fbpx
Wikipedia

Malthusianism

Malthusianism is the idea that population growth is potentially exponential while the growth of the food supply or other resources is linear, which eventually reduces living standards to the point of triggering a population die off. This event, called a Malthusian catastrophe (also known as a Malthusian trap, population trap, Malthusian check, Malthusian crisis, Malthusian spectre, or Malthusian crunch) occurs when population growth outpaces agricultural production, causing famine or war, resulting in poverty and depopulation. Such a catastrophe inevitably has the effect of forcing the population to "correct" back to a lower, more easily sustainable level (quite rapidly, due to the potential severity and unpredictable results of the mitigating factors involved, as compared to the relatively slow time scales and well-understood processes governing unchecked growth or growth affected by preventive checks). [1][2] Malthusianism has been linked to a variety of political and social movements, but almost always refers to advocates of population control.[3]

Thomas Robert Malthus, after whom Malthusianism is named

These concepts derive from the political and economic thought of the Reverend Thomas Robert Malthus, as laid out in his 1798 writings, An Essay on the Principle of Population. Malthus suggested that while technological advances could increase a society's supply of resources, such as food, and thereby improve the standard of living, the resource abundance would enable population growth, which would eventually bring the per capita supply of resources back to its original level. Some economists contend that since the industrial revolution, mankind has broken out of the trap.[4][5] Others argue that the continuation of extreme poverty indicates that the Malthusian trap continues to operate.[6] Others further argue that due to lack of food availability coupled with excessive pollution, developing countries show more evidence of the trap.[7] A similar, more modern concept, is that of human overpopulation.

Neo-Malthusianism is the advocacy of human population planning to ensure resources and environmental integrities for current and future human populations as well as for other species.[2] In Britain the term 'Malthusian' can also refer more specifically to arguments made in favour of preventive birth control, hence organizations such as the Malthusian League.[8] Neo-Malthusians differ from Malthus's theories mainly in their support for the use of contraception. Malthus, a devout Christian, believed that "self-control" (i.e., abstinence) was preferable to artificial birth control. He also worried that the effect of contraceptive use would be too powerful in curbing growth, conflicting with the common 18th century perspective (to which Malthus himself adhered) that a steadily growing population remained a necessary factor in the continuing "progress of society", generally. Modern neo-Malthusians are generally more concerned than Malthus with environmental degradation and catastrophic famine than with poverty.

Malthusianism has attracted criticism from diverse schools of thought, including Georgists, Marxists[9] and socialists,[10] libertarians and free market enthusiasts,[11] feminists[12] and human rights advocates, characterising it as excessively pessimistic, misanthropic or inhuman.[13][14][3][15] Many critics believe Malthusianism has been discredited since the publication of Principle of Population, often citing advances in agricultural techniques and modern reductions in human fertility.[16] Some modern proponents believe that the basic concept of population growth eventually outstripping resources is still fundamentally valid, and that positive checks are still likely to occur in humanity's future if no action is taken to intentionally curb population growth.[17][18][better source needed] In spite of the variety of criticisms against it, the Malthusian argument remains a major discourse based on which national and international environmental regulations are promoted.

History

Malthus' theoretical argument

In 1798, Thomas Malthus proposed his hypothesis in An Essay on the Principle of Population.

He argued that although human populations tend to increase, the happiness of a nation requires a like increase in food production. "The happiness of a country does not depend, absolutely, upon its poverty, or its riches, upon its youth, or its age, upon its being thinly, or fully inhabited, but upon the rapidity with which it is increasing, upon the degree in which the yearly increase of food approaches to the yearly increase of an unrestricted population."[19]

However, the propensity for population increase also leads to a natural cycle of abundance and shortages:

We will suppose the means of subsistence in any country just equal to the easy support of its inhabitants. The constant effort towards population...increases the number of people before the means of subsistence are increased. The food therefore which before supported seven millions, must now be divided among seven millions and a half or eight millions. The poor consequently must live much worse, and many of them be reduced to severe distress. The number of labourers also being above the proportion of the work in the market, the price of labour must tend toward a decrease; while the price of provisions would at the same time tend to rise. The labourer therefore must work harder to earn the same as he did before. During this season of distress, the discouragements to marriage, and the difficulty of rearing a family are so great, that population is at a stand. In the mean time the cheapness of labour, the plenty of labourers, and the necessity of an increased industry amongst them, encourage cultivators to employ more labour upon their land; to turn up fresh soil, and to manure and improve more completely what is already in tillage; till ultimately the means of subsistence become in the same proportion to the population as at the period from which we set out. The situation of the labourer being then again tolerably comfortable, the restraints to population are in some degree loosened; and the same retrograde and progressive movements with respect to happiness are repeated.

— Thomas Malthus, 1798. An Essay on the Principle of Population, Chapter II.

Famine seems to be the last, the most dreadful resource of nature. The power of population is so superior to the power of the earth to produce subsistence for man, that premature death must in some shape or other visit the human race. The vices of mankind are active and able ministers of depopulation. They are the precursors in the great army of destruction, and often finish the dreadful work themselves. But should they fail in this war of extermination, sickly seasons, epidemics, pestilence, and plague advance in terrific array, and sweep off their thousands and tens of thousands. Should success be still incomplete, gigantic inevitable famine stalks in the rear, and with one mighty blow levels the population with the food of the world.

— Thomas Malthus, 1798. An Essay on the Principle of Population. Chapter VII, p. 61[20]

Malthus faced opposition from economists both during his life and since. A vocal critic several decades later was Friedrich Engels.[21][22]

Early history

Malthus was not the first to outline the problems he perceived. The original essay was part of an ongoing intellectual discussion at the end of the 18th century regarding the origins of poverty. Principle of Population was specifically written as a rebuttal to thinkers like William Godwin and the Marquis de Condorcet, and Malthus's own father who believed in the perfectibility of humanity. Malthus believed humanity's ability to reproduce too rapidly doomed efforts at perfection and caused various other problems.

His criticism of the working class's tendency to reproduce rapidly, and his belief that this, rather than exploitation by capitalists, led to their poverty, brought widespread criticism of his theory.[23]

Malthusians perceived ideas of charity to the poor, typified by Tory paternalism, were futile, as these would only result in increased numbers of the poor; these theories played into Whig economic ideas exemplified by the Poor Law Amendment Act of 1834. The Act was described by opponents as "a Malthusian bill designed to force the poor to emigrate, to work for lower wages, to live on a coarser sort of food",[24] which initiated the construction of workhouses despite riots and arson.

Malthus revised his theories in later editions of An Essay on the Principles of Population, taking a more optimistic tone, although there is some scholarly debate on the extent of his revisions.[1] According to Dan Ritschel of the Center for History Education at the University of Maryland, Baltimore County,

The great Malthusian dread was that "indiscriminate charity" would lead to exponential growth in the population in poverty, increased charges to the public purse to support this growing army of the dependent, and, eventually, the catastrophe of national bankruptcy. Though Malthusianism has since come to be identified with the issue of general over-population, the original Malthusian concern was more specifically with the fear of over-population by the dependent poor.[25]

One of the earliest critics was David Ricardo. Malthus immediately and correctly recognised it to be an attack on his theory of wages. Ricardo and Malthus debated this in a lengthy personal correspondence.[26]

Another one of the 19th century critics of Malthusian theory was Karl Marx who referred to it as "nothing more than a schoolboyish, superficial plagiary of De Foe, Sir James Steuart, Townsend, Franklin, Wallace" (in Capital, see Marx's footnote on Malthus from Capital – reference below). Marx and Engels described Malthus as a "lackey of the bourgeoisie".[23] Socialists and communists believed that Malthusian theories "blamed the poor" for their own exploitation by the capitalist classes, and could be used to suppress the proletariat to an even greater degree, whether through attempts to reduce fertility or by justifying the generally poor conditions of labour in the 19th century.[citation needed]

One proponent of Malthusianism was the novelist Harriet Martineau whose circle of acquaintances included Charles Darwin, and the ideas of Malthus were a significant influence on the inception of Darwin's theory of evolution.[27] Darwin was impressed by the idea that population growth would eventually lead to more organisms than could possibly survive in any given environment, leading him to theorize that organisms with a relative advantage in the struggle for survival and reproduction would be able to pass their characteristics on to further generations. Proponents of Malthusianism were in turn influenced by Darwin's ideas, both schools coming to influence the field of eugenics. Henry Fairfield Osborn Jr. advocated "humane birth selection through humane birth control" in order to avoid a Malthusian catastrophe by eliminating the "unfit".[1]

Malthusianism became a less common intellectual tradition as the 19th century advanced, mostly as a result of technological increases, the opening of new territory to agriculture, and increasing international trade.[1] Although a "conservationist" movement in the United States concerned itself with resource depletion and natural protection in the first half of the twentieth century, Desrochers and Hoffbauer write, "It is probably fair to say ... that it was not until the publication of Osborn's and Vogt's books [1948] that a Malthusian revival took hold of a significant segment of the American population".[1]

Modern formulation

 
Oded Galor

The modern formulation of the Malthusian theory was developed by Qumarul Ashraf and Oded Galor.[28] Their theoretical structure suggests that as long as: (i) higher income has a positive effect on reproductive success, and (ii) land is limited factor of production, then technological progress has only a temporary effect in income per capita. While in the short-run technological progress increases income per capita, resource abundance created by technological progress would enable population growth, and would eventually bring the per capita income back to its original long-run level.

The testable prediction of the theory is that during the Malthusian epoch technologically advanced economies were characterized by higher population density, but their level of income per capita was not different from the level in societies that are technologically backward.

Preventive vs. positive population controls

 
The Malthusian catastrophe simplistically illustrated

To manage population growth with respect to food supply, Malthus proposed methods which he described as preventive or positive checks:

  • A preventive check according to Malthus is ways that in which nature may alter population changes. Some primary examples are celibacy and chastity but also contraception, which Malthus condemned as morally indefensible along with infanticide, abortion and adultery.[29] In other words, preventive checks control the population by reducing fertility rates.[30]
  • A positive check is any event or circumstance that shortens the human life span. The primary examples of this are war, plague and famine.[31] However, poor health and economic conditions are also considered instances of positive checks.[32] When these lead to high rates of premature death, the result is termed a Malthusian catastrophe. The adjacent diagram depicts the abstract point at which such an event would occur, in terms of existing population and food supply: when the population reaches or exceeds the capacity of the shared supply, positive checks are forced to occur, restoring balance. (In reality the situation would be significantly more nuanced due to complex regional and individual disparities around access to food, water, and other resources.)

Neo-Malthusian theory

Malthusian theory is a recurrent theme in many social science venues. John Maynard Keynes, in Economic Consequences of the Peace, opens his polemic with a Malthusian portrayal of the political economy of Europe as unstable due to Malthusian population pressure on food supplies.[33] Many models of resource depletion and scarcity are Malthusian in character: the rate of energy consumption will outstrip the ability to find and produce new energy sources, and so lead to a crisis.[citation needed]

In France, terms such as "politique malthusienne" ("Malthusian politics") refer to population control strategies. The concept of restriction of the population associated with Malthus morphed, in later political-economic theory, into the notion of restriction of production. In the French sense, a "Malthusian economy" is one in which protectionism and the formation of cartels is not only tolerated but encouraged.[citation needed]

Vladimir Lenin, the leader of the Bolshevik Party and the main architect of the Soviet Union was a critic of Neo-Malthusian theory (but not of birth control and abortion in general).[34]

"Neo-Malthusianism" is a concern that overpopulation as well as overconsumption may increase resource depletion and/or environmental degradation will lead to ecological collapse or other hazards.[citation needed]

The rapid increase in the global population of the past century exemplifies Malthus's predicted population patterns; it also appears to describe socio-demographic dynamics of complex pre-industrial societies. These findings are the basis for neo-Malthusian modern mathematical models of long-term historical dynamics.[35]

There was a general "neo-Malthusian" revival in the mid-to-late 1940s, continuing through to the 2010s after the publication of two influential books in 1948 (Fairfield Osborn's Our Plundered Planet and William Vogt's Road to Survival). During that time the population of the world rose dramatically. Many in environmental movements began to sound the alarm regarding the potential dangers of population growth.[1] In 1968, ecologist Garrett Hardin published an influential essay in Science that drew heavily from Malthusian theory. His essay, "The Tragedy of the Commons", argued that "a finite world can support only a finite population" and that "freedom to breed will bring ruin to all."[36] The Club of Rome published a book entitled The Limits to Growth in 1972. The report and the organisation soon became central to the neo-Malthusian revival.[37] Paul R. Ehrlich has been one of the most prominent neo-Malthusians since the publication of The Population Bomb in 1968. Leading ecological economist Herman Daly has acknowledged the influence of Malthus on his concept of a steady-state economy.[38] Other prominent Malthusians include the Paddock brothers, authors of Famine 1975! America's Decision: Who Will Survive?

The neo-Malthusian revival has drawn criticism from writers who claim the Malthusian warnings were overstated or premature because the green revolution has brought substantial increases in food production and will be able to keep up with continued population growth.[16][39] Julian Simon, a cornucopian, has written that contrary to neo-Malthusian theory, Earth's "carrying capacity" is essentially limitless.[1] Simon argues not that there is an infinite physical amount of, say, copper, but for human purposes that amount should be treated as infinite because it is not bounded or limited in any economic sense, because: 1) known reserves are of uncertain quantity 2) New reserves may become available, either through discovery or via the development of new extraction techniques 3) recycling 4) more efficient utilization of existing reserves (e.g., "It takes much less copper now to pass a given message than a hundred years ago." [The Ultimate Resource 2, 1996, footnote, p. 62]) 5) development of economic equivalents, e.g., optic fibre in the case of copper for telecommunications. Responding to Simon, Al Bartlett reiterates the potential of population growth as an exponential (or as expressed by Malthus, "geometrical") curve to outstrip both natural resources and human ingenuity.[40] Bartlett writes and lectures particularly on energy supplies, and describes the "inability to understand the exponential function" as the "greatest shortcoming of the human race".

Prominent neo-Malthusians such as Paul Ehrlich maintain that ultimately, population growth on Earth is still too high, and will eventually lead to a serious crisis.[13][41] The 2007–2008 world food price crisis inspired further Malthusian arguments regarding the prospects for global food supply.[42]

From approximately 2004 to 2011, concerns about "peak oil" and other forms of resource depletion became widespread in the United States, and motivated a large if short-lived subculture of neo-Malthusian "peakists".[43]

A United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization study conducted in 2009[44] said that food production would have to increase by 70% over the next 40 years, and food production in the developing world would need to double[45] to feed a projected population increase from 7.8 billion to 9.1 billion in 2050. The effects of global warming (floods, droughts, and other extreme weather events) are expected to negatively affect food production, with different impacts in different regions.[46][47] The FAO also said the use of agricultural resources for biofuels may also put downward pressure on food availability.[48] The more recent emergence of bio-energy with carbon capture (BECCS) as a prevalent 'negative emissions' strategy for reaching Paris Climate Accord goals is another such pressure.

Evidence in support

Research indicates that technological superiority and higher land productivity had significant positive effects on population density but insignificant effects on the standard of living during the time period 1–1500 AD.[49] In addition, scholars have reported on the lack of a significant trend of wages in various places over the world for very long stretches of time.[5][50] In Babylonia during the period 1800 to 1600 BC, for example, the daily wage for a common laborer was enough to buy about 15 pounds of wheat. In Classical Athens in about 328 BC, the corresponding wage could buy about 24 pounds of wheat. In England in 1800 AD the wage was about 13 pounds of wheat.[5]: 50  In spite of the technological developments across these societies, the daily wage hardly varied. In Britain between 1200 and 1800, only relatively minor fluctuations from the mean (less than a factor of two) in real wages occurred. Following depopulation by the Black Death and other epidemics, real income in Britain peaked around 1450–1500 and began declining until the British Agricultural Revolution.[51] Historian Walter Scheidel posits that waves of plague following the initial outbreak of the Black Death throughout Europe had a leveling effect that changed the ratio of land to labor, reducing the value of the former while boosting that of the latter, which lowered economic inequality by making employers and landowners less well off while improving the economic prospects and living standards of workers. He says that "the observed improvement in living standards of the laboring population was rooted in the suffering and premature death of tens of millions over the course of several generations." This leveling effect was reversed by a "demographic recovery that resulted in renewed population pressure."[52]

Robert Fogel published a study of lifespans and nutrition from about a century before Malthus to the 19th century that examined European birth and death records, military and other records of height and weight that found significant stunted height and low body weight indicative of chronic hunger and malnutrition. He also found short lifespans that he attributed to chronic malnourishment which left people susceptible to disease. Lifespans, height and weight began to steadily increase in the UK and France after 1750. Fogel's findings are consistent with estimates of available food supply.[53]

Evidence supporting Malthusianism today can be seen in the poorer countries of the world with booming populations. In East Africa specifically, experts say that this area of the world has not yet escaped the Malthusian effects of population growth.[54] Jared Diamond in his book Collapse (2005), for example, argues that the Rwandan Genocide was brought about in part due to excessive population pressures. He argues that Rwanda "illustrates a case where Malthus's worst-case scenario does seem to have been right." Due to population pressures in Rwanda, Diamond explains that the population density combined with lagging technological advancements caused its food production to not be able to keep up with its population. Diamond claims that this environment is what caused the mass killings of Tutsi and even some Hutu Rwandans.[55] The genocide, in this instance, provides a potential example of a Malthusian trap.

Theory of breakout via technology

Industrial Revolution

Some researchers contend that a British breakout occurred due to technological improvements and structural change away from agricultural production, while coal, capital, and trade played a minor role.[56] Economic historian Gregory Clark, building on the insights of Galor and Moav,[57] has argued, in his book A Farewell to Alms, that a British breakout may have been caused by differences in reproduction rates among the rich and the poor (the rich were more likely to marry, tended to have more children, and, in a society where disease was rampant and childhood mortality at times approached 50%, upper-class children were more likely to survive to adulthood than poor children.) This in turn led to sustained "downward mobility": the descendants of the rich becoming more populous in British society and spreading middle-class values such as hard work and literacy.

20th century

 
Global deaths in conflicts since the year 1400
 
A chart of estimated annual growth rates in world population, 1800–2005. Rates before 1950 are annualized historical estimates from the US Census Bureau.[58] Red = USCB projections to 2025.
 
Growth in food production has historically been greater than the population growth. Food per person increased since 1961. The graph runs up to slightly past 2010.[59]

After World War II, mechanized agriculture produced a dramatic increase in productivity of agriculture and the Green Revolution greatly increased crop yields, expanding the world's food supply while lowering food prices. In response, the growth rate of the world's population accelerated rapidly, resulting in predictions by Paul R. Ehrlich, Simon Hopkins,[60] and many others of an imminent Malthusian catastrophe. However, populations of most developed countries grew slowly enough to be outpaced by gains in productivity.

By the early 21st century, many technologically-developed countries had passed through the demographic transition, a complex social development encompassing a drop in total fertility rates in response to various fertility factors, including lower infant mortality, increased urbanization, and a wider availability of effective birth control.

On the assumption that the demographic transition is now spreading from the developed countries to less developed countries, the United Nations Population Fund estimates that human population may peak in the late 21st century rather than continue to grow until it has exhausted available resources.[61] Recent empirical research corroborates this assumption for most of the less developed countries, with the exception of most of Sub-Saharan Africa.[62]

A 2004 study by a group of prominent economists and ecologists, including Kenneth Arrow and Paul Ehrlich[63] suggests that the central concerns regarding sustainability have shifted from population growth to the consumption/savings ratio, due to shifts in population growth rates since the 1970s. Empirical estimates show that public policy (taxes or the establishment of more complete property rights) can promote more efficient consumption and investment that are sustainable in an ecological sense; that is, given the current (relatively low) population growth rate, the Malthusian catastrophe can be avoided by either a shift in consumer preferences[example needed] or public policy that induces a similar shift.

According to Malthus, population doubled every 25 years (Sandmo). Population sat at less than 17 million people in the U.S in the 1850s and a century later, according to the United States Census Bureau, population had risen to 150 million. Malthus overpopulation would lead to war, famine, and diseases and in the future, society won't be able to feed every person and eventually die. Malthus theory was incorrect, however, because by the early 1900s and mid 1900s, the rise of conventional foods brought a decline to food production and efficiency increased exponentially. More supply was being produced with less work, less resources, and less time. Processed foods had much to do with it, many wives wanting to spend less time in the kitchen and instead work. This was the beginning of technological advancements adhering to food demand even in the middle of a war. Economists disregarded Malthus population theory because Malthus didn't factor in important roles society would have on economic growth. These factors concerned the society's need to improve their quality of life and there want for economic prosperity(Sandmo). Cultural shifts also had much to do with food production increase, and this put end to the population theory.[64][65][66]

Criticism

Thomas Carlyle dismissed Malthusianism as pessimistic sophistry. In Chartism (1839), he denied the possibility that "twenty-four millions" of English "working people[s]", "scattered over a hundred and eighteen thousand square miles of space", could collectively "take a resolution" to diminish the supply of labourers "and act on it". Even if they could, the ongoing influx of Irish immigrants would render their efforts redundant. Associating Malthusianism with laissez-faire, he instead advocated proactive legislation.[67] His later essay "Indian Meal" (1849) argued that maize production would remedy the failure of the potato crop as well as any prospective food shortages.[68]

Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels argued that Malthus failed to recognize a crucial difference between humans and other species. In capitalist societies, as Engels put it, scientific and technological "progress is as unlimited and at least as rapid as that of population".[69] Marx argued, even more broadly, that the growth of both a human population in toto and the "relative surplus population" within it, occurred in direct proportion to accumulation.[70]

Henry George in Progress and Poverty (1879) criticized Malthus's view that population growth was a cause of poverty, arguing that poverty was caused by the concentration of ownership of land and natural resources. George noted that humans are distinct from other species, because unlike most species humans can use their minds to leverage the reproductive forces of nature to their advantage. He wrote, "Both the jayhawk and the man eat chickens; but the more jayhawks, the fewer chickens, while the more men, the more chickens."[71]

D. E. C. Eversley observed that Malthus appeared unaware of the extent of industrialization, and either ignored or discredited the possibility that it could improve living conditions of the poorer classes.[72]

Barry Commoner believed in The Closing Circle (1971) that technological progress will eventually reduce the demographic growth and environmental damage created by civilization. He also opposed coercive measures postulated by neo-malthusian movements of his time arguing that their cost will fall disproportionately on the low-income population who are struggling already.

Ester Boserup suggested that expanding population leads to agricultural intensification and development of more productive and less labor-intensive methods of farming. Thus, human population levels determines agricultural methods, rather than agricultural methods determining population.[73]

Environmentalist founder of Ecomodernism, Stewart Brand, summarized how the Malthusian predictions of The Population Bomb and The Limits to Growth failed to materialize due to radical changes in fertility that peaked at a growth of 2 percent per year in 1963 globally and has since rapidly declined.[74]

While short-term trends, even on the scale of decades or centuries, cannot prove or disprove the existence of mechanisms promoting a Malthusian catastrophe over longer periods, due to the prosperity of a major fraction of the human population at the beginning of the 21st century, and the debatability of the predictions for ecological collapse made by Paul R. Ehrlich in the 1960s and 1970s, some people, such as economist Julian L. Simon who wrote The Ultimate Resource which it contends is human technology and medical statistician Hans Rosling questioned its inevitability.[75]

 
Wheat yields in developing countries since 1961, in kg/ha Largely due to effects of the "Green Revolution". In developing countries maize yields are also still rapidly rising.[76]

Joseph Tainter asserts that science has diminishing marginal returns[77][incomplete short citation] and that scientific progress is becoming more difficult, harder to achieve, and more costly, which may reduce efficiency of the factors that prevented the Malthusian scenarios from happening in the past.

The view that a "breakout" from the Malthusian trap has led to an era of sustained economic growth is explored by "unified growth theory".[4][78] One branch of unified growth theory is devoted to the interaction between human evolution and economic development. In particular, Oded Galor and Omer Moav argue that the forces of natural selection during the Malthusian epoch selected beneficial traits to the growth process and this growth enhancing change in the composition of human traits brought about the escape from the Malthusian trap, the demographic transition, and the take-off to modern growth.[79]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ a b c d e f g Pierre Desrochers; Christine Hoffbauer (2009). (PDF). The Electronic Journal of Sustainable Development. 1 (3). Archived from the original (PDF) on March 2, 2012. Retrieved 2010-02-01.[unreliable source?]
  2. ^ a b Meredith Marsh, Peter S. Alagona, ed. (2008). Barrons AP Human Geography 2008 Edition. Barron's Educational Series. ISBN 978-0-7641-3817-1.
  3. ^ a b Dolan, Brian (2000). Malthus, Medicine & Morality: Malthusianism after 1798. Rodopi. ISBN 978-90-420-0851-9.
  4. ^ a b Galor, Oded (2005). "From Stagnation to Growth: Unified Growth Theory". Handbook of Economic Growth. Vol. 1. Elsevier. pp. 171–293.
  5. ^ a b c Clark, Gregory (2007). A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-12135-2.
  6. ^ Julia Zinkina & Andrey Korotayev. Explosive Population Growth in Tropical Africa: Crucial Omission in Development Forecasts (Emerging Risks and Way Out). World Futures 70/2 (2014): 120–39.
  7. ^ Tisdell, Clem (1 January 2015). "The Malthusian Trap and Development in Pre-Industrial Societies: A View Differing from the Standard One" (PDF). University of Queensland. Retrieved 26 February 2017.
  8. ^ Hall, Lesley (2000). "Malthusian Mutations: The changing politics and moral meanings of birth control in Britain". Malthus, Medicine, & Morality. Clio Medica (Amsterdam, Netherlands). Vol. 59. Dolan (2000), Malthus, Medicine & Morality: Malthusianism after 1798, p. 141: Rodopi. pp. 141–163. doi:10.1163/9789004333338_008. ISBN 978-9042008519. PMID 11027073.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location (link)
  9. ^ See, for example, Ronald L. Meek, ed. (1973). . The Ramparts Press. Archived from the original on 2000-05-21.
  10. ^ Barry Commoner (May 1972). "A Bulletin Dialogue: on "The Closing Circle"  – Response". Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists: 17–56.
  11. ^ Simon, Julian L. (1980-06-27). "Resources, Population, Environment: An Oversupply of False Bad News". Science. 208 (4451): 1431–1437. Bibcode:1980Sci...208.1431S. doi:10.1126/science.7384784. ISSN 0036-8075. PMID 7384784.
  12. ^ Knudsen, Lara Reproductive Rights in a Global Context: South Africa, Uganda, Peru, Denmark, United States, Vietnam, Jordan, Vanderbilt University Press, 2006, pp. 2–4. ISBN 0-8265-1528-2, ISBN 978-0-8265-1528-5.
  13. ^ a b Kunstler, James Howard (2005). The Long Emergency. Grove Press. p. 6. ISBN 978-0-8021-4249-8.
  14. ^ Serge Luryi (May 2006). (PDF). Physics Today. 59 (5): 51. doi:10.1063/1.2216962. Archived from the original (PDF) on July 21, 2011.
  15. ^ Frank W. Elwell (2001). "Reclaiming Malthus, Keynote address to the Annual Meeting of the Anthropologists and Sociologist of Kentucky". Retrieved 2011-04-19.
  16. ^ a b Bjørn Lomborg (2002). The Skeptical Environmentalist: Measuring the Real State of the World. Cambridge University Press. p. 30. ISBN 978-0-521-01068-9.
  17. ^ Colin Fraser (February 3, 2008). "Green revolution could still blow up in our face". The Age.
  18. ^ Cristina Luiggi (2010). . The Scientist. 24 (12): 26. Archived from the original on January 1, 2011.
  19. ^ Malthus, Essay on the Principle of Population, Ch. VII.
  20. ^ Oxford World's Classics reprint
  21. ^ Engels, Fredrick (1892). The Condition of the Working-Class in England in 1844. London: Swan Sonnenschein & Co. Engels wrote that poverty and poor living conditions in 1844 had largely disappeared.
  22. ^ Fogel, Robert W. (2004). The Escape from Hunger and Premature Death, 1700–2100. London: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521808781.[page needed]
  23. ^ a b Neurath, Paul (1994). From Malthus to the Club of Rome and Back. M.E. Sharpe. p. 5. ISBN 978-1563244070.
  24. ^ Adrian Desmond (1992). The Politics of Evolution: Morphology, Medicine, and Reform in Radical London. University of Chicago Press. p. 126. ISBN 978-0226143743.
  25. ^ UMBC. June 21, 2007, at the Wayback Machine
  26. ^ David Ricardo, The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, ed. Piero Sraffa with the Collaboration of M. H. Dobb (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2005), 11 vols.
  27. ^ Charles Darwin: gentleman naturalist A biographical sketch by John van Wyhe, 2006
  28. ^ Ashraf, Quamrul; Galor, Oded (2011). "Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch". American Economic Review. 101 (5): 2003–2041. doi:10.1257/aer.101.5.2003. PMC 4262154. PMID 25506082.
  29. ^ Niyibizi, S. (1991). "Malthus, malthusianism, family planning and ONAPO". Imbonezamuryango (21): 5–9. PMID 12317099. French: le malthusianisme, le planning familial et l'ONAPO
  30. ^ "Reading: Demographic Theories | Introductory Sociology".
  31. ^ Malthus, Thomas Robert (1798). "An Essay on The Principle of Population" (PDF). Electronic Scholarly Publishing Project. Retrieved 29 March 2018.
  32. ^ Simkins, Charles (2001). "Can South Africa Avoid a Malthusian Positive Check?". Daedalus. 130 (1): 123–150. JSTOR 20027682. PMID 19068951.
  33. ^ Garcia, Cardiff. "When Keynes pondered Malthus". Financial Times. Retrieved 2019-08-10.
  34. ^ V. I. Lenin, "The Working Class and Neo-Malthusianism", 1913.
  35. ^ See, e.g., Peter Turchin 2003; Turchin and Korotayev 2006 February 29, 2012, at the Wayback Machine; Peter Turchin et al. 2007; Korotayev et al. 2006.
  36. ^ Hardin, Garrett (1968). "The Tragedy of the Commons". Science. 162 (3859): 1243–1248. Bibcode:1968Sci...162.1243H. doi:10.1126/science.162.3859.1243. PMID 17756331.
  37. ^ Wouter van Dieren, ed. (1995). Taking Nature Into Account: A Report to the Club of Rome. Springer Books. ISBN 978-0387945330.
  38. ^ Daly, Herman E. (1991). Steady-state economics (2nd ed.). Washington, D.C.: Island Press. p. xvi. ISBN 978-1559630726.
  39. ^ Dan Gardner (2010). Future Babble: Why Expert Predictions Fail – and Why We Believe Them Anyway. Toronto: McClelland and Stewart.
  40. ^ Bartlett, Al (September 1996). "The New Flat Earth Society". The Physics Teacher. 34 (6): 342–343. doi:10.1119/1.2344473. Retrieved 9 April 2013.
  41. ^ Paul R. Ehrlich; Anne H. Ehrlich (2009). "The Population Bomb Revisited" (PDF). Electronic Journal of Sustainable Development. 1 (3): 63–71. Retrieved 2010-02-01.
  42. ^ Brown, Lester (May–June 2011). . Foreign Policy. Archived from the original on 27 November 2011. Retrieved 7 June 2011.
  43. ^ Schneider-Mayerson, Matthew (2015). Peak oil : apocalyptic environmentalism and libertarian political culture. ISBN 978-0226285573. OCLC 951562545.[page needed]
  44. ^ How to feed the world in 2050
  45. ^ 2050: A third more mouths to feed
  46. ^ Climate Change and Land report
  47. ^ Climate Change Threatens the World's Food Supply, United Nations Warns
  48. ^ . Population Institute. Archived from the original on 21 June 2019. Retrieved 7 February 2021.
  49. ^ Ashraf, Quamrul; Galor, Oded (2011). "Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch". American Economic Review. 101 (5): 2003–2041. doi:10.1257/aer.101.5.2003. PMC 4262154. PMID 25506082.
  50. ^ Allen, R. C. (2001). "The Great Divergence in European Wages and Prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War". Explorations in Economic History. 38 (4): 411–447. doi:10.1006/exeh.2001.0775.
  51. ^ Overton, Mark (1996). Agricultural Revolution in England: The transformation of the agrarian economy 1500–1850. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521568593.
  52. ^ Scheidel, Walter (2017). The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century. Princeton University Press. pp. 292–293, 304. ISBN 978-0691165028.
  53. ^ Fogel, Robert W. (2004). The Escape from Hunger and Premature Death, 1700–2100. London: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521808781.[page needed]
  54. ^ Korotayev, Andrey; Zinkina, Julia (2015). "East Africa in the Malthusian Trap? A statistical analysis of financial, economic, and demographic indicators". arXiv:1503.08441 [q-fin.GN].
  55. ^ Diamond, Jared (2005). Collapse. New York: Viking. pp. 311–328. ISBN 978-0670033379.
  56. ^ Tepper, Alexander and Karol J. Borowiecki. Accounting for Breakout in Britain: The Industrial Revolution through a Malthusian Lens (2013). Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 639. Available at: https://ideas.repec.org/p/fip/fednsr/639.html
  57. ^ Voth, Hans-Joachim (2008). "Clark's intellectual Sudoku". European Review of Economic History. 12 (2): 149–155. doi:10.1017/S1361491608002190.
  58. ^ . Archived from the original on 2000-03-02.
  59. ^ Data source: http://faostat3.fao.org/download/Q/QI/E, see graph metadata for further details.
  60. ^ Hopkins, Simon (1966). A Systematic Foray into the Future. Barker Books. pp. 513–569.[ISBN missing]
  61. ^ "2004 UN Population Projections, 2004" (PDF).
  62. ^ Crombach, L. and J. Smits, "The Demographic Window of Opportunity and Economic Growth at Sub-National Level in 91 Developing Countries" Social Indicators Research, 2021
  63. ^ Arrow, K., P. Dasgupta, L. Goulder, G. Daily, P. Ehrlich, G. Heal, S. Levin, K. Mäler, S. Schneider, D. Starrett and B. Walker, "Are We Consuming Too Much" Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3), 147–172, 2004.
  64. ^ “Chapter 4.” Economics Evolving: A History of Economic Thought, by Agnar Sandmo, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 2011.
  65. ^ “New Ways to Make Food Are Coming-but Will Consumers Bite?” The Economist, The Economist Newspaper, www.economist.com/leaders/2021/10/02/new-ways-to-make-food-are-coming-but-will-consumers-bite.
  66. ^ "Major Moments in Food & Agriculture: 1900's Until Now".
  67. ^ Jordan, Alexander (19 May 2017). "Thomas Carlyle and Political Economy: The 'Dismal Science' in Context". The English Historical Review. 132 (555): 286–317. doi:10.1093/ehr/cex068. ISSN 0013-8266.
  68. ^ Cumming, Mark, ed. (2004). "Indian Meal". The Carlyle Encyclopedia. Madison and Teaneck, NJ: Fairleigh Dickinson University Press. p. 237. ISBN 978-0838637920.
  69. ^ Engels, Friedrich."Outlines of a Critique of Political Economy", Deutsch-Französische Jahrbücher, 1844, p. 1.
  70. ^ Karl Marx (transl. Ben Fowkes), Capital Volume 1, Harmondsworth, Penguin, 1976 (originally 1867), pp. 782–802.
  71. ^ "Progress and Poverty, Chapter 7". www.henrygeorge.org. Retrieved 2020-05-17.
  72. ^ Charles., Eversley, David Edward (1959). Social theories of fertility and the Malthusian debate. Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood Press. ISBN 978-0837176284. OCLC 1287575.[page needed]
  73. ^ Boserup, Ester (1966). "The Conditions of Agricultural Growth. The Economics of Agrarian Change under Population Pressure". Population. 21 (2): 402. doi:10.2307/1528968. JSTOR 1528968.
  74. ^ Brand, Stewart (2010). Whole Earth Discipline. ISBN 978-1843548164.[page needed]
  75. ^ Simon, Julian L, "More People, Greater Wealth, More Resources, Healthier Environment", Economic Affairs: J. Inst. Econ. Affairs, April 1994.
  76. ^ Fischer, R. A.; Byerlee, Eric; Edmeades, E. O. "Can Technology Deliver on the Yield Challenge to 2050" (PDF). Expert Meeting on How to Feed the World. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations: 12.
  77. ^ Tainter, Joseph. The Collapse of Complex Societies, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 2003.[ISBN missing][page needed]
  78. ^ Galor, Oded (2011). Unified Growth Theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  79. ^ Galor, Oded; Moav, Omer (2002). "Natural Selection and The Origin of Economic Growth". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117 (4): 1133–1191. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.199.2634. doi:10.1162/003355302320935007.

References

  • Korotayev, A., Malkov A., Khaltourina D. Introduction to Social Macrodynamics: Compact Macromodels of the World System Growth. Moscow: URSS, 2006. ISBN 5-484-00414-4
  • Korotayev A., Malkov A., Khaltourina D. Introduction to Social Macrodynamics: Secular Cycles and Millennial Trends. Moscow: URSS, 2006. ISBN 5-484-00559-0 See especially Chapter 2 of this book
  • Korotayev A. & Khaltourina D. Introduction to Social Macrodynamics: Secular Cycles and Millennial Trends in Africa. Moscow: URSS, 2006. ISBN 5-484-00560-4
  • Malthus, Thomas Robert (1798). "An Essay on the Principle of Population" (PDF). Electronic Scholarly Publishing Project (First ed.). London. Retrieved 29 March 2018.
  • Turchin, P., et al., eds. (2007). History & Mathematics: Historical Dynamics and Development of Complex Societies. Moscow: KomKniga. ISBN 5-484-01002-0
  • A Trap At The Escape From The Trap? Demographic-Structural Factors of Political Instability in Modern Africa and West Asia. Cliodynamics 2/2 (2011): 1–28.
  • Lueger, T. (2019). The Principle of Population and the Malthusian Trap. Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics 232, 2018. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3492297
  • Turchin, P.; Korotayev (2006). "Population Dynamics and Internal Warfare: A Reconsideration". Social Evolution & History. 5 (2): 112–47.
  • Malthus, Thomas Robert (1826). An Essay on the Principle of Population: A View of its Past and Present Effects on Human Happiness; with an Inquiry into Our Prospects Respecting the Future Removal or Mitigation of the Evils which It Occasions (Sixth ed.). London: John Murray.
  • Pomeranz, Kenneth (2000). The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy. ISBN 978-0-691-09010-8.
  • Rosen, William (2010). The Most Powerful Idea in the World. New York: Random House. ISBN 978-1-4000-6705-3.
  • A Trap At The Escape From The Trap? Demographic-Structural Factors of Political Instability in Modern Africa and West Asia. Cliodynamics 2/2 (2011): 1–28.

External links

  • . Jason Godesky. The Anthropik Network. Archived from the original on 2015-07-11.
  • Essay on life of Thomas Malthus
  • David Friedman's essay arguing against Malthus' conclusions
  • United Nations Population Division World Population Trends homepage

malthusianism, idea, that, population, growth, potentially, exponential, while, growth, food, supply, other, resources, linear, which, eventually, reduces, living, standards, point, triggering, population, this, event, called, malthusian, catastrophe, also, kn. Malthusianism is the idea that population growth is potentially exponential while the growth of the food supply or other resources is linear which eventually reduces living standards to the point of triggering a population die off This event called a Malthusian catastrophe also known as a Malthusian trap population trap Malthusian check Malthusian crisis Malthusian spectre or Malthusian crunch occurs when population growth outpaces agricultural production causing famine or war resulting in poverty and depopulation Such a catastrophe inevitably has the effect of forcing the population to correct back to a lower more easily sustainable level quite rapidly due to the potential severity and unpredictable results of the mitigating factors involved as compared to the relatively slow time scales and well understood processes governing unchecked growth or growth affected by preventive checks 1 2 Malthusianism has been linked to a variety of political and social movements but almost always refers to advocates of population control 3 Thomas Robert Malthus after whom Malthusianism is namedThese concepts derive from the political and economic thought of the Reverend Thomas Robert Malthus as laid out in his 1798 writings An Essay on the Principle of Population Malthus suggested that while technological advances could increase a society s supply of resources such as food and thereby improve the standard of living the resource abundance would enable population growth which would eventually bring the per capita supply of resources back to its original level Some economists contend that since the industrial revolution mankind has broken out of the trap 4 5 Others argue that the continuation of extreme poverty indicates that the Malthusian trap continues to operate 6 Others further argue that due to lack of food availability coupled with excessive pollution developing countries show more evidence of the trap 7 A similar more modern concept is that of human overpopulation Neo Malthusianism is the advocacy of human population planning to ensure resources and environmental integrities for current and future human populations as well as for other species 2 In Britain the term Malthusian can also refer more specifically to arguments made in favour of preventive birth control hence organizations such as the Malthusian League 8 Neo Malthusians differ from Malthus s theories mainly in their support for the use of contraception Malthus a devout Christian believed that self control i e abstinence was preferable to artificial birth control He also worried that the effect of contraceptive use would be too powerful in curbing growth conflicting with the common 18th century perspective to which Malthus himself adhered that a steadily growing population remained a necessary factor in the continuing progress of society generally Modern neo Malthusians are generally more concerned than Malthus with environmental degradation and catastrophic famine than with poverty Malthusianism has attracted criticism from diverse schools of thought including Georgists Marxists 9 and socialists 10 libertarians and free market enthusiasts 11 feminists 12 and human rights advocates characterising it as excessively pessimistic misanthropic or inhuman 13 14 3 15 Many critics believe Malthusianism has been discredited since the publication of Principle of Population often citing advances in agricultural techniques and modern reductions in human fertility 16 Some modern proponents believe that the basic concept of population growth eventually outstripping resources is still fundamentally valid and that positive checks are still likely to occur in humanity s future if no action is taken to intentionally curb population growth 17 18 better source needed In spite of the variety of criticisms against it the Malthusian argument remains a major discourse based on which national and international environmental regulations are promoted Contents 1 History 1 1 Malthus theoretical argument 1 2 Early history 1 3 Modern formulation 2 Preventive vs positive population controls 3 Neo Malthusian theory 4 Evidence in support 5 Theory of breakout via technology 5 1 Industrial Revolution 5 2 20th century 6 Criticism 7 See also 8 Notes 9 References 10 External linksHistory EditMalthus theoretical argument Edit In 1798 Thomas Malthus proposed his hypothesis in An Essay on the Principle of Population He argued that although human populations tend to increase the happiness of a nation requires a like increase in food production The happiness of a country does not depend absolutely upon its poverty or its riches upon its youth or its age upon its being thinly or fully inhabited but upon the rapidity with which it is increasing upon the degree in which the yearly increase of food approaches to the yearly increase of an unrestricted population 19 However the propensity for population increase also leads to a natural cycle of abundance and shortages We will suppose the means of subsistence in any country just equal to the easy support of its inhabitants The constant effort towards population increases the number of people before the means of subsistence are increased The food therefore which before supported seven millions must now be divided among seven millions and a half or eight millions The poor consequently must live much worse and many of them be reduced to severe distress The number of labourers also being above the proportion of the work in the market the price of labour must tend toward a decrease while the price of provisions would at the same time tend to rise The labourer therefore must work harder to earn the same as he did before During this season of distress the discouragements to marriage and the difficulty of rearing a family are so great that population is at a stand In the mean time the cheapness of labour the plenty of labourers and the necessity of an increased industry amongst them encourage cultivators to employ more labour upon their land to turn up fresh soil and to manure and improve more completely what is already in tillage till ultimately the means of subsistence become in the same proportion to the population as at the period from which we set out The situation of the labourer being then again tolerably comfortable the restraints to population are in some degree loosened and the same retrograde and progressive movements with respect to happiness are repeated Thomas Malthus 1798 An Essay on the Principle of Population Chapter II Famine seems to be the last the most dreadful resource of nature The power of population is so superior to the power of the earth to produce subsistence for man that premature death must in some shape or other visit the human race The vices of mankind are active and able ministers of depopulation They are the precursors in the great army of destruction and often finish the dreadful work themselves But should they fail in this war of extermination sickly seasons epidemics pestilence and plague advance in terrific array and sweep off their thousands and tens of thousands Should success be still incomplete gigantic inevitable famine stalks in the rear and with one mighty blow levels the population with the food of the world Thomas Malthus 1798 An Essay on the Principle of Population Chapter VII p 61 20 Malthus faced opposition from economists both during his life and since A vocal critic several decades later was Friedrich Engels 21 22 Early history Edit Malthus was not the first to outline the problems he perceived The original essay was part of an ongoing intellectual discussion at the end of the 18th century regarding the origins of poverty Principle of Population was specifically written as a rebuttal to thinkers like William Godwin and the Marquis de Condorcet and Malthus s own father who believed in the perfectibility of humanity Malthus believed humanity s ability to reproduce too rapidly doomed efforts at perfection and caused various other problems His criticism of the working class s tendency to reproduce rapidly and his belief that this rather than exploitation by capitalists led to their poverty brought widespread criticism of his theory 23 Malthusians perceived ideas of charity to the poor typified by Tory paternalism were futile as these would only result in increased numbers of the poor these theories played into Whig economic ideas exemplified by the Poor Law Amendment Act of 1834 The Act was described by opponents as a Malthusian bill designed to force the poor to emigrate to work for lower wages to live on a coarser sort of food 24 which initiated the construction of workhouses despite riots and arson Malthus revised his theories in later editions of An Essay on the Principles of Population taking a more optimistic tone although there is some scholarly debate on the extent of his revisions 1 According to Dan Ritschel of the Center for History Education at the University of Maryland Baltimore County The great Malthusian dread was that indiscriminate charity would lead to exponential growth in the population in poverty increased charges to the public purse to support this growing army of the dependent and eventually the catastrophe of national bankruptcy Though Malthusianism has since come to be identified with the issue of general over population the original Malthusian concern was more specifically with the fear of over population by the dependent poor 25 One of the earliest critics was David Ricardo Malthus immediately and correctly recognised it to be an attack on his theory of wages Ricardo and Malthus debated this in a lengthy personal correspondence 26 Another one of the 19th century critics of Malthusian theory was Karl Marx who referred to it as nothing more than a schoolboyish superficial plagiary of De Foe Sir James Steuart Townsend Franklin Wallace in Capital see Marx s footnote on Malthus from Capital reference below Marx and Engels described Malthus as a lackey of the bourgeoisie 23 Socialists and communists believed that Malthusian theories blamed the poor for their own exploitation by the capitalist classes and could be used to suppress the proletariat to an even greater degree whether through attempts to reduce fertility or by justifying the generally poor conditions of labour in the 19th century citation needed One proponent of Malthusianism was the novelist Harriet Martineau whose circle of acquaintances included Charles Darwin and the ideas of Malthus were a significant influence on the inception of Darwin s theory of evolution 27 Darwin was impressed by the idea that population growth would eventually lead to more organisms than could possibly survive in any given environment leading him to theorize that organisms with a relative advantage in the struggle for survival and reproduction would be able to pass their characteristics on to further generations Proponents of Malthusianism were in turn influenced by Darwin s ideas both schools coming to influence the field of eugenics Henry Fairfield Osborn Jr advocated humane birth selection through humane birth control in order to avoid a Malthusian catastrophe by eliminating the unfit 1 Malthusianism became a less common intellectual tradition as the 19th century advanced mostly as a result of technological increases the opening of new territory to agriculture and increasing international trade 1 Although a conservationist movement in the United States concerned itself with resource depletion and natural protection in the first half of the twentieth century Desrochers and Hoffbauer write It is probably fair to say that it was not until the publication of Osborn s and Vogt s books 1948 that a Malthusian revival took hold of a significant segment of the American population 1 Modern formulation Edit Oded Galor The modern formulation of the Malthusian theory was developed by Qumarul Ashraf and Oded Galor 28 Their theoretical structure suggests that as long as i higher income has a positive effect on reproductive success and ii land is limited factor of production then technological progress has only a temporary effect in income per capita While in the short run technological progress increases income per capita resource abundance created by technological progress would enable population growth and would eventually bring the per capita income back to its original long run level The testable prediction of the theory is that during the Malthusian epoch technologically advanced economies were characterized by higher population density but their level of income per capita was not different from the level in societies that are technologically backward Preventive vs positive population controls Edit The Malthusian catastrophe simplistically illustrated To manage population growth with respect to food supply Malthus proposed methods which he described as preventive or positive checks A preventive check according to Malthus is ways that in which nature may alter population changes Some primary examples are celibacy and chastity but also contraception which Malthus condemned as morally indefensible along with infanticide abortion and adultery 29 In other words preventive checks control the population by reducing fertility rates 30 A positive check is any event or circumstance that shortens the human life span The primary examples of this are war plague and famine 31 However poor health and economic conditions are also considered instances of positive checks 32 When these lead to high rates of premature death the result is termed a Malthusian catastrophe The adjacent diagram depicts the abstract point at which such an event would occur in terms of existing population and food supply when the population reaches or exceeds the capacity of the shared supply positive checks are forced to occur restoring balance In reality the situation would be significantly more nuanced due to complex regional and individual disparities around access to food water and other resources Neo Malthusian theory EditThis section needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed March 2016 Learn how and when to remove this template message Malthusian theory is a recurrent theme in many social science venues John Maynard Keynes in Economic Consequences of the Peace opens his polemic with a Malthusian portrayal of the political economy of Europe as unstable due to Malthusian population pressure on food supplies 33 Many models of resource depletion and scarcity are Malthusian in character the rate of energy consumption will outstrip the ability to find and produce new energy sources and so lead to a crisis citation needed In France terms such as politique malthusienne Malthusian politics refer to population control strategies The concept of restriction of the population associated with Malthus morphed in later political economic theory into the notion of restriction of production In the French sense a Malthusian economy is one in which protectionism and the formation of cartels is not only tolerated but encouraged citation needed Vladimir Lenin the leader of the Bolshevik Party and the main architect of the Soviet Union was a critic of Neo Malthusian theory but not of birth control and abortion in general 34 Neo Malthusianism is a concern that overpopulation as well as overconsumption may increase resource depletion and or environmental degradation will lead to ecological collapse or other hazards citation needed The rapid increase in the global population of the past century exemplifies Malthus s predicted population patterns it also appears to describe socio demographic dynamics of complex pre industrial societies These findings are the basis for neo Malthusian modern mathematical models of long term historical dynamics 35 There was a general neo Malthusian revival in the mid to late 1940s continuing through to the 2010s after the publication of two influential books in 1948 Fairfield Osborn s Our Plundered Planet and William Vogt s Road to Survival During that time the population of the world rose dramatically Many in environmental movements began to sound the alarm regarding the potential dangers of population growth 1 In 1968 ecologist Garrett Hardin published an influential essay in Science that drew heavily from Malthusian theory His essay The Tragedy of the Commons argued that a finite world can support only a finite population and that freedom to breed will bring ruin to all 36 The Club of Rome published a book entitled The Limits to Growth in 1972 The report and the organisation soon became central to the neo Malthusian revival 37 Paul R Ehrlich has been one of the most prominent neo Malthusians since the publication of The Population Bomb in 1968 Leading ecological economist Herman Daly has acknowledged the influence of Malthus on his concept of a steady state economy 38 Other prominent Malthusians include the Paddock brothers authors of Famine 1975 America s Decision Who Will Survive The neo Malthusian revival has drawn criticism from writers who claim the Malthusian warnings were overstated or premature because the green revolution has brought substantial increases in food production and will be able to keep up with continued population growth 16 39 Julian Simon a cornucopian has written that contrary to neo Malthusian theory Earth s carrying capacity is essentially limitless 1 Simon argues not that there is an infinite physical amount of say copper but for human purposes that amount should be treated as infinite because it is not bounded or limited in any economic sense because 1 known reserves are of uncertain quantity 2 New reserves may become available either through discovery or via the development of new extraction techniques 3 recycling 4 more efficient utilization of existing reserves e g It takes much less copper now to pass a given message than a hundred years ago The Ultimate Resource 2 1996 footnote p 62 5 development of economic equivalents e g optic fibre in the case of copper for telecommunications Responding to Simon Al Bartlett reiterates the potential of population growth as an exponential or as expressed by Malthus geometrical curve to outstrip both natural resources and human ingenuity 40 Bartlett writes and lectures particularly on energy supplies and describes the inability to understand the exponential function as the greatest shortcoming of the human race Prominent neo Malthusians such as Paul Ehrlich maintain that ultimately population growth on Earth is still too high and will eventually lead to a serious crisis 13 41 The 2007 2008 world food price crisis inspired further Malthusian arguments regarding the prospects for global food supply 42 From approximately 2004 to 2011 concerns about peak oil and other forms of resource depletion became widespread in the United States and motivated a large if short lived subculture of neo Malthusian peakists 43 A United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization study conducted in 2009 44 said that food production would have to increase by 70 over the next 40 years and food production in the developing world would need to double 45 to feed a projected population increase from 7 8 billion to 9 1 billion in 2050 The effects of global warming floods droughts and other extreme weather events are expected to negatively affect food production with different impacts in different regions 46 47 The FAO also said the use of agricultural resources for biofuels may also put downward pressure on food availability 48 The more recent emergence of bio energy with carbon capture BECCS as a prevalent negative emissions strategy for reaching Paris Climate Accord goals is another such pressure Evidence in support EditResearch indicates that technological superiority and higher land productivity had significant positive effects on population density but insignificant effects on the standard of living during the time period 1 1500 AD 49 In addition scholars have reported on the lack of a significant trend of wages in various places over the world for very long stretches of time 5 50 In Babylonia during the period 1800 to 1600 BC for example the daily wage for a common laborer was enough to buy about 15 pounds of wheat In Classical Athens in about 328 BC the corresponding wage could buy about 24 pounds of wheat In England in 1800 AD the wage was about 13 pounds of wheat 5 50 In spite of the technological developments across these societies the daily wage hardly varied In Britain between 1200 and 1800 only relatively minor fluctuations from the mean less than a factor of two in real wages occurred Following depopulation by the Black Death and other epidemics real income in Britain peaked around 1450 1500 and began declining until the British Agricultural Revolution 51 Historian Walter Scheidel posits that waves of plague following the initial outbreak of the Black Death throughout Europe had a leveling effect that changed the ratio of land to labor reducing the value of the former while boosting that of the latter which lowered economic inequality by making employers and landowners less well off while improving the economic prospects and living standards of workers He says that the observed improvement in living standards of the laboring population was rooted in the suffering and premature death of tens of millions over the course of several generations This leveling effect was reversed by a demographic recovery that resulted in renewed population pressure 52 Robert Fogel published a study of lifespans and nutrition from about a century before Malthus to the 19th century that examined European birth and death records military and other records of height and weight that found significant stunted height and low body weight indicative of chronic hunger and malnutrition He also found short lifespans that he attributed to chronic malnourishment which left people susceptible to disease Lifespans height and weight began to steadily increase in the UK and France after 1750 Fogel s findings are consistent with estimates of available food supply 53 Evidence supporting Malthusianism today can be seen in the poorer countries of the world with booming populations In East Africa specifically experts say that this area of the world has not yet escaped the Malthusian effects of population growth 54 Jared Diamond in his book Collapse 2005 for example argues that the Rwandan Genocide was brought about in part due to excessive population pressures He argues that Rwanda illustrates a case where Malthus s worst case scenario does seem to have been right Due to population pressures in Rwanda Diamond explains that the population density combined with lagging technological advancements caused its food production to not be able to keep up with its population Diamond claims that this environment is what caused the mass killings of Tutsi and even some Hutu Rwandans 55 The genocide in this instance provides a potential example of a Malthusian trap Theory of breakout via technology EditSee also Industrial Revolution Causes and British Agricultural Revolution Industrial Revolution Edit Some researchers contend that a British breakout occurred due to technological improvements and structural change away from agricultural production while coal capital and trade played a minor role 56 Economic historian Gregory Clark building on the insights of Galor and Moav 57 has argued in his book A Farewell to Alms that a British breakout may have been caused by differences in reproduction rates among the rich and the poor the rich were more likely to marry tended to have more children and in a society where disease was rampant and childhood mortality at times approached 50 upper class children were more likely to survive to adulthood than poor children This in turn led to sustained downward mobility the descendants of the rich becoming more populous in British society and spreading middle class values such as hard work and literacy 20th century Edit Global deaths in conflicts since the year 1400 A chart of estimated annual growth rates in world population 1800 2005 Rates before 1950 are annualized historical estimates from the US Census Bureau 58 Red USCB projections to 2025 Growth in food production has historically been greater than the population growth Food per person increased since 1961 The graph runs up to slightly past 2010 59 After World War II mechanized agriculture produced a dramatic increase in productivity of agriculture and the Green Revolution greatly increased crop yields expanding the world s food supply while lowering food prices In response the growth rate of the world s population accelerated rapidly resulting in predictions by Paul R Ehrlich Simon Hopkins 60 and many others of an imminent Malthusian catastrophe However populations of most developed countries grew slowly enough to be outpaced by gains in productivity By the early 21st century many technologically developed countries had passed through the demographic transition a complex social development encompassing a drop in total fertility rates in response to various fertility factors including lower infant mortality increased urbanization and a wider availability of effective birth control On the assumption that the demographic transition is now spreading from the developed countries to less developed countries the United Nations Population Fund estimates that human population may peak in the late 21st century rather than continue to grow until it has exhausted available resources 61 Recent empirical research corroborates this assumption for most of the less developed countries with the exception of most of Sub Saharan Africa 62 A 2004 study by a group of prominent economists and ecologists including Kenneth Arrow and Paul Ehrlich 63 suggests that the central concerns regarding sustainability have shifted from population growth to the consumption savings ratio due to shifts in population growth rates since the 1970s Empirical estimates show that public policy taxes or the establishment of more complete property rights can promote more efficient consumption and investment that are sustainable in an ecological sense that is given the current relatively low population growth rate the Malthusian catastrophe can be avoided by either a shift in consumer preferences example needed or public policy that induces a similar shift According to Malthus population doubled every 25 years Sandmo Population sat at less than 17 million people in the U S in the 1850s and a century later according to the United States Census Bureau population had risen to 150 million Malthus overpopulation would lead to war famine and diseases and in the future society won t be able to feed every person and eventually die Malthus theory was incorrect however because by the early 1900s and mid 1900s the rise of conventional foods brought a decline to food production and efficiency increased exponentially More supply was being produced with less work less resources and less time Processed foods had much to do with it many wives wanting to spend less time in the kitchen and instead work This was the beginning of technological advancements adhering to food demand even in the middle of a war Economists disregarded Malthus population theory because Malthus didn t factor in important roles society would have on economic growth These factors concerned the society s need to improve their quality of life and there want for economic prosperity Sandmo Cultural shifts also had much to do with food production increase and this put end to the population theory 64 65 66 Criticism EditSee also Club of Rome Critics and Limits to Growth CriticismThomas Carlyle dismissed Malthusianism as pessimistic sophistry In Chartism 1839 he denied the possibility that twenty four millions of English working people s scattered over a hundred and eighteen thousand square miles of space could collectively take a resolution to diminish the supply of labourers and act on it Even if they could the ongoing influx of Irish immigrants would render their efforts redundant Associating Malthusianism with laissez faire he instead advocated proactive legislation 67 His later essay Indian Meal 1849 argued that maize production would remedy the failure of the potato crop as well as any prospective food shortages 68 Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels argued that Malthus failed to recognize a crucial difference between humans and other species In capitalist societies as Engels put it scientific and technological progress is as unlimited and at least as rapid as that of population 69 Marx argued even more broadly that the growth of both a human population in toto and the relative surplus population within it occurred in direct proportion to accumulation 70 Henry George in Progress and Poverty 1879 criticized Malthus s view that population growth was a cause of poverty arguing that poverty was caused by the concentration of ownership of land and natural resources George noted that humans are distinct from other species because unlike most species humans can use their minds to leverage the reproductive forces of nature to their advantage He wrote Both the jayhawk and the man eat chickens but the more jayhawks the fewer chickens while the more men the more chickens 71 D E C Eversley observed that Malthus appeared unaware of the extent of industrialization and either ignored or discredited the possibility that it could improve living conditions of the poorer classes 72 Barry Commoner believed in The Closing Circle 1971 that technological progress will eventually reduce the demographic growth and environmental damage created by civilization He also opposed coercive measures postulated by neo malthusian movements of his time arguing that their cost will fall disproportionately on the low income population who are struggling already Ester Boserup suggested that expanding population leads to agricultural intensification and development of more productive and less labor intensive methods of farming Thus human population levels determines agricultural methods rather than agricultural methods determining population 73 Environmentalist founder of Ecomodernism Stewart Brand summarized how the Malthusian predictions of The Population Bomb and The Limits to Growth failed to materialize due to radical changes in fertility that peaked at a growth of 2 percent per year in 1963 globally and has since rapidly declined 74 While short term trends even on the scale of decades or centuries cannot prove or disprove the existence of mechanisms promoting a Malthusian catastrophe over longer periods due to the prosperity of a major fraction of the human population at the beginning of the 21st century and the debatability of the predictions for ecological collapse made by Paul R Ehrlich in the 1960s and 1970s some people such as economist Julian L Simon who wrote The Ultimate Resource which it contends is human technology and medical statistician Hans Rosling questioned its inevitability 75 See also Simon Ehrlich wager The Ultimate Resource and Factfulness Ten Reasons We re Wrong About the World and Why Things Are Better Than You Think Wheat yields in developing countries since 1961 in kg ha Largely due to effects of the Green Revolution In developing countries maize yields are also still rapidly rising 76 Joseph Tainter asserts that science has diminishing marginal returns 77 incomplete short citation and that scientific progress is becoming more difficult harder to achieve and more costly which may reduce efficiency of the factors that prevented the Malthusian scenarios from happening in the past The view that a breakout from the Malthusian trap has led to an era of sustained economic growth is explored by unified growth theory 4 78 One branch of unified growth theory is devoted to the interaction between human evolution and economic development In particular Oded Galor and Omer Moav argue that the forces of natural selection during the Malthusian epoch selected beneficial traits to the growth process and this growth enhancing change in the composition of human traits brought about the escape from the Malthusian trap the demographic transition and the take off to modern growth 79 See also Edit Economics portalAntinatalism Cliodynamics Conservative Party UK Demographic trap Food Race History of economic thought Jevons paradox John B Calhoun National Security Study Memorandum 200 a U S National Security Council Study advocating population reduction in selected countries to advance U S interests Overshoot population Political demography Subsistence theory of wagesNotes Edit a b c d e f g Pierre Desrochers Christine Hoffbauer 2009 The Post War Intellectual Roots of the Population Bomb PDF The Electronic Journal of Sustainable Development 1 3 Archived from the original PDF on March 2 2012 Retrieved 2010 02 01 unreliable source a b Meredith Marsh Peter S Alagona ed 2008 Barrons AP Human Geography 2008 Edition Barron s Educational Series ISBN 978 0 7641 3817 1 a b Dolan Brian 2000 Malthus Medicine amp Morality Malthusianism after 1798 Rodopi ISBN 978 90 420 0851 9 a b Galor Oded 2005 From Stagnation to Growth Unified Growth Theory Handbook of Economic Growth Vol 1 Elsevier pp 171 293 a b c Clark Gregory 2007 A Farewell to Alms A Brief Economic History of the World Princeton University Press ISBN 978 0 691 12135 2 Julia Zinkina amp Andrey Korotayev Explosive Population Growth in Tropical Africa Crucial Omission in Development Forecasts Emerging Risks and Way Out World Futures 70 2 2014 120 39 Tisdell Clem 1 January 2015 The Malthusian Trap and Development in Pre Industrial Societies A View Differing from the Standard One PDF University of Queensland Retrieved 26 February 2017 Hall Lesley 2000 Malthusian Mutations The changing politics and moral meanings of birth control in Britain Malthus Medicine amp Morality Clio Medica Amsterdam Netherlands Vol 59 Dolan 2000 Malthus Medicine amp Morality Malthusianism after 1798 p 141 Rodopi pp 141 163 doi 10 1163 9789004333338 008 ISBN 978 9042008519 PMID 11027073 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint location link See for example Ronald L Meek ed 1973 Marx and Engels on the Population Bomb The Ramparts Press Archived from the original on 2000 05 21 Barry Commoner May 1972 A Bulletin Dialogue on The Closing Circle Response Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists 17 56 Simon Julian L 1980 06 27 Resources Population Environment An Oversupply of False Bad News Science 208 4451 1431 1437 Bibcode 1980Sci 208 1431S doi 10 1126 science 7384784 ISSN 0036 8075 PMID 7384784 Knudsen Lara Reproductive Rights in a Global Context South Africa Uganda Peru Denmark United States Vietnam Jordan Vanderbilt University Press 2006 pp 2 4 ISBN 0 8265 1528 2 ISBN 978 0 8265 1528 5 a b Kunstler James Howard 2005 The Long Emergency Grove Press p 6 ISBN 978 0 8021 4249 8 Serge Luryi May 2006 Physics Philosophy and Ecology PDF Physics Today 59 5 51 doi 10 1063 1 2216962 Archived from the original PDF on July 21 2011 Frank W Elwell 2001 Reclaiming Malthus Keynote address to the Annual Meeting of the Anthropologists and Sociologist of Kentucky Retrieved 2011 04 19 a b Bjorn Lomborg 2002 The Skeptical Environmentalist Measuring the Real State of the World Cambridge University Press p 30 ISBN 978 0 521 01068 9 Colin Fraser February 3 2008 Green revolution could still blow up in our face The Age Cristina Luiggi 2010 Still Ticking The Scientist 24 12 26 Archived from the original on January 1 2011 Malthus Essay on the Principle of Population Ch VII Oxford World s Classics reprint Engels Fredrick 1892 The Condition of the Working Class in England in 1844 London Swan Sonnenschein amp Co Engels wrote that poverty and poor living conditions in 1844 had largely disappeared Fogel Robert W 2004 The Escape from Hunger and Premature Death 1700 2100 London Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0521808781 page needed a b Neurath Paul 1994 From Malthus to the Club of Rome and Back M E Sharpe p 5 ISBN 978 1563244070 Adrian Desmond 1992 The Politics of Evolution Morphology Medicine and Reform in Radical London University of Chicago Press p 126 ISBN 978 0226143743 UMBC Archived June 21 2007 at the Wayback Machine David Ricardo The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo ed Piero Sraffa with the Collaboration of M H Dobb Indianapolis Liberty Fund 2005 11 vols Charles Darwin gentleman naturalist A biographical sketch by John van Wyhe 2006 Ashraf Quamrul Galor Oded 2011 Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch American Economic Review 101 5 2003 2041 doi 10 1257 aer 101 5 2003 PMC 4262154 PMID 25506082 Niyibizi S 1991 Malthus malthusianism family planning and ONAPO Imbonezamuryango 21 5 9 PMID 12317099 French le malthusianisme le planning familial et l ONAPO Reading Demographic Theories Introductory Sociology Malthus Thomas Robert 1798 An Essay on The Principle of Population PDF Electronic Scholarly Publishing Project Retrieved 29 March 2018 Simkins Charles 2001 Can South Africa Avoid a Malthusian Positive Check Daedalus 130 1 123 150 JSTOR 20027682 PMID 19068951 Garcia Cardiff When Keynes pondered Malthus Financial Times Retrieved 2019 08 10 V I Lenin The Working Class and Neo Malthusianism 1913 See e g Peter Turchin 2003 Turchin and Korotayev 2006 Archived February 29 2012 at the Wayback Machine Peter Turchin et al 2007 Korotayev et al 2006 Hardin Garrett 1968 The Tragedy of the Commons Science 162 3859 1243 1248 Bibcode 1968Sci 162 1243H doi 10 1126 science 162 3859 1243 PMID 17756331 Wouter van Dieren ed 1995 Taking Nature Into Account A Report to the Club of Rome Springer Books ISBN 978 0387945330 Daly Herman E 1991 Steady state economics 2nd ed Washington D C Island Press p xvi ISBN 978 1559630726 Dan Gardner 2010 Future Babble Why Expert Predictions Fail and Why We Believe Them Anyway Toronto McClelland and Stewart Bartlett Al September 1996 The New Flat Earth Society The Physics Teacher 34 6 342 343 doi 10 1119 1 2344473 Retrieved 9 April 2013 Paul R Ehrlich Anne H Ehrlich 2009 The Population Bomb Revisited PDF Electronic Journal of Sustainable Development 1 3 63 71 Retrieved 2010 02 01 Brown Lester May June 2011 The New Geopolitics of Food Foreign Policy Archived from the original on 27 November 2011 Retrieved 7 June 2011 Schneider Mayerson Matthew 2015 Peak oil apocalyptic environmentalism and libertarian political culture ISBN 978 0226285573 OCLC 951562545 page needed How to feed the world in 2050 2050 A third more mouths to feed Climate Change and Land report Climate Change Threatens the World s Food Supply United Nations Warns FAO says Food Production must Rise by 70 Population Institute Archived from the original on 21 June 2019 Retrieved 7 February 2021 Ashraf Quamrul Galor Oded 2011 Dynamics and Stagnation in the Malthusian Epoch American Economic Review 101 5 2003 2041 doi 10 1257 aer 101 5 2003 PMC 4262154 PMID 25506082 Allen R C 2001 The Great Divergence in European Wages and Prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War Explorations in Economic History 38 4 411 447 doi 10 1006 exeh 2001 0775 Overton Mark 1996 Agricultural Revolution in England The transformation of the agrarian economy 1500 1850 Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0521568593 Scheidel Walter 2017 The Great Leveler Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty First Century Princeton University Press pp 292 293 304 ISBN 978 0691165028 Fogel Robert W 2004 The Escape from Hunger and Premature Death 1700 2100 London Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0521808781 page needed Korotayev Andrey Zinkina Julia 2015 East Africa in the Malthusian Trap A statistical analysis of financial economic and demographic indicators arXiv 1503 08441 q fin GN Diamond Jared 2005 Collapse New York Viking pp 311 328 ISBN 978 0670033379 Tepper Alexander and Karol J Borowiecki Accounting for Breakout in Britain The Industrial Revolution through a Malthusian Lens 2013 Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 639 Available at https ideas repec org p fip fednsr 639 html Voth Hans Joachim 2008 Clark s intellectual Sudoku European Review of Economic History 12 2 149 155 doi 10 1017 S1361491608002190 Historical Estimates of World Population Archived from the original on 2000 03 02 Data source http faostat3 fao org download Q QI E see graph metadata for further details Hopkins Simon 1966 A Systematic Foray into the Future Barker Books pp 513 569 ISBN missing 2004 UN Population Projections 2004 PDF Crombach L and J Smits The Demographic Window of Opportunity and Economic Growth at Sub National Level in 91 Developing Countries Social Indicators Research 2021 Arrow K P Dasgupta L Goulder G Daily P Ehrlich G Heal S Levin K Maler S Schneider D Starrett and B Walker Are We Consuming Too Much Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 3 147 172 2004 Chapter 4 Economics Evolving A History of Economic Thought by Agnar Sandmo Princeton University Press Princeton NJ 2011 New Ways to Make Food Are Coming but Will Consumers Bite The Economist The Economist Newspaper www economist com leaders 2021 10 02 new ways to make food are coming but will consumers bite Major Moments in Food amp Agriculture 1900 s Until Now Jordan Alexander 19 May 2017 Thomas Carlyle and Political Economy The Dismal Science in Context The English Historical Review 132 555 286 317 doi 10 1093 ehr cex068 ISSN 0013 8266 Cumming Mark ed 2004 Indian Meal The Carlyle Encyclopedia Madison and Teaneck NJ Fairleigh Dickinson University Press p 237 ISBN 978 0838637920 Engels Friedrich Outlines of a Critique of Political Economy Deutsch Franzosische Jahrbucher 1844 p 1 Karl Marx transl Ben Fowkes Capital Volume 1 Harmondsworth Penguin 1976 originally 1867 pp 782 802 Progress and Poverty Chapter 7 www henrygeorge org Retrieved 2020 05 17 Charles Eversley David Edward 1959 Social theories of fertility and the Malthusian debate Westport Connecticut Greenwood Press ISBN 978 0837176284 OCLC 1287575 page needed Boserup Ester 1966 The Conditions of Agricultural Growth The Economics of Agrarian Change under Population Pressure Population 21 2 402 doi 10 2307 1528968 JSTOR 1528968 Brand Stewart 2010 Whole Earth Discipline ISBN 978 1843548164 page needed Simon Julian L More People Greater Wealth More Resources Healthier Environment Economic Affairs J Inst Econ Affairs April 1994 Fischer R A Byerlee Eric Edmeades E O Can Technology Deliver on the Yield Challenge to 2050 PDF Expert Meeting on How to Feed the World Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations 12 Tainter Joseph The Collapse of Complex Societies Cambridge University Press Cambridge UK 2003 ISBN missing page needed Galor Oded 2011 Unified Growth Theory Princeton Princeton University Press Galor Oded Moav Omer 2002 Natural Selection and The Origin of Economic Growth Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 4 1133 1191 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 199 2634 doi 10 1162 003355302320935007 References EditKorotayev A Malkov A Khaltourina D Introduction to Social Macrodynamics Compact Macromodels of the World System Growth Moscow URSS 2006 ISBN 5 484 00414 4 Korotayev A Malkov A Khaltourina D Introduction to Social Macrodynamics Secular Cycles and Millennial Trends Moscow URSS 2006 ISBN 5 484 00559 0 See especially Chapter 2 of this book Korotayev A amp Khaltourina D Introduction to Social Macrodynamics Secular Cycles and Millennial Trends in Africa Moscow URSS 2006 ISBN 5 484 00560 4 Malthus Thomas Robert 1798 An Essay on the Principle of Population PDF Electronic Scholarly Publishing Project First ed London Retrieved 29 March 2018 Turchin P et al eds 2007 History amp Mathematics Historical Dynamics and Development of Complex Societies Moscow KomKniga ISBN 5 484 01002 0 A Trap At The Escape From The Trap Demographic Structural Factors of Political Instability in Modern Africa and West Asia Cliodynamics 2 2 2011 1 28 Lueger T 2019 The Principle of Population and the Malthusian Trap Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics 232 2018 https papers ssrn com sol3 papers cfm abstract id 3492297 Turchin P Korotayev 2006 Population Dynamics and Internal Warfare A Reconsideration Social Evolution amp History 5 2 112 47 Malthus Thomas Robert 1826 An Essay on the Principle of Population A View of its Past and Present Effects on Human Happiness with an Inquiry into Our Prospects Respecting the Future Removal or Mitigation of the Evils which It Occasions Sixth ed London John Murray Pomeranz Kenneth 2000 The Great Divergence China Europe and the Making of the Modern World Economy ISBN 978 0 691 09010 8 Rosen William 2010 The Most Powerful Idea in the World New York Random House ISBN 978 1 4000 6705 3 A Trap At The Escape From The Trap Demographic Structural Factors of Political Instability in Modern Africa and West Asia Cliodynamics 2 2 2011 1 28 External links Edit The Opposite of Malthus Jason Godesky The Anthropik Network Archived from the original on 2015 07 11 Essay on life of Thomas Malthus Malthus Essay on the Principle of Population David Friedman s essay arguing against Malthus conclusions United Nations Population Division World Population Trends homepage Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Malthusianism amp oldid 1133961650, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.