fbpx
Wikipedia

Mathematical sociology

Mathematical sociology or the sociology of mathematics[1] is an interdisciplinary field of research concerned both with the use of mathematics within sociological research[2] as well as research into the relationships that exist between maths and society.[3]

Mathematical Bridge, or officially Wooden Bridge, is an arch bridge in Cambridge, United Kingdom. The arrangement of timbers is a series of tangents that describe the arc of the bridge, with radial members to tie the tangents together and triangulate the structure, making it rigid and self-supporting.

Because of this, mathematical sociology can have a diverse meaning depending on the authors in question and the kind of research being carried out. This creates contestation over whether mathematical sociology is a derivative of sociology, an intersection of the two disciplines, or a discipline in its own right.[4] This is a dynamic, ongoing academic development that leaves mathematical sociology sometimes blurred and lacking in uniformity, presenting grey areas and need for further research into developing its academic merit.[5][6]

History edit

Starting in the early 1940s, Nicolas Rashevsky,[7][8] and subsequently in the late 1940s, Anatol Rapoport and others, developed a relational and probabilistic approach to the characterization of large social networks in which the nodes are persons and the links are acquaintanceship. During the late 1940s, formulas were derived that connected local parameters such as closure of contacts – if A is linked to both B and C, then there is a greater than chance probability that B and C are linked to each other – to the global network property of connectivity.[9]

Moreover, acquaintanceship is a positive tie, but what about negative ties such as animosity among persons? To tackle this problem, graph theory, which is the mathematical study of abstract representations of networks of points and lines, can be extended to include these two types of links and thereby to create models that represent both positive and negative sentiment relations, which are represented as signed graphs. A signed graph is called balanced if the product of the signs of all relations in every cycle (links in every graph cycle) is positive. Through formalization by mathematician Frank Harary, this work produced the fundamental theorem of this theory. It says that if a network of interrelated positive and negative ties is balanced, e.g. as illustrated by the psychological principle that "my friend's enemy is my enemy", then it consists of two sub-networks such that each has positive ties among its nodes and there are only negative ties between nodes in distinct sub-networks.[10] The imagery here is of a social system that splits into two cliques. There is, however, a special case where one of the two sub-networks is empty, which might occur in very small networks. In another model, ties have relative strengths. 'Acquaintanceship' can be viewed as a 'weak' tie and 'friendship' is represented as a strong tie. Like its uniform cousin discussed above, there is a concept of closure, called strong triadic closure. A graph satisfies strong triadic closure If A is strongly connected to B, and B is strongly connected to C, then A and C must have a tie (either weak or strong).

In these two developments we have mathematical models bearing upon the analysis of structure. Other early influential developments in mathematical sociology pertained to process. For instance, in 1952 Herbert A. Simon produced a mathematical formalization of a published theory[11] of social groups by constructing a model consisting of a deterministic system of differential equations. A formal study of the system led to theorems about the dynamics and the implied equilibrium states of any group.

The emergence of mathematical models in the social sciences was part of the zeitgeist in the 1940s and 1950s in which a variety of new interdisciplinary scientific innovations occurred, such as information theory, game theory, cybernetics and mathematical model building in the social and behavioral sciences.[12]

Approaches edit

Mathematics in sociology edit

Focusing on mathematics within sociological research, mathematical sociology uses mathematics to construct social theories. Mathematical sociology aims to take sociological theory and to express it in mathematical terms. The benefits of this approach include increased clarity and the ability to use mathematics to derive implications of a theory that cannot be arrived at intuitively. In mathematical sociology, the preferred style is encapsulated in the phrase "constructing a mathematical model." This means making specified assumptions about some social phenomenon, expressing them in formal mathematics, and providing an empirical interpretation for the ideas. It also means deducing properties of the model and comparing these with relevant empirical data. Social network analysis is the best-known contribution of this subfield to sociology as a whole and to the scientific community at large. The models typically used in mathematical sociology allow sociologists to understand how predictable local interactions are and they are often able to elicit global patterns of social structure.[13]

Society and mathematics edit

Interested in the relationship between society and mathematical knowledge, mathematical sociology or the sociology of mathematics forms a complementary sphere from disciplines like the sociology of knowledge and sociology of science that tries to understand the social roots of mathematics as well as the impact maths has had on society.[14][15] This reflexivity on the development and use of maths within sociology attempts to understand how the facts of mathematics related to social constructions and the implications of bias that maths may bring when applied to efforts in understanding social phenomanon.[16][17]

Further developments edit

In 1954, a critical expository analysis of Rashevsky's social behavior models was written by sociologist James S. Coleman.[18] Rashevsky's models and as well as the model constructed by Simon raise a question: how can one connect such theoretical models to the data of sociology, which often take the form of surveys in which the results are expressed in the form of proportions of people believing or doing something. This suggests deriving the equations from assumptions about the chances of an individual changing state in a small interval of time, a procedure well known in the mathematics of stochastic processes.

Coleman embodied this idea in his 1964 book Introduction to Mathematical Sociology, which showed how stochastic processes in social networks could be analyzed in such a way as to enable testing of the constructed model by comparison with the relevant data. The same idea can and has been applied to processes of change in social relations, an active research theme in the study of social networks, illustrated by an empirical study appearing in the journal Science.[19]

In other work, Coleman employed mathematical ideas drawn from economics, such as general equilibrium theory, to argue that general social theory should begin with a concept of purposive action and, for analytical reasons, approximate such action by the use of rational choice models (Coleman, 1990). This argument is similar to viewpoints expressed by other sociologists in their efforts to use rational choice theory in sociological analysis although such efforts have met with substantive and philosophical criticisms.[20]

Meanwhile, structural analysis of the type indicated earlier received a further extension to social networks based on institutionalized social relations, notably those of kinship. The linkage of mathematics and sociology here involved abstract algebra, in particular, group theory.[21] This, in turn, led to a focus on a data-analytical version of homomorphic reduction of a complex social network (which along with many other techniques is presented in Wasserman and Faust 1994[22]).

In regard to Rapoport's random and biased net theory, his 1961 study of a large sociogram, co-authored with Horvath turned out to become a very influential paper.[23] There was early evidence of this influence. In 1964, Thomas Fararo and a co-author analyzed another large friendship sociogram using a biased net model.[24] Later in the 1960s, Stanley Milgram described the small world problem and undertook a field experiment dealing with it.[25][26] A highly fertile idea was suggested and applied by Mark Granovetter in which he drew upon Rapoport's 1961 paper to suggest and apply a distinction between weak and strong ties. The key idea was that there was "strength" in weak ties.[27]

Some programs of research in sociology employ experimental methods to study social interaction processes. Joseph Berger and his colleagues initiated such a program in which the central idea is the use of the theoretical concept "expectation state" to construct theoretical models to explain interpersonal processes, e.g., those linking external status in society to differential influence in local group decision-making. Much of this theoretical work is linked to mathematical model building, especially after the late 1970s adoption of a graph theoretic representation of social information processing, as Berger (2000) describes in looking back upon the development of his program of research. In 1962 he and his collaborators explained model building by reference to the goal of the model builder, which could be explication of a concept in a theory, representation of a single recurrent social process, or a broad theory based on a theoretical construct, such as, respectively, the concept of balance in psychological and social structures, the process of conformity in an experimental situation, and stimulus sampling theory.[28]

The generations of mathematical sociologists that followed Rapoport, Simon, Harary, Coleman, White and Berger, including those entering the field in the 1960s such as Thomas Fararo, Philip Bonacich, and Tom Mayer, among others, drew upon their work in a variety of ways.

Present research edit

Mathematical sociology remains a small subfield within the discipline, but it has succeeded in spawning a number of other subfields which share its goals of formally modeling social life. The foremost of these fields is social network analysis, which has become among the fastest growing areas of sociology in the 21st century.[29] The other major development in the field is the rise of computational sociology, which expands the mathematical toolkit with the use of computer simulations, artificial intelligence and advanced statistical methods. The latter subfield also makes use of the vast new data sets on social activity generated by social interaction on the internet.

One important indicator of the significance of mathematical sociology is that the general interest journals in the field, including such central journals as The American Journal of Sociology and The American Sociological Review, have published mathematical models that became influential in the field at large.

More recent trends in mathematical sociology are evident in contributions to The Journal of Mathematical Sociology (JMS). Several trends stand out: the further development of formal theories that explain experimental data dealing with small group processes, the continuing interest in structural balance as a major mathematical and theoretical idea, the interpenetration of mathematical models oriented to theory and innovative quantitative techniques relating to methodology, the use of computer simulations to study problems in social complexity, interest in micro–macro linkage and the problem of emergence, and ever-increasing research on networks of social relations.

Thus, topics from the earliest days, like balance and network models, continue to be of contemporary interest. The formal techniques employed remain many of the standard and well-known methods of mathematics: differential equations, stochastic processes and game theory. Newer tools like agent-based models used in computer simulation studies are prominently represented. Perennial substantive problems still drive research: social diffusion, social influence, social status origins and consequences, segregation, cooperation, collective action, power, and much more.

Research programs edit

Many of the developments in mathematical sociology, including formal theory, have exhibited notable decades-long advances that began with path-setting contributions by leading mathematical sociologists and formal theorists. This provides another way of taking note of recent contributions but with an emphasis on continuity with early work through the use of the idea of “research program,” which is a coherent series of theoretical and empirical studies based on some fundamental principle or approach. There are more than a few of these programs and what follows is no more than a brief capsule description of leading exemplars of this idea in which there is an emphasis on the originating leadership in each program and its further development over decades.

(1) Rational Choice Theory and James S. Coleman: After his 1964 pioneering Introduction to Mathematical Sociology, Coleman continued to make contributions to social theory and mathematical model building and his 1990 volume, Foundations of Social Theory was the major theoretical work of a career that spanned the period from 1950s to 1990s and included many other research-based contributions.[30] The Foundation book combined accessible examples of how rational choice theory could function in the analysis of such sociological topics as authority, trust, social capital and the norms (in particular, their emergence). In this way, the book showed how rational choice theory could provide an effective basis for making the transition from micro to macro levels of sociological explanation. An important feature of the book is its use of mathematical ideas in generalizing the rational choice model to include interpersonal sentiment relations as modifiers of outcomes and doing so such that the generalized theory captures the original more self-oriented theory as a special case, as point emphasized in a later analysis of the theory.[31] The rationality presupposition of the theory led to debates among sociological theorists.[32] Nevertheless, many sociologists drew upon Coleman's formulation of a general template for micro-macro transition to gain leverage on the continuation of topics central to his and the discipline's explanatory focus on a variety of macrosocial phenomena in which rational choice simplified the micro level in the interest of combining individual actions to account for macro outcomes of social processes.[33]

(2) Structuralism (Formal) and Harrison C. White: In the decades since his earliest contributions, Harrison White has led the field in putting social structural analysis on a mathematical and empirical basis, including the 1970 publication of Chains of Opportunity: System Models of Mobility in Organizations which set out and applied to data a vacancy chain model for mobility in and across organizations. His very influential other work includes the operational concepts of blockmodel and structural equivalence which start from a body of social relational data to produce analytical results using these procedures and concepts. These ideas and methods were developed in collaboration with his former students François Lorraine, Ronald Breiger, and Scott Boorman. These three are among the more than 30 students who earned their doctorates under White in the period 1963-1986.[34] The theory and application of blockmodels has been set out in detail in a recent monograph.[35] White's later contributions include a structuralist approach to markets[36] and, in 1992, a general theoretical framework,[37] later appearing in a revised edition.[38]

(3) Expectation states theory and Joseph Berger: Under Berger's intellectual and organizational leadership, Expectation States Theory branched out into a large number of specific programs of research on specific problems, each treated in terms of the master concept of expectation states. He and his colleague and frequent collaborator Morris Zelditch Jr not only produced work of their own but created a doctoral program at Stanford University that led to an enormous outpouring of research by notable former students, including Murray Webster, David Wagner, and Hamit Fisek. Collaboration with mathematician Robert Z. Norman led to the use of mathematical graph theory as a way of representing and analyzing social information processing in self-other interactions. Berger and Zelditch also advanced work in formal theorizing and mathematical model building as early as 1962 with a collaborative expository analysis of types of models.[39] Berger and Zelditch stimulated advances in other theoretical research programs by providing outlets for the publication of new work, culminating in a 2002 edited volume[40] that includes a chapter that presents an authoritative overview of Expectation states theory as a program of cumulative research dealing with group processes.

(4) Formalization in Theoretical Sociology and Thomas J. Fararo: Many of this sociologist's contributions have been devoted to bringing mathematical thinking into greater contact with sociological theory.[41] He organized a symposium attended by sociological theorists in which formal theorists delivered papers that were subsequently published in 2000.[42] Through collaborations with students and colleagues his own theoretical research program dealt with such topics as macrostructural theory and E-state structuralism (both with former student John Skvoretz), subjective images of stratification[43] (with former student Kenji Kosaka), tripartite structural analysis (with colleague Patrick Doreian)[44] and computational sociology (with colleague Norman P. Hummon).[45][46] Two of his books are extended treatments of his approach to theoretical sociology.[47][48]

(5) Social Network Analysis and Linton C. Freeman: In the early 1960s Freeman directed a sophisticated empirical study of community power structure. In 1978 he established the journal Social Networks. It rapidly became a major outlet for original research papers that used mathematical techniques to analyze network data. The journal also publishes conceptual and theoretical contributions, including his paper “Centrality in Social Networks: Conceptual Clarification.” The paper has been cited more than 13,000 times.[49] In turn, the mathematical concept defined in that paper led to further elaborations of the ideas, to experimental tests, and to numerous applications in empirical studies.[50] He is the author of a study of the history and sociology of the field of social network analysis.[51]

(6) Quantitative Methodology and Kenneth C. Land: Kenneth Land has been on the frontier of quantitative methodology in sociology as well as formal theoretical model building. The influential yearly volume Sociological Methodology has been one of Land's favorite outlets for the publication of papers that often lie in the intersection of quantitative methodology and mathematical sociology. Two of his theoretical papers appeared early in this journal: “Mathematical Formalization of Durkheim's Theory of Division of Labor” (1970) and “Formal Theory” (1971). His decades-long research program includes contributions relating to numerous special topics and methods, including social statistics, social indicators, stochastic processes, mathematical criminology, demography and social forecasting. Thus Land brings to these fields the skills of a statistician, a mathematician and a sociologist, combined.

(7) Affect Control Theory and David R. Heise: In 1979, Heise published a groundbreaking formal and empirical study in the tradition of interpretive sociology, especially symbolic interactionism, Understanding Events: Affect and the Construction of Social Action. It was the origination of a research program that has included his further theoretical and empirical studies and those of other sociologists, such as Lynn Smith-Lovin, Dawn Robinson and Neil MacKinnon. Definition of the situation and self-other definitions are two of the leading concepts in affect control theory. The formalism used by Heise and other contributors uses a validated form of measurement and a cybernetic control mechanism in which immediate feelings and compared with fundamental sentiments in such a way as to generate an effort to bring immediate feelings in a situation into correspondence with sentiments. In the simplest models, each person in an interactive pair, is represented in terms of one side of a role relationship in which fundamental sentiments associated with each role guide the process of immediate interaction. A higher level of the control process can be activated in which the definition of the situation is transformed. This research program comprises several of the key chapters in a 2006 volume[52] of contributions to control systems theory (in the sense of Powers 1975 [53]) in sociology.

(8) "Distributive Justice Theory" and Guillermina Jasso: Since 1980, Jasso has treated problems of distributive justice with an original theory that uses mathematical methods.[54] She has elaborated upon and applied this theory to a wide range of social phenomena.[55] Her most general mathematical apparatus – with the theory of distributive justice as a special case—deals with any subjective comparison between some actual state and some reference level for it, e.g., a comparison of an actual reward with an expected reward. In her justice theory, she starts with a very simple premise, the justice evaluation function (the natural logarithm of the ratio of actual to just reward) and then derives numerous empirically testable implications.[56]

(9) Collaborative research and John Skvoretz. A major feature of modern science is collaborative research in which the distinctive skills of the participants combine to produce original research. Skvoretz, in addition to this other contributions, has been a frequent collaborator in a variety of theoretical research programs, often using mathematical expertise as well as skills in experimental design, statistical data analysis and simulation methods. Some examples are: (1) Collaborative work on theoretical, statistical and mathematical problems in biased net theory.[57] (2) Collaborative contributions to Expectation States Theory.[58] (3) Collaborative contributions to Elementary Theory.[59] (4) Collaboration with Bruce Mayhew in a structuralist research program.[60] From the early 1970s, Skvoretz has been one of the most prolific of contributors to the advance of mathematical sociology.[61]

The above discussion could be expanded to include many other programs and individuals including European sociologists such as Peter Abell and the late Raymond Boudon.

Awards in mathematical sociology edit

The Mathematical Sociology section of The American Sociological Association in 2002 initiated awards for contributions to the field, including The James S. Coleman Distinguished Career Achievement Award. (Coleman had died in 1995 before the section had been established.) Given every other year, the awardees include some of those just listed in terms of their career-long research programs:

The section's other categories of awards and their recipients are listed at ASA Section on Mathematical Sociology

Texts and journals edit

Mathematical sociology textbooks cover a variety of models, usually explaining the required mathematical background before discussing important work in the literature (Fararo 1973, Leik and Meeker 1975, Bonacich and Lu 2012). An earlier text by Otomar Bartos (1967) is still of relevance. Of wider scope and mathematical sophistication is the text by Rapoport (1983). A very reader-friendly and imaginative introduction to explanatory thinking leading to models is Lave and March (1975, reprinted 1993). The Journal of Mathematical Sociology (started in 1971) has been open to papers covering a broad spectrum of topics employing a variety of types of mathematics, especially through frequent special issues. Other journals in sociology who publish papers with substantial use of mathematics are Computational and Mathematical Organization Theory, Journal of social structure, Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation

Articles in Social Networks, a journal devoted to social structural analysis, very often employ mathematical models and related structural data analyses. In addition – importantly indicating the penetration of mathematical model building into sociological research – the major comprehensive journals in sociology, especially The American Journal of Sociology and The American Sociological Review, regularly publish articles featuring mathematical formulations.

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ Struik, D. J. (1942). "On the Sociology of Mathematics". Science & Society. 6 (1): 58–70. ISSN 0036-8237. JSTOR 40399680.
  2. ^ Edling, Christofer R. (2002). "Mathematics in Sociology". Annual Review of Sociology. 28 (1): 197–220. doi:10.1146/annurev.soc.28.110601.140942. ISSN 0360-0572.
  3. ^ Restivo, Sal (1985), "The Sociology of Mathematics", The Social Relations of Physics, Mysticism, and Mathematics, Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands, pp. 161–175, doi:10.1007/978-94-009-7058-8_8, ISBN 978-90-277-2084-9, retrieved 2021-11-15
  4. ^ Skvoretz, John; Fararo, Thomas J. (2011). "Mathematical sociology". Sociopedia.isa. 1. doi:10.1177/205684601110 (inactive 31 January 2024).{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of January 2024 (link)
  5. ^ Skvoretz, John (2000). "Looking Backwards into the Future: Mathematical Sociology Then and Now". Sociological Theory. 18 (3): 510–517. doi:10.1111/0735-2751.00117. ISSN 0735-2751. S2CID 144850864.
  6. ^ Fararo, Thomas J. (1997). "Reflections on Mathematical Sociology". Sociological Forum. 12 (1): 73–101. doi:10.1023/A:1024656623205. ISSN 0884-8971. JSTOR 684856. S2CID 141186170.
  7. ^ * Nicolas Rashevsky.: 1947/1949 (2nd ed.). Mathematical Theory of Human Relations: An Approach to Mathematical Biology of Social Phenomena. Bloomington, ID: Principia Press.
  8. ^ Nicolas Rashevsky. 1938/1948 (2nd ed.). Mathematical Biophysics:Physico-Mathematical Foundations of Biology., University of Chicago Press : Chicago Press.
  9. ^ Rapoport, Anatol. (1957). "Contributions to the Theory of Random and Biased Nets." Bulletin of Mathematical Biophysics 19: 257-277.
  10. ^ Cartwright, Dorwin & Harary, Frank. (1956). "Structural Balance: A Generalization of Heider's Theory." Psychological Review 63:277-293.
  11. ^ Homans, George C (1950). The Human Group. New York: Harcourt, Brace and World.
  12. ^ Lazarsfeld, Paul F; Henry, Neil W (1966). Editors. Readings in Mathematical Social Science. MIT Press.
  13. ^ . Archived from the original on 2015-09-24.
  14. ^ Restivo, Sal (1982). "Mathematics and the Sociology of Knowledge". Knowledge. 4 (1): 127–144. doi:10.1177/0164025982004001008. ISSN 0164-0259. S2CID 145189340.
  15. ^ van Kerkhove, Bart; van Bendegem, Jean Paul (2007). Perspectives on mathematical practices : bringing together philosophy of mathematics, sociology of mathematics, and mathematics education. Bart van Kerkhove, Jean Paul van Bendegem. Dordrecht: Springer. ISBN 978-1-4020-5033-6. OCLC 187310586.
  16. ^ Bentley, Arthur F. (1931). "Sociology and Mathematics". The Sociological Review. a23 (3): 149–172. doi:10.1111/j.1467-954X.1931.tb02499.x. ISSN 0038-0261. S2CID 144558897.
  17. ^ Landri, Paolo (2007). "The Pragmatics of Passion: A Sociology of Attachment to Mathematics". Organization. 14 (3): 413–435. doi:10.1177/1350508407076152. ISSN 1350-5084. S2CID 144071342.
  18. ^ Coleman, James S (1954). "An expository analysis of some of Rashevsky's social behavior models". Mathematical Thinking in the Social Sciences Edited by Paul F. Lazarsfeld (New York: The Free Press).
  19. ^ Kossinets, Gueorgi; Watts, Duncan J (2006). "An empirical analysis of an evolving social network". Science. 311 (5757): 88–90. doi:10.1126/science.1116869. PMID 16400149. S2CID 8624120.
  20. ^ Coleman, James S; Fararo, Thomas J (1992). Rational Choice Theory: Advocacy and Critique. Editors. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
  21. ^ White, Harrison C. 1963. An Anatomy of Kinship. Prentice-Hall
  22. ^ Wasserman, S., & Faust, K.. Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications. New York and Cambridge, ENG: Cambridge University Press.
  23. ^ Rapoport, Anatol; Horvath, N J (1961). "A study of a large sociogram". Behavioral Science. 6 (4): 279–291. doi:10.1002/bs.3830060402. PMID 14490358.
  24. ^ Fararo, Thomas J; Sunshine, Morris (1964). A Study of Biased Friendship Net. Syracuse, NY: Youth Development Center and Syracuse University Press.
  25. ^ Milgram, Stanley (May 1967). "The small world problem". Psychology Today.
  26. ^ Travers, Jeffrey; Milgram, Stanley (1969). "An experimental study of the small world problem". Sociometry. 32 (4): 425–443. doi:10.2307/2786545. JSTOR 2786545.
  27. ^ Granovetter, Mark (1973). "The Strength of Weak Ties". American Journal of Sociology. 78 (6): 1360–1380. doi:10.1086/225469. S2CID 59578641.
  28. ^ Berger, Joseph; Cohen, Bernard P; Snell, J Laurie; Zelditch Jr, Morris (1962). Types of Formalization. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.
  29. ^ Scott, John (2017). Social Network Analysis. 4th Edition. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
  30. ^ Clark, Jon Editor (1996). James S Coleman. London, UK: Routledge. Taylor and Francis Group. {{cite book}}: |first1= has generic name (help)
  31. ^ Fararo, Thomas J (2001). Social Action Systems. Westport, CT: Praeger. pp. 255–278 (Ch. 11). ISBN 9780275973629.
  32. ^ Coleman, James S.; Fararo, Thomas J. (1992). Editors. Rational Choice Theory: Advocacy and Critique. Sage.
  33. ^ Raub, Werner; Buskens, Vincent; Van Assen, Marcel (2011). "Micro-macro links and microfoundations in sociology". Journal of Mathematical Sociology. 35 (1–3): 1–25. doi:10.1080/0022250X.2010.532263. S2CID 1027308.
  34. ^ Azarian, Reza (2003). The General Sociology of Harrison White. Stockholm, Sweden: Department of Sociology, Stockholm University. pp. 213–216. ISBN 978-91-7265-603-1.
  35. ^ Doreian, Patrick; Batagelj, Vladimir; Ferligoj, Anuska (2004). Generalized Blockmodeling. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-84085-9.
  36. ^ White, Harrison C. (2002). Markets from Networks: Socioeconomic Models of Production. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
  37. ^ White, Harrison C. (1992). Identity and Control: A Structural Theory of Social Action. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. ISBN 9780691003986.
  38. ^ White, Harrison C. (2008). Identity and Control. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
  39. ^ Berger, Joseph; Cohen, Bernard P.; Snell, J. Laurie; Zelditch Jr, Morris (1962). Types of Formalization. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.
  40. ^ Berger, Joseph; Zelditch Jr, Morris (2002). New Directions in Contemporary Sociological Theory. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.
  41. ^ Fararo, Thomas J. (1984). Editor. Mathematical Ideas and Sociological Theory: Current State and Prospects. New York, NY: Gordon and Breach.
  42. ^ Fararo, Thomas J. (November 2000). "Symposium on Formal Theory". Sociological Theory. 18 (3): 475–523. doi:10.1111/0735-2751.00112. S2CID 145568310.
  43. ^ Fararo, Thomas J; Kosaka, Kenji (2003). Generating Images of Stratification: A Formal Theory. New York: Springer.
  44. ^ Fararo, Thomas J; Doreian, Patrick (1984). "Tripartite structural analysis". Social Networks. 6 (2): 141–175. doi:10.1016/0378-8733(84)90015-7.
  45. ^ Hummon, Norman P; Fararo, Thomas J (1995). "The emergence of computational sociology". Journal of Mathematical Sociology. 20 (2–3): 79–87. doi:10.1080/0022250X.1995.9990155.
  46. ^ Hummon, Norman P; Fararo, Thomas J (1995). "Actors and networks as objects". Social Networks. 17: 1–26. doi:10.1016/0378-8733(94)00245-6.
  47. ^ Fararo, Thomas (2001). Social Action Systems. Westport, CT: Praeger.
  48. ^ Fararo, Thomas J (1989). The Meaning of General Theoretical Sociology: Tradition and Formalization. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521372589.
  49. ^ "Linton C Freeman". Google Scholar. {{cite web}}: Missing or empty |url= (help)
  50. ^ Freeman, Linton C; Roeder, Douglas; Mulholland, Robert (1979–1980). "Centrality in social networks II. Experimental results". Social Networks. 2 (2): 119–141. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.484.9992. doi:10.1016/0378-8733(79)90002-9.
  51. ^ Freeman, Linton C (2004). The development of social network analysis: a study in the sociology of science. North Charleston, SC: BookSurge.
  52. ^ McClelland, Kent; Fararo, Thomas (2006). Purpose, Meaning and Action: Control Systems Theories in Sociology. New York, N.Y.: Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 9781403967985.
  53. ^ Powers, William (1975). Behavior: The Control of Perception. Chicago, IL.: Aldine.
  54. ^ Jasso, Guillermina (1980). "A new theory of distributive justice". American Sociological Review. 45 (1): 3–32. doi:10.2307/2095239. JSTOR 2095239.
  55. ^ Jasso, Guillermina. "Curriculum Vitae 2018" (PDF).
  56. ^ Jasso, Gullermina (2002). "Seven secrets of doing theory". New Directions in Contemporary Sociological Theory Edited by J Berger and M Zelditch Jr: 317–342.
  57. ^ Skvoretz, John; Fararo, Thomas J; Agneessens, F (2004). "Advances in biased net theory:Definitions, derivations, and estimations". Social Networks. 26 (2): 113–139. doi:10.1016/j.socnet.2004.01.005.
  58. ^ Skvoretz, John; Fararo, Thomas J (1996). "Status and participation in task groups: A dynamic network model". American Journal of Sociology. 101 (5): 1366–1414. doi:10.1086/230826. S2CID 144193428.
  59. ^ Skvoretz, John; Willer, Dave (1993). "Exclusion and power: a test of four theories of power in exchange networks". American Sociological Review. 58 (6): 801–818. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.295.2551. doi:10.2307/2095952. JSTOR 2095952.
  60. ^ Skvoretz, John; Mayhew, Bruce (1988). "The structure of stratified systems and the structure of mobility: a first approximation to a structural theory of vertical mobility". Journal of Mathematical Sociology. 13 (3): 193–242. doi:10.1080/0022250X.1988.9990033.
  61. ^ Skvoretz, John (2000). "Looking backwards into the future: Mathematical sociology then and now". Sociological Theory. 18 (3): 510–517. doi:10.1111/0735-2751.00117. S2CID 144850864.

Further reading edit

  • Bartos, Otomar. 1967. "Simple Models of Group Behavior." Columbia University Press.
  • Berger, Joseph. 2000. "Theory and Formalization: Some Reflections on Experience." Sociological Theory 18(3):482-489.
  • Berger, Joseph, Bernard P. Cohen, J. Laurie Snell, and Morris Zelditch, Jr. 1962. Types of Formalization in Small Group Research. Houghton-Mifflin.
  • Berger, Joseph and Morris Zelditch Jr. 2002. New Directions in Contemporary Sociological Theory Rowman and Littlefield.
  • Bonacich, Philip and Philip Lu. Introduction to Mathematical Sociology. Princeton University Press.
  • Coleman, James S. 1964. An Introduction to Mathematical Sociology. Free Press.
  • _____. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Harvard University Press.
  • Doreian, Patrick, Vladimir Batagelj, and Anuska Ferligoj. 2004. Generalized Blockmodeling. Cambridge University Press.
  • Edling, Christofer R. 2002. "Mathematics in Sociology," Annual Review of Sociology.
  • Fararo, Thomas J. 1973. Mathematical Sociology. Wiley. Reprinted by Krieger, 1978.
  • _____. 1984. Editor. Mathematical Ideas and Sociological Theory. Gordon and Breach.
  • _____. 1989. The Meaning of General Theoretical Sociology: Tradition and Formalization. Cambridge University Press.
  • Freeman, Linton C. 2004. The Development of Social Network Analysis. Empirical Press.
  • Heise, David R. 1979. Understanding Events: Affect and the Construction of Social Action. Cambridge University Press.
  • Helbing, Dirk. 1995. Quantitative Sociodynamics. Kluwer Academics.
  • Lave, Charles and James March. 1975. An Introduction to Models in the Social Sciences. Harper and Row.
  • Leik, Robert K. and Barbara F. Meeker. 1975. Mathematical Sociology. Prentice-Hall.
  • Rapoport, Anatol. 1983. Mathematical Models in the Social and Behavioral Sciences. Wiley.
  • Nicolas Rashevsky.: 1965, The Representation of Organisms in Terms of Predicates, Bulletin of Mathematical Biophysics 27: 477-491.
  • Nicolas Rashevsky.: 1969, Outline of a Unified Approach to Physics, Biology and Sociology., Bulletin of Mathematical Biophysics 31: 159-198.
  • Rosen, Robert. 1972. "Tribute to Nicolas Rashevsky 1899-1972." Progress in Theoretical Biology 2.
  • Leik, Robert K. and Barbara F. Meeker. 1975. Mathematical Sociology. Prentice-Hall.
  • Simon, Herbert A. 1952. "A Formal Theory of Interaction in Social Groups." American Sociological Review 17:202-212.
  • Wasserman, Stanley and Katherine Faust. 1994. Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications. Cambridge University Press.
  • White, Harrison C. 1963. An Anatomy of Kinship. Prentice-Hall.
  • _____. 1970. Chains of Opportunity. Harvard University Press.
  • _____. 1992. Identity and Control: A Structural Theory of Action. Princeton University Press.
  • _____. 2008. Identity and Control: How Social Formations Emerge. 2nd Ed. (Revised) Princeton University Press.

External links edit

  • John Skvoretz; Thomas J Fararo (1952). "Mathematical sociology" (PDF). Sociopedia.isa. 170 (4314): 3. Bibcode:1952Natur.170....3G. doi:10.1038/170003a0. S2CID 4181915.
  • Home Page of Mathematical Sociology Section of the American Sociological Association
  • The Society for Mathematical Biology
  • Bulletin of Mathematical Biophysics
  • Mathematical Sociology Section Home Page

mathematical, sociology, sociology, mathematics, interdisciplinary, field, research, concerned, both, with, mathematics, within, sociological, research, well, research, into, relationships, that, exist, between, maths, society, mathematical, bridge, officially. Mathematical sociology or the sociology of mathematics 1 is an interdisciplinary field of research concerned both with the use of mathematics within sociological research 2 as well as research into the relationships that exist between maths and society 3 Mathematical Bridge or officially Wooden Bridge is an arch bridge in Cambridge United Kingdom The arrangement of timbers is a series of tangents that describe the arc of the bridge with radial members to tie the tangents together and triangulate the structure making it rigid and self supporting Because of this mathematical sociology can have a diverse meaning depending on the authors in question and the kind of research being carried out This creates contestation over whether mathematical sociology is a derivative of sociology an intersection of the two disciplines or a discipline in its own right 4 This is a dynamic ongoing academic development that leaves mathematical sociology sometimes blurred and lacking in uniformity presenting grey areas and need for further research into developing its academic merit 5 6 Contents 1 History 2 Approaches 2 1 Mathematics in sociology 2 2 Society and mathematics 3 Further developments 4 Present research 5 Research programs 6 Awards in mathematical sociology 7 Texts and journals 8 See also 9 References 10 Further reading 11 External linksHistory editStarting in the early 1940s Nicolas Rashevsky 7 8 and subsequently in the late 1940s Anatol Rapoport and others developed a relational and probabilistic approach to the characterization of large social networks in which the nodes are persons and the links are acquaintanceship During the late 1940s formulas were derived that connected local parameters such as closure of contacts if A is linked to both B and C then there is a greater than chance probability that B and C are linked to each other to the global network property of connectivity 9 Moreover acquaintanceship is a positive tie but what about negative ties such as animosity among persons To tackle this problem graph theory which is the mathematical study of abstract representations of networks of points and lines can be extended to include these two types of links and thereby to create models that represent both positive and negative sentiment relations which are represented as signed graphs A signed graph is called balanced if the product of the signs of all relations in every cycle links in every graph cycle is positive Through formalization by mathematician Frank Harary this work produced the fundamental theorem of this theory It says that if a network of interrelated positive and negative ties is balanced e g as illustrated by the psychological principle that my friend s enemy is my enemy then it consists of two sub networks such that each has positive ties among its nodes and there are only negative ties between nodes in distinct sub networks 10 The imagery here is of a social system that splits into two cliques There is however a special case where one of the two sub networks is empty which might occur in very small networks In another model ties have relative strengths Acquaintanceship can be viewed as a weak tie and friendship is represented as a strong tie Like its uniform cousin discussed above there is a concept of closure called strong triadic closure A graph satisfies strong triadic closure If A is strongly connected to B and B is strongly connected to C then A and C must have a tie either weak or strong In these two developments we have mathematical models bearing upon the analysis of structure Other early influential developments in mathematical sociology pertained to process For instance in 1952 Herbert A Simon produced a mathematical formalization of a published theory 11 of social groups by constructing a model consisting of a deterministic system of differential equations A formal study of the system led to theorems about the dynamics and the implied equilibrium states of any group The emergence of mathematical models in the social sciences was part of the zeitgeist in the 1940s and 1950s in which a variety of new interdisciplinary scientific innovations occurred such as information theory game theory cybernetics and mathematical model building in the social and behavioral sciences 12 Approaches editMathematics in sociology edit Focusing on mathematics within sociological research mathematical sociology uses mathematics to construct social theories Mathematical sociology aims to take sociological theory and to express it in mathematical terms The benefits of this approach include increased clarity and the ability to use mathematics to derive implications of a theory that cannot be arrived at intuitively In mathematical sociology the preferred style is encapsulated in the phrase constructing a mathematical model This means making specified assumptions about some social phenomenon expressing them in formal mathematics and providing an empirical interpretation for the ideas It also means deducing properties of the model and comparing these with relevant empirical data Social network analysis is the best known contribution of this subfield to sociology as a whole and to the scientific community at large The models typically used in mathematical sociology allow sociologists to understand how predictable local interactions are and they are often able to elicit global patterns of social structure 13 Society and mathematics edit Interested in the relationship between society and mathematical knowledge mathematical sociology or the sociology of mathematics forms a complementary sphere from disciplines like the sociology of knowledge and sociology of science that tries to understand the social roots of mathematics as well as the impact maths has had on society 14 15 This reflexivity on the development and use of maths within sociology attempts to understand how the facts of mathematics related to social constructions and the implications of bias that maths may bring when applied to efforts in understanding social phenomanon 16 17 Further developments editIn 1954 a critical expository analysis of Rashevsky s social behavior models was written by sociologist James S Coleman 18 Rashevsky s models and as well as the model constructed by Simon raise a question how can one connect such theoretical models to the data of sociology which often take the form of surveys in which the results are expressed in the form of proportions of people believing or doing something This suggests deriving the equations from assumptions about the chances of an individual changing state in a small interval of time a procedure well known in the mathematics of stochastic processes Coleman embodied this idea in his 1964 book Introduction to Mathematical Sociology which showed how stochastic processes in social networks could be analyzed in such a way as to enable testing of the constructed model by comparison with the relevant data The same idea can and has been applied to processes of change in social relations an active research theme in the study of social networks illustrated by an empirical study appearing in the journal Science 19 In other work Coleman employed mathematical ideas drawn from economics such as general equilibrium theory to argue that general social theory should begin with a concept of purposive action and for analytical reasons approximate such action by the use of rational choice models Coleman 1990 This argument is similar to viewpoints expressed by other sociologists in their efforts to use rational choice theory in sociological analysis although such efforts have met with substantive and philosophical criticisms 20 Meanwhile structural analysis of the type indicated earlier received a further extension to social networks based on institutionalized social relations notably those of kinship The linkage of mathematics and sociology here involved abstract algebra in particular group theory 21 This in turn led to a focus on a data analytical version of homomorphic reduction of a complex social network which along with many other techniques is presented in Wasserman and Faust 1994 22 In regard to Rapoport s random and biased net theory his 1961 study of a large sociogram co authored with Horvath turned out to become a very influential paper 23 There was early evidence of this influence In 1964 Thomas Fararo and a co author analyzed another large friendship sociogram using a biased net model 24 Later in the 1960s Stanley Milgram described the small world problem and undertook a field experiment dealing with it 25 26 A highly fertile idea was suggested and applied by Mark Granovetter in which he drew upon Rapoport s 1961 paper to suggest and apply a distinction between weak and strong ties The key idea was that there was strength in weak ties 27 Some programs of research in sociology employ experimental methods to study social interaction processes Joseph Berger and his colleagues initiated such a program in which the central idea is the use of the theoretical concept expectation state to construct theoretical models to explain interpersonal processes e g those linking external status in society to differential influence in local group decision making Much of this theoretical work is linked to mathematical model building especially after the late 1970s adoption of a graph theoretic representation of social information processing as Berger 2000 describes in looking back upon the development of his program of research In 1962 he and his collaborators explained model building by reference to the goal of the model builder which could be explication of a concept in a theory representation of a single recurrent social process or a broad theory based on a theoretical construct such as respectively the concept of balance in psychological and social structures the process of conformity in an experimental situation and stimulus sampling theory 28 The generations of mathematical sociologists that followed Rapoport Simon Harary Coleman White and Berger including those entering the field in the 1960s such as Thomas Fararo Philip Bonacich and Tom Mayer among others drew upon their work in a variety of ways Present research editThis section needs expansion You can help by adding to it April 2010 Mathematical sociology remains a small subfield within the discipline but it has succeeded in spawning a number of other subfields which share its goals of formally modeling social life The foremost of these fields is social network analysis which has become among the fastest growing areas of sociology in the 21st century 29 The other major development in the field is the rise of computational sociology which expands the mathematical toolkit with the use of computer simulations artificial intelligence and advanced statistical methods The latter subfield also makes use of the vast new data sets on social activity generated by social interaction on the internet One important indicator of the significance of mathematical sociology is that the general interest journals in the field including such central journals as The American Journal of Sociology and The American Sociological Review have published mathematical models that became influential in the field at large More recent trends in mathematical sociology are evident in contributions to The Journal of Mathematical Sociology JMS Several trends stand out the further development of formal theories that explain experimental data dealing with small group processes the continuing interest in structural balance as a major mathematical and theoretical idea the interpenetration of mathematical models oriented to theory and innovative quantitative techniques relating to methodology the use of computer simulations to study problems in social complexity interest in micro macro linkage and the problem of emergence and ever increasing research on networks of social relations Thus topics from the earliest days like balance and network models continue to be of contemporary interest The formal techniques employed remain many of the standard and well known methods of mathematics differential equations stochastic processes and game theory Newer tools like agent based models used in computer simulation studies are prominently represented Perennial substantive problems still drive research social diffusion social influence social status origins and consequences segregation cooperation collective action power and much more Research programs editMany of the developments in mathematical sociology including formal theory have exhibited notable decades long advances that began with path setting contributions by leading mathematical sociologists and formal theorists This provides another way of taking note of recent contributions but with an emphasis on continuity with early work through the use of the idea of research program which is a coherent series of theoretical and empirical studies based on some fundamental principle or approach There are more than a few of these programs and what follows is no more than a brief capsule description of leading exemplars of this idea in which there is an emphasis on the originating leadership in each program and its further development over decades 1 Rational Choice Theory and James S Coleman After his 1964 pioneering Introduction to Mathematical Sociology Coleman continued to make contributions to social theory and mathematical model building and his 1990 volume Foundations of Social Theory was the major theoretical work of a career that spanned the period from 1950s to 1990s and included many other research based contributions 30 The Foundation book combined accessible examples of how rational choice theory could function in the analysis of such sociological topics as authority trust social capital and the norms in particular their emergence In this way the book showed how rational choice theory could provide an effective basis for making the transition from micro to macro levels of sociological explanation An important feature of the book is its use of mathematical ideas in generalizing the rational choice model to include interpersonal sentiment relations as modifiers of outcomes and doing so such that the generalized theory captures the original more self oriented theory as a special case as point emphasized in a later analysis of the theory 31 The rationality presupposition of the theory led to debates among sociological theorists 32 Nevertheless many sociologists drew upon Coleman s formulation of a general template for micro macro transition to gain leverage on the continuation of topics central to his and the discipline s explanatory focus on a variety of macrosocial phenomena in which rational choice simplified the micro level in the interest of combining individual actions to account for macro outcomes of social processes 33 2 Structuralism Formal and Harrison C White In the decades since his earliest contributions Harrison White has led the field in putting social structural analysis on a mathematical and empirical basis including the 1970 publication of Chains of Opportunity System Models of Mobility in Organizations which set out and applied to data a vacancy chain model for mobility in and across organizations His very influential other work includes the operational concepts of blockmodel and structural equivalence which start from a body of social relational data to produce analytical results using these procedures and concepts These ideas and methods were developed in collaboration with his former students Francois Lorraine Ronald Breiger and Scott Boorman These three are among the more than 30 students who earned their doctorates under White in the period 1963 1986 34 The theory and application of blockmodels has been set out in detail in a recent monograph 35 White s later contributions include a structuralist approach to markets 36 and in 1992 a general theoretical framework 37 later appearing in a revised edition 38 3 Expectation states theory and Joseph Berger Under Berger s intellectual and organizational leadership Expectation States Theory branched out into a large number of specific programs of research on specific problems each treated in terms of the master concept of expectation states He and his colleague and frequent collaborator Morris Zelditch Jr not only produced work of their own but created a doctoral program at Stanford University that led to an enormous outpouring of research by notable former students including Murray Webster David Wagner and Hamit Fisek Collaboration with mathematician Robert Z Norman led to the use of mathematical graph theory as a way of representing and analyzing social information processing in self other interactions Berger and Zelditch also advanced work in formal theorizing and mathematical model building as early as 1962 with a collaborative expository analysis of types of models 39 Berger and Zelditch stimulated advances in other theoretical research programs by providing outlets for the publication of new work culminating in a 2002 edited volume 40 that includes a chapter that presents an authoritative overview of Expectation states theory as a program of cumulative research dealing with group processes 4 Formalization in Theoretical Sociology and Thomas J Fararo Many of this sociologist s contributions have been devoted to bringing mathematical thinking into greater contact with sociological theory 41 He organized a symposium attended by sociological theorists in which formal theorists delivered papers that were subsequently published in 2000 42 Through collaborations with students and colleagues his own theoretical research program dealt with such topics as macrostructural theory and E state structuralism both with former student John Skvoretz subjective images of stratification 43 with former student Kenji Kosaka tripartite structural analysis with colleague Patrick Doreian 44 and computational sociology with colleague Norman P Hummon 45 46 Two of his books are extended treatments of his approach to theoretical sociology 47 48 5 Social Network Analysis and Linton C Freeman In the early 1960s Freeman directed a sophisticated empirical study of community power structure In 1978 he established the journal Social Networks It rapidly became a major outlet for original research papers that used mathematical techniques to analyze network data The journal also publishes conceptual and theoretical contributions including his paper Centrality in Social Networks Conceptual Clarification The paper has been cited more than 13 000 times 49 In turn the mathematical concept defined in that paper led to further elaborations of the ideas to experimental tests and to numerous applications in empirical studies 50 He is the author of a study of the history and sociology of the field of social network analysis 51 6 Quantitative Methodology and Kenneth C Land Kenneth Land has been on the frontier of quantitative methodology in sociology as well as formal theoretical model building The influential yearly volume Sociological Methodology has been one of Land s favorite outlets for the publication of papers that often lie in the intersection of quantitative methodology and mathematical sociology Two of his theoretical papers appeared early in this journal Mathematical Formalization of Durkheim s Theory of Division of Labor 1970 and Formal Theory 1971 His decades long research program includes contributions relating to numerous special topics and methods including social statistics social indicators stochastic processes mathematical criminology demography and social forecasting Thus Land brings to these fields the skills of a statistician a mathematician and a sociologist combined 7 Affect Control Theory and David R Heise In 1979 Heise published a groundbreaking formal and empirical study in the tradition of interpretive sociology especially symbolic interactionism Understanding Events Affect and the Construction of Social Action It was the origination of a research program that has included his further theoretical and empirical studies and those of other sociologists such as Lynn Smith Lovin Dawn Robinson and Neil MacKinnon Definition of the situation and self other definitions are two of the leading concepts in affect control theory The formalism used by Heise and other contributors uses a validated form of measurement and a cybernetic control mechanism in which immediate feelings and compared with fundamental sentiments in such a way as to generate an effort to bring immediate feelings in a situation into correspondence with sentiments In the simplest models each person in an interactive pair is represented in terms of one side of a role relationship in which fundamental sentiments associated with each role guide the process of immediate interaction A higher level of the control process can be activated in which the definition of the situation is transformed This research program comprises several of the key chapters in a 2006 volume 52 of contributions to control systems theory in the sense of Powers 1975 53 in sociology 8 Distributive Justice Theory and Guillermina Jasso Since 1980 Jasso has treated problems of distributive justice with an original theory that uses mathematical methods 54 She has elaborated upon and applied this theory to a wide range of social phenomena 55 Her most general mathematical apparatus with the theory of distributive justice as a special case deals with any subjective comparison between some actual state and some reference level for it e g a comparison of an actual reward with an expected reward In her justice theory she starts with a very simple premise the justice evaluation function the natural logarithm of the ratio of actual to just reward and then derives numerous empirically testable implications 56 9 Collaborative research and John Skvoretz A major feature of modern science is collaborative research in which the distinctive skills of the participants combine to produce original research Skvoretz in addition to this other contributions has been a frequent collaborator in a variety of theoretical research programs often using mathematical expertise as well as skills in experimental design statistical data analysis and simulation methods Some examples are 1 Collaborative work on theoretical statistical and mathematical problems in biased net theory 57 2 Collaborative contributions to Expectation States Theory 58 3 Collaborative contributions to Elementary Theory 59 4 Collaboration with Bruce Mayhew in a structuralist research program 60 From the early 1970s Skvoretz has been one of the most prolific of contributors to the advance of mathematical sociology 61 The above discussion could be expanded to include many other programs and individuals including European sociologists such as Peter Abell and the late Raymond Boudon Awards in mathematical sociology editThe Mathematical Sociology section of The American Sociological Association in 2002 initiated awards for contributions to the field including The James S Coleman Distinguished Career Achievement Award Coleman had died in 1995 before the section had been established Given every other year the awardees include some of those just listed in terms of their career long research programs 2022 Guillermina Jasso New York University 2020 Noah Friedkin University of California Santa Barbara 2018 Ronald Breiger University of Arizona 2017 Lynn Smith Lovin Duke University 2014 Philip Bonacich University of California Los Angeles 2012 John Skvoretz University of South Florida 2010 David R Heise Indiana University 2008 Scott Boorman Yale University 2006 Linton Freeman University of California Irvine 2004 Thomas Fararo University of Pittsburgh 2002 Harrison White Columbia University The section s other categories of awards and their recipients are listed at ASA Section on Mathematical SociologyTexts and journals editMathematical sociology textbooks cover a variety of models usually explaining the required mathematical background before discussing important work in the literature Fararo 1973 Leik and Meeker 1975 Bonacich and Lu 2012 An earlier text by Otomar Bartos 1967 is still of relevance Of wider scope and mathematical sophistication is the text by Rapoport 1983 A very reader friendly and imaginative introduction to explanatory thinking leading to models is Lave and March 1975 reprinted 1993 The Journal of Mathematical Sociology started in 1971 has been open to papers covering a broad spectrum of topics employing a variety of types of mathematics especially through frequent special issues Other journals in sociology who publish papers with substantial use of mathematics are Computational and Mathematical Organization Theory Journal of social structure Journal of Artificial Societies and Social SimulationArticles in Social Networks a journal devoted to social structural analysis very often employ mathematical models and related structural data analyses In addition importantly indicating the penetration of mathematical model building into sociological research the major comprehensive journals in sociology especially The American Journal of Sociology and The American Sociological Review regularly publish articles featuring mathematical formulations See also editIsaac Asimov s Foundation series based on a massive expansion of the premise Positivism Statistics Computational sociology Game Theory Thomas Schelling Peter Blau Harrison White Nicolas Rashevsky Society for Mathematical Biology Interpersonal ties James Samuel Coleman James D Montgomery Thomas Fararo Social networkReferences edit Struik D J 1942 On the Sociology of Mathematics Science amp Society 6 1 58 70 ISSN 0036 8237 JSTOR 40399680 Edling Christofer R 2002 Mathematics in Sociology Annual Review of Sociology 28 1 197 220 doi 10 1146 annurev soc 28 110601 140942 ISSN 0360 0572 Restivo Sal 1985 The Sociology of Mathematics The Social Relations of Physics Mysticism and Mathematics Dordrecht Springer Netherlands pp 161 175 doi 10 1007 978 94 009 7058 8 8 ISBN 978 90 277 2084 9 retrieved 2021 11 15 Skvoretz John Fararo Thomas J 2011 Mathematical sociology Sociopedia isa 1 doi 10 1177 205684601110 inactive 31 January 2024 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a CS1 maint DOI inactive as of January 2024 link Skvoretz John 2000 Looking Backwards into the Future Mathematical Sociology Then and Now Sociological Theory 18 3 510 517 doi 10 1111 0735 2751 00117 ISSN 0735 2751 S2CID 144850864 Fararo Thomas J 1997 Reflections on Mathematical Sociology Sociological Forum 12 1 73 101 doi 10 1023 A 1024656623205 ISSN 0884 8971 JSTOR 684856 S2CID 141186170 Nicolas Rashevsky 1947 1949 2nd ed Mathematical Theory of Human Relations An Approach to Mathematical Biology of Social Phenomena Bloomington ID Principia Press Nicolas Rashevsky 1938 1948 2nd ed Mathematical Biophysics Physico Mathematical Foundations of Biology University of Chicago Press Chicago Press Rapoport Anatol 1957 Contributions to the Theory of Random and Biased Nets Bulletin of Mathematical Biophysics 19 257 277 Cartwright Dorwin amp Harary Frank 1956 Structural Balance A Generalization of Heider s Theory Psychological Review 63 277 293 Homans George C 1950 The Human Group New York Harcourt Brace and World Lazarsfeld Paul F Henry Neil W 1966 Editors Readings in Mathematical Social Science MIT Press Department of Sociology Department of Sociology Cornell Arts amp Sciences Archived from the original on 2015 09 24 Restivo Sal 1982 Mathematics and the Sociology of Knowledge Knowledge 4 1 127 144 doi 10 1177 0164025982004001008 ISSN 0164 0259 S2CID 145189340 van Kerkhove Bart van Bendegem Jean Paul 2007 Perspectives on mathematical practices bringing together philosophy of mathematics sociology of mathematics and mathematics education Bart van Kerkhove Jean Paul van Bendegem Dordrecht Springer ISBN 978 1 4020 5033 6 OCLC 187310586 Bentley Arthur F 1931 Sociology and Mathematics The Sociological Review a23 3 149 172 doi 10 1111 j 1467 954X 1931 tb02499 x ISSN 0038 0261 S2CID 144558897 Landri Paolo 2007 The Pragmatics of Passion A Sociology of Attachment to Mathematics Organization 14 3 413 435 doi 10 1177 1350508407076152 ISSN 1350 5084 S2CID 144071342 Coleman James S 1954 An expository analysis of some of Rashevsky s social behavior models Mathematical Thinking in the Social Sciences Edited by Paul F Lazarsfeld New York The Free Press Kossinets Gueorgi Watts Duncan J 2006 An empirical analysis of an evolving social network Science 311 5757 88 90 doi 10 1126 science 1116869 PMID 16400149 S2CID 8624120 Coleman James S Fararo Thomas J 1992 Rational Choice Theory Advocacy and Critique Editors Newbury Park CA Sage White Harrison C 1963 An Anatomy of Kinship Prentice Hall Wasserman S amp Faust K Social Network Analysis Methods and Applications New York and Cambridge ENG Cambridge University Press Rapoport Anatol Horvath N J 1961 A study of a large sociogram Behavioral Science 6 4 279 291 doi 10 1002 bs 3830060402 PMID 14490358 Fararo Thomas J Sunshine Morris 1964 A Study of Biased Friendship Net Syracuse NY Youth Development Center and Syracuse University Press Milgram Stanley May 1967 The small world problem Psychology Today Travers Jeffrey Milgram Stanley 1969 An experimental study of the small world problem Sociometry 32 4 425 443 doi 10 2307 2786545 JSTOR 2786545 Granovetter Mark 1973 The Strength of Weak Ties American Journal of Sociology 78 6 1360 1380 doi 10 1086 225469 S2CID 59578641 Berger Joseph Cohen Bernard P Snell J Laurie Zelditch Jr Morris 1962 Types of Formalization Boston MA Houghton Mifflin Scott John 2017 Social Network Analysis 4th Edition Thousand Oaks CA Sage Clark Jon Editor 1996 James S Coleman London UK Routledge Taylor and Francis Group a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a first1 has generic name help Fararo Thomas J 2001 Social Action Systems Westport CT Praeger pp 255 278 Ch 11 ISBN 9780275973629 Coleman James S Fararo Thomas J 1992 Editors Rational Choice Theory Advocacy and Critique Sage Raub Werner Buskens Vincent Van Assen Marcel 2011 Micro macro links and microfoundations in sociology Journal of Mathematical Sociology 35 1 3 1 25 doi 10 1080 0022250X 2010 532263 S2CID 1027308 Azarian Reza 2003 The General Sociology of Harrison White Stockholm Sweden Department of Sociology Stockholm University pp 213 216 ISBN 978 91 7265 603 1 Doreian Patrick Batagelj Vladimir Ferligoj Anuska 2004 Generalized Blockmodeling Cambridge U K Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 84085 9 White Harrison C 2002 Markets from Networks Socioeconomic Models of Production Princeton N J Princeton University Press White Harrison C 1992 Identity and Control A Structural Theory of Social Action Princeton N J Princeton University Press ISBN 9780691003986 White Harrison C 2008 Identity and Control Princeton N J Princeton University Press Berger Joseph Cohen Bernard P Snell J Laurie Zelditch Jr Morris 1962 Types of Formalization Boston MA Houghton Mifflin Berger Joseph Zelditch Jr Morris 2002 New Directions in Contemporary Sociological Theory Lanham MD Rowman amp Littlefield Fararo Thomas J 1984 Editor Mathematical Ideas and Sociological Theory Current State and Prospects New York NY Gordon and Breach Fararo Thomas J November 2000 Symposium on Formal Theory Sociological Theory 18 3 475 523 doi 10 1111 0735 2751 00112 S2CID 145568310 Fararo Thomas J Kosaka Kenji 2003 Generating Images of Stratification A Formal Theory New York Springer Fararo Thomas J Doreian Patrick 1984 Tripartite structural analysis Social Networks 6 2 141 175 doi 10 1016 0378 8733 84 90015 7 Hummon Norman P Fararo Thomas J 1995 The emergence of computational sociology Journal of Mathematical Sociology 20 2 3 79 87 doi 10 1080 0022250X 1995 9990155 Hummon Norman P Fararo Thomas J 1995 Actors and networks as objects Social Networks 17 1 26 doi 10 1016 0378 8733 94 00245 6 Fararo Thomas 2001 Social Action Systems Westport CT Praeger Fararo Thomas J 1989 The Meaning of General Theoretical Sociology Tradition and Formalization Cambridge UK Cambridge University Press ISBN 9780521372589 Linton C Freeman Google Scholar a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a Missing or empty url help Freeman Linton C Roeder Douglas Mulholland Robert 1979 1980 Centrality in social networks II Experimental results Social Networks 2 2 119 141 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 484 9992 doi 10 1016 0378 8733 79 90002 9 Freeman Linton C 2004 The development of social network analysis a study in the sociology of science North Charleston SC BookSurge McClelland Kent Fararo Thomas 2006 Purpose Meaning and Action Control Systems Theories in Sociology New York N Y Palgrave Macmillan ISBN 9781403967985 Powers William 1975 Behavior The Control of Perception Chicago IL Aldine Jasso Guillermina 1980 A new theory of distributive justice American Sociological Review 45 1 3 32 doi 10 2307 2095239 JSTOR 2095239 Jasso Guillermina Curriculum Vitae 2018 PDF Jasso Gullermina 2002 Seven secrets of doing theory New Directions in Contemporary Sociological Theory Edited by J Berger and M Zelditch Jr 317 342 Skvoretz John Fararo Thomas J Agneessens F 2004 Advances in biased net theory Definitions derivations and estimations Social Networks 26 2 113 139 doi 10 1016 j socnet 2004 01 005 Skvoretz John Fararo Thomas J 1996 Status and participation in task groups A dynamic network model American Journal of Sociology 101 5 1366 1414 doi 10 1086 230826 S2CID 144193428 Skvoretz John Willer Dave 1993 Exclusion and power a test of four theories of power in exchange networks American Sociological Review 58 6 801 818 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 295 2551 doi 10 2307 2095952 JSTOR 2095952 Skvoretz John Mayhew Bruce 1988 The structure of stratified systems and the structure of mobility a first approximation to a structural theory of vertical mobility Journal of Mathematical Sociology 13 3 193 242 doi 10 1080 0022250X 1988 9990033 Skvoretz John 2000 Looking backwards into the future Mathematical sociology then and now Sociological Theory 18 3 510 517 doi 10 1111 0735 2751 00117 S2CID 144850864 Further reading editBartos Otomar 1967 Simple Models of Group Behavior Columbia University Press Berger Joseph 2000 Theory and Formalization Some Reflections on Experience Sociological Theory 18 3 482 489 Berger Joseph Bernard P Cohen J Laurie Snell and Morris Zelditch Jr 1962 Types of Formalization in Small Group Research Houghton Mifflin Berger Joseph and Morris Zelditch Jr 2002 New Directions in Contemporary Sociological Theory Rowman and Littlefield Bonacich Philip and Philip Lu Introduction to Mathematical Sociology Princeton University Press Coleman James S 1964 An Introduction to Mathematical Sociology Free Press 1990 Foundations of Social Theory Harvard University Press Doreian Patrick Vladimir Batagelj and Anuska Ferligoj 2004 Generalized Blockmodeling Cambridge University Press Edling Christofer R 2002 Mathematics in Sociology Annual Review of Sociology Fararo Thomas J 1973 Mathematical Sociology Wiley Reprinted by Krieger 1978 1984 Editor Mathematical Ideas and Sociological Theory Gordon and Breach 1989 The Meaning of General Theoretical Sociology Tradition and Formalization Cambridge University Press Freeman Linton C 2004 The Development of Social Network Analysis Empirical Press Heise David R 1979 Understanding Events Affect and the Construction of Social Action Cambridge University Press Helbing Dirk 1995 Quantitative Sociodynamics Kluwer Academics Lave Charles and James March 1975 An Introduction to Models in the Social Sciences Harper and Row Leik Robert K and Barbara F Meeker 1975 Mathematical Sociology Prentice Hall Rapoport Anatol 1983 Mathematical Models in the Social and Behavioral Sciences Wiley Nicolas Rashevsky 1965 The Representation of Organisms in Terms of Predicates Bulletin of Mathematical Biophysics 27 477 491 Nicolas Rashevsky 1969 Outline of a Unified Approach to Physics Biology and Sociology Bulletin of Mathematical Biophysics 31 159 198 Rosen Robert 1972 Tribute to Nicolas Rashevsky 1899 1972 Progress in Theoretical Biology 2 Leik Robert K and Barbara F Meeker 1975 Mathematical Sociology Prentice Hall Simon Herbert A 1952 A Formal Theory of Interaction in Social Groups American Sociological Review 17 202 212 Wasserman Stanley and Katherine Faust 1994 Social Network Analysis Methods and Applications Cambridge University Press White Harrison C 1963 An Anatomy of Kinship Prentice Hall 1970 Chains of Opportunity Harvard University Press 1992 Identity and Control A Structural Theory of Action Princeton University Press 2008 Identity and Control How Social Formations Emerge 2nd Ed Revised Princeton University Press External links editJohn Skvoretz Thomas J Fararo 1952 Mathematical sociology PDF Sociopedia isa 170 4314 3 Bibcode 1952Natur 170 3G doi 10 1038 170003a0 S2CID 4181915 Home Page of Mathematical Sociology Section of the American Sociological Association The Society for Mathematical Biology Bulletin of Mathematical Biophysics European Society for Mathematical and Theoretical Biology ESMTB Mathematical Sociology Section Home Page Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Mathematical sociology amp oldid 1201963348, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.