fbpx
Wikipedia

Information asymmetry

In contract theory and economics, information asymmetry deals with the study of decisions in transactions where one party has more or better information than the other.

Diagram illustrating the balance of power with perfect information by buyers and sellers.

Information asymmetry creates an imbalance of power in transactions, which can sometimes cause the transactions to be inefficient, causing market failure in the worst case. Examples of this problem are adverse selection,[1] moral hazard,[2] and monopolies of knowledge.[3]

A common way to visualise information asymmetry is with a scale, with one side being the seller and the other the buyer. When the seller has more or better information, the transaction will more likely occur in the seller's favour ("the balance of power has shifted to the seller"). An example of this could be when a used car is sold, the seller is likely to have a much better understanding of the car's condition and hence its market value than the buyer, who can only estimate the market value based on the information provided by the seller and their own assessment of the vehicle.[4] The balance of power can, however, also be in the hands of the buyer. When buying health insurance, the buyer is not always required to provide full details of future health risks. By not providing this information to the insurance company, the buyer will pay the same premium as someone much less likely to require a payout in the future.[5] The adjacent image illustrates the balance of power between two agents when there is Perfect information. Perfect information means that all parties have complete knowledge. If the buyer has more information, the power to manipulate the transaction will be represented by the scale leaning towards the buyer's side.

Information asymmetry extends to non-economic behaviour. Private firms have better information than regulators about the actions that they would take in the absence of regulation, and the effectiveness of a regulation may be undermined.[6] International relations theory has recognized that wars may be caused by asymmetric information[7] and that "Most of the great wars of the modern era resulted from leaders miscalculating their prospects for victory".[8] Jackson and Morelli wrote that there is asymmetric information between national leaders, when there are differences "in what they know [i.e. believe] about each other's armaments, quality of military personnel and tactics, determination, geography, political climate, or even just about the relative probability of different outcomes" or where they have "incomplete information about the motivations of other agents".[9]

Information asymmetries are studied in the context of principal–agent problems where they are a major cause of misinforming and is essential in every communication process.[10] Information asymmetry is in contrast to perfect information, which is a key assumption in neo-classical economics.[11]

In 1996, a Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics was awarded to James A. Mirrlees and William Vickrey for their "fundamental contributions to the economic theory of incentives under asymmetric information".[12] This led the Nobel Committee to acknowledge the importance of information problems in economics.[13] They later awarded another Nobel Prize in 2001 to George Akerlof, Michael Spence, and Joseph E. Stiglitz for their "analyses of markets with asymmetric information".[14]

History edit

The puzzle of information asymmetry has existed for as long as the market itself but remained largely unstudied until the post-WWII period. It is an umbrella term that can contain a vast diversity of topics.

Greek Stoics (2nd century BCE) treated the advantage that sellers derive from privileged information in the story of the Merchant of Rhodes. Accordingly, a famine had broken out on the island of Rhodes and several grain merchants in Alexandria set sail to deliver supplies. One of these merchants who arrives ahead of his competitors faces a choice: should he let Rhodians know that grain supplies are on the way or keep this knowledge to himself? Either decision will determine his profit margin. Cicero related this dilemma in De Officiis and agreed with Greek Stoics that the merchant had a duty to disclose. Thomas Aquinas overturned this consensus and considered price disclosure was not obligatory.

The three topics mentioned above drew on some important predecessors. Joseph Stiglitz considered the work of earlier economists, including Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill, and Max Weber. He ultimately concludes that though these economists seemed to have an understanding of the problems of information, they largely did not consider the implications of them, and tended to minimize the impact they could have or consider them merely secondary issues.[13]

One exception to this is the work of economist Friedrich Hayek. His work with prices as information conveying relative scarcity of goods can be noted as an early form of acknowledging information asymmetry, but with a different name.[13]

2001 Nobel Prize Inspirations edit

Information problems have always affected the lives of humans, yet it was not studied with any seriousness until near the 1970s when three economists fleshed out models which revolutionized the way we think about information and its interaction with the market. George Akerlof's paper The Market for Lemons[4] introduced a model to help explain a variety of market outcomes when quality is uncertain. Akerlof's primary model considers the automobile market where the seller knows the exact quality of a car. In contrast, the buyer only knows the probability of whether a vehicle is good or bad (a lemon). Since the buyer pays the same price (based on their expected quality) for good cars and bad cars, sellers with high-quality cars may find the transaction unprofitable and leave, resulting in a market with a higher proportion of bad cars. The pathological path can continue as the buyer adjusts the expected quality and offers even lower prices, further driving out cars with not-so-bad quality. This results in a market failure purely driven by information asymmetry, as under perfect information, all cars can be sold according to their quality. Akerlof extends the model to explain other phenomena: Why raising the insurance price cannot facilitate seniors getting medical insurance? Why may employers rationally refuse to hire minorities? Through various applications, Akerlof developed the importance of trust in markets and highlighted the "cost of dishonesty" in insurance markets, credit markets, and developing areas. Around the same time, an economist by the name of Michael Spence wrote on the topic of job market signaling, and was introduced a work of the same name.[15] The final topic is Stiglitz's work on the mechanism of screening.[16] These three economists helped to further clarify a variety of economic puzzles at the time and would go on to win a Nobel Prize in 2001 for their contributions to the field. Since then, several economists have followed in their footsteps to solve more pieces of the puzzle.

Akerlof edit

Akerlof drew heavily from the work of economist Kenneth Arrow. Arrow, who was awarded a Nobel Prize in Economics in 1972, studied uncertainty in the field of medical care, among other things (Arrow 1963). His work highlighted several factors which became important to Akerlof's studies. First, is the idea of moral hazard. By being insured, customers may be inclined to be less careful than they otherwise would without insurance because they know the costs will be covered. Thus, an incentive to be less careful and increase risk exists. Second, Arrow studied the business models of insurance companies and noted that higher-risk individuals are pooled with lower-risk individuals, but both are covered at the same cost. Third, Arrow noted the role of trust in the relationship between doctor and patient. Medical providers only get paid when a patient is sick, and not when a person is healthy. Because of this, there is a great incentive for doctors to not provide the quality of care they could. A patient must defer to the doctor and trust that the doctor is using their knowledge to their best advantage to provide the patient with the best care. Thus, a relationship of trust is established. According to Arrow, the doctor relies on the social obligation of trust to sell their services to the public, even though the patients do not or cannot inspect the quality of a doctor's work. Last, he notes how this unique relationship demands that high levels of education and certification be attained by doctors in order to maintain the quality of medical service provided by doctors. These four ideas from Arrow contributed largely to Akerlof's work.

Spence edit

Spence cited no sources for his inspiration. However, he did acknowledge Kenneth Arrow and Thomas Schelling as helpful in discussing ideas during his pursuit of knowledge.[15] He was the first to coin the term "signaling",[15] and encouraged other economists to follow in his footsteps because he believed he had introduced an important concept in economics.

Stiglitz edit

Most of Stiglitz's academic inspirations were from his contemporaries. Stiglitz primarily attributes his thinking to articles by Spence, Akerlof, and a few earlier works by him and his co-author Michael Rothschild (Rothschild and Stiglitz 1976), each discussing various aspects of screening and the role of education. Stiglitz's work was a complement to the works of Spence and Akerlof and thus drew from some of the same inspirations from Arrow as Akerlof had.

The discussion of information asymmetry came to the forefront of economics in the 1970s when Akerlof introduced the idea of a "market for lemons" in a paper by the same name (Akerlof 1970). In this paper, Akerlof introduced a fundamental concept that certain sellers of used cars have more knowledge than the buyers, and this can lead to what is known as "adverse selection". This idea may be one of the most important in the history and understanding of asymmetric information in economics.[13]

Spence introduced the idea of "signaling" shortly after the publication of Akerlof's work.

Stiglitz expanded upon the ideas of Spence and Akerlof by introducing an economic function of information asymmetry called "screening". Stiglitz's work in this area referred to the market for insurance, which is rife with information asymmetry problems to be studied.[16]

Impact of 2001 Nobel Work edit

These three economists' simple yet revolutionary work birthed a movement in economics that changed how the field viewed the market forever. No longer can perfect information be assumed in some problems, as in most neoclassical models. Information asymmetry began to grow in prevalence in academic literature.[13] In 1996, a Nobel Prize was given to James Mirrlees and William Vickrey for their research back in the 1970s and 1970s on incentive problems when facing uncertainty under asymmetric information.[17] The impact of such academic work can go unrecognized for decades. Differing from the topics presented by Akerlof, Spence and Stiglitz, Mirrlees and Vickrey focused on how income taxation and auctions can be used as a mechanism to draw out information from market participants efficiently. This award marked the importance of information asymmetry in economics. It began a greater discussion on the topic that later led the Nobel committee to award three economists again in 2001 for significant contributions to the aforementioned topics.[18]

These economists continued after the 1970s to contribute to the field of economics and develop their theories, and they have all had significant impacts. Akerlof's work had more impact than just the market for used cars. The pooling effect in the used car market also happens in the employment market for minorities.

One of the most notable impacts of Akerlof's work is its impact on Keynesian theory.[13] Akerlof argues that the Keynesian theory of unemployment being voluntary implies that quits would rise with unemployment. He argues against his critics by drawing upon reasoning based on psychology and sociology rather than pure economics. He supplemented this with an argument that people do not always behave rationally, but rather information asymmetry leads to only "near rationality", which causes people to deviate from optimal behavior regarding employment practices.[19]

Akerlof continues to champion behavioral economics, that these breaches into the fields of psychology and sociology are profound extensions of information asymmetry.[13]

Stiglitz wrote that the trio's work has created a substantial wave in the field of economics. He notes how he explored the economies of third-world countries, and they seemed to exhibit behavior consistent with their theories. He noted how other economists have referred to gaining information as a transaction cost.[20] Stiglitz also attempts to narrow down the sources of information asymmetries. He ties it back to the nature of each individual having information that others do not. Stiglitz also mentions how information asymmetry can be overcome. He believes there are two crucial things to consider: first, the incentives, and second, the mechanisms for overcoming information asymmetry. He argues that the incentives will always be there because markets are inherently informationally inefficient. If there is an opportunity to profit from gaining knowledge, people will do so. If there is no profit to be had, then people will not do so.

Spence's work on signaling moved on in the 1980s to spawn the field of study known as game theory.[21]

The idea of information asymmetry has also had a significant effect on management research. It continues to offer additional improvements and opportunities as scholars continue their work.[22]

Models edit

Information asymmetry models assume one party possesses some information that other parties have no access to. Some asymmetric information models can also be used in situations where at least one party can enforce, or effectively retaliate for breaches of, certain parts of an agreement, whereas the other(s) cannot.

Adverse Selection edit

Akerlof suggested that information asymmetry leads to adverse selections.[4] In adverse selection models, the ignorant party lacks of has differing information while negotiating an agreed understanding of or contract to the transaction. An example of adverse selection is when people who are high-risk are more likely to buy insurance because the insurance company cannot effectively discriminate against them, usually due to lack of information about the particular individual's risk but also sometimes by force of law or other constraints.

Credence Goods fits in the adverse selection model of information asymmetry. These are goods where the buyer lacks the knowledge even after a product is consumed to disguise the product's quality or where the buyer is unaware of the quality needed.[23] An example of this are complex medical treatments such as heart surgery.

Moral Hazard edit

Moral hazard occurs when the ignorant party lacks information about the performance of the agreed-upon transaction or lacks the ability to retaliate for a breach of the agreement. This can result in a situation where a party is more likely to take risks because they are not fully responsible for the consequences of their actions. An example of moral hazard is when people are more likely to behave recklessly after becoming insured, either because the insurer cannot observe this behaviour or cannot effectively retaliate against it, for example, by failing to renew the insurance.[2] Moral Hazard is not limited to individuals firms can act more recklessly if they know they will be bailed out. For example, banks will allow parties to take out risky loans if they know that the government will bail them out.[24]

Monopolies of Knowledge edit

In the model of monopolies of knowledge, the ignorant party has no right to access all the critical information about a situation for decision-making. Meaning one party has exclusive control over information. This type of information asymmetry can be seen in government. An example of monopolies of knowledge is that in some enterprises, only high-level management can fully access the corporate information provided by a third party. At the same time, lower-level employees are required to make important decisions with only limited information provided to them.[25]

Solutions edit

Countermeasures have widely been discussed to reduce information asymmetry. The classic paper on adverse selection is George Akerlof's "The Market for Lemons" from 1970, which brought informational issues to the forefront of economic theory. Exploring signaling and screening, the paper discusses two primary solutions to this problem.[26] A similar concept is moral hazard, which differs from adverse selection at the timing level. While adverse selection affects parties before the interaction, moral hazard affects parties after the interaction. Regulatory instruments such as mandatory information disclosure can also reduce information asymmetry.[27] Warranties can further help mitigate the effect of asymmetric information.[28]

Signalling edit

Michael Spence originally proposed the idea of signalling.[15] He suggested that in a situation with information asymmetry, it is possible for people to signal their type, thus believably transferring information to the other party and resolving the asymmetry.

This idea was initially studied in the context of matching in the job market. An employer is interested in hiring a new employee who is "skilled in learning". Of course, all prospective employees will claim to be "skilled in learning", but only they know if they really are. This is an information asymmetry.

Spence proposes, for example, that going to college can function as a credible signal of an ability to learn. Assuming that people who are skilled in learning can finish college more easily than people who are unskilled, then by finishing college, the skilled people signal their skills to prospective employers. No matter how much or how little they may have learned in college or what they studied, finishing functions as a signal of their capacity for learning. However, finishing college may merely function as a signal of their ability to pay for college; it may signal the willingness of individuals to adhere to orthodox views, or it may signal a willingness to comply with authority.

Signalling theory can be used in e-commerce research. Information asymmetry in e-commerce comes from information distortion that leads to the buyer's misunderstanding of the seller's true characteristics before the contract. Mavlanova, Benbunan-Fich and Koufaris (2012) noticed that signalling theory explains the relation between signals and qualities, illustrating why some signals are trustworthy and others are not. In e-commerce, signals deliver information about the characteristics of the seller. For instance, high-quality sellers are able to show their identity to buyers by using signs and logos, and then buyers check these signals to evaluate the credibility and validity of a seller's qualities. The study of Mavlanova, Benbunan-Fich and Koufaris (2012) also confirmed that signal usage is different between low-quality and high-quality online sellers. Low-quality sellers are more likely to avoid using expensive, easy-to-verify signals and tend to use fewer signals than high-quality sellers. Thus, signals help reduce information asymmetry.[29]

Screening edit

Joseph E. Stiglitz pioneered the theory of screening. In this way, the under informed party can induce the other party to reveal their information. They can provide a menu of choices in such a way that the choice depends on the private information of the other party.

The side of asymmetry can occur on either buyer or seller. For example, sellers with better information than buyers include used-car salespeople, mortgage brokers and loan originators, stockbrokers and real estate agents. Alternatively, situations where the buyer usually has better information than the seller include estate sales as specified in a last will and testament, life insurance, or sales of old art pieces without a prior professional assessment of their value. This situation was first described by Kenneth J. Arrow in an article on health care in 1963.[5]

George Akerlof, in The Market for Lemons notices that, in such a market, the average value of the commodity tends to go down, even for those of perfectly good quality. Because of information asymmetry, unscrupulous sellers can sell "forgeries" (like replica goods such as watches) and defraud the buyer. Meanwhile, buyers usually do not have enough information to distinguish lemons from quality goods. As a result, many people not willing to risk getting ripped off will avoid certain types of purchases or will not spend as much for a given item. Akerlof demonstrates that it is even possible for the market to decay to the point of nonexistence.

 
As lower-risk participants leave the pool, expected costs of the pool increase which causes premiums to increase

An example of adverse selection and information asymmetry causing market failure is the market for health insurance. Policies usually group subscribers together, where people can leave, but no one can join after it is set. As health conditions are realized over time, information involving health costs will arise, and low-risk policyholders will realize the mismatch in the premiums and health conditions. Due to this, healthy policyholders are incentivized to leave and reapply to get a cheaper policy that matches their expected health costs, which causes the premiums to increase. As high-risk policyholders are more dependent on insurance, they are stuck with higher premium costs as the group size reduces, which causes premiums to increase even further. This cycle repeats until the high-risk policy holders also find similar health policies with cheaper premiums, in which the initial group disappears. This concept is known as the death spiral and has been researched as early as 1988.[30]

Akerlof also suggests different methods with which information asymmetry can be reduced. One of those instruments that can be used to reduce the information asymmetry between market participants is intermediary market institutions called counteracting institutions, for instance, guarantees for goods. By providing a guarantee, the buyer in the transaction can use extra time to obtain the same amount of information about the good as the seller before the buyer takes on the complete risk of the good being a "lemon". Other market mechanisms that help reduce the imbalance in information include brand names, chains and franchising that guarantee the buyer a threshold quality level. These mechanisms also let owners of high-quality products get the full value of the goods. These counteracting institutions then keep the market size from reducing to zero.

Warranty edit

Warranties are utilised as a method of verifying the credibility of a product and are a guarantee issued by the seller promising to replace or repair the good should the quality not be sufficient. Product warranties are often requested from buying parties or financial lenders and have been used as a form of mediation dating back to the Babylonian era.[31] Warranties can come in the form of insurance and can also come at the expense of the buyer. The implementation of "lemon laws" has eradicated the effect of information asymmetry upon customers who have received a faulty item. Essentially, this involves the customers returning a defective product regardless of circumstances within a certain time period.[32]

Mandatory information disclosure edit

Both signaling and screening resemble voluntary information disclosure, where the party having more information, for their own best interest, use various measures to inform the other party. However, voluntary information disclosure is not always feasible. Regulators can thus take active measures to facilitate the spread of information. For example, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) initiated Regulation Fair Disclosure (RFD) so that companies must faithfully disclose material information to investors. The policy has reduced information asymmetry, reflected in the lower trading costs.[33]

Incentives and penalties edit

For firms to reduce moral hazard, they can implement penalties for bad behaviour and incentives to align objectives.[34] An example of building in an incentive is insurance companies not insuring customers for the total value; this provides an incentive to be less reckless as the customer will suffer financial liability as well.

Information gathering edit

Most models in traditional contract theory assume that asymmetric information is exogenously given.[35][36] Yet, some authors have also studied contract-theoretic models in which asymmetric information arises endogenously because agents decide whether or not to gather information. Specifically, Crémer and Khalil (1992) and Crémer, Khalil, and Rochet (1998a) study an agent's incentives to acquire private information after a principal has offered a contract.[37][38] In a laboratory experiment, Hoppe and Schmitz (2013) have provided empirical support for the theory.[39] Several further models have been developed which study variants of this setup. For instance, when the agent has not gathered information at the outset, does it make a difference whether or not he learns the information later on, before production starts?[40] What happens if the information can be gathered already before a contract is offered?[41] What happens if the principal observes the agent's decision to acquire information?[42] Finally, the theory has been applied in several contexts, such as public-private partnerships and vertical integration.[43][44]

Sources edit

Information asymmetry within societies can be created and maintained in several ways. Firstly, media outlets, due to their ownership structure or political influences, may fail to disseminate certain viewpoints or choose to engage in propaganda campaigns. Furthermore, an educational system relying on substantial tuition fees can generate information imbalances between the poor and the affluent. Imbalances can also be fortified by specific organizational and legal measures, such as document classification procedures or non-disclosure clauses. Exclusive information networks that are operational around the world further contribute to the asymmetry. Copyright laws increase information imbalances between the poor and the affluent. Lastly, mass surveillance helps the political and industrial leaders to amass large volumes of information, which is typically not shared with the rest of society.[45]

Market impact edit

Zavolokina, Schlegel, and Schwabe (2020) state that Information asymmetry makes buyers and sellers distrust each other, which leads to opportunistic behaviour and may even lead to complete break down of the market.[46] At the same time, lower quality provision in markets is also one of the consequences, as sellers do not get benefits enough to cover their production costs of providing higher quality products.

Countermeasures

  • Abito, Jose Miguel, & Salant, Yuval proposed that warranty enhancing consumer welfare highlights the relevance of policies that directly guide consumer decisions and increases buyers' trust in high-quality buyers.[47]
  • Establish a real-time information announce platform, according to the collect information to achieve market transparency,eliminate trading concerns thereby.
  • Enhance customer experience by third-party quality checks like providing expert reviews.
  • Consumer protection law ensure that product quality meets expectations and that contract terms are fair.
  • Ensure quality in the form of standards and certificates and prove that all technical parameters have been tested.

Application in research edit

Accounting and finance edit

A substantial portion of research in the field of accounting can be framed in terms of information asymmetry, since accounting involves the transmission of an enterprise's information from those who have it to those who need it for decision-making. Bartov and Bodnar (1996) mentioned that the different accounting methods used by enterprises can lead to information asymmetry.[48] For instance aggressively recognising revenue can result in preparers of financial statements having a much better understanding of the levels of future revenue then those reading the statements. Likewise, in finance literature, the acknowledgment of information asymmetry between organizations challenged the Modigliani–Miller theorem, which states that the valuation of a firm is unaffected by its financial structure. It challenges the theorem as one of the key assumptions is that investors would have the same information as a corporation. If there is not symmetry in information corporations can leverage their capital structure to get the most out of their valuation. Information asymmetry shed light on the importance of aligning interests of managers with those of stakeholders. As managers with significant power from information may make decision based on their own interest as opposed to the companies. When the level of information asymmetry and associated monitoring cost is high, firms tend to rely less on board monitoring and more on incentive alignment.[49] Various measures are used to align interest of managers to stop them from abusing their power from information asymmetry such as compensating based on performance using a bonus structure. This field of study is referred to as agency theory. Furthermore, financial economists apply information asymmetry in studies of differentially informed financial market participants (insiders, stock analysts, investors, etc.) or in the cost of finance for MFIs.[50]

Effect of blogging edit

The effect of blogging as a source of information asymmetry as well as a tool reduce asymmetric information has also been well studied. Blogging on financial websites provides bottom-up communication among investors, analysts, journalists, and academics, as financial blogs help prevent people in charge from withholding financial information from their company and the general public.[51] Compared to traditional forms of media such as newspapers and magazines, blogging provides an easy-to-access venue for information. A 2013 study by Gregory Saxton and Ashley Anker concluded that more participation on blogging sites from credible individuals reduces information asymmetry between corporate insiders, additionally reducing the risk of insider trading.[52]

 
A game of imperfect information with sub-games. Here each player will have no information of each other's move while making decisions. This representation is of one person's decisions in a game, however, it does not correspond to the actual timing of the player's decisions. The dashed line between nodes represent information asymmetry and show that, during the game, a party cannot distinguish between the nodes.

Game theory edit

Game theory can be used to analyse asymmetric information.[53] A large amount of the foundational ideas in game theory builds on the framework of information asymmetry. In simultaneous games, each player has no prior knowledge of an opponent's move. In sequential games, players may observe all or part of the opponent's moves. One example of information asymmetry is one player can observe the opponent's past activities while the other player cannot. Therefore, the existence and level of information asymmetry in a game determines the dynamics of the game. James Fearon in his study of the explanations for war in a game theoretic context notices that war could be a consequence of information asymmetry – two countries will not reach a non-violent settlement because they have incentives to distort the amount of military resources they possess.[54]

Contract theory edit

Contract theory provides insights into how various economic agents can enter contractual arrangements in situation of unequal levels of information. The development of contract theory is based on assuming its parties possess different levels of information on the contract's subject. For instance, in a road construction contract, a civil engineer may have more information on the various inputs required to undertake the project, than the other parties. Through contract theory, economic agents gain insights on how they can exploit information available to them, to enter beneficial contractual arrangements. The impact information asymmetry causes among parties with competing interests, such as games, has contributed to game theory. In no game do its players have complete information about each other; most importantly, no player knows the strategy the others intends to use to realize a win. This information asymmetry, together with the competing interests have resulted in the development of game theory (which seeks to provides insights as to how parties caught up in a situation where they are required to compete under a set of rules, can maximize their expected outcomes).

Information asymmetry occurs in situations where some parties have more information regarding an issue than others. It is considered a major cause of market failure.[55] The contribution of information asymmetry to market failure arises from the fact that it impairs with the free hand which is expected to guide how modern markets work. For example, the stock market forms a major avenue through which publicly traded entities can raise their capital. The operation of stock markets across the world, is carried in a way that ensures current and potential investors have the same level of information about the stocks or any other securities that may be listed in that market. That level of information symmetry helps to ensure similar conditions to all parties in the market, which in turn helps to ensure the securities listed in those markets trade at fair value.[55] However, cases of information sometimes arise, when certain parties obtain information that is not in the public domain. This can create market return abnormalities, such as an abrupt surge or decline in a security.

Artificial intelligence edit

Tshilidzi Marwala and Evan Hurwitz in their study of the relationship between information asymmetry and artificial intelligence observed that there is a reduced level of information asymmetry between two artificial intelligent agents than between two human agents. As a consequence, when these artificial intelligent agents engage in financial markets it reduces arbitrage opportunities making markets more efficient. The study also revealed that as the number of artificial intelligent agents in the market increase, the volume of trades in the market will decrease.[56][57] This is primarily because information asymmetry of the perceptions of value of goods and services is the basis of trade.

Management edit

Information asymmetry has been applied in a variety of ways in management research ranging from conceptualizations of information asymmetry to building resolutions to reduce it.[22] Studies have shown that information asymmetry can be a source of competitive advantage for the firms.[58] A 2013 study by Schmidt and Keil has revealed that the presence of private information asymmetry within firms influences normal business activities. Firms that have a more concrete understanding of their resources can use this information to gauge their advantage over competitors.[59] In Ozeml, Reuer and Gulati's 2013 study, they found that 'different information' was an additional source of information asymmetry in venture capitalist and alliance networks; when different team members bring diverse, specialized knowledge, values and outlooks towards a common strategic decision, the lack of homogeneous information distribution among the members leads to inefficient decision making.[60]

Firms have the ability to apply strategies that exploit their informational gap. One way they can do this is through impression management, which involves undertaking actions and releasing information to influence stakeholders' and analysts' opinions positively, exploiting information asymmetry as external parties heavily rely on the information released by firms.[61] A second way that firms exploit information asymmetry is through decoupling. This describes the discrepancy between formal procedures and failure to implement them.[62] An example of this is executives announcing a stock repurchase plan without any intention of carrying it out, allowing them to raise new cash flow for their own benefit at the expense of shareholders.[22] Management research goes on to explain that agents can perpetuate information asymmetry through information concealment. This involves firms not sharing information to exploit the informational advantage over rivals. In resource-based theory, it shows firms concealing information about their competitive advantage in order to build causal ambiguity to protect their firm from imitation.[63][22]

Information asymmetry problems can be addressed by management through several approaches. First is the usage of incentives to encourage the disclosure and sharing information. An example of this is partnering specifically with companies that disclose relatively more information. Second, is through precommitment, where actions are undertaken at present to ensure future commitments. Third, is the usage of an information intermediary in which an intermediary is used to gather and relay information between two parties. A common example of this are financial analysts that gather information from the financial statements of a company, and uses it to create reports and advice for potential investors and clients. Fourth, is the usage of monitoring and reward. Monitoring allows management to confirm information that was previously uncertain, such as performance and behaviour. Monitoring can also be used alongside other incentives such as rewarding for performance.[22]

Online Advertising edit

Online advertising is a dominant form of advertising, and a potential source of information asymmetry. Online advertising consists of utilities(a good) being encoded into a message received by a customer who decodes the message, making a purchasing decision.[64] Firms' messages are tailored to specific goals and intentions, and can be a source of information asymmetry due to interpretation, or intent. The nature of the internet and prevalence of social media in society has given firms opportunities to create promotional content in a less passive way than other forms of advertising. 'Noise' represents any techniques that are used with the intent of obstructing, altering, or blocking the interpretation of the message by the receiver.[65] This can increase the amount of information asymmetry in a transaction, as the buyer may not understand the product to its fullest extent, even if they believe to fully understand the message being sent to them.

Firms communicate to the virtual marketplace through online advertising, and as such the feedback of consumers feeling manipulated or feeling the presence of information asymmetry may be indicative of the lack of transparency by a firm. Highly advertised and strongly promoted items are generally more likely to be bought by customers, even if the product is inferior to less advertised competition, introducing adverse selection. The power of the internet also changes how consumers deal with information asymmetry, as they have the means to find vast amounts of information about products with relatively little effort. While a consumer can use this power to assist their research to find a product that is not being marketed maliciously, this decision is made due to information asymmetry, not due to the customer being perfectly rational.[64]

Some consumers are aware of the usage of strategies and techniques by firms to advertise and influence their media consumption, however do not necessarily alter their trust in the source of the information accordingly.[66] Online advertising that appears trustworthy but can be malicious in intent can still be trusted by consumers, despite the information asymmetry, even if consumers themselves identify as critical of the medium. Social media personalities, much like other celebrities, also have influence over consumers who would otherwise consider themselves dissuaded by the advertising, providing firms another method of aggressive advertising with potential information asymmetry.[66]

See also edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ Charles Wilson (2008). "adverse selection," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition. Abstract.
  2. ^ a b Dembe, Allard E. and Boden, Leslie I. (2000). "Moral Hazard: A Question of Morality?" New Solutions 2000 10(3). 257–79
  3. ^ John O. Ledyard (2008). "market failure,"  The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Ed.  Abstract.
  4. ^ a b c Akerlof, George A. (1970-08-01). "The Market for "Lemons": Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 84 (3): 488–500. doi:10.2307/1879431. ISSN 0033-5533. JSTOR 1879431. S2CID 6738765.
  5. ^ a b Arrow, Kenneth J. (1963). "Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care". American Economic Review. American Economic Association. 53 (5): 941–973. JSTOR 1812044.
  6. ^ Fullerton, Don; Wolfram, Catherine (13 May 2010). The Design and Implementation of U.S. Climate Policy (PDF). Chicago Illinois: University of Chicago Press. p. 11. ISBN 9780226269146. Retrieved 9 March 2019.
  7. ^ Jackson & Morelli 2011, pp. 35, 40–43.
  8. ^ Ikenberry 1999, p. 128.
  9. ^ Jackson & Morelli 2011, pp. 40, 42.
  10. ^ Christozov D., Chukova S., Mateev P., Chapter 11. Informing Processes, Risks, Evaluation of the Risk of Misinforming, in Foundations of Informing Science, ISI, 2009, pp. 323–356
  11. ^ "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2001". NobelPrize.org. Retrieved 2020-03-07.
  12. ^ "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1996". NobelPrize.org. Retrieved 2020-11-19.
  13. ^ a b c d e f g Rosser, J. Barkley Jr. (2003-01-01). "A Nobel Prize for Asymmetric Information: The economic contributions of George Akerlof, Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz". Review of Political Economy. 15 (1): 3–21. doi:10.1080/09538250308445. ISSN 0953-8259. S2CID 154549764.
  14. ^ "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2001: Information for the Public", press release from the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, Nobel Foundation, nobelprize.org, October 2001, accessed November 12, 2007.
  15. ^ a b c d Spence, Michael (August 1973). "Job Market Signaling". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 87 (3): 355–374. doi:10.2307/1882010. ISSN 0033-5533. JSTOR 1882010.
  16. ^ a b Rothschild, Michael, and Stiglitz, Joseph. 1976. "Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 90, no. 4: 629.
  17. ^ Sandmar, Agmo. 1999. "Asymmetric Information and Public Economics: The Mirrlees-Vickrey Nobel Prize." The Journal of Economic Perspectives 13, no. 1: 165.
  18. ^ Löfgren, Karl-Gustaf, Torsten Persson, and Jörgen W. Weibull. 2002. "Markets with Asymmetric Information: The Contributions of George Akerlof, Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz." The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 104, no. 2: 195–211
  19. ^ Akerlof, George A.; Yellen, Janet L. (1985-01-01). "A Near-Rational Model of the Business Cycle, with Wage and Price Inertia". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 100 (Supplement): 823–838. doi:10.1093/qje/100.Supplement.823. ISSN 0033-5533.
  20. ^ Stigler, George J. (1961-06-01). "The Economics of Information". Journal of Political Economy. 69 (3): 213–225. doi:10.1086/258464. ISSN 0022-3808. S2CID 222441709.
  21. ^ Riley, John G. (June 2001). "Silver Signals: Twenty-Five Years of Screening and Signaling". Journal of Economic Literature. 39 (2): 432–478. doi:10.1257/jel.39.2.432. ISSN 0022-0515.
  22. ^ a b c d e Bergh, Donald D.; Ketchen, David J.; Orlandi, Ilaria; Heugens, Pursey P. M. A. R.; Boyd, Brian K. (2018-09-21). "Information Asymmetry in Management Research: Past Accomplishments and Future Opportunities". Journal of Management. 45 (1): 122–158. doi:10.1177/0149206318798026. ISSN 0149-2063. S2CID 150012600.
  23. ^ Dranove, David (2011-01-01), Pauly, Mark V.; Mcguire, Thomas G.; Barros, Pedro P. (eds.), Chapter Ten - Health Care Markets, Regulators, and Certifiers, Handbook of Health Economics, vol. 2, Elsevier, pp. 639–690, doi:10.1016/B978-0-444-53592-4.00010-4, retrieved 2022-05-03
  24. ^ Cordella, T., & Yeyati, E. L. (2003). Bank bailouts: moral hazard vs. value effect. Journal of Financial intermediation, 12(4), 300-330.
  25. ^ Innis, Harold. (1951) The Bias of Communication. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, pp. 179-180.
  26. ^ Johannes Hörne (2008). "signalling and screening" The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
  27. ^ Zhu, Xufeng; Zhang, Chao (2012). "Reducing information asymmetry in the power industry: Mandatory and voluntary information disclosure regulations of sulphur dioxide emission". Energy Policy. 45: 704–713. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2012.03.024.
  28. ^ Ross, Sean. "How can the problem of asymmetric information be overcome?". Investopedia. Retrieved 2021-04-26.
  29. ^ Mavlanova, Tamilla; Benbunan-Fich, Raquel; Koufaris, Marios (2012-07-01). "Signaling theory and information asymmetry in online commerce". Information & Management. 49 (5): 240–247. doi:10.1016/j.im.2012.05.004. ISSN 0378-7206.
  30. ^ Cutler, David M.; Zeckhauser, Richard J. (1998). "Adverse Selection in Health Insurance" (PDF). Forum for Health Economics & Policy. 1 (1). doi:10.2202/1558-9544.1056.
  31. ^ Loomba, Arvinder P.S. (June 1998). "Evolution of product warranty: a chronological study". Journal of Management History (Archive). 4 (2): 124–136. doi:10.1108/13552529810219601. ISSN 1355-252X.
  32. ^ Ross, Sean. "How can the problem of asymmetric information be overcome?". Investopedia. Retrieved 2021-04-26.
  33. ^ Eleswarapu, Venkat R.; Thompson, Rex; Venkataraman, Kumar (2012). "The Impact of Regulation Fair Disclosure: Trading Costs and Information Asymmetry". The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis. 39 (2): 209–225. doi:10.1017/S0022109000003045. JSTOR 30031853. S2CID 54649344.
  34. ^ Eisenhardt K. M. 1989. Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review, 14: 57-74.
  35. ^ Baron, David P.; Myerson, Roger B. (1982). "Regulating a Monopolist with Unknown Costs". Econometrica. 50 (4): 911–930. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.407.6185. doi:10.2307/1912769. JSTOR 1912769.
  36. ^ Maskin, Eric; Riley, John (1984). "Monopoly with Incomplete Information". The RAND Journal of Economics. 15 (2): 171. doi:10.2307/2555674. ISSN 0741-6261. JSTOR 2555674.
  37. ^ Cremer, Jacques; Khalil, Fahad (1992). "Gathering Information before Signing a Contract". American Economic Review. 82 (3): 566–578.
  38. ^ Crémer, Jacques; Khalil, Fahad; Rochet, Jean-Charles (1998a). "Contracts and Productive Information Gathering". Games and Economic Behavior. 25 (2): 174–193. doi:10.1006/game.1998.0651. ISSN 0899-8256.
  39. ^ Hoppe, Eva I.; Schmitz, Patrick W. (2013). "Contracting under Incomplete Information and Social Preferences: An Experimental Study". Review of Economic Studies. 80 (4): 1516–1544. doi:10.1093/restud/rdt010.
  40. ^ Hoppe, Eva I.; Schmitz, Patrick W. (2010). "The costs and benefits of additional information in agency models with endogenous information structures". Economics Letters. 107 (1): 58–62. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2009.12.026. ISSN 0165-1765.
  41. ^ Crémer, Jacques; Khalil, Fahad; Rochet, Jean-Charles (1998b). "Strategic Information Gathering before a Contract Is Offered". Journal of Economic Theory. 81 (1): 163–200. doi:10.1006/jeth.1998.2415. ISSN 0022-0531.
  42. ^ Hoppe, Eva I. (2013). "Observability of information acquisition in agency models". Economics Letters. 119 (1): 104–107. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2013.01.015. ISSN 0165-1765.
  43. ^ Hoppe, Eva I.; Schmitz, Patrick W. (2013). "Public-private partnerships versus traditional procurement: Innovation incentives and information gathering" (PDF). The RAND Journal of Economics. 44 (1): 56–74. doi:10.1111/1756-2171.12010. ISSN 0741-6261.
  44. ^ Khalil, Fahad; Kim, Doyoung; Shin, Dongsoo (2006). "Optimal Task Design: To Integrate or Separate Planning and Implementation?". Journal of Economics & Management Strategy. 15 (2): 457–478. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.186.157. doi:10.1111/j.1530-9134.2006.00107.x. ISSN 1058-6407. S2CID 154686412.
  45. ^ The tools used to create information asymmetries are described in the following article http://ssrn.com/abstract=2383166
  46. ^ Zavolokina, Liudmila; Schlegel, Manuel; Schwabe, Gerhard (2020-02-18). "How can we reduce information asymmetries and enhance trust in 'The Market for Lemons'?". Information Systems and E-Business Management. 19 (3): 883–908. doi:10.1007/s10257-020-00466-4. ISSN 1617-9846. S2CID 213260199.
  47. ^ Abito, Jose Miguel; Salant, Yuval (2018-09-04). "The Effect of Product Misperception on Economic Outcomes: Evidence from the Extended Warranty Market". The Review of Economic Studies. 86 (6): 2285–2318. doi:10.1093/restud/rdy045. ISSN 0034-6527.
  48. ^ Bartov, Eli; Bodnar, Gordon M. (1996). "Alternative Accounting Methods, Information Asymmetry and Liquidity: Theory and Evidence". The Accounting Review. 71 (3): 397–418. ISSN 0001-4826. JSTOR 248295.
  49. ^ Cai, Jie; Qian, Yiming; Yu, Miaomiao (2015). "Information asymmetry and corporate governance". The Quarterly Journal of Finance. 05 (3). doi:10.1142/S2010139215500147.
  50. ^ Garmaise, M. & G. Natividad (2010). "Information, the Cost of Credit, and Operational Efficiency: An Empirical Study of Microfinance". Review of Financial Studies. 23 (6): 2560–2590. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhq021.
  51. ^ Saxton, Gregory D. (3 August 2008). "Financial blogs and information asymmetry between firm insiders and outsiders". Annual Meeting of the American Accounting Association.
  52. ^ Saxton, G. D. and A. E. Anker (2013). "The Aggregate Effects of Decentralized Knowledge Production: Financial Bloggers and Information Asymmetries in the Stock Market." Journal of Communication 63(6): 1054–1069.
  53. ^ Wilkinson, Nick (2005-05-05). Managerial Economics: A Problem-Solving Approach (1 ed.). Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511810534.015. ISBN 978-0-521-81993-0.
  54. ^ Fearon, James D. (1995). "Rationalist Explanations for War". International Organization. 49 (3): 379–414. doi:10.1017/S0020818300033324. ISSN 0020-8183. JSTOR 2706903. S2CID 38573183.
  55. ^ a b Lambert, R., Leuz, C., & Verrecchia., 2012. Information Asymmetry, Information Precision and the Cost of Capital. Review of Finance, 16(1), pp. 1-29.
  56. ^ Marwala, Tshilidzi; Hurwitz, Evan (2017). Artificial Intelligence and Economic Theory: Skynet in the Market. London: Springer. ISBN 978-3-319-66104-9.
  57. ^ "Artificial Intelligence can Reduce Information Asymmetry : Networks Course blog for INFO 2040/CS 2850/Econ 2040/SOC 2090". Retrieved 2020-03-01.
  58. ^ Makadok, Richard (September 2011). Barney, Jay B.; Ketchen, David J.; Wright, Mike (eds.). "Invited Editorial: The Four Theories of Profit and Their Joint Effects". Journal of Management. 37 (5): 1316–1334. doi:10.1177/0149206310385697. ISSN 0149-2063. S2CID 144052666.
  59. ^ Schmidt, Jens; Keil, Thomas (2013-04-01). "What Makes a Resource Valuable? Identifying the Drivers of Firm-Idiosyncratic Resource Value". Academy of Management Review. 38 (2): 206–228. doi:10.5465/amr.2010.0404. ISSN 0363-7425.
  60. ^ Ozmel, Umit; Reuer, Jeffrey J.; Gulati, Ranjay (2012-07-24). "Signals across Multiple Networks: How Venture Capital and Alliance Networks Affect Interorganizational Collaboration". Academy of Management Journal. 56 (3): 852–866. doi:10.5465/amj.2009.0549. ISSN 0001-4273.
  61. ^ Dutton, J. E., Ashford, S. J., O’neill, R. M., Hayes, E., & Wierba, E. E. (1997). Reading the wind: How middle managers assess the context for selling issues to top managers. Strategic management journal, 18(5), 407-423.
  62. ^ Westphal, J. D., & Zajac, E. J. (2001). Decoupling policy from practice: The case of stock repurchase programs. Administrative science quarterly, 46(2), 202-228.
  63. ^ Brush, T. H., & Artz, K. W. (1999). Toward a contingent resource‐based theory: the impact of information asymmetry on the value of capabilities in veterinary medicine. Strategic Management Journal, 20(3), 223-250.
  64. ^ a b Wiktor, Jan W.; Sanak-Kosmowska, Katarzyna (2021-09-30). Information Asymmetry in Online Advertising. London: Routledge. pp. 45–47. doi:10.4324/9781003134121. ISBN 978-1-003-13412-1. S2CID 238682686.
  65. ^ McQuail, Denis (2005). Mass communication theory. Sage. ISBN 1-4129-0372-6. OCLC 1151855593.
  66. ^ a b Sanak-Kosmowska, Katarzyna; Wiktor, Jan W. (17 October 2020). "Empirical Identification of Latent Classes in the Assessment of Information Asymmetry and Manipulation in Online Advertising". Sustainability. 12 (20): 8693. doi:10.3390/su12208693. ISSN 2071-1050.

References edit

  • Aboody, David; Lev, Baruch (2000). "Information Asymmetry, R&D, and Insider Gains". Journal of Finance. 55 (6): 2747–2766. doi:10.1111/0022-1082.00305.
  • Akerlof, George A. (1970). "The Market for 'Lemons': Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 84 (3): 488–500. doi:10.2307/1879431. JSTOR 1879431. S2CID 6738765.
  • Bartov, Eli; Bodnar, Gordon M. (1996). "Alternative Accounting Methods, Information Asymmetry and Liquidity: Theory and Evidence". The Accounting Review. 71 (3): 397–418. JSTOR 248295 – via JSTOR.
  • Brown, Stephen; Hillegeist, Stephen; Lo, Kin (2004). "Conference calls and information asymmetry". Journal of Accounting and Economics. 37 (3): 343–366. doi:10.1016/j.jacceco.2004.02.001.
  • Hayes, Beth (1984). "Unions and Strikes with Asymmetric Information" (PDF). Journal of Labor Economics. [University of Chicago Press, Society of Labor Economists, NORC at the University of Chicago]. 2 (1): 57–83. doi:10.1086/298023. hdl:10419/220907. JSTOR 2535017. S2CID 154864920.
  • Ikenberry, G. John (1999). "Causes of War: Power and the Roots of International Conflict by Stephen Van Evers". Foreign Affairs. 78 (4): 128–9. doi:10.2307/20049381. JSTOR 20049381.
  • Izquierdo, Segismundo S.; Izquierdo, Luis R. (2007). "The impact of quality uncertainty without asymmetric information on market efficiency". Journal of Business Research. 60 (8): 858–867. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.412.9956. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2007.02.010. ISSN 0148-2963.
  • Jackson, Matthew O.; Morelli, Massimo (2011). "The Reasons for Wars – an Updated Survey". In Coyne, Chris J.; Mathers, Rachel L. (eds.). The Handbook on the Political Economy of War. Edward Elgar Publishing. pp. 34–57. ISBN 978-1849808323.
  • Koehler, Benedikt (2020). "Thomas Aquinas on the conduct of sales". Economic Affairs. 40 (3): 358–366. doi:10.1111/ecaf.12436. S2CID 229017093.
  • Mas-Colell, Andreu; Whinston, Michael D.; Green, Jerry R. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-507340-9. (Chaps. 13 and 14 discuss applications of adverse selection and moral hazard models to contract theory.)
  • Mavlanova, Tamilla; Benbunan-Fich, Raquel; Koufaris, Marios (2012). "Signaling theory and information asymmetry in online commerce". Information & Management. 49 (5): 240–247. doi:10.1016/j.im.2012.05.004 – via Elsevier.
  • Saxton, Gregory; Anker, Ashley (2013). "The Aggregate Effects of Decentralized Knowledge Production: Financial Bloggers and Information Asymmetries in the Stock Market". Journal of Communication. Wiley Subscription Services, Inc. 63 (6): 1054–1069. doi:10.1111/jcom.12060. S2CID 154672974.
  • Spence, Michael (1973). "Job Market Signaling". Quarterly Journal of Economics. The MIT Press. 87 (3): 355–374. doi:10.2307/1882010. JSTOR 1882010.
  • Stigler, George J. (1961). "The Economics of Information". Journal of Political Economy. University of Chicago Press. 69 (3): 213–225. doi:10.1086/258464. JSTOR 1829263. S2CID 222441709.

External links edit

  • "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2001" – Official Prize announcement by the Nobel Foundation, nobelprize.org, October 2001. Accessed November 12, 2007. (Related links.)
  • The Economist: Information asymmetry, Secrets and agents, [1]

information, asymmetry, contract, theory, economics, information, asymmetry, deals, with, study, decisions, transactions, where, party, more, better, information, than, other, diagram, illustrating, balance, power, with, perfect, information, buyers, sellers, . In contract theory and economics information asymmetry deals with the study of decisions in transactions where one party has more or better information than the other Diagram illustrating the balance of power with perfect information by buyers and sellers Information asymmetry creates an imbalance of power in transactions which can sometimes cause the transactions to be inefficient causing market failure in the worst case Examples of this problem are adverse selection 1 moral hazard 2 and monopolies of knowledge 3 A common way to visualise information asymmetry is with a scale with one side being the seller and the other the buyer When the seller has more or better information the transaction will more likely occur in the seller s favour the balance of power has shifted to the seller An example of this could be when a used car is sold the seller is likely to have a much better understanding of the car s condition and hence its market value than the buyer who can only estimate the market value based on the information provided by the seller and their own assessment of the vehicle 4 The balance of power can however also be in the hands of the buyer When buying health insurance the buyer is not always required to provide full details of future health risks By not providing this information to the insurance company the buyer will pay the same premium as someone much less likely to require a payout in the future 5 The adjacent image illustrates the balance of power between two agents when there is Perfect information Perfect information means that all parties have complete knowledge If the buyer has more information the power to manipulate the transaction will be represented by the scale leaning towards the buyer s side Information asymmetry extends to non economic behaviour Private firms have better information than regulators about the actions that they would take in the absence of regulation and the effectiveness of a regulation may be undermined 6 International relations theory has recognized that wars may be caused by asymmetric information 7 and that Most of the great wars of the modern era resulted from leaders miscalculating their prospects for victory 8 Jackson and Morelli wrote that there is asymmetric information between national leaders when there are differences in what they know i e believe about each other s armaments quality of military personnel and tactics determination geography political climate or even just about the relative probability of different outcomes or where they have incomplete information about the motivations of other agents 9 Information asymmetries are studied in the context of principal agent problems where they are a major cause of misinforming and is essential in every communication process 10 Information asymmetry is in contrast to perfect information which is a key assumption in neo classical economics 11 In 1996 a Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics was awarded to James A Mirrlees and William Vickrey for their fundamental contributions to the economic theory of incentives under asymmetric information 12 This led the Nobel Committee to acknowledge the importance of information problems in economics 13 They later awarded another Nobel Prize in 2001 to George Akerlof Michael Spence and Joseph E Stiglitz for their analyses of markets with asymmetric information 14 Contents 1 History 1 1 2001 Nobel Prize Inspirations 1 1 1 Akerlof 1 1 2 Spence 1 1 3 Stiglitz 1 2 Impact of 2001 Nobel Work 2 Models 2 1 Adverse Selection 2 2 Moral Hazard 2 3 Monopolies of Knowledge 3 Solutions 3 1 Signalling 3 2 Screening 3 3 Warranty 3 4 Mandatory information disclosure 3 5 Incentives and penalties 4 Information gathering 5 Sources 6 Market impact 7 Application in research 7 1 Accounting and finance 7 2 Effect of blogging 7 3 Game theory 7 4 Contract theory 7 5 Artificial intelligence 7 6 Management 7 7 Online Advertising 8 See also 9 Notes 10 References 11 External linksHistory editThe puzzle of information asymmetry has existed for as long as the market itself but remained largely unstudied until the post WWII period It is an umbrella term that can contain a vast diversity of topics Greek Stoics 2nd century BCE treated the advantage that sellers derive from privileged information in the story of the Merchant of Rhodes Accordingly a famine had broken out on the island of Rhodes and several grain merchants in Alexandria set sail to deliver supplies One of these merchants who arrives ahead of his competitors faces a choice should he let Rhodians know that grain supplies are on the way or keep this knowledge to himself Either decision will determine his profit margin Cicero related this dilemma in De Officiis and agreed with Greek Stoics that the merchant had a duty to disclose Thomas Aquinas overturned this consensus and considered price disclosure was not obligatory The three topics mentioned above drew on some important predecessors Joseph Stiglitz considered the work of earlier economists including Adam Smith John Stuart Mill and Max Weber He ultimately concludes that though these economists seemed to have an understanding of the problems of information they largely did not consider the implications of them and tended to minimize the impact they could have or consider them merely secondary issues 13 One exception to this is the work of economist Friedrich Hayek His work with prices as information conveying relative scarcity of goods can be noted as an early form of acknowledging information asymmetry but with a different name 13 2001 Nobel Prize Inspirations edit Information problems have always affected the lives of humans yet it was not studied with any seriousness until near the 1970s when three economists fleshed out models which revolutionized the way we think about information and its interaction with the market George Akerlof s paper The Market for Lemons 4 introduced a model to help explain a variety of market outcomes when quality is uncertain Akerlof s primary model considers the automobile market where the seller knows the exact quality of a car In contrast the buyer only knows the probability of whether a vehicle is good or bad a lemon Since the buyer pays the same price based on their expected quality for good cars and bad cars sellers with high quality cars may find the transaction unprofitable and leave resulting in a market with a higher proportion of bad cars The pathological path can continue as the buyer adjusts the expected quality and offers even lower prices further driving out cars with not so bad quality This results in a market failure purely driven by information asymmetry as under perfect information all cars can be sold according to their quality Akerlof extends the model to explain other phenomena Why raising the insurance price cannot facilitate seniors getting medical insurance Why may employers rationally refuse to hire minorities Through various applications Akerlof developed the importance of trust in markets and highlighted the cost of dishonesty in insurance markets credit markets and developing areas Around the same time an economist by the name of Michael Spence wrote on the topic of job market signaling and was introduced a work of the same name 15 The final topic is Stiglitz s work on the mechanism of screening 16 These three economists helped to further clarify a variety of economic puzzles at the time and would go on to win a Nobel Prize in 2001 for their contributions to the field Since then several economists have followed in their footsteps to solve more pieces of the puzzle Akerlof edit Akerlof drew heavily from the work of economist Kenneth Arrow Arrow who was awarded a Nobel Prize in Economics in 1972 studied uncertainty in the field of medical care among other things Arrow 1963 His work highlighted several factors which became important to Akerlof s studies First is the idea of moral hazard By being insured customers may be inclined to be less careful than they otherwise would without insurance because they know the costs will be covered Thus an incentive to be less careful and increase risk exists Second Arrow studied the business models of insurance companies and noted that higher risk individuals are pooled with lower risk individuals but both are covered at the same cost Third Arrow noted the role of trust in the relationship between doctor and patient Medical providers only get paid when a patient is sick and not when a person is healthy Because of this there is a great incentive for doctors to not provide the quality of care they could A patient must defer to the doctor and trust that the doctor is using their knowledge to their best advantage to provide the patient with the best care Thus a relationship of trust is established According to Arrow the doctor relies on the social obligation of trust to sell their services to the public even though the patients do not or cannot inspect the quality of a doctor s work Last he notes how this unique relationship demands that high levels of education and certification be attained by doctors in order to maintain the quality of medical service provided by doctors These four ideas from Arrow contributed largely to Akerlof s work Spence edit Spence cited no sources for his inspiration However he did acknowledge Kenneth Arrow and Thomas Schelling as helpful in discussing ideas during his pursuit of knowledge 15 He was the first to coin the term signaling 15 and encouraged other economists to follow in his footsteps because he believed he had introduced an important concept in economics Stiglitz edit Most of Stiglitz s academic inspirations were from his contemporaries Stiglitz primarily attributes his thinking to articles by Spence Akerlof and a few earlier works by him and his co author Michael Rothschild Rothschild and Stiglitz 1976 each discussing various aspects of screening and the role of education Stiglitz s work was a complement to the works of Spence and Akerlof and thus drew from some of the same inspirations from Arrow as Akerlof had The discussion of information asymmetry came to the forefront of economics in the 1970s when Akerlof introduced the idea of a market for lemons in a paper by the same name Akerlof 1970 In this paper Akerlof introduced a fundamental concept that certain sellers of used cars have more knowledge than the buyers and this can lead to what is known as adverse selection This idea may be one of the most important in the history and understanding of asymmetric information in economics 13 Spence introduced the idea of signaling shortly after the publication of Akerlof s work Stiglitz expanded upon the ideas of Spence and Akerlof by introducing an economic function of information asymmetry called screening Stiglitz s work in this area referred to the market for insurance which is rife with information asymmetry problems to be studied 16 Impact of 2001 Nobel Work edit These three economists simple yet revolutionary work birthed a movement in economics that changed how the field viewed the market forever No longer can perfect information be assumed in some problems as in most neoclassical models Information asymmetry began to grow in prevalence in academic literature 13 In 1996 a Nobel Prize was given to James Mirrlees and William Vickrey for their research back in the 1970s and 1970s on incentive problems when facing uncertainty under asymmetric information 17 The impact of such academic work can go unrecognized for decades Differing from the topics presented by Akerlof Spence and Stiglitz Mirrlees and Vickrey focused on how income taxation and auctions can be used as a mechanism to draw out information from market participants efficiently This award marked the importance of information asymmetry in economics It began a greater discussion on the topic that later led the Nobel committee to award three economists again in 2001 for significant contributions to the aforementioned topics 18 These economists continued after the 1970s to contribute to the field of economics and develop their theories and they have all had significant impacts Akerlof s work had more impact than just the market for used cars The pooling effect in the used car market also happens in the employment market for minorities One of the most notable impacts of Akerlof s work is its impact on Keynesian theory 13 Akerlof argues that the Keynesian theory of unemployment being voluntary implies that quits would rise with unemployment He argues against his critics by drawing upon reasoning based on psychology and sociology rather than pure economics He supplemented this with an argument that people do not always behave rationally but rather information asymmetry leads to only near rationality which causes people to deviate from optimal behavior regarding employment practices 19 Akerlof continues to champion behavioral economics that these breaches into the fields of psychology and sociology are profound extensions of information asymmetry 13 Stiglitz wrote that the trio s work has created a substantial wave in the field of economics He notes how he explored the economies of third world countries and they seemed to exhibit behavior consistent with their theories He noted how other economists have referred to gaining information as a transaction cost 20 Stiglitz also attempts to narrow down the sources of information asymmetries He ties it back to the nature of each individual having information that others do not Stiglitz also mentions how information asymmetry can be overcome He believes there are two crucial things to consider first the incentives and second the mechanisms for overcoming information asymmetry He argues that the incentives will always be there because markets are inherently informationally inefficient If there is an opportunity to profit from gaining knowledge people will do so If there is no profit to be had then people will not do so Spence s work on signaling moved on in the 1980s to spawn the field of study known as game theory 21 The idea of information asymmetry has also had a significant effect on management research It continues to offer additional improvements and opportunities as scholars continue their work 22 Models editInformation asymmetry models assume one party possesses some information that other parties have no access to Some asymmetric information models can also be used in situations where at least one party can enforce or effectively retaliate for breaches of certain parts of an agreement whereas the other s cannot Adverse Selection edit Main article adverse selection Akerlof suggested that information asymmetry leads to adverse selections 4 In adverse selection models the ignorant party lacks of has differing information while negotiating an agreed understanding of or contract to the transaction An example of adverse selection is when people who are high risk are more likely to buy insurance because the insurance company cannot effectively discriminate against them usually due to lack of information about the particular individual s risk but also sometimes by force of law or other constraints Credence Goods fits in the adverse selection model of information asymmetry These are goods where the buyer lacks the knowledge even after a product is consumed to disguise the product s quality or where the buyer is unaware of the quality needed 23 An example of this are complex medical treatments such as heart surgery Moral Hazard edit Main article Moral Hazard Moral hazard occurs when the ignorant party lacks information about the performance of the agreed upon transaction or lacks the ability to retaliate for a breach of the agreement This can result in a situation where a party is more likely to take risks because they are not fully responsible for the consequences of their actions An example of moral hazard is when people are more likely to behave recklessly after becoming insured either because the insurer cannot observe this behaviour or cannot effectively retaliate against it for example by failing to renew the insurance 2 Moral Hazard is not limited to individuals firms can act more recklessly if they know they will be bailed out For example banks will allow parties to take out risky loans if they know that the government will bail them out 24 Monopolies of Knowledge edit Main article monopolies of knowledge In the model of monopolies of knowledge the ignorant party has no right to access all the critical information about a situation for decision making Meaning one party has exclusive control over information This type of information asymmetry can be seen in government An example of monopolies of knowledge is that in some enterprises only high level management can fully access the corporate information provided by a third party At the same time lower level employees are required to make important decisions with only limited information provided to them 25 Solutions editCountermeasures have widely been discussed to reduce information asymmetry The classic paper on adverse selection is George Akerlof s The Market for Lemons from 1970 which brought informational issues to the forefront of economic theory Exploring signaling and screening the paper discusses two primary solutions to this problem 26 A similar concept is moral hazard which differs from adverse selection at the timing level While adverse selection affects parties before the interaction moral hazard affects parties after the interaction Regulatory instruments such as mandatory information disclosure can also reduce information asymmetry 27 Warranties can further help mitigate the effect of asymmetric information 28 Signalling edit Main article Signalling economics Michael Spence originally proposed the idea of signalling 15 He suggested that in a situation with information asymmetry it is possible for people to signal their type thus believably transferring information to the other party and resolving the asymmetry This idea was initially studied in the context of matching in the job market An employer is interested in hiring a new employee who is skilled in learning Of course all prospective employees will claim to be skilled in learning but only they know if they really are This is an information asymmetry Spence proposes for example that going to college can function as a credible signal of an ability to learn Assuming that people who are skilled in learning can finish college more easily than people who are unskilled then by finishing college the skilled people signal their skills to prospective employers No matter how much or how little they may have learned in college or what they studied finishing functions as a signal of their capacity for learning However finishing college may merely function as a signal of their ability to pay for college it may signal the willingness of individuals to adhere to orthodox views or it may signal a willingness to comply with authority Signalling theory can be used in e commerce research Information asymmetry in e commerce comes from information distortion that leads to the buyer s misunderstanding of the seller s true characteristics before the contract Mavlanova Benbunan Fich and Koufaris 2012 noticed that signalling theory explains the relation between signals and qualities illustrating why some signals are trustworthy and others are not In e commerce signals deliver information about the characteristics of the seller For instance high quality sellers are able to show their identity to buyers by using signs and logos and then buyers check these signals to evaluate the credibility and validity of a seller s qualities The study of Mavlanova Benbunan Fich and Koufaris 2012 also confirmed that signal usage is different between low quality and high quality online sellers Low quality sellers are more likely to avoid using expensive easy to verify signals and tend to use fewer signals than high quality sellers Thus signals help reduce information asymmetry 29 Screening edit Main article Screening economics Joseph E Stiglitz pioneered the theory of screening In this way the under informed party can induce the other party to reveal their information They can provide a menu of choices in such a way that the choice depends on the private information of the other party The side of asymmetry can occur on either buyer or seller For example sellers with better information than buyers include used car salespeople mortgage brokers and loan originators stockbrokers and real estate agents Alternatively situations where the buyer usually has better information than the seller include estate sales as specified in a last will and testament life insurance or sales of old art pieces without a prior professional assessment of their value This situation was first described by Kenneth J Arrow in an article on health care in 1963 5 George Akerlof in The Market for Lemons notices that in such a market the average value of the commodity tends to go down even for those of perfectly good quality Because of information asymmetry unscrupulous sellers can sell forgeries like replica goods such as watches and defraud the buyer Meanwhile buyers usually do not have enough information to distinguish lemons from quality goods As a result many people not willing to risk getting ripped off will avoid certain types of purchases or will not spend as much for a given item Akerlof demonstrates that it is even possible for the market to decay to the point of nonexistence nbsp As lower risk participants leave the pool expected costs of the pool increase which causes premiums to increaseAn example of adverse selection and information asymmetry causing market failure is the market for health insurance Policies usually group subscribers together where people can leave but no one can join after it is set As health conditions are realized over time information involving health costs will arise and low risk policyholders will realize the mismatch in the premiums and health conditions Due to this healthy policyholders are incentivized to leave and reapply to get a cheaper policy that matches their expected health costs which causes the premiums to increase As high risk policyholders are more dependent on insurance they are stuck with higher premium costs as the group size reduces which causes premiums to increase even further This cycle repeats until the high risk policy holders also find similar health policies with cheaper premiums in which the initial group disappears This concept is known as the death spiral and has been researched as early as 1988 30 Akerlof also suggests different methods with which information asymmetry can be reduced One of those instruments that can be used to reduce the information asymmetry between market participants is intermediary market institutions called counteracting institutions for instance guarantees for goods By providing a guarantee the buyer in the transaction can use extra time to obtain the same amount of information about the good as the seller before the buyer takes on the complete risk of the good being a lemon Other market mechanisms that help reduce the imbalance in information include brand names chains and franchising that guarantee the buyer a threshold quality level These mechanisms also let owners of high quality products get the full value of the goods These counteracting institutions then keep the market size from reducing to zero Warranty edit Warranties are utilised as a method of verifying the credibility of a product and are a guarantee issued by the seller promising to replace or repair the good should the quality not be sufficient Product warranties are often requested from buying parties or financial lenders and have been used as a form of mediation dating back to the Babylonian era 31 Warranties can come in the form of insurance and can also come at the expense of the buyer The implementation of lemon laws has eradicated the effect of information asymmetry upon customers who have received a faulty item Essentially this involves the customers returning a defective product regardless of circumstances within a certain time period 32 Mandatory information disclosure edit Both signaling and screening resemble voluntary information disclosure where the party having more information for their own best interest use various measures to inform the other party However voluntary information disclosure is not always feasible Regulators can thus take active measures to facilitate the spread of information For example the Securities and Exchange Commission SEC initiated Regulation Fair Disclosure RFD so that companies must faithfully disclose material information to investors The policy has reduced information asymmetry reflected in the lower trading costs 33 Incentives and penalties edit For firms to reduce moral hazard they can implement penalties for bad behaviour and incentives to align objectives 34 An example of building in an incentive is insurance companies not insuring customers for the total value this provides an incentive to be less reckless as the customer will suffer financial liability as well Information gathering editMost models in traditional contract theory assume that asymmetric information is exogenously given 35 36 Yet some authors have also studied contract theoretic models in which asymmetric information arises endogenously because agents decide whether or not to gather information Specifically Cremer and Khalil 1992 and Cremer Khalil and Rochet 1998a study an agent s incentives to acquire private information after a principal has offered a contract 37 38 In a laboratory experiment Hoppe and Schmitz 2013 have provided empirical support for the theory 39 Several further models have been developed which study variants of this setup For instance when the agent has not gathered information at the outset does it make a difference whether or not he learns the information later on before production starts 40 What happens if the information can be gathered already before a contract is offered 41 What happens if the principal observes the agent s decision to acquire information 42 Finally the theory has been applied in several contexts such as public private partnerships and vertical integration 43 44 Sources editInformation asymmetry within societies can be created and maintained in several ways Firstly media outlets due to their ownership structure or political influences may fail to disseminate certain viewpoints or choose to engage in propaganda campaigns Furthermore an educational system relying on substantial tuition fees can generate information imbalances between the poor and the affluent Imbalances can also be fortified by specific organizational and legal measures such as document classification procedures or non disclosure clauses Exclusive information networks that are operational around the world further contribute to the asymmetry Copyright laws increase information imbalances between the poor and the affluent Lastly mass surveillance helps the political and industrial leaders to amass large volumes of information which is typically not shared with the rest of society 45 Market impact editZavolokina Schlegel and Schwabe 2020 state that Information asymmetry makes buyers and sellers distrust each other which leads to opportunistic behaviour and may even lead to complete break down of the market 46 At the same time lower quality provision in markets is also one of the consequences as sellers do not get benefits enough to cover their production costs of providing higher quality products Countermeasures Abito Jose Miguel amp Salant Yuval proposed that warranty enhancing consumer welfare highlights the relevance of policies that directly guide consumer decisions and increases buyers trust in high quality buyers 47 Establish a real time information announce platform according to the collect information to achieve market transparency eliminate trading concerns thereby Enhance customer experience by third party quality checks like providing expert reviews Consumer protection law ensure that product quality meets expectations and that contract terms are fair Ensure quality in the form of standards and certificates and prove that all technical parameters have been tested Application in research editAccounting and finance edit A substantial portion of research in the field of accounting can be framed in terms of information asymmetry since accounting involves the transmission of an enterprise s information from those who have it to those who need it for decision making Bartov and Bodnar 1996 mentioned that the different accounting methods used by enterprises can lead to information asymmetry 48 For instance aggressively recognising revenue can result in preparers of financial statements having a much better understanding of the levels of future revenue then those reading the statements Likewise in finance literature the acknowledgment of information asymmetry between organizations challenged the Modigliani Miller theorem which states that the valuation of a firm is unaffected by its financial structure It challenges the theorem as one of the key assumptions is that investors would have the same information as a corporation If there is not symmetry in information corporations can leverage their capital structure to get the most out of their valuation Information asymmetry shed light on the importance of aligning interests of managers with those of stakeholders As managers with significant power from information may make decision based on their own interest as opposed to the companies When the level of information asymmetry and associated monitoring cost is high firms tend to rely less on board monitoring and more on incentive alignment 49 Various measures are used to align interest of managers to stop them from abusing their power from information asymmetry such as compensating based on performance using a bonus structure This field of study is referred to as agency theory Furthermore financial economists apply information asymmetry in studies of differentially informed financial market participants insiders stock analysts investors etc or in the cost of finance for MFIs 50 Effect of blogging edit The effect of blogging as a source of information asymmetry as well as a tool reduce asymmetric information has also been well studied Blogging on financial websites provides bottom up communication among investors analysts journalists and academics as financial blogs help prevent people in charge from withholding financial information from their company and the general public 51 Compared to traditional forms of media such as newspapers and magazines blogging provides an easy to access venue for information A 2013 study by Gregory Saxton and Ashley Anker concluded that more participation on blogging sites from credible individuals reduces information asymmetry between corporate insiders additionally reducing the risk of insider trading 52 nbsp A game of imperfect information with sub games Here each player will have no information of each other s move while making decisions This representation is of one person s decisions in a game however it does not correspond to the actual timing of the player s decisions The dashed line between nodes represent information asymmetry and show that during the game a party cannot distinguish between the nodes Game theory edit Game theory can be used to analyse asymmetric information 53 A large amount of the foundational ideas in game theory builds on the framework of information asymmetry In simultaneous games each player has no prior knowledge of an opponent s move In sequential games players may observe all or part of the opponent s moves One example of information asymmetry is one player can observe the opponent s past activities while the other player cannot Therefore the existence and level of information asymmetry in a game determines the dynamics of the game James Fearon in his study of the explanations for war in a game theoretic context notices that war could be a consequence of information asymmetry two countries will not reach a non violent settlement because they have incentives to distort the amount of military resources they possess 54 Contract theory edit Contract theory provides insights into how various economic agents can enter contractual arrangements in situation of unequal levels of information The development of contract theory is based on assuming its parties possess different levels of information on the contract s subject For instance in a road construction contract a civil engineer may have more information on the various inputs required to undertake the project than the other parties Through contract theory economic agents gain insights on how they can exploit information available to them to enter beneficial contractual arrangements The impact information asymmetry causes among parties with competing interests such as games has contributed to game theory In no game do its players have complete information about each other most importantly no player knows the strategy the others intends to use to realize a win This information asymmetry together with the competing interests have resulted in the development of game theory which seeks to provides insights as to how parties caught up in a situation where they are required to compete under a set of rules can maximize their expected outcomes Information asymmetry occurs in situations where some parties have more information regarding an issue than others It is considered a major cause of market failure 55 The contribution of information asymmetry to market failure arises from the fact that it impairs with the free hand which is expected to guide how modern markets work For example the stock market forms a major avenue through which publicly traded entities can raise their capital The operation of stock markets across the world is carried in a way that ensures current and potential investors have the same level of information about the stocks or any other securities that may be listed in that market That level of information symmetry helps to ensure similar conditions to all parties in the market which in turn helps to ensure the securities listed in those markets trade at fair value 55 However cases of information sometimes arise when certain parties obtain information that is not in the public domain This can create market return abnormalities such as an abrupt surge or decline in a security Artificial intelligence edit Tshilidzi Marwala and Evan Hurwitz in their study of the relationship between information asymmetry and artificial intelligence observed that there is a reduced level of information asymmetry between two artificial intelligent agents than between two human agents As a consequence when these artificial intelligent agents engage in financial markets it reduces arbitrage opportunities making markets more efficient The study also revealed that as the number of artificial intelligent agents in the market increase the volume of trades in the market will decrease 56 57 This is primarily because information asymmetry of the perceptions of value of goods and services is the basis of trade Management edit Information asymmetry has been applied in a variety of ways in management research ranging from conceptualizations of information asymmetry to building resolutions to reduce it 22 Studies have shown that information asymmetry can be a source of competitive advantage for the firms 58 A 2013 study by Schmidt and Keil has revealed that the presence of private information asymmetry within firms influences normal business activities Firms that have a more concrete understanding of their resources can use this information to gauge their advantage over competitors 59 In Ozeml Reuer and Gulati s 2013 study they found that different information was an additional source of information asymmetry in venture capitalist and alliance networks when different team members bring diverse specialized knowledge values and outlooks towards a common strategic decision the lack of homogeneous information distribution among the members leads to inefficient decision making 60 Firms have the ability to apply strategies that exploit their informational gap One way they can do this is through impression management which involves undertaking actions and releasing information to influence stakeholders and analysts opinions positively exploiting information asymmetry as external parties heavily rely on the information released by firms 61 A second way that firms exploit information asymmetry is through decoupling This describes the discrepancy between formal procedures and failure to implement them 62 An example of this is executives announcing a stock repurchase plan without any intention of carrying it out allowing them to raise new cash flow for their own benefit at the expense of shareholders 22 Management research goes on to explain that agents can perpetuate information asymmetry through information concealment This involves firms not sharing information to exploit the informational advantage over rivals In resource based theory it shows firms concealing information about their competitive advantage in order to build causal ambiguity to protect their firm from imitation 63 22 Information asymmetry problems can be addressed by management through several approaches First is the usage of incentives to encourage the disclosure and sharing information An example of this is partnering specifically with companies that disclose relatively more information Second is through precommitment where actions are undertaken at present to ensure future commitments Third is the usage of an information intermediary in which an intermediary is used to gather and relay information between two parties A common example of this are financial analysts that gather information from the financial statements of a company and uses it to create reports and advice for potential investors and clients Fourth is the usage of monitoring and reward Monitoring allows management to confirm information that was previously uncertain such as performance and behaviour Monitoring can also be used alongside other incentives such as rewarding for performance 22 Online Advertising edit Online advertising is a dominant form of advertising and a potential source of information asymmetry Online advertising consists of utilities a good being encoded into a message received by a customer who decodes the message making a purchasing decision 64 Firms messages are tailored to specific goals and intentions and can be a source of information asymmetry due to interpretation or intent The nature of the internet and prevalence of social media in society has given firms opportunities to create promotional content in a less passive way than other forms of advertising Noise represents any techniques that are used with the intent of obstructing altering or blocking the interpretation of the message by the receiver 65 This can increase the amount of information asymmetry in a transaction as the buyer may not understand the product to its fullest extent even if they believe to fully understand the message being sent to them Firms communicate to the virtual marketplace through online advertising and as such the feedback of consumers feeling manipulated or feeling the presence of information asymmetry may be indicative of the lack of transparency by a firm Highly advertised and strongly promoted items are generally more likely to be bought by customers even if the product is inferior to less advertised competition introducing adverse selection The power of the internet also changes how consumers deal with information asymmetry as they have the means to find vast amounts of information about products with relatively little effort While a consumer can use this power to assist their research to find a product that is not being marketed maliciously this decision is made due to information asymmetry not due to the customer being perfectly rational 64 Some consumers are aware of the usage of strategies and techniques by firms to advertise and influence their media consumption however do not necessarily alter their trust in the source of the information accordingly 66 Online advertising that appears trustworthy but can be malicious in intent can still be trusted by consumers despite the information asymmetry even if consumers themselves identify as critical of the medium Social media personalities much like other celebrities also have influence over consumers who would otherwise consider themselves dissuaded by the advertising providing firms another method of aggressive advertising with potential information asymmetry 66 See also editArtificial scarcity Asymmetric competition Bounded rationality Caveat emptor Inequality of bargaining power Natural borrowing limit Perfect information Real prices and ideal pricesNotes edit Charles Wilson 2008 adverse selection The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract a b Dembe Allard E and Boden Leslie I 2000 Moral Hazard A Question of Morality New Solutions 2000 10 3 257 79 John O Ledyard 2008 market failure The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Ed Abstract a b c Akerlof George A 1970 08 01 The Market for Lemons Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism The Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 3 488 500 doi 10 2307 1879431 ISSN 0033 5533 JSTOR 1879431 S2CID 6738765 a b Arrow Kenneth J 1963 Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care American Economic Review American Economic Association 53 5 941 973 JSTOR 1812044 Fullerton Don Wolfram Catherine 13 May 2010 The Design and Implementation of U S Climate Policy PDF Chicago Illinois University of Chicago Press p 11 ISBN 9780226269146 Retrieved 9 March 2019 Jackson amp Morelli 2011 pp 35 40 43 Ikenberry 1999 p 128 Jackson amp Morelli 2011 pp 40 42 Christozov D Chukova S Mateev P Chapter 11 Informing Processes Risks Evaluation of the Risk of Misinforming in Foundations of Informing Science ISI 2009 pp 323 356 The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2001 NobelPrize org Retrieved 2020 03 07 The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1996 NobelPrize org Retrieved 2020 11 19 a b c d e f g Rosser J Barkley Jr 2003 01 01 A Nobel Prize for Asymmetric Information The economic contributions of George Akerlof Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz Review of Political Economy 15 1 3 21 doi 10 1080 09538250308445 ISSN 0953 8259 S2CID 154549764 The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2001 Information for the Public press release from the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences Nobel Foundation nobelprize org October 2001 accessed November 12 2007 a b c d Spence Michael August 1973 Job Market Signaling The Quarterly Journal of Economics 87 3 355 374 doi 10 2307 1882010 ISSN 0033 5533 JSTOR 1882010 a b Rothschild Michael and Stiglitz Joseph 1976 Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information The Quarterly Journal of Economics 90 no 4 629 Sandmar Agmo 1999 Asymmetric Information and Public Economics The Mirrlees Vickrey Nobel Prize The Journal of Economic Perspectives 13 no 1 165 Lofgren Karl Gustaf Torsten Persson and Jorgen W Weibull 2002 Markets with Asymmetric Information The Contributions of George Akerlof Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 104 no 2 195 211 Akerlof George A Yellen Janet L 1985 01 01 A Near Rational Model of the Business Cycle with Wage and Price Inertia The Quarterly Journal of Economics 100 Supplement 823 838 doi 10 1093 qje 100 Supplement 823 ISSN 0033 5533 Stigler George J 1961 06 01 The Economics of Information Journal of Political Economy 69 3 213 225 doi 10 1086 258464 ISSN 0022 3808 S2CID 222441709 Riley John G June 2001 Silver Signals Twenty Five Years of Screening and Signaling Journal of Economic Literature 39 2 432 478 doi 10 1257 jel 39 2 432 ISSN 0022 0515 a b c d e Bergh Donald D Ketchen David J Orlandi Ilaria Heugens Pursey P M A R Boyd Brian K 2018 09 21 Information Asymmetry in Management Research Past Accomplishments and Future Opportunities Journal of Management 45 1 122 158 doi 10 1177 0149206318798026 ISSN 0149 2063 S2CID 150012600 Dranove David 2011 01 01 Pauly Mark V Mcguire Thomas G Barros Pedro P eds Chapter Ten Health Care Markets Regulators and Certifiers Handbook of Health Economics vol 2 Elsevier pp 639 690 doi 10 1016 B978 0 444 53592 4 00010 4 retrieved 2022 05 03 Cordella T amp Yeyati E L 2003 Bank bailouts moral hazard vs value effect Journal of Financial intermediation 12 4 300 330 Innis Harold 1951 The Bias of Communication Toronto University of Toronto Press pp 179 180 Johannes Horne 2008 signalling and screening The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract Zhu Xufeng Zhang Chao 2012 Reducing information asymmetry in the power industry Mandatory and voluntary information disclosure regulations of sulphur dioxide emission Energy Policy 45 704 713 doi 10 1016 j enpol 2012 03 024 Ross Sean How can the problem of asymmetric information be overcome Investopedia Retrieved 2021 04 26 Mavlanova Tamilla Benbunan Fich Raquel Koufaris Marios 2012 07 01 Signaling theory and information asymmetry in online commerce Information amp Management 49 5 240 247 doi 10 1016 j im 2012 05 004 ISSN 0378 7206 Cutler David M Zeckhauser Richard J 1998 Adverse Selection in Health Insurance PDF Forum for Health Economics amp Policy 1 1 doi 10 2202 1558 9544 1056 Loomba Arvinder P S June 1998 Evolution of product warranty a chronological study Journal of Management History Archive 4 2 124 136 doi 10 1108 13552529810219601 ISSN 1355 252X Ross Sean How can the problem of asymmetric information be overcome Investopedia Retrieved 2021 04 26 Eleswarapu Venkat R Thompson Rex Venkataraman Kumar 2012 The Impact of Regulation Fair Disclosure Trading Costs and Information Asymmetry The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 39 2 209 225 doi 10 1017 S0022109000003045 JSTOR 30031853 S2CID 54649344 Eisenhardt K M 1989 Agency theory An assessment and review Academy of Management Review 14 57 74 Baron David P Myerson Roger B 1982 Regulating a Monopolist with Unknown Costs Econometrica 50 4 911 930 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 407 6185 doi 10 2307 1912769 JSTOR 1912769 Maskin Eric Riley John 1984 Monopoly with Incomplete Information The RAND Journal of Economics 15 2 171 doi 10 2307 2555674 ISSN 0741 6261 JSTOR 2555674 Cremer Jacques Khalil Fahad 1992 Gathering Information before Signing a Contract American Economic Review 82 3 566 578 Cremer Jacques Khalil Fahad Rochet Jean Charles 1998a Contracts and Productive Information Gathering Games and Economic Behavior 25 2 174 193 doi 10 1006 game 1998 0651 ISSN 0899 8256 Hoppe Eva I Schmitz Patrick W 2013 Contracting under Incomplete Information and Social Preferences An Experimental Study Review of Economic Studies 80 4 1516 1544 doi 10 1093 restud rdt010 Hoppe Eva I Schmitz Patrick W 2010 The costs and benefits of additional information in agency models with endogenous information structures Economics Letters 107 1 58 62 doi 10 1016 j econlet 2009 12 026 ISSN 0165 1765 Cremer Jacques Khalil Fahad Rochet Jean Charles 1998b Strategic Information Gathering before a Contract Is Offered Journal of Economic Theory 81 1 163 200 doi 10 1006 jeth 1998 2415 ISSN 0022 0531 Hoppe Eva I 2013 Observability of information acquisition in agency models Economics Letters 119 1 104 107 doi 10 1016 j econlet 2013 01 015 ISSN 0165 1765 Hoppe Eva I Schmitz Patrick W 2013 Public private partnerships versus traditional procurement Innovation incentives and information gathering PDF The RAND Journal of Economics 44 1 56 74 doi 10 1111 1756 2171 12010 ISSN 0741 6261 Khalil Fahad Kim Doyoung Shin Dongsoo 2006 Optimal Task Design To Integrate or Separate Planning and Implementation Journal of Economics amp Management Strategy 15 2 457 478 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 186 157 doi 10 1111 j 1530 9134 2006 00107 x ISSN 1058 6407 S2CID 154686412 The tools used to create information asymmetries are described in the following article http ssrn com abstract 2383166 Zavolokina Liudmila Schlegel Manuel Schwabe Gerhard 2020 02 18 How can we reduce information asymmetries and enhance trust in The Market for Lemons Information Systems and E Business Management 19 3 883 908 doi 10 1007 s10257 020 00466 4 ISSN 1617 9846 S2CID 213260199 Abito Jose Miguel Salant Yuval 2018 09 04 The Effect of Product Misperception on Economic Outcomes Evidence from the Extended Warranty Market The Review of Economic Studies 86 6 2285 2318 doi 10 1093 restud rdy045 ISSN 0034 6527 Bartov Eli Bodnar Gordon M 1996 Alternative Accounting Methods Information Asymmetry and Liquidity Theory and Evidence The Accounting Review 71 3 397 418 ISSN 0001 4826 JSTOR 248295 Cai Jie Qian Yiming Yu Miaomiao 2015 Information asymmetry and corporate governance The Quarterly Journal of Finance 05 3 doi 10 1142 S2010139215500147 Garmaise M amp G Natividad 2010 Information the Cost of Credit and Operational Efficiency An Empirical Study of Microfinance Review of Financial Studies 23 6 2560 2590 doi 10 1093 rfs hhq021 Saxton Gregory D 3 August 2008 Financial blogs and information asymmetry between firm insiders and outsiders Annual Meeting of the American Accounting Association Saxton G D and A E Anker 2013 The Aggregate Effects of Decentralized Knowledge Production Financial Bloggers and Information Asymmetries in the Stock Market Journal of Communication 63 6 1054 1069 Wilkinson Nick 2005 05 05 Managerial Economics A Problem Solving Approach 1 ed Cambridge University Press doi 10 1017 cbo9780511810534 015 ISBN 978 0 521 81993 0 Fearon James D 1995 Rationalist Explanations for War International Organization 49 3 379 414 doi 10 1017 S0020818300033324 ISSN 0020 8183 JSTOR 2706903 S2CID 38573183 a b Lambert R Leuz C amp Verrecchia 2012 Information Asymmetry Information Precision and the Cost of Capital Review of Finance 16 1 pp 1 29 Marwala Tshilidzi Hurwitz Evan 2017 Artificial Intelligence and Economic Theory Skynet in the Market London Springer ISBN 978 3 319 66104 9 Artificial Intelligence can Reduce Information Asymmetry Networks Course blog for INFO 2040 CS 2850 Econ 2040 SOC 2090 Retrieved 2020 03 01 Makadok Richard September 2011 Barney Jay B Ketchen David J Wright Mike eds Invited Editorial The Four Theories of Profit and Their Joint Effects Journal of Management 37 5 1316 1334 doi 10 1177 0149206310385697 ISSN 0149 2063 S2CID 144052666 Schmidt Jens Keil Thomas 2013 04 01 What Makes a Resource Valuable Identifying the Drivers of Firm Idiosyncratic Resource Value Academy of Management Review 38 2 206 228 doi 10 5465 amr 2010 0404 ISSN 0363 7425 Ozmel Umit Reuer Jeffrey J Gulati Ranjay 2012 07 24 Signals across Multiple Networks How Venture Capital and Alliance Networks Affect Interorganizational Collaboration Academy of Management Journal 56 3 852 866 doi 10 5465 amj 2009 0549 ISSN 0001 4273 Dutton J E Ashford S J O neill R M Hayes E amp Wierba E E 1997 Reading the wind How middle managers assess the context for selling issues to top managers Strategic management journal 18 5 407 423 Westphal J D amp Zajac E J 2001 Decoupling policy from practice The case of stock repurchase programs Administrative science quarterly 46 2 202 228 Brush T H amp Artz K W 1999 Toward a contingent resource based theory the impact of information asymmetry on the value of capabilities in veterinary medicine Strategic Management Journal 20 3 223 250 a b Wiktor Jan W Sanak Kosmowska Katarzyna 2021 09 30 Information Asymmetry in Online Advertising London Routledge pp 45 47 doi 10 4324 9781003134121 ISBN 978 1 003 13412 1 S2CID 238682686 McQuail Denis 2005 Mass communication theory Sage ISBN 1 4129 0372 6 OCLC 1151855593 a b Sanak Kosmowska Katarzyna Wiktor Jan W 17 October 2020 Empirical Identification of Latent Classes in the Assessment of Information Asymmetry and Manipulation in Online Advertising Sustainability 12 20 8693 doi 10 3390 su12208693 ISSN 2071 1050 References editAboody David Lev Baruch 2000 Information Asymmetry R amp D and Insider Gains Journal of Finance 55 6 2747 2766 doi 10 1111 0022 1082 00305 Akerlof George A 1970 The Market for Lemons Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 3 488 500 doi 10 2307 1879431 JSTOR 1879431 S2CID 6738765 Bartov Eli Bodnar Gordon M 1996 Alternative Accounting Methods Information Asymmetry and Liquidity Theory and Evidence The Accounting Review 71 3 397 418 JSTOR 248295 via JSTOR Brown Stephen Hillegeist Stephen Lo Kin 2004 Conference calls and information asymmetry Journal of Accounting and Economics 37 3 343 366 doi 10 1016 j jacceco 2004 02 001 Hayes Beth 1984 Unions and Strikes with Asymmetric Information PDF Journal of Labor Economics University of Chicago Press Society of Labor Economists NORC at the University of Chicago 2 1 57 83 doi 10 1086 298023 hdl 10419 220907 JSTOR 2535017 S2CID 154864920 Ikenberry G John 1999 Causes of War Power and the Roots of International Conflict by Stephen Van Evers Foreign Affairs 78 4 128 9 doi 10 2307 20049381 JSTOR 20049381 Izquierdo Segismundo S Izquierdo Luis R 2007 The impact of quality uncertainty without asymmetric information on market efficiency Journal of Business Research 60 8 858 867 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 412 9956 doi 10 1016 j jbusres 2007 02 010 ISSN 0148 2963 Jackson Matthew O Morelli Massimo 2011 The Reasons for Wars an Updated Survey In Coyne Chris J Mathers Rachel L eds The Handbook on the Political Economy of War Edward Elgar Publishing pp 34 57 ISBN 978 1849808323 Koehler Benedikt 2020 Thomas Aquinas on the conduct of sales Economic Affairs 40 3 358 366 doi 10 1111 ecaf 12436 S2CID 229017093 Mas Colell Andreu Whinston Michael D Green Jerry R 1995 Microeconomic Theory New York Oxford University Press ISBN 978 0 19 507340 9 Chaps 13 and 14 discuss applications of adverse selection and moral hazard models to contract theory Mavlanova Tamilla Benbunan Fich Raquel Koufaris Marios 2012 Signaling theory and information asymmetry in online commerce Information amp Management 49 5 240 247 doi 10 1016 j im 2012 05 004 via Elsevier Saxton Gregory Anker Ashley 2013 The Aggregate Effects of Decentralized Knowledge Production Financial Bloggers and Information Asymmetries in the Stock Market Journal of Communication Wiley Subscription Services Inc 63 6 1054 1069 doi 10 1111 jcom 12060 S2CID 154672974 Spence Michael 1973 Job Market Signaling Quarterly Journal of Economics The MIT Press 87 3 355 374 doi 10 2307 1882010 JSTOR 1882010 Stigler George J 1961 The Economics of Information Journal of Political Economy University of Chicago Press 69 3 213 225 doi 10 1086 258464 JSTOR 1829263 S2CID 222441709 External links edit nbsp Wikimedia Commons has media related to Asymmetric information The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2001 Official Prize announcement by the Nobel Foundation nobelprize org October 2001 Accessed November 12 2007 Related links The Economist Information asymmetry Secrets and agents 1 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Information asymmetry amp oldid 1189387819, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.