fbpx
Wikipedia

National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933

The National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933 (NIRA) was a US labor law and consumer law passed by the 73rd US Congress to authorize the president to regulate industry for fair wages and prices that would stimulate economic recovery. It also established a national public works program known as the Public Works Administration (PWA). The National Recovery Administration (NRA) portion was widely hailed in 1933, but by 1934 business opinion of the act had soured.

National Industrial Recovery Act
Long titleAn Act to encourage national industrial recovery, to foster fair competition, and to provide for the construction of certain useful public works and for other purposes.
Acronyms (colloquial)NIRA
Enacted bythe 73rd United States Congress
EffectiveJune 16, 1933
Citations
Public lawPub. L.Tooltip Public Law (United States) 73–67
Statutes at Large48 Stat. 195
Legislative history
  • Introduced in the House as H.R. 5755 by Robert L. Doughton (DNC) on May 17, 1933
  • Committee consideration by Ways and Means, Senate Finance
  • Passed the House on May 26, 1933 (329-80)
  • Passed the Senate on June 9, 1933 (61-26)
  • Reported by the joint conference committee on June 10, 1933; agreed to by the House on June 10, 1933 (approved) and by the Senate on June 13, 1933 (48-42)
  • Signed into law by President Franklin D. Roosevelt on June 16, 1933
United States Supreme Court cases
Front page of the National Industrial Recovery Act, as signed by President Franklin D. Roosevelt on June 16, 1933.

The legislation was enacted in June 1933 during the Great Depression as part of President Franklin D. Roosevelt's New Deal legislative program. Section 7(a) of the bill, which protected collective bargaining rights for unions, proved contentious (especially in the Senate). Congress eventually enacted the legislation and President Roosevelt signed the bill into law on June 16, 1933. The Act had two main titles (sections). Title I was devoted to industrial recovery, authorizing the promulgation of industrial codes of fair competition, guaranteed trade union rights, permitted the regulation of working standards, and regulated the price of certain refined petroleum products and their transportation. Title II established the Public Works Administration, outlined the projects and funding opportunities it could engage in. Title II also provided funding for the Act.

The act was implemented by the NRA and the PWA. Large numbers of regulations were generated under the authority granted to the NRA by the Act, which led to a significant loss of business support for the legislation. NIRA was set to expire in June 1935, but in a major constitutional ruling the Supreme Court held Title I of the Act unconstitutional on May 27, 1935, in Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States.

The National Industrial Recovery Act is widely considered a policy failure, both in the 1930s and by historians today. Disputes over the reasons for this failure continue. Among the suggested causes are that the act promoted economically harmful monopolies, lacked critical support from the business community, and that it was poorly administered. The NIRA had no mechanisms for handling these problems, which led Congress to pass the National Labor Relations Act in 1935. The act was also a major force behind a major modification of the law criminalizing making false statements.

Background and enactment edit

The Depression began in the United States in October 1929 and grew steadily worse to its nadir in early 1933.[1][2][3] President Herbert Hoover feared that too much intervention or coercion by the government would destroy individuality and self-reliance, which he considered to be important American values. His laissez-faire views appeared to be shared by the Secretary of the Treasury Andrew W. Mellon.[4][5][6] To combat the growing economic decline, Hoover organized a number of voluntary measures with businesses, encouraged state and local government responses, and accelerated federal building projects.[7] However, his policies had little or no effect on economic recovery.[8][9][10] Toward the end of his term, however, Hoover supported several legislative solutions which he felt might lift the country out of the depression. The final attempt of the Hoover administration to rescue the economy was the passage of the Emergency Relief and Construction Act (which provided funds for public works programs) and the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC) (which provided low-interest loans to businesses).[11][12][13][14]

Hoover was defeated for re-election by Roosevelt in the 1932 presidential election. Roosevelt was convinced that federal activism was needed to reverse the country's economic decline. In his first hundred days in office, the Congress enacted at Roosevelt's request a series of bills designed to strengthen the banking system, including the Emergency Banking Act, the Glass–Steagall Act (which created the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation), and the 1933 Banking Act.[15][16] The Congress also passed the Agricultural Adjustment Act to stabilize the nation's agricultural industry.[17][18]

Enactment edit

 
Hugh S. Johnson, one of the primary authors of NIRA, was Time magazine's Man of the Year for 1933.

Enactment of the National Industrial Recovery Act climaxed the first 100 days of Roosevelt's presidency. Hugh S. Johnson, Raymond Moley, Donald Richberg, Rexford Tugwell, Jerome Frank, and Bernard Baruch—key Roosevelt advisors—believed that unrestrained competition had helped cause the Great Depression and that government had a critical role to play through national planning, limited regulation, the fostering of trade associations, support for "fair" trade practices, and support for "democratization of the workplace" (a standard work week, shorter working hours, and better working conditions).[19][20][21][22][23][24] Roosevelt, himself the former head of a trade association,[25] believed that government promotion of "self-organization" by trade associations was the least-intrusive and yet most effective method for achieving national planning and economic improvement.[26]

Some work on an industrial relief bill had been done in the weeks following Roosevelt's election, but much of this was in the nature of talk and the exchange of ideas rather than legislative research and drafting. The administration, preoccupied with banking and agriculture legislation, did not begin working on industrial relief legislation until early April.[27] Congress, however, was moving on its own industrial legislation. In the Senate, Robert F. Wagner, Edward P. Costigan, and Robert M. La Follette, Jr. were promoting public works legislation, and Hugo Black was pushing short-work-week legislation.[28][29] Motivated to work on his own industrial relief bill by these efforts, Roosevelt ordered Moley to work with these Senators (and anyone else in government who seemed interested) to craft a bill.[30] Overburdened, Moley delegated this work to Hugh S. Johnson.[29]

By May 1933, two draft bills had emerged, a cautious and legalistic one by John Dickinson (Under Secretary of Commerce) and an ambitious one focusing on trade associations by Hugh Johnson.[31] Many leading businessmen—including Gerard Swope (head of General Electric), Charles M. Schwab (chairman of Bethlehem Steel Corporation), E. H. Harriman (chairman of the Union Pacific Railroad), and Henry I. Harriman, president of the U.S. Chamber of Commerce—helped draft the legislation.[32] A two-part bill, the first section promoting cooperative action among business to achieve fair competition and provide for national planning and a second section establishing a national public works program, was submitted to Congress on May 15, 1933.[33]

The House of Representatives easily passed the bill in just seven days.[34] The most contentious issue was the inclusion of Section 7(a), which protected collective bargaining rights for unions.[35] Section 7(a) was nearly eliminated from the bill, but Senator Wagner, Jerome Frank, and Leon Keyserling (another Roosevelt aide) worked to retain the section in order to win the support of the American labor movement.[36]

The bill had a more difficult time in the Senate. The National Association of Manufacturers and Chamber of Commerce opposed its passage due to the labor provision.[36][37] Despite the positions of these two important trade associations, most businesses initially supported the NIRA.[38][26] Senator Bennett Champ Clark introduced an amendment to weaken Section 7(a), but Wagner and Senator George W. Norris led the successful opposition to the change.[36] The bulk of the Senate debate, however, turned on the bill's suspension of antitrust law. Senators William E. Borah, Burton K. Wheeler, and Hugo Black opposed any relaxation of the Sherman Antitrust Act, arguing that this would exacerbate existing severe economic inequality and concentrate wealth in the hands of the rich[39] (a severe problem which many economists at the time believed was one of the causes of the Great Depression).[40][41] Wagner defended the bill, arguing that the bill's promotion of codes of fair trade practices would help create progressive standards for wages, hours, and working conditions, and eliminate sweatshops and child labor.[42] The Senate passed the amended legislation 57-to-24 on June 9.[43]

A House–Senate conference committee met throughout the evening of June 9 and all day June 10 to reconcile the two versions of the bill, approving a final version on the afternoon of June 10. The House approved the conference committee's bill on the evening of June 10.[44] After extensive debate, the Senate approved the final bill, 46-to-39, on June 13.[45] President Roosevelt signed the bill into law on June 16, 1933.[46]

Structure of the Act edit

The National Industrial Recovery Act had two major titles (sections).

Title I was devoted to industrial recovery. Title I, Section 2 empowered the President to establish executive branch agencies to carry out the purposes of the Act, and provided for a sunset provision nullifying the Act in two years.[47] The heart of the Act was Title I, Section 3, which permitted trade or industrial associations to seek presidential approval of codes of fair competition (so long as such codes did not promote monopolies or provide unfair competition against small businesses) and provided for enforcement of these codes.[48] Title I, Section 5 exempted the codes from the federal antitrust laws.[49][50]

Title I, Section 7(a) guaranteed the right of workers to form unions and banned yellow-dog contracts:

... employees shall have the right to organize and bargain collectively through representatives of their own choosing, and shall be free from the interference restraint, or coercion of employers of labor, or their agents, in the designation of such representatives or in self-organization or in other concerted activities for the purpose of collective bargaining or other mutual aid or protection; [and] (2) that no employee and no one seeking employment shall be required as a condition of employment to join any company union or to refrain from joining, organizing, or assisting a labor organization of his own choosing... .[51]

Title I, Section 7(b) permitted the establishment of standards regarding maximum hours of labor, minimum rates of pay, and working conditions in the industries covered by the codes, while Section 7(c) authorized the President to impose such standards on codes when voluntary agreement could not be reached.[52] Title I, Section 9 authorized the regulation of oil pipelines and prices for the transportation of all petroleum products by pipeline.[53] Section 9(b) permitted the executive to take over any oil pipeline company, subsidiary, or business if the parent company was found in violation of the Act.[54]

Title II established the Public Works Administration. Title II, Section 201 established the agency and provided for a two-year sunset provision.[55] Section 202 outlines the types of public works which the new agency may seek to fund or build.[56] Title II, Section 203 authorized the Public Works Administration to provide grants and/or loans to states and localities in order to more rapidly reduce unemployment as well as to use the power of eminent domain to seize land or materials to engage in public works.[57] Title II, Section 204 explicitly provided $400 million for the construction of public highways, bridges, roads, railroad crossings, paths, and other transportation projects.[58]

Title II, Section 208 authorized the president to expend up to $25 million to purchase farms for the purpose of relocating individuals living in overcrowded urban areas (such as cities) to these farms and allowing them to raise crops and earn a living there.[59]

Title II, Sections 210–219 provided for revenues to fund the Act, and Section 220 appropriated money for the Act's implementation.[60]

Title III of the Act contained miscellaneous provisions, and transferred the authority to engage in public works from the Reconstruction Finance Corporation to the Public Works Administration.[61]

Implementation edit

Implementation of the act began immediately, with the NRA and PWA the leading agencies.[62][63][64][65] Hugh Johnson spent most of May and June planning for implementation, and the National Recovery Administration (NRA) was established on June 20, 1933—a scant four days after the law's enactment.[66] Roosevelt angered Johnson by having him administer only the NRA, while the Public Works Administration (PWA) went to Harold L. Ickes.[67][68] NRA and PWA reported to different cabinet agencies, making coordination difficult, and PWA money flowed so slowly into the economy[69][68] that NRA proved to be the more important agency by far.

National Recovery Administration edit

 
NRA Blue Eagle poster, the image most commonly associated with the NIRA.

NIRA, as implemented by the NRA, became notorious for generating large numbers of regulations. By March 1934 the “NRA was engaged chiefly in drawing up these industrial codes for all industries to adopt."[70] The agency approved 557 basic and 189 supplemental industry codes in two years.[71] Between 4,000 and 5,000 business practices were prohibited, some 3,000 administrative orders running to over 10,000 pages promulgated, and thousands of opinions and guides from national, regional, and local code boards interpreted and enforced the Act.[37]

The premiere symbol of the NIRA was the Blue Eagle.[72]

By the end of 1934, large and small business owners[73][71] and most of the public[74] had turned against the NRA. Roosevelt himself shifted his views on the best way to achieve economic recovery, and began a new legislative program (known as the "Second New Deal") in 1935.[75][76]

Labor organizing provision edit

Implementation of Section 7(a) of the NIRA proved immensely problematic as well. The protections of the Act led to a massive wave of union organizing punctuated by employer and union violence, general strikes, and recognition strikes.[77][78][79] At the outset, NRA Administrator Hugh Johnson naïvely believed that Section 7(a) would be self-enforcing, but he quickly learned otherwise.[80] On August 5, 1933, the National Labor Board was established under the auspices of the NRA to implement the collective bargaining provisions of the Act.[80] The National Labor Board, too, proved to be ineffective, and on July 5, 1935, a new law—the National Labor Relations Act—superseded the NIRA and established a new, long-lasting federal labor policy.[81]

Public Works Administration edit

NIRA also created a Public Works Administration (not to be confused with the Works Progress Administration (WPA) of 1935).[82]

The leadership of the Public Works Authority was torn over the new agency's mission. PWA could initiate its own construction projects, distribute money to other federal agencies to fund their construction projects, or make loans to states and localities to fund their construction projects.[83] But many in the Roosevelt administration felt PWA should not spend money, for fear of worsening the federal deficit, and so funds flowed slowly.[84] Furthermore, the very nature of construction (planning, specifications, and blueprints) also held up the disbursement of money. Harold Ickes, too, was determined to ensure that graft and corruption did not tarnish the agency's reputation and lead to loss of political support in Congress, and so moved cautiously in spending the agency's money.[85] Although the U.S. Supreme Court would rule Title I of NIRA unconstitutional, the severability clause in the Act enabled the PWA to survive. Among the projects it funded between 1935 and 1939 are: the USS Yorktown; USS Enterprise; the 30th Street railroad station in Philadelphia, Pennsylvania; the Triborough Bridge; the port of Brownsville; Grand Coulee Dam; Boulder Dam; Fort Peck Dam; Bonneville Dam; and the Overseas Highway connecting Key West, Florida, with the mainland.[86] The agency survived until 1943, when the Reorganization Act of 1939 consolidated most federal public works and work relief functions of the federal government into the new Federal Works Agency.[87][88]

Proposed reauthorization edit

President Roosevelt sought an extension of NIRA on February 20, 1935.[89] But the business backlash against the New Deal,[73][38] coupled with continuing congressional concern over the Act's suspension of antitrust law, left the President's request politically dead.[37] A U.S. Senate committee investigation into the effectiveness of the NRA, PWA, and Section 7(a) revealed only limited political support for the law among Senators. The Senate bill reauthorizing NIRA provided for only a 10-month extension, with significant new limitations on NRA powers. The House reauthorization bill contained no new limits on the NRA, and proposed a two-year extension.[90] By May 1935, the issue was moot as the U.S. Supreme Court had ruled Title I of NIRA unconstitutional.

Legal challenge and nullification edit

 
Chief Justice of the U.S. Charles Evans Hughes.

On April 13, 1934, the President had approved the "Code of Fair Competition for the Live Poultry Industry of the Metropolitan Area in and about the City of New York."[91] The goal of the code was to ensure that live poultry (provided to kosher slaughterhouses for butchering and sale to observant Jews) were fit for human consumption and to prevent the submission of false sales and price reports. The industry was almost entirely centered on New York City.[92] Under the new poultry code, the Schechter brothers were indicted on 60 counts (of which 27 were dismissed by the trial court), acquitted on 14, and convicted in 19.[93] One of the counts on which they were convicted was for selling a diseased bird, leading Hugh Johnson to jokingly call the suit the "sick chicken case".

Even before these legal aspects became widely known, a number of court challenges to the NIRA were winding their way through the courts. The constitutionality of the NIRA was tested in Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495 (1935). Courts identified three problems with the NIRA: "(i) was the subject matter sought to be regulated by the power of Congress; (ii) if the regulations violated the Fifth Amendment to the United States Constitution; and (iii) had Congress properly delegated its power to the executive."[94]

Although Roosevelt, most of his aides, Johnson, and the NIRA staff felt the Act would survive a court test, the U.S. Department of Justice had on March 25, 1935, declined to appeal an appellate court ruling overturning the lumber industry code on the grounds that the case was not a good test of the NIRA's constitutionality.[95] The Justice Department's action worried many in the administration. But on April 1, 1935, the Second Circuit Court of Appeals upheld the constitutionality of the NIRA in the Schechter case.[95] Although Donald Richberg and others felt the government's case in Schechter was not a strong one, the Schechters were determined to appeal their conviction. So the government appealed first, and the Supreme Court heard oral argument on May 2 and 3.[96]

On May 27, 1935, Chief Justice Charles Evans Hughes wrote for a unanimous Court in Schechter Poultry Corp. v. The United States that Title I of the National Industrial Recovery Act was unconstitutional.[97][98][1] First, Hughes concluded that the law was void for vagueness because of the critical term "fair competition"[a] was nowhere defined in the Act.[99] Second, Hughes found the Act's delegation of authority to the executive branch unconstitutionally overbroad:

To summarize and conclude upon this point: Section 3 of the Recovery Act (15 USCA 703) is without precedent. It supplies no standards for any trade, industry, or activity. It does not undertake to prescribe rules of conduct to be applied to particular states of fact determined by appropriate administrative procedure. Instead of prescribing rules of conduct, it authorizes the making of codes to prescribe them. For that legislative undertaking, section 3 sets up no standards, aside from the statement of the general aims of rehabilitation, correction, and expansion described in section 1. In view of the scope of that broad declaration and of the nature of the few restrictions that are imposed, the discretion of the President in approving or prescribing codes, and thus enacting laws for the government of trade and industry throughout the country, is virtually unfettered. We think that the code-making authority thus conferred is an unconstitutional delegation of legislative power.[100]

Finally, in a very restrictive reading of what constituted interstate commerce,[101] Hughes held that the "'current' or 'flow'" of commerce involved was simply too minute to constitute interstate commerce, and subsequently Congress had no power under the Commerce Clause to enact legislation affecting such commercial transactions.[102] The Court dismissed with a bare paragraph the government's ability to regulate wages and hours.[103] Although the government had argued that the national economic emergency required special consideration, Hughes disagreed. The dire economic circumstances the country faced did not justify the overly broad delegation or overreach of the Act, the majority concluded. "Extraordinary conditions may call for extraordinary remedies. But the argument necessarily stops short of an attempt to justify action which lies outside the sphere of constitutional authority. Extraordinary conditions do not create or enlarge constitutional power."[104]

Although the decision emasculated NIRA, it had little practical impact, as Congress was unlikely to have reauthorized the Act in any case.[101][b]

Criticism edit

At the time and in recent analyzes, NIRA is generally considered to be a failure.[105][106][107][108]

A key criticism of the Act at the time as well as more recently is that the NIRA endorsed monopolies, with the attendant economic problems associated with that type of market failure.[71][109] Even the National Recovery Review Board, established by President Roosevelt in March 1934 to review the performance of the NIRA, concluded that the Act hindered economic growth by promoting cartels and monopolies.[c] One of the economic effects of monopoly and cartels is higher prices—this was seen as necessary because the severe deflation of 1929–33 had depressed prices 20% and more.[111][112] There is anecdotal evidence that these higher prices led to some stability in industry,[113] but a number of scholars maintain that these prices were so high that economic recovery was inhibited.[109][114] But other economists disagree, pointing to far more important monetary, budgetary, and tax policies as contributors to the continuation of the Great Depression.[115] Others point out that the cartels created by the Act were inherently unstable (as all cartels are), and that the effect on prices was minimal because the codes collapsed so quickly.[116][117]

A second key criticism of the Act is that it lacked support from the business community, and thus was doomed to failure. Business support for national planning and government intervention was very strong in 1933, but had collapsed by mid-1934.[73][71] Many studies conclude, however, that business support for NIRA was never uniform. Larger, older businesses embraced the legislation while smaller, newer ones (more nimble in a highly competitive market and with less capital investment to lose if they failed) did not.[26][118] This is a classic problem of cartels, and thus NIRA codes failed as small business abandoned the cartels.[116][117] Studies of the steel, automobile manufacturing, lumber, textile, and rubber industries and the level and source of support for the NIRA tend to support this conclusion.[119] Without the support of industry, the Act could never have performed as it was intended.

A third major criticism of the Act is that it was poorly administered. The Act purposefully brought together competing for interests (labor and business, big business and small business, etc.) in a coalition to support passage of the legislation, but these competing interests soon fought one another over the Act's implementation.[120][116] As a consequence, NIRA collapsed due to failure of leadership and confusion about its goals. By the end of 1934, NIRA leaders had practically abandoned the progressive interventionist policy which motivated the Act's passage, and were supporting free-market philosophies—contributing to the collapse of almost all industry codes.[113]

There are a wide range of additional critiques as well. One is that NIRA's industry codes interfered with capital markets, inhibiting economic recovery.[121] But more recent analyzes conclude that NIRA had little effect on capital markets one way or the other.[122] Another is that political uncertainty created by the NIRA caused a drop in business confidence, inhibiting recovery.[123] But at least one study has shown no effect whatsoever.[124]

Section 7(a) led to significant increases in union organizing, but NRA administrative rulings effectively gutted this section by permitting company union{{{1}}}.[125] Although Section 7(a) was not affected by the Supreme Court's decision in Schechter Poultry, the failure of the section led directly to passage of the National Labor Relations Act in July 1935.[81]

Historian Alan Brinkley stated that by 1935 the NIRA was a "woeful failure, even a political embarrassment." Many liberals, probably including Roosevelt, were quietly relieved by its demise. However, New Dealers were worried by the Supreme Court's strict interpretation of the interstate commerce clause and worried that other legislation was jeopardized.[126]

Legacy edit

In 1934, at the request of the Secretary Ickes, who wished to use the statute criminalizing making false statements to enforce Section 9(c) of the NIRA against producers of "hot oil", oil produced in violation of production restrictions established pursuant to the NIRA, Congress passed Pub. L.Tooltip Public Law (United States) 73–394, 48 Stat. 996, enacted June 18, 1934, which amended the False Claims Act of 1863 to read:[127]

... or whoever, for the purpose of obtaining or aiding to obtain the payment or approval of such claim, or for the purpose and with the intent of cheating and swindling or defrauding the Government of the United States, or any department thereof, or any corporation in which the United States of America is a stockholder, shall knowingly and willfully falsify or conceal or cover up by any trick, scheme, or device a material fact, or make or cause to be made any false or fraudulent statements or representations, or make or use or cause to be made or used any false bill, receipt, voucher, roll, account, claim, certificate, affidavit, or deposition, knowing the same to contain any fraudulent or fictitious statement or entry, in any matter within the jurisdiction of any department or agency of the United States or of any corporation in which the United States of America is a stockholder ...

This form of the statute, in slightly modified form, still exists today at 18 U.S.C. § 1001.

References edit

Notes
  1. ^ The National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title I, Sec. 3(a) reads: "Upon the application to the President by one or more trade or industrial associations or groups, the President may approve a code or codes of fair competition for the trade or industry or subdivision thereof..."
  2. ^ As of 2007, Schechter Poultry and Panama Refining Co. v. Ryan, 293 U.S. 388 (1935), are the only cases in which the Supreme Court has struck down an act of Congress for overbroad delegation of legislative authority. See: Ross, The Chief Justiceship of Charles Evans Hughes, 1930–1941, 2007.
  3. ^ This was not, however, unexpected: Senator Gerald Nye, an ardent opponent of monopolies, named five of the board's six members, and long-time antitrust advocate Clarence Darrow led the Board.[110]
Citations
  1. ^ a b Kennedy 2005, pp. 151–154.
  2. ^ Hall & Ferguson 1998, p. 113.
  3. ^ Dorich 2021, p. 75.
  4. ^ Smith 1970, pp. 57, 64.
  5. ^ Barber 1989, pp. 82, 108.
  6. ^ Sobel 1975, pp. 56, 64.
  7. ^ Barber 1989, pp. 16, 20 93, 105, 176.
  8. ^ Schlesinger 2003a, pp. 248–249.
  9. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, pp. 87–176.
  10. ^ Kennedy 2005, pp. 93, 151–154.
  11. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 87-176, 236, 263.
  12. ^ Kennedy 2005, p. 84, 151-154.
  13. ^ Olson 2001, p. 93.
  14. ^ Barber 1989, pp. 178–180.
  15. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, pp. 20–21, 87–176.
  16. ^ Kennedy 2005, pp. 138–140, .
  17. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, pp. 39–44.
  18. ^ Kennedy 2005, pp. 143.
  19. ^ Vadney 1970, pp. 98, 119, 191, 204.
  20. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, pp. 88, 92–94.
  21. ^ Brand 1988, pp. 74–79.
  22. ^ Hawley 1966, p. 172.
  23. ^ Stabile & Kozak 2012, pp. 77–79.
  24. ^ Sternsher 1964, pp. 102–105.
  25. ^ Schlesinger 2003a, p. 374.
  26. ^ a b c Eisner 2000, p. 85.
  27. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, pp. 95–98.
  28. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 95.
  29. ^ a b Houck 2001, p. 185.
  30. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 96.
  31. ^ McKenna 2002, p. 77.
  32. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, pp. 36–37, 88–89, 97–88.
  33. ^ Peters, Gerhard; Woolley, John T. "Franklin D. Roosevelt: "Message to Congress Recommending Enactment of the National Industrial Recovery Act.," May 17, 1933". The American Presidency Project. University of California – Santa Barbara.
  34. ^ McKenna 2002, pp. 77–78.
  35. ^ Morris 2004, p. xviii.
  36. ^ a b c Schlesinger 2003b, p. 99.
  37. ^ a b c Best 1991.
  38. ^ a b Brand 1988, p. 27.
  39. ^ Bellush 1975.
  40. ^ Galbraith 1997, pp. 182–183, 191.
  41. ^ "Borah Debates With Wagner". The New York Times. June 8, 1933. p. 4.
  42. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 174.
  43. ^ "Income Publicity Voted". The New York Times. June 10, 1933. pp. 1, 4.
  44. ^ "Recess Taken to Monday". The New York Times. June 11, 1933. pp. 1, 3.
  45. ^ "Lund and Harriman Back Recovery Act". The New York Times. June 14, 1933. pp. 1, 7.
  46. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, pp. 21, 102.
  47. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title I, Sec. 2.
  48. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title I, Sec. 3.
  49. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title I, Sec. 5.
  50. ^ Taylor 2019, pp. 15, 18.
  51. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title I, Sec. 7(a).
  52. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title I, Sec. 7(b).
  53. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title I, Sec. 9(a).
  54. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title I, Sec. 9(b).
  55. ^ Sections in Title I of the NIRA are numbered 1, 2, 3, etc. However, in a discrepancy, sections in Title II and III of the NIRA are numbered 201, 202, 203, etc. and 301, 302, 303, etc. National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title II, Sec. 201.
  56. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title II, Sec. 202.
  57. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title II, Sec. 203.
  58. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title II, Sec. 204.
  59. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title II, Sec. 208.
  60. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title II, Sec. 210–220.
  61. ^ National Industrial Recovery Act, Ch. 90, 48 Stat. 195, Title III.
  62. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 282.
  63. ^ Kennedy 2005, p. 151.
  64. ^ Stabile & Kozak 2012, p. 197.
  65. ^ Kemp 2000, p. 210.
  66. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 107.
  67. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 104.
  68. ^ a b Kennedy 2005, p. 178.
  69. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 109.
  70. ^ "Our Documents". National Industrial Recovery Act. National Archives. Retrieved April 15, 2014.
  71. ^ a b c d Eisner 2000, p. 86.
  72. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 114.
  73. ^ a b c Schlesinger 2003c, pp. 211–215.
  74. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 166.
  75. ^ Schlesinger 2003c, pp. 385–389.
  76. ^ Venn 1999, pp. 57–59.
  77. ^ Dubofsky & Dulles 2010, pp. 257–163.
  78. ^ Bernstein 2010.
  79. ^ Rayback 1974, pp. 327–329.
  80. ^ a b Morris 2004, p. 25.
  81. ^ a b Watkins 2000, pp. 297–300.
  82. ^ Elving, Ron (April 4, 2020). "In The 1930s, Works Program Spelled HOPE For Millions of Jobless Americans". NPR. Retrieved November 5, 2022.
  83. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 284.
  84. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 202.
  85. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 285.
  86. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 288.
  87. ^ "Executive Order 9357 – Transferring the Functions of the Public Works Administration to the Federal Works Agency". The American Presidency Project. June 30, 1943. Retrieved November 20, 2022.
  88. ^ Olson 2001, pp. 111, 233.
  89. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, p. 165.
  90. ^ Bellush 1975, pp. 165–167.
  91. ^ Schechter Poultry Corp. v. The United States, 295 U.S. 495, 555, fn. 5.
  92. ^ Barnett & Blackman 2021, p. 222.
  93. ^ Schechter Poultry Corp. v. The United States, 295 U.S. 495, 555, fn. 2.
  94. ^ Harvard Law Review 1933, pp. 86–87.
  95. ^ a b Schlesinger 2003c, p. 277.
  96. ^ Schlesinger 2003c, p. 279.
  97. ^ Schlesinger 2003c, pp. 279–280.
  98. ^ Biles 1991, pp. 78–95.
  99. ^ Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495, 531.
  100. ^ Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495, 541–542.
  101. ^ a b Ross, The Chief Justiceship of Charles Evans Hughes, 1930–1941, 2007.
  102. ^ Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495, 542–548.
  103. ^ Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495, 548–550.
  104. ^ Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 U.S. 495, 528.
  105. ^ Geisst 2006, p. 298.
  106. ^ Walton 1992, p. 302.
  107. ^ Skocpol 1994, pp. 345–347.
  108. ^ Delton 2020, p. 120.
  109. ^ a b Cole, Harold L.; Ohanian, Lee E. (February 2, 2009). "How Government Prolonged the Depression". The Wall Street Journal. Retrieved November 20, 2022.
  110. ^ Schlesinger 2003b, pp. 132–134.
  111. ^ Eisner 2000, pp. 83–84.
  112. ^ Fisher 1933, pp. 344, 352.
  113. ^ a b Horwitz 1989, p. 72.
  114. ^ Weinstein, Recovery and Redistribution Under the NIRA, 1980[page needed]; Roose, The Economics of Recession and Revival: An Interpretation of 1937–38, 1954[page needed]; Hayes, Business Confidence and Business Activity: A Case Study of the Recession of 1937, 1951.[page needed]
  115. ^ Friedman and Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960, 1963[page needed]; Bernanke, B.; Parkinson, M. (1989). "Unemployment, Inflation, and Wages in the American Depression: Are There Lessons for Europe?". The American Economic Review. 79 (2): 210–14. doi:10.3386/w2862. JSTOR 1827758.
  116. ^ a b c Krepps, M (1999). "Facilitating practices and the path-dependence of collusion". International Journal of Industrial Organization. 17 (6): 887–901. doi:10.1016/S0167-7187(97)00066-0.; Krepps, Matthew B. (1997). "Another Look at the Impact of the National Industrial Recovery Act on Cartel Formation and Maintenance Costs". Review of Economics and Statistics. 79: 151–54. doi:10.1162/003465397556502. S2CID 57568487.
  117. ^ a b Lande, Robert H.; Connor, John M. (2005). "How High Do Cartels Raise Prices? Implications for Reform of the Antitrust Sentencing Guidelines". Tulane Law Review. 80. SSRN 787907.; Harringtonjr, J; Chen, J (2006). "Cartel pricing dynamics with cost variability and endogenous buyer detection". International Journal of Industrial Organization. 24 (6): 1185–212. doi:10.1016/j.ijindorg.2006.04.012.; Perloff, Jeffrey M; Karp, Larry S.; and Golan, Amos. Estimating Market Power and Strategies. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2007. ISBN 052180440X[page needed]
  118. ^ Galambos, Competition and Cooperation: The Emergence of a National Trade Association, 1966[page needed]; Collins, R. M. (1978). "Positive Business Responses to the New Deal: The Roots of the Committee for Economic Development, 1933–1942". The Business History Review. 52 (3): 369–91. doi:10.2307/3113736. JSTOR 3113736. S2CID 146238143.
  119. ^ Stewart, Steel – Problems of a Great Industry, 1937[page needed]; Kennedy, The Automobile Industry: The Coming of Age of Capitalism's Favorite Child, 1941[page needed]; Daugherty, et al., The Economics of the Iron and Steel Industry, 1937[page needed]; Rae, American Automobile Manufacturers: The First Forty Years, 1959[page needed]; James, L. M. (1946). "Restrictive Agreements and Practices in the Lumber Industry, 1880–1939". Southern Economic Journal. 13 (2): 115–25. doi:10.2307/1052520. JSTOR 1052520.; Shaffer, In Restraint of Trade: The Business Campaign Against Competition, 1918–1938, 1997[page needed]; Pennock, P. (1997). "The National Recovery Administration and the Rubber Tire Industry, 1933–1935". The Business History Review. 71 (4): 543–68. doi:10.2307/3116306. JSTOR 3116306. S2CID 154346794.
  120. ^ Eisner 2000, pp. 84–86.
  121. ^ Lyon, et al., The National Recovery Administration: An Analysis and Appraisal, 1935.
  122. ^ Anderson, William L. (2000). "Risk and the National Industrial Recovery Act: An Empirical Evaluation". Public Choice. 103: 139–61. doi:10.1023/A:1005054019819. S2CID 152916565.
  123. ^ Bernstein, The Great Depression: Delayed Recovery and Economic Change in America, 1929–1939, 1989.
  124. ^ Mayer, Thomas; Chatterji, Monojit (2009). "Political Shocks and Investment: Some Evidence from the 1930s". The Journal of Economic History. 45 (4): 913–924. doi:10.1017/S0022050700035166. JSTOR 2121886. S2CID 155005461.
  125. ^ Bellush 1975, pp. 176–177.
  126. ^ Brinkley 1995, p. 18.
  127. ^ United States v. Gilliland, 312 US 86, 93–94 (1941) ("Legislation had been sought by the Secretary of the Interior to aid the enforcement of laws relating to the functions of the Department of the Interior and, in particular, to the enforcement of regulations under Sec. 9(c) of the [NIRA].").

Bibliography edit

  • Anderson, William L. (April 2000). "Risk and the National Industrial Recovery Act: An Empirical Evaluation". Public Choice. 103 (1–2): 139–161. doi:10.1023/A:1005054019819. S2CID 152916565.
  • Barber, William J. (1989). From New Era to New Deal: Herbert Hoover, the Economists, and American Economic Policy, 1921–1933. New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521367370.
  • Barnett, Randy E.; Blackman, Josh (2021). Constitutional Law: Cases in Context. New York: Wolters Kluwer. ISBN 9781543838787.
  • Bellush, Bernard (1975). The Failure of the NRA. New York: W.W. Norton. ISBN 9780393055481.
  • Bernanke, Ben; Parkinson, Martin (May 1989). "Unemployment, Inflation and Wages in the American Depression: Are There Lessons for Europe?". American Economic Review. 79 (2): 210–214. doi:10.3386/w2862.
  • Bernstein, Irving (2010) [1969]. The Turbulent Years: A History of the American Worker, 1933–1941. Chicago: Haymarket Books. ISBN 9781608460649.
  • Bernstein, Michael (1987). The Great Depression: Delayed Recovery and Economic Change in America, 1929–1939. New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521379854.
  • Best, Gary Dean (1991). Pride, Prejudice, and Politics: Roosevelt Versus Recovery, 1933–1938. New York: Praeger Publishers. ISBN 9780275935245.
  • Biles, Roger (1991). A New Deal for the American People. DeKalb, Ill.: Northern Illinois University Press. ISBN 9780875801612.
  • Brand, Donald Robert (1988). Corporatism and the Rule of Law: A Study of the National Recovery Administration. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press. ISBN 9780801421693.
  • Brinkley, Alan (1995). The End of Reform: New Deal Liberalism in Recession and War. New York: Vintage Books. ISBN 9780679753148.
  • Collins, Robert M. (Autumn 1978). "Positive Business Responses to the New Deal: The Roots of the Committee for Economic Development, 1933–1942". Business History Review. 52 (3): 369–391. doi:10.2307/3113736. JSTOR 3113736. S2CID 146238143.
  • Daugherty, Carroll R.; de Chazeau, Melvin G.; Stratton, Samuel S. (1937). The Economics of the Iron and Steel Industry. Pittsburgh: Bureau of Business Research, University of Pittsburgh. OCLC 503553.
  • Delton, Jennifer (2020). The Industrialists: Now the National Association of Manufacturers Shaped American Capitalism. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. ISBN 9780691167862.
  • Dorich, Thomas J. (2021). Big Business in America: The Corporate Century, 1900-2000. Lanham, Md.: Lexington Books. ISBN 9781498595971.
  • Dubofsky, Melvyn; Dulles, Foster Rhea (2010). Labor in America: A History. Hoboken, N.J.: John Wiley & Sons. ISBN 9780882952734.
  • Eisner, Marc Allen (2000). Regulatory Politics in Transition. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press. ISBN 9780801864926.
  • Farrell, Chris (2004). Deflation: What Happens When Prices Fall. New York: HarperCollins. ISBN 9780060576455.
  • Fine, Sidney (1963). Automobile Under the Blue Eagle: Labor, Management, and the Automobile Manufacturing Code. Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press. OCLC 999975.
  • Fisher, Irving (October 1933). "The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions" (PDF). Econometrica. 1 (4): 337–357. doi:10.2307/1907327. JSTOR 1907327.
  • Friedman, Milton; Schwartz, Anna J. (1963). A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. ISBN 9781400829330. OCLC 1331033779.
  • Galambos, Louis (1966). Competition and Cooperation: The Emergence of a National Trade Association. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press. OCLC 237577.
  • Galbraith, John Kenneth (1997) [1954]. The Great Crash of 1929. Boston: Houghton Mifflin & Co. ISBN 9780395859995.
  • Geisst, Charles R. (2006). Encyclopedia of American Business History. New York: Facts On File. ISBN 9780816043507.
  • Gross, James A. (1974). The Making of the National Labor Relations Board: A Study in Economics, Politics, and the Law. Albany, N.Y.: State University of New York Press Press. ISBN 9780873952705.
  • Hall, Thomas E.; Ferguson, David (1998). The Great Depression: An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies. Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press. ISBN 9780472096671.
  • Harrington, Joseph E., Jr.; Chen, Joe (November 2006). "Cartel Pricing Dynamics With Cost Variability and Endogenous Buyer Detection". International Journal of Industrial Organization. 24 (6): 1185–1212. doi:10.1016/j.ijindorg.2006.04.012.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  • Hawley, Ellis (1966). The New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. ISBN 9781400875313.
  • Hayes, Douglas A. (1951). Business Confidence and Business Activity: A Case Study of the Recession of 1937. Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press. OCLC 3700753.
  • Horwitz, Robert Britt (1989). The Irony of Regulatory Reform: The Deregulation of American Telecommunications. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780195054453.
  • Houck, David W. (2001). Rhetoric As Currency: Hoover, Roosevelt, and the Great Depression. College Station, Tx.: Texas A&M University Press. ISBN 9781585441099.
  • James, Lee M. (October 1946). "Restrictive Agreements and Practices in the Lumber Industry, 1880–1939". Southern Economic Journal. 13 (2): 115–125. doi:10.2307/1052520. JSTOR 1052520.
  • Kemp, Emory L. (2000). The Great Kanawha Navigation. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. ISBN 9780822941125.
  • Kennedy, David M. (2005). Freedom from Fear: The American People in Depression and War, 1929–1945. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780195144031.
  • Kennedy, Edward Donald (1941). The Automobile Industry: The Coming of Age of Capitalism's Favorite Child. New York: Reynal and Hitchcock. OCLC 3247284.
  • Krepps, Matthew B. (February 1997). "Another Look at the Impact of the National Industrial Recovery Act on Cartel Formation and Maintenance Costs". Review of Economics and Statistics. 79 (1): 151–154. doi:10.1162/003465397556502. S2CID 57568487.
  • Krepps, Matthew B. (August 1999). "Facilitating Practices and the Path-Dependence of Collusion". International Journal of Industrial Organization. 17 (6): 887–901. doi:10.1016/S0167-7187(97)00066-0.
  • Lande, Robert H.; Connor, John M (December 2005). "How High Do Cartels Raise Prices? Implications for Reform of the Antitrust Sentencing Guidelines". Tulane Law Review. 80 (2): 513–570. doi:10.2139/ssrn.787907. S2CID 155973465.
  • Levine, Rhonda F. (1988). Class Struggle and the New Deal: Industrial Labor, Industrial Capital and the State. Lawrence, Kan.: University Press of Kansas. ISBN 9780700603732.
  • Lyon, Leverett S.; Homan, Paul T.; George, Terborgh; Lorwin, Lewis L.; Dearing, Charles L.; Marshall, Leon C. (1935). The National Recovery Administration: An Analysis and Appraisal. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution. OCLC 1050549832.
  • Mayer, Thomas; Chatterji, Monojit (December 1985). "Political Shocks and Investment: Some Evidence from the 1930s". Journal of Economic History. 45 (4): 913=924. doi:10.1017/S0022050700035166. S2CID 155005461.
  • McKenna, Marian C. (2002). Franklin Roosevelt and the Great Constitutional War: The Court-Packing Crisis of 1937. New York: Fordham University Press. ISBN 9780823221547.
  • Morris, Charles (2004). The Blue Eagle At Work: Reclaiming Democratic Rights In The American Workplace. Ithaca, N.Y.: ILR Press. ISBN 9780801443176.
  • Olson, James Stuart (2001). Historical Dictionary of the Great Depression, 1929–1940. Westport, Conn.: Greenwood Press. ISBN 9780313306181.
  • Pennock, Pamela (Winter 1997). "The National Recovery Administration and the Rubber Tire Industry, 1933–1935". Business History Review. 71 (4): 543–568. doi:10.2307/3116306. JSTOR 3116306. S2CID 154346794.
  • Perloff, Jeffrey M.; Karp, Larry S.; Golan, Amos (2007). Estimating Market Power and Strategies. New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521011143.
  • Rae, John B. (1959). American Automobile Manufacturers: The First Forty Years. Philadelphia: Chilton Book. OCLC 1004807020.
  • Rayback, Joseph G. (1974). A History of American Labor. New York: Macmillan. ISBN 9781439118993. OCLC 615514713.
  • Roose, Kenneth D. (1954). The Economics of Recession and Revival. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press. OCLC 252427283.
  • Ross, William G. (2007). The Chief Justiceship of Charles Evans Hughes, 1930–1941. Columbia, S.C.: University of South Carolina Press. ISBN 9781570036798.
  • Schlesinger, Arthur M., Jr. (2003). The Age of Roosevelt. Vol. 1: Crisis of the Old Order. Boston: Houghton Mifflin. ISBN 9780618340859.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  • Schlesinger, Arthur M., Jr. (2003). The Age of Roosevelt. Vol. 2: The Coming of the New Deal. Boston: Houghton Mifflin. ISBN 9780618340866.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  • Schlesinger, Arthur M., Jr. (2003). The Age of Roosevelt. Vol. 3: The Politics of Upheaval, 1935–1936. Boston: Houghton Mifflin. ISBN 9780547524252.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  • Shaffer, Butler D. (1997). In Restraint of Trade: The Business Campaign Against Competition, 1918–1938. Lewisburg, Pa.: Bucknell University Press. ISBN 9780838753255.
  • Skocpol, Theda (1994). "Political Response to Capitalist Crisis: Neo-Marxist Theories of the State and the Case of the New Deal". In Scott, John (ed.). Power: Critical Concepts. Volume 3. New York: Routledge. ISBN 9780415079372.
  • Smith, Gene (1970). The Shattered Dream: Herbert Hoover and the Great Depression. New York: Willam Morrow and Co. OCLC 76078.
  • Sobel, Robert (1975). Herbert Hoover at the Onset of the Great Depression, 1929–1930. New York: Lippincott. ISBN 9780397473342.
  • "Some Legal Aspects of the National Industrial Recovery Act". Harvard Law Review. 47 (1): 85–125. November 1933. doi:10.2307/1332107. JSTOR 1332107.
  • Stabile, Donald R.; Kozak, Andrew R. (2012). Markets, Planning and the Moral Economy: Business Cycles in the Progressive Era and New Deal. Northampton, Mass.: Edward Elgar Publishing. ISBN 9781781006764.
  • Sternsher, Bernard (1964). Rexford Tugwell and the New Deal. New Brunswick, N.J.: Rutgers University Press. OCLC 466310.
  • Stewart, Maxwell S. (1937). Steel—Problems of a Great Industry. New York: Public Affairs Committee. OCLC 3716534.
  • Taylor, Jason E. (2019). Deconstructing the Monolith: The Microeconomics of the National Industrial Recovery Act. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. ISBN 9780226603308.
  • Tomlins, Christopher L. (1985). The State and the Unions: Labor Relations, Law, and the Organized Labor Movement in America, 1880–1960. New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521314527.
  • Vadney, Thomas E. (1970). The Wayward Liberal: A Political Biography of Donald Richberg. Lexington, Ky.: The University Press of Kentucky. ISBN 9780813112435.
  • Venn, Fiona (1999). The New Deal. New York: Taylor & Francis. ISBN 9781315062532.
  • Vittoz, Stanley (1987). New Deal Labor Policy and the American Industrial Economy. Chapel Hill, N.C.: University of North Carolina Press. ISBN 9780807817292.
  • Walton, John (1992). Western Times and Water Wars: State, Culture, and Rebellion in California. Berkeley, Calif.: University of California Press. ISBN 9780520072459.
  • Watkins, T.H. (2000). The Hungry Hears: A Narrative History of the Great Depression in America. New York: Henry Holt & Co. ISBN 9780805065060.
  • Weinstein, Michael (1980). Recovery and Redistribution Under the NIRA. New York: North-Holland Publishing. ISBN 9780444860071.

For further reading edit

  • Beaudreau, Bernard C. "Why Did the National Industrial Recovery Act Fail?" European Review of Economic History, 20, 2015 79–101.
  • Bernstein, Irving (2020) [1950]. The New Deal Collective Bargaining Policy. Berkeley, Calif.: University of California Press. ISBN 9780520346956.
  • Clarke, Jeanne Nienaber (1996). Roosevelt's Warrior: Harold L. Ickes and the New Deal. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press. ISBN 978-0801850943.
  • Himmelberg, Robert (1993). The Origins of the National Recovery Administration. New York: Fordham University Press. ISBN 978-0823215409.
  • Johnson, Hugh S. (1935). The Blue Eagle, From Egg to Earth. New York: Doubleday, Doran & Co. OCLC 1064791053.
  • Moley, Raymond (1936). After Seven Years. New York: Harper & Brothers. OCLC 854808142.
  • National Recovery Review Board (1934). Report to the President of the United States: First Report of the National Recovery Review Board (Report). Washington, D.C.: National Recovery Administration. hdl:2027/mdp.35112103647402. OCLC 35406585.
  • Ohl, John Kennedy. Hugh S. Johnson and the New Deal. Dekalb, Ill.: Northern Illinois University Press, 1985. ISBN 0-87580-110-2
  • Paulsen, George E. (March 1989). "The Federal Trade Commission versus the National Recovery Administration: Fair Trade Practices and Voluntary Codes, 1935". Social Science Quarterly. 70 (1): 149–163.
  • Phillips, Cabell B.H. (2000). From the Crash to the Blitz, 1929–1939: The 'New York Times' Chronicle of American Life. New York: Fordham University Press. ISBN 978-0823219995.
  • Richberg, Donald (1954). My Hero: The Indiscreet Memoirs of an Eventful But Unheroic Life. New York: Putnam. OCLC 1522089.
  • Shogan, Robert (2006). Backlash: The Killing of the New Deal. Chicago: Ivan R. Dee. ISBN 978-1566636742.
  • Smith, Angella LaNette. Economic revolution from within: Herbert Hoover, Franklin Delano Roosevelt and the emergence of the National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933" (PhD dissertation,  Wayne State University, 2015; ProQuest Dissertations Publishing, 2015. 3734689).

External links edit

  • Text of the National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933

national, industrial, recovery, 1933, nira, labor, consumer, passed, 73rd, congress, authorize, president, regulate, industry, fair, wages, prices, that, would, stimulate, economic, recovery, also, established, national, public, works, program, known, public, . The National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933 NIRA was a US labor law and consumer law passed by the 73rd US Congress to authorize the president to regulate industry for fair wages and prices that would stimulate economic recovery It also established a national public works program known as the Public Works Administration PWA The National Recovery Administration NRA portion was widely hailed in 1933 but by 1934 business opinion of the act had soured National Industrial Recovery ActLong titleAn Act to encourage national industrial recovery to foster fair competition and to provide for the construction of certain useful public works and for other purposes Acronyms colloquial NIRAEnacted bythe 73rd United States CongressEffectiveJune 16 1933CitationsPublic lawPub L Tooltip Public Law United States 73 67Statutes at Large48 Stat 195Legislative historyIntroduced in the House as H R 5755 by Robert L Doughton D NC on May 17 1933Committee consideration by Ways and Means Senate FinancePassed the House on May 26 1933 329 80 Passed the Senate on June 9 1933 61 26 Reported by the joint conference committee on June 10 1933 agreed to by the House on June 10 1933 approved and by the Senate on June 13 1933 48 42 Signed into law by President Franklin D Roosevelt on June 16 1933United States Supreme Court casesPanama Refining Co v Ryan 1935 Schechter Poultry Corp v United States 1935 Front page of the National Industrial Recovery Act as signed by President Franklin D Roosevelt on June 16 1933 The legislation was enacted in June 1933 during the Great Depression as part of President Franklin D Roosevelt s New Deal legislative program Section 7 a of the bill which protected collective bargaining rights for unions proved contentious especially in the Senate Congress eventually enacted the legislation and President Roosevelt signed the bill into law on June 16 1933 The Act had two main titles sections Title I was devoted to industrial recovery authorizing the promulgation of industrial codes of fair competition guaranteed trade union rights permitted the regulation of working standards and regulated the price of certain refined petroleum products and their transportation Title II established the Public Works Administration outlined the projects and funding opportunities it could engage in Title II also provided funding for the Act The act was implemented by the NRA and the PWA Large numbers of regulations were generated under the authority granted to the NRA by the Act which led to a significant loss of business support for the legislation NIRA was set to expire in June 1935 but in a major constitutional ruling the Supreme Court held Title I of the Act unconstitutional on May 27 1935 in Schechter Poultry Corp v United States The National Industrial Recovery Act is widely considered a policy failure both in the 1930s and by historians today Disputes over the reasons for this failure continue Among the suggested causes are that the act promoted economically harmful monopolies lacked critical support from the business community and that it was poorly administered The NIRA had no mechanisms for handling these problems which led Congress to pass the National Labor Relations Act in 1935 The act was also a major force behind a major modification of the law criminalizing making false statements Contents 1 Background and enactment 1 1 Enactment 2 Structure of the Act 3 Implementation 3 1 National Recovery Administration 3 2 Labor organizing provision 3 3 Public Works Administration 3 4 Proposed reauthorization 4 Legal challenge and nullification 5 Criticism 6 Legacy 7 References 8 Bibliography 9 For further reading 10 External linksBackground and enactment editThe Depression began in the United States in October 1929 and grew steadily worse to its nadir in early 1933 1 2 3 President Herbert Hoover feared that too much intervention or coercion by the government would destroy individuality and self reliance which he considered to be important American values His laissez faire views appeared to be shared by the Secretary of the Treasury Andrew W Mellon 4 5 6 To combat the growing economic decline Hoover organized a number of voluntary measures with businesses encouraged state and local government responses and accelerated federal building projects 7 However his policies had little or no effect on economic recovery 8 9 10 Toward the end of his term however Hoover supported several legislative solutions which he felt might lift the country out of the depression The final attempt of the Hoover administration to rescue the economy was the passage of the Emergency Relief and Construction Act which provided funds for public works programs and the Reconstruction Finance Corporation RFC which provided low interest loans to businesses 11 12 13 14 Hoover was defeated for re election by Roosevelt in the 1932 presidential election Roosevelt was convinced that federal activism was needed to reverse the country s economic decline In his first hundred days in office the Congress enacted at Roosevelt s request a series of bills designed to strengthen the banking system including the Emergency Banking Act the Glass Steagall Act which created the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation and the 1933 Banking Act 15 16 The Congress also passed the Agricultural Adjustment Act to stabilize the nation s agricultural industry 17 18 Enactment edit nbsp Hugh S Johnson one of the primary authors of NIRA was Time magazine s Man of the Year for 1933 Enactment of the National Industrial Recovery Act climaxed the first 100 days of Roosevelt s presidency Hugh S Johnson Raymond Moley Donald Richberg Rexford Tugwell Jerome Frank and Bernard Baruch key Roosevelt advisors believed that unrestrained competition had helped cause the Great Depression and that government had a critical role to play through national planning limited regulation the fostering of trade associations support for fair trade practices and support for democratization of the workplace a standard work week shorter working hours and better working conditions 19 20 21 22 23 24 Roosevelt himself the former head of a trade association 25 believed that government promotion of self organization by trade associations was the least intrusive and yet most effective method for achieving national planning and economic improvement 26 Some work on an industrial relief bill had been done in the weeks following Roosevelt s election but much of this was in the nature of talk and the exchange of ideas rather than legislative research and drafting The administration preoccupied with banking and agriculture legislation did not begin working on industrial relief legislation until early April 27 Congress however was moving on its own industrial legislation In the Senate Robert F Wagner Edward P Costigan and Robert M La Follette Jr were promoting public works legislation and Hugo Black was pushing short work week legislation 28 29 Motivated to work on his own industrial relief bill by these efforts Roosevelt ordered Moley to work with these Senators and anyone else in government who seemed interested to craft a bill 30 Overburdened Moley delegated this work to Hugh S Johnson 29 By May 1933 two draft bills had emerged a cautious and legalistic one by John Dickinson Under Secretary of Commerce and an ambitious one focusing on trade associations by Hugh Johnson 31 Many leading businessmen including Gerard Swope head of General Electric Charles M Schwab chairman of Bethlehem Steel Corporation E H Harriman chairman of the Union Pacific Railroad and Henry I Harriman president of the U S Chamber of Commerce helped draft the legislation 32 A two part bill the first section promoting cooperative action among business to achieve fair competition and provide for national planning and a second section establishing a national public works program was submitted to Congress on May 15 1933 33 The House of Representatives easily passed the bill in just seven days 34 The most contentious issue was the inclusion of Section 7 a which protected collective bargaining rights for unions 35 Section 7 a was nearly eliminated from the bill but Senator Wagner Jerome Frank and Leon Keyserling another Roosevelt aide worked to retain the section in order to win the support of the American labor movement 36 The bill had a more difficult time in the Senate The National Association of Manufacturers and Chamber of Commerce opposed its passage due to the labor provision 36 37 Despite the positions of these two important trade associations most businesses initially supported the NIRA 38 26 Senator Bennett Champ Clark introduced an amendment to weaken Section 7 a but Wagner and Senator George W Norris led the successful opposition to the change 36 The bulk of the Senate debate however turned on the bill s suspension of antitrust law Senators William E Borah Burton K Wheeler and Hugo Black opposed any relaxation of the Sherman Antitrust Act arguing that this would exacerbate existing severe economic inequality and concentrate wealth in the hands of the rich 39 a severe problem which many economists at the time believed was one of the causes of the Great Depression 40 41 Wagner defended the bill arguing that the bill s promotion of codes of fair trade practices would help create progressive standards for wages hours and working conditions and eliminate sweatshops and child labor 42 The Senate passed the amended legislation 57 to 24 on June 9 43 A House Senate conference committee met throughout the evening of June 9 and all day June 10 to reconcile the two versions of the bill approving a final version on the afternoon of June 10 The House approved the conference committee s bill on the evening of June 10 44 After extensive debate the Senate approved the final bill 46 to 39 on June 13 45 President Roosevelt signed the bill into law on June 16 1933 46 Structure of the Act editThe National Industrial Recovery Act had two major titles sections Title I was devoted to industrial recovery Title I Section 2 empowered the President to establish executive branch agencies to carry out the purposes of the Act and provided for a sunset provision nullifying the Act in two years 47 The heart of the Act was Title I Section 3 which permitted trade or industrial associations to seek presidential approval of codes of fair competition so long as such codes did not promote monopolies or provide unfair competition against small businesses and provided for enforcement of these codes 48 Title I Section 5 exempted the codes from the federal antitrust laws 49 50 Title I Section 7 a guaranteed the right of workers to form unions and banned yellow dog contracts employees shall have the right to organize and bargain collectively through representatives of their own choosing and shall be free from the interference restraint or coercion of employers of labor or their agents in the designation of such representatives or in self organization or in other concerted activities for the purpose of collective bargaining or other mutual aid or protection and 2 that no employee and no one seeking employment shall be required as a condition of employment to join any company union or to refrain from joining organizing or assisting a labor organization of his own choosing 51 Title I Section 7 b permitted the establishment of standards regarding maximum hours of labor minimum rates of pay and working conditions in the industries covered by the codes while Section 7 c authorized the President to impose such standards on codes when voluntary agreement could not be reached 52 Title I Section 9 authorized the regulation of oil pipelines and prices for the transportation of all petroleum products by pipeline 53 Section 9 b permitted the executive to take over any oil pipeline company subsidiary or business if the parent company was found in violation of the Act 54 Title II established the Public Works Administration Title II Section 201 established the agency and provided for a two year sunset provision 55 Section 202 outlines the types of public works which the new agency may seek to fund or build 56 Title II Section 203 authorized the Public Works Administration to provide grants and or loans to states and localities in order to more rapidly reduce unemployment as well as to use the power of eminent domain to seize land or materials to engage in public works 57 Title II Section 204 explicitly provided 400 million for the construction of public highways bridges roads railroad crossings paths and other transportation projects 58 Title II Section 208 authorized the president to expend up to 25 million to purchase farms for the purpose of relocating individuals living in overcrowded urban areas such as cities to these farms and allowing them to raise crops and earn a living there 59 Title II Sections 210 219 provided for revenues to fund the Act and Section 220 appropriated money for the Act s implementation 60 Title III of the Act contained miscellaneous provisions and transferred the authority to engage in public works from the Reconstruction Finance Corporation to the Public Works Administration 61 Implementation editImplementation of the act began immediately with the NRA and PWA the leading agencies 62 63 64 65 Hugh Johnson spent most of May and June planning for implementation and the National Recovery Administration NRA was established on June 20 1933 a scant four days after the law s enactment 66 Roosevelt angered Johnson by having him administer only the NRA while the Public Works Administration PWA went to Harold L Ickes 67 68 NRA and PWA reported to different cabinet agencies making coordination difficult and PWA money flowed so slowly into the economy 69 68 that NRA proved to be the more important agency by far National Recovery Administration edit Main article National Recovery Administration nbsp NRA Blue Eagle poster the image most commonly associated with the NIRA NIRA as implemented by the NRA became notorious for generating large numbers of regulations By March 1934 the NRA was engaged chiefly in drawing up these industrial codes for all industries to adopt 70 The agency approved 557 basic and 189 supplemental industry codes in two years 71 Between 4 000 and 5 000 business practices were prohibited some 3 000 administrative orders running to over 10 000 pages promulgated and thousands of opinions and guides from national regional and local code boards interpreted and enforced the Act 37 The premiere symbol of the NIRA was the Blue Eagle 72 By the end of 1934 large and small business owners 73 71 and most of the public 74 had turned against the NRA Roosevelt himself shifted his views on the best way to achieve economic recovery and began a new legislative program known as the Second New Deal in 1935 75 76 Labor organizing provision edit Implementation of Section 7 a of the NIRA proved immensely problematic as well The protections of the Act led to a massive wave of union organizing punctuated by employer and union violence general strikes and recognition strikes 77 78 79 At the outset NRA Administrator Hugh Johnson naively believed that Section 7 a would be self enforcing but he quickly learned otherwise 80 On August 5 1933 the National Labor Board was established under the auspices of the NRA to implement the collective bargaining provisions of the Act 80 The National Labor Board too proved to be ineffective and on July 5 1935 a new law the National Labor Relations Act superseded the NIRA and established a new long lasting federal labor policy 81 Public Works Administration edit Main article Public Works Administration NIRA also created a Public Works Administration not to be confused with the Works Progress Administration WPA of 1935 82 The leadership of the Public Works Authority was torn over the new agency s mission PWA could initiate its own construction projects distribute money to other federal agencies to fund their construction projects or make loans to states and localities to fund their construction projects 83 But many in the Roosevelt administration felt PWA should not spend money for fear of worsening the federal deficit and so funds flowed slowly 84 Furthermore the very nature of construction planning specifications and blueprints also held up the disbursement of money Harold Ickes too was determined to ensure that graft and corruption did not tarnish the agency s reputation and lead to loss of political support in Congress and so moved cautiously in spending the agency s money 85 Although the U S Supreme Court would rule Title I of NIRA unconstitutional the severability clause in the Act enabled the PWA to survive Among the projects it funded between 1935 and 1939 are the USS Yorktown USS Enterprise the 30th Street railroad station in Philadelphia Pennsylvania the Triborough Bridge the port of Brownsville Grand Coulee Dam Boulder Dam Fort Peck Dam Bonneville Dam and the Overseas Highway connecting Key West Florida with the mainland 86 The agency survived until 1943 when the Reorganization Act of 1939 consolidated most federal public works and work relief functions of the federal government into the new Federal Works Agency 87 88 Proposed reauthorization edit President Roosevelt sought an extension of NIRA on February 20 1935 89 But the business backlash against the New Deal 73 38 coupled with continuing congressional concern over the Act s suspension of antitrust law left the President s request politically dead 37 A U S Senate committee investigation into the effectiveness of the NRA PWA and Section 7 a revealed only limited political support for the law among Senators The Senate bill reauthorizing NIRA provided for only a 10 month extension with significant new limitations on NRA powers The House reauthorization bill contained no new limits on the NRA and proposed a two year extension 90 By May 1935 the issue was moot as the U S Supreme Court had ruled Title I of NIRA unconstitutional Legal challenge and nullification edit nbsp Chief Justice of the U S Charles Evans Hughes On April 13 1934 the President had approved the Code of Fair Competition for the Live Poultry Industry of the Metropolitan Area in and about the City of New York 91 The goal of the code was to ensure that live poultry provided to kosher slaughterhouses for butchering and sale to observant Jews were fit for human consumption and to prevent the submission of false sales and price reports The industry was almost entirely centered on New York City 92 Under the new poultry code the Schechter brothers were indicted on 60 counts of which 27 were dismissed by the trial court acquitted on 14 and convicted in 19 93 One of the counts on which they were convicted was for selling a diseased bird leading Hugh Johnson to jokingly call the suit the sick chicken case Even before these legal aspects became widely known a number of court challenges to the NIRA were winding their way through the courts The constitutionality of the NIRA was tested in Schechter Poultry Corp v United States 295 U S 495 1935 Courts identified three problems with the NIRA i was the subject matter sought to be regulated by the power of Congress ii if the regulations violated the Fifth Amendment to the United States Constitution and iii had Congress properly delegated its power to the executive 94 Although Roosevelt most of his aides Johnson and the NIRA staff felt the Act would survive a court test the U S Department of Justice had on March 25 1935 declined to appeal an appellate court ruling overturning the lumber industry code on the grounds that the case was not a good test of the NIRA s constitutionality 95 The Justice Department s action worried many in the administration But on April 1 1935 the Second Circuit Court of Appeals upheld the constitutionality of the NIRA in the Schechter case 95 Although Donald Richberg and others felt the government s case in Schechter was not a strong one the Schechters were determined to appeal their conviction So the government appealed first and the Supreme Court heard oral argument on May 2 and 3 96 On May 27 1935 Chief Justice Charles Evans Hughes wrote for a unanimous Court in Schechter Poultry Corp v The United States that Title I of the National Industrial Recovery Act was unconstitutional 97 98 1 First Hughes concluded that the law was void for vagueness because of the critical term fair competition a was nowhere defined in the Act 99 Second Hughes found the Act s delegation of authority to the executive branch unconstitutionally overbroad To summarize and conclude upon this point Section 3 of the Recovery Act 15 USCA 703 is without precedent It supplies no standards for any trade industry or activity It does not undertake to prescribe rules of conduct to be applied to particular states of fact determined by appropriate administrative procedure Instead of prescribing rules of conduct it authorizes the making of codes to prescribe them For that legislative undertaking section 3 sets up no standards aside from the statement of the general aims of rehabilitation correction and expansion described in section 1 In view of the scope of that broad declaration and of the nature of the few restrictions that are imposed the discretion of the President in approving or prescribing codes and thus enacting laws for the government of trade and industry throughout the country is virtually unfettered We think that the code making authority thus conferred is an unconstitutional delegation of legislative power 100 Finally in a very restrictive reading of what constituted interstate commerce 101 Hughes held that the current or flow of commerce involved was simply too minute to constitute interstate commerce and subsequently Congress had no power under the Commerce Clause to enact legislation affecting such commercial transactions 102 The Court dismissed with a bare paragraph the government s ability to regulate wages and hours 103 Although the government had argued that the national economic emergency required special consideration Hughes disagreed The dire economic circumstances the country faced did not justify the overly broad delegation or overreach of the Act the majority concluded Extraordinary conditions may call for extraordinary remedies But the argument necessarily stops short of an attempt to justify action which lies outside the sphere of constitutional authority Extraordinary conditions do not create or enlarge constitutional power 104 Although the decision emasculated NIRA it had little practical impact as Congress was unlikely to have reauthorized the Act in any case 101 b Criticism editAt the time and in recent analyzes NIRA is generally considered to be a failure 105 106 107 108 A key criticism of the Act at the time as well as more recently is that the NIRA endorsed monopolies with the attendant economic problems associated with that type of market failure 71 109 Even the National Recovery Review Board established by President Roosevelt in March 1934 to review the performance of the NIRA concluded that the Act hindered economic growth by promoting cartels and monopolies c One of the economic effects of monopoly and cartels is higher prices this was seen as necessary because the severe deflation of 1929 33 had depressed prices 20 and more 111 112 There is anecdotal evidence that these higher prices led to some stability in industry 113 but a number of scholars maintain that these prices were so high that economic recovery was inhibited 109 114 But other economists disagree pointing to far more important monetary budgetary and tax policies as contributors to the continuation of the Great Depression 115 Others point out that the cartels created by the Act were inherently unstable as all cartels are and that the effect on prices was minimal because the codes collapsed so quickly 116 117 A second key criticism of the Act is that it lacked support from the business community and thus was doomed to failure Business support for national planning and government intervention was very strong in 1933 but had collapsed by mid 1934 73 71 Many studies conclude however that business support for NIRA was never uniform Larger older businesses embraced the legislation while smaller newer ones more nimble in a highly competitive market and with less capital investment to lose if they failed did not 26 118 This is a classic problem of cartels and thus NIRA codes failed as small business abandoned the cartels 116 117 Studies of the steel automobile manufacturing lumber textile and rubber industries and the level and source of support for the NIRA tend to support this conclusion 119 Without the support of industry the Act could never have performed as it was intended A third major criticism of the Act is that it was poorly administered The Act purposefully brought together competing for interests labor and business big business and small business etc in a coalition to support passage of the legislation but these competing interests soon fought one another over the Act s implementation 120 116 As a consequence NIRA collapsed due to failure of leadership and confusion about its goals By the end of 1934 NIRA leaders had practically abandoned the progressive interventionist policy which motivated the Act s passage and were supporting free market philosophies contributing to the collapse of almost all industry codes 113 There are a wide range of additional critiques as well One is that NIRA s industry codes interfered with capital markets inhibiting economic recovery 121 But more recent analyzes conclude that NIRA had little effect on capital markets one way or the other 122 Another is that political uncertainty created by the NIRA caused a drop in business confidence inhibiting recovery 123 But at least one study has shown no effect whatsoever 124 Section 7 a led to significant increases in union organizing but NRA administrative rulings effectively gutted this section by permitting company union 1 125 Although Section 7 a was not affected by the Supreme Court s decision in Schechter Poultry the failure of the section led directly to passage of the National Labor Relations Act in July 1935 81 Historian Alan Brinkley stated that by 1935 the NIRA was a woeful failure even a political embarrassment Many liberals probably including Roosevelt were quietly relieved by its demise However New Dealers were worried by the Supreme Court s strict interpretation of the interstate commerce clause and worried that other legislation was jeopardized 126 Legacy editIn 1934 at the request of the Secretary Ickes who wished to use the statute criminalizing making false statements to enforce Section 9 c of the NIRA against producers of hot oil oil produced in violation of production restrictions established pursuant to the NIRA Congress passed Pub L Tooltip Public Law United States 73 394 48 Stat 996 enacted June 18 1934 which amended the False Claims Act of 1863 to read 127 or whoever for the purpose of obtaining or aiding to obtain the payment or approval of such claim or for the purpose and with the intent of cheating and swindling or defrauding the Government of the United States or any department thereof or any corporation in which the United States of America is a stockholder shall knowingly and willfully falsify or conceal or cover up by any trick scheme or device a material fact or make or cause to be made any false or fraudulent statements or representations or make or use or cause to be made or used any false bill receipt voucher roll account claim certificate affidavit or deposition knowing the same to contain any fraudulent or fictitious statement or entry in any matter within the jurisdiction of any department or agency of the United States or of any corporation in which the United States of America is a stockholder This form of the statute in slightly modified form still exists today at 18 U S C 1001 References editNotes The National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title I Sec 3 a reads Upon the application to the President by one or more trade or industrial associations or groups the President may approve a code or codes of fair competition for the trade or industry or subdivision thereof As of 2007 Schechter Poultry and Panama Refining Co v Ryan 293 U S 388 1935 are the only cases in which the Supreme Court has struck down an act of Congress for overbroad delegation of legislative authority See Ross The Chief Justiceship of Charles Evans Hughes 1930 1941 2007 This was not however unexpected Senator Gerald Nye an ardent opponent of monopolies named five of the board s six members and long time antitrust advocate Clarence Darrow led the Board 110 Citations a b Kennedy 2005 pp 151 154 Hall amp Ferguson 1998 p 113 Dorich 2021 p 75 Smith 1970 pp 57 64 Barber 1989 pp 82 108 Sobel 1975 pp 56 64 Barber 1989 pp 16 20 93 105 176 Schlesinger 2003a pp 248 249 Schlesinger 2003b pp 87 176 Kennedy 2005 pp 93 151 154 Schlesinger 2003b p 87 176 236 263 Kennedy 2005 p 84 151 154 Olson 2001 p 93 Barber 1989 pp 178 180 Schlesinger 2003b pp 20 21 87 176 Kennedy 2005 pp 138 140 Schlesinger 2003b pp 39 44 Kennedy 2005 pp 143 Vadney 1970 pp 98 119 191 204 Schlesinger 2003b pp 88 92 94 Brand 1988 pp 74 79 Hawley 1966 p 172 Stabile amp Kozak 2012 pp 77 79 Sternsher 1964 pp 102 105 Schlesinger 2003a p 374 a b c Eisner 2000 p 85 Schlesinger 2003b pp 95 98 Schlesinger 2003b p 95 a b Houck 2001 p 185 Schlesinger 2003b p 96 McKenna 2002 p 77 Schlesinger 2003b pp 36 37 88 89 97 88 Peters Gerhard Woolley John T Franklin D Roosevelt Message to Congress Recommending Enactment of the National Industrial Recovery Act May 17 1933 The American Presidency Project University of California Santa Barbara McKenna 2002 pp 77 78 Morris 2004 p xviii a b c Schlesinger 2003b p 99 a b c Best 1991 a b Brand 1988 p 27 Bellush 1975 Galbraith 1997 pp 182 183 191 Borah Debates With Wagner The New York Times June 8 1933 p 4 Schlesinger 2003b p 174 Income Publicity Voted The New York Times June 10 1933 pp 1 4 Recess Taken to Monday The New York Times June 11 1933 pp 1 3 Lund and Harriman Back Recovery Act The New York Times June 14 1933 pp 1 7 Schlesinger 2003b pp 21 102 National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title I Sec 2 National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title I Sec 3 National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title I Sec 5 Taylor 2019 pp 15 18 National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title I Sec 7 a National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title I Sec 7 b National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title I Sec 9 a National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title I Sec 9 b Sections in Title I of the NIRA are numbered 1 2 3 etc However in a discrepancy sections in Title II and III of the NIRA are numbered 201 202 203 etc and 301 302 303 etc National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title II Sec 201 National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title II Sec 202 National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title II Sec 203 National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title II Sec 204 National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title II Sec 208 National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title II Sec 210 220 National Industrial Recovery Act Ch 90 48 Stat 195 Title III Schlesinger 2003b p 282 Kennedy 2005 p 151 Stabile amp Kozak 2012 p 197 Kemp 2000 p 210 Schlesinger 2003b p 107 Schlesinger 2003b p 104 a b Kennedy 2005 p 178 Schlesinger 2003b p 109 Our Documents National Industrial Recovery Act National Archives Retrieved April 15 2014 a b c d Eisner 2000 p 86 Schlesinger 2003b p 114 a b c Schlesinger 2003c pp 211 215 Schlesinger 2003b p 166 Schlesinger 2003c pp 385 389 Venn 1999 pp 57 59 Dubofsky amp Dulles 2010 pp 257 163 Bernstein 2010 Rayback 1974 pp 327 329 a b Morris 2004 p 25 a b Watkins 2000 pp 297 300 Elving Ron April 4 2020 In The 1930s Works Program Spelled HOPE For Millions of Jobless Americans NPR Retrieved November 5 2022 Schlesinger 2003b p 284 Schlesinger 2003b p 202 Schlesinger 2003b p 285 Schlesinger 2003b p 288 Executive Order 9357 Transferring the Functions of the Public Works Administration to the Federal Works Agency The American Presidency Project June 30 1943 Retrieved November 20 2022 Olson 2001 pp 111 233 Schlesinger 2003b p 165 Bellush 1975 pp 165 167 Schechter Poultry Corp v The United States 295 U S 495 555 fn 5 Barnett amp Blackman 2021 p 222 Schechter Poultry Corp v The United States 295 U S 495 555 fn 2 Harvard Law Review 1933 pp 86 87 a b Schlesinger 2003c p 277 Schlesinger 2003c p 279 Schlesinger 2003c pp 279 280 Biles 1991 pp 78 95 Schechter Poultry Corp v United States 295 U S 495 531 Schechter Poultry Corp v United States 295 U S 495 541 542 a b Ross The Chief Justiceship of Charles Evans Hughes 1930 1941 2007 Schechter Poultry Corp v United States 295 U S 495 542 548 Schechter Poultry Corp v United States 295 U S 495 548 550 Schechter Poultry Corp v United States 295 U S 495 528 Geisst 2006 p 298 Walton 1992 p 302 Skocpol 1994 pp 345 347 Delton 2020 p 120 a b Cole Harold L Ohanian Lee E February 2 2009 How Government Prolonged the Depression The Wall Street Journal Retrieved November 20 2022 Schlesinger 2003b pp 132 134 Eisner 2000 pp 83 84 Fisher 1933 pp 344 352 a b Horwitz 1989 p 72 Weinstein Recovery and Redistribution Under the NIRA 1980 page needed Roose The Economics of Recession and Revival An Interpretation of 1937 38 1954 page needed Hayes Business Confidence and Business Activity A Case Study of the Recession of 1937 1951 page needed Friedman and Schwartz A Monetary History of the United States 1867 1960 1963 page needed Bernanke B Parkinson M 1989 Unemployment Inflation and Wages in the American Depression Are There Lessons for Europe The American Economic Review 79 2 210 14 doi 10 3386 w2862 JSTOR 1827758 a b c Krepps M 1999 Facilitating practices and the path dependence of collusion International Journal of Industrial Organization 17 6 887 901 doi 10 1016 S0167 7187 97 00066 0 Krepps Matthew B 1997 Another Look at the Impact of the National Industrial Recovery Act on Cartel Formation and Maintenance Costs Review of Economics and Statistics 79 151 54 doi 10 1162 003465397556502 S2CID 57568487 a b Lande Robert H Connor John M 2005 How High Do Cartels Raise Prices Implications for Reform of the Antitrust Sentencing Guidelines Tulane Law Review 80 SSRN 787907 Harringtonjr J Chen J 2006 Cartel pricing dynamics with cost variability and endogenous buyer detection International Journal of Industrial Organization 24 6 1185 212 doi 10 1016 j ijindorg 2006 04 012 Perloff Jeffrey M Karp Larry S and Golan Amos Estimating Market Power and Strategies New York Cambridge University Press 2007 ISBN 052180440X page needed Galambos Competition and Cooperation The Emergence of a National Trade Association 1966 page needed Collins R M 1978 Positive Business Responses to the New Deal The Roots of the Committee for Economic Development 1933 1942 The Business History Review 52 3 369 91 doi 10 2307 3113736 JSTOR 3113736 S2CID 146238143 Stewart Steel Problems of a Great Industry 1937 page needed Kennedy The Automobile Industry The Coming of Age of Capitalism s Favorite Child 1941 page needed Daugherty et al The Economics of the Iron and Steel Industry 1937 page needed Rae American Automobile Manufacturers The First Forty Years 1959 page needed James L M 1946 Restrictive Agreements and Practices in the Lumber Industry 1880 1939 Southern Economic Journal 13 2 115 25 doi 10 2307 1052520 JSTOR 1052520 Shaffer In Restraint of Trade The Business Campaign Against Competition 1918 1938 1997 page needed Pennock P 1997 The National Recovery Administration and the Rubber Tire Industry 1933 1935 The Business History Review 71 4 543 68 doi 10 2307 3116306 JSTOR 3116306 S2CID 154346794 Eisner 2000 pp 84 86 Lyon et al The National Recovery Administration An Analysis and Appraisal 1935 Anderson William L 2000 Risk and the National Industrial Recovery Act An Empirical Evaluation Public Choice 103 139 61 doi 10 1023 A 1005054019819 S2CID 152916565 Bernstein The Great Depression Delayed Recovery and Economic Change in America 1929 1939 1989 Mayer Thomas Chatterji Monojit 2009 Political Shocks and Investment Some Evidence from the 1930s The Journal of Economic History 45 4 913 924 doi 10 1017 S0022050700035166 JSTOR 2121886 S2CID 155005461 Bellush 1975 pp 176 177 Brinkley 1995 p 18 United States v Gilliland 312 US 86 93 94 1941 Legislation had been sought by the Secretary of the Interior to aid the enforcement of laws relating to the functions of the Department of the Interior and in particular to the enforcement of regulations under Sec 9 c of the NIRA Bibliography editAnderson William L April 2000 Risk and the National Industrial Recovery Act An Empirical Evaluation Public Choice 103 1 2 139 161 doi 10 1023 A 1005054019819 S2CID 152916565 Barber William J 1989 From New Era to New Deal Herbert Hoover the Economists and American Economic Policy 1921 1933 New York Cambridge University Press ISBN 9780521367370 Barnett Randy E Blackman Josh 2021 Constitutional Law Cases in Context New York Wolters Kluwer ISBN 9781543838787 Bellush Bernard 1975 The Failure of the NRA New York W W Norton ISBN 9780393055481 Bernanke Ben Parkinson Martin May 1989 Unemployment Inflation and Wages in the American Depression Are There Lessons for Europe American Economic Review 79 2 210 214 doi 10 3386 w2862 Bernstein Irving 2010 1969 The Turbulent Years A History of the American Worker 1933 1941 Chicago Haymarket Books ISBN 9781608460649 Bernstein Michael 1987 The Great Depression Delayed Recovery and Economic Change in America 1929 1939 New York Cambridge University Press ISBN 9780521379854 Best Gary Dean 1991 Pride Prejudice and Politics Roosevelt Versus Recovery 1933 1938 New York Praeger Publishers ISBN 9780275935245 Biles Roger 1991 A New Deal for the American People DeKalb Ill Northern Illinois University Press ISBN 9780875801612 Brand Donald Robert 1988 Corporatism and the Rule of Law A Study of the National Recovery Administration Ithaca N Y Cornell University Press ISBN 9780801421693 Brinkley Alan 1995 The End of Reform New Deal Liberalism in Recession and War New York Vintage Books ISBN 9780679753148 Collins Robert M Autumn 1978 Positive Business Responses to the New Deal The Roots of the Committee for Economic Development 1933 1942 Business History Review 52 3 369 391 doi 10 2307 3113736 JSTOR 3113736 S2CID 146238143 Daugherty Carroll R de Chazeau Melvin G Stratton Samuel S 1937 The Economics of the Iron and Steel Industry Pittsburgh Bureau of Business Research University of Pittsburgh OCLC 503553 Delton Jennifer 2020 The Industrialists Now the National Association of Manufacturers Shaped American Capitalism Princeton N J Princeton University Press ISBN 9780691167862 Dorich Thomas J 2021 Big Business in America The Corporate Century 1900 2000 Lanham Md Lexington Books ISBN 9781498595971 Dubofsky Melvyn Dulles Foster Rhea 2010 Labor in America A History Hoboken N J John Wiley amp Sons ISBN 9780882952734 Eisner Marc Allen 2000 Regulatory Politics in Transition Baltimore The Johns Hopkins University Press ISBN 9780801864926 Farrell Chris 2004 Deflation What Happens When Prices Fall New York HarperCollins ISBN 9780060576455 Fine Sidney 1963 Automobile Under the Blue Eagle Labor Management and the Automobile Manufacturing Code Ann Arbor Mich University of Michigan Press OCLC 999975 Fisher Irving October 1933 The Debt Deflation Theory of Great Depressions PDF Econometrica 1 4 337 357 doi 10 2307 1907327 JSTOR 1907327 Friedman Milton Schwartz Anna J 1963 A Monetary History of the United States 1867 1960 Princeton N J Princeton University Press ISBN 9781400829330 OCLC 1331033779 Galambos Louis 1966 Competition and Cooperation The Emergence of a National Trade Association Baltimore The Johns Hopkins University Press OCLC 237577 Galbraith John Kenneth 1997 1954 The Great Crash of 1929 Boston Houghton Mifflin amp Co ISBN 9780395859995 Geisst Charles R 2006 Encyclopedia of American Business History New York Facts On File ISBN 9780816043507 Gross James A 1974 The Making of the National Labor Relations Board A Study in Economics Politics and the Law Albany N Y State University of New York Press Press ISBN 9780873952705 Hall Thomas E Ferguson David 1998 The Great Depression An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies Ann Arbor Mich University of Michigan Press ISBN 9780472096671 Harrington Joseph E Jr Chen Joe November 2006 Cartel Pricing Dynamics With Cost Variability and Endogenous Buyer Detection International Journal of Industrial Organization 24 6 1185 1212 doi 10 1016 j ijindorg 2006 04 012 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Hawley Ellis 1966 The New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly Princeton N J Princeton University Press ISBN 9781400875313 Hayes Douglas A 1951 Business Confidence and Business Activity A Case Study of the Recession of 1937 Ann Arbor Mich University of Michigan Press OCLC 3700753 Horwitz Robert Britt 1989 The Irony of Regulatory Reform The Deregulation of American Telecommunications New York Oxford University Press ISBN 9780195054453 Houck David W 2001 Rhetoric As Currency Hoover Roosevelt and the Great Depression College Station Tx Texas A amp M University Press ISBN 9781585441099 James Lee M October 1946 Restrictive Agreements and Practices in the Lumber Industry 1880 1939 Southern Economic Journal 13 2 115 125 doi 10 2307 1052520 JSTOR 1052520 Kemp Emory L 2000 The Great Kanawha Navigation Pittsburgh University of Pittsburgh Press ISBN 9780822941125 Kennedy David M 2005 Freedom from Fear The American People in Depression and War 1929 1945 New York Oxford University Press ISBN 9780195144031 Kennedy Edward Donald 1941 The Automobile Industry The Coming of Age of Capitalism s Favorite Child New York Reynal and Hitchcock OCLC 3247284 Krepps Matthew B February 1997 Another Look at the Impact of the National Industrial Recovery Act on Cartel Formation and Maintenance Costs Review of Economics and Statistics 79 1 151 154 doi 10 1162 003465397556502 S2CID 57568487 Krepps Matthew B August 1999 Facilitating Practices and the Path Dependence of Collusion International Journal of Industrial Organization 17 6 887 901 doi 10 1016 S0167 7187 97 00066 0 Lande Robert H Connor John M December 2005 How High Do Cartels Raise Prices Implications for Reform of the Antitrust Sentencing Guidelines Tulane Law Review 80 2 513 570 doi 10 2139 ssrn 787907 S2CID 155973465 Levine Rhonda F 1988 Class Struggle and the New Deal Industrial Labor Industrial Capital and the State Lawrence Kan University Press of Kansas ISBN 9780700603732 Lyon Leverett S Homan Paul T George Terborgh Lorwin Lewis L Dearing Charles L Marshall Leon C 1935 The National Recovery Administration An Analysis and Appraisal Washington D C The Brookings Institution OCLC 1050549832 Mayer Thomas Chatterji Monojit December 1985 Political Shocks and Investment Some Evidence from the 1930s Journal of Economic History 45 4 913 924 doi 10 1017 S0022050700035166 S2CID 155005461 McKenna Marian C 2002 Franklin Roosevelt and the Great Constitutional War The Court Packing Crisis of 1937 New York Fordham University Press ISBN 9780823221547 Morris Charles 2004 The Blue Eagle At Work Reclaiming Democratic Rights In The American Workplace Ithaca N Y ILR Press ISBN 9780801443176 Olson James Stuart 2001 Historical Dictionary of the Great Depression 1929 1940 Westport Conn Greenwood Press ISBN 9780313306181 Pennock Pamela Winter 1997 The National Recovery Administration and the Rubber Tire Industry 1933 1935 Business History Review 71 4 543 568 doi 10 2307 3116306 JSTOR 3116306 S2CID 154346794 Perloff Jeffrey M Karp Larry S Golan Amos 2007 Estimating Market Power and Strategies New York Cambridge University Press ISBN 9780521011143 Rae John B 1959 American Automobile Manufacturers The First Forty Years Philadelphia Chilton Book OCLC 1004807020 Rayback Joseph G 1974 A History of American Labor New York Macmillan ISBN 9781439118993 OCLC 615514713 Roose Kenneth D 1954 The Economics of Recession and Revival New Haven Conn Yale University Press OCLC 252427283 Ross William G 2007 The Chief Justiceship of Charles Evans Hughes 1930 1941 Columbia S C University of South Carolina Press ISBN 9781570036798 Schlesinger Arthur M Jr 2003 The Age of Roosevelt Vol 1 Crisis of the Old Order Boston Houghton Mifflin ISBN 9780618340859 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Schlesinger Arthur M Jr 2003 The Age of Roosevelt Vol 2 The Coming of the New Deal Boston Houghton Mifflin ISBN 9780618340866 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Schlesinger Arthur M Jr 2003 The Age of Roosevelt Vol 3 The Politics of Upheaval 1935 1936 Boston Houghton Mifflin ISBN 9780547524252 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Shaffer Butler D 1997 In Restraint of Trade The Business Campaign Against Competition 1918 1938 Lewisburg Pa Bucknell University Press ISBN 9780838753255 Skocpol Theda 1994 Political Response to Capitalist Crisis Neo Marxist Theories of the State and the Case of the New Deal In Scott John ed Power Critical Concepts Volume 3 New York Routledge ISBN 9780415079372 Smith Gene 1970 The Shattered Dream Herbert Hoover and the Great Depression New York Willam Morrow and Co OCLC 76078 Sobel Robert 1975 Herbert Hoover at the Onset of the Great Depression 1929 1930 New York Lippincott ISBN 9780397473342 Some Legal Aspects of the National Industrial Recovery Act Harvard Law Review 47 1 85 125 November 1933 doi 10 2307 1332107 JSTOR 1332107 Stabile Donald R Kozak Andrew R 2012 Markets Planning and the Moral Economy Business Cycles in the Progressive Era and New Deal Northampton Mass Edward Elgar Publishing ISBN 9781781006764 Sternsher Bernard 1964 Rexford Tugwell and the New Deal New Brunswick N J Rutgers University Press OCLC 466310 Stewart Maxwell S 1937 Steel Problems of a Great Industry New York Public Affairs Committee OCLC 3716534 Taylor Jason E 2019 Deconstructing the Monolith The Microeconomics of the National Industrial Recovery Act Chicago The University of Chicago Press ISBN 9780226603308 Tomlins Christopher L 1985 The State and the Unions Labor Relations Law and the Organized Labor Movement in America 1880 1960 New York Cambridge University Press ISBN 9780521314527 Vadney Thomas E 1970 The Wayward Liberal A Political Biography of Donald Richberg Lexington Ky The University Press of Kentucky ISBN 9780813112435 Venn Fiona 1999 The New Deal New York Taylor amp Francis ISBN 9781315062532 Vittoz Stanley 1987 New Deal Labor Policy and the American Industrial Economy Chapel Hill N C University of North Carolina Press ISBN 9780807817292 Walton John 1992 Western Times and Water Wars State Culture and Rebellion in California Berkeley Calif University of California Press ISBN 9780520072459 Watkins T H 2000 The Hungry Hears A Narrative History of the Great Depression in America New York Henry Holt amp Co ISBN 9780805065060 Weinstein Michael 1980 Recovery and Redistribution Under the NIRA New York North Holland Publishing ISBN 9780444860071 For further reading editBeaudreau Bernard C Why Did the National Industrial Recovery Act Fail European Review of Economic History 20 2015 79 101 Bernstein Irving 2020 1950 The New Deal Collective Bargaining Policy Berkeley Calif University of California Press ISBN 9780520346956 Clarke Jeanne Nienaber 1996 Roosevelt s Warrior Harold L Ickes and the New Deal Baltimore The Johns Hopkins University Press ISBN 978 0801850943 Himmelberg Robert 1993 The Origins of the National Recovery Administration New York Fordham University Press ISBN 978 0823215409 Johnson Hugh S 1935 The Blue Eagle From Egg to Earth New York Doubleday Doran amp Co OCLC 1064791053 Moley Raymond 1936 After Seven Years New York Harper amp Brothers OCLC 854808142 National Recovery Review Board 1934 Report to the President of the United States First Report of the National Recovery Review Board Report Washington D C National Recovery Administration hdl 2027 mdp 35112103647402 OCLC 35406585 Ohl John Kennedy Hugh S Johnson and the New Deal Dekalb Ill Northern Illinois University Press 1985 ISBN 0 87580 110 2 Paulsen George E March 1989 The Federal Trade Commission versus the National Recovery Administration Fair Trade Practices and Voluntary Codes 1935 Social Science Quarterly 70 1 149 163 Phillips Cabell B H 2000 From the Crash to the Blitz 1929 1939 The New York Times Chronicle of American Life New York Fordham University Press ISBN 978 0823219995 Richberg Donald 1954 My Hero The Indiscreet Memoirs of an Eventful But Unheroic Life New York Putnam OCLC 1522089 Shogan Robert 2006 Backlash The Killing of the New Deal Chicago Ivan R Dee ISBN 978 1566636742 Smith Angella LaNette Economic revolution from within Herbert Hoover Franklin Delano Roosevelt and the emergence of the National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933 PhD dissertation Wayne State University 2015 ProQuest Dissertations Publishing 2015 3734689 External links editText of the National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933 amp oldid 1166031848, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.