fbpx
Wikipedia

Permanent income hypothesis

The permanent income hypothesis (PIH) is a model in the field of economics to explain the formation of consumption patterns. It suggests consumption patterns are formed from future expectations and consumption smoothing.[α] The theory was developed by Milton Friedman and published in his A Theory of Consumption Function, published in 1957 and subsequently formalized by Robert Hall in a rational expectations model. Originally applied to consumption and income, the process of future expectations is thought to influence other phenomena. In its simplest form, the hypothesis states changes in permanent income (human capital, property, assets), rather than changes in temporary income (unexpected income), are what drive changes in consumption.

Nobel laureate and inventor of the Permanent Income Hypothesis Milton Friedman

The formation of consumption patterns opposite to predictions was an outstanding problem faced by the Keynesian orthodoxy. Friedman's predictions of consumption smoothing, where people spread out transitory changes in income over time, departed from the traditional Keynesian emphasis on a higher marginal propensity to consume[β] out of current income.

Income consists of a permanent (anticipated and planned) component and a transitory (unexpected and surprising) component. In the permanent income hypothesis model, the key determinant of consumption is an individual's lifetime income, not their current income. Unlike permanent income, transitory incomes are volatile.

Background and history edit

Until A Theory of Consumption Function, the Keynesian absolute income hypothesis and interpretation of the consumption function were the most advanced and sophisticated.[2][3] In its post-war synthesis, the Keynesian perspective was responsible for pioneering many innovations in recession management, economic history, and macroeconomics. Like the neoclassical school that preceded it, early inconsistencies had their roots in socio-political events contrary to the predictions put forward.[2][3]

The introduction of the absolute income hypothesis is often attributed to John Maynard Keynes, a British economist, who wrote several books which are now the basis for Keynesian economics.[4] The hypothesis put forward by Keynes was accepted and placed into the post–war synthesis. However, inconsistencies were not resolved swiftly, and economists were unable to explain the consistency of the savings rate in the face of rising real incomes (Fig. 1).[2][3]

Relationship between Saving and Consumption Based on Budget Data[5]
United States (USD)
Date Consumer Units Avg. Income APC[γ] MPC[δ]
1881–90 Selected wage-earner families $682 .90 .67
1901 Selected wage-earner normal families $651 .92 .68
1917–19 Selected wage-earner families $1,513 .91 .78
1935–36 Nonrelief nonfarm families $1,952 .89 .73
1935–36 Nonrelief farm families $1,259 .87 .57
1941 Urban families $2,865 .92 .79
1941 Farm families $1,680 .83 .57
1944 Urban families $3,411 .82 .57
1947 Urban families $3,323 .92 .78
1950 Nonfarm families $4,084 .91 .73
1950 Spending units of one or more persons $3,220 .92 .75

Fig. 1: Analysis of consumption and income; taken from Friedman (1957)

Before the neoclassical synthesis was established, Keynes and his hypothesis challenged the orthodoxy of neoclassical economics.[3] As a result of the Great Depression, Keynes rapidly became among the leaders of economic thought. His MPC and MPS spending multipliers developed into the absolute income hypothesis (1), and were influential to the government responses to the ensuing depression.[3][6]

 

 

 

 

 

(1)

Origins edit

The American economist Milton Friedman developed the permanent income hypothesis in his 1957 book A Theory of the Consumption Function.[7] In his book, Friedman posits a theory that explained how and why future expectations change consumption.[8]

Friedman's 1957 book A Theory of the Consumption Function created the basis for consumption smoothing. He argued the consumption model, in which outcomes are stochastic,[ε] where consumers face risks and uncertainty to their labor incomes,[ζ] complicates interpretations of indifference curves,[11] and causes consumers to spread out or 'smooth' their spending based on their permanent income, which represents their anticipated income over their lifetimes.[7][8] Friedman explains this by how, for example, consumers would consistently save more when they expect their long-term income to increase.[7] A further elaboration is provided below:[12]

'Yet from another point of view, the assumption seems highly implausible. Will not a man who receives an unexpected windfall use at least some part of it in "riotous living," i.e. in consumption expenditures? Would he be likely to add the whole of it to his wealth? The answer to these questions depends greatly on how "consumption" is defined. The offhand affirmative answer reflects in large measure, I believe, an implicit definition of consumption in terms of purchases, including durable goods, rather than in terms of the value of services. If the latter definition is adopted, as seems highly desirable in applying the hypothesis to empirical data—though unfortunately I have been able to do so to only a limited extent—much that one classifies offhand as consumption is reclassified as savings. Is not the windfall likely to be used for the purchase of durable goods? Or, to put it differently, is not the timing of the replacement of durable goods and of additions to the stock of such goods likely to some extent to be adjusted so as to coincide with windfalls?'

— A Theory of Consumption Function

Theoretical considerations edit

In his theory, John Maynard Keynes supported economic policy makers by his argument emphasizing their capability of macroeconomic fine tuning. For Keynes, consumption expenditures are linked to disposable income by a parameter called the marginal propensity to consume (the amount per dollar consumers are willing to spend;  ).[13] Since the marginal propensity to consume itself is a function of income, it is also true that additional increases in disposable income lead to diminishing increases in consumption expenditures. It must be stressed that the relation characterized by substantial stability links current consumption expenditures to current disposable income—and, on these grounds, a considerable leeway is provided for aggregate demand stimulation, since a change in income immediately results in a multiplied shift in aggregate demand (this is the essence of the Keynesian case of the multiplier effect). The same is true of tax cut policies. According to the basic theory of Keynes, governments are always capable of countercyclical fine tuning of macroeconomic systems through demand management,[14] although Friedman disputes this, arguing in a 1961 journal article that Keynesian macroeconomic fine tuning will succumb to 'long and variable lags.'[15]

 
Model of the consumption function, where a is autonomous consumption, b is the MPC, and Yd is disposable income

The permanent income hypothesis questions this ability of governments. However, it is also true that permanent income theory is concentrated mainly on long run dynamics and relations, while Keynes focused primarily on short run considerations.[16] Friedman's argument, which challenged the use of fiscal policy in smoothing out business cycles,[17] was challenged by stressing the relation between consumption and disposable income still follows (more or less) the mechanism supposed by Keynes.[2][18]

Friedman starts elaborating his theory under the assumption of complete certainty. Under such circumstances, for Friedman, two motives exist for a consumer unit to spend more or less on consumption than its income: The first is to smooth its consumption expenditures through appropriate timing of borrowing and lending; and the second is either to realize interest earnings on deposits if the relevant rate of interest is positive, or to benefit from borrowing if the interest rate is negative.[19]

According to the PIH, the distribution of consumption across consecutive periods is the result of an optimizing method by which each consumer tries to maximize his utility. At the same time, whatever ratio of income one devotes to consumption in each period, all these consumption expenditures are allocated in the course of an optimization process—that is, consumer units try to optimize not only across periods but within each period.[2][7]

Calculation of income and consumption edit

Friedman's 1957 book also made an argument for an entirely new way of calculating income (income is represented by the variable  ) by differentiating between transitory and permanent income (which was also taken to include ordinal elements like human capital and talents).[20] In A Theory of Consumption Function, Friedman develops:   as a formula. In an earlier study, Friedman, Kuznets (1945), he proposes the idea of transitory and permanent income.[21]

Friedman also developed a consumption formula,  , with   meaning the permanent component of consumption, with   being the transitory component. Friedman also drew a distinction between   and  . Transitory consumption can be interpreted as surprising or unexpected bills, such as a high water bill, or unexpected doctor's visit, which, in Friedman's mind, cannot be spurred by  , because unexpected or 'surprise' consumption is not often financed through windfall gains.[7]

Simple model edit

Consider a (potentially infinitely lived) consumer who maximizes his expected lifetime utility from the consumption of a stream of goods   between periods   and  , as determined by one period utility function  . In each period  , he receives an income  , which he can either spend on a consumption good   or save in the form of an asset   that pays a constant real interest rate   in the next period.[22]

The utility of consumption in future periods is discounted at the rate  . Finally, let   denote the expected value conditional on the information available in period  . Formally, the consumer's problem is then

 

subject to

 

Assuming the utility function is quadratic, and that  , the optimal consumption choice of the consumer is governed by the Euler equation

 

Given a finite time horizon of length  , we set   with the understanding the consumer spends all his wealth by the end of the last period. Solving the consumer's budget constraint forward to the last period, we determine the consumption function is given by

 

 

 

 

 

(2)

Over an infinite time horizon, we instead impose a no Ponzi game condition, which prevents the consumer from continuously borrowing and rolling over their debt to future periods, by requiring

 

The resulting consumption function is then

 

 

 

 

 

(3)

Both expressions (2) and (3) capture the essence of the permanent income hypothesis: current consumption is determined by a combination of current non human wealth   and human capital wealth  . The fraction of total wealth consumed today further depends on the interest rate   and the length of the time horizon over which the consumer is optimizing.[22]

Liquidity constraints edit

Some have attempted to improve Friedman's original hypothesis by including liquidity constraints, most notably Christopher D. Carroll.[8][23]

Empirical evidence edit

Observations, recorded from 1888 to 1941, of stagnant average propensity to consume in the face of rising real incomes provide strong evidence for the existence of the permanent income hypothesis.[24] An early test of the permanent income hypothesis was reported by Robert Hall in 1978, and, assuming rational expectations, finds consumption follows a martingale sequence.[25] Hall & Mishkin (1982) analyze data from 2,000 households and find consumption responds much more strongly to permanent than to transitory movements of income, and reinforce the compatibility of the PIH with 80% of households in the sample.[26] Bernanke (1984) finds 'no evidence against the permanent income hypothesis' when looking at data on automobile consumption.[27]

 
Median American household spending

In contrast, Flavin (1981) finds consumption is very sensitive to transitory income shocks ('excess sensitivity'),[28] while Mankiw & Shapiro (1985) dispute these findings, arguing that Flavin's test specification (which assumes income is stationary) is biased towards finding excess sensitivity.[29]

Souleles (1999) uses income tax refunds to test the PIH.[30] Since a refund depends on income in the previous year, it is predictable income and should thus not alter consumption in the year of its receipt.[30] The evidence finds that consumption is sensitive to the income refund, with a marginal propensity to consume between 35 and 60%. Stephens (2003) finds the consumption patterns of social security recipients in the United States is not well explained by the permanent income hypothesis.[31]

Stafford (1974) argues that Friedman's explanation cannot account for market failures such as liquidity constraints.[32] Carroll (1997) and Carroll (2001) dispute this, and adjust the model for limits on borrowing.[8][23] A comprehensive analysis of 3000 tests of the hypothesis provides another explanation. It argues that rejections of the hypothesis are based on publication bias[33] and that after correction, it is consistent with data.[34]

Policy implications edit

According to Costas Meghir, unresolved inconsistencies explain the failure of transitory Keynesian demand management techniques to achieve its policy targets.[2] In a simple Keynesian framework the marginal propensity to consume (MPC)[η] is assumed constant, and so temporary tax cuts can have a large stimulating effect on demand.[35] Shapiro & Slemrod (2003) find that consumers spread tax rebates over their temporal horizon.[36]

Reception edit

Criticism edit

Some critics of the permanent income hypothesis, such as Frank Stafford, have criticized the permanent income hypothesis for its lack of liquidity constraints.[32] However, some studies have adapted the hypothesis for certain circumstances and found that the permanent income hypothesis is compatible with liquidity constraints and other market failures unaccounted for in the original hypothesis.[8][23]

Alvarez-Cuadrado & Van Long (2011) argue that more affluent consumers save more of their permanent incomes, against what would be expected given the permanent income hypothesis.[37]

Praise edit

Friedman received the 1976 Sveriges Riksbank prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 'For his achievements in the field of consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and for his demonstration of the complexity of stabilization policy.'[38] The 'consumption analysis' has been interpreted by Worek (2010) as representing Friedman's contributions in the form of the permanent income hypothesis,[38] while the monetary history and stabilization section has been interpreted to refer to his work on monetary policy and history, and monetarism, which seeks to stabilize a currency, preventing erratic swings, respectively.[38][39]

The Permanent Income Hypothesis has been met with praise from Austrian economists, such as Robert Mulligan.[40]

See also edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ a b c d Mankiw & Taylor 2006, p. 870.
  2. ^ a b c d e f Meghir 2004, p. 293–306.
  3. ^ a b c d e Thomas 1985, p. 42–78.
  4. ^ Thomas 1985, p. 160.
  5. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 41.
  6. ^ Keynes 1936, p. 89–134.
  7. ^ a b c d e Friedman 1957, p. 20–37.
  8. ^ a b c d e Carroll 2001, p. 23–45.
  9. ^ Stirzaker 2005, p. 45.
  10. ^ Mankiw & Taylor 2006, p. 155-86.
  11. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 14–17.
  12. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 28.
  13. ^ Keynes 1936, p. 96.
  14. ^ Mankiw & Taylor 2006, p. 607-24.
  15. ^ Friedman 1961, p. 447–466.
  16. ^ Keynes 1923, p. 80.
  17. ^ Mankiw 2006, p. 5.
  18. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 38–114.
  19. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 7.
  20. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 21.
  21. ^ Friedman & Kuznets 1945, p. 352.
  22. ^ a b Ireland 1995, p. 49–63.
  23. ^ a b c Carroll 1997, p. 1–55.
  24. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 38–43.
  25. ^ Hall 1978, p. 971–987.
  26. ^ Hall & Mishkin 1982, p. 461–81.
  27. ^ Bernanke 1984, p. 587–614.
  28. ^ Flavin 1981, p. 974–1009.
  29. ^ Mankiw & Shapiro 1984, p. 165–174.
  30. ^ a b Souleles 1999, p. 947–958.
  31. ^ Stephens 2003, p. 406–422.
  32. ^ a b Stafford 1974, p. 195–196.
  33. ^ Runkle 1991, p. 73–98.
  34. ^ Havranek & Sokolova 2020, p. 97–122.
  35. ^ Lee 1975, p. 407–417.
  36. ^ Shapiro & Slemrod 2003, p. 381–396.
  37. ^ Alvarez-Cuadrado & Van Long 2011, p. 1489–1501.
  38. ^ a b c Worek 2010, p. 221.
  39. ^ Forder & Monnery 2019, p. 130–145.
  40. ^ Mulligan 2014, p. 344–346.
  1. ^ The term "consumption smoothing" refers to the tendency of consumers to "smooth out" consumption over their lifetimes; effectively, consumers spread out consumption over time because they want to guarantee stability and prevent diminishing marginal utility from decreasing their utility
  2. ^ The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) represents how much of a dollar a consumer spends or consumes, whereas the marginal propensity to save (MPS) represents how much of a dollar a consumer saves; these units are tracking marginal decision making[1]
  3. ^ The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) represents how much of a dollar a consumer spends or consumes, whereas the marginal propensity to save (MPS) represents how much of a dollar a consumer saves; these units are tracking marginal decision making[1]
  4. ^ The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) represents how much of a dollar a consumer spends or consumes, whereas the marginal propensity to save (MPS) represents how much of a dollar a consumer saves; these units are tracking marginal decision making[1]
  5. ^ Stochastic refers to the property of being well described by a random probability distribution[9]
  6. ^ Unlike capital (k), labor inputs are not fixed in the short term[10]
  7. ^ The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) represents how much of a dollar a consumer spends or consumes, whereas the marginal propensity to save (MPS) represents how much of a dollar a consumer saves; these units are tracking marginal decision making[1]

References edit

permanent, income, hypothesis, permanent, income, hypothesis, model, field, economics, explain, formation, consumption, patterns, suggests, consumption, patterns, formed, from, future, expectations, consumption, smoothing, theory, developed, milton, friedman, . The permanent income hypothesis PIH is a model in the field of economics to explain the formation of consumption patterns It suggests consumption patterns are formed from future expectations and consumption smoothing a The theory was developed by Milton Friedman and published in his A Theory of Consumption Function published in 1957 and subsequently formalized by Robert Hall in a rational expectations model Originally applied to consumption and income the process of future expectations is thought to influence other phenomena In its simplest form the hypothesis states changes in permanent income human capital property assets rather than changes in temporary income unexpected income are what drive changes in consumption Nobel laureate and inventor of the Permanent Income Hypothesis Milton FriedmanThe formation of consumption patterns opposite to predictions was an outstanding problem faced by the Keynesian orthodoxy Friedman s predictions of consumption smoothing where people spread out transitory changes in income over time departed from the traditional Keynesian emphasis on a higher marginal propensity to consume b out of current income Income consists of a permanent anticipated and planned component and a transitory unexpected and surprising component In the permanent income hypothesis model the key determinant of consumption is an individual s lifetime income not their current income Unlike permanent income transitory incomes are volatile Contents 1 Background and history 2 Origins 3 Theoretical considerations 4 Calculation of income and consumption 5 Simple model 5 1 Liquidity constraints 6 Empirical evidence 7 Policy implications 8 Reception 8 1 Criticism 8 2 Praise 9 See also 10 Notes 11 ReferencesBackground and history editUntil A Theory of Consumption Function the Keynesian absolute income hypothesis and interpretation of the consumption function were the most advanced and sophisticated 2 3 In its post war synthesis the Keynesian perspective was responsible for pioneering many innovations in recession management economic history and macroeconomics Like the neoclassical school that preceded it early inconsistencies had their roots in socio political events contrary to the predictions put forward 2 3 The introduction of the absolute income hypothesis is often attributed to John Maynard Keynes a British economist who wrote several books which are now the basis for Keynesian economics 4 The hypothesis put forward by Keynes was accepted and placed into the post war synthesis However inconsistencies were not resolved swiftly and economists were unable to explain the consistency of the savings rate in the face of rising real incomes Fig 1 2 3 Relationship between Saving and Consumption Based on Budget Data 5 United States USD Date Consumer Units Avg Income APC g MPC d 1881 90 Selected wage earner families 682 90 671901 Selected wage earner normal families 651 92 681917 19 Selected wage earner families 1 513 91 781935 36 Nonrelief nonfarm families 1 952 89 731935 36 Nonrelief farm families 1 259 87 571941 Urban families 2 865 92 791941 Farm families 1 680 83 571944 Urban families 3 411 82 571947 Urban families 3 323 92 781950 Nonfarm families 4 084 91 731950 Spending units of one or more persons 3 220 92 75Fig 1 Analysis of consumption and income taken from Friedman 1957 Before the neoclassical synthesis was established Keynes and his hypothesis challenged the orthodoxy of neoclassical economics 3 As a result of the Great Depression Keynes rapidly became among the leaders of economic thought His MPC and MPS spending multipliers developed into the absolute income hypothesis 1 and were influential to the government responses to the ensuing depression 3 6 C a b Yd displaystyle C a b cdot Y d nbsp 1 Origins editThe American economist Milton Friedman developed the permanent income hypothesis in his 1957 book A Theory of the Consumption Function 7 In his book Friedman posits a theory that explained how and why future expectations change consumption 8 Friedman s 1957 book A Theory of the Consumption Function created the basis for consumption smoothing He argued the consumption model in which outcomes are stochastic e where consumers face risks and uncertainty to their labor incomes z complicates interpretations of indifference curves 11 and causes consumers to spread out or smooth their spending based on their permanent income which represents their anticipated income over their lifetimes 7 8 Friedman explains this by how for example consumers would consistently save more when they expect their long term income to increase 7 A further elaboration is provided below 12 Yet from another point of view the assumption seems highly implausible Will not a man who receives an unexpected windfall use at least some part of it in riotous living i e in consumption expenditures Would he be likely to add the whole of it to his wealth The answer to these questions depends greatly on how consumption is defined The offhand affirmative answer reflects in large measure I believe an implicit definition of consumption in terms of purchases including durable goods rather than in terms of the value of services If the latter definition is adopted as seems highly desirable in applying the hypothesis to empirical data though unfortunately I have been able to do so to only a limited extent much that one classifies offhand as consumption is reclassified as savings Is not the windfall likely to be used for the purchase of durable goods Or to put it differently is not the timing of the replacement of durable goods and of additions to the stock of such goods likely to some extent to be adjusted so as to coincide with windfalls A Theory of Consumption FunctionTheoretical considerations editIn his theory John Maynard Keynes supported economic policy makers by his argument emphasizing their capability of macroeconomic fine tuning For Keynes consumption expenditures are linked to disposable income by a parameter called the marginal propensity to consume the amount per dollar consumers are willing to spend 1 MPS MPC displaystyle 1 MPS MPC nbsp 13 Since the marginal propensity to consume itself is a function of income it is also true that additional increases in disposable income lead to diminishing increases in consumption expenditures It must be stressed that the relation characterized by substantial stability links current consumption expenditures to current disposable income and on these grounds a considerable leeway is provided for aggregate demand stimulation since a change in income immediately results in a multiplied shift in aggregate demand this is the essence of the Keynesian case of the multiplier effect The same is true of tax cut policies According to the basic theory of Keynes governments are always capable of countercyclical fine tuning of macroeconomic systems through demand management 14 although Friedman disputes this arguing in a 1961 journal article that Keynesian macroeconomic fine tuning will succumb to long and variable lags 15 nbsp Model of the consumption function where a is autonomous consumption b is the MPC and Yd is disposable incomeThe permanent income hypothesis questions this ability of governments However it is also true that permanent income theory is concentrated mainly on long run dynamics and relations while Keynes focused primarily on short run considerations 16 Friedman s argument which challenged the use of fiscal policy in smoothing out business cycles 17 was challenged by stressing the relation between consumption and disposable income still follows more or less the mechanism supposed by Keynes 2 18 Friedman starts elaborating his theory under the assumption of complete certainty Under such circumstances for Friedman two motives exist for a consumer unit to spend more or less on consumption than its income The first is to smooth its consumption expenditures through appropriate timing of borrowing and lending and the second is either to realize interest earnings on deposits if the relevant rate of interest is positive or to benefit from borrowing if the interest rate is negative 19 According to the PIH the distribution of consumption across consecutive periods is the result of an optimizing method by which each consumer tries to maximize his utility At the same time whatever ratio of income one devotes to consumption in each period all these consumption expenditures are allocated in the course of an optimization process that is consumer units try to optimize not only across periods but within each period 2 7 Calculation of income and consumption editFriedman s 1957 book also made an argument for an entirely new way of calculating income income is represented by the variable y displaystyle y nbsp by differentiating between transitory and permanent income which was also taken to include ordinal elements like human capital and talents 20 In A Theory of Consumption Function Friedman develops y yp yt displaystyle y y p y t nbsp as a formula In an earlier study Friedman Kuznets 1945 he proposes the idea of transitory and permanent income 21 Friedman also developed a consumption formula c cp ct displaystyle c c p c t nbsp with cp displaystyle c p nbsp meaning the permanent component of consumption with ct displaystyle c t nbsp being the transitory component Friedman also drew a distinction between yt displaystyle y t nbsp and ct displaystyle c t nbsp Transitory consumption can be interpreted as surprising or unexpected bills such as a high water bill or unexpected doctor s visit which in Friedman s mind cannot be spurred by yt displaystyle y t nbsp because unexpected or surprise consumption is not often financed through windfall gains 7 Simple model editConsider a potentially infinitely lived consumer who maximizes his expected lifetime utility from the consumption of a stream of goods c displaystyle c nbsp between periods t displaystyle t nbsp and T displaystyle T nbsp as determined by one period utility function u displaystyle u cdot nbsp In each period t displaystyle t nbsp he receives an income yt displaystyle y t nbsp which he can either spend on a consumption good ct displaystyle c t nbsp or save in the form of an asset At displaystyle A t nbsp that pays a constant real interest rate r displaystyle r nbsp in the next period 22 The utility of consumption in future periods is discounted at the rate b 0 1 displaystyle beta in 0 1 nbsp Finally let Et displaystyle operatorname E t cdot nbsp denote the expected value conditional on the information available in period t displaystyle t nbsp Formally the consumer s problem is then max ck k tTEt k 0T tbku ct k displaystyle max c k k t T operatorname E t sum k 0 T t beta k u c t k nbsp subject to At 1 1 r At yt ct displaystyle A t 1 1 r A t y t c t nbsp Assuming the utility function is quadratic and that 1 r b 1 displaystyle 1 r beta 1 nbsp the optimal consumption choice of the consumer is governed by the Euler equation ct Et ct 1 displaystyle c t operatorname E t c t 1 nbsp Given a finite time horizon of length T t displaystyle T t nbsp we set AT 1 0 displaystyle A T 1 0 nbsp with the understanding the consumer spends all his wealth by the end of the last period Solving the consumer s budget constraint forward to the last period we determine the consumption function is given by ct r 1 r 1 r T t At k 0T t 11 r kEt yt k displaystyle c t frac r 1 r 1 r T t left A t sum k 0 T t left frac 1 1 r right k operatorname E t y t k right nbsp 2 Over an infinite time horizon we instead impose a no Ponzi game condition which prevents the consumer from continuously borrowing and rolling over their debt to future periods by requiring limt 11 r tAt 0 displaystyle lim t to infty left frac 1 1 r right t A t 0 nbsp The resulting consumption function is then ct r1 r At k 0 11 r kEt yt k displaystyle c t frac r 1 r left A t sum k 0 infty left frac 1 1 r right k operatorname E t y t k right nbsp 3 Both expressions 2 and 3 capture the essence of the permanent income hypothesis current consumption is determined by a combination of current non human wealth At displaystyle A t nbsp and human capital wealth yt displaystyle y t nbsp The fraction of total wealth consumed today further depends on the interest rate r displaystyle r nbsp and the length of the time horizon over which the consumer is optimizing 22 Liquidity constraints edit Some have attempted to improve Friedman s original hypothesis by including liquidity constraints most notably Christopher D Carroll 8 23 Empirical evidence editObservations recorded from 1888 to 1941 of stagnant average propensity to consume in the face of rising real incomes provide strong evidence for the existence of the permanent income hypothesis 24 An early test of the permanent income hypothesis was reported by Robert Hall in 1978 and assuming rational expectations finds consumption follows a martingale sequence 25 Hall amp Mishkin 1982 analyze data from 2 000 households and find consumption responds much more strongly to permanent than to transitory movements of income and reinforce the compatibility of the PIH with 80 of households in the sample 26 Bernanke 1984 finds no evidence against the permanent income hypothesis when looking at data on automobile consumption 27 nbsp Median American household spendingIn contrast Flavin 1981 finds consumption is very sensitive to transitory income shocks excess sensitivity 28 while Mankiw amp Shapiro 1985 dispute these findings arguing that Flavin s test specification which assumes income is stationary is biased towards finding excess sensitivity 29 Souleles 1999 uses income tax refunds to test the PIH 30 Since a refund depends on income in the previous year it is predictable income and should thus not alter consumption in the year of its receipt 30 The evidence finds that consumption is sensitive to the income refund with a marginal propensity to consume between 35 and 60 Stephens 2003 finds the consumption patterns of social security recipients in the United States is not well explained by the permanent income hypothesis 31 Stafford 1974 argues that Friedman s explanation cannot account for market failures such as liquidity constraints 32 Carroll 1997 and Carroll 2001 dispute this and adjust the model for limits on borrowing 8 23 A comprehensive analysis of 3000 tests of the hypothesis provides another explanation It argues that rejections of the hypothesis are based on publication bias 33 and that after correction it is consistent with data 34 Policy implications editAccording to Costas Meghir unresolved inconsistencies explain the failure of transitory Keynesian demand management techniques to achieve its policy targets 2 In a simple Keynesian framework the marginal propensity to consume MPC h is assumed constant and so temporary tax cuts can have a large stimulating effect on demand 35 Shapiro amp Slemrod 2003 find that consumers spread tax rebates over their temporal horizon 36 Reception editCriticism edit Some critics of the permanent income hypothesis such as Frank Stafford have criticized the permanent income hypothesis for its lack of liquidity constraints 32 However some studies have adapted the hypothesis for certain circumstances and found that the permanent income hypothesis is compatible with liquidity constraints and other market failures unaccounted for in the original hypothesis 8 23 Alvarez Cuadrado amp Van Long 2011 argue that more affluent consumers save more of their permanent incomes against what would be expected given the permanent income hypothesis 37 Praise edit Friedman received the 1976 Sveriges Riksbank prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel For his achievements in the field of consumption analysis monetary history and theory and for his demonstration of the complexity of stabilization policy 38 The consumption analysis has been interpreted by Worek 2010 as representing Friedman s contributions in the form of the permanent income hypothesis 38 while the monetary history and stabilization section has been interpreted to refer to his work on monetary policy and history and monetarism which seeks to stabilize a currency preventing erratic swings respectively 38 39 The Permanent Income Hypothesis has been met with praise from Austrian economists such as Robert Mulligan 40 See also editConsumption smoothing Income Economic definitions Milton Friedman Ricardian equivalence Risk compensation Milton Friedman bibliographyNotes edit a b c d Mankiw amp Taylor 2006 p 870 a b c d e f Meghir 2004 p 293 306 a b c d e Thomas 1985 p 42 78 Thomas 1985 p 160 Friedman 1957 p 41 Keynes 1936 p 89 134 a b c d e Friedman 1957 p 20 37 a b c d e Carroll 2001 p 23 45 Stirzaker 2005 p 45 Mankiw amp Taylor 2006 p 155 86 Friedman 1957 p 14 17 Friedman 1957 p 28 Keynes 1936 p 96 Mankiw amp Taylor 2006 p 607 24 Friedman 1961 p 447 466 Keynes 1923 p 80 Mankiw 2006 p 5 Friedman 1957 p 38 114 Friedman 1957 p 7 Friedman 1957 p 21 Friedman amp Kuznets 1945 p 352 a b Ireland 1995 p 49 63 a b c Carroll 1997 p 1 55 Friedman 1957 p 38 43 Hall 1978 p 971 987 Hall amp Mishkin 1982 p 461 81 Bernanke 1984 p 587 614 Flavin 1981 p 974 1009 Mankiw amp Shapiro 1984 p 165 174 a b Souleles 1999 p 947 958 Stephens 2003 p 406 422 a b Stafford 1974 p 195 196 Runkle 1991 p 73 98 Havranek amp Sokolova 2020 p 97 122 Lee 1975 p 407 417 Shapiro amp Slemrod 2003 p 381 396 Alvarez Cuadrado amp Van Long 2011 p 1489 1501 a b c Worek 2010 p 221 Forder amp Monnery 2019 p 130 145 Mulligan 2014 p 344 346 The term consumption smoothing refers to the tendency of consumers to smooth out consumption over their lifetimes effectively consumers spread out consumption over time because they want to guarantee stability and prevent diminishing marginal utility from decreasing their utility The marginal propensity to consume MPC represents how much of a dollar a consumer spends or consumes whereas the marginal propensity to save MPS represents how much of a dollar a consumer saves these units are tracking marginal decision making 1 The marginal propensity to consume MPC represents how much of a dollar a consumer spends or consumes whereas the marginal propensity to save MPS represents how much of a dollar a consumer saves these units are tracking marginal decision making 1 The marginal propensity to consume MPC represents how much of a dollar a consumer spends or consumes whereas the marginal propensity to save MPS represents how much of a dollar a consumer saves these units are tracking marginal decision making 1 Stochastic refers to the property of being well described by a random probability distribution 9 Unlike capital k labor inputs are not fixed in the short term 10 The marginal propensity to consume MPC represents how much of a dollar a consumer spends or consumes whereas the marginal propensity to save MPS represents how much of a dollar a consumer saves these units are tracking marginal decision making 1 References editFriedman Milton 1957 A Theory of Consumption Function Princeton University Press ISBN 0 691 04182 2 Meghir Konstantinos 2004 A Retrospective on Friedman s Theory of Permanent Income The Economic Journal 114 496 Oxford University Press 293 306 doi 10 1111 j 1468 0297 2004 00223 x hdl 10419 71440 JSTOR 3590064 S2CID 10847795 via JSTOR Friedman Milton Kuznets Simon 1945 Incomes from Independent Professional Practice National Bureau of Economic Research ISBN 0 87014 044 2 Carlin Wendy Soskice David 2014 Macroeconomics Institutions Instability and the Financial System Oxford University Press ISBN 9780199655793 Carroll Christopher D 2001 A Theory of the Consumption Function with and without Liquidity Constraints The Journal of Economic Perspectives 15 3 American Economic Association 23 45 doi 10 1257 jep 15 3 23 JSTOR 2696555 via JSTOR Keynes John Maynard 1936 The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money The United Kingdom Palgrave Macmillan ISBN 978 0 230 00476 4 Friedman Milton 1961 The Lag in Effect of Monetary Policy Journal of Political Economy 69 5 University of Chicago Press 447 466 doi 10 1086 258537 JSTOR 1828534 S2CID 154475740 via JSTOR Keynes John Maynard 1923 A Tract on Monetary Reform Pickle Partners Publishing ISBN 1789120713 Ireland Peter N 1995 Using the Permanent Income Hypothesis for Forecasting FRB Richmond Economic Quarterly 81 1 49 63 SSRN 2129374 via SSRN Carroll Christopher D 1997 Buffer Stock Saving and the Life Cycle Permanent Income Hypothesis The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 1 1 55 doi 10 1162 003355397555109 S2CID 14047708 Hall Robert E 1978 Stochastic Implications of the Life Cycle Permanent Income Hypothesis Theory and Evidence Journal of Political Economy 86 6 University of Chicago Press 971 987 doi 10 1086 260724 S2CID 54528038 Hall Robert E Mishkin Frederic S 1982 The Sensitivity of Consumption to Transitory Income Estimates from Panel Data on Households PDF Econometrica 50 2 461 482 doi 10 2307 1912638 JSTOR 1912638 S2CID 154542841 Bernanke Ben S 1984 Permanent Income Liquidity and Expenditure on Automobiles Evidence From Panel Data PDF The Quarterly Journal of Economics 99 3 587 614 doi 10 2307 1885966 JSTOR 1885966 S2CID 154797278 via JSTOR Flavin Marjorie A 1981 The Adjustment of Consumption to Changing Expectations About Future Income Journal of Political Economy 89 5 University of Chicago Press 974 1009 doi 10 1086 261016 S2CID 154169138 Mankiw N Gregory Shapiro Matthew D 1984 Trends Random Walks and Tests of the Permanent Income Hypothesis PDF Journal of Monetary Economics 89 5 165 174 doi 10 1016 0304 3932 85 90028 5 Souleles Nicholas S 1999 The Response of Household Consumption to Income Tax Refunds American Economic Review 89 4 947 58 doi 10 1257 aer 89 4 947 Stephens Melvin 2003 3rd of tha Month Do Social Security Recipients Smooth Consumption Between Checks PDF American Economic Review 93 1 406 422 doi 10 1257 000282803321455386 S2CID 154450192 Stafford Frank P 1974 Permanent income wealth and consumption A critique of the permanent income theory the life cycle hypothesis and related theories Econometrics 2 2 Berkeley University of California Press 195 196 doi 10 1016 0304 4076 74 90040 2 hdl 2027 42 22322 ISSN 0304 4076 via Elsevier Science Direct Runkle David E 1991 Liquidity constraints and the permanent income hypothesis Evidence from panel data Journal of Monetary Economics 27 1 Elsevier 73 98 doi 10 1016 0304 3932 91 90005 9 ISSN 0304 3932 via Elsevier Science Direct Havranek Tomas Sokolova Anna 2020 Do consumers really follow a rule of thumb Three thousand estimates from 144 studies say probably not Review of Economic Dynamics 35 Elsevier 97 122 doi 10 1016 j red 2019 05 004 hdl 10419 174182 ISSN 1094 2025 S2CID 191678223 via Elsevier Science Direct Lee Tong Hun 1975 More on Windfall Income and Consumption Journal of Political Economy 83 2 University of Chicago Press 407 417 doi 10 1086 260330 JSTOR 1830930 S2CID 153493431 via JSTOR Shapiro Matthew D Slemrod Joel 2003 Consumer Response to Tax Rebates American Economic Review 93 1 National Bureau of Economic Research 381 396 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 159 3723 doi 10 1257 000282803321455368 Alvarez Cuadrado Francisco Van Long Ngo 2011 The Relative Income Hypothesis Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 35 9 1489 1501 doi 10 1016 j jedc 2011 03 012 ISSN 0165 1889 via Elsevier Science Direct Worek Michael 2010 Nobel A Century of Prize Winners Buffalo New York Firefly Books ISBN 978 1 55407 780 9 Mulligan Robert F 2014 The Central Fallacy of Keynesian Economics Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 17 3 Mises Institute 338 364 ISSN 1936 4806 Thomas R Leighton 1985 Introductory Econometrics Theory and Applications London Longman ISBN 058229634X OCLC 10348689 Forder James Monnery Hugo 2019 Why Did Milton Friedman Win the Nobel Prize A Consideration of His Early Work on Stabilization Policy Economic Journal Watch 16 1 Fraser Institute 130 145 Mankiw N Gregory 2006 The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer Journal of Economic Perspectives 20 4 29 46 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 214 5101 doi 10 1257 jep 20 4 29 Stirzaker David 2005 Stochastic Processes and Models Oxford University Press ISBN 9780198568148 Mankiw Gregory N Taylor Timothy 2006 Principles of Microeconomics ISBN 978 0324319163 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Permanent income hypothesis amp oldid 1195802312, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.