fbpx
Wikipedia

The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2018), 3rd ed., is a twenty-volume reference work on economics published by Palgrave Macmillan. It contains around 3,000 entries, including many classic essays from the original Inglis Palgrave Dictionary, and a significant increase in new entries from the previous editions by the most prominent economists in the field, among them 36 winners of the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel.[1] Articles are classified according to Journal of Economic Literature (JEL) classification codes.[2]

The New Palgrave is also available in a hyperlinked online version. Online content is added to the 2018 edition, and a 4th edition under the editorship of J. Barkley Rosser Jr., Esteban Pérez Caldentey, and Matías Vernengo will be published in the future. The first edition was titled The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (1987), was and edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman, as a way of recovering the legacy of Inglis Palgrave famous dictionary. It was published in four volumes, while the second edition was under the direction of Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume and was published in eight volumes.[3] Both are discussed in a section below.

Access to full-text articles (for all editions and post-2018 updates) are available online by subscription, whether of an organization, a person, or a person through an organization.[4][5]

The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics

The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (1987) is the title of the first New Palgrave edition. It is a four-volume reference edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman. It has 4,000 pages of entries, including 1,300 subject entries (with 4,000 cross-references), and 655 biographies. There were 927 contributors, including 13 Nobel Laureates in Economics at the time of first publication. It includes about 50 articles from Palgrave's Dictionary of Political Economy (1925–1927).[3] It was roughly twice the length of its predecessor and differed further in excluding most subjects not on economics or closely related to its practice.[6] It was developed as a modern version of the old Inglis Palgrave dictionary, with entries written by prominent economists for a highly specialized public.

Reviews

General remarks

Reviewing the 1987 edition for the New York Times, Robert M. Solow concluded that "this is a dictionary only in a very special sense. There are excellent survey articles, in various sizes, on various subjects. But the best of them are written by professionals for professionals." According to Solow, graduate students in economics would find the dictionary useful, but most of the articles would be inaccessible to non-economists, even undergraduate students of the liberal arts. For economists, however, the dictionary provided many excellent overviews of contemporary research.[7] In response, editor Milgate (1992) confirmed that the articles were written for an audience of professional economists, and so neither for the general reading public nor for specialist economists.

Mathematics and contemporary economics

According to Milgate, New Palgrave downplayed mathematics, in comparison to leading economic journals. Only 24% of the columns contained "any mathematics" (and so required expensive hand-typesetting), while only 25% of the most recent issue of the American Economic Review (AER) in fact lacked mathematics, according to Milgate, who averred that the AER's mathematical usage was typical of leading contemporary journals: The New Palgrave's usage of mathematics was the reciprocal of the contemporary profession's. (Milgate 1992, p. 299) "It must be concluded that the New Palgrave actually under-represented the mathematical element in modern economics; and under-represented it to a significant degree", wrote Milgate (1992, p. 300).

Commenting on contemporary economics, Solow described technical economics as its essential "infrastructure":

There is a lesson in the fate of Palgrave. Economics is no longer a fit conversation piece for ladies and gentlemen. It has become a technical subject. Like any technical subject it attracts some people who are more interested in the technique than the subject. That is too bad, but it may be inevitable. In any case, do not kid yourself: the technical core of economics is indispensable infrastructure for the political economy. That is why, if you consult Palgrave looking for enlightenment about the world today, you will be led to technical economics, or history, or nothing at all.[7]

More advanced mathematics was implicit in some of the articles, many of which were well written and reasonably accessible. Solow recommended the "broad and deep" article on game theory by Robert J. Aumann for well-equipped graduate students, along with John Harsanyi's article on bargaining theory. The articles on financial economics were "written by the best people—Stephen Ross, Robert Merton, and others—and they show it"; however, they were too difficult for the average investor. Complimenting the article on international trade, Solow added a caveat lector: "But God forbid that" a reader without knowledge of economics should try to understand protectionism, by consulting the New Palgrave.[7]

In his review, George Stigler commended the dictionary's non-technical and conceptually rich article on social choice, which was written by Kenneth Arrow, among "numerous" excellent articles. However, Stigler criticized the inclusion of "dozens" of articles in mathematical economics, which failed to provide intuitive introductions to the problem, how it was solved, and what the solution is: "These articles were written, not for a tolerably competent economist, but exclusively for fellow specialists."[8]

Exclusion of empirical material

Whitaker wrote, "Readers to whom economics is nothing if not a science based on empirical inquiry may be dismayed by the lack of attention to empirical studies and factual matters".[9]

Stigler criticized the New Palgrave for largely ignoring empirical economics—economic data, summary statistics, and econometric investigations. According to Stigler, the empirical investigation of consumption and production functions has profoundly influenced microeconomic theory, while the empirical investigation of price levels has profoundly influenced monetary economics: The New Palgrave's neglect of empirical economics also weakened its treatment of economic theory and the history of economic thought. Furthermore, the editors failed to explain their neglect of empirical economics, while they gave large space to treatments of "technical economics", especially mathematical economics, and faddish topics, wrote Stigler.[10]

"The article on 'Profit and profit theory' does not contain a single number for what profits are or ever have been, in the United States or any other country, or any reference to any source that might provide such a number", wrote Herbert Stein, who complained "There are articles about elasticities of this or that but no estimate of the elasticity of anything."[11]

Reviewing the critics of the over-emphasis on theoretical and "doctrinal" economics, editor Milgate admitted that the New Palgrave was flawed by its neglect of empirical economics.[12]

Criticisms of undue weight for heterodox approaches

Robert M. Solow criticized the 1987 edition for slighting mainstream economics by giving excessive space to the "dissenting fringes within academic economics", namely Marxist economics as well as "Austrian persuasion", Post-Keynesians, and neo-Ricardian.[7]

Nevertheless, there is usually a definite consensus—there is one now—and an accurate picture of the discipline would make that clear. It would have to give dissent a fair shake. It would have to treat mainstream ideas critically. But it should keep the various "paradigms" in proportion. I do not think The New Palgrave has managed to do that.

The most obvious, though not the most important, manifestation of imbalance is the large number of items devoted to Marxist themes, from "abstract and concrete labor" to "vulgar economy." Some of the articles are informative, some are mystifying; but that is not the point. Marx was an important and influential thinker, and Marxism has been a doctrine with intellectual and practical influence. The fact is, however, that most serious English-speaking economists regard Marxist economics as an irrelevant dead end. The New Palgrave does not take up the issue head on, but I think it gives a false impression of the state of play by this deadpan statement. It is rather as if a medical dictionary were to intersperse articles on mainstream orthopedics, written by orthopedists, with articles on osteopathy, written by osteopaths, and were to leave it at that.[7]

The 1987 dictionary's discussion of heterodox approaches was also criticized by George Stigler, who complained that these articles were written by sympathetic editors in a partisan manner:

The selection of sympathetic writers ... is in fact a general practice in Palgrave II. Israel Kirzner's essay on the Austrian economists does not hint at the existence of error, misrepresentation of critics, or tasteless attacks upon the German Historical School, and Klaus Henning did little better with Böhm-Bawerk. An ersatz Austrian is apparently more loyal than the genuine article.[8] [Italics added]

Stigler complained about the extensive and biased articles on Marxist economics, including "neo-Ricardian" economists (who follow Piero Sraffa): "A nonprofessional reader would never guess from these volumes that economists working in the Marxian-Sraffian tradition represent a small minority of modern economists, and that their writings have virtually no impact upon the professional work of most economists in major English-language universities." Stigler provided a table of articles that were biased by Marxist orthodoxy and criticized some authors by name, especially a "violently pro-Marxist" entry by C. B. Macpherson.[8]

The 2nd edition (2008)

The General Editors were Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume.[13] It added considerably on the previous edition, and maintained the general conception of the dictionary as written for advanced specialists. The list of Nobel laureates increased to 25, and the number of volumes also doubled. Perhaps as a result of already being an established institution there were a considerably smaller number of reviews. Declan Trott argued that the Dictionary is not properly a dictionary or an encyclopedia and that the quality and depth of the entries are very uneven, comparing it with Wikipedia as a source for information on economics.[14]

Earlier editions

R. H. Inglis Palgrave's Dictionary of Political Economy (1894–1899), 3 v., was the forerunner of The New Palgrave. The initial contractual agreement between Palgrave and the publisher Macmillan & Co. is dated 1888. Serial installments in 1891–92 had disappointing sales. An appendix was added to Volume III in 1908, so completing publication of the set. The Dictionary was wide-ranging and sometimes idiosyncratic. It included for example a comprehensive treatment of laws on property and commercial transactions. Professional reaction has been described as generally favorable and unsurprising, "given that almost all economists of any repute had already endorsed the enterprise by agreeing to contribute."[6] Nearly thirty years after the first volume appeared, Palgrave's Dictionary of Political Economy (1923–1926), edited by Henry Higgs, appeared with Palgrave's name added to the title but few changes in structure or contents.[15]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Durlauf, Steven N.; Blume, Lawrence E. (2008). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (8 volume set) (2nd ed.). Basingstoke, Hampshire New York: Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 9780333786765.
  2. ^ Durlauf, Steven N.; Blume, Lawrence E., eds. (2008), "Appendix IV – subject index", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed.), Basingstoke, Hampshire New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 854–69, ISBN 9780333786765
  3. ^ a b Eatwell, John; Milgate, Murray; Newman, Peter K. (1987). The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed.). London New York Tokyo: Macmillan Stockton Press Maruzen. ISBN 9780333740408.
  4. ^ . Archived from the original on 2015-02-06. Retrieved 2015-02-07.
  5. ^ . Archived from the original on 2015-02-06. Retrieved 2015-02-07.
  6. ^ a b Stigler (1988).
  7. ^ a b c d e Robert M. Solow, The New York Times "The Wide, Wide World of Wealth", March 28, 1998
  8. ^ a b c Stigler (1988), p. 1732
  9. ^ Whitaker, John K. (1989). "Palgrave resurrected: a review article". Journal of Political Economy. 97 (2): 484. doi:10.1086/261612. JSTOR 1831322. (subscription required)
  10. ^ Stigler (1988), p. 1731
  11. ^ Stein, Herbert, 1988. "The state of economics", The AEI Economist, January, pp. 1–7, as cited by Milgate (1992), p. 291.
  12. ^ Milgate (1992), p. 291
  13. ^ Blaug, Mark; Sturges, Rodney P. (1999). Who's who in economics. Cheltenham, UK Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing. ISBN 9781858988863.
  14. ^ Trott, Declan (2008). "Reviewed Work: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online by Steven N. Durlauf, Lawrence E. Blume". Agenda - A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform. 15 (4): 61–64. ISSN 1322-1833. JSTOR 43199543.
  15. ^ Eatwell, John; Milgate, Murray; Newman, Peter K., eds. (1987), "Palgrave", The New Palgrave: a dictionary of economics (2nd ed.), London New York Tokyo: Macmillan Stockton Press Maruzen, pp. 791–92, ISBN 9780333740408

References

  • Eatwell, John; Milgate, Murray; Newman, Peter K. (1987). The New Palgrave: a dictionary of economics (2nd ed.). London New York Tokyo: Macmillan Stockton Press Maruzen. ISBN 9780333740408.
  • Durlauf, Steven N.; Blume, Lawrence E. (2008). The New Palgrave dictionary of economics (8 volume set) (2nd ed.). Basingstoke, Hampshire New York: Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 9780333786765.
  • Solow, Robert M. (20 March 1988). "The wide, wide world of wealth (review of "The New Palgrave: a dictionary of economics")". New York Times.
  • Milgate, Murray (1992). "Reviewing the reviews of the New Palgrave". Revue Européenne des Sciences Sociales (English Translation of Journal Title: "European Review of Social Sciences"). Librairie Droz. 30 (92 (Special issue: "Editing economists and economists as editors"): 279–312. JSTOR 40372983.
  • Stigler, George J. (December 1988). "Palgrave's dictionary of economics (book review)". Journal of Economic Literature. American Economic Association. 26 (4): 1729–36. JSTOR 2726859.(subscription required)

palgrave, dictionary, economics, 2018, twenty, volume, reference, work, economics, published, palgrave, macmillan, contains, around, entries, including, many, classic, essays, from, original, inglis, palgrave, dictionary, significant, increase, entries, from, . The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2018 3rd ed is a twenty volume reference work on economics published by Palgrave Macmillan It contains around 3 000 entries including many classic essays from the original Inglis Palgrave Dictionary and a significant increase in new entries from the previous editions by the most prominent economists in the field among them 36 winners of the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1 Articles are classified according to Journal of Economic Literature JEL classification codes 2 The New Palgrave is also available in a hyperlinked online version Online content is added to the 2018 edition and a 4th edition under the editorship of J Barkley Rosser Jr Esteban Perez Caldentey and Matias Vernengo will be published in the future The first edition was titled The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics 1987 was and edited by John Eatwell Murray Milgate and Peter Newman as a way of recovering the legacy of Inglis Palgrave famous dictionary It was published in four volumes while the second edition was under the direction of Steven N Durlauf and Lawrence E Blume and was published in eight volumes 3 Both are discussed in a section below Access to full text articles for all editions and post 2018 updates are available online by subscription whether of an organization a person or a person through an organization 4 5 Contents 1 The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics 1 1 Reviews 1 1 1 General remarks 1 1 2 Mathematics and contemporary economics 1 1 3 Exclusion of empirical material 1 1 4 Criticisms of undue weight for heterodox approaches 2 The 2nd edition 2008 3 Earlier editions 4 See also 5 Notes 6 ReferencesThe New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics EditThe New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics 1987 is the title of the first New Palgrave edition It is a four volume reference edited by John Eatwell Murray Milgate and Peter Newman It has 4 000 pages of entries including 1 300 subject entries with 4 000 cross references and 655 biographies There were 927 contributors including 13 Nobel Laureates in Economics at the time of first publication It includes about 50 articles from Palgrave s Dictionary of Political Economy 1925 1927 3 It was roughly twice the length of its predecessor and differed further in excluding most subjects not on economics or closely related to its practice 6 It was developed as a modern version of the old Inglis Palgrave dictionary with entries written by prominent economists for a highly specialized public Reviews Edit General remarks Edit Reviewing the 1987 edition for the New York Times Robert M Solow concluded that this is a dictionary only in a very special sense There are excellent survey articles in various sizes on various subjects But the best of them are written by professionals for professionals According to Solow graduate students in economics would find the dictionary useful but most of the articles would be inaccessible to non economists even undergraduate students of the liberal arts For economists however the dictionary provided many excellent overviews of contemporary research 7 In response editor Milgate 1992 confirmed that the articles were written for an audience of professional economists and so neither for the general reading public nor for specialist economists Mathematics and contemporary economics Edit According to Milgate New Palgrave downplayed mathematics in comparison to leading economic journals Only 24 of the columns contained any mathematics and so required expensive hand typesetting while only 25 of the most recent issue of the American Economic Review AER in fact lacked mathematics according to Milgate who averred that the AER s mathematical usage was typical of leading contemporary journals The New Palgrave s usage of mathematics was the reciprocal of the contemporary profession s Milgate 1992 p 299 It must be concluded that the New Palgrave actually under represented the mathematical element in modern economics and under represented it to a significant degree wrote Milgate 1992 p 300 Commenting on contemporary economics Solow described technical economics as its essential infrastructure There is a lesson in the fate of Palgrave Economics is no longer a fit conversation piece for ladies and gentlemen It has become a technical subject Like any technical subject it attracts some people who are more interested in the technique than the subject That is too bad but it may be inevitable In any case do not kid yourself the technical core of economics is indispensable infrastructure for the political economy That is why if you consult Palgrave looking for enlightenment about the world today you will be led to technical economics or history or nothing at all 7 More advanced mathematics was implicit in some of the articles many of which were well written and reasonably accessible Solow recommended the broad and deep article on game theory by Robert J Aumann for well equipped graduate students along with John Harsanyi s article on bargaining theory The articles on financial economics were written by the best people Stephen Ross Robert Merton and others and they show it however they were too difficult for the average investor Complimenting the article on international trade Solow added a caveat lector But God forbid that a reader without knowledge of economics should try to understand protectionism by consulting the New Palgrave 7 In his review George Stigler commended the dictionary s non technical and conceptually rich article on social choice which was written by Kenneth Arrow among numerous excellent articles However Stigler criticized the inclusion of dozens of articles in mathematical economics which failed to provide intuitive introductions to the problem how it was solved and what the solution is These articles were written not for a tolerably competent economist but exclusively for fellow specialists 8 Exclusion of empirical material Edit Whitaker wrote Readers to whom economics is nothing if not a science based on empirical inquiry may be dismayed by the lack of attention to empirical studies and factual matters 9 Stigler criticized the New Palgrave for largely ignoring empirical economics economic data summary statistics and econometric investigations According to Stigler the empirical investigation of consumption and production functions has profoundly influenced microeconomic theory while the empirical investigation of price levels has profoundly influenced monetary economics The New Palgrave s neglect of empirical economics also weakened its treatment of economic theory and the history of economic thought Furthermore the editors failed to explain their neglect of empirical economics while they gave large space to treatments of technical economics especially mathematical economics and faddish topics wrote Stigler 10 The article on Profit and profit theory does not contain a single number for what profits are or ever have been in the United States or any other country or any reference to any source that might provide such a number wrote Herbert Stein who complained There are articles about elasticities of this or that but no estimate of the elasticity of anything 11 Reviewing the critics of the over emphasis on theoretical and doctrinal economics editor Milgate admitted that the New Palgrave was flawed by its neglect of empirical economics 12 Criticisms of undue weight for heterodox approaches Edit Robert M Solow criticized the 1987 edition for slighting mainstream economics by giving excessive space to the dissenting fringes within academic economics namely Marxist economics as well as Austrian persuasion Post Keynesians and neo Ricardian 7 Nevertheless there is usually a definite consensus there is one now and an accurate picture of the discipline would make that clear It would have to give dissent a fair shake It would have to treat mainstream ideas critically But it should keep the various paradigms in proportion I do not think The New Palgrave has managed to do that The most obvious though not the most important manifestation of imbalance is the large number of items devoted to Marxist themes from abstract and concrete labor to vulgar economy Some of the articles are informative some are mystifying but that is not the point Marx was an important and influential thinker and Marxism has been a doctrine with intellectual and practical influence The fact is however that most serious English speaking economists regard Marxist economics as an irrelevant dead end The New Palgrave does not take up the issue head on but I think it gives a false impression of the state of play by this deadpan statement It is rather as if a medical dictionary were to intersperse articles on mainstream orthopedics written by orthopedists with articles on osteopathy written by osteopaths and were to leave it at that 7 The 1987 dictionary s discussion of heterodox approaches was also criticized by George Stigler who complained that these articles were written by sympathetic editors in a partisan manner The selection of sympathetic writers is in fact a general practice in Palgrave II Israel Kirzner s essay on the Austrian economists does not hint at the existence of error misrepresentation of critics or tasteless attacks upon the German Historical School and Klaus Henning did little better with Bohm Bawerk An ersatz Austrian is apparently more loyal than the genuine article 8 Italics added Stigler complained about the extensive and biased articles on Marxist economics including neo Ricardian economists who follow Piero Sraffa A nonprofessional reader would never guess from these volumes that economists working in the Marxian Sraffian tradition represent a small minority of modern economists and that their writings have virtually no impact upon the professional work of most economists in major English language universities Stigler provided a table of articles that were biased by Marxist orthodoxy and criticized some authors by name especially a violently pro Marxist entry by C B Macpherson 8 The 2nd edition 2008 EditThe General Editors were Steven N Durlauf and Lawrence E Blume 13 It added considerably on the previous edition and maintained the general conception of the dictionary as written for advanced specialists The list of Nobel laureates increased to 25 and the number of volumes also doubled Perhaps as a result of already being an established institution there were a considerably smaller number of reviews Declan Trott argued that the Dictionary is not properly a dictionary or an encyclopedia and that the quality and depth of the entries are very uneven comparing it with Wikipedia as a source for information on economics 14 Earlier editions EditR H Inglis Palgrave s Dictionary of Political Economy 1894 1899 3 v was the forerunner of The New Palgrave The initial contractual agreement between Palgrave and the publisher Macmillan amp Co is dated 1888 Serial installments in 1891 92 had disappointing sales An appendix was added to Volume III in 1908 so completing publication of the set The Dictionary was wide ranging and sometimes idiosyncratic It included for example a comprehensive treatment of laws on property and commercial transactions Professional reaction has been described as generally favorable and unsurprising given that almost all economists of any repute had already endorsed the enterprise by agreeing to contribute 6 Nearly thirty years after the first volume appeared Palgrave s Dictionary of Political Economy 1923 1926 edited by Henry Higgs appeared with Palgrave s name added to the title but few changes in structure or contents 15 See also EditConcise Encyclopedia of Economics Economics handbooks International Encyclopedia of the Social amp Behavioral Sciences List of encyclopedias by branch of knowledgeNotes Edit Durlauf Steven N Blume Lawrence E 2008 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 8 volume set 2nd ed Basingstoke Hampshire New York Palgrave Macmillan ISBN 9780333786765 Durlauf Steven N Blume Lawrence E eds 2008 Appendix IV subject index The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd ed Basingstoke Hampshire New York Palgrave Macmillan pp 854 69 ISBN 9780333786765 a b Eatwell John Milgate Murray Newman Peter K 1987 The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics 2nd ed London New York Tokyo Macmillan Stockton Press Maruzen ISBN 9780333740408 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online Help Archived from the original on 2015 02 06 Retrieved 2015 02 07 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online About Archived from the original on 2015 02 06 Retrieved 2015 02 07 a b Stigler 1988 a b c d e Robert M Solow The New York Times The Wide Wide World of Wealth March 28 1998 a b c Stigler 1988 p 1732 Whitaker John K 1989 Palgrave resurrected a review article Journal of Political Economy 97 2 484 doi 10 1086 261612 JSTOR 1831322 subscription required Stigler 1988 p 1731 Stein Herbert 1988 The state of economics The AEI Economist January pp 1 7 as cited by Milgate 1992 p 291 Milgate 1992 p 291 Blaug Mark Sturges Rodney P 1999 Who s who in economics Cheltenham UK Northampton MA Edward Elgar Publishing ISBN 9781858988863 Trott Declan 2008 Reviewed Work The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online by Steven N Durlauf Lawrence E Blume Agenda A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform 15 4 61 64 ISSN 1322 1833 JSTOR 43199543 Eatwell John Milgate Murray Newman Peter K eds 1987 Palgrave The New Palgrave a dictionary of economics 2nd ed London New York Tokyo Macmillan Stockton Press Maruzen pp 791 92 ISBN 9780333740408References EditEatwell John Milgate Murray Newman Peter K 1987 The New Palgrave a dictionary of economics 2nd ed London New York Tokyo Macmillan Stockton Press Maruzen ISBN 9780333740408 Durlauf Steven N Blume Lawrence E 2008 The New Palgrave dictionary of economics 8 volume set 2nd ed Basingstoke Hampshire New York Palgrave Macmillan ISBN 9780333786765 Solow Robert M 20 March 1988 The wide wide world of wealth review of The New Palgrave a dictionary of economics New York Times Milgate Murray 1992 Reviewing the reviews of the New Palgrave Revue Europeenne des Sciences Sociales English Translation of Journal Title European Review of Social Sciences Librairie Droz 30 92 Special issue Editing economists and economists as editors 279 312 JSTOR 40372983 Stigler George J December 1988 Palgrave s dictionary of economics book review Journal of Economic Literature American Economic Association 26 4 1729 36 JSTOR 2726859 subscription required Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics amp oldid 1105527358 The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.