5% decline in real GNP; a 15% decline in non-agricultural employment; a two-point rise in unemployment to a level of at least 6%.
  • In terms of diffusion – A decline in non-agricultural employment in more than 75% of industries, as measured over six-month spans, for six months or longer.[8][9][10]

Over the years, some commentators dropped most of Shiskin's "recession-spotting" criteria for the simplistic rule-of-thumb of a decline in real GNP for two consecutive quarters.[11]

In the United States, the Business Cycle Dating Committee of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) is generally seen as the authority for dating US recessions. The NBER, a private economic research organization, defines an economic recession as: "a significant decline in economic activity spread across the economy, lasting more than a few months, normally visible in real GDP, real income, employment, industrial production, and wholesale-retail sales".[12] The NBER is considered the official arbiter of recession start and end dates for the United States.[13][14][15] The Bureau of Economic Analysis, an independent federal agency that provides official macroeconomic and industry statistics,[16] says "the often-cited identification of a recession with two consecutive quarters of negative GDP growth is not an official designation" and that instead, "The designation of a recession is the province of a committee of experts at the National Bureau of Economic Research".[17]

The European Union adopted a definition similar to that of the NBER, using GDP alongside additional macroeconomic variables such as employment and other measures to assess the depth of decline in economic activity.[4][5]

Recessions in the United Kingdom are generally defined as two consecutive quarters of negative economic growth, as measured by the seasonal adjusted quarter-on-quarter figures for real GDP.[6][7]

The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) defines a recession as a period of at least two years during which the cumulative output gap reaches at least 2% of GDP, and the output gap is at least 1% for at least one year.[18]

Recession can be defined as decline of GDP per capita instead of decline of total GDP.[19]

Attributes edit

A recession has many attributes that can occur simultaneously and includes declines in component measures of economic activity (GDP) such as consumption, investment, government spending, and net export activity. These summary measures reflect underlying drivers such as employment levels and skills, household savings rates, corporate investment decisions, interest rates, demographics, and government policies.

Economist Richard C. Koo wrote that under ideal conditions, a country's economy should have the household sector as net savers and the corporate sector as net borrowers, with the government budget nearly balanced and net exports near zero.[20][21]

A severe (GDP down by 10%) or prolonged (three or four years) recession is referred to as an economic depression, although some argue that their causes and cures can be different.[22] As an informal shorthand, economists sometimes refer to different recession shapes, such as V-shaped, U-shaped, L-shaped and W-shaped recessions.[23]

Type of recession or shape edit

The type and shape of recessions are distinctive. In the US, v-shaped, or short-and-sharp contractions followed by rapid and sustained recovery, occurred in 1954 and 1990–1991; U-shaped (prolonged slump) in 1974–1975, and W-shaped, or double-dip recessions in 1949 and 1980–1982. Japan's 1993–1994 recession was U-shaped and its 8-out-of-9 quarters of contraction in 1997–1999 can be described as L-shaped. Korea, Hong Kong and South-east Asia experienced U-shaped recessions in 1997–1998, although Thailand's eight consecutive quarters of decline should be termed L-shaped.[24]

Psychological aspects edit

Recessions have psychological and confidence aspects. For example, if companies expect economic activity to slow, they may reduce employment levels and save money rather than invest. Such expectations can create a self-reinforcing downward cycle, bringing about or worsening a recession.[25] Consumer confidence is one measure used to evaluate economic sentiment.[26] The term animal spirits has been used to describe the psychological factors underlying economic activity. Keynes, in his The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, was the first economist to claim that such emotional mindsets significantly affect the economy.[27] Economist Robert J. Shiller wrote that the term "refers also to the sense of trust we have in each other, our sense of fairness in economic dealings, and our sense of the extent of corruption and bad faith. When animal spirits are on ebb, consumers do not want to spend and businesses do not want to make capital expenditures or hire people."[28] Behavioral economics has also explained many psychological biases that may trigger a recession including the availability heuristic, the money illusion, and normalcy bias.[29]

Balance sheet recession edit

Excessive levels of indebtedness or the bursting of a real estate or financial asset price bubble can cause what is called a "balance sheet recession". This occurs when large numbers of consumers or corporations pay down debt (i.e., save) rather than spend or invest, which slows the economy.[21] The term balance sheet derives from an accounting identity that holds that assets must always equal the sum of liabilities plus equity.[30] If asset prices fall below the value of the debt incurred to purchase them, then the equity must be negative, meaning the consumer or corporation is insolvent. Economist Paul Krugman wrote in 2014 that "the best working hypothesis seems to be that the financial crisis was only one manifestation of a broader problem of excessive debt—that it was a so-called "balance sheet recession". In Krugman's view, such crises require debt reduction strategies combined with higher government spending to offset declines from the private sector as it pays down its debt.[31]

For example, economist Richard Koo wrote that Japan's "Great Recession" that began in 1990 was a "balance sheet recession". It was triggered by a collapse in land and stock prices, which caused Japanese firms to have negative equity, meaning their assets were worth less than their liabilities. Despite zero interest rates and expansion of the money supply to encourage borrowing, Japanese corporations in aggregate opted to pay down their debts from their own business earnings rather than borrow to invest as firms typically do. Corporate investment, a key demand component of GDP, fell enormously (22% of GDP) between 1990 and its peak decline in 2003. Japanese firms overall became net savers after 1998, as opposed to borrowers. Koo argues that it was massive fiscal stimulus (borrowing and spending by the government) that offset this decline and enabled Japan to maintain its level of GDP. In his view, this avoided a U.S. type Great Depression, in which U.S. GDP fell by 46%. He argued that monetary policy was ineffective because there was limited demand for funds while firms paid down their liabilities. In a balance sheet recession, GDP declines by the amount of debt repayment and un-borrowed individual savings, leaving government stimulus spending as the primary remedy.[20][21][32]

Krugman discussed the balance sheet recession concept in 2010, agreeing with Koo's situation assessment and view that sustained deficit spending when faced with a balance sheet recession would be appropriate. However, Krugman argued that monetary policy could also affect savings behavior, as inflation or credible promises of future inflation (generating negative real interest rates) would encourage less savings. In other words, people would tend to spend more rather than save if they believe inflation is on the horizon. In more technical terms, Krugman argues that the private sector savings curve is elastic even during a balance sheet recession (responsive to changes in real interest rates), disagreeing with Koo's view that it is inelastic (non-responsive to changes in real interest rates).[33][34]

A July 2012 survey of balance sheet recession research reported that consumer demand and employment are affected by household leverage levels. Both durable and non-durable goods consumption declined as households moved from low to high leverage with the decline in property values experienced during the subprime mortgage crisis. Further, reduced consumption due to higher household leverage can account for a significant decline in employment levels. Policies that help reduce mortgage debt or household leverage could therefore have stimulative effects.[35][36]

Liquidity trap edit

A liquidity trap is a Keynesian theory that a situation can develop in which interest rates reach near zero (zero interest-rate policy) yet do not effectively stimulate the economy.[37] In theory, near-zero interest rates should encourage firms and consumers to borrow and spend. However, if too many individuals or corporations focus on saving or paying down debt rather than spending, lower interest rates have less effect on investment and consumption behavior; increasing the money supply is like "pushing on a string".[38] Economist Paul Krugman described the U.S. 2009 recession and Japan's lost decade as liquidity traps. One remedy to a liquidity trap is expanding the money supply via quantitative easing or other techniques in which money is effectively printed to purchase assets, thereby creating inflationary expectations that cause savers to begin spending again. Government stimulus spending and mercantilist policies to stimulate exports and reduce imports are other techniques to stimulate demand.[39] He estimated in March 2010 that developed countries representing 70% of the world's GDP were caught in a liquidity trap.[40]

Paradoxes of thrift and deleveraging edit

Behavior that may be optimal for an individual (e.g., saving more during adverse economic conditions) can be detrimental if too many individuals pursue the same behavior, as ultimately, one person's consumption is another person's income. Too many consumers attempting to save (or pay down debt) simultaneously is called the paradox of thrift[41] and can cause or deepen a recession. Economist Hyman Minsky also described a "paradox of deleveraging" as financial institutions that have too much leverage (debt relative to equity) cannot all de-leverage simultaneously without significant declines in the value of their assets.[42]

In April 2009, U.S. Federal Reserve Vice Chair Janet Yellen discussed these paradoxes: "Once this massive credit crunch hit, it didn't take long before we were in a recession. The recession, in turn, deepened the credit crunch as demand and employment fell, and credit losses of financial institutions surged. Indeed, we have been in the grips of precisely this adverse feedback loop for more than a year. A process of balance sheet deleveraging has spread to nearly every corner of the economy. Consumers are pulling back on purchases, especially durable goods, to build their savings. Businesses are cancelling planned investments and laying off workers to preserve cash. And financial institutions are shrinking assets to bolster capital and improve their chances of weathering the current storm. Once again, Minsky understood this dynamic. He spoke of the paradox of deleveraging, in which precautions that may be smart for individuals and firms—and indeed essential to return the economy to a normal state—nevertheless magnify the distress of the economy as a whole."[42]

Predictors edit

A handful of measures exist that are held to generally predict the possibility of a recession:

  • The U.S. Conference Board's Present Situation Index year-over-year change turns negative by more than 15 points before a recession.[43][44][45]
  • The U.S. Conference Board Leading Economic Indicator year-over-year change turns negative before a recession.[46][47]
  • When the CFNAI Diffusion Index drops below the value of −0.35, then there is an increased probability of the beginning a recession. Usually, the signal happens in the three months of the recession. The CFNAI Diffusion Index signal tends to happen about one month before a related signal by the CFNAI-MA3 (3-month moving average) drops below the −0.7 level. The CFNAI-MA3 correctly identified the 7 recessions between March 1967 – August 2019, while triggering only 2 false alarms.[48]

Except for the above, there are no known completely reliable predictors. Analysis by Prakash Loungani of the International Monetary Fund found that only two of the sixty recessions around the world during the 1990s had been predicted by a consensus of economists one year earlier, while there were zero consensus predictions one year earlier for the 49 recessions during 2009.[49]

However, the following are considered possible predictors:[50]

  • The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago posts updates of the Brave-Butters-Kelley Indexes (BBKI).[51]
  • The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis posts the Weekly Economic Index (Lewis-Mertens-Stock) (WEI).[52]
  • The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis posts the Smoothed U.S. Recession Probabilities (RECPROUSM156N).[53]
  • Inverted yield curve,[54][55] the model developed by economist Jonathan H. Wright, uses yields on 10-year and three-month Treasury securities as well as the Fed's overnight funds rate.[56] Another model developed by Federal Reserve Bank of New York economists uses only the 10-year/three-month spread.[57][58][59]
  • The three-month change in the unemployment rate and initial jobless claims.[60] U.S. unemployment index is defined as the difference between the 3-month average of the unemployment rate and the 12-month minimum of the unemployment rate.[61] Unemployment momentum and acceleration with Hidden Markov model.[62]
  • Index of Leading (Economic) Indicators (includes some of the above indicators).[63]
  • Lowering of asset prices, such as homes and financial assets, or high personal and corporate debt levels.
  • Commodity prices may increase before recessions, which usually hinders consumer spending by making necessities like transportation and housing costlier. This will tend to constrict spending for non-essential goods and services. Once the recession occurs, commodity prices will usually reset to a lower level.
  • Increased income inequality.[64][65]
  • Decreasing recreational vehicle shipments.[66]
  • Declining trucking volumes.[67][68]
  • The S&P 500 and BBB bond spread.[69]

Government responses edit

Keynesian economists favor the use of expansionary macroeconomic policy during recessions to increase aggregate demand.[70][71][72][73] Strategies favored for moving an economy out of a recession vary depending on which economic school the policymakers follow. Monetarists, exemplified by economist Milton Friedman, would favor the use of limited expansionary monetary policy, while Keynesian economists may advocate increased government spending to spark economic growth. Supply-side economists promote tax cuts to stimulate business capital investment. For example, the Trump administration claimed that lower effective tax rates on new investment imposed by the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 would raise investment, thereby making workers more productive and raising output and wages. Investment patterns in the United States through 2019, however, indicated that the supply-side incentives of the TCJA had little effect on investment growth. Although investments increased after 2017, much of the increase was a response to oil prices, and investment in other sectors had negligible growth.[74]

Monetarist economists have argued that objectives of monetary policy, i.e., controlling the money supply to influence interest rates, are best achieved by targeting the growth rate of the money supply. They maintain that money may affect output in the short term but that in the long run, expansionary monetary policy leads to inflation only. Keynesian economists have mostly adopted this analysis, modifying the theory with better integration of short and long run trends and an understanding that a change in the money supply "affects only nominal variables in the economy, such as prices and wages, and has no effect on real variables, like employment and output".[75][76] The Federal Reserve traditionally uses monetary accommodation, a policy instrument of lowering its main benchmark interest rate, to accommodate sudden supply-side shifts in the economy. When the federal funds rate reaches the boundary of an interest rate of 0%, called the zero lower bound, the government resorts to unconventional monetary policy to stimulate recovery.[77]

Gauti B. Eggertsson of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, using a New Keynesian macroeconomic model for policy analysis, writes that cutting taxes on labor or capital is contractionary under certain circumstances, such as those that prevailed following the economic crisis of 2008, and that temporarily increasing government spending at such times has much larger effects than under normal conditions. He says other forms of tax cuts, such as a reduction in sales taxes and investment tax credits, e.g., in the context of Japan's "Great Recession", are also very effective. Eggertsson infers from his analysis that the contractionary effects of labor and capital tax cuts, and the strong expansionary effect of government spending, are peculiar to the unusual environment created by zero interest rates. He asserts that with positive interest rates a labor tax cut is expansionary, per the established literature, but at zero interest rates, it reverses and tax cuts become contractionary. Further, while capital tax cuts are inconsequential in his model with a positive interest rate, they become strongly negative at zero, and the multiplier of government spending is then almost five times larger.[78]

Paul Krugman wrote in December 2010 that significant, sustained government spending was necessary because indebted households were paying down debts and unable to carry the U.S. economy as they had previously: "The root of our current troubles lies in the debt American families ran up during the Bush-era housing bubble...highly indebted Americans not only can't spend the way they used to, they're having to pay down the debts they ran up in the bubble years. This would be fine if someone else were taking up the slack. But what's actually happening is that some people are spending much less while nobody is spending more—and this translates into a depressed economy and high unemployment. What the government should be doing in this situation is spending more while the private sector is spending less, supporting employment while those debts are paid down. And this government spending needs to be sustained..."[79]

John Maynard Keynes believed that government institutions could stimulate aggregate demand in a crisis:

Keynes showed that if somehow the level of aggregate demand could be triggered, possibly by the government printing currency notes to employ people to dig holes and fill them up, the wages that would be paid out would resuscitate the economy by generating successive rounds of demand through the multiplier process.

— Anatomy of the Financial Crisis: Between Keynes and Schumpeter, Economic and Political Weekly[80]

Stock market edit

Some recessions have been anticipated by stock market declines. In Stocks for the Long Run, Siegel mentions that since 1948, ten recessions were preceded by a stock market decline, by a lead time of 0 to 13 months (average 5.7 months), while ten stock market declines of greater than 10% in the Dow Jones Industrial Average were not followed by a recession.[81]

The real estate market also usually weakens before a recession.[82] However, real estate declines can last much longer than recessions.[83]

Since the business cycle is very hard to predict, Siegel argues that it is not possible to take advantage of economic cycles for timing investments. Even the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) takes a few months to determine if a peak or trough has occurred in the US.[84]

U.S. politics edit

An administration generally gets credit or blame for the state of the economy during its time in office;[85] this state of affairs has caused disagreements about how particular recessions actually started.[86]

For example, the 1981 recession is thought to have been caused by the tight-money policy adopted by Paul Volcker, chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, before Ronald Reagan took office. Reagan supported that policy. Economist Walter Heller, chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers in the 1960s, said that "I call it a Reagan-Volcker-Carter recession."[87]

Consequences edit

Unemployment edit

Unemployment is particularly high during a recession. Many economists working within the neoclassical paradigm argue that there is a natural rate of unemployment which, when subtracted from the actual rate of unemployment, can be used to estimate the GDP gap during a recession. In other words, unemployment never reaches 0%, so it is not a negative indicator of the health of an economy, unless it exceeds the "natural rate", in which case the excess corresponds directly to a loss in the GDP.[88]

The full impact of a recession on employment may not be felt for several quarters. After recessions in Britain in the 1980s and 1990s, it took five years for unemployment to fall back to its original levels.[89] Employment discrimination claims rise during a recession.[90]

Business edit

Productivity tends to fall in the early stages of a recession, then rises again as weaker firms close. The variation in profitability between firms rises sharply.[citation needed] The fall in productivity could also be attributed to several macro-economic factors, such as the loss in productivity observed across the UK due to Brexit, which may create a mini-recession in the region. Global epidemics, such as COVID-19, could be another example, since they disrupt the global supply chain or prevent the movement of goods, services, and people.

Recessions have also provided opportunities for anti-competitive mergers, with a negative impact on the wider economy; the suspension of competition policy in the United States in the 1930s may have extended the Great Depression.[89]

Social effects edit

The living standards of people dependent on wages and salaries are less affected by recessions than those who rely on fixed incomes or welfare benefits. The loss of a job is known to have a negative impact on the stability of families, and individuals' health and well-being. Fixed income benefits receive small cuts[why?] which make it tougher to survive.[89]

History edit

Global edit

According to the International Monetary Fund (IMF), "Global recessions seem to occur over a cycle lasting between eight and 10 years."[91] The IMF takes many factors into account when defining a global recession. Until April 2009, IMF several times communicated to the press, that a global annual real GDP growth of 3.0% or less in their view was "equivalent to a global recession".[92][93]

By this measure, six periods since 1970 qualify: 1974–1975,[94] 1980–1983,[94] 1990–1993,[94][95] 1998,[94][95] 2001–2002,[94][95] and 2008–2009.[96] During what IMF in April 2002 termed the past three global recessions of the last three decades, global per capita output growth was zero or negative, and IMF argued—at that time—that because of the opposite being found for 2001, the economic state in this year by itself did not qualify as a global recession.[91]

In April 2009, IMF had changed their Global recession definition to "A decline in annual per‑capita real World GDP (purchasing power parity weighted), backed up by a decline or worsening for one or more of the seven other global macroeconomic indicators: Industrial production, trade, capital flows, oil consumption, unemployment rate, per‑capita investment, and per‑capita consumption."[97][98] By this new definition, a total of four global recessions took place since World War II: 1975, 1982, 1991 and 2009. All of them only lasted one year, although the third would have lasted three years (1991–1993) if IMF as criteria had used the normal exchange rate weighted per‑capita real World GDP rather than the purchase power parity weighted per‑capita real World GDP.[97][98]

Australia edit

As a result of late 1920s profit issues in agriculture and cutbacks, 1931–1932 saw Australia's biggest recession in its entire history. It fared better than other nations that underwent depressions, but their poor economic states influenced Australia, which depended on them for export, as well as foreign investments. The nation also benefited from greater productivity in manufacturing, facilitated by trade protection, which also helped with lessening the effects.

The economy had gone into a brief recession in 1961 because of a credit squeeze. Australia was facing a rising level of inflation in 1973, caused partially by the oil crisis happening in that same year, which brought inflation at a 13% increase. Economic recession hit by the middle of the year 1974, with no change in policy enacted by the government as a measure to counter the economic situation of the country. Consequently, the unemployment level rose and the trade deficit increased significantly.[99]

Another recession—the most recent one to date—came at the beginning of the 1990s as the result of a major stock collapse in October 1987,[100] referred to now as Black Monday. Although the collapse was larger than the one in 1929, the global economy recovered quickly, but North America still suffered a decline in lumbering savings and loans, which led to a crisis. The recession was not limited to the United States, but it also affected partnering nations such as Australia. The unemployment level increased to 10.8%, employment declined by 3.4% and the GDP also decreased as much as 1.7%. Inflation, however, was successfully reduced.

Australia faced recession in 2020 due to the impact of huge bush fires and the COVID-19 pandemic's effect on tourism and other important aspects of the economy.[101][needs update]

European Union edit

The Eurozone experienced a recession in 2012: the economies of the 17-nation region failed to grow during any quarter of the 2012 calendar year. The recession deepened during the final quarter of the year, with the French, German and Italian economies all affected.[102]

United Kingdom edit

The most recent recession to affect the United Kingdom was the 2020 recession[103] attributed to the COVID-19 global pandemic, the first recession since the Great Recession.

United States edit

 
Recessions in the United States – 1930 through 2021
 
Inverted yield curves correlation to recessions
  10 Year Treasury Bond
  2 Year Treasury Bond
  3 month Treasury Bond
  Effective Federal Funds Rate
  CPI inflation year/year
  Recessions

According to economists, since 1854, the U.S. has encountered 32 cycles of expansions and contractions, with an average of 17 months of contraction and 38 months of expansion.[12] From 1980 to 2018 there were only eight periods of negative economic growth over one fiscal quarter or more,[104] and four periods considered recessions:

For the last three of these recessions, the NBER decision has approximately conformed with the definition involving two consecutive quarters of decline. While the 2001 recession did not involve two consecutive quarters of decline, it was preceded by two quarters of alternating decline and weak growth.[104]

Since then, the NBER has also declared a 2-month COVID-19 recession for February 2020 – April 2020.[107]

In July 2022, the NBER released a statement regarding declaring a recession following a second consecutive quarter of shrinking GDP, "There is no fixed rule about what measures contribute information to the process or how they are weighted in our decisions".[108]

NBER has sometimes declared a recession before a second quarter of GDP shrinkage has been reported, but beginnings and endings can also be declared over a year after they are reckoned to have occurred. In 1947, NBER did not declare a recession despite two quarters of declining GDP, due to strong economic activity reported for employment, industrial production, and consumer spending.[109]

Late 2000s edit

Official economic data shows that a substantial number of nations were in recession as of early 2009. The US entered a recession at the end of 2007,[110] and 2008 saw many other nations follow suit. The US recession of 2007 ended in June 2009[111] as the nation entered the current economic recovery. The timeline of the Great Recession details the many elements of this period.

United States edit

The United States housing market correction (a consequence of the United States housing bubble) and subprime mortgage crisis significantly contributed to a recession.

The 2007–2009 recession saw private consumption fall for the first time in nearly 20 years. This indicated the depth and severity of the recession. With consumer confidence so low, economic recovery took a long time. Consumers in the U.S. were hit hard by the Great Recession, with the value of their houses dropping and their pension savings decimated on the stock market.[112]

U.S. employers shed 63,000 jobs in February 2008,[113] the most in five years. Former Federal Reserve chairman Alan Greenspan said on 6 April 2008 that "There is more than a 50 percent chance the United States could go into recession."[114] On 1 October, the Bureau of Economic Analysis reported that an additional 156,000 jobs had been lost in September. On 29 April 2008, Moody's declared that nine US states were in a recession. In November 2008, employers eliminated 533,000 jobs, the largest single-month loss in 34 years.[115] In 2008, an estimated 2.6 million U.S. jobs were eliminated.[116]

The unemployment rate in the U.S. grew to 8.5% in March 2009,[117] and there were 5.1 million job losses by March 2009 since the recession began in December 2007.[118] That was about five million more people unemployed compared to just a year prior,[119] which was the largest annual jump in the number of unemployed persons since the 1940s.[120]

Although the US economy grew in the first quarter by 1%,[121][122] by June 2008 some analysts stated that due to a protracted credit crisis and "rampant inflation in commodities such as oil, food, and steel", the country was nonetheless in a recession.[123] The third quarter of 2008 brought on a GDP retraction of 0.5%,[124] the biggest decline since 2001. The 6.4% decline in spending during Q3 on non-durable goods, like clothing and food, was the largest since 1950.[125]

A November 2008 report from the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia based on the survey of 51 forecasters, suggested that the recession started in April 2008 and would last 14 months.[126] They projected real GDP declining at an annual rate of 2.9% in the fourth quarter and 1.1% in the first quarter of 2009. These forecasts represented significant downward revisions from the forecasts of three months prior.

A December 2008 report from the National Bureau of Economic Research stated that the U.S. had been in a recession since December 2007, when economic activity peaked, based on several measures including job losses, declines in personal income, and declines in real GDP.[127] By July 2009, a growing number of economists believed that the recession may have ended.[128][129] The National Bureau of Economic Research announced on 20 September 2010 that the 2008/2009 recession ended in June 2009, making it the longest recession since World War II.[130] Prior to the start of the recession, it appears that no known formal theoretical or empirical model was able to accurately predict the advance of this recession, except for minor signals in the sudden rise of forecasted probabilities, which were still well under 50%.[58]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ "recession". Merriam-Webster.com Dictionary.
  2. ^ "Recession definition". . Microsoft Corporation. 2007. Archived from the original on 28 March 2009. Retrieved 19 November 2008.
  3. ^ "Business Cycle Dating Committee Announcement January 7, 2008". www.nber.org. 7 January 2008.
  4. ^ a b "FAQ | EABCN". eabcn.org. from the original on 29 April 2022. Retrieved 29 December 2021.
  5. ^ a b "The CEPR and NBER Approaches". eabcn.org. Retrieved 30 July 2022.
  6. ^ a b "Q&A: What is a recession?". BBC News. 8 July 2008.
  7. ^ a b . HM Treasury. Archived from the original on 2 November 2012. Retrieved 25 October 2012.
  8. ^ Shiskin, Julius (1 December 1974). "Points of View". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. from the original on 25 March 2020. Retrieved 27 July 2022.
  9. ^ Dale, Edwin L. Jr (6 April 1974). "U.S. to Broaden the Base Of Consumer Price Index". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. from the original on 27 July 2022. Retrieved 27 July 2022.
  10. ^ Silk, Leonard (28 August 1974). "Recession: Some Criteria Missing, So Far". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. from the original on 27 July 2022. Retrieved 27 July 2022.
  11. ^ Lakshman, Achuthan; Banerji, Anirvan (7 May 2008). "The risk of redefining recession". CNN Money. Retrieved 8 August 2022.
  12. ^ a b "Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions". National Bureau of Economic Research. from the original on 5 March 2020. Retrieved 20 March 2020.
  13. ^ Anstey, Chris (28 July 2022). "'Technical Recession' Sets Up Washington War of the Words". Bloomberg News. Retrieved 28 July 2022.
  14. ^ Cox, Jeff (28 July 2022). "The economy may look like it's in recession, but we still don't know for sure". CNBC. from the original on 28 July 2022. Retrieved 28 July 2022.
  15. ^ Jacobsen, Louis (26 July 2022). "What exactly is a recession? Sorting out a confusing topic". PolitiFact. from the original on 27 July 2022. Retrieved 28 July 2022.
  16. ^ Loe, Megan; Lewis, Brandon (28 July 2022). "Yes, there is an official definition of a recession". KUSA.com. Retrieved 31 July 2022.
  17. ^ "Recession | U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA)". www.bea.gov. Bureau of Economic Analysis. 2022. Retrieved 31 July 2022.
  18. ^ "OECD Economic Outlook, Volume 2008 Issue 2". oecd-ilibrary.org. 2008.
  19. ^ Jiří, Mazurek. "On some issues concerning definition of an economic recession." (2012).
  20. ^ a b Koo, Richard (2009). The Holy Grail of Macroeconomics-Lessons from Japan's Great Recession. John Wiley & Sons (Asia) Pte. Ltd. ISBN 978-0-470-82494-8.
  21. ^ a b c Koo, Richard C. (12 December 2011). (PDF). Real-World Economics Review (58): 19. Archived from the original (PDF) on 10 January 2020. Retrieved 3 August 2022.
  22. ^ Saul Eslake (November 2008). . Archived from the original on 23 July 2021.
  23. ^ Kaur, Rajwant; Sidhu, A.S. (Spring 2012). Sarkar, Siddhartha (ed.). "Global Recession and Its Impact on Foreign Trade in India". International Journal of Afro-Asian Studies. Universal-Publishers. 3 (1): 62. ISBN 9781612336084.
  24. ^ . ADB.org. Archived from the original on 17 March 2010. Retrieved 31 July 2010.
  25. ^ Samuelson, Robert J. (14 June 2010). "Our economy's crisis of confidence". The Washington Post. from the original on 26 March 2020. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  26. ^ "The Conference Board – Consumer Confidence Survey Press Release – May 2010". Conference-board.org. 25 March 2010. from the original on 3 March 2020. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  27. ^ Akerlof, George A.; Shiller, Robert J. (2010). Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton University Press. p. 23. ISBN 978-1-4008-3472-3.
  28. ^ Shiller, Robert J. (27 January 2009). "Animal Spirits Depend on Trust". The Wall Street Journal. from the original on 11 February 2020. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  29. ^ How to be an Adult (13 May 2020). "Psychological Biases and Errors that led to historic bubbles and crashes". Medium. from the original on 28 July 2020. Retrieved 13 May 2020.
  30. ^ Jupe, Robert (2014). "Accounting, balance sheet". In Michie, Jonathan (ed.). Reader's Guide to the Social Sciences. Routledge. p. 11. ISBN 978-1-135-93226-8.
  31. ^ Krugman, Paul (10 July 2014). "Does He Pass the Test? 'Stress Test: Reflections on Financial Crises' by Timothy Geithner". New York Review of Books. from the original on 5 November 2015. Retrieved 26 November 2018.
  32. ^ White, Gregory (14 April 2010). "Presentation by Richard Koo – The Age of Balance Sheet Recessions". Business Insider. from the original on 5 May 2021. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  33. ^ Krugman, Paul (17 August 2010). "Notes On Koo (Wonkish)". The New York Times. from the original on 15 April 2021. Retrieved 26 November 2018.
  34. ^ Krugman, Paul (18 November 2010). "Debt, deleveraging, and the liquidity trap". Voxeu.org). from the original on 21 April 2021. Retrieved 26 November 2018.
  35. ^ Krugman, Paul (6 July 2012). "Grim Natural Experiments". from the original on 22 April 2021. Retrieved 26 November 2018.
  36. ^ Konczal, Mike (3 July 2012). . Next New Deal. Roosevelt Institute. Archived from the original on 16 October 2015.
  37. ^ Eggertsson, Gauti B. (2018). "Liquidity Trap". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan UK. pp. 7929–7936. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2482. ISBN 978-1-349-95189-5.
  38. ^ Correia, Isabel; Farhi, Emmanuel; Nicolini, Juan Pablo; Teles, Pedro (August 2012). "Unconventional Fiscal Policy at the Zero Bound: Working Paper 698" (PDF). Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. p. 1. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  39. ^ Krugman, Paul (2009). The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008. W.W. Norton Company Limited. ISBN 978-0-393-07101-6.
  40. ^ "How Much of the World is in a Liquidity Trap?". Krugman.blogs.nytimes.com. 17 March 2010. from the original on 24 April 2020. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  41. ^ Lipsey, Richard G.; Harbury, Colin (1992). First Principles of Economics. Oxford University Press. p. 294. ISBN 978-0-297-82120-5.
  42. ^ a b "A Minsky Meltdown: Lessons for Central Bankers". Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco speeches. 16 April 2009. from the original on 5 January 2013. Retrieved 4 June 2019.
  43. ^ Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Consumer Confidence: A Useful Indicator of … the Labor Market? 14 May 2020 at the Wayback Machine Jason Bram, Robert Rich, and Joshua Abel ... Conference Board's Present Situation Index   This article incorporates text from this source, which is in the public domain.
  44. ^ . Archived from the original on 28 April 2020. Retrieved 14 February 2020.
  45. ^ Consumer Confidence Drops – Why Does It Matter? 18 March 2020 at the Wayback Machine Forbes. 27 June 2019. Brad McMillan.
  46. ^ "Gundlach: We don't see a recession on the horizon. But there's bad news..." Yahoo! Finance. 14 February 2019. from the original on 25 September 2019. Retrieved 25 September 2019.
  47. ^ "Seeking Alpha | Take Me To Your Leader: Analyzing The Latest Leading Indicators | by −1.9% | 24 September 2019".
  48. ^ "Background on the Chicago Fed National Activity Index | Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago | 19 September 2019" (PDF). (PDF) from the original on 14 May 2020. Retrieved 25 September 2019.
  49. ^ "Grim Stock Signals Piling Up as Wall Street Mulls Recession Odds". Bloomberg L.P. 25 November 2018. from the original on 4 March 2020. Retrieved 26 November 2018.
  50. ^ A Estrella, FS Mishkin (1995). "Predicting U.S. Recessions: Financial Variables as Leading Indicators" (PDF). Review of Economics and Statistics. MIT Press. 80: 45–61. doi:10.1162/003465398557320. S2CID 11641969. (PDF) from the original on 6 April 2020. Retrieved 25 August 2019.
  51. ^ "A 'Big Data' View of the U.S. Economy: Introducing the Brave-Butters-Kelley Indexes – Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago". chicagofed.org. from the original on 28 May 2020. Retrieved 6 May 2020.
  52. ^ "Weekly Economic Index (Lewis-Mertens-Stock)". FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. 5 January 2008. from the original on 19 July 2021. Retrieved 19 July 2021.
  53. ^ "Smoothed U.S. Recession Probabilities". FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. 1 February 1967. from the original on 2 May 2020. Retrieved 6 May 2020.
  54. ^ Ulatan, Jeffrey (3 July 2020). "2020 Recession Signals, After US-Iran Airstrike. Vanguard ETF Best Performing Funds for 2020". Harvard Dataverse. doi:10.7910/DVN/AWWQPN.
  55. ^ Grading Bonds on Inverted Curve 7 May 2019 at the Wayback Machine By Michael Hudson
  56. ^ Wright, Jonathan H., The Yield Curve and Predicting Recessions 28 July 2020 at the Wayback Machine (March 2006). FEDs Working Paper No. 2006-7.
  57. ^ "The Yield Curve as a Leading Indicator". newyorkfed.org. Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 2020. from the original on 14 May 2017. Retrieved 20 March 2020.
  58. ^ a b Park, Byeong U.; Simar, Léopold; Zelenyuk, Valentin (15 May 2019). "Forecasting of recessions via dynamic probit for time series: replication and extension of Kauppi and Saikkonen (2008)". Empirical Economics. Springer Science and Business Media LLC. 58 (1): 379–392. doi:10.1007/s00181-019-01708-2. ISSN 0377-7332. S2CID 253717746.
  59. ^ [1] 19 March 2020 at the Wayback Machine Using the U.S. Treasury Yield Curve to predict S&P 500 returns and U.S. recessions | Theodore Gregory Hanks | Pennsylvania State University, Schreyer Honors College Department of Finance | Spring 2012
  60. ^ "Labor Model Predicts Lower Recession Odds". The Wall Street Journal. 28 January 2008. from the original on 19 August 2020. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  61. ^ Sahm, Claudia (6 May 2019). "Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals" (PDF). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. (PDF) from the original on 31 March 2020. Retrieved 25 August 2019.
  62. ^ Lihn, Stephen H. T. (10 August 2019). "Real-time Recession Probability with Hidden Markov Model and Unemployment Momentum". SSRN 3435667.
  63. ^ Leading Economic Indicators Suggest U.S. In Recession 6 July 2009 at the Wayback Machine 21 January 2008
  64. ^ "Income and wealth inequality make recessions worse, research reveals". phys.org. 2016. from the original on 13 December 2019. Retrieved 25 August 2019.
  65. ^ Neves, Pedro Cunha; Afonso, Óscar; Silva, Sandra Tavares (February 2016). "A Meta-Analytic Reassessment of the Effects of Inequality on Growth". World Development. 78: 386–400. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2015.10.038.
  66. ^ Raice, Shayndi (19 August 2019). "An Economic Warning Sign: RV Shipments Are Slipping". The Wall Street Journal. from the original on 8 June 2020. Retrieved 18 September 2019.
  67. ^ Premack, Rachel. "The "bloodbath" in America's trucking industry has officially spilled over to the rest of the economy". Business Insider. from the original on 8 February 2020. Retrieved 18 September 2019.
  68. ^ "Cass Freight Index Report" (PDF). August 2019. (PDF) from the original on 13 December 2019. Retrieved 18 September 2019.
  69. ^ [2] 6 December 2020 at the Wayback Machine JPMorgan | The US Economic Outlook | Feb. 2020 | Page 22]
  70. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph E.; Ocampo, José Antonio, eds. (2008). Capital Market Liberalization and Development. OUP Oxford. p. 360. ISBN 978-0-19-923058-7.
  71. ^ Ahuja, H.L. (2019). "Monetarism and Friedman's Restatement of Quantity Theory of Money". Macroeconomics, 20e. S. Chand Publishing. p. 527. ISBN 978-93-5283-732-8.
  72. ^ Thornton, Saranna (2018). Bucking The Deficit: Economic Policymaking In America. Routledge. p. 30. ISBN 978-0-429-97052-8.
  73. ^ Mason, J.W (2020). "Chapter 1: Macroeconomic lessons from the past decade". In MacLean, Brian K.; Bougrine, Hassan; Rochon, Louis-Philippe (eds.). Aggregate Demand and Employment: International Perspectives. Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 29. ISBN 978-1-78643-205-6.
  74. ^ Gale, William G.; Haldeman, Claire (6 July 2021). "Searching for supply-side effects of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act" (PDF). Brookings. pp. 3–4. Retrieved 5 August 2022.
  75. ^ Jahan, Sarwat; Mahmud, Ahmed Saber; Papageorgiou, Chris (September 2014). "What Is Keynesian Economics? – Back to Basics" (PDF). Finance & Development. 51 (1): 54.
  76. ^ Jahan, Sarwat; Papageorgiou, Chris (March 2014). "What Is Monetarism? – Back to Basics" (PDF). Finance and Development. 51 (1): 38.
  77. ^ Skaperdas, Arsenios (7 July 2017). "How Effective is Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound? Identification Through Industry Heterogeneity" (PDF). pp. 2–3.
  78. ^ Eggertsson, Gauti B. (1 January 2011). "What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates?". NBER Macroeconomics Annual. 25: 59–60. doi:10.1086/657529. hdl:10419/60825. ISSN 0889-3365. S2CID 16071568.
  79. ^ Krugman, Paul (13 December 2010). "Opinion – Block Those Economic Metaphors". The New York Times. from the original on 20 August 2019. Retrieved 26 November 2018.
  80. ^ Nayak, Pulin B. (2009). "Anatomy of the Financial Crisis: Between Keynes and Schumpeter". Economic and Political Weekly. 44 (13): 160. ISSN 0012-9976. JSTOR 40278675.
  81. ^ Siegel, Jeremy J. (2002). Stocks for the Long Run: The Definitive Guide to Financial Market Returns and Long-Term Investment Strategies, 3rd, New York: McGraw-Hill, 388. ISBN 978-0-07-137048-6
  82. ^ "From the subprime to the terrigenous: Recession begins at home". Land Values Research Group. 2 June 2009. from the original on 12 June 2009. Retrieved 16 June 2009. A downturn in the property market, especially in turnover (sales) of properties, is a leading indicator of recession, with a lead time of up to 9 quarters...
  83. ^ Shiller, Robert J. (6 June 2009). "Why Home Prices May Keep Falling". The New York Times. from the original on 3 July 2020. Retrieved 10 April 2010.
  84. ^ Sloan, Allan (11 December 2007). "Recession Predictions and Investment Decisions". The Washington Post. from the original on 28 July 2020. Retrieved 10 September 2017.
  85. ^ "Economy puts Republicans at risk". BBC. 29 January 2008. from the original on 2 February 2008. Retrieved 8 March 2008.
  86. ^ The Bush Recession 4 February 2011 at the Wayback Machine Prepared by: Democratic staff, Senate Budget Committee, 31 July 2003
  87. ^ Church, George J. (23 November 1981). . Time. Archived from the original on 23 April 2008.
  88. ^ Unemployment Rate 12 September 2012 at the Wayback Machine p. 1. The Saylor Foundation. Retrieved 20 June 2012.
  89. ^ a b c Vaitilingam, Romesh (17 September 2009). . Economic and Social Research Council. Archived from the original on 2 January 2010. Retrieved 22 January 2010.
  90. ^ Rampell, Catherine (11 January 2011). "More Workers Complain of Bias on the Job, a Trend Linked to Widespread Layoffs". The New York Times. from the original on 23 July 2016. Retrieved 7 February 2017.
  91. ^ a b The Recession that Almost Was. 12 December 2008 at the Wayback Machine Kenneth Rogoff, International Monetary Fund, Financial Times, 5 April 2002
  92. ^ "The world economy Bad, or worse". The Economist. 9 October 2008. from the original on 21 February 2009. Retrieved 15 April 2009.
  93. ^ Lall, Subir. International Monetary Fund, 9 April 2008. "IMF Predicts Slower World Growth Amid Serious Market Crisis" 28 February 2009 at the Wayback Machine
  94. ^ a b c d e Global Economic Slump Challenges Policies 9 January 2020 at the Wayback Machine IMF. January 2009.
  95. ^ a b c . Bloomberg L.P. 28 January 2008. Archived from the original on 21 March 2010. Retrieved 15 April 2009.
  96. ^ "World Economic Outlook (WEO) April 2013: Statistical appendix – Table A1 – Summary of World Output" (PDF). IMF. 16 April 2013. (PDF) from the original on 25 May 2013. Retrieved 16 April 2013.
  97. ^ a b Davis, Bob (22 April 2009). "What's a Global Recession?". The Wall Street Journal. from the original on 28 February 2019. Retrieved 17 September 2013.
  98. ^ a b "World Economic Outlook – April 2009: Crisis and Recovery" (PDF). Box 1.1 (pp. 11–14). IMF. 24 April 2009. (PDF) from the original on 31 December 2010. Retrieved 17 September 2013.
  99. ^ Australian Economic Indicators, Australian Bureau of Statistics, 27 February 1998, from the original on 16 October 2015, retrieved 11 August 2015
  100. ^ , The Age, Melbourne, 2 December 2006, archived from the original on 12 April 2014, retrieved 11 August 2015
  101. ^ Janda, Michael (3 June 2020), Australian Recession, Australian Broadcasting Corporation, from the original on 3 June 2020, retrieved 3 June 2020
  102. ^ "Eurozone recession deepened at end of 2012". BBC News. 14 February 2013.
  103. ^ "UK officially in recession for first time in 11 years". The BBC. 12 August 2020. from the original on 12 August 2020. Retrieved 23 May 2022.
  104. ^ a b . U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). Archived from the original on 14 August 2018. Retrieved 26 November 2018.
  105. ^ Isidore, Chris (1 December 2008). "It's official: Recession since Dec. '07". CNN. from the original on 14 August 2021. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  106. ^ "US economy out of recession". BBC News – Business. 29 October 2009. from the original on 28 July 2020. Retrieved 6 February 2010.
  107. ^ "Business Cycle Dating Committee Announcement July 19, 2021". NBER. 19 July 2021. from the original on 26 April 2022. Retrieved 19 July 2021.
  108. ^ "Business Cycle Dating Procedure: Frequently Asked Questions". NBER. from the original on 29 July 2022. Retrieved 29 July 2022.
  109. ^ Blake, Aaron (28 July 2022). "What two negative GDP quarters means for 'recession' – and our politics". The Washington Post.
  110. ^ "Determination of the December 2007 Peak in Economic Activity" (PDF). NBER Business Cycle Dating Committee. 11 December 2008. (PDF) from the original on 19 April 2009. Retrieved 26 April 2009.
  111. ^ Izzo, Phil (20 September 2010). "Recession Over in June 2009". The Wall Street Journal. from the original on 7 December 2017. Retrieved 4 August 2017.
  112. ^ Economic Crisis: When will it End? IBISWorld Recession Briefing " 14 May 2011 at the Wayback Machine Dr. Richard J. Buczynski and Michael Bright, IBISWorld, January 2009
  113. ^ Andrews, Edmund L. (7 March 2008). "Employment Falls for Second Month". The New York Times. from the original on 11 August 2019. Retrieved 10 March 2020.
  114. ^ Recession unlikely if US economy gets through next two crucial months 12 August 2011 at the Wayback Machine
  115. ^ Uchitelle, Louis; Andrews, Edmund L.; Labaton, Stephen (6 December 2008). "U.S. Loses 533,000 Jobs in Biggest Drop Since 1974". The New York Times. from the original on 9 April 2009. Retrieved 10 April 2010.
  116. ^ Uchitelle, Louis (9 January 2009). "U.S. lost 2.6 million jobs in 2008". The New York Times. from the original on 1 March 2020. Retrieved 10 March 2020.
  117. ^ Unemployment rate in March 2009 6 August 2020 at the Wayback Machine 6 April 2009. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Retrieved 10 March 2020.
  118. ^ 2 million jobs lost so far in '09 11 January 2020 at the Wayback Machine CNN/Money. 3 April 2009. Retrieved 10 March 2020.
  119. ^ "Employment Situation Summary". Bls.gov. 2 July 2010. from the original on 6 October 2009. Retrieved 31 July 2010.
  120. ^ Goldman, David (9 January 2009). "Worst year for jobs since '45". CNN. from the original on 6 October 2013. Retrieved 10 April 2010.
  121. ^ Meyer, Brent (16 October 2008). . Clevelandfed.org. Archived from the original on 5 October 2008. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  122. ^ . Yahoo! Finance. Archived from the original on 7 July 2008.
  123. ^ Why it's worse than you think 1 October 2009 at the Wayback Machine, 16 June 2008, Newsweek.
  124. ^ "Gross Domestic Product: Third quarter 2008". Bea.gov. from the original on 14 August 2018. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  125. ^ Chandra, Shobhana (30 October 2008). "U.S. Economy Contracts Most Since the 2001 Recession". Bloomberg. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  126. ^ . Philadelphiafed.org. 17 November 2008. Archived from the original on 3 July 2009. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  127. ^ "Text of the NBER's statement on the recession". USA Today. 1 December 2008. from the original on 14 November 2010. Retrieved 29 January 2011.
  128. ^ Gross, Daniel (13 July 2009). "Daniel Gross: The Recession is Over?". Newsweek.
  129. ^ Keilis-Borok, V. I.; Soloviev, A. A.; Intriligator, M. D.; Winberg, F. E. (2008). "Pattern of Macroeconomic Indicators Preceding the End of an American Economic Recession". Journal of Pattern Recognition Research. 3 (1): 40–53. doi:10.13176/11.106. ISSN 1558-884X.
  130. ^ "Business Cycle Dating Committee, National Bureau of Economic Research". nber.org. 20 September 2010. from the original on 2 March 2021. Retrieved 26 November 2018.

External links edit

recession, this, article, about, slowdown, economic, activity, other, uses, disambiguation, economics, recession, business, cycle, contraction, that, occurs, when, there, general, decline, economic, activity, generally, occur, when, there, widespread, drop, sp. This article is about a slowdown in economic activity For other uses see Recession disambiguation In economics a recession is a business cycle contraction that occurs when there is a general decline in economic activity 1 2 Recessions generally occur when there is a widespread drop in spending an adverse demand shock This may be triggered by various events such as a financial crisis an external trade shock an adverse supply shock the bursting of an economic bubble or a large scale anthropogenic or natural disaster e g a pandemic In the United States a recession is defined as a significant decline in economic activity spread across the market lasting more than a few months normally visible in real GDP real income employment industrial production and wholesale retail sales 3 The European Union has adopted a similar definition 4 5 In the United Kingdom a recession is defined as negative economic growth for two consecutive quarters 6 7 Governments usually respond to recessions by adopting expansionary macroeconomic policies such as increasing money supply and decreasing interest rates or increasing government spending and decreasing taxation Contents 1 Definitions 2 Attributes 2 1 Type of recession or shape 2 2 Psychological aspects 2 3 Balance sheet recession 2 4 Liquidity trap 2 5 Paradoxes of thrift and deleveraging 3 Predictors 4 Government responses 5 Stock market 6 U S politics 7 Consequences 7 1 Unemployment 7 2 Business 7 3 Social effects 8 History 8 1 Global 8 2 Australia 8 3 European Union 8 4 United Kingdom 8 5 United States 8 6 Late 2000s 8 6 1 United States 9 See also 10 References 11 External linksDefinitions editIn a 1974 article by The New York Times Commissioner of the Bureau of Labor Statistics Julius Shiskin suggested that a rough translation of the bureau s qualitative definition of a recession into a quantitative one that almost anyone can use might run like this In terms of duration Declines in real gross national product GNP for two consecutive quarters a decline in industrial production over a six month period In terms of depth A 1 5 decline in real GNP a 15 decline in non agricultural employment a two point rise in unemployment to a level of at least 6 In terms of diffusion A decline in non agricultural employment in more than 75 of industries as measured over six month spans for six months or longer 8 9 10 Over the years some commentators dropped most of Shiskin s recession spotting criteria for the simplistic rule of thumb of a decline in real GNP for two consecutive quarters 11 In the United States the Business Cycle Dating Committee of the National Bureau of Economic Research NBER is generally seen as the authority for dating US recessions The NBER a private economic research organization defines an economic recession as a significant decline in economic activity spread across the economy lasting more than a few months normally visible in real GDP real income employment industrial production and wholesale retail sales 12 The NBER is considered the official arbiter of recession start and end dates for the United States 13 14 15 The Bureau of Economic Analysis an independent federal agency that provides official macroeconomic and industry statistics 16 says the often cited identification of a recession with two consecutive quarters of negative GDP growth is not an official designation and that instead The designation of a recession is the province of a committee of experts at the National Bureau of Economic Research 17 The European Union adopted a definition similar to that of the NBER using GDP alongside additional macroeconomic variables such as employment and other measures to assess the depth of decline in economic activity 4 5 Recessions in the United Kingdom are generally defined as two consecutive quarters of negative economic growth as measured by the seasonal adjusted quarter on quarter figures for real GDP 6 7 The Organisation for Economic Co operation and Development OECD defines a recession as a period of at least two years during which the cumulative output gap reaches at least 2 of GDP and the output gap is at least 1 for at least one year 18 Recession can be defined as decline of GDP per capita instead of decline of total GDP 19 Attributes editA recession has many attributes that can occur simultaneously and includes declines in component measures of economic activity GDP such as consumption investment government spending and net export activity These summary measures reflect underlying drivers such as employment levels and skills household savings rates corporate investment decisions interest rates demographics and government policies Economist Richard C Koo wrote that under ideal conditions a country s economy should have the household sector as net savers and the corporate sector as net borrowers with the government budget nearly balanced and net exports near zero 20 21 A severe GDP down by 10 or prolonged three or four years recession is referred to as an economic depression although some argue that their causes and cures can be different 22 As an informal shorthand economists sometimes refer to different recession shapes such as V shaped U shaped L shaped and W shaped recessions 23 Type of recession or shape edit Main article Recession shapes The type and shape of recessions are distinctive In the US v shaped or short and sharp contractions followed by rapid and sustained recovery occurred in 1954 and 1990 1991 U shaped prolonged slump in 1974 1975 and W shaped or double dip recessions in 1949 and 1980 1982 Japan s 1993 1994 recession was U shaped and its 8 out of 9 quarters of contraction in 1997 1999 can be described as L shaped Korea Hong Kong and South east Asia experienced U shaped recessions in 1997 1998 although Thailand s eight consecutive quarters of decline should be termed L shaped 24 Psychological aspects edit Recessions have psychological and confidence aspects For example if companies expect economic activity to slow they may reduce employment levels and save money rather than invest Such expectations can create a self reinforcing downward cycle bringing about or worsening a recession 25 Consumer confidence is one measure used to evaluate economic sentiment 26 The term animal spirits has been used to describe the psychological factors underlying economic activity Keynes in his The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money was the first economist to claim that such emotional mindsets significantly affect the economy 27 Economist Robert J Shiller wrote that the term refers also to the sense of trust we have in each other our sense of fairness in economic dealings and our sense of the extent of corruption and bad faith When animal spirits are on ebb consumers do not want to spend and businesses do not want to make capital expenditures or hire people 28 Behavioral economics has also explained many psychological biases that may trigger a recession including the availability heuristic the money illusion and normalcy bias 29 Balance sheet recession edit Main article Balance sheet recession Excessive levels of indebtedness or the bursting of a real estate or financial asset price bubble can cause what is called a balance sheet recession This occurs when large numbers of consumers or corporations pay down debt i e save rather than spend or invest which slows the economy 21 The term balance sheet derives from an accounting identity that holds that assets must always equal the sum of liabilities plus equity 30 If asset prices fall below the value of the debt incurred to purchase them then the equity must be negative meaning the consumer or corporation is insolvent Economist Paul Krugman wrote in 2014 that the best working hypothesis seems to be that the financial crisis was only one manifestation of a broader problem of excessive debt that it was a so called balance sheet recession In Krugman s view such crises require debt reduction strategies combined with higher government spending to offset declines from the private sector as it pays down its debt 31 For example economist Richard Koo wrote that Japan s Great Recession that began in 1990 was a balance sheet recession It was triggered by a collapse in land and stock prices which caused Japanese firms to have negative equity meaning their assets were worth less than their liabilities Despite zero interest rates and expansion of the money supply to encourage borrowing Japanese corporations in aggregate opted to pay down their debts from their own business earnings rather than borrow to invest as firms typically do Corporate investment a key demand component of GDP fell enormously 22 of GDP between 1990 and its peak decline in 2003 Japanese firms overall became net savers after 1998 as opposed to borrowers Koo argues that it was massive fiscal stimulus borrowing and spending by the government that offset this decline and enabled Japan to maintain its level of GDP In his view this avoided a U S type Great Depression in which U S GDP fell by 46 He argued that monetary policy was ineffective because there was limited demand for funds while firms paid down their liabilities In a balance sheet recession GDP declines by the amount of debt repayment and un borrowed individual savings leaving government stimulus spending as the primary remedy 20 21 32 Krugman discussed the balance sheet recession concept in 2010 agreeing with Koo s situation assessment and view that sustained deficit spending when faced with a balance sheet recession would be appropriate However Krugman argued that monetary policy could also affect savings behavior as inflation or credible promises of future inflation generating negative real interest rates would encourage less savings In other words people would tend to spend more rather than save if they believe inflation is on the horizon In more technical terms Krugman argues that the private sector savings curve is elastic even during a balance sheet recession responsive to changes in real interest rates disagreeing with Koo s view that it is inelastic non responsive to changes in real interest rates 33 34 A July 2012 survey of balance sheet recession research reported that consumer demand and employment are affected by household leverage levels Both durable and non durable goods consumption declined as households moved from low to high leverage with the decline in property values experienced during the subprime mortgage crisis Further reduced consumption due to higher household leverage can account for a significant decline in employment levels Policies that help reduce mortgage debt or household leverage could therefore have stimulative effects 35 36 Liquidity trap edit A liquidity trap is a Keynesian theory that a situation can develop in which interest rates reach near zero zero interest rate policy yet do not effectively stimulate the economy 37 In theory near zero interest rates should encourage firms and consumers to borrow and spend However if too many individuals or corporations focus on saving or paying down debt rather than spending lower interest rates have less effect on investment and consumption behavior increasing the money supply is like pushing on a string 38 Economist Paul Krugman described the U S 2009 recession and Japan s lost decade as liquidity traps One remedy to a liquidity trap is expanding the money supply via quantitative easing or other techniques in which money is effectively printed to purchase assets thereby creating inflationary expectations that cause savers to begin spending again Government stimulus spending and mercantilist policies to stimulate exports and reduce imports are other techniques to stimulate demand 39 He estimated in March 2010 that developed countries representing 70 of the world s GDP were caught in a liquidity trap 40 Paradoxes of thrift and deleveraging edit Behavior that may be optimal for an individual e g saving more during adverse economic conditions can be detrimental if too many individuals pursue the same behavior as ultimately one person s consumption is another person s income Too many consumers attempting to save or pay down debt simultaneously is called the paradox of thrift 41 and can cause or deepen a recession Economist Hyman Minsky also described a paradox of deleveraging as financial institutions that have too much leverage debt relative to equity cannot all de leverage simultaneously without significant declines in the value of their assets 42 In April 2009 U S Federal Reserve Vice Chair Janet Yellen discussed these paradoxes Once this massive credit crunch hit it didn t take long before we were in a recession The recession in turn deepened the credit crunch as demand and employment fell and credit losses of financial institutions surged Indeed we have been in the grips of precisely this adverse feedback loop for more than a year A process of balance sheet deleveraging has spread to nearly every corner of the economy Consumers are pulling back on purchases especially durable goods to build their savings Businesses are cancelling planned investments and laying off workers to preserve cash And financial institutions are shrinking assets to bolster capital and improve their chances of weathering the current storm Once again Minsky understood this dynamic He spoke of the paradox of deleveraging in which precautions that may be smart for individuals and firms and indeed essential to return the economy to a normal state nevertheless magnify the distress of the economy as a whole 42 Predictors editMain article Inverted yield curve A handful of measures exist that are held to generally predict the possibility of a recession The U S Conference Board s Present Situation Index year over year change turns negative by more than 15 points before a recession 43 44 45 The U S Conference Board Leading Economic Indicator year over year change turns negative before a recession 46 47 When the CFNAI Diffusion Index drops below the value of 0 35 then there is an increased probability of the beginning a recession Usually the signal happens in the three months of the recession The CFNAI Diffusion Index signal tends to happen about one month before a related signal by the CFNAI MA3 3 month moving average drops below the 0 7 level The CFNAI MA3 correctly identified the 7 recessions between March 1967 August 2019 while triggering only 2 false alarms 48 Except for the above there are no known completely reliable predictors Analysis by Prakash Loungani of the International Monetary Fund found that only two of the sixty recessions around the world during the 1990s had been predicted by a consensus of economists one year earlier while there were zero consensus predictions one year earlier for the 49 recessions during 2009 49 However the following are considered possible predictors 50 The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago posts updates of the Brave Butters Kelley Indexes BBKI 51 The Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis posts the Weekly Economic Index Lewis Mertens Stock WEI 52 The Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis posts the Smoothed U S Recession Probabilities RECPROUSM156N 53 Inverted yield curve 54 55 the model developed by economist Jonathan H Wright uses yields on 10 year and three month Treasury securities as well as the Fed s overnight funds rate 56 Another model developed by Federal Reserve Bank of New York economists uses only the 10 year three month spread 57 58 59 The three month change in the unemployment rate and initial jobless claims 60 U S unemployment index is defined as the difference between the 3 month average of the unemployment rate and the 12 month minimum of the unemployment rate 61 Unemployment momentum and acceleration with Hidden Markov model 62 Index of Leading Economic Indicators includes some of the above indicators 63 Lowering of asset prices such as homes and financial assets or high personal and corporate debt levels Commodity prices may increase before recessions which usually hinders consumer spending by making necessities like transportation and housing costlier This will tend to constrict spending for non essential goods and services Once the recession occurs commodity prices will usually reset to a lower level Increased income inequality 64 65 Decreasing recreational vehicle shipments 66 Declining trucking volumes 67 68 The S amp P 500 and BBB bond spread 69 Government responses editSee also Stabilization policy Keynesian economists favor the use of expansionary macroeconomic policy during recessions to increase aggregate demand 70 71 72 73 Strategies favored for moving an economy out of a recession vary depending on which economic school the policymakers follow Monetarists exemplified by economist Milton Friedman would favor the use of limited expansionary monetary policy while Keynesian economists may advocate increased government spending to spark economic growth Supply side economists promote tax cuts to stimulate business capital investment For example the Trump administration claimed that lower effective tax rates on new investment imposed by the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 would raise investment thereby making workers more productive and raising output and wages Investment patterns in the United States through 2019 however indicated that the supply side incentives of the TCJA had little effect on investment growth Although investments increased after 2017 much of the increase was a response to oil prices and investment in other sectors had negligible growth 74 Monetarist economists have argued that objectives of monetary policy i e controlling the money supply to influence interest rates are best achieved by targeting the growth rate of the money supply They maintain that money may affect output in the short term but that in the long run expansionary monetary policy leads to inflation only Keynesian economists have mostly adopted this analysis modifying the theory with better integration of short and long run trends and an understanding that a change in the money supply affects only nominal variables in the economy such as prices and wages and has no effect on real variables like employment and output 75 76 The Federal Reserve traditionally uses monetary accommodation a policy instrument of lowering its main benchmark interest rate to accommodate sudden supply side shifts in the economy When the federal funds rate reaches the boundary of an interest rate of 0 called the zero lower bound the government resorts to unconventional monetary policy to stimulate recovery 77 Gauti B Eggertsson of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York using a New Keynesian macroeconomic model for policy analysis writes that cutting taxes on labor or capital is contractionary under certain circumstances such as those that prevailed following the economic crisis of 2008 and that temporarily increasing government spending at such times has much larger effects than under normal conditions He says other forms of tax cuts such as a reduction in sales taxes and investment tax credits e g in the context of Japan s Great Recession are also very effective Eggertsson infers from his analysis that the contractionary effects of labor and capital tax cuts and the strong expansionary effect of government spending are peculiar to the unusual environment created by zero interest rates He asserts that with positive interest rates a labor tax cut is expansionary per the established literature but at zero interest rates it reverses and tax cuts become contractionary Further while capital tax cuts are inconsequential in his model with a positive interest rate they become strongly negative at zero and the multiplier of government spending is then almost five times larger 78 Paul Krugman wrote in December 2010 that significant sustained government spending was necessary because indebted households were paying down debts and unable to carry the U S economy as they had previously The root of our current troubles lies in the debt American families ran up during the Bush era housing bubble highly indebted Americans not only can t spend the way they used to they re having to pay down the debts they ran up in the bubble years This would be fine if someone else were taking up the slack But what s actually happening is that some people are spending much less while nobody is spending more and this translates into a depressed economy and high unemployment What the government should be doing in this situation is spending more while the private sector is spending less supporting employment while those debts are paid down And this government spending needs to be sustained 79 John Maynard Keynes believed that government institutions could stimulate aggregate demand in a crisis Keynes showed that if somehow the level of aggregate demand could be triggered possibly by the government printing currency notes to employ people to dig holes and fill them up the wages that would be paid out would resuscitate the economy by generating successive rounds of demand through the multiplier process Anatomy of the Financial Crisis Between Keynes and Schumpeter Economic and Political Weekly 80 Stock market editSome recessions have been anticipated by stock market declines In Stocks for the Long Run Siegel mentions that since 1948 ten recessions were preceded by a stock market decline by a lead time of 0 to 13 months average 5 7 months while ten stock market declines of greater than 10 in the Dow Jones Industrial Average were not followed by a recession 81 The real estate market also usually weakens before a recession 82 However real estate declines can last much longer than recessions 83 Since the business cycle is very hard to predict Siegel argues that it is not possible to take advantage of economic cycles for timing investments Even the National Bureau of Economic Research NBER takes a few months to determine if a peak or trough has occurred in the US 84 U S politics editAn administration generally gets credit or blame for the state of the economy during its time in office 85 this state of affairs has caused disagreements about how particular recessions actually started 86 For example the 1981 recession is thought to have been caused by the tight money policy adopted by Paul Volcker chairman of the Federal Reserve Board before Ronald Reagan took office Reagan supported that policy Economist Walter Heller chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers in the 1960s said that I call it a Reagan Volcker Carter recession 87 Consequences editUnemployment edit Unemployment is particularly high during a recession Many economists working within the neoclassical paradigm argue that there is a natural rate of unemployment which when subtracted from the actual rate of unemployment can be used to estimate the GDP gap during a recession In other words unemployment never reaches 0 so it is not a negative indicator of the health of an economy unless it exceeds the natural rate in which case the excess corresponds directly to a loss in the GDP 88 The full impact of a recession on employment may not be felt for several quarters After recessions in Britain in the 1980s and 1990s it took five years for unemployment to fall back to its original levels 89 Employment discrimination claims rise during a recession 90 Business edit Productivity tends to fall in the early stages of a recession then rises again as weaker firms close The variation in profitability between firms rises sharply citation needed The fall in productivity could also be attributed to several macro economic factors such as the loss in productivity observed across the UK due to Brexit which may create a mini recession in the region Global epidemics such as COVID 19 could be another example since they disrupt the global supply chain or prevent the movement of goods services and people Recessions have also provided opportunities for anti competitive mergers with a negative impact on the wider economy the suspension of competition policy in the United States in the 1930s may have extended the Great Depression 89 Social effects edit The living standards of people dependent on wages and salaries are less affected by recessions than those who rely on fixed incomes or welfare benefits The loss of a job is known to have a negative impact on the stability of families and individuals health and well being Fixed income benefits receive small cuts why which make it tougher to survive 89 History editGlobal edit Main article Global recession According to the International Monetary Fund IMF Global recessions seem to occur over a cycle lasting between eight and 10 years 91 The IMF takes many factors into account when defining a global recession Until April 2009 IMF several times communicated to the press that a global annual real GDP growth of 3 0 or less in their view was equivalent to a global recession 92 93 By this measure six periods since 1970 qualify 1974 1975 94 1980 1983 94 1990 1993 94 95 1998 94 95 2001 2002 94 95 and 2008 2009 96 During what IMF in April 2002 termed the past three global recessions of the last three decades global per capita output growth was zero or negative and IMF argued at that time that because of the opposite being found for 2001 the economic state in this year by itself did not qualify as a global recession 91 In April 2009 IMF had changed their Global recession definition to A decline in annual per capita real World GDP purchasing power parity weighted backed up by a decline or worsening for one or more of the seven other global macroeconomic indicators Industrial production trade capital flows oil consumption unemployment rate per capita investment and per capita consumption 97 98 By this new definition a total of four global recessions took place since World War II 1975 1982 1991 and 2009 All of them only lasted one year although the third would have lasted three years 1991 1993 if IMF as criteria had used the normal exchange rate weighted per capita real World GDP rather than the purchase power parity weighted per capita real World GDP 97 98 Australia edit As a result of late 1920s profit issues in agriculture and cutbacks 1931 1932 saw Australia s biggest recession in its entire history It fared better than other nations that underwent depressions but their poor economic states influenced Australia which depended on them for export as well as foreign investments The nation also benefited from greater productivity in manufacturing facilitated by trade protection which also helped with lessening the effects The economy had gone into a brief recession in 1961 because of a credit squeeze Australia was facing a rising level of inflation in 1973 caused partially by the oil crisis happening in that same year which brought inflation at a 13 increase Economic recession hit by the middle of the year 1974 with no change in policy enacted by the government as a measure to counter the economic situation of the country Consequently the unemployment level rose and the trade deficit increased significantly 99 Another recession the most recent one to date came at the beginning of the 1990s as the result of a major stock collapse in October 1987 100 referred to now as Black Monday Although the collapse was larger than the one in 1929 the global economy recovered quickly but North America still suffered a decline in lumbering savings and loans which led to a crisis The recession was not limited to the United States but it also affected partnering nations such as Australia The unemployment level increased to 10 8 employment declined by 3 4 and the GDP also decreased as much as 1 7 Inflation however was successfully reduced Australia faced recession in 2020 due to the impact of huge bush fires and the COVID 19 pandemic s effect on tourism and other important aspects of the economy 101 needs update European Union edit The Eurozone experienced a recession in 2012 the economies of the 17 nation region failed to grow during any quarter of the 2012 calendar year The recession deepened during the final quarter of the year with the French German and Italian economies all affected 102 United Kingdom edit Main article List of recessions in the United Kingdom The most recent recession to affect the United Kingdom was the 2020 recession 103 attributed to the COVID 19 global pandemic the first recession since the Great Recession United States edit Main article List of recessions in the United States nbsp Recessions in the United States 1930 through 2021 nbsp Inverted yield curves correlation to recessions 30 year mortgage average 30 Year Treasury Bond 10 Year Treasury Bond 2 Year Treasury Bond 3 month Treasury Bond Effective Federal Funds Rate CPI inflation year year RecessionsAccording to economists since 1854 the U S has encountered 32 cycles of expansions and contractions with an average of 17 months of contraction and 38 months of expansion 12 From 1980 to 2018 there were only eight periods of negative economic growth over one fiscal quarter or more 104 and four periods considered recessions July 1981 November 1982 15 months July 1990 March 1991 8 months March 2001 November 2001 8 months December 2007 June 2009 18 months 105 106 For the last three of these recessions the NBER decision has approximately conformed with the definition involving two consecutive quarters of decline While the 2001 recession did not involve two consecutive quarters of decline it was preceded by two quarters of alternating decline and weak growth 104 Since then the NBER has also declared a 2 month COVID 19 recession for February 2020 April 2020 107 In July 2022 the NBER released a statement regarding declaring a recession following a second consecutive quarter of shrinking GDP There is no fixed rule about what measures contribute information to the process or how they are weighted in our decisions 108 NBER has sometimes declared a recession before a second quarter of GDP shrinkage has been reported but beginnings and endings can also be declared over a year after they are reckoned to have occurred In 1947 NBER did not declare a recession despite two quarters of declining GDP due to strong economic activity reported for employment industrial production and consumer spending 109 Late 2000s edit Main article Great Recession Official economic data shows that a substantial number of nations were in recession as of early 2009 The US entered a recession at the end of 2007 110 and 2008 saw many other nations follow suit The US recession of 2007 ended in June 2009 111 as the nation entered the current economic recovery The timeline of the Great Recession details the many elements of this period United States edit The United States housing market correction a consequence of the United States housing bubble and subprime mortgage crisis significantly contributed to a recession The 2007 2009 recession saw private consumption fall for the first time in nearly 20 years This indicated the depth and severity of the recession With consumer confidence so low economic recovery took a long time Consumers in the U S were hit hard by the Great Recession with the value of their houses dropping and their pension savings decimated on the stock market 112 U S employers shed 63 000 jobs in February 2008 113 the most in five years Former Federal Reserve chairman Alan Greenspan said on 6 April 2008 that There is more than a 50 percent chance the United States could go into recession 114 On 1 October the Bureau of Economic Analysis reported that an additional 156 000 jobs had been lost in September On 29 April 2008 Moody s declared that nine US states were in a recession In November 2008 employers eliminated 533 000 jobs the largest single month loss in 34 years 115 In 2008 an estimated 2 6 million U S jobs were eliminated 116 The unemployment rate in the U S grew to 8 5 in March 2009 117 and there were 5 1 million job losses by March 2009 since the recession began in December 2007 118 That was about five million more people unemployed compared to just a year prior 119 which was the largest annual jump in the number of unemployed persons since the 1940s 120 Although the US economy grew in the first quarter by 1 121 122 by June 2008 some analysts stated that due to a protracted credit crisis and rampant inflation in commodities such as oil food and steel the country was nonetheless in a recession 123 The third quarter of 2008 brought on a GDP retraction of 0 5 124 the biggest decline since 2001 The 6 4 decline in spending during Q3 on non durable goods like clothing and food was the largest since 1950 125 A November 2008 report from the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia based on the survey of 51 forecasters suggested that the recession started in April 2008 and would last 14 months 126 They projected real GDP declining at an annual rate of 2 9 in the fourth quarter and 1 1 in the first quarter of 2009 These forecasts represented significant downward revisions from the forecasts of three months prior A December 2008 report from the National Bureau of Economic Research stated that the U S had been in a recession since December 2007 when economic activity peaked based on several measures including job losses declines in personal income and declines in real GDP 127 By July 2009 a growing number of economists believed that the recession may have ended 128 129 The National Bureau of Economic Research announced on 20 September 2010 that the 2008 2009 recession ended in June 2009 making it the longest recession since World War II 130 Prior to the start of the recession it appears that no known formal theoretical or empirical model was able to accurately predict the advance of this recession except for minor signals in the sudden rise of forecasted probabilities which were still well under 50 58 See also editCredit crunch Deflation Depression Disinflation Economic collapse Economic stagnation Flooding the market Foreclosure Inventory bounce List of recessions in the United States Overproduction Stagflation Underconsumption COVID 19 recessionReferences edit recession Merriam Webster com Dictionary Recession definition Encarta World English Dictionary North American Edition Microsoft Corporation 2007 Archived from the original on 28 March 2009 Retrieved 19 November 2008 Business Cycle Dating Committee Announcement January 7 2008 www nber org 7 January 2008 a b FAQ EABCN eabcn org Archived from the original on 29 April 2022 Retrieved 29 December 2021 a b The CEPR and NBER Approaches eabcn org Retrieved 30 July 2022 a b Q amp A What is a recession BBC News 8 July 2008 a b Glossary of Treasury terms HM Treasury Archived from the original on 2 November 2012 Retrieved 25 October 2012 Shiskin Julius 1 December 1974 Points of View The New York Times ISSN 0362 4331 Archived from the original on 25 March 2020 Retrieved 27 July 2022 Dale Edwin L Jr 6 April 1974 U S to Broaden the Base Of Consumer Price Index The New York Times ISSN 0362 4331 Archived from the original on 27 July 2022 Retrieved 27 July 2022 Silk Leonard 28 August 1974 Recession Some Criteria Missing So Far The New York Times ISSN 0362 4331 Archived from the original on 27 July 2022 Retrieved 27 July 2022 Lakshman Achuthan Banerji Anirvan 7 May 2008 The risk of redefining recession CNN Money Retrieved 8 August 2022 a b Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions National Bureau of Economic Research Archived from the original on 5 March 2020 Retrieved 20 March 2020 Anstey Chris 28 July 2022 Technical Recession Sets Up Washington War of the Words Bloomberg News Retrieved 28 July 2022 Cox Jeff 28 July 2022 The economy may look like it s in recession but we still don t know for sure CNBC Archived from the original on 28 July 2022 Retrieved 28 July 2022 Jacobsen Louis 26 July 2022 What exactly is a recession Sorting out a confusing topic PolitiFact Archived from the original on 27 July 2022 Retrieved 28 July 2022 Loe Megan Lewis Brandon 28 July 2022 Yes there is an official definition of a recession KUSA com Retrieved 31 July 2022 Recession U S Bureau of Economic Analysis BEA www bea gov Bureau of Economic Analysis 2022 Retrieved 31 July 2022 OECD Economic Outlook Volume 2008 Issue 2 oecd ilibrary org 2008 Jiri Mazurek On some issues concerning definition of an economic recession 2012 a b Koo Richard 2009 The Holy Grail of Macroeconomics Lessons from Japan s Great Recession John Wiley amp Sons Asia Pte Ltd ISBN 978 0 470 82494 8 a b c Koo Richard C 12 December 2011 The world in balance sheet recession causes cure and politics PDF Real World Economics Review 58 19 Archived from the original PDF on 10 January 2020 Retrieved 3 August 2022 Saul Eslake November 2008 What is the difference between a recession and a depression Archived from the original on 23 July 2021 Kaur Rajwant Sidhu A S Spring 2012 Sarkar Siddhartha ed Global Recession and Its Impact on Foreign Trade in India International Journal of Afro Asian Studies Universal Publishers 3 1 62 ISBN 9781612336084 Key Indicators 2001 Growth and Change in Asia and the Pacific ADB org Archived from the original on 17 March 2010 Retrieved 31 July 2010 Samuelson Robert J 14 June 2010 Our economy s crisis of confidence The Washington Post Archived from the original on 26 March 2020 Retrieved 29 January 2011 The Conference Board Consumer Confidence Survey Press Release May 2010 Conference board org 25 March 2010 Archived from the original on 3 March 2020 Retrieved 29 January 2011 Akerlof George A Shiller Robert J 2010 Animal Spirits How Human Psychology Drives the Economy and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism Princeton University Press p 23 ISBN 978 1 4008 3472 3 Shiller Robert J 27 January 2009 Animal Spirits Depend on Trust The Wall Street Journal Archived from the original on 11 February 2020 Retrieved 29 January 2011 How to be an Adult 13 May 2020 Psychological Biases and Errors that led to historic bubbles and crashes Medium Archived from the original on 28 July 2020 Retrieved 13 May 2020 Jupe Robert 2014 Accounting balance sheet In Michie Jonathan ed Reader s Guide to the Social Sciences Routledge p 11 ISBN 978 1 135 93226 8 Krugman Paul 10 July 2014 Does He Pass the Test Stress Test Reflections on Financial Crises by Timothy Geithner New York Review of Books Archived from the original on 5 November 2015 Retrieved 26 November 2018 White Gregory 14 April 2010 Presentation by Richard Koo The Age of Balance Sheet Recessions Business Insider Archived from the original on 5 May 2021 Retrieved 29 January 2011 Krugman Paul 17 August 2010 Notes On Koo Wonkish The New York Times Archived from the original on 15 April 2021 Retrieved 26 November 2018 Krugman Paul 18 November 2010 Debt deleveraging and the liquidity trap Voxeu org Archived from the original on 21 April 2021 Retrieved 26 November 2018 Krugman Paul 6 July 2012 Grim Natural Experiments Archived from the original on 22 April 2021 Retrieved 26 November 2018 Konczal Mike 3 July 2012 New Report A Literature Summary on New Balance Sheet Recession Research Next New Deal Roosevelt Institute Archived from the original on 16 October 2015 Eggertsson Gauti B 2018 Liquidity Trap The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Palgrave Macmillan UK pp 7929 7936 doi 10 1057 978 1 349 95189 5 2482 ISBN 978 1 349 95189 5 Correia Isabel Farhi Emmanuel Nicolini Juan Pablo Teles Pedro August 2012 Unconventional Fiscal Policy at the Zero Bound Working Paper 698 PDF Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis p 1 Retrieved 5 August 2022 Krugman Paul 2009 The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008 W W Norton Company Limited ISBN 978 0 393 07101 6 How Much of the World is in a Liquidity Trap Krugman blogs nytimes com 17 March 2010 Archived from the original on 24 April 2020 Retrieved 29 January 2011 Lipsey Richard G Harbury Colin 1992 First Principles of Economics Oxford University Press p 294 ISBN 978 0 297 82120 5 a b A Minsky Meltdown Lessons for Central Bankers Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco speeches 16 April 2009 Archived from the original on 5 January 2013 Retrieved 4 June 2019 Federal Reserve Bank of New York Consumer Confidence A Useful Indicator of the Labor Market Archived 14 May 2020 at the Wayback Machine Jason Bram Robert Rich and Joshua Abel Conference Board s Present Situation Index nbsp This article incorporates text from this source which is in the public domain Wall Street starts 2017 with tailwind By Juergen Buettner 4 January 2017 Chart 1 Consumer Confidence Index and Historically Shocks Archived from the original on 28 April 2020 Retrieved 14 February 2020 Consumer Confidence Drops Why Does It Matter Archived 18 March 2020 at the Wayback Machine Forbes 27 June 2019 Brad McMillan Gundlach We don t see a recession on the horizon But there s bad news Yahoo Finance 14 February 2019 Archived from the original on 25 September 2019 Retrieved 25 September 2019 Seeking Alpha Take Me To Your Leader Analyzing The Latest Leading Indicators by 1 9 24 September 2019 Background on the Chicago Fed National Activity Index Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 19 September 2019 PDF Archived PDF from the original on 14 May 2020 Retrieved 25 September 2019 Grim Stock Signals Piling Up as Wall Street Mulls Recession Odds Bloomberg L P 25 November 2018 Archived from the original on 4 March 2020 Retrieved 26 November 2018 A Estrella FS Mishkin 1995 Predicting U S Recessions Financial Variables as Leading Indicators PDF Review of Economics and Statistics MIT Press 80 45 61 doi 10 1162 003465398557320 S2CID 11641969 Archived PDF from the original on 6 April 2020 Retrieved 25 August 2019 A Big Data View of the U S Economy Introducing the Brave Butters Kelley Indexes Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago chicagofed org Archived from the original on 28 May 2020 Retrieved 6 May 2020 Weekly Economic Index Lewis Mertens Stock FRED Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis 5 January 2008 Archived from the original on 19 July 2021 Retrieved 19 July 2021 Smoothed U S Recession Probabilities FRED Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis 1 February 1967 Archived from the original on 2 May 2020 Retrieved 6 May 2020 Ulatan Jeffrey 3 July 2020 2020 Recession Signals After US Iran Airstrike Vanguard ETF Best Performing Funds for 2020 Harvard Dataverse doi 10 7910 DVN AWWQPN Grading Bonds on Inverted Curve Archived 7 May 2019 at the Wayback Machine By Michael Hudson Wright Jonathan H The Yield Curve and Predicting Recessions Archived 28 July 2020 at the Wayback Machine March 2006 FEDs Working Paper No 2006 7 The Yield Curve as a Leading Indicator newyorkfed org Federal Reserve Bank of New York 2020 Archived from the original on 14 May 2017 Retrieved 20 March 2020 a b Park Byeong U Simar Leopold Zelenyuk Valentin 15 May 2019 Forecasting of recessions via dynamic probit for time series replication and extension of Kauppi and Saikkonen 2008 Empirical Economics Springer Science and Business Media LLC 58 1 379 392 doi 10 1007 s00181 019 01708 2 ISSN 0377 7332 S2CID 253717746 1 Archived 19 March 2020 at the Wayback Machine Using the U S Treasury Yield Curve to predict S amp P 500 returns and U S recessions Theodore Gregory Hanks Pennsylvania State University Schreyer Honors College Department of Finance Spring 2012 Labor Model Predicts Lower Recession Odds The Wall Street Journal 28 January 2008 Archived from the original on 19 August 2020 Retrieved 29 January 2011 Sahm Claudia 6 May 2019 Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals PDF Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Archived PDF from the original on 31 March 2020 Retrieved 25 August 2019 Lihn Stephen H T 10 August 2019 Real time Recession Probability with Hidden Markov Model and Unemployment Momentum SSRN 3435667 Leading Economic Indicators Suggest U S In Recession Archived 6 July 2009 at the Wayback Machine 21 January 2008 Income and wealth inequality make recessions worse research reveals phys org 2016 Archived from the original on 13 December 2019 Retrieved 25 August 2019 Neves Pedro Cunha Afonso oscar Silva Sandra Tavares February 2016 A Meta Analytic Reassessment of the Effects of Inequality on Growth World Development 78 386 400 doi 10 1016 j worlddev 2015 10 038 Raice Shayndi 19 August 2019 An Economic Warning Sign RV Shipments Are Slipping The Wall Street Journal Archived from the original on 8 June 2020 Retrieved 18 September 2019 Premack Rachel The bloodbath in America s trucking industry has officially spilled over to the rest of the economy Business Insider Archived from the original on 8 February 2020 Retrieved 18 September 2019 Cass Freight Index Report PDF August 2019 Archived PDF from the original on 13 December 2019 Retrieved 18 September 2019 2 Archived 6 December 2020 at the Wayback Machine JPMorgan The US Economic Outlook Feb 2020 Page 22 Stiglitz Joseph E Ocampo Jose Antonio eds 2008 Capital Market Liberalization and Development OUP Oxford p 360 ISBN 978 0 19 923058 7 Ahuja H L 2019 Monetarism and Friedman s Restatement of Quantity Theory of Money Macroeconomics 20e S Chand Publishing p 527 ISBN 978 93 5283 732 8 Thornton Saranna 2018 Bucking The Deficit Economic Policymaking In America Routledge p 30 ISBN 978 0 429 97052 8 Mason J W 2020 Chapter 1 Macroeconomic lessons from the past decade In MacLean Brian K Bougrine Hassan Rochon Louis Philippe eds Aggregate Demand and Employment International Perspectives Edward Elgar Publishing p 29 ISBN 978 1 78643 205 6 Gale William G Haldeman Claire 6 July 2021 Searching for supply side effects of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act PDF Brookings pp 3 4 Retrieved 5 August 2022 Jahan Sarwat Mahmud Ahmed Saber Papageorgiou Chris September 2014 What Is Keynesian Economics Back to Basics PDF Finance amp Development 51 1 54 Jahan Sarwat Papageorgiou Chris March 2014 What Is Monetarism Back to Basics PDF Finance and Development 51 1 38 Skaperdas Arsenios 7 July 2017 How Effective is Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound Identification Through Industry Heterogeneity PDF pp 2 3 Eggertsson Gauti B 1 January 2011 What Fiscal Policy Is Effective at Zero Interest Rates NBER Macroeconomics Annual 25 59 60 doi 10 1086 657529 hdl 10419 60825 ISSN 0889 3365 S2CID 16071568 Krugman Paul 13 December 2010 Opinion Block Those Economic Metaphors The New York Times Archived from the original on 20 August 2019 Retrieved 26 November 2018 Nayak Pulin B 2009 Anatomy of the Financial Crisis Between Keynes and Schumpeter Economic and Political Weekly 44 13 160 ISSN 0012 9976 JSTOR 40278675 Siegel Jeremy J 2002 Stocks for the Long Run The Definitive Guide to Financial Market Returns and Long Term Investment Strategies 3rd New York McGraw Hill 388 ISBN 978 0 07 137048 6 From the subprime to the terrigenous Recession begins at home Land Values Research Group 2 June 2009 Archived from the original on 12 June 2009 Retrieved 16 June 2009 A downturn in the property market especially in turnover sales of properties is a leading indicator of recession with a lead time of up to 9 quarters Shiller Robert J 6 June 2009 Why Home Prices May Keep Falling The New York Times Archived from the original on 3 July 2020 Retrieved 10 April 2010 Sloan Allan 11 December 2007 Recession Predictions and Investment Decisions The Washington Post Archived from the original on 28 July 2020 Retrieved 10 September 2017 Economy puts Republicans at risk BBC 29 January 2008 Archived from the original on 2 February 2008 Retrieved 8 March 2008 The Bush Recession Archived 4 February 2011 at the Wayback Machine Prepared by Democratic staff Senate Budget Committee 31 July 2003 Church George J 23 November 1981 Ready for a Real Downer Time Archived from the original on 23 April 2008 Unemployment Rate Archived 12 September 2012 at the Wayback Machine p 1 The Saylor Foundation Retrieved 20 June 2012 a b c Vaitilingam Romesh 17 September 2009 Recession Britain New ESRC report on the impact of recession on people s jobs businesses and daily lives Economic and Social Research Council Archived from the original on 2 January 2010 Retrieved 22 January 2010 Rampell Catherine 11 January 2011 More Workers Complain of Bias on the Job a Trend Linked to Widespread Layoffs The New York Times Archived from the original on 23 July 2016 Retrieved 7 February 2017 a b The Recession that Almost Was Archived 12 December 2008 at the Wayback Machine Kenneth Rogoff International Monetary Fund Financial Times 5 April 2002 The world economy Bad or worse The Economist 9 October 2008 Archived from the original on 21 February 2009 Retrieved 15 April 2009 Lall Subir International Monetary Fund 9 April 2008 IMF Predicts Slower World Growth Amid Serious Market Crisis Archived 28 February 2009 at the Wayback Machine a b c d e Global Economic Slump Challenges Policies Archived 9 January 2020 at the Wayback Machine IMF January 2009 a b c Global Recession Risk Grows as U S Damage Spreads Jan 2008 Bloomberg L P 28 January 2008 Archived from the original on 21 March 2010 Retrieved 15 April 2009 World Economic Outlook WEO April 2013 Statistical appendix Table A1 Summary of World Output PDF IMF 16 April 2013 Archived PDF from the original on 25 May 2013 Retrieved 16 April 2013 a b Davis Bob 22 April 2009 What s a Global Recession The Wall Street Journal Archived from the original on 28 February 2019 Retrieved 17 September 2013 a b World Economic Outlook April 2009 Crisis and Recovery PDF Box 1 1 pp 11 14 IMF 24 April 2009 Archived PDF from the original on 31 December 2010 Retrieved 17 September 2013 Australian Economic Indicators Australian Bureau of Statistics 27 February 1998 archived from the original on 16 October 2015 retrieved 11 August 2015 Reasons for 1990s Recession The Age Melbourne 2 December 2006 archived from the original on 12 April 2014 retrieved 11 August 2015 Janda Michael 3 June 2020 Australian Recession Australian Broadcasting Corporation archived from the original on 3 June 2020 retrieved 3 June 2020 Eurozone recession deepened at end of 2012 BBC News 14 February 2013 UK officially in recession for first time in 11 years The BBC 12 August 2020 Archived from the original on 12 August 2020 Retrieved 23 May 2022 a b Percent change from preceding period U S Bureau of Economic Analysis BEA Archived from the original on 14 August 2018 Retrieved 26 November 2018 Isidore Chris 1 December 2008 It s official Recession since Dec 07 CNN Archived from the original on 14 August 2021 Retrieved 29 January 2011 US economy out of recession BBC News Business 29 October 2009 Archived from the original on 28 July 2020 Retrieved 6 February 2010 Business Cycle Dating Committee Announcement July 19 2021 NBER 19 July 2021 Archived from the original on 26 April 2022 Retrieved 19 July 2021 Business Cycle Dating Procedure Frequently Asked Questions NBER Archived from the original on 29 July 2022 Retrieved 29 July 2022 Blake Aaron 28 July 2022 What two negative GDP quarters means for recession and our politics The Washington Post Determination of the December 2007 Peak in Economic Activity PDF NBER Business Cycle Dating Committee 11 December 2008 Archived PDF from the original on 19 April 2009 Retrieved 26 April 2009 Izzo Phil 20 September 2010 Recession Over in June 2009 The Wall Street Journal Archived from the original on 7 December 2017 Retrieved 4 August 2017 Economic Crisis When will it End IBISWorld Recession Briefing Archived 14 May 2011 at the Wayback Machine Dr Richard J Buczynski and Michael Bright IBISWorld January 2009 Andrews Edmund L 7 March 2008 Employment Falls for Second Month The New York Times Archived from the original on 11 August 2019 Retrieved 10 March 2020 Recession unlikely if US economy gets through next two crucial months Archived 12 August 2011 at the Wayback Machine Uchitelle Louis Andrews Edmund L Labaton Stephen 6 December 2008 U S Loses 533 000 Jobs in Biggest Drop Since 1974 The New York Times Archived from the original on 9 April 2009 Retrieved 10 April 2010 Uchitelle Louis 9 January 2009 U S lost 2 6 million jobs in 2008 The New York Times Archived from the original on 1 March 2020 Retrieved 10 March 2020 Unemployment rate in March 2009 Archived 6 August 2020 at the Wayback Machine 6 April 2009 U S Bureau of Labor Statistics Retrieved 10 March 2020 2 million jobs lost so far in 09 Archived 11 January 2020 at the Wayback Machine CNN Money 3 April 2009 Retrieved 10 March 2020 Employment Situation Summary Bls gov 2 July 2010 Archived from the original on 6 October 2009 Retrieved 31 July 2010 Goldman David 9 January 2009 Worst year for jobs since 45 CNN Archived from the original on 6 October 2013 Retrieved 10 April 2010 Meyer Brent 16 October 2008 Real GDP First Quarter 2008 Preliminary Estimate Brent Meyer Economic Trends 06 03 08 Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Clevelandfed org Archived from the original on 5 October 2008 Retrieved 29 January 2011 Fragile economy improves but not out of woods yet Yahoo Finance Archived from the original on 7 July 2008 Why it s worse than you think Archived 1 October 2009 at the Wayback Machine 16 June 2008 Newsweek Gross Domestic Product Third quarter 2008 Bea gov Archived from the original on 14 August 2018 Retrieved 29 January 2011 Chandra Shobhana 30 October 2008 U S Economy Contracts Most Since the 2001 Recession Bloomberg Retrieved 29 January 2011 Fourth quarter 2008 Survey of Professional Forecasters Philadelphiafed org 17 November 2008 Archived from the original on 3 July 2009 Retrieved 29 January 2011 Text of the NBER s statement on the recession USA Today 1 December 2008 Archived from the original on 14 November 2010 Retrieved 29 January 2011 Gross Daniel 13 July 2009 Daniel Gross The Recession is Over Newsweek Keilis Borok V I Soloviev A A Intriligator M D Winberg F E 2008 Pattern of Macroeconomic Indicators Preceding the End of an American Economic Recession Journal of Pattern Recognition Research 3 1 40 53 doi 10 13176 11 106 ISSN 1558 884X Business Cycle Dating Committee National Bureau of Economic Research nber org 20 September 2010 Archived from the original on 2 March 2021 Retrieved 26 November 2018 External links editMoore Geoffrey H 2002 Recessions In Henderson David R ed Concise Encyclopedia of Economics 1st ed Library of Economics and Liberty OCLC 317650570 50016270 163149563 Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions The National Bureau Of Economic Research Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Recession amp oldid 1207651954, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.