fbpx
Wikipedia

Roman economy

The study of the Roman economy, which is, the economies of the ancient city-state of Rome and its empire during the Republican and Imperial periods remains highly speculative. There are no surviving records of business and government accounts, such as detailed reports of tax revenues, and few literary sources regarding economic activity. Instead, the study of this ancient economy is today mainly based on the surviving archeological and literary evidence that allow researchers to form conjectures based on comparisons with other more recent pre-industrial economies.

Solidus issued under Constantine II, and on the reverse Victoria, one of the last deities to appear on Roman coins, gradually transforming into an angel under Christian rule[1]

During the early centuries of the Roman Republic, it is conjectured that the economy was largely agrarian and centered on the trading of commodities such as grain and wine.[2] Financial markets were established through such trade, and financial institutions, which extended credit for personal use and public infrastructure, were established primarily by interfamily wealth.[3] In times of agricultural and cash shortfall, Roman officials and moneyers tended to respond by coining money, which happened during the prolonged crisis of the First Punic War and created economic distortion and difficulties.

Following the Punic Wars, during the late Republic and the early Roman Empire, the economy became more monetized and a more sophisticated financial system emerged.[4] Emperors issued coinage stamped with their portraits to disseminate propaganda, to create public goodwill, and to symbolize their wealth and power.[5] The Roman Imperial monetary economy often suffered bouts of inflation in part by emperors who issued money to fund high-profile imperial projects such as public building works or costly wars that offered opportunities for propaganda but little or no material gain.[4]

Emperors of the Antonine and the Severan dynasties overall debased the currency, particularly the denarius, under the pressures of meeting military payrolls.[6] Sudden inflation during the reign of Commodus damaged the credit market.[7] In the mid-200s, the supply of specie contracted sharply.[8] Conditions during the Crisis of the Third Century, such as reductions in long-distance trade, the disruption of mining operations, and the physical transfer of gold coinage outside the empire by invading enemies, greatly diminished the money supply and the banking sector by the year 300.[9] Although Roman coinage had long been fiat money or fiduciary currency, general economic anxieties came to a head under Aurelian, and bankers lost confidence in coins legitimately issued by the central government. Despite Diocletian's introduction of the gold solidus and monetary reforms, the credit market of the Empire never recovered its former robustness.[7]

Banking system edit

The setup of the banking system under the Empire allowed the exchange of extremely large sums without the physical transfer of coins, which led to fiat money. With no central bank, a professional deposit banker (argentarius, coactor argentarius, or later nummularius) received and held deposits for a fixed or indefinite term and lent money to third parties.[10] Generally, available capital exceeded the amount needed by borrowers and so loans were made and credit was extended on risky terms.[7][11] The senatorial elite were involved heavily in private lending, as both creditors and borrowers, and made loans from their personal fortunes on the basis of social connections.[4]

Banks of classical antiquity typically kept less in reserves than the full total of customers' deposits, as they had no incentive to ensure that customers' deposits would be insured in the event of a bank run.[4] It was common consensus among Romans at the time, especially by Seneca's ideologies, that anyone involved in commerce should have access to credit.[12] That tendency toward fiat money caused the money supply to fluctuate consistently.[12]

Mining and metallurgy edit

 
Landscape resulting from the ruina montium mining technique at Las Médulas, Roman Spain, one of the most important gold mines in the Roman Empire

The main mining regions of the Empire were Spain (gold, silver, copper, tin, lead); Gaul (gold, silver, iron); Britain (mainly iron, lead, tin), the Danubian provinces (gold, iron); Macedonia and Thrace (gold, silver); and Asia Minor (gold, silver, iron, tin). Intensive large-scale mining—of alluvial deposits, and by means of open-cast mining and underground mining—took place from the reign of Augustus up to the early 3rd century AD, when the instability of the Empire disrupted production. The gold mines of Dacia, for instance, were no longer available for Roman exploitation after the province was surrendered in 271. Mining seems to have resumed to some extent during the 4th century.[13]

 
World production of lead, estimated from Greenland ice cores, peaked in the 1st century AD, and strongly declined thereafter.[14] World production would only surpass Roman levels in the middle of the 18th century.

Hydraulic mining, which Pliny referred to as ruina montium ("ruin of the mountains"), allowed base and precious metals to be extracted on a proto-industrial scale.[15] The total annual iron output is estimated at 82,500 tonnes.[16] Copper was produced at an annual rate of 15,000 t,[17] and lead at 80,000 t,[18] both production levels unmatched until the Industrial Revolution;[19] Spain alone had a 40 percent share in world lead production.[20] The high lead output was a by-product of extensive silver mining which reached 200 t per annum.[21] At its peak around the mid-2nd century AD, the Roman silver stock is estimated at 10,000 t, five to ten times larger than the combined silver mass of medieval Europe and the Abbasid Caliphate around 800 AD.[22] As an indication of the scale of Roman metal production, lead pollution in the Greenland ice sheet quadrupled over its prehistoric levels during the Imperial era, and dropped again thereafter.[23]

The invention and widespread application of hydraulic mining, namely hushing and ground-sluicing, aided by the ability of the Romans to plan and execute mining operations on a large scale, allowed various base and precious metals to be extracted on a proto-industrial scale only rarely, if ever, matched until the Industrial Revolution.[24] The most common fuel by far for smelting and forging operations, as well as heating purposes, was wood and particularly charcoal, which is nearly twice as efficient.[25] In addition, coal was mined in some regions to a fairly large extent: Almost all major coalfields in Roman Britain were exploited by the late 2nd century AD, and a lively trade along the English North Sea coast developed, which extended to the continental Rhineland, where bituminous coal was already used for the smelting of iron ore.[26]

Annual metal production in metric tons
Output per annum Comment
Iron 82,500 t[27] Based on estimate of iron production at 1.5 kg per head in Roman Britain, extrapolated to population size of 55 million for entire empire[28]
Copper 15,000 t[29] Largest preindustrial producer[30]
Lead 80,000 t[31] Largest preindustrial producer[32]
Silver 11,200 t[33] At its peak around the mid-2nd century AD, Roman stock is estimated at 10,000 t, five to ten times larger than the combined silver mass of medieval Europe and the Caliphate around 800 AD.[34]
Gold 11,119 t[35] Production in Asturia, Callaecia, and Lusitania (all Iberian Peninsula) alone

Transportation and communication edit

 
The number of dated of shipwrecks discovered provides evidence of the intensity of maritime commerce in the mediterranean sea across different historical periods. One should keep in mind that ships carrying cargoes with marble and ceramic vessels are more likely to be discovered than ships carrying more perishable cargoes.

The Roman Empire completely encircled the Mediterranean, which they called "our sea" (mare nostrum).[36] Roman sailing vessels navigated the Mediterranean as well as the major rivers of the Empire, including the Guadalquivir, Ebro, Rhône, Rhine, Tiber and Nile.[37] Transport by water was preferred where possible, as moving commodities by land was more difficult[38] and much more expensive: during Roman times, travel by sea was 50 to 60 times cheaper than travel by land according to Keith Hopkins.[39] During the Roman period, sea trade in the Mediterranean reached its pre-modern peak.[40] Vehicles, wheels, and ships indicate the existence of a great number of skilled woodworkers.[41]

 
The Roman Empire in the time of Hadrian (r. 117–138), showing the network of main Roman roads

Land transport utilized the advanced system of Roman roads. The in-kind taxes paid by communities included the provision of personnel, animals, or vehicles for the cursus publicus, the state mail and transport service established by Augustus. Relay stations were located along the roads every seven to twelve Roman miles, and tended to grow into a village or trading post.[42] A mansio (plural mansiones) was a privately run service station franchised by the imperial bureaucracy for the cursus publicus. The support staff at such a facility included muleteers, secretaries, blacksmiths, cartwrights, a veterinarian, and a few military police and couriers. The distance between mansiones was determined by how far a wagon could travel in a day.[42] Mules were the animal most often used for pulling carts, travelling about 6.4 km/h.[43] As an example of the pace of communication, it took a messenger a minimum of nine days to travel to Rome from Mainz in the province of Germania Superior, even on a matter of urgency.[44] In addition to the mansiones, some taverns offered accommodations as well as food and drink; one recorded tab for a stay showed charges for wine, bread, mule feed, and the services of a prostitute.[45]

Trade and commodities edit

 
Green Roman glass cup unearthed from an Eastern Han Dynasty (25-220 AD) tomb, Guangxi, China; the first Roman glassware discovered in China, dating to the early 1st century BC, was excavated from a Western Han tomb in the southern port city of Guangzhou, most likely arriving via the Indian Ocean and South China Sea.[46]

Roman provinces traded among themselves, but trade extended outside the frontiers to regions as far away as China and India.[47] The main commodity was grain.[48] Chinese trade was mostly conducted overland through middle men along the Silk Road; Indian trade, however, also occurred by sea from Egyptian ports on the Red Sea. Also traded were olive oil, various foodstuffs, garum (fish sauce), slaves, ore and manufactured metal objects, fibres and textiles, timber, pottery, glassware, marble, papyrus, spices and materia medica, ivory, pearls, and gemstones.[49]

Though most provinces were capable of producing wine, regional varietals were desirable and wine was a central item of trade. Shortages of vin ordinaire were rare.[50] The major suppliers for the city of Rome were the west coast of Italy, southern Gaul, the Tarraconensis region of Spain, and Crete. Alexandria, the second-largest city, imported wine from Laodicea in Syria and the Aegean.[51] At the retail level, taverns or specialty wine shops (vinaria) sold wine by the jug for carryout and by the drink on-premises, with price ranges reflecting quality.[52]

Trade in the early Roman Empire allowed Rome to become as vast and great as it did. Emperor Augustus, despite his intense public and private spending, took control of trade from the government and expanded Roman influence by opening new trading markets in overseas areas such as Britain, Germany, and Africa.[53] Rome dominated trade and influence over the world in the age of the Roman Empire but could not advance in their industrial and manufacturing processes.[53] This ultimately threatened the expanding trading and commerce industries that Augustus brought about, as well as the strong standing of the Empire in the eyes of the Romans and the world.

Whereas the Roman economy was able to thrive in the first few centuries AD thanks to its advanced trade and commerce, the boom was tempered as their ways of conducting business changed drastically. Due to Augustus and the aristocracy holding the large majority of land and wealth in Rome,[53] trade and commerce in the basic everyday commodities began to decline. Trade began to only take place for the more luxurious commodities, effectively excluding the majority of Romans due to their poverty.[53] Foreign trade was also incredibly significant to the rise and complexity of the Roman economy, and the Romans traded commodities such as wine, oil, grain, salt, arms, and iron to countries primarily in the West.[53][37] When those countries came under decline in around 2nd century AD, and respective trade between them and the Roman Empire had to cease as a result, this put a dent in the strength of the Roman economy as foreign trade was a major factor of economic growth for the superfluously resourced Empire.[53] Compounded with their inability to make proper production advancements to keep up with their growing and evolving economy, these events hindered Roman trade, limited their array of commodities and harmed the economy.

Labour and occupations edit

 
Workers at a cloth-processing shop, in a painting from the fullonica of Veranius Hypsaeus in Pompeii

Inscriptions record 268 different occupations in the city of Rome, and 85 in Pompeii.[54] Professional associations or trade guilds (collegia) are attested for a wide range of occupations, including fishermen (piscatores), salt merchants (salinatores), olive oil dealers (olivarii), entertainers (scaenici), cattle dealers (pecuarii), goldsmiths (aurifices), teamsters (asinarii or muliones), and stonecutters (lapidarii).[55] These are sometimes quite specialized: one collegium at Rome was strictly limited to craftsmen who worked in ivory and citrus wood.[56]

Work performed by slaves falls into five general categories: domestic, with epitaphs recording at least 55 different household jobs; imperial or public service; urban crafts and services; agriculture; and mining.[57] Convicts provided much of the labour in the mines or quarries, where conditions were notoriously brutal.[58] In practice, there was little division of labour between slave and free,[59] and most workers were illiterate and without special skills.[60] The greatest number of common labourers were employed in agriculture: in the Italian system of industrial farming (latifundia), these may have been mostly slaves, but throughout the Empire, slave farm labour was probably less important than other forms of dependent labour by people who were technically not enslaved.[59]

Textile and clothing production was a major source of employment. Both textiles and finished garments were traded among the peoples of the Empire, whose products were often named for them or a particular town, rather like a fashion "label".[61] Better ready-to-wear was exported by businessmen (negotiatores or mercatores) who were often well-to-do residents of the production centres.[62] Finished garments might be retailed by their sales agents, who travelled to potential customers, or by vestiarii, clothing dealers who were mostly freedmen; or they might be peddled by itinerant merchants.[62] In Egypt, textile producers could run prosperous small businesses employing apprentices, free workers earning wages, and slaves.[63] The fullers (fullones) and dye workers (coloratores) had their own guilds.[64] Centonarii were guild workers who specialized in textile production and the recycling of old clothes into pieced goods.[65]

Estimates of national accounts and income distribution edit

As there are no surviving records that allow economic historians to produce reliable estimates for the national accounts of ancient Rome, thus the estimation of ancient Roman product levels remains speculative. Estimates of the gross domestic product of the Roman economy during the Principate.[66] For the sample years of 14, 100, and 150 AD, estimates of per capita GDP range from 166 to 380 sestertii.

The Roman Empire was not uniformly developed. The GDP per capita of Italy is estimated to be higher than the average of the Empire during the Principate, due to a higher degree of urbanization and trade (partly thanks to Mediterranean access compared to the provinces in the imperial periphery), and the concentration of elite income in the heartland. Other regions next to the Mediterranean, such as the Aegean and North Africa are also thought to be more developed than the imperial average in the same period.[67] Estimates of the difference between Italian income levels and the average for the Empire vary from 40,[68] to 66,[69] to 100 [70] percent higher than in the rest of the Empire.

In the Scheidel–Friesen model of Roman national accounts, the total annual income generated by the Empire is placed at nearly 20 billion sestertii, with about 5 percent extracted by the imperial government. Households in the top 1.5 percent of income distribution captured about 20 percent of income. Another 20 percent went to about 10 percent of the population who can be characterized as a non-elite middle. The remaining "vast majority" produced more than half of the total income, but lived near subsistence.[71] All cited economic historians stress the point that any estimate can only be regarded as a rough approximation to the realities of the ancient economy, given the general paucity of surviving pertinent data.

Based on the evidence left by the archaeological remains of the houses of the prosperous Roman town of Pompeii, Geoffrey Kron[72] estimates that the mean household income of Pompeii was at 7,900 sestertii, a much higher than is implied by the GDP estimates for the whole Empire. Based on the distribution of house sizes from these archaeological remains, he also estimated a distribution of income that implies that Pompeii had a much larger middle-class than would be expected in the Scheidel–Friesen model. His estimates pointed to a level of living standards in Pompeii superior to 19th century Western Europe. He concluded that existing estimates of Roman GDP should be revised upwards.

Estimates of Roman per-capita and total GDP[A]
Unit Goldsmith
1984[73]
Hopkins
1995/96[74]
Temin
2006[75]
Maddison
2007[76]
Bang
2008[77]
Scheidel/Friesen
2009[78]
Lo Cascio/Malanima
2009[68]
GDP per capita in Sestertii 380 225 166 380 229 260
Wheat equivalent (kg) 843 491 614 843 500 680
2022 dollars 1,277 1,389 2,106
Population
(Approx. year)
55 million
(14 AD)
60 million
(14 AD)
55 million
(100 AD)
44 million
(14 AD)
60 million
(150 AD)
70 million
(150 AD)

(14 AD)
Total GDP in Sestertii 20.9 billion 13.5 billion - 16.7 billion 13.7 billion 17-19 billion
Wheat equivalent (Mt) 46.4 29.5 33.8 37.1 30 50
2022 dollars $56 billion $97 billion
"–" indicates unknown value.

A ^ Decimal fractions rounded to the nearest tenth. Italic numbers not directly given by the authors; they are obtained by multiplying the respective value of GDP per capita by estimated population size.

Regional breakdown edit

 
Total GDP around 1 AD for various regions of the Roman Empire[79]
Maddison's breakdown per region (14 AD)[80]
Region Population
(thousands)
NDI per capita
(2022 dollars)
Total NDI
(millions of 2022 dollars)
Roman Europe (including Italy) 23,100 1,328 30,663
Roman Europe (excluding Italy) 16,100 1,071 17,223
Roman Asia 12,200 1,232 15,030
Roman Africa 8,700 1,212 10,550
Total Roman Empire 44,000 1,277 56,243

Angus Maddison is the only economist cited who offers a detailed breakdown of the national disposable income (NDI) of the various parts of the Roman Empire. His "highly provisional" estimate (see right) relies on a low-count of the Roman population of only 44 million at the time of the death of Augustus in 14 AD. Italia is considered to have been the richest region, due to tax transfers from the provinces and the concentration of elite income in the heartland; its NDI per capita is estimated at having been between 40%[68] and 66%[69] higher than in the rest of the empire. Besides Italy, the wealthiest province was Egypt, in terms of NDI per capita.[81]

The European NDI per capita was higher than in the Asian and African provinces if Italy is included, but without it, the rest of Europe had a lower NDI per capita than the Asian and African provinces.[80] The Hellenistic Eastern provinces (Greece, Asia Minor, Syria, Egypt) were about 20% wealthier than their mostly Latin-speaking Western counterparts, with Egypt alone being about 28% wealthier. However, Italia, which was not administered as a province, enjoyed a higher per capita income than any one of them.[82]

Taxation edit

Historians conjectured that imperial taxation under amounted to about 5% of the Empire's gross product.[83] The typical tax rate paid by individuals ranged from 2 to 5%.[84] This tax burden did not include the tax revenues levied by the local cities, called municipia in the Latin-speaking parts of the Empire and poleis in the Greek-speaking parts.[85]

The tax code was "bewildering" in its complicated system of direct and indirect taxes, some paid in cash and some in kind. Taxes might be specific to a province, or kinds of properties such as fisheries or salt evaporation ponds; they might be in effect for a limited time.[86] Tax collection was justified by the need to maintain the military,[87][88] and taxpayers sometimes got a refund if the army captured a surplus of booty.[89] In-kind taxes were accepted from less-monetized areas, particularly those who could supply grain or goods to army camps.[90]

 
Personification of the River Nile and his children, from the Temple of Serapis and Isis in Rome (1st century AD)

The primary source of direct tax revenue was individuals, who paid a poll tax and a tax on their land, construed as a tax on its produce or productive capacity.[84] Supplemental forms could be filed by those eligible for certain exemptions; for example, Egyptian farmers could register fields as fallow and tax-exempt depending on flood patterns of the Nile.[91] Tax obligations were determined by the Census, which required each head of household to appear before the presiding official and provide a head count of his household, as well as an accounting of property he owned that was suitable for agriculture or habitation.[91]

A major source of indirect-tax revenue was the portoria, customs and tolls on imports and exports, including among provinces.[84] Special taxes were levied on the slave trade. Towards the end of his reign, Augustus instituted a 4% tax on the sale of slaves,[92] which Nero shifted from the purchaser to the dealers, who responded by raising their prices.[93] An owner who manumitted a slave paid a "freedom tax", calculated at 5% of value.[94]

An inheritance tax of 5% was assessed when Roman citizens above a certain net worth left property to anyone but members of their immediate family. Revenues from the estate tax and from a 1% sales tax on auctions went towards the veterans' pension fund (aerarium militare).[84]

Low taxes helped the Roman aristocracy increase their wealth, which equalled or exceeded the revenues of the central government. An emperor sometimes replenished his treasury by confiscating the estates of the "super-rich", but in the later period, the resistance of the wealthy to paying taxes was one of the factors contributing to the collapse of the Empire.[87]

State revenues edit

Existing literary sources provide only fragmentary evidence regarding Roman state revenues. Some of the existing literary evidence is detailed as follows: With the conclusion of the Third Mithridatic War in 63 BC, the Roman Republic now incorporated the Kingdom of Pontus, Cilicia, most of Syria, and the island of Crete into its growing dominion, as well as turning the Kingdom of Judea into a client state.[95] The Roman historian Plutarch records that after Pompey's return to Rome as a renowned conqueror of the east, tablets were presented showing that state revenues had increased from 50 million denarii to 85 million, an increase from 200 to 340 million sesterces from new taxes levied.[95] Yet this was apparently roughly the size of the entire state budget of the Ptolemaic Kingdom of Hellenistic Egypt. Both Cicero and Strabo related how at the beginning of the reign of Ptolemy XII Auletes (80–51 BC) his kingdom received an annual revenue of 12,500 talents, the equivalent of 75 million denarii, or 300 million sesterces.[95] Hence, with the Roman conquest of Egypt in the Final War of the Roman Republic (32–30 BC) and transformation of Egypt into a Roman province, one would readily assume a considerable increase in state revenues was made. The revenues garnered in Egypt in 80 BC alone was seven times the amount of tax money contemporary Roman Gaul offered to the Roman coffers following its conquest by Julius Caesar, a mere 40 million sesterces.[95] Yet this was roughly the same amount of taxes Rome was able to levy from Egypt (i.e., 40 million sesterces) after its conquest by Octavian, bringing the total figure for state revenues up to 420 million (which included 40 million from newly conquered Egypt, 40 million from Gaul, and 340 million from all other provinces).[96] The whole of Roman Britain after its conquest produced only about 11 million sesterces in revenues whereas the city of Alexandria in Egypt alone generated roughly 36 million sesterces.[97] Gold mining from the Roman provinces of Hispania on the Iberian Peninsula produced roughly 80 million sesterces every year.[97]

During the 1st century AD, the total value of imported goods form the maritime trade coming from the Indian Ocean region (including the silk and spice trade) was roughly 1,000 million sesterces, allowing the Roman state to garner 250 million sesterces of that figure in tax revenue.[98] Even after the reduction in the number of Roman legions from about fifty to twenty-eight (500,000 down to 300,000 full-time soldiers and auxiliaries) the Roman state under Augustus still spent 640 million sesterces on military costs alone per annum (with total state expenses hovering around 1,000 million).[99] Raoul McLaughlin stresses that "as long as international commerce thrived, the Roman Empire could meet these high-level military costs."[99] A further 25 million sesterces in state revenues was gathered by taxing the Roman exported goods loaded on ships destined for Arabia and India (worth roughly 100 million in total).[100]

Advertising edit

 
Ancient Roman advertisement for wine

In ancient Rome businesses advertised themselves primarily through word of mouth, the usage of the trade sign, and through black or red writings inscribed on surfaces.[101] They were displayed as frescoes or mosaics. Masters would task their slaves with inscribing advertisements onto the walls of ancient Roman settlements.[102] In ancient Rome, graffiti was the equivalent of billboards.[103] Goods and products in ancient Rome may have carried inscriptions which were used to advertise other goods and services. Toy chariots were inscribed with the names of famous charioteers and lamps and bowls had images of famous gladiators.[104] It was also common for merchants to advertise their brands on amphorae.[103] These markers were known as the titulus pictus. They were used to convey information about the good and provide an easily recognizable label that attracted consumers to the product.[105] Merchants would hire orators to spread the news of their product on the streets of the Roman cities.[106] Wealthy businessmen would pay people to mention their business in literature.[103]

Roman vendors could also market based on their own unique product brand. In Pompeii merchants advertised their own brands of garum, a Roman fish sauce, based on its ingredients, processing, and the manufacturer. Two known marketing slogans from Pompeii are "essence of the best mackerel" and "best available." Wine merchants in ancient Rome used positioning, which is a marketing term referring to the place a brand holds in the customer's minds. They marketed their wine as high-class.[106]

Archaeological excavations in Pompeii revealed one advertisement that stated:[107]

The gladiators owned by Aulus Suettius Certus will fight at Pompeii on May 31. There will be an animal hunt and awnings will be provided.

— Unknown

Advertising in ancient Rome served multiple purposes. It helped businesses market their services, it promoted politicians, and it advertised games and entertainment.[106]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ J. Rufus Fears, "The Theology of Victory at Rome: Approaches and Problem," Aufstieg und Niedergang der römischen Welt II.17.2 (1981), pp. 752 and 824, and in the same volume, "The Cult of Virtues and Roman Imperial Ideology," p. 908.
  2. ^ Garnsey, Peter, et al. The Roman Empire: Economy, Society and Culture. 2nd ed., University of California Press, 2015, www.jstor.org/stable/10.1525/j.ctt9qh25h.
  3. ^ Temin, Peter. “Financial Intermediation in the Early Roman Empire.” The Journal of Economic History, vol. 64, no. 3, 2004, pp. 705–733., www.jstor.org/stable/3874817.
  4. ^ a b c d Andreau, Banking and Business in the Roman World, p. 2; Harris, "The Nature of Roman Money," n.p.
  5. ^ Bond, Shelagh (October 1957). "The Coinage of the Early Roman Empire". Greece & Rome. 4 (2): 149–159. doi:10.1017/S001738350001593X. JSTOR 642136. S2CID 163277451.
  6. ^ Harl, Coinage in the Roman Economy, 300 B.C. to A.D. 700, p. 125–136.
  7. ^ a b c Harris, "The Nature of Roman Money," in The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans, n.p.
  8. ^ Harl, Coinage in the Roman Economy, 300 B.C. to A.D. 700, pp. 128–129.
  9. ^ Harris, "The Nature of Roman Money," in The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans, n.p.; Harl, Coinage in the Roman Economy, 300 B.C. to A.D. 700, pp. 128–129.
  10. ^ Jean Andreau, Banking and Business in the Roman World (Cambridge University Press, 1999), p. 2.
  11. ^ name=":18">David Kessler and Peter Temin, "Money and Prices in the Early Roman Empire," in The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans, in The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans (Oxford University Press, 2008), n.p.
  12. ^ a b W.V. Harris, "The Nature of Roman Money," in The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans, n.p.
  13. ^ "Mining," in Late Antiquity: A Guide to the Postclassical World p. 579.
  14. ^ Hong, Sungmin; Candelone, Jean-Pierre; Patterson, Clair C.; Boutron, Claude F. (1994). "Greenland Ice Evidence of Hemispheric Lead Pollution Two Millennia Ago by Greek and Roman Civilizations". Science. 265 (5180): 1841–1843. Bibcode:1994Sci...265.1841H. doi:10.1126/science.265.5180.1841. PMID 17797222. S2CID 45080402.
  15. ^ Wilson, Andrew (2002): "Machines, Power and the Ancient Economy", The Journal of Roman Studies, Vol. 92, pp. 1–32 (17–21, 25, 32)
  16. ^ Craddock, Paul T. (2008): "Mining and Metallurgy", in: Oleson, John Peter (ed.): The Oxford Handbook of Engineering and Technology in the Classical World, Oxford University Press, ISBN 978-0-19-518731-1, p. 108; Sim, David; Ridge, Isabel (2002): Iron for the Eagles. The Iron Industry of Roman Britain, Tempus, Stroud, Gloucestershire, ISBN 0-7524-1900-5, p. 23; Healy, John F. (1978): Mining and Metallurgy in the Greek and Roman World, Thames and Hudson, London, ISBN 0-500-40035-0, p. 196. Assumes a productive capacity of c. 1.5 kg per capita. Healy, John F. (1978): Mining and Metallurgy in the Greek and Roman World, Thames and Hudson, London, ISBN 0-500-40035-0, p. 196
  17. ^ Hong, Sungmin; Candelone, Jean-Pierre; Patterson, Clair C.; Boutron, Claude F. (1996): "History of Ancient Copper Smelting Pollution During Roman and Medieval Times Recorded in Greenland Ice", Science, Vol. 272, No. 5259, pp. 246–249 (366–369); cf. also Wilson, Andrew (2002): "Machines, Power and the Ancient Economy", The Journal of Roman Studies, Vol. 92, pp. 1–32 (25–29)
  18. ^ Hong, Sungmin; Candelone, Jean-Pierre; Patterson, Clair C.; Boutron, Claude F. (1994): "Greenland Ice Evidence of Hemispheric Lead Pollution Two Millennia Ago by Greek and Roman Civilizations", Science, Vol. 265, No. 5180, pp. 1841–1843; Callataÿ, François de (2005): "The Graeco-Roman Economy in the Super Long-Run: Lead, Copper, and Shipwrecks", Journal of Roman Archaeology, Vol. 18, pp. 361–372 (361–365); Settle, Dorothy M.; Patterson, Clair C. (1980): "Lead in Albacore: Guide to Lead Pollution in Americans", Science, Vol. 207, No. 4436, pp. 1167–1176 (1170f.); cf. also Wilson, Andrew (2002): "Machines, Power and the Ancient Economy", The Journal of Roman Studies, Vol. 92, pp. 1–32 (25–29)
  19. ^ Callataÿ, François de (2005): "The Graeco-Roman Economy in the Super Long-Run: Lead, Copper, and Shipwrecks", Journal of Roman Archaeology, Vol. 18, pp. 361–372 (361–369); Hong, Sungmin; Candelone, Jean-Pierre; Patterson, Clair C.; Boutron, Claude F. (1996): "History of Ancient Copper Smelting Pollution During Roman and Medieval Times Recorded in Greenland Ice", Science, Vol. 272, No. 5259, pp. 246–249 (247, fig. 1 and 2; 248, table 1); Hong, Sungmin; Candelone, Jean-Pierre; Patterson, Clair C.; Boutron, Claude F. (1994): "Greenland Ice Evidence of Hemispheric Lead Pollution Two Millennia Ago by Greek and Roman Civilizations", Science, Vol. 265, No. 5180, pp. 1841–1843; Settle, Dorothy M.; Patterson, Clair C. (1980): "Lead in Albacore: Guide to Lead Pollution in Americans", Science, Vol. 207, No. 4436, pp. 1167–1176 (1170f.)
  20. ^ Hong, Sungmin; Candelone, Jean-Pierre; Patterson, Clair C.; Boutron, Claude F. (1994). "Greenland Ice Evidence of Hemispheric Lead Pollution Two Millennia Ago by Greek and Roman Civilizations". Science. 265 (5180): 1841–1843. Bibcode:1994Sci...265.1841H. doi:10.1126/science.265.5180.1841. PMID 17797222. S2CID 45080402.
  21. ^ Patterson, C. C. (1972): "Silver Stocks and Losses in Ancient and Medieval Times", The Economic History Review, Vol. 25, No. 2, pp. 205–235 (228, table 6); Callataÿ, François de (2005): "The Graeco-Roman Economy in the Super Long-Run: Lead, Copper, and Shipwrecks", Journal of Roman Archaeology, Vol. 18, pp. 361–372 (365f.)
  22. ^ Patterson, C. C. (1972): "Silver Stocks and Losses in Ancient and Medieval Times", The Economic History Review, Vol. 25, No. 2, pp. 205–235 (216, table 2); Callataÿ, François de (2005): "The Graeco-Roman Economy in the Super Long-Run: Lead, Copper, and Shipwrecks", Journal of Roman Archaeology, Vol. 18, pp. 361–372 (365f.)
  23. ^ Hopkins, The Political Economy of the Roman Empire, p. 197.
  24. ^ Wilson 2002, pp. 17–21, 25, 32
  25. ^ Cech 2010, p. 20
  26. ^ Smith 1997, pp. 322–324
  27. ^ Craddock 2008, p. 108; Sim, Ridge 2002, p. 23; Healy 1978, p. 196
  28. ^ Sim, Ridge 2002, p. 23; Healy 1978, p. 196
  29. ^ World output, the large bulk of which is attributed to Roman mining and smelting activities (mainly in Spain, Cyprus and Central Europe): Hong, Candelone, Patterson, Boutron 1996, p. 247; Callataÿ 2005, pp. 366–369; cf. also Wilson 2002, pp. 25–29
  30. ^ Hong, Candelone, Patterson, Boutron 1996, p. 247, fig. 1 & 2; 248, table 1; Callataÿ 2005, pp. 366–369
  31. ^ World output, the large bulk of which is attributed to Roman silver mining and smelting activities (in Central Europe, Britain, the Balkans, Greece, Asia Minor and, above all, Spain, with a 40% share in world production alone): Hong, Candelone, Patterson, Boutron 1994, p. 1841–1843; Callataÿ 2005, pp. 361–365; Settle, Patterson 1980, pp. 1170f.; cf. also Wilson 2002, pp. 25–29
  32. ^ Hong, Candelone, Patterson, Boutron 1994, p. 1841–1843; Settle, Patterson 1980, pp. 1170f.; Callataÿ 2005, pp. 361–365 follows the aforementioned authors, but cautions that the Greco-Roman levels may have already been surpassed by the end of the Middle Ages (p. 365).
  33. ^ Patterson 1972, p. 228, table 6; Callataÿ 2005, pp. 365f.; cf. also Wilson 2002, pp. 25–29
  34. ^ Patterson 1972, p. 216, table 2; Callataÿ 2005, pp. 365f.
  35. ^ Pliny: Naturalis Historia, 33.21.78, in: Wilson 2002, p. 27
  36. ^ Kevin Greene, The Archaeology of the Roman Economy p. 17.
  37. ^ a b W.V. Harris, "Trade," in The Cambridge Ancient History: The High Empire A.D. 70–192 (Cambridge University Press, 2000), vol. 11, p. 713.
  38. ^ Harris, "Trade," in CAH 11, p. 714.
  39. ^ Keith Hopkins, On the Political Economy of the Roman Empire
  40. ^ Quantifying the Roman Economy: Methods and Problems (Oxford Studies on the Roman Economy), edited by Alan Bowman, and Andrew Wilson.
  41. ^ Roger Bradley Ulrich, Roman Woodworking (Yale University Press, pp. 1–2.
  42. ^ a b Stambaugh, The Ancient Roman City, p. 253.
  43. ^ Ray Laurence, "Land Transport in Roman Italy: Costs, Practice and the Economy," in Trade, Traders and the Ancient City (Routledge, 1998), p. 129.
  44. ^ Keith Hopkins, "The Political Economy of the Roman Empire," in The Dynamics of Ancient Empires : State Power from Assyria to Byzantium (Oxford University Press, 2009), p. 187.
  45. ^ Holleran, Shopping in Ancient Rome, p. 142.
  46. ^ An, Jiayao. (2002), "When Glass Was Treasured in China," in Annette L. Juliano and Judith A. Lerner (eds), Silk Road Studies VII: Nomads, Traders, and Holy Men Along China's Silk Road, 79–94, Turnhout: Brepols Publishers, ISBN 2503521789, p. 83.
  47. ^ Harris, "Trade," in CAH 11, p. 713.
  48. ^ Harris, "Trade," in CAH 11, p. 710.
  49. ^ Harris, "Trade," in CAH 11, pp. 717–729.
  50. ^ Mireille Corbier, "Coinage, Society, and Economy," in Cambridge Ancient History: The Crisis of Empire, A.D. 193–337 (Cambridge University Press, 2005), vol. 12, p. 404; Harris, "Trade," in CAH 11, p. 719.
  51. ^ Harris, "Trade," in CAH 11, p. 720.
  52. ^ Holleran, Shopping in Ancient Rome, pp. 146–147.
  53. ^ a b c d e f West, Louis C. (November 1932). "The Economic Collapse of the Roman Empire". The Classical Journal. 28 (2): 98. JSTOR 3290252.
  54. ^ Hopkins, "The Political Economy of the Roman Empire," p. 196.
  55. ^ Verboven, "The Associative Order: Status and Ethos among Roman Businessmen," preprint pp. 18, 23.
  56. ^ Eborarii and citriarii: Verboven, "The Associative Order: Status and Ethos among Roman Businessmen," preprint p. 21.
  57. ^ "Slavery in Rome," in The Oxford Encyclopedia of Ancient Greece and Rome (Oxford University Press, 2010), p. 323.
  58. ^ "Slavery in Rome," in The Oxford Encyclopedia of Ancient Greece and Rome, p. 323.
  59. ^ a b Garnsey and Saller, The Roman Empire: Economy, Society and Culture, p. 111.
  60. ^ Peter Temin, "The Labor Market of the Early Roman Empire," Journal of Interdisciplinary History 34.1 (2004), p. 517.
  61. ^ A.H.M. Jones, "The Cloth Industry under the Roman Empire," Economic History Review 13.2 (1960), pp. 184–185.
  62. ^ a b Jones, "The Cloth Industry under the Roman Empire,"p. 192.
  63. ^ Jones, "The Cloth Industry under the Roman Empire," pp. 188–189.
  64. ^ Jones, "The Cloth Industry under the Roman Empire," pp. 190–191.
  65. ^ Vout, "The Myth of the Toga," p. 212. The college of centonarii is an elusive topic in scholarship, since they are also widely attested as urban firefighters; see Jinyu Liu, Collegia Centonariorum: The Guilds of Textile Dealers in the Roman West (Brill, 2009). Liu sees them as "primarily tradesmen and/or manufacturers engaged in the production and distribution of low- or medium-quality woolen textiles and clothing, including felt and its products."
  66. ^ Scheidel, Walter; Morris, Ian; Saller, Richard, eds. (2007): The Cambridge Economic History of the Greco-Roman World, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 978-0-521-78053-7
  67. ^ Kron Geoffrey “Comparative evidence and the reconstruction of the ancient economy: Greco-Roman housing and the level and distribution of wealth and income,” in F. de Callataÿ (ed.), Quantifying the Greco-Roman Economy and Beyond, 123-46. Bari: Edipuglia, 2014.
  68. ^ a b c Lo Cascio, Elio; Malanima, Paolo (Dec. 2009): "GDP in Pre-Modern Agrarian Economies (1–1820 AD). A Revision of the Estimates", Rivista di storia economica, Vol. 25, No. 3, pp. 391–420 (391–401)
  69. ^ a b Maddison 2007, pp. 47–51
  70. ^ Temin 2006, pp. 136
  71. ^ Scheidel, Walter; Friesen, Steven J. (2009). "The Size of the Economy and the Distribution of Income in the Roman Empire". Journal of Roman Studies. 99: 62–63. doi:10.3815/007543509789745223. S2CID 202968244.
  72. ^ Kron (2014), Comparative evidence and the reconstruction of the ancient economy: Greco-Roman housing and the level and distribution of wealth and income in F. de Callataÿ (ed.), Quantifying the Greco-Roman Economy and Beyond (Bari: Edipuglia, 2014) pp. 123-46.
  73. ^ Goldsmith 1984, pp. 263–288
  74. ^ Hopkins 1995/96, pp. 41–75. His estimates are upward revisions from Hopkins 1980, pp. 101–125, where he lays out his basic method.
  75. ^ Temin 2006, pp. 31–54
  76. ^ Maddison 2007, pp. 43–47; 50, table 1.10; 54, table 1.12
  77. ^ Bang 2008, pp. 86–91
  78. ^ Scheidel, Friesen Nov. 2009, pp. 61–91
  79. ^ "Statistics on World Population, GDP and Per Capita GDP, 1–f>". 27 July 2016.
  80. ^ a b Maddison 2007, p. 54, table 1.12
  81. ^ Maddison 2007, p. 55, table 1.14
  82. ^ Maddison 2007, p. 57, table 1.14
  83. ^ Morris, p. 183.
  84. ^ a b c d Potter (2009), p. 187.
  85. ^ Mogens Herman-Hansen (2006), Polis: An Introduction to the Ancient Greek City-State, Oxford University Press, USA.
  86. ^ Potter (2009), pp. 185–187.
  87. ^ a b Morris, p. 184.
  88. ^ Potter (2009), p. 185
  89. ^ Potter (2009), p. 185.
  90. ^ Potter (2009), p. 188.
  91. ^ a b Potter (2009), p. 186.
  92. ^ Cassius Dio 55.31.4.
  93. ^ Tacitus, Annales 13.31.2.
  94. ^ This was the vicesima libertatis, "the twentieth for freedom"; Potter (2009), p. 187.
  95. ^ a b c d Raoul McLaughlin (2014). The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean: the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa, Arabia, and India. Barnsley: Pen & Sword Military. ISBN 978-1-78346-381-7, p. 6.
  96. ^ Raoul McLaughlin (2014). The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean: the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa, Arabia, and India. Barnsley: Pen & Sword Military. ISBN 978-1-78346-381-7, p. 7.
  97. ^ a b Raoul McLaughlin (2014). The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean: the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa, Arabia, and India. Barnsley: Pen & Sword Military. ISBN 978-1-78346-381-7, p. 12.
  98. ^ Raoul McLaughlin (2014). The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean: the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa, Arabia, and India. Barnsley: Pen & Sword Military. ISBN 978-1-78346-381-7, p. 14.
  99. ^ a b Raoul McLaughlin (2014). The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean: the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa, Arabia, and India. Barnsley: Pen & Sword Military. ISBN 978-1-78346-381-7, p. 16.
  100. ^ Raoul McLaughlin (2014). The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean: the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa, Arabia, and India. Barnsley: Pen & Sword Military. ISBN 978-1-78346-381-7, p. 19.
  101. ^ Plessis, D. F. du (2000). Introduction to Public Relations and Advertising. Juta and Company Ltd. p. 80. ISBN 978-0-7021-5557-4.
  102. ^ Dekeyser, Thomas (2018). "The material geographies of advertising: Concrete objects, affective affordance and urban space". Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space. 50 (7): 1425–1442. doi:10.1177/0308518X18780374. ISSN 0308-518X. S2CID 158657199.
  103. ^ a b c Curtis, Robert I. (1984). "Product Identification and Advertising on Roman Commercial Amphorae". Ancient Society. 15/17: 209–228. ISSN 0066-1619. JSTOR 44080242.
  104. ^ Hood, John McDonald (2005). Selling the Dream: Why Advertising is Good Business. Greenwood Publishing Group. pp. 10–14. ISBN 978-0-275-98435-9.
  105. ^ Curtis, Robert I. (1991-01-01). Merchandising. Brill. ISBN 978-90-04-37726-4.
  106. ^ a b c Wharton, Chris (2014-12-05). Advertising: Critical Approaches. Routledge. pp. 26–30. ISBN 978-1-135-04357-5.
  107. ^ Williams, Brenda; Williams, Brian (2007-09-15). Staying Alive in Ancient Rome: Life in Ancient Rome. Capstone Classroom. p. 19. ISBN 978-1-4109-2897-9.

Sources edit

  • Bang, Peter Fibiger (2008): The Roman Bazaar: A Comparative Study of Trade and Markets in a Tributary Empire, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 0-521-85532-2, pp. 86–91
  • Bang, Peter Fibiger (2009). "The Ancient Economy and New Institutional Economics". The Journal of Roman Studies. 99: 194–206. doi:10.3815/007543509789744783. S2CID 144103813.
  • Callataÿ, François de (2005). "The Graeco-Roman Economy in the Super Long-Run: Lead, Copper, and Shipwrecks". Journal of Roman Archaeology. 18: 361–372. doi:10.1017/S104775940000742X. S2CID 232346123.
  • Cech, Brigitte (2010): Technik in der Antike, Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft, Darmstadt, ISBN 978-3-8062-2080-3
  • Cleere, H. & Crossley, D. (1995): The Iron industry of the Weald. 2nd edition, Merton Priory Press, Cardiff, ISBN 1-898937-04-4: republishing the 1st edition (Leicester University Press 1985) with a supplement.
  • Cleere, Henry. 1981. The Iron Industry of Roman Britain. Wealden Iron Research Group. p. 74-75
  • Craddock, Paul T. (2008): "Mining and Metallurgy", in: Oleson, John Peter (ed.): The Oxford Handbook of Engineering and Technology in the Classical World, Oxford University Press, ISBN 978-0-19-518731-1, pp. 93–120
  • Goldsmith, Raymond W. (1984). "An Estimate of the Size and Structure of the National Product of the Early Roman Empire". Review of Income and Wealth. 30 (3): 263–288. doi:10.1111/j.1475-4991.1984.tb00552.x.
  • Healy, John F. (1978): Mining and Metallurgy in the Greek and Roman World, Thames and Hudson, London, ISBN 0-500-40035-0
  • Hong, Sungmin; Candelone, Jean-Pierre; Patterson, Clair C.; Boutron, Claude F. (1994). "Greenland Ice Evidence of Hemispheric Lead Pollution Two Millennia Ago by Greek and Roman Civilizations". Science. 265 (5180): 1841–1843. Bibcode:1994Sci...265.1841H. doi:10.1126/science.265.5180.1841. PMID 17797222. S2CID 45080402.
  • Hong, Sungmin; Candelone, Jean-Pierre; Patterson, Clair C.; Boutron, Claude F. (1996). "History of Ancient Copper Smelting Pollution During Roman and Medieval Times Recorded in Greenland Ice". Science. 272 (5259): 246–249. Bibcode:1996Sci...272..246H. doi:10.1126/science.272.5259.246. S2CID 176767223.
  • Hopkins, Keith (1980). "Taxes and Trade in the Roman Empire (200 B.C.–A.D. 400)". The Journal of Roman Studies. 70: 101–125. doi:10.2307/299558. JSTOR 299558. S2CID 162507113.
  • Hopkins, Keith (1995/6): "Rome, Taxes, Rents, and Trade", Kodai, Vol. 6/7, pp. 41–75
  • Kron, Geoffrey (2014): “Comparative evidence and the reconstruction of the ancient economy: Greco-Roman housing and the level and distribution of wealth and income,” in F. de Callataÿ (ed.), Quantifying the Greco-Roman Economy and Beyond, 123-46. Bari: Edipuglia.
  • Lo Cascio, Elio; Malanima, Paolo (2009). "GDP in Pre-Modern Agrarian Economies (1–1820 AD). A Revision of the Estimates". Rivista di storia economica. 25 (3): 391–420.
  • Maddison, Angus (2007): "Contours of the World Economy, 1–2030 AD. Essays in Macro-Economic History", Oxford University Press, ISBN 978-0-19-922721-1
  • Parker, A. J. (1992): "Ancient Shipwrecks of the Mediterranean and the Roman Provinces", Archaeopress (British Archaeological Reports (BAR) International S.), ISBN 0-86054-736-1
  • Patterson, C. C. (1972). "Silver Stocks and Losses in Ancient and Medieval Times". The Economic History Review. 25 (2): 205–235. doi:10.2307/2593904. JSTOR 2593904.
  • Scheidel, Walter (April 2006): Population and Demography, Princeton/Stanford Working Papers in Classics, Version 1.0
  • Scheidel, Walter; Friesen, Steven J. (2009). "The Size of the Economy and the Distribution of Income in the Roman Empire". The Journal of Roman Studies. 99: 61–91. doi:10.3815/007543509789745223. S2CID 202968244.
  • Settle, Dorothy M.; Patterson, Clair C. (1980). "Lead in Albacore: Guide to Lead Pollution in Americans". Science. 207 (4436): 1167–1176. Bibcode:1980Sci...207.1167S. doi:10.1126/science.6986654. PMID 6986654.
  • Sim, David; Ridge, Isabel (2002): Iron for the Eagles. The Iron Industry of Roman Britain, Tempus, Stroud, Gloucestershire, ISBN 0-7524-1900-5
  • Smith, A. H. V. (1997). "Provenance of Coals from Roman Sites in England and Wales". Britannia. 28: 297–324. doi:10.2307/526770. JSTOR 526770. S2CID 164153278.
  • Temin, Peter (2006): "The Economy of the Early Roman Empire", https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/089533006776526148
  • Temin, Peter (2006): "Estimating GDP in the Early Roman Empire", Lo Cascio, Elio (ed.): Innovazione tecnica e progresso economico nel mondo romano, Edipuglia, Bari, ISBN 978-88-7228-405-6, pp. 31–54
  • Temin, Peter (2012): "The Roman Market Economy", Princeton University Press, New Jersey, United States.
  • Wilson, Andrew (2002). "Machines, Power and the Ancient Economy". The Journal of Roman Studies. 92: 1–32. doi:10.1017/s0075435800032135.

Further reading edit

  • Bowman, A. K. and Wilson, A. I. (eds) (2009), Quantifying the Roman Economy: Methods and Problems, Oxford Studies in the Roman Economy 1. Oxford University Press, Oxford
  • Bowman, A. K. and Wilson, A. I. (eds) (2012), Settlement, Urbanisation and Population, Oxford Studies in the Roman Economy 2. Oxford University Press, Oxford
  • Scheidel, Walter; Morris, Ian; Saller, Richard, eds. (2007): The Cambridge Economic History of the Greco-Roman World, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 978-0-521-78053-7
  • Temin, Peter (2006). "The Economy of the Early Roman Empire". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 20 (1): 133–151. doi:10.1257/089533006776526148. ISSN 0895-3309.
  • Temin, Peter. "Price Behaviour in the Roman Empire". - Presentation for the "Long-Term Quantification in Mediterranean Ancient History" conference in October 2009, held in Brussels, Belgium
  • The Roman Peasant Project 2009-2014. University of Pennsylvania Press. 2021. ISBN 978-1-949057-08-9.

External links edit

  • The Oxford Roman Economy Project

roman, economy, this, article, about, ancient, roman, empire, economy, economy, modern, city, rome, economy, rome, study, which, economies, ancient, city, state, rome, empire, during, republican, imperial, periods, remains, highly, speculative, there, survivin. This article is about the ancient Roman Empire s economy For the economy of the modern city of Rome see Economy of Rome The study of the Roman economy which is the economies of the ancient city state of Rome and its empire during the Republican and Imperial periods remains highly speculative There are no surviving records of business and government accounts such as detailed reports of tax revenues and few literary sources regarding economic activity Instead the study of this ancient economy is today mainly based on the surviving archeological and literary evidence that allow researchers to form conjectures based on comparisons with other more recent pre industrial economies Solidus issued under Constantine II and on the reverse Victoria one of the last deities to appear on Roman coins gradually transforming into an angel under Christian rule 1 During the early centuries of the Roman Republic it is conjectured that the economy was largely agrarian and centered on the trading of commodities such as grain and wine 2 Financial markets were established through such trade and financial institutions which extended credit for personal use and public infrastructure were established primarily by interfamily wealth 3 In times of agricultural and cash shortfall Roman officials and moneyers tended to respond by coining money which happened during the prolonged crisis of the First Punic War and created economic distortion and difficulties Following the Punic Wars during the late Republic and the early Roman Empire the economy became more monetized and a more sophisticated financial system emerged 4 Emperors issued coinage stamped with their portraits to disseminate propaganda to create public goodwill and to symbolize their wealth and power 5 The Roman Imperial monetary economy often suffered bouts of inflation in part by emperors who issued money to fund high profile imperial projects such as public building works or costly wars that offered opportunities for propaganda but little or no material gain 4 Emperors of the Antonine and the Severan dynasties overall debased the currency particularly the denarius under the pressures of meeting military payrolls 6 Sudden inflation during the reign of Commodus damaged the credit market 7 In the mid 200s the supply of specie contracted sharply 8 Conditions during the Crisis of the Third Century such as reductions in long distance trade the disruption of mining operations and the physical transfer of gold coinage outside the empire by invading enemies greatly diminished the money supply and the banking sector by the year 300 9 Although Roman coinage had long been fiat money or fiduciary currency general economic anxieties came to a head under Aurelian and bankers lost confidence in coins legitimately issued by the central government Despite Diocletian s introduction of the gold solidus and monetary reforms the credit market of the Empire never recovered its former robustness 7 Contents 1 Banking system 2 Mining and metallurgy 3 Transportation and communication 4 Trade and commodities 5 Labour and occupations 6 Estimates of national accounts and income distribution 6 1 Regional breakdown 6 2 Taxation 7 State revenues 8 Advertising 9 See also 10 References 11 Sources 12 Further reading 13 External linksBanking system editMain article Banking in ancient Rome The setup of the banking system under the Empire allowed the exchange of extremely large sums without the physical transfer of coins which led to fiat money With no central bank a professional deposit banker argentarius coactor argentarius or later nummularius received and held deposits for a fixed or indefinite term and lent money to third parties 10 Generally available capital exceeded the amount needed by borrowers and so loans were made and credit was extended on risky terms 7 11 The senatorial elite were involved heavily in private lending as both creditors and borrowers and made loans from their personal fortunes on the basis of social connections 4 Banks of classical antiquity typically kept less in reserves than the full total of customers deposits as they had no incentive to ensure that customers deposits would be insured in the event of a bank run 4 It was common consensus among Romans at the time especially by Seneca s ideologies that anyone involved in commerce should have access to credit 12 That tendency toward fiat money caused the money supply to fluctuate consistently 12 Mining and metallurgy editMain articles Mining in ancient Rome and Roman metallurgy nbsp Landscape resulting from the ruina montium mining technique at Las Medulas Roman Spain one of the most important gold mines in the Roman EmpireThe main mining regions of the Empire were Spain gold silver copper tin lead Gaul gold silver iron Britain mainly iron lead tin the Danubian provinces gold iron Macedonia and Thrace gold silver and Asia Minor gold silver iron tin Intensive large scale mining of alluvial deposits and by means of open cast mining and underground mining took place from the reign of Augustus up to the early 3rd century AD when the instability of the Empire disrupted production The gold mines of Dacia for instance were no longer available for Roman exploitation after the province was surrendered in 271 Mining seems to have resumed to some extent during the 4th century 13 nbsp World production of lead estimated from Greenland ice cores peaked in the 1st century AD and strongly declined thereafter 14 World production would only surpass Roman levels in the middle of the 18th century Hydraulic mining which Pliny referred to as ruina montium ruin of the mountains allowed base and precious metals to be extracted on a proto industrial scale 15 The total annual iron output is estimated at 82 500 tonnes 16 Copper was produced at an annual rate of 15 000 t 17 and lead at 80 000 t 18 both production levels unmatched until the Industrial Revolution 19 Spain alone had a 40 percent share in world lead production 20 The high lead output was a by product of extensive silver mining which reached 200 t per annum 21 At its peak around the mid 2nd century AD the Roman silver stock is estimated at 10 000 t five to ten times larger than the combined silver mass of medieval Europe and the Abbasid Caliphate around 800 AD 22 As an indication of the scale of Roman metal production lead pollution in the Greenland ice sheet quadrupled over its prehistoric levels during the Imperial era and dropped again thereafter 23 The invention and widespread application of hydraulic mining namely hushing and ground sluicing aided by the ability of the Romans to plan and execute mining operations on a large scale allowed various base and precious metals to be extracted on a proto industrial scale only rarely if ever matched until the Industrial Revolution 24 The most common fuel by far for smelting and forging operations as well as heating purposes was wood and particularly charcoal which is nearly twice as efficient 25 In addition coal was mined in some regions to a fairly large extent Almost all major coalfields in Roman Britain were exploited by the late 2nd century AD and a lively trade along the English North Sea coast developed which extended to the continental Rhineland where bituminous coal was already used for the smelting of iron ore 26 Annual metal production in metric tons Output per annum CommentIron 82 500 t 27 Based on estimate of iron production at 1 5 kg per head in Roman Britain extrapolated to population size of 55 million for entire empire 28 Copper 15 000 t 29 Largest preindustrial producer 30 Lead 80 000 t 31 Largest preindustrial producer 32 Silver 11 200 t 33 At its peak around the mid 2nd century AD Roman stock is estimated at 10 000 t five to ten times larger than the combined silver mass of medieval Europe and the Caliphate around 800 AD 34 Gold 11 11 9 t 35 Production in Asturia Callaecia and Lusitania all Iberian Peninsula aloneTransportation and communication edit nbsp The number of dated of shipwrecks discovered provides evidence of the intensity of maritime commerce in the mediterranean sea across different historical periods One should keep in mind that ships carrying cargoes with marble and ceramic vessels are more likely to be discovered than ships carrying more perishable cargoes See also Roman roadsThe Roman Empire completely encircled the Mediterranean which they called our sea mare nostrum 36 Roman sailing vessels navigated the Mediterranean as well as the major rivers of the Empire including the Guadalquivir Ebro Rhone Rhine Tiber and Nile 37 Transport by water was preferred where possible as moving commodities by land was more difficult 38 and much more expensive during Roman times travel by sea was 50 to 60 times cheaper than travel by land according to Keith Hopkins 39 During the Roman period sea trade in the Mediterranean reached its pre modern peak 40 Vehicles wheels and ships indicate the existence of a great number of skilled woodworkers 41 nbsp The Roman Empire in the time of Hadrian r 117 138 showing the network of main Roman roadsLand transport utilized the advanced system of Roman roads The in kind taxes paid by communities included the provision of personnel animals or vehicles for the cursus publicus the state mail and transport service established by Augustus Relay stations were located along the roads every seven to twelve Roman miles and tended to grow into a village or trading post 42 A mansio plural mansiones was a privately run service station franchised by the imperial bureaucracy for the cursus publicus The support staff at such a facility included muleteers secretaries blacksmiths cartwrights a veterinarian and a few military police and couriers The distance between mansiones was determined by how far a wagon could travel in a day 42 Mules were the animal most often used for pulling carts travelling about 6 4 km h 43 As an example of the pace of communication it took a messenger a minimum of nine days to travel to Rome from Mainz in the province of Germania Superior even on a matter of urgency 44 In addition to the mansiones some taverns offered accommodations as well as food and drink one recorded tab for a stay showed charges for wine bread mule feed and the services of a prostitute 45 Trade and commodities editMain article Roman commerce Further information Indo Roman trade and relations and Sino Roman relations nbsp Green Roman glass cup unearthed from an Eastern Han Dynasty 25 220 AD tomb Guangxi China the first Roman glassware discovered in China dating to the early 1st century BC was excavated from a Western Han tomb in the southern port city of Guangzhou most likely arriving via the Indian Ocean and South China Sea 46 Roman provinces traded among themselves but trade extended outside the frontiers to regions as far away as China and India 47 The main commodity was grain 48 Chinese trade was mostly conducted overland through middle men along the Silk Road Indian trade however also occurred by sea from Egyptian ports on the Red Sea Also traded were olive oil various foodstuffs garum fish sauce slaves ore and manufactured metal objects fibres and textiles timber pottery glassware marble papyrus spices and materia medica ivory pearls and gemstones 49 Though most provinces were capable of producing wine regional varietals were desirable and wine was a central item of trade Shortages of vin ordinaire were rare 50 The major suppliers for the city of Rome were the west coast of Italy southern Gaul the Tarraconensis region of Spain and Crete Alexandria the second largest city imported wine from Laodicea in Syria and the Aegean 51 At the retail level taverns or specialty wine shops vinaria sold wine by the jug for carryout and by the drink on premises with price ranges reflecting quality 52 Trade in the early Roman Empire allowed Rome to become as vast and great as it did Emperor Augustus despite his intense public and private spending took control of trade from the government and expanded Roman influence by opening new trading markets in overseas areas such as Britain Germany and Africa 53 Rome dominated trade and influence over the world in the age of the Roman Empire but could not advance in their industrial and manufacturing processes 53 This ultimately threatened the expanding trading and commerce industries that Augustus brought about as well as the strong standing of the Empire in the eyes of the Romans and the world Whereas the Roman economy was able to thrive in the first few centuries AD thanks to its advanced trade and commerce the boom was tempered as their ways of conducting business changed drastically Due to Augustus and the aristocracy holding the large majority of land and wealth in Rome 53 trade and commerce in the basic everyday commodities began to decline Trade began to only take place for the more luxurious commodities effectively excluding the majority of Romans due to their poverty 53 Foreign trade was also incredibly significant to the rise and complexity of the Roman economy and the Romans traded commodities such as wine oil grain salt arms and iron to countries primarily in the West 53 37 When those countries came under decline in around 2nd century AD and respective trade between them and the Roman Empire had to cease as a result this put a dent in the strength of the Roman economy as foreign trade was a major factor of economic growth for the superfluously resourced Empire 53 Compounded with their inability to make proper production advancements to keep up with their growing and evolving economy these events hindered Roman trade limited their array of commodities and harmed the economy Labour and occupations edit nbsp Workers at a cloth processing shop in a painting from the fullonica of Veranius Hypsaeus in PompeiiInscriptions record 268 different occupations in the city of Rome and 85 in Pompeii 54 Professional associations or trade guilds collegia are attested for a wide range of occupations including fishermen piscatores salt merchants salinatores olive oil dealers olivarii entertainers scaenici cattle dealers pecuarii goldsmiths aurifices teamsters asinarii or muliones and stonecutters lapidarii 55 These are sometimes quite specialized one collegium at Rome was strictly limited to craftsmen who worked in ivory and citrus wood 56 Work performed by slaves falls into five general categories domestic with epitaphs recording at least 55 different household jobs imperial or public service urban crafts and services agriculture and mining 57 Convicts provided much of the labour in the mines or quarries where conditions were notoriously brutal 58 In practice there was little division of labour between slave and free 59 and most workers were illiterate and without special skills 60 The greatest number of common labourers were employed in agriculture in the Italian system of industrial farming latifundia these may have been mostly slaves but throughout the Empire slave farm labour was probably less important than other forms of dependent labour by people who were technically not enslaved 59 Textile and clothing production was a major source of employment Both textiles and finished garments were traded among the peoples of the Empire whose products were often named for them or a particular town rather like a fashion label 61 Better ready to wear was exported by businessmen negotiatores or mercatores who were often well to do residents of the production centres 62 Finished garments might be retailed by their sales agents who travelled to potential customers or by vestiarii clothing dealers who were mostly freedmen or they might be peddled by itinerant merchants 62 In Egypt textile producers could run prosperous small businesses employing apprentices free workers earning wages and slaves 63 The fullers fullones and dye workers coloratores had their own guilds 64 Centonarii were guild workers who specialized in textile production and the recycling of old clothes into pieced goods 65 Estimates of national accounts and income distribution editAs there are no surviving records that allow economic historians to produce reliable estimates for the national accounts of ancient Rome thus the estimation of ancient Roman product levels remains speculative Estimates of the gross domestic product of the Roman economy during the Principate 66 For the sample years of 14 100 and 150 AD estimates of per capita GDP range from 166 to 380 sestertii The Roman Empire was not uniformly developed The GDP per capita of Italy is estimated to be higher than the average of the Empire during the Principate due to a higher degree of urbanization and trade partly thanks to Mediterranean access compared to the provinces in the imperial periphery and the concentration of elite income in the heartland Other regions next to the Mediterranean such as the Aegean and North Africa are also thought to be more developed than the imperial average in the same period 67 Estimates of the difference between Italian income levels and the average for the Empire vary from 40 68 to 66 69 to 100 70 percent higher than in the rest of the Empire In the Scheidel Friesen model of Roman national accounts the total annual income generated by the Empire is placed at nearly 20 billion sestertii with about 5 percent extracted by the imperial government Households in the top 1 5 percent of income distribution captured about 20 percent of income Another 20 percent went to about 10 percent of the population who can be characterized as a non elite middle The remaining vast majority produced more than half of the total income but lived near subsistence 71 All cited economic historians stress the point that any estimate can only be regarded as a rough approximation to the realities of the ancient economy given the general paucity of surviving pertinent data Based on the evidence left by the archaeological remains of the houses of the prosperous Roman town of Pompeii Geoffrey Kron 72 estimates that the mean household income of Pompeii was at 7 900 sestertii a much higher than is implied by the GDP estimates for the whole Empire Based on the distribution of house sizes from these archaeological remains he also estimated a distribution of income that implies that Pompeii had a much larger middle class than would be expected in the Scheidel Friesen model His estimates pointed to a level of living standards in Pompeii superior to 19th century Western Europe He concluded that existing estimates of Roman GDP should be revised upwards Estimates of Roman per capita and total GDP A Unit Goldsmith1984 73 Hopkins1995 96 74 Temin2006 75 Maddison2007 76 Bang2008 77 Scheidel Friesen2009 78 Lo Cascio Malanima2009 68 GDP per capita in Sestertii 380 225 166 380 229 260 Wheat equivalent kg 843 491 614 843 500 680 2022 dollars 1 277 1 389 2 106Population Approx year 55 million 14 AD 60 million 14 AD 55 million 100 AD 44 million 14 AD 60 million 150 AD 70 million 150 AD 14 AD Total GDP in Sestertii 20 9 billion 13 5 billion 16 7 billion 13 7 billion 17 19 billion Wheat equivalent Mt 46 4 29 5 33 8 37 1 30 50 2022 dollars 56 billion 97 billion indicates unknown value A Decimal fractions rounded to the nearest tenth Italic numbers not directly given by the authors they are obtained by multiplying the respective value of GDP per capita by estimated population size Regional breakdown edit nbsp Total GDP around 1 AD for various regions of the Roman Empire 79 Maddison s breakdown per region 14 AD 80 Region Population thousands NDI per capita 2022 dollars Total NDI millions of 2022 dollars Roman Europe including Italy 23 100 1 328 30 663Roman Europe excluding Italy 16 100 1 071 17 223Roman Asia 12 200 1 232 15 030Roman Africa 8 700 1 212 10 550Total Roman Empire 44 000 1 277 56 243Angus Maddison is the only economist cited who offers a detailed breakdown of the national disposable income NDI of the various parts of the Roman Empire His highly provisional estimate see right relies on a low count of the Roman population of only 44 million at the time of the death of Augustus in 14 AD Italia is considered to have been the richest region due to tax transfers from the provinces and the concentration of elite income in the heartland its NDI per capita is estimated at having been between 40 68 and 66 69 higher than in the rest of the empire Besides Italy the wealthiest province was Egypt in terms of NDI per capita 81 The European NDI per capita was higher than in the Asian and African provinces if Italy is included but without it the rest of Europe had a lower NDI per capita than the Asian and African provinces 80 The Hellenistic Eastern provinces Greece Asia Minor Syria Egypt were about 20 wealthier than their mostly Latin speaking Western counterparts with Egypt alone being about 28 wealthier However Italia which was not administered as a province enjoyed a higher per capita income than any one of them 82 Taxation edit Main article Taxation in ancient Rome Historians conjectured that imperial taxation under amounted to about 5 of the Empire s gross product 83 The typical tax rate paid by individuals ranged from 2 to 5 84 This tax burden did not include the tax revenues levied by the local cities called municipia in the Latin speaking parts of the Empire and poleis in the Greek speaking parts 85 The tax code was bewildering in its complicated system of direct and indirect taxes some paid in cash and some in kind Taxes might be specific to a province or kinds of properties such as fisheries or salt evaporation ponds they might be in effect for a limited time 86 Tax collection was justified by the need to maintain the military 87 88 and taxpayers sometimes got a refund if the army captured a surplus of booty 89 In kind taxes were accepted from less monetized areas particularly those who could supply grain or goods to army camps 90 nbsp Personification of the River Nile and his children from the Temple of Serapis and Isis in Rome 1st century AD The primary source of direct tax revenue was individuals who paid a poll tax and a tax on their land construed as a tax on its produce or productive capacity 84 Supplemental forms could be filed by those eligible for certain exemptions for example Egyptian farmers could register fields as fallow and tax exempt depending on flood patterns of the Nile 91 Tax obligations were determined by the Census which required each head of household to appear before the presiding official and provide a head count of his household as well as an accounting of property he owned that was suitable for agriculture or habitation 91 A major source of indirect tax revenue was the portoria customs and tolls on imports and exports including among provinces 84 Special taxes were levied on the slave trade Towards the end of his reign Augustus instituted a 4 tax on the sale of slaves 92 which Nero shifted from the purchaser to the dealers who responded by raising their prices 93 An owner who manumitted a slave paid a freedom tax calculated at 5 of value 94 An inheritance tax of 5 was assessed when Roman citizens above a certain net worth left property to anyone but members of their immediate family Revenues from the estate tax and from a 1 sales tax on auctions went towards the veterans pension fund aerarium militare 84 Low taxes helped the Roman aristocracy increase their wealth which equalled or exceeded the revenues of the central government An emperor sometimes replenished his treasury by confiscating the estates of the super rich but in the later period the resistance of the wealthy to paying taxes was one of the factors contributing to the collapse of the Empire 87 State revenues editExisting literary sources provide only fragmentary evidence regarding Roman state revenues Some of the existing literary evidence is detailed as follows With the conclusion of the Third Mithridatic War in 63 BC the Roman Republic now incorporated the Kingdom of Pontus Cilicia most of Syria and the island of Crete into its growing dominion as well as turning the Kingdom of Judea into a client state 95 The Roman historian Plutarch records that after Pompey s return to Rome as a renowned conqueror of the east tablets were presented showing that state revenues had increased from 50 million denarii to 85 million an increase from 200 to 340 million sesterces from new taxes levied 95 Yet this was apparently roughly the size of the entire state budget of the Ptolemaic Kingdom of Hellenistic Egypt Both Cicero and Strabo related how at the beginning of the reign of Ptolemy XII Auletes 80 51 BC his kingdom received an annual revenue of 12 500 talents the equivalent of 75 million denarii or 300 million sesterces 95 Hence with the Roman conquest of Egypt in the Final War of the Roman Republic 32 30 BC and transformation of Egypt into a Roman province one would readily assume a considerable increase in state revenues was made The revenues garnered in Egypt in 80 BC alone was seven times the amount of tax money contemporary Roman Gaul offered to the Roman coffers following its conquest by Julius Caesar a mere 40 million sesterces 95 Yet this was roughly the same amount of taxes Rome was able to levy from Egypt i e 40 million sesterces after its conquest by Octavian bringing the total figure for state revenues up to 420 million which included 40 million from newly conquered Egypt 40 million from Gaul and 340 million from all other provinces 96 The whole of Roman Britain after its conquest produced only about 11 million sesterces in revenues whereas the city of Alexandria in Egypt alone generated roughly 36 million sesterces 97 Gold mining from the Roman provinces of Hispania on the Iberian Peninsula produced roughly 80 million sesterces every year 97 During the 1st century AD the total value of imported goods form the maritime trade coming from the Indian Ocean region including the silk and spice trade was roughly 1 000 million sesterces allowing the Roman state to garner 250 million sesterces of that figure in tax revenue 98 Even after the reduction in the number of Roman legions from about fifty to twenty eight 500 000 down to 300 000 full time soldiers and auxiliaries the Roman state under Augustus still spent 640 million sesterces on military costs alone per annum with total state expenses hovering around 1 000 million 99 Raoul McLaughlin stresses that as long as international commerce thrived the Roman Empire could meet these high level military costs 99 A further 25 million sesterces in state revenues was gathered by taxing the Roman exported goods loaded on ships destined for Arabia and India worth roughly 100 million in total 100 Advertising edit nbsp Ancient Roman advertisement for wineIn ancient Rome businesses advertised themselves primarily through word of mouth the usage of the trade sign and through black or red writings inscribed on surfaces 101 They were displayed as frescoes or mosaics Masters would task their slaves with inscribing advertisements onto the walls of ancient Roman settlements 102 In ancient Rome graffiti was the equivalent of billboards 103 Goods and products in ancient Rome may have carried inscriptions which were used to advertise other goods and services Toy chariots were inscribed with the names of famous charioteers and lamps and bowls had images of famous gladiators 104 It was also common for merchants to advertise their brands on amphorae 103 These markers were known as the titulus pictus They were used to convey information about the good and provide an easily recognizable label that attracted consumers to the product 105 Merchants would hire orators to spread the news of their product on the streets of the Roman cities 106 Wealthy businessmen would pay people to mention their business in literature 103 Roman vendors could also market based on their own unique product brand In Pompeii merchants advertised their own brands of garum a Roman fish sauce based on its ingredients processing and the manufacturer Two known marketing slogans from Pompeii are essence of the best mackerel and best available Wine merchants in ancient Rome used positioning which is a marketing term referring to the place a brand holds in the customer s minds They marketed their wine as high class 106 Archaeological excavations in Pompeii revealed one advertisement that stated 107 The gladiators owned by Aulus Suettius Certus will fight at Pompeii on May 31 There will be an animal hunt and awnings will be provided UnknownAdvertising in ancient Rome served multiple purposes It helped businesses market their services it promoted politicians and it advertised games and entertainment 106 See also edit nbsp Ancient Rome portalAgriculture in ancient Rome Roman finance Roman currency Roman Republican currency Roman provincial currency Ancient Greek economy Byzantine economyReferences edit J Rufus Fears The Theology of Victory at Rome Approaches and Problem Aufstieg und Niedergang der romischen Welt II 17 2 1981 pp 752 and 824 and in the same volume The Cult of Virtues and Roman Imperial Ideology p 908 Garnsey Peter et al The Roman Empire Economy Society and Culture 2nd ed University of California Press 2015 www jstor org stable 10 1525 j ctt9qh25h Temin Peter Financial Intermediation in the Early Roman Empire The Journal of Economic History vol 64 no 3 2004 pp 705 733 www jstor org stable 3874817 a b c d Andreau Banking and Business in the Roman World p 2 Harris The Nature of Roman Money n p Bond Shelagh October 1957 The Coinage of the Early Roman Empire Greece amp Rome 4 2 149 159 doi 10 1017 S001738350001593X JSTOR 642136 S2CID 163277451 Harl Coinage in the Roman Economy 300 B C to A D 700 p 125 136 a b c Harris The Nature of Roman Money in The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans n p Harl Coinage in the Roman Economy 300 B C to A D 700 pp 128 129 Harris The Nature of Roman Money in The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans n p Harl Coinage in the Roman Economy 300 B C to A D 700 pp 128 129 Jean Andreau Banking and Business in the Roman World Cambridge University Press 1999 p 2 name 18 gt David Kessler and Peter Temin Money and Prices in the Early Roman Empire in The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans in The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans Oxford University Press 2008 n p a b W V Harris The Nature of Roman Money in The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans n p Mining in Late Antiquity A Guide to the Postclassical World p 579 Hong Sungmin Candelone Jean Pierre Patterson Clair C Boutron Claude F 1994 Greenland Ice Evidence of Hemispheric Lead Pollution Two Millennia Ago by Greek and Roman Civilizations Science 265 5180 1841 1843 Bibcode 1994Sci 265 1841H doi 10 1126 science 265 5180 1841 PMID 17797222 S2CID 45080402 Wilson Andrew 2002 Machines Power and the Ancient Economy The Journal of Roman Studies Vol 92 pp 1 32 17 21 25 32 Craddock Paul T 2008 Mining and Metallurgy in Oleson John Peter ed The Oxford Handbook of Engineering and Technology in the Classical World Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 518731 1 p 108 Sim David Ridge Isabel 2002 Iron for the Eagles The Iron Industry of Roman Britain Tempus Stroud Gloucestershire ISBN 0 7524 1900 5 p 23 Healy John F 1978 Mining and Metallurgy in the Greek and Roman World Thames and Hudson London ISBN 0 500 40035 0 p 196 Assumes a productive capacity of c 1 5 kg per capita Healy John F 1978 Mining and Metallurgy in the Greek and Roman World Thames and Hudson London ISBN 0 500 40035 0 p 196 Hong Sungmin Candelone Jean Pierre Patterson Clair C Boutron Claude F 1996 History of Ancient Copper Smelting Pollution During Roman and Medieval Times Recorded in Greenland Ice Science Vol 272 No 5259 pp 246 249 366 369 cf also Wilson Andrew 2002 Machines Power and the Ancient Economy The Journal of Roman Studies Vol 92 pp 1 32 25 29 Hong Sungmin Candelone Jean Pierre Patterson Clair C Boutron Claude F 1994 Greenland Ice Evidence of Hemispheric Lead Pollution Two Millennia Ago by Greek and Roman Civilizations Science Vol 265 No 5180 pp 1841 1843 Callatay Francois de 2005 The Graeco Roman Economy in the Super Long Run Lead Copper and Shipwrecks Journal of Roman Archaeology Vol 18 pp 361 372 361 365 Settle Dorothy M Patterson Clair C 1980 Lead in Albacore Guide to Lead Pollution in Americans Science Vol 207 No 4436 pp 1167 1176 1170f cf also Wilson Andrew 2002 Machines Power and the Ancient Economy The Journal of Roman Studies Vol 92 pp 1 32 25 29 Callatay Francois de 2005 The Graeco Roman Economy in the Super Long Run Lead Copper and Shipwrecks Journal of Roman Archaeology Vol 18 pp 361 372 361 369 Hong Sungmin Candelone Jean Pierre Patterson Clair C Boutron Claude F 1996 History of Ancient Copper Smelting Pollution During Roman and Medieval Times Recorded in Greenland Ice Science Vol 272 No 5259 pp 246 249 247 fig 1 and 2 248 table 1 Hong Sungmin Candelone Jean Pierre Patterson Clair C Boutron Claude F 1994 Greenland Ice Evidence of Hemispheric Lead Pollution Two Millennia Ago by Greek and Roman Civilizations Science Vol 265 No 5180 pp 1841 1843 Settle Dorothy M Patterson Clair C 1980 Lead in Albacore Guide to Lead Pollution in Americans Science Vol 207 No 4436 pp 1167 1176 1170f Hong Sungmin Candelone Jean Pierre Patterson Clair C Boutron Claude F 1994 Greenland Ice Evidence of Hemispheric Lead Pollution Two Millennia Ago by Greek and Roman Civilizations Science 265 5180 1841 1843 Bibcode 1994Sci 265 1841H doi 10 1126 science 265 5180 1841 PMID 17797222 S2CID 45080402 Patterson C C 1972 Silver Stocks and Losses in Ancient and Medieval Times The Economic History Review Vol 25 No 2 pp 205 235 228 table 6 Callatay Francois de 2005 The Graeco Roman Economy in the Super Long Run Lead Copper and Shipwrecks Journal of Roman Archaeology Vol 18 pp 361 372 365f Patterson C C 1972 Silver Stocks and Losses in Ancient and Medieval Times The Economic History Review Vol 25 No 2 pp 205 235 216 table 2 Callatay Francois de 2005 The Graeco Roman Economy in the Super Long Run Lead Copper and Shipwrecks Journal of Roman Archaeology Vol 18 pp 361 372 365f Hopkins The Political Economy of the Roman Empire p 197 Wilson 2002 pp 17 21 25 32 Cech 2010 p 20 Smith 1997 pp 322 324 Craddock 2008 p 108 Sim Ridge 2002 p 23 Healy 1978 p 196 Sim Ridge 2002 p 23 Healy 1978 p 196 World output the large bulk of which is attributed to Roman mining and smelting activities mainly in Spain Cyprus and Central Europe Hong Candelone Patterson Boutron 1996 p 247 Callatay 2005 pp 366 369 cf also Wilson 2002 pp 25 29 Hong Candelone Patterson Boutron 1996 p 247 fig 1 amp 2 248 table 1 Callatay 2005 pp 366 369 World output the large bulk of which is attributed to Roman silver mining and smelting activities in Central Europe Britain the Balkans Greece Asia Minor and above all Spain with a 40 share in world production alone Hong Candelone Patterson Boutron 1994 p 1841 1843 Callatay 2005 pp 361 365 Settle Patterson 1980 pp 1170f cf also Wilson 2002 pp 25 29 Hong Candelone Patterson Boutron 1994 p 1841 1843 Settle Patterson 1980 pp 1170f Callatay 2005 pp 361 365 follows the aforementioned authors but cautions that the Greco Roman levels may have already been surpassed by the end of the Middle Ages p 365 Patterson 1972 p 228 table 6 Callatay 2005 pp 365f cf also Wilson 2002 pp 25 29 Patterson 1972 p 216 table 2 Callatay 2005 pp 365f Pliny Naturalis Historia 33 21 78 in Wilson 2002 p 27 Kevin Greene The Archaeology of the Roman Economy p 17 a b W V Harris Trade in The Cambridge Ancient History The High Empire A D 70 192 Cambridge University Press 2000 vol 11 p 713 Harris Trade in CAH 11 p 714 Keith Hopkins On the Political Economy of the Roman Empire Quantifying the Roman Economy Methods and Problems Oxford Studies on the Roman Economy edited by Alan Bowman and Andrew Wilson Roger Bradley Ulrich Roman Woodworking Yale University Press pp 1 2 a b Stambaugh The Ancient Roman City p 253 Ray Laurence Land Transport in Roman Italy Costs Practice and the Economy in Trade Traders and the Ancient City Routledge 1998 p 129 Keith Hopkins The Political Economy of the Roman Empire in The Dynamics of Ancient Empires State Power from Assyria to Byzantium Oxford University Press 2009 p 187 Holleran Shopping in Ancient Rome p 142 An Jiayao 2002 When Glass Was Treasured in China in Annette L Juliano and Judith A Lerner eds Silk Road Studies VII Nomads Traders and Holy Men Along China s Silk Road 79 94 Turnhout Brepols Publishers ISBN 2503521789 p 83 Harris Trade in CAH 11 p 713 Harris Trade in CAH 11 p 710 Harris Trade in CAH 11 pp 717 729 Mireille Corbier Coinage Society and Economy in Cambridge Ancient History The Crisis of Empire A D 193 337 Cambridge University Press 2005 vol 12 p 404 Harris Trade in CAH 11 p 719 Harris Trade in CAH 11 p 720 Holleran Shopping in Ancient Rome pp 146 147 a b c d e f West Louis C November 1932 The Economic Collapse of the Roman Empire The Classical Journal 28 2 98 JSTOR 3290252 Hopkins The Political Economy of the Roman Empire p 196 Verboven The Associative Order Status and Ethos among Roman Businessmen preprint pp 18 23 Eborarii and citriarii Verboven The Associative Order Status and Ethos among Roman Businessmen preprint p 21 Slavery in Rome in The Oxford Encyclopedia of Ancient Greece and Rome Oxford University Press 2010 p 323 Slavery in Rome in The Oxford Encyclopedia of Ancient Greece and Rome p 323 a b Garnsey and Saller The Roman Empire Economy Society and Culture p 111 Peter Temin The Labor Market of the Early Roman Empire Journal of Interdisciplinary History 34 1 2004 p 517 A H M Jones The Cloth Industry under the Roman Empire Economic History Review 13 2 1960 pp 184 185 a b Jones The Cloth Industry under the Roman Empire p 192 Jones The Cloth Industry under the Roman Empire pp 188 189 Jones The Cloth Industry under the Roman Empire pp 190 191 Vout The Myth of the Toga p 212 The college of centonarii is an elusive topic in scholarship since they are also widely attested as urban firefighters see Jinyu Liu Collegia Centonariorum The Guilds of Textile Dealers in the Roman West Brill 2009 Liu sees them as primarily tradesmen and or manufacturers engaged in the production and distribution of low or medium quality woolen textiles and clothing including felt and its products Scheidel Walter Morris Ian Saller Richard eds 2007 The Cambridge Economic History of the Greco Roman World Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 78053 7 Kron Geoffrey Comparative evidence and the reconstruction of the ancient economy Greco Roman housing and the level and distribution of wealth and income in F de Callatay ed Quantifying the Greco Roman Economy and Beyond 123 46 Bari Edipuglia 2014 a b c Lo Cascio Elio Malanima Paolo Dec 2009 GDP in Pre Modern Agrarian Economies 1 1820 AD A Revision of the Estimates Rivista di storia economica Vol 25 No 3 pp 391 420 391 401 a b Maddison 2007 pp 47 51 Temin 2006 pp 136 Scheidel Walter Friesen Steven J 2009 The Size of the Economy and the Distribution of Income in the Roman Empire Journal of Roman Studies 99 62 63 doi 10 3815 007543509789745223 S2CID 202968244 Kron 2014 Comparative evidence and the reconstruction of the ancient economy Greco Roman housing and the level and distribution of wealth and income in F de Callatay ed Quantifying the Greco Roman Economy and Beyond Bari Edipuglia 2014 pp 123 46 Goldsmith 1984 pp 263 288 Hopkins 1995 96 pp 41 75 His estimates are upward revisions from Hopkins 1980 pp 101 125 where he lays out his basic method Temin 2006 pp 31 54 Maddison 2007 pp 43 47 50 table 1 10 54 table 1 12 Bang 2008 pp 86 91 Scheidel Friesen Nov 2009 pp 61 91 Statistics on World Population GDP and Per Capita GDP 1 f gt 27 July 2016 a b Maddison 2007 p 54 table 1 12 Maddison 2007 p 55 table 1 14 Maddison 2007 p 57 table 1 14 Morris p 183 a b c d Potter 2009 p 187 Mogens Herman Hansen 2006 Polis An Introduction to the Ancient Greek City State Oxford University Press USA Potter 2009 pp 185 187 a b Morris p 184 Potter 2009 p 185 Potter 2009 p 185 Potter 2009 p 188 a b Potter 2009 p 186 Cassius Dio 55 31 4 Tacitus Annales 13 31 2 This was the vicesima libertatis the twentieth for freedom Potter 2009 p 187 a b c d Raoul McLaughlin 2014 The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa Arabia and India Barnsley Pen amp Sword Military ISBN 978 1 78346 381 7 p 6 Raoul McLaughlin 2014 The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa Arabia and India Barnsley Pen amp Sword Military ISBN 978 1 78346 381 7 p 7 a b Raoul McLaughlin 2014 The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa Arabia and India Barnsley Pen amp Sword Military ISBN 978 1 78346 381 7 p 12 Raoul McLaughlin 2014 The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa Arabia and India Barnsley Pen amp Sword Military ISBN 978 1 78346 381 7 p 14 a b Raoul McLaughlin 2014 The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa Arabia and India Barnsley Pen amp Sword Military ISBN 978 1 78346 381 7 p 16 Raoul McLaughlin 2014 The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean the Ancient World Economy and the Kingdoms of Africa Arabia and India Barnsley Pen amp Sword Military ISBN 978 1 78346 381 7 p 19 Plessis D F du 2000 Introduction to Public Relations and Advertising Juta and Company Ltd p 80 ISBN 978 0 7021 5557 4 Dekeyser Thomas 2018 The material geographies of advertising Concrete objects affective affordance and urban space Environment and Planning A Economy and Space 50 7 1425 1442 doi 10 1177 0308518X18780374 ISSN 0308 518X S2CID 158657199 a b c Curtis Robert I 1984 Product Identification and Advertising on Roman Commercial Amphorae Ancient Society 15 17 209 228 ISSN 0066 1619 JSTOR 44080242 Hood John McDonald 2005 Selling the Dream Why Advertising is Good Business Greenwood Publishing Group pp 10 14 ISBN 978 0 275 98435 9 Curtis Robert I 1991 01 01 Merchandising Brill ISBN 978 90 04 37726 4 a b c Wharton Chris 2014 12 05 Advertising Critical Approaches Routledge pp 26 30 ISBN 978 1 135 04357 5 Williams Brenda Williams Brian 2007 09 15 Staying Alive in Ancient Rome Life in Ancient Rome Capstone Classroom p 19 ISBN 978 1 4109 2897 9 Sources editBang Peter Fibiger 2008 The Roman Bazaar A Comparative Study of Trade and Markets in a Tributary Empire Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 85532 2 pp 86 91 Bang Peter Fibiger 2009 The Ancient Economy and New Institutional Economics The Journal of Roman Studies 99 194 206 doi 10 3815 007543509789744783 S2CID 144103813 Callatay Francois de 2005 The Graeco Roman Economy in the Super Long Run Lead Copper and Shipwrecks Journal of Roman Archaeology 18 361 372 doi 10 1017 S104775940000742X S2CID 232346123 Cech Brigitte 2010 Technik in der Antike Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft Darmstadt ISBN 978 3 8062 2080 3 Cleere H amp Crossley D 1995 The Iron industry of the Weald 2nd edition Merton Priory Press Cardiff ISBN 1 898937 04 4 republishing the 1st edition Leicester University Press 1985 with a supplement Cleere Henry 1981 The Iron Industry of Roman Britain Wealden Iron Research Group p 74 75 Craddock Paul T 2008 Mining and Metallurgy in Oleson John Peter ed The Oxford Handbook of Engineering and Technology in the Classical World Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 518731 1 pp 93 120 Goldsmith Raymond W 1984 An Estimate of the Size and Structure of the National Product of the Early Roman Empire Review of Income and Wealth 30 3 263 288 doi 10 1111 j 1475 4991 1984 tb00552 x Healy John F 1978 Mining and Metallurgy in the Greek and Roman World Thames and Hudson London ISBN 0 500 40035 0 Hong Sungmin Candelone Jean Pierre Patterson Clair C Boutron Claude F 1994 Greenland Ice Evidence of Hemispheric Lead Pollution Two Millennia Ago by Greek and Roman Civilizations Science 265 5180 1841 1843 Bibcode 1994Sci 265 1841H doi 10 1126 science 265 5180 1841 PMID 17797222 S2CID 45080402 Hong Sungmin Candelone Jean Pierre Patterson Clair C Boutron Claude F 1996 History of Ancient Copper Smelting Pollution During Roman and Medieval Times Recorded in Greenland Ice Science 272 5259 246 249 Bibcode 1996Sci 272 246H doi 10 1126 science 272 5259 246 S2CID 176767223 Hopkins Keith 1980 Taxes and Trade in the Roman Empire 200 B C A D 400 The Journal of Roman Studies 70 101 125 doi 10 2307 299558 JSTOR 299558 S2CID 162507113 Hopkins Keith 1995 6 Rome Taxes Rents and Trade Kodai Vol 6 7 pp 41 75 Kron Geoffrey 2014 Comparative evidence and the reconstruction of the ancient economy Greco Roman housing and the level and distribution of wealth and income in F de Callatay ed Quantifying the Greco Roman Economy and Beyond 123 46 Bari Edipuglia Lo Cascio Elio Malanima Paolo 2009 GDP in Pre Modern Agrarian Economies 1 1820 AD A Revision of the Estimates Rivista di storia economica 25 3 391 420 Maddison Angus 2007 Contours of the World Economy 1 2030 AD Essays in Macro Economic History Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 922721 1 Parker A J 1992 Ancient Shipwrecks of the Mediterranean and the Roman Provinces Archaeopress British Archaeological Reports BAR International S ISBN 0 86054 736 1 Patterson C C 1972 Silver Stocks and Losses in Ancient and Medieval Times The Economic History Review 25 2 205 235 doi 10 2307 2593904 JSTOR 2593904 Scheidel Walter April 2006 Population and Demography Princeton Stanford Working Papers in Classics Version 1 0 Scheidel Walter Friesen Steven J 2009 The Size of the Economy and the Distribution of Income in the Roman Empire The Journal of Roman Studies 99 61 91 doi 10 3815 007543509789745223 S2CID 202968244 Settle Dorothy M Patterson Clair C 1980 Lead in Albacore Guide to Lead Pollution in Americans Science 207 4436 1167 1176 Bibcode 1980Sci 207 1167S doi 10 1126 science 6986654 PMID 6986654 Sim David Ridge Isabel 2002 Iron for the Eagles The Iron Industry of Roman Britain Tempus Stroud Gloucestershire ISBN 0 7524 1900 5 Smith A H V 1997 Provenance of Coals from Roman Sites in England and Wales Britannia 28 297 324 doi 10 2307 526770 JSTOR 526770 S2CID 164153278 Temin Peter 2006 The Economy of the Early Roman Empire https www aeaweb org articles id 10 1257 089533006776526148 Temin Peter 2006 Estimating GDP in the Early Roman Empire Lo Cascio Elio ed Innovazione tecnica e progresso economico nel mondo romano Edipuglia Bari ISBN 978 88 7228 405 6 pp 31 54 Temin Peter 2012 The Roman Market Economy Princeton University Press New Jersey United States Wilson Andrew 2002 Machines Power and the Ancient Economy The Journal of Roman Studies 92 1 32 doi 10 1017 s0075435800032135 Further reading editBowman A K and Wilson A I eds 2009 Quantifying the Roman Economy Methods and Problems Oxford Studies in the Roman Economy 1 Oxford University Press Oxford Bowman A K and Wilson A I eds 2012 Settlement Urbanisation and Population Oxford Studies in the Roman Economy 2 Oxford University Press Oxford Scheidel Walter Morris Ian Saller Richard eds 2007 The Cambridge Economic History of the Greco Roman World Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 78053 7 Temin Peter 2006 The Economy of the Early Roman Empire Journal of Economic Perspectives 20 1 133 151 doi 10 1257 089533006776526148 ISSN 0895 3309 Temin Peter Price Behaviour in the Roman Empire Presentation for the Long Term Quantification in Mediterranean Ancient History conference in October 2009 held in Brussels Belgium The Roman Peasant Project 2009 2014 University of Pennsylvania Press 2021 ISBN 978 1 949057 08 9 External links editThe Oxford Roman Economy Project Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Roman economy amp oldid 1187890234, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.