fbpx
Wikipedia

Jevons paradox

In economics, the Jevons paradox (/ˈɛvənz/; sometimes Jevons effect) occurs when technological progress or government policy increases the efficiency with which a resource is used (reducing the amount necessary for any one use), but the falling cost of use induces increases in demand enough that resource use is increased, rather than reduced.[1][2][3] Governments typically assume that efficiency gains will lower resource consumption, ignoring the possibility of the paradox arising.[4]

Coal-burning factories in 19th-century Manchester, England. Improved technology allowed coal to fuel the Industrial Revolution, greatly increasing the consumption of coal.

In 1865, the English economist William Stanley Jevons observed that technological improvements that increased the efficiency of coal use led to the increased consumption of coal in a wide range of industries. He argued that, contrary to common intuition, technological progress could not be relied upon to reduce fuel consumption.[5][6]

The issue has been re-examined by modern economists studying consumption rebound effects from improved energy efficiency. In addition to reducing the amount needed for a given use, improved efficiency also lowers the relative cost of using a resource, which increases the quantity demanded. This may counteract (to some extent) the reduction in use from improved efficiency. Additionally, improved efficiency increases real incomes and accelerates economic growth, further increasing the demand for resources. The Jevons paradox occurs when the effect from increased demand predominates, and the improved efficiency results in a faster rate of resource utilization.[6]

Considerable debate exists about the size of the rebound in energy efficiency and the relevance of the Jevons paradox to energy conservation. Some dismiss the effect, while others worry that it may be self-defeating to pursue sustainability by increasing energy efficiency.[4] Some environmental economists have proposed that efficiency gains be coupled with conservation policies that keep the cost of use the same (or higher) to avoid the Jevons paradox.[7] Conservation policies that increase cost of use (such as cap and trade or green taxes) can be used to control the rebound effect.[8]

History edit

 
William Stanley Jevons, after whom the effect is named

The Jevons paradox was first described by the English economist William Stanley Jevons in his 1865 book The Coal Question. Jevons observed that England's consumption of coal soared after James Watt introduced the Watt steam engine, which greatly improved the efficiency of the coal-fired steam engine from Thomas Newcomen's earlier design. Watt's innovations made coal a more cost-effective power source, leading to the increased use of the steam engine in a wide range of industries. This in turn increased total coal consumption, even as the amount of coal required for any particular application fell. Jevons argued that improvements in fuel efficiency tend to increase (rather than decrease) fuel use, writing: "It is a confusion of ideas to suppose that the economical use of fuel is equivalent to diminished consumption. The very contrary is the truth."[5]

At that time, many in Britain worried that coal reserves were rapidly dwindling, but some experts opined that improving technology would reduce coal consumption. Jevons argued that this view was incorrect, as further increases in efficiency would tend to increase the use of coal. Hence, improving technology would tend to increase the rate at which England's coal deposits were being depleted, and could not be relied upon to solve the problem.[5][6]

Although Jevons originally focused on coal, the concept has since been extended to other resources, e.g., water usage.[9] The Jevons paradox is also found in socio-hydrology, in the safe development paradox called the reservoir effect, where construction of a reservoir to reduce the risk of water shortage can instead exacerbate that risk, as increased water availability leads to more development and hence more water consumption.[10]

Cause edit

 
Elastic Demand: A 20% increase in efficiency causes a 40% increase in travel. Fuel consumption increases and the Jevons paradox occurs.
 
Inelastic Demand: A 20% increase in efficiency causes a 10% increase in travel. The Jevons paradox does not occur.

Economists have observed that consumers tend to travel more when their cars are more fuel efficient, causing a 'rebound' in the demand for fuel.[11] An increase in the efficiency with which a resource (e.g. fuel) is used causes a decrease in the cost of using that resource when measured in terms of what it can achieve (e.g. travel). Generally speaking, a decrease in the cost (or price) of a good or service will increase the quantity demanded (the law of demand). With a lower cost for travel, consumers will travel more, increasing the demand for fuel. This increase in demand is known as the rebound effect, and it may or may not be large enough to offset the original drop in fuel use from the increased efficiency. The Jevons paradox occurs when the rebound effect is greater than 100%, exceeding the original efficiency gains.[6]

The size of the direct rebound effect is dependent on the price elasticity of demand for the good.[12] In a perfectly competitive market where fuel is the sole input used, if the price of fuel remains constant but efficiency is doubled, the effective price of travel would be halved (twice as much travel can be purchased). If in response, the amount of travel purchased more than doubles (i.e. demand is price elastic), then fuel consumption would increase, and the Jevons paradox would occur. If demand is price inelastic, the amount of travel purchased would less than double, and fuel consumption would decrease. However, goods and services generally use more than one type of input (e.g. fuel, labour, machinery), and other factors besides input cost may also affect price. These factors tend to reduce the rebound effect, making the Jevons paradox less likely to occur.[6]

Khazzoom–Brookes postulate edit

In the 1980s, economists Daniel Khazzoom and Leonard Brookes revisited the Jevons paradox for the case of society's energy use. Brookes, then chief economist at the UK Atomic Energy Authority, argued that attempts to reduce energy consumption by increasing energy efficiency would simply raise demand for energy in the economy as a whole. Khazzoom focused on the narrower point that the potential for rebound was ignored in mandatory performance standards for domestic appliances being set by the California Energy Commission.[13][14]

In 1992, the economist Harry Saunders dubbed the hypothesis that improvements in energy efficiency work to increase (rather than decrease) energy consumption the Khazzoom–Brookes postulate, and argued that the hypothesis is broadly supported by neoclassical growth theory (the mainstream economic theory of capital accumulation, technological progress and long-run economic growth). Saunders showed that the Khazzoom–Brookes postulate occurs in the neoclassical growth model under a wide range of assumptions.[13][15]

According to Saunders, increased energy efficiency tends to increase energy consumption by two means. First, increased energy efficiency makes the use of energy relatively cheaper, thus encouraging increased use (the direct rebound effect). Second, increased energy efficiency increases real incomes and leads to increased economic growth, which pulls up energy use for the whole economy. At the microeconomic level (looking at an individual market), even with the rebound effect, improvements in energy efficiency usually result in reduced energy consumption.[16] That is, the rebound effect is usually less than 100%. However, at the macroeconomic level, more efficient (and hence comparatively cheaper) energy leads to faster economic growth, which increases energy use throughout the economy. Saunders argued that taking into account both microeconomic and macroeconomic effects, the technological progress that improves energy efficiency will tend to increase overall energy use.[13]

Energy conservation policy edit

Jevons warned that fuel efficiency gains tend to increase fuel use. However, this does not imply that improved fuel efficiency is worthless if the Jevons paradox occurs; higher fuel efficiency enables greater production and a higher material quality of life.[17] For example, a more efficient steam engine allowed the cheaper transport of goods and people that contributed to the Industrial Revolution. Nonetheless, if the Khazzoom–Brookes postulate is correct, increased fuel efficiency, by itself, will not reduce the rate of depletion of fossil fuels.[13]

There is considerable debate about whether the Khazzoom-Brookes Postulate is correct, and of the relevance of the Jevons paradox to energy conservation policy. Most governments, environmentalists and NGOs pursue policies that improve efficiency, holding that these policies will lower resource consumption and reduce environmental problems. Others, including many environmental economists, doubt this 'efficiency strategy' towards sustainability, and worry that efficiency gains may in fact lead to higher production and consumption. They hold that for resource use to fall, efficiency gains should be coupled with other policies that limit resource use.[4][15][18] However, other environmental economists argue that, while the Jevons paradox may occur in some situations, the empirical evidence for its widespread applicability is limited.[19]

The Jevons paradox is sometimes used to argue that energy conservation efforts are futile, for example, that more efficient use of oil will lead to increased demand, and will not slow the arrival or the effects of peak oil. This argument is usually presented as a reason not to enact environmental policies or pursue fuel efficiency (e.g. if cars are more efficient, it will simply lead to more driving).[20][21] Several points have been raised against this argument. First, in the context of a mature market such as for oil in developed countries, the direct rebound effect is usually small, and so increased fuel efficiency usually reduces resource use, other conditions remaining constant.[11][16][22] Second, even if increased efficiency does not reduce the total amount of fuel used, there remain other benefits associated with improved efficiency. For example, increased fuel efficiency may mitigate the price increases, shortages and disruptions in the global economy associated with crude oil depletion.[23] Third, environmental economists have pointed out that fuel use will unambiguously decrease if increased efficiency is coupled with an intervention (e.g. a fuel tax) that keeps the cost of fuel use the same or higher.[7]

The Jevons paradox indicates that increased efficiency by itself may not reduce fuel use, and that sustainable energy policy must rely on other types of government interventions as well.[8] As the imposition of conservation standards or other government interventions that increase cost-of-use do not display the Jevons paradox, they can be used to control the rebound effect.[8] To ensure that efficiency-enhancing technological improvements reduce fuel use, efficiency gains can be paired with government intervention that reduces demand (e.g. green taxes, cap and trade, or higher emissions standards). The ecological economists Mathis Wackernagel and William Rees have suggested that any cost savings from efficiency gains be "taxed away or otherwise removed from further economic circulation. Preferably they should be captured for reinvestment in natural capital rehabilitation."[7] By mitigating the economic effects of government interventions designed to promote ecologically sustainable activities, efficiency-improving technological progress may make the imposition of these interventions more palatable, and more likely to be implemented.[24][25][26]

Other examples edit

Agriculture edit

Increasing the yield of a crop, such as wheat, for a given area will reduce the area required to achieve the same total yield. However, increasing efficiency may make it more profitable to grow wheat and lead farmers to convert land to the production of wheat, thereby increasing land use instead.[27]

See also edit

  • Andy and Bill's law, new software will always consume any increase in computing power that new hardware can provide
  • Downs–Thomson paradox, increasing road capacity can make traffic congestion worse
  • Tragedy of the commons, a phenomenon in which common resources to which access is not regulated tend to become depleted
  • Wirth's law, faster hardware can trigger the development of less-efficient software
  • Dutch Disease, strong revenue from a dominant sector renders other sectors uncompetitive and starves them

References edit

  1. ^ Bauer, Diana; Papp, Kathryn (18 March 2009). "Book Review Perspectives: The Jevons Paradox and the Myth of Resource Efficiency Improvements". Sustainability: Science, Practice, & Policy. 5 (1). doi:10.1080/15487733.2009.11908028.
  2. ^ York, Richard; McGee, Julius Alexander (2 January 2016). "Understanding the Jevons paradox". Environmental Sociology. 2 (1): 77–87. doi:10.1080/23251042.2015.1106060. S2CID 156762601.
  3. ^ York, Richard (2006). "Ecological paradoxes: William Stanley Jevons and the paperless office" (PDF). Human Ecology Review. 13 (2): 143–147. Retrieved 2015-05-05.
  4. ^ a b c Alcott, Blake (July 2005). "Jevons' paradox". Ecological Economics. 54 (1): 9–21. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2005.03.020. hdl:1942/22574.
  5. ^ a b c Jevons, William Stanley (1866). "VII". The Coal Question (2nd ed.). London: Macmillan and Company. OCLC 464772008. Retrieved 2008-07-21.
  6. ^ a b c d e Alcott, Blake (2008). "Historical Overview of the Jevons paradox in the Literature". In JM Polimeni; K Mayumi; M Giampietro (eds.). The Jevons Paradox and the Myth of Resource Efficiency Improvements. Earthscan. pp. 7–78. ISBN 978-1-84407-462-4.
  7. ^ a b c Wackernagel, Mathis; Rees, William (1997). "Perceptual and structural barriers to investing in natural capital: Economics from an ecological footprint perspective". Ecological Economics. 20 (3): 3–24. doi:10.1016/S0921-8009(96)00077-8.
  8. ^ a b c Freire-González, Jaume; Puig-Ventosa, Ignasi (2015). "Energy Efficiency Policies and the Jevons Paradox". International Journal of Energy Economics and Policy. 5 (1): 69–79. Retrieved 29 May 2015.
  9. ^ Dumont, A.; Mayor, B.; López-Gunn, E. (2013). "Is the Rebound Effect or Jevons Paradox a Useful Concept for Better Management of Water Resources? Insights from the Irrigation Modernisation Process in Spain". Aquatic Procedia. 1: 64–76. doi:10.1016/j.aqpro.2013.07.006.
  10. ^ Di Baldassarre, Giuliano; Wanders, Niko; AghaKouchak, Amir; Kuil, Linda; Rangecroft, Sally; Veldkamp, Ted I. E.; Garcia, Margaret; van Oel, Pieter R.; Breinl, Korbinian; Van Loon, Anne F. (November 2018). "Water shortages worsened by reservoir effects". Nature Sustainability. 1 (11): 617–622. doi:10.1038/s41893-018-0159-0. ISSN 2398-9629. S2CID 134508048.
  11. ^ a b Small, Kenneth A.; Kurt Van Dender (2005-09-21). "The Effect of Improved Fuel Economy on Vehicle Miles Traveled: Estimating the Rebound Effect Using U.S. State Data, 1966–2001". Policy and Economics. Retrieved 2010-09-01.
  12. ^ Chan, Nathan W.; Gillingham, Kenneth (1 March 2015). "The Microeconomic Theory of the Rebound Effect and Its Welfare Implications". Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists. 2 (1): 133–159. doi:10.1086/680256. ISSN 2333-5955. S2CID 3681642.
  13. ^ a b c d Saunders, Harry D. (October 1992). "The Khazzoom-Brookes Postulate and Neoclassical Growth". The Energy Journal. 13 (4): 131–148. doi:10.5547/ISSN0195-6574-EJ-Vol13-No4-7. JSTOR 41322471.
  14. ^ Herring, Horace (19 July 1999). "Does energy efficiency save energy? The debate and its consequences". Applied Energy. 63 (3): 209–226. doi:10.1016/S0306-2619(99)00030-6. ISSN 0306-2619.
  15. ^ a b Sorrell, Steve (April 2009). "Jevons' Paradox revisited: The evidence for backfire from improved energy efficiency". Energy Policy. 37 (4): 1456–1469. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2008.12.003.
  16. ^ a b Greening, Lorna; David L. Greene; Carmen Difiglio (2000). "Energy efficiency and consumption—the rebound effect—a survey". Energy Policy. 28 (6–7): 389–401. doi:10.1016/S0301-4215(00)00021-5.
  17. ^ Ryan, Lisa; Campbell, Nina (2012). "Spreading the net: the multiple benefits of energy efficiency improvements". IEA Energy Papers. doi:10.1787/20792581. Retrieved 5 June 2015.
  18. ^ Owen, David (December 20, 2010). "Annals of Environmentalism: The Efficiency Dilemma". The New Yorker. pp. 78–.
  19. ^ Gillingham, Kenneth; Kotchen, Matthew J.; Rapson, David S.; Wagner, Gernot (23 January 2013). "Energy policy: The rebound effect is overplayed". Nature. 493 (7433): 475–476. Bibcode:2013Natur.493..475G. doi:10.1038/493475a. ISSN 0028-0836. PMID 23344343. S2CID 3220092.
  20. ^ Potter, Andrew (2007-02-13). . Maclean's. 120 (5): 14. Archived from the original on 2007-12-14. Retrieved 2010-09-01.
  21. ^ Strassel, Kimberley A. (2001-05-17). . The Wall Street Journal. Archived from the original on 2005-11-13. Retrieved 2009-07-31.
  22. ^ Gottron, Frank (2001-07-30). "Energy Efficiency and the Rebound Effect: Does Increasing Efficiency Decrease Demand?" (PDF). National Council for Science and the Environment. Retrieved 2012-02-24.
  23. ^ Hirsch, R. L.; Bezdek, R.; and Wendling, R. (2006). "Peaking of World Oil Production and Its Mitigation". AIChE Journal. 52 (1): 2–8. doi:10.1002/aic.10747.
  24. ^ Laitner, John A.; De Canio, Stephen J.; Peters, Irene (2003). Incorporating Behavioural, Social, and Organizational Phenomena in the Assessment of Climate Change Mitigation Options. Advances in Global Change Research. Vol. 8. pp. 1–64. doi:10.1007/0-306-48160-X_1. ISBN 978-0-7923-6802-1. {{cite book}}: |journal= ignored (help)
  25. ^ Freire-González, Jaume (1 February 2021). "Governing Jevons' Paradox: Policies and systemic alternatives to avoid the rebound effect". Energy Research & Social Science. 72: 101893. doi:10.1016/j.erss.2020.101893. S2CID 234020339.
  26. ^ Siami, Navid; Winter, Ralph A. (1 September 2021). "Jevons' paradox revisited: Implications for climate change". Economics Letters. 206: 109955. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2021.109955.
  27. ^ "Drones, crops and Jevons' Paradox". Centre for Society, Technology and Values. 2016-08-22. Retrieved 2022-05-12.

Further reading edit

  • Jenkins, Jesse; Nordhaus, Ted; Shellenberger, Michael (February 17, 2011). (Report). Oakland, CA: The Breakthrough Institute. Archived from the original on 25 May 2015. Retrieved 29 May 2015.
  • Lords Select Committee on Science and Technology (5 July 2005). "3: The economics of energy efficiency". Select Committee on Science and Technology Second Report (Report). Session 2005–06. London, UK: House of Lords.
  • Michaels, Robert J. (July 6, 2012). Energy Efficiency and Climate Policy: The Rebound Dilemma (PDF) (Report). Washington, D.C.: Institute for Energy Research. Retrieved 5 June 2015.

jevons, paradox, economics, sometimes, jevons, effect, occurs, when, technological, progress, government, policy, increases, efficiency, with, which, resource, used, reducing, amount, necessary, falling, cost, induces, increases, demand, enough, that, resource. In economics the Jevons paradox ˈ dʒ ɛ v e n z sometimes Jevons effect occurs when technological progress or government policy increases the efficiency with which a resource is used reducing the amount necessary for any one use but the falling cost of use induces increases in demand enough that resource use is increased rather than reduced 1 2 3 Governments typically assume that efficiency gains will lower resource consumption ignoring the possibility of the paradox arising 4 Coal burning factories in 19th century Manchester England Improved technology allowed coal to fuel the Industrial Revolution greatly increasing the consumption of coal In 1865 the English economist William Stanley Jevons observed that technological improvements that increased the efficiency of coal use led to the increased consumption of coal in a wide range of industries He argued that contrary to common intuition technological progress could not be relied upon to reduce fuel consumption 5 6 The issue has been re examined by modern economists studying consumption rebound effects from improved energy efficiency In addition to reducing the amount needed for a given use improved efficiency also lowers the relative cost of using a resource which increases the quantity demanded This may counteract to some extent the reduction in use from improved efficiency Additionally improved efficiency increases real incomes and accelerates economic growth further increasing the demand for resources The Jevons paradox occurs when the effect from increased demand predominates and the improved efficiency results in a faster rate of resource utilization 6 Considerable debate exists about the size of the rebound in energy efficiency and the relevance of the Jevons paradox to energy conservation Some dismiss the effect while others worry that it may be self defeating to pursue sustainability by increasing energy efficiency 4 Some environmental economists have proposed that efficiency gains be coupled with conservation policies that keep the cost of use the same or higher to avoid the Jevons paradox 7 Conservation policies that increase cost of use such as cap and trade or green taxes can be used to control the rebound effect 8 Contents 1 History 2 Cause 3 Khazzoom Brookes postulate 4 Energy conservation policy 5 Other examples 5 1 Agriculture 6 See also 7 References 7 1 Further readingHistory edit nbsp William Stanley Jevons after whom the effect is namedThe Jevons paradox was first described by the English economist William Stanley Jevons in his 1865 book The Coal Question Jevons observed that England s consumption of coal soared after James Watt introduced the Watt steam engine which greatly improved the efficiency of the coal fired steam engine from Thomas Newcomen s earlier design Watt s innovations made coal a more cost effective power source leading to the increased use of the steam engine in a wide range of industries This in turn increased total coal consumption even as the amount of coal required for any particular application fell Jevons argued that improvements in fuel efficiency tend to increase rather than decrease fuel use writing It is a confusion of ideas to suppose that the economical use of fuel is equivalent to diminished consumption The very contrary is the truth 5 At that time many in Britain worried that coal reserves were rapidly dwindling but some experts opined that improving technology would reduce coal consumption Jevons argued that this view was incorrect as further increases in efficiency would tend to increase the use of coal Hence improving technology would tend to increase the rate at which England s coal deposits were being depleted and could not be relied upon to solve the problem 5 6 Although Jevons originally focused on coal the concept has since been extended to other resources e g water usage 9 The Jevons paradox is also found in socio hydrology in the safe development paradox called the reservoir effect where construction of a reservoir to reduce the risk of water shortage can instead exacerbate that risk as increased water availability leads to more development and hence more water consumption 10 Cause editMain article Rebound effect conservation nbsp Elastic Demand A 20 increase in efficiency causes a 40 increase in travel Fuel consumption increases and the Jevons paradox occurs nbsp Inelastic Demand A 20 increase in efficiency causes a 10 increase in travel The Jevons paradox does not occur Economists have observed that consumers tend to travel more when their cars are more fuel efficient causing a rebound in the demand for fuel 11 An increase in the efficiency with which a resource e g fuel is used causes a decrease in the cost of using that resource when measured in terms of what it can achieve e g travel Generally speaking a decrease in the cost or price of a good or service will increase the quantity demanded the law of demand With a lower cost for travel consumers will travel more increasing the demand for fuel This increase in demand is known as the rebound effect and it may or may not be large enough to offset the original drop in fuel use from the increased efficiency The Jevons paradox occurs when the rebound effect is greater than 100 exceeding the original efficiency gains 6 The size of the direct rebound effect is dependent on the price elasticity of demand for the good 12 In a perfectly competitive market where fuel is the sole input used if the price of fuel remains constant but efficiency is doubled the effective price of travel would be halved twice as much travel can be purchased If in response the amount of travel purchased more than doubles i e demand is price elastic then fuel consumption would increase and the Jevons paradox would occur If demand is price inelastic the amount of travel purchased would less than double and fuel consumption would decrease However goods and services generally use more than one type of input e g fuel labour machinery and other factors besides input cost may also affect price These factors tend to reduce the rebound effect making the Jevons paradox less likely to occur 6 Khazzoom Brookes postulate editMain article Khazzoom Brookes postulate In the 1980s economists Daniel Khazzoom and Leonard Brookes revisited the Jevons paradox for the case of society s energy use Brookes then chief economist at the UK Atomic Energy Authority argued that attempts to reduce energy consumption by increasing energy efficiency would simply raise demand for energy in the economy as a whole Khazzoom focused on the narrower point that the potential for rebound was ignored in mandatory performance standards for domestic appliances being set by the California Energy Commission 13 14 In 1992 the economist Harry Saunders dubbed the hypothesis that improvements in energy efficiency work to increase rather than decrease energy consumption the Khazzoom Brookes postulate and argued that the hypothesis is broadly supported by neoclassical growth theory the mainstream economic theory of capital accumulation technological progress and long run economic growth Saunders showed that the Khazzoom Brookes postulate occurs in the neoclassical growth model under a wide range of assumptions 13 15 According to Saunders increased energy efficiency tends to increase energy consumption by two means First increased energy efficiency makes the use of energy relatively cheaper thus encouraging increased use the direct rebound effect Second increased energy efficiency increases real incomes and leads to increased economic growth which pulls up energy use for the whole economy At the microeconomic level looking at an individual market even with the rebound effect improvements in energy efficiency usually result in reduced energy consumption 16 That is the rebound effect is usually less than 100 However at the macroeconomic level more efficient and hence comparatively cheaper energy leads to faster economic growth which increases energy use throughout the economy Saunders argued that taking into account both microeconomic and macroeconomic effects the technological progress that improves energy efficiency will tend to increase overall energy use 13 Energy conservation policy editSee also Steady state economy Resource decoupling and the rebound effect Jevons warned that fuel efficiency gains tend to increase fuel use However this does not imply that improved fuel efficiency is worthless if the Jevons paradox occurs higher fuel efficiency enables greater production and a higher material quality of life 17 For example a more efficient steam engine allowed the cheaper transport of goods and people that contributed to the Industrial Revolution Nonetheless if the Khazzoom Brookes postulate is correct increased fuel efficiency by itself will not reduce the rate of depletion of fossil fuels 13 There is considerable debate about whether the Khazzoom Brookes Postulate is correct and of the relevance of the Jevons paradox to energy conservation policy Most governments environmentalists and NGOs pursue policies that improve efficiency holding that these policies will lower resource consumption and reduce environmental problems Others including many environmental economists doubt this efficiency strategy towards sustainability and worry that efficiency gains may in fact lead to higher production and consumption They hold that for resource use to fall efficiency gains should be coupled with other policies that limit resource use 4 15 18 However other environmental economists argue that while the Jevons paradox may occur in some situations the empirical evidence for its widespread applicability is limited 19 The Jevons paradox is sometimes used to argue that energy conservation efforts are futile for example that more efficient use of oil will lead to increased demand and will not slow the arrival or the effects of peak oil This argument is usually presented as a reason not to enact environmental policies or pursue fuel efficiency e g if cars are more efficient it will simply lead to more driving 20 21 Several points have been raised against this argument First in the context of a mature market such as for oil in developed countries the direct rebound effect is usually small and so increased fuel efficiency usually reduces resource use other conditions remaining constant 11 16 22 Second even if increased efficiency does not reduce the total amount of fuel used there remain other benefits associated with improved efficiency For example increased fuel efficiency may mitigate the price increases shortages and disruptions in the global economy associated with crude oil depletion 23 Third environmental economists have pointed out that fuel use will unambiguously decrease if increased efficiency is coupled with an intervention e g a fuel tax that keeps the cost of fuel use the same or higher 7 The Jevons paradox indicates that increased efficiency by itself may not reduce fuel use and that sustainable energy policy must rely on other types of government interventions as well 8 As the imposition of conservation standards or other government interventions that increase cost of use do not display the Jevons paradox they can be used to control the rebound effect 8 To ensure that efficiency enhancing technological improvements reduce fuel use efficiency gains can be paired with government intervention that reduces demand e g green taxes cap and trade or higher emissions standards The ecological economists Mathis Wackernagel and William Rees have suggested that any cost savings from efficiency gains be taxed away or otherwise removed from further economic circulation Preferably they should be captured for reinvestment in natural capital rehabilitation 7 By mitigating the economic effects of government interventions designed to promote ecologically sustainable activities efficiency improving technological progress may make the imposition of these interventions more palatable and more likely to be implemented 24 25 26 Other examples editThis section needs expansion with sourced examples and additional citations You can help by adding to it February 2024 Agriculture edit Increasing the yield of a crop such as wheat for a given area will reduce the area required to achieve the same total yield However increasing efficiency may make it more profitable to grow wheat and lead farmers to convert land to the production of wheat thereby increasing land use instead 27 See also editAndy and Bill s law new software will always consume any increase in computing power that new hardware can provide Downs Thomson paradox increasing road capacity can make traffic congestion worse Tragedy of the commons a phenomenon in which common resources to which access is not regulated tend to become depleted Wirth s law faster hardware can trigger the development of less efficient software Dutch Disease strong revenue from a dominant sector renders other sectors uncompetitive and starves themReferences edit Bauer Diana Papp Kathryn 18 March 2009 Book Review Perspectives The Jevons Paradox and the Myth of Resource Efficiency Improvements Sustainability Science Practice amp Policy 5 1 doi 10 1080 15487733 2009 11908028 York Richard McGee Julius Alexander 2 January 2016 Understanding the Jevons paradox Environmental Sociology 2 1 77 87 doi 10 1080 23251042 2015 1106060 S2CID 156762601 York Richard 2006 Ecological paradoxes William Stanley Jevons and the paperless office PDF Human Ecology Review 13 2 143 147 Retrieved 2015 05 05 a b c Alcott Blake July 2005 Jevons paradox Ecological Economics 54 1 9 21 doi 10 1016 j ecolecon 2005 03 020 hdl 1942 22574 a b c Jevons William Stanley 1866 VII The Coal Question 2nd ed London Macmillan and Company OCLC 464772008 Retrieved 2008 07 21 a b c d e Alcott Blake 2008 Historical Overview of the Jevons paradox in the Literature In JM Polimeni K Mayumi M Giampietro eds The Jevons Paradox and the Myth of Resource Efficiency Improvements Earthscan pp 7 78 ISBN 978 1 84407 462 4 a b c Wackernagel Mathis Rees William 1997 Perceptual and structural barriers to investing in natural capital Economics from an ecological footprint perspective Ecological Economics 20 3 3 24 doi 10 1016 S0921 8009 96 00077 8 a b c Freire Gonzalez Jaume Puig Ventosa Ignasi 2015 Energy Efficiency Policies and the Jevons Paradox International Journal of Energy Economics and Policy 5 1 69 79 Retrieved 29 May 2015 Dumont A Mayor B Lopez Gunn E 2013 Is the Rebound Effect or Jevons Paradox a Useful Concept for Better Management of Water Resources Insights from the Irrigation Modernisation Process in Spain Aquatic Procedia 1 64 76 doi 10 1016 j aqpro 2013 07 006 Di Baldassarre Giuliano Wanders Niko AghaKouchak Amir Kuil Linda Rangecroft Sally Veldkamp Ted I E Garcia Margaret van Oel Pieter R Breinl Korbinian Van Loon Anne F November 2018 Water shortages worsened by reservoir effects Nature Sustainability 1 11 617 622 doi 10 1038 s41893 018 0159 0 ISSN 2398 9629 S2CID 134508048 a b Small Kenneth A Kurt Van Dender 2005 09 21 The Effect of Improved Fuel Economy on Vehicle Miles Traveled Estimating the Rebound Effect Using U S State Data 1966 2001 Policy and Economics Retrieved 2010 09 01 Chan Nathan W Gillingham Kenneth 1 March 2015 The Microeconomic Theory of the Rebound Effect and Its Welfare Implications Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 2 1 133 159 doi 10 1086 680256 ISSN 2333 5955 S2CID 3681642 a b c d Saunders Harry D October 1992 The Khazzoom Brookes Postulate and Neoclassical Growth The Energy Journal 13 4 131 148 doi 10 5547 ISSN0195 6574 EJ Vol13 No4 7 JSTOR 41322471 Herring Horace 19 July 1999 Does energy efficiency save energy The debate and its consequences Applied Energy 63 3 209 226 doi 10 1016 S0306 2619 99 00030 6 ISSN 0306 2619 a b Sorrell Steve April 2009 Jevons Paradox revisited The evidence for backfire from improved energy efficiency Energy Policy 37 4 1456 1469 doi 10 1016 j enpol 2008 12 003 a b Greening Lorna David L Greene Carmen Difiglio 2000 Energy efficiency and consumption the rebound effect a survey Energy Policy 28 6 7 389 401 doi 10 1016 S0301 4215 00 00021 5 Ryan Lisa Campbell Nina 2012 Spreading the net the multiple benefits of energy efficiency improvements IEA Energy Papers doi 10 1787 20792581 Retrieved 5 June 2015 Owen David December 20 2010 Annals of Environmentalism The Efficiency Dilemma The New Yorker pp 78 Gillingham Kenneth Kotchen Matthew J Rapson David S Wagner Gernot 23 January 2013 Energy policy The rebound effect is overplayed Nature 493 7433 475 476 Bibcode 2013Natur 493 475G doi 10 1038 493475a ISSN 0028 0836 PMID 23344343 S2CID 3220092 Potter Andrew 2007 02 13 Planet friendly design Bah humbug Maclean s 120 5 14 Archived from the original on 2007 12 14 Retrieved 2010 09 01 Strassel Kimberley A 2001 05 17 Conservation Wastes Energy The Wall Street Journal Archived from the original on 2005 11 13 Retrieved 2009 07 31 Gottron Frank 2001 07 30 Energy Efficiency and the Rebound Effect Does Increasing Efficiency Decrease Demand PDF National Council for Science and the Environment Retrieved 2012 02 24 Hirsch R L Bezdek R and Wendling R 2006 Peaking of World Oil Production and Its Mitigation AIChE Journal 52 1 2 8 doi 10 1002 aic 10747 Laitner John A De Canio Stephen J Peters Irene 2003 Incorporating Behavioural Social and Organizational Phenomena in the Assessment of Climate Change Mitigation Options Advances in Global Change Research Vol 8 pp 1 64 doi 10 1007 0 306 48160 X 1 ISBN 978 0 7923 6802 1 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a journal ignored help Freire Gonzalez Jaume 1 February 2021 Governing Jevons Paradox Policies and systemic alternatives to avoid the rebound effect Energy Research amp Social Science 72 101893 doi 10 1016 j erss 2020 101893 S2CID 234020339 Siami Navid Winter Ralph A 1 September 2021 Jevons paradox revisited Implications for climate change Economics Letters 206 109955 doi 10 1016 j econlet 2021 109955 Drones crops and Jevons Paradox Centre for Society Technology and Values 2016 08 22 Retrieved 2022 05 12 Further reading edit Jenkins Jesse Nordhaus Ted Shellenberger Michael February 17 2011 Energy Emergence Rebound and Backfire as Emergent Phenomena Report Oakland CA The Breakthrough Institute Archived from the original on 25 May 2015 Retrieved 29 May 2015 Lords Select Committee on Science and Technology 5 July 2005 3 The economics of energy efficiency Select Committee on Science and Technology Second Report Report Session 2005 06 London UK House of Lords Michaels Robert J July 6 2012 Energy Efficiency and Climate Policy The Rebound Dilemma PDF Report Washington D C Institute for Energy Research Retrieved 5 June 2015 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Jevons paradox amp oldid 1201988130, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.