fbpx
Wikipedia

Incentive

In general, incentives are anything that persuade a person to alter their behavior in the desired manner.[1] It is emphasized that incentives matter by the basic law of economists and the laws of behavior, which state that higher incentives amount to greater levels of effort and therefore higher levels of performance.[2]

Protest sign displaying "Stop Climate Change" at climate strike in Melbourne, Australia. Climate movements may incentivize governments and industry to take collective action in the fight against climate change.

Divisions edit

An incentive is a powerful tool to influence certain desired behaviors or action often adopted by governments and businesses.[3] Incentives can be broadly broken down into two categories: intrinsic incentives and extrinsic incentives.[4] Overall, both types of incentives can be powerful tools often employ to increase effort and higher performance according to the "law of behavior."

Incentives are most studied in the area of personnel economics where economic analysts, such as those who take part in human resources management practices, focus on how firms make employees more motivated, through pay and career concerns, compensation and performance evaluation, to motivate employees and best achieve the firms' desired performance outcomes.[5]

Intrinsic and extrinsic incentive edit

An intrinsic incentive is when a person is motivated to act in a certain way for their own personal satisfaction without seeking any external reward, nor facing any external pressure to perform the task.[6] For instance, a singer who enjoys singing may be intrinsically motivated to spend several hours a day to improve their performance without receiving any recognition or awards from others.[7] Often, intrinsic incentives are useful in increasing one's empowerment, utility level, and autonomy and can reinforce employees’ work involvement and commitment.[8]

Intrinsic incentives and extrinsic incentives are both important in driving people's behavior. Experts believe that intrinsic incentives are stronger motivators compared to extrinsic incentives as they increase employees’ work engagement and genuine enjoyment of work.[9] However, people's intrinsic motivation tends to decrease when they are offered too many extrinsic rewards. In order to maintain the action, constant incentives have to be provided. This is known as the Overjustification Effect.

While both types of incentive are a fundamental concept in economics that play a crucial role in motivating behavior, the extent to which and how they influence individual may depend on varies factors. Factors to consider may include the type of activity being incentivized, the individual's personal values and goals, and the context in which the incentive is offered. A well-designed incentive system should take into account to avoid unintended consequences and ensure that they align with the desired outcomes.

There are some parties who oppose the benefits of using extrinsic incentives and believe that they cause more harm than good. These opponents believe that the constant use of extrinsic incentives can lead to the crowding out of intrinsic incentives, which are also valuable performance motivators.[2] When people are constantly being incentivized by external pressures, they neglect their intrinsic motives which could consequently be detrimental to their work ethic.[10] Employees can become too comfortable with consistently gaining some reward for acting in a manner which is consistent with the interests of the firm. As a result, employees begin to believe that they deserve to earn rewards for doing certain things, not for the benefit of the firm but rather for their own benefit, which leads to them shirking if no extrinsic incentive is offered in return for high effort.[10]

Nonetheless, incentives (both intrinsic and extrinsic) can be beneficial in altering a person's behavior and can be effectively used and executed within many different areas of life including in the workforce, in education and within one's personal life.[1]

Classification edit

Classified by David Callahan, the types of incentives can be further broken down into three broad classes according to the different ways in which they motivate agents to take a particular course of actions:[11][12]

Class Definition
Remunerative incentives (or financial incentives) Exist where an agent can expect some form of a material reward like money in exchange for acting in a particular way.[12]
Moral incentives Exist where a particular choice is widely regarded as the right thing to do or is particularly admirable among others.[12] An agent acting on a moral incentive can expect a sense of positive self-esteem, and praise or admiration from their community. However, an agent acting against a moral incentive can expect a sense of guilt, condemnation or even ostracism from the community.[12]
Coercive incentives Exist where an agent can expect that the failure to act in a specific way will result in physical force being used against them by others – for example, by inflicting pain, or by imprisonment, or by confiscating or destroying their possessions.[12]

Monetary incentives edit

Monetary incentives are any form of financial good given to someone to incentivize their actions and align their incentives with those of the principal who provides the monetary incentive.[13] This is a type of extrinsic incentive and is commonly seen in the workplace. The effect of monetary incentive can be broken down into two categories: the "standard direct price effect," and "indirect psychological effect". These two types of monetary effect often work in opposite direction and crowd out incentivised behaviour.[14] However, several studies have suggested that it is possible to manage the crowding-out effects by utilising a principal-agent model that incorporates nonstandard assumptions.[14] For instance, a monetary incentive may come in the forms of profit sharing, bonuses, stock options or even paid vacation time. As such, a well-chosen monetary incentive programs can produce positive motivation and influence the productivity and output of individuals and firms.[15]

A common monetary incentive system used by firms is performance-based pay where incentives are paid based on employees' productivity or output over a particular period of time. Some methods are commission-based where the employee, for example a salesperson, receives a payment directly correlated to their output level. Firms also pay additional wages or rewards for employees who work overtime and for their additional work above firm expectations. Expectancy theory implies that, provided employees place sufficient value on the monetary incentive to justify their extra effort and perceive that greater effort will result in better performance, such incentives can motivate employees to maintain high levels of effort and discourage shirking. This in turn increases the individual productivity of workers and the overall productivity of the firm.[13]

Other monetary incentives are less direct, such as awarding periodic, discretionary bonuses to top performers, offering the possibility of a promotion to a higher-paying position or profit sharing for team projects.[16] Alternatively, firms can also incentivize their employees to perform by threatening to demote or terminate them for poor performance.[16] When employees feel that their careers are in jeopardy, they are more likely to increase their efforts.

Monetary incentives do affect the effort and average performance of employees but are likely dependent on the scope of the job and the task variables. For routine jobs such as clerical and administration jobs that are mundane, the presence of monetary incentives will encourage employees to demonstrate consistent effort of diligence when the intrinsic incentive has been exhausted. On the other hand, if the task assigned is too challenging, monetary incentives make little to no difference in increasing an employee's contribution to work.[17]

The effect of monetary incentives can depend on the framing of the rewards. For example, in cadaveric organ donation, funeral aids are perceived to be more ethical (particularly in showing gratitude and honoring the deceased donor) and potentially increase donation willingness than direct cash payments of the same monetary value.[18][19]

Non-monetary incentives edit

Non-monetary incentives can act as an impactful reward system to employees with superior performance that is independent to predetermined targets.[20] They refer to the use of rewards or benefits that are not directly related to money or financial compensation to motivate individuals to perform specific actions or achieve desired outcomes [21]

The use of non-monetary incentives is based on the recognition that individuals are motivated by a range of factors beyond financial rewards and acts as a reinforcement to encourage work engagement and productivity.[22] Some examples of these incentives include extra paid holidays, recognition, praise, opportunity for personal or professional growth, gifts, family benefits or even work-based perks such as more interesting projects or work.

Individual may be motivated by a sense of purpose, a desire for personal fulfillment or growth, a need for social recognition or status, or other non-financial factors. By providing these types of incentives tend to boost employees' job satisfaction as they feel more appreciated for their efforts and lower turnover rates. Compared to monetary incentives, studies have shown that employees find non-monetary incentives more memorable as they are separated from normal pay and hence are more distinguishable.[23] In addition, non-monetary incentives are known to promote long-term commitment and loyalty among employees[21] Effective use of non-monetary incentives can positively influence employees’ perception of the company's image as well as increase the morale of firms.[24] Compared to monetary incentives, non-monetary incentives hold a stronger and longer-lasting influence on employees’ motivation as it results in a higher utility level.[25] Employees with higher job satisfaction and morale were found to have better overall performance, contribution and hence higher productivity.[26] Another advantage of non-monetary incentives that it allows a positive work culture that emphasizes cooperation, teamwork, and social responsibility.

However, non-monetary incentives also have some limitations and undesirable consequence.[21] For instance, it can be less effective in motivating individuals who are primarily motivated by monetary incentives such as financial rewards. This may be especially true for individuals who are in low-paying jobs or who face significant financial stress or insecurity. Another concern is that non-monetary incentives may be more difficult to quantify and evaluate than monetary incentives.[21] This may create several challenges for a firm or organisation to design and implement effective incentive programs that are aligned with their goals and objectives.

Overall, both monetary and non-monetary incentives are important tools to influence individual and organizational behavior. While monetary incentives may be more effective for some individuals or in some contexts, non-monetary incentives can be equally effective in promoting long-term commitment, fostering a positive work culture, and promoting social responsibility. Ultimately, the most effective incentive programs will likely incorporate a combination of monetary and non-monetary incentives to create a positive and comprehensive approach to motivation and performance.

Incentives in the economic context edit

The economic analysis of incentives focuses on the systems that determine the incentives needed for an agent to achieve a desired outcome dictated by the principal.[16] Incentives can help companies link employees' rewards to their productivity. When a firm wants their employees to produce a certain amount of output, it must be prepared to offer a compensation scheme such as a monetary bonus to persuade employees to reach the target output.[16] Compensation must achieve two goals. The first is to reduce employee turnover and retain the highest performing and most productive employees. Compensating employees can help attract workers to work harder and retain their ability. The second is to improve productivity. Compensation can not only stimulate the ability of workers to produce output, but also improve the enthusiasm of employees to work, thus promoting business development.[16] A rise in pay variance across the firm reflects an increased demand for highly productive workers, and therefore compensation has begun shifting towards pay-for-performance.[27] This helps employees recognize the direct relationship between their work output and their reward.

While incentive has become one of a powerful tool to motivate and influence certain behaviour or action, they can also have unintended consequences.[28] Recent research indicated how extensive and intrinsic can come into conflict with other motivation. For example, a poorly designed incentive system can potentially lead to unintended behaviours and actions as such, individuals or companies gaming the system to earn rewards without actually achieving the desired outcomes. This is known as the "principal-agent problem," where the incentives of the principal (e.g., the government or a company) do not align with the incentives of the agent (e.g., individuals or employees). This incentive conflicts can lead to adverse selection and moral hazard.[22] A moral hazard refers to a situation in which a particular party engage in a risky behaviour because it fails to bear the full costs of that risk. On the other hand, an adverse selection occur when there is a asymmetric information between different parties. As such, adverse selection often creates an incentive for plans to inefficiently distorts benefits. As incentive can bring conflicts between parties involve, effective management plan is required to resolve incentive conflicts.

Misaligned incentives edit

A misaligned incentive refers to a situation where the goals of different parties involved in a particular situation such as a firm or system are not aligned and may even conflict with each other. Misaligned incentives can potentially arise in many other contexts, such as in government policies, healthcare, education, and environmental regulations. Principals within a firm want their agents to work for the principals' best interests, but agents often have different goals than the principals.[29] Due to this problem of misaligned incentives, firms must design compensation plans to induce workers to act in the firm's best interest and generate a level of output that maximizes the firm's profits.[16] The problem of asymmetric information means that the principal does not know exactly how to motivate its agents to act in the firm's best interests. Consequently, compensation plans are difficult for firms to design.[30] The principal-agent theory is used as the guiding framework when aligning incentives with the employee's effort to obtain the efficient level of output for the firm.[16] For example, a manager may want a certain level of output from an employee but does not know the capabilities of the employee in the presence of imperfect monitoring, and to achieve the best outcome, an optimal incentive scheme must be designed to motivate the worker to increase their productivity.[30] Research shows that if a principal offers a high incentive, the agent will also recompense with a higher effort.[31]

However, in this relationship, an informal advantage usually exists among agents over the principal. A moral hazard could be present where principals are unable to know for sure if agents are giving their all on a delegated task, and an adverse selection could exist as principals usually have insufficient knowledge on the agents’ capabilities and face difficulties in selecting the agent best suited for a task.[32] In instances where principals have contradicting goals with the agents, agents would have an incentive to shirk and to leak information to competing principals.[33] Self-interested agents may also want to maximize their own interest by lying [34] or deliberately hiding information from the principal to decrease their workload.[32]

CEO incentives edit

The board of directors in a company plays an important role in creating incentives for CEOs so that their best interest aligns with that of the shareholders. CEOs can be given incentives in many forms, including salary, bonuses, shares, and stock options to reward spectacular performance while penalties can be imposed for unsatisfactory performance. To ensure that the CEOs are appropriately incentivized, CEOs can be made the substantial owners of the company's stock by the board of directors. CEOs that own a portion of the company's stock will have an incentive to work towards the common best interest of themselves and the company shareholders. Threat to dismiss the CEOs for unsatisfactory performance can also act as an incentive to reinforce the performance of the CEOs, which can in turn maximize the company's value. The possibility of dismissal will increase CEOs’ accountability for their own actions considering that the possible dismissal would likely lead to a poor reputation for themselves. As a result, a potential increase in work engagement and performance can be seen.[35]

Apart from monetary incentives, non-monetary incentives also play a part in increasing the work performance of CEOs. Non-monetary incentives can be introduced in the form of benefits such as power, public acknowledgement, prestige, and title. However, some argue that non-monetary incentives are less impactful. [35]

Tournament theory edit

Tournament theory describes a framework of compensation based on an individual's position within a firm's hierarchy.[5] The theory demonstrates that individuals are not promoted on the basis of their absolute performance and output, but instead based on their performance relative to other employees in the same position within the organization.[5] Ceteris paribus, the larger the difference in compensation between one position to the next, the greater the incentive to exert more effort in order to achieve a promotion.[13] However, that incentive is diminished as the size of the firm (and therefore the potential candidates for promotion) increases.

Firms must address the risk that a relative compensation scheme could incentivize uncooperative behavior amongst co-workers. Accordingly, firms encounter a trade-off between incentivizing workers to increase their efforts by increasing pay variance between the promoted and the unpromoted and, on the other hand, minimizing disharmony amongst co-workers by maintaining some level of pay compression.[13]

Self-selection effects of incentives edit

Employees know more about their own abilities, competitiveness and risk attitudes than potential employers. Due to this asymmetric information, firms design incentives not only to enhance employees’ motivation to act in the interests of the firm and maximize their output, but also to influence the type and quality of workers that they attract.[36] This is known as the self-selection or sorting effect of incentives. For example, empirical studies have shown that firms which implement pay-for-performance rather than fixed wage compensation schemes tend to attract more productive workers who are less risk averse.[37] Greater risk aversion reduces workers' willingness to work for variable as opposed to fixed pay.[38] Accordingly, firms may use incentives as a method of filtering out low productivity workers or workers who lack the personal characteristics that those firms are searching for.

Team-based incentives edit

Production is increasingly organized around teams in many large firms.[5] Teamwork may enhance company productivity for firms that encounter multidimensional, complex problems. A firm may be able to solve a complex task which requires a high level of various different skills by assigning it to expert workers with complementary skills.[5] Due to constantly advancing technologies, seldom does an individual employee have an absolute advantage across all skills that are required to solve the complicated problems that firms face, hence team collaboration is crucial and beneficial to ensure the success of a team.[5]

Individualized incentives are said to be dysfunctional in an interdependent working environment where individual performance is difficult to observe[39] and so firms may opt for team-based incentives instead. Team-based incentive refers to the incentive system that rewards employees based on performance of the team.[40] Team-based incentives are described as more beneficial to companies than individual-based incentives. By paying a straight piece rate to individual employees, they would have little to no motivation to help each other as the incentives they receive are irrespective of the result of others. On the other hand, paying team incentives based on team output can promote cohesiveness, trust, cooperation, and support within a team.[41] Researchers found a positive relationship between team-based incentive and employees’ work efficacy, stability, and salary[42] as well as company output.[43]

Research shows that employees prefer individual-based incentives over team-based incentives due to a few reasons. Firstly, they believe that team-based incentives are prone to unfairness. Employees with more contributions may be discouraged from seeing employees that contributed less receiving the same level of incentive.[44] Moreover, as a team expands and the effect of team incentives weakens, employees struggle to establish a clear link between effort given and incentives received.[44] It is also inevitable that team incentives could induce the free-rider problem because an employee's motivation to maximize their individual output could be diminished.[45] Managers may need to offer a team incentive that is strong enough to ensure that each worker's individual payoff from exerting the level of effort that allows the company to maximize its profits is greater than their individual payoff from free riding on the efforts of other team members.[46]

 
Payoffs of two employees assigned to a group project and faced with the choice of working hard or free riding.

Using Game theory to illustrate this, firms need to implement a team-based incentive that results in the value of ‘Y’ in Game 1 being greater than 100 and enforce a punishment for free-riding that makes the value of ‘X’ less than 40. This would ensure that both team members’ dominant strategy in Game 1 is to work hard and the Nash equilibrium is (Work Hard, Work Hard).

In contrast, some studies have shown that peer pressure and employees’ intrinsic incentive to perform well in a team environment may mitigate the free-rider problem associated with team-based incentives.[47][48] Such case studies demonstrate that team incentives increase firm productivity in settings that involve complex, interdependent production where peer pressure and intrinsic incentives outweigh selfish preferences.[47] Peer rating system can also be introduced for team members to rate each other's contribution to a task. Research findings show that imposing a penalty on free riders is useful in decreasing the tendency of free riding.[49]

Potential issues associated with the use of incentives in firms edit

Ratchet effect edit

Incentives are arguably beneficial in increasing productivity, however, they can also have an adverse effect on the firm.[16] This is evident through the ratchet effect. A firm may use its observation of an employee's output level when they are first employed as a guide to set performance standard and objectives for the future.[50] Knowing this, an employee may deliberately reduce their output level when first employed or hide their ability to produce at a higher output with the intent of exploiting being rewarded in the future when they strategically increase their output level.[50] Best performances of employees can be limited from it. Thus, the ratchet effect can significantly diminish production levels of a firm and planned economies.[51]

Crowding-out effect edit

Additionally, in the 1970s psychologists began exploring the relationship between extrinsic and intrinsic motivation whilst economists were simultaneously studying the "crowding-out" effects of monetary incentives. This came as a result of Richard Titmuss' 1970 publication, "The Gift Relationship", which explained how the constant use of extrinsic incentives can result in conflict with intrinsic motivators and lead to the desired behavior being "crowded out".[52] In his publication, Titmuss argued that the use of monetary incentives was disrupting social norms around the idea of voluntary contribution and would ultimately have a crowding-out effect. He acknowledged that if the incentives are large enough, they are more likely to offset crowding-out effects (at least in the short run while the incentives are being offered). However, Titmuss noted that making the incentives too large could also have an adverse effect due to the possibility of negative inferences being drawn from the size of the incentives.[53] Crowding-out effects can also occur when temporary incentives are removed in the long run. In the workplace, the complete removal of extrinsic incentives can result in employee effort levels being lower than they were when the incentives were offered, thereby hindering motivation and performance.[52]

Stock options edit

Incentives are not always effective at aligning employees' incentives with those of the firm.[54] For example, some corporate policies popular during the 1990s aimed to encourage productivity have led to failures as a result of unintended consequences.[55] Moreover, providing stock options was intended to boost CEO productivity through offering a remunerative incentive to align the CEOs' interests with those of the shareholders to improve company performance.[55] However, CEOs were found to either make good decisions which resulted in a reward of a long-term price increase of the stock, or were found to have fabricated the accounting information to give the illusion of economic success and to retain their incentive-based pay.[55] Furthermore, it has been found to be extremely costly for firms to incentivize CEOs with stock options. Nevertheless, firms are forced to pay substantial amounts of money to ensure that CEOs act in the best interest of the firms.[16]

Conflicts generated by pay variance edit

Incentives can have a bipolar effect on the company. On the one hand, the company's incentives to employees may create a pay gap. For example, low-paid employees may reduce their production or contribution to the company. Low-paid employees and high-paid employees may not be able to communicate and cooperate effectively, causing low-paid employees to gradually lose their enthusiasm for work.[56] Firms should provide a fair amount of incentives for both low-paid and other employees, incentives for low-paid workers can be breaks rather than monetary incentives. Motivating employees with financial rewards may make a difference. That's because if the company is profitable in the first year, it may have plenty of bonuses to hand out to employees. However, if the company makes less money in the second year than it did in the first year, the company may not be able to give employees the same bonuses as in the first year even though they put in the same effort. This also reduces employees' motivation to work. Therefore, incentives may be counterproductive. Firm can provide other types of incentives rather than monetary incentives, such as promotion or vacation breaks for high-performing employees.

Incentives in the context of voluntary contributions edit

When it comes to volunteering activities, monetary incentives can bring negative effects. According to the Self-perception theory, humans constantly seek explanations for their behavior.[57] When individuals are involved in volunteering activities, they most likely perceive themselves as prosocial and altruistic, and attach a symbolic price to the act of volunteering.[58][59] When a monetary reward is attached to an otherwise prosocial activity such as volunteering, people may perceive that their originally altruistic actions are now linked to extrinsic incentives,[60] causing their self-image benefit[61] and prosocial motivation to decrease.[62] A crowding-out effect leads to a decrease in individuals’ desire to volunteer and people eventually stop contributing due to the rewards attached. For example, if monetary incentives are offered for voluntary blood donation, it will have a negative effect on the number of people donating blood.[60]

Incentives in education edit

Extrinsic incentives offered to unmotivated students can potentially have positive short-run effects on education.[52] However, the use of extrinsic incentives in education has been opposed on the basis that they are morally corrupt and have the potential to crowd out intrinsic incentives for educational effort.[52] Furthermore, there is scarce empirical evidence to support the success of monetary incentives awarded for educational outputs such as academic achievement as opposed to educational inputs such as attendance and enrolment.[63]

The dynamic effects of incentives are evident in the context of education. Studies have demonstrated that the impact of monetary incentives is dependent on previous academic performance and individual ability.[64] Monetary incentives tend to improve the academic results of high-ability students but have an adverse effect on the performance of students with lower aptitude.[64]

Conclusion edit

Ultimately, there is always potential for conflicts to arise, both in the short and in the long run, during the application of incentives in different areas, as incentives that seek to change behaviors can crowd-out intrinsic motivators. A growing pool of evidence suggests that economists must broaden their focus when exploring the effects of incentives as the effect they have is largely dependent on how they are designed and specifically how they interact with intrinsic and social motivators in the short run and the long run.[26]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ a b Gneezy, Uri (2011). "When and Why Incentives (Don't) Work to Modify Behavior". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 25 (4): 191. doi:10.1257/jep.25.4.191.
  2. ^ a b Gneezy, Uri; Meier, Stephan; Rey-Biel, Pedro (Fall 2011). "When and Why Incentives (Don't) Work to Modify Behavior". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 25 (4): 191. doi:10.1257/jep.25.4.191.
  3. ^ Clark, Peter B.; Wilson, James Q. (1961). "Incentive Systems: A Theory of Organizations". Administrative Science Quarterly. 6 (2): 129–166. doi:10.2307/2390752. ISSN 0001-8392. JSTOR 2390752.
  4. ^ Masterclass. "Understanding Incentives in Economics: 5 Common Types of Economic Incentives". Masterclass. Retrieved 2022-04-29.
  5. ^ a b c d e f Lazear, Edward. P; Shaw, Kathryn. L (2007). "Personnel Economics: The Economist's View of Human Resources" (PDF). Journal of Economic Perspectives. 21 (4): 91–114. doi:10.1257/jep.21.4.91.
  6. ^ Li, Pamela (19 April 2019). "What is Intrinsic Motivation & How Does it Work?". Parenting for Brain. Retrieved 2022-04-29.
  7. ^ Benati, Igor; Coccia, Mario (2018). "Rewards in Bureaucracy and Politics". In Farazmand, Ali (ed.). Global Encyclopedia of Public Administration, Public Policy, and Governance. Cham: Springer International Publishing. pp. 1–6. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-31816-5_3417-1. ISBN 978-3-319-31816-5. S2CID 158421245.
  8. ^ O'Reilly, C. A.; Chatman, J.; Caldwell, D. F. (September 1991). "People and Organizational Culture: A Profile Comparison Approach to Assessing Person-Organization Fit". Academy of Management Journal. 34 (3): 487–516. doi:10.2307/256404. ISSN 0001-4273. JSTOR 256404. S2CID 45619898.
  9. ^ Waqas, Zafarullah; Saleem, Sharjeel (2014-11-01). The Effect of Monetary and Non-Monetary Rewards on Employee Engagement and Firm Performance. The International Institute for Science, Technology and Education (IISTE). OCLC 1358510932.
  10. ^ a b Behavioral Science Solutions. "Incentives". Behavioral Economics. Retrieved 2022-04-29.
  11. ^ Callahan, David (2004). The cheating culture: Why more Americans are doing wrong to get ahead. Harcourt. ISBN 9780156030052.
  12. ^ a b c d e Dalkir, Kimiz (2011). Knowledge Management in Theory and Practice (Second ed.). The MIT Press. ISBN 9780262015080.
  13. ^ a b c d Lazear, Edward P. (Summer 2018). "Compensation and Incentives in the Workplace". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 32 (3): 195–214. doi:10.1257/jep.32.3.195. ISSN 0895-3309. S2CID 158410132.
  14. ^ a b Gneezy, Uri; Meier, Stephan; Rey-Biel, Pedro (2011-11-01). "When and Why Incentives (Don't) Work to Modify Behavior". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 25 (4): 191–210. doi:10.1257/jep.25.4.191. ISSN 0895-3309.
  15. ^ Pokorny, Kathrin (May 2008). "Pay—but do not pay too much: An experimental study on the impact of incentives". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 66 (2): 251–264. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2006.03.007. ISSN 0167-2681.
  16. ^ a b c d e f g h i Neilson, William S. (2007). Personnel Economics. Pearson Education Inc. p. 11. ISBN 9780131488564.
  17. ^ Camerer, Colin F.; Hogarth, Robin M.; Budescu, David V.; Eckel, Catherine (1999). "The Effects of Financial Incentives in Experiments: A Review and Capital-Labor-Production Framework". In Fischhoff, Baruch; Manski, Charles F. (eds.). Elicitation of Preferences. Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands. pp. 7–48. doi:10.1007/978-94-017-1406-8_2. ISBN 978-90-481-5776-1.
  18. ^ Arnold, R.; Bartlett, S.; Bernat, J.; Colonna, J.; Dafoe, D. (2002). "Financial incentives for cadaver organ donation: an ethical reappraisal". Transplantation. 73 (8): 1361–1367. doi:10.1097/00007890-200204270-00034. PMID 11981440. S2CID 29823737.
  19. ^ Pham, V. (2021). "Cash, Funeral Benefits or Nothing at All: How to Incentivize Family Consent for Organ Donation" (PDF). Review of Behavioral Economics. 8 (2): 147–192. doi:10.1561/105.00000136. S2CID 237705443.
  20. ^ Hooi, L. W.; Abdullah, A. A. (2013). "Relationships of Non-Monetary Incentives, Job Satisfaction and Employee Job Performance". International Review of Management and Business Research. 2 (4): 1085–1091.
  21. ^ a b c d Lefebvre, Mathieu; Stenger, Anne (2020-01-17). "Short- & long-term effects of monetary and non-monetary incentives to cooperate in public good games: An experiment". PLOS ONE. 15 (1): e0227360. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0227360. ISSN 1932-6203. PMC 6968839. PMID 31951622.
  22. ^ a b Burgess, S. (2003-06-01). "The Role of Incentives in the Public Sector: Issues and Evidence". Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 19 (2): 285–300. doi:10.1093/oxrep/19.2.285. ISSN 1460-2121.
  23. ^ Cassar, Lea; Meier, Stephan (Summer 2018). "Nonmonetary Incentives and the Implications of Work as a Source of Meaning". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 32 (3): 215–238. doi:10.1257/jep.32.3.215. ISSN 0895-3309. S2CID 52834710.
  24. ^ Depedri, Sara; Tortia, Ermanno C.; Carpita, Maurizio (2010). "Incentives, Job Satisfaction and Performance: Empirical Evidence in Italian Social Enterprises". Euricse Working Papers. N.012 | 10. SSRN 1698598.
  25. ^ Jeffrey, S. (2004). "The benefits of tangible non-monetary incentives". University of Chicago: 702–77.
  26. ^ a b Gneezy, Uri; Meier, Stephan; Rey-Biel, Pedro (Fall 2011). "When and Why Incentives (Don't) Work to Modify Behavior". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 25 (4): 206. doi:10.1257/jep.25.4.191.
  27. ^ Lazear, Edward P.; Shaw, Kathryn L. (2007). "Personnel Economics: The Economist's View of Human Resources" (PDF). The Journal of Economic Perspectives. American Economic Association. 21 (4): 91–114. doi:10.1257/jep.21.4.91. JSTOR 30033753.
  28. ^ Edmans, Alex; Fang, Vivian W.; Huang, Allen (2018). "The Long-Term Consequences of Short-Term Incentives". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3037354. ISSN 1556-5068. S2CID 53073899.
  29. ^ Prendergast, Canice (March 1999). "The Provision of Incentives in Firms". Journal of Economic Literature. 37 (1): 7–63. doi:10.1257/jel.37.1.7.
  30. ^ a b (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2015-11-23.
  31. ^ Irlenbusch, Bernd; Sliwka, Dirk (September 2005). "Incentives, Decision Frames, and Motivation Crowding Out – an Experimental Investigation". IZA Discussion Paper No. 1758. doi:10.2139/ssrn.822866. hdl:10419/33245. S2CID 16424059. SSRN 822866.
  32. ^ a b Braun, Dietmar; Guston, David H (October 2003). "Principal-agent theory and research policy: an introduction" (PDF). Science and Public Policy. 30 (5): 302–308. doi:10.3152/147154303781780290. ISSN 0302-3427. S2CID 144005311.
  33. ^ Waterman, Richard W.; Meier, Kenneth J. (1998). "Principal-Agent Models: An Expansion?". Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory. 8 (2): 173–202. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.jpart.a024377.
  34. ^ Williamson, Oliver E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism: firms, markets, relational contracting. The Free Press. ISBN 978-0-684-86374-0. OCLC 12216444.
  35. ^ a b Jensen, Michael C.; Murphy, Kevin J. (Winter 2010). "CEO Incentives-It's Not How Much You Pay, But How". Journal of Applied Corporate Finance. 22 (1): 64–76. doi:10.1111/j.1745-6622.2010.00262.x. ISSN 1078-1196. S2CID 219968200.
  36. ^ Prendergast, Canice (March 1999). "The Provision of Incentives in Firms". Journal of Economic Literature. 37 (1): 14–15. doi:10.1257/jel.37.1.7.
  37. ^ Bram Cadsby, C.; Song, F.; Tapon, F. (April 2007). "Sorting and Incentive Effects of Pay for Performance: An Experimental Investigation". The Academy of Management Journal. 50 (2): 389–392.
  38. ^ Dohmen, T.; Folk, A. (2010). "Yout Get What You Pay For: Incentives and Selection in the Education System". The Economic Journal. 120 (546): 257–258. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2010.02376.x. JSTOR 40784482. S2CID 12928709.
  39. ^ Franco-Santos, Monica; Gomez-Mejia, Luis R. (2015). "Creating a culture of collaboration, innovation and performance through team-based incentives". Team-based incentives: Creating a Culture of Collaboration, Innovation, and Performance. The Compensation Handbook (6th ed.). McGraw-Hill. pp. 199–209.
  40. ^ DeMatteo, J. S.; Eby, L. T.; Sundstrom, E. (1998). Team-based rewards: Current empirical evidence and directions for future research. Research in organizational behavior. Vol. 20 (B. M. Staw & L.L. Cummings ed.). Elsevier Science/JAI Press. pp. 141–183.
  41. ^ Beersma, B.; Hollenbeck, J. R.; Humphrey, S. E.; Moon, H.; Conlon, D. E.; Ilgen, D. R. (2003). "Cooperation, Competition, and Team Performance: Towards a Contingency Approach". Academy of Management Journal. 46 (5): 572–590. doi:10.2139/ssrn.325401. ISSN 0001-4273. SSRN 325401.
  42. ^ Kruse, Douglas (May 2022) [December 2016]. "Does employee ownership improve performance?". IZA World of Labor. 311. doi:10.15185/izawol.311. hdl:10419/148536. ISSN 2054-9571.
  43. ^ Hamilton, Barton H.; Nickerson, Jack A.; Owan, Hideo (June 2003). "Team Incentives and Worker Heterogeneity: An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Teams on Productivity and Participation". Journal of Political Economy. 111 (3): 465–497. doi:10.1086/374182. ISSN 0022-3808. S2CID 11969481.
  44. ^ a b Gerhart, Barry; Rynes, Sara L.; Fulmer, Ingrid Smithey (January 2009). "6 Pay and Performance: Individuals, Groups, and Executives". Academy of Management Annals. 3 (1): 251–315. doi:10.5465/19416520903047269. ISSN 1941-6520.
  45. ^ Holmstrom, Bengt (1982). "Moral Hazard in Teams". The Bell Journal of Economics. 13 (2): 325–328. doi:10.2307/3003457. JSTOR 3003457.
  46. ^ Alchian, A.; Demsetz, H. (1972). "Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization". The American Economic Review. 62 (5): 779–781. JSTOR 1815199.
  47. ^ a b Frederiksen, A.; Hansen, D.; Manchester, C. (2022). "Does Group-Based Incentive Pay Lead To Higher Productivity? Evidence from a Complex and Interdependent Industrial Production Process". IZA Institute of Labor Economics: 2–4.
  48. ^ Kandel, E.; Lazear, E. (1992). "Peer Pressure and Partnerships". Journal of Political Economy. 100 (4): 803–811. doi:10.1086/261840. JSTOR 2138688. S2CID 16757647.
  49. ^ Hashim, Matthew J.; Bockstedt, Jesse C. (5–8 January 2015). "Overcoming Free-Riding in Information Goods: Sanctions or Rewards?". 2015 48th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences. Kauai, HI, USA: IEEE. pp. 4834–4843. doi:10.1109/hicss.2015.574.
  50. ^ a b Kanemoto, Yoshitsugu; MacLeod, W. Bentley (1992). "The Ratchet Effect and the Market for Secondhand Workers". Journal of Labor Economics. University of Chicago Press. 10 (1): 85–98. doi:10.1086/298279. JSTOR 2535130. S2CID 154244118.
  51. ^ Cooper, David J.; Kagel, John H.; Lo, Wei; Gu, Qing Liang (1999). "Gaming against Managers in Incentive Systems: Experimental Results with Chinese Students and Chinese Managers" (PDF). The American Economic Review. 89 (4): 781–804. doi:10.1257/aer.89.4.781. ISSN 0002-8282. JSTOR 117159.
  52. ^ a b c d Gneezy, Uri; Meier, Stephan; Rey-Biel, Pedro (Fall 2011). "When and Why Incentives (Don't) Work to Modify Behavior". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 25 (4): 192. doi:10.1257/jep.25.4.191.
  53. ^ Ariely, Dan; Gneezy, Uri; Loewenstein, George; Mazar, Nina (2009). "Large Stakes and Big Mistakes" (PDF). The Review of Economic Studies. 76 (2): 451–469. doi:10.1111/j.1467-937X.2009.00534.x. Retrieved 3 May 2022.
  54. ^ Chiappori; Salanié (2003). "Testing contract theory: a survey of some recent work". In M. Dewatripont; L. Hansen; S. Turnovsky (eds.). Advances in Economics and Econometrics (PDF). Vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. pp. 115–149. doi:10.1017/CBO9780511610240.005. ISBN 9780511610240. S2CID 3067063.
  55. ^ a b c Jain, Abha (2019). Sports Psychology. India: Friends Publications. p. 215. ISBN 978-93-88457-75-0.
  56. ^ Breza, Emily; Kaur, Supreet; Shamdasani, Yogita (10 October 2017). "The Morale Effects of Pay Inequality*". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 133 (2): 611–663. doi:10.1093/qje/qjx041.
  57. ^ Bem, Daryl J. (1972). "Self-Perception Theory". In Leonard Berkowitz (ed.). Advances in Experimental Social Psychology. Vol. 6. Academic Press. pp. 1–62. doi:10.1016/s0065-2601(08)60024-6. ISBN 9780120152063.
  58. ^ Frey, Bruno S.; Jegen, Reto (December 2001). "Motivation Crowding Theory". Journal of Economic Surveys. 15 (5): 589–611. doi:10.1111/1467-6419.00150. ISSN 0950-0804.
  59. ^ Heyman, James; Ariely, Dan (November 2004). "Effort for Payment". Psychological Science. 15 (11): 787–793. doi:10.1111/j.0956-7976.2004.00757.x. ISSN 0956-7976. PMID 15482452. S2CID 8573184.
  60. ^ a b Bolle, Friedel; Otto, Philipp E. (February 2010). "A Price Is a Signal: on Intrinsic Motivation, Crowding-out, and Crowding-in". Kyklos. 63 (1): 9–22. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6435.2010.00458.x. ISSN 0023-5962. S2CID 154039981.
  61. ^ Brekke, Kjell Arne; Kverndokk, Snorre; Nyborg, Karine (September 2003). "An economic model of moral motivation". Journal of Public Economics. 87 (9–10): 1967–1983. doi:10.1016/s0047-2727(01)00222-5. hdl:10419/192272. ISSN 0047-2727.
  62. ^ Qiao, Dandan; Lee, Shun-Yang; Whinston, Andrew B.; Wei, Qiang (2021-01-02). "Mitigating the Adverse Effect of Monetary Incentives on Voluntary Contributions Online". Journal of Management Information Systems. 38 (1): 82–107. doi:10.1080/07421222.2021.1870385. ISSN 0742-1222. S2CID 232765666.
  63. ^ Fryer, Roland (November 2011). "Financial Incentives and Student Achievement: Evidence from Randomized Trials". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 126 (4): 1758. doi:10.1093/qje/qjr045.
  64. ^ a b Leuven, E.; Osteerbeck, H.; van der Klaauw, B. (2010). "The Effect of Financial Rewards on Students' Achievement: Evidence from a Randomized Experiment". Journal of the European Economic Association. 8 (6): 1259.

incentive, other, uses, disambiguation, general, incentives, anything, that, persuade, person, alter, their, behavior, desired, manner, emphasized, that, incentives, matter, basic, economists, laws, behavior, which, state, that, higher, incentives, amount, gre. For other uses see Incentive disambiguation In general incentives are anything that persuade a person to alter their behavior in the desired manner 1 It is emphasized that incentives matter by the basic law of economists and the laws of behavior which state that higher incentives amount to greater levels of effort and therefore higher levels of performance 2 Protest sign displaying Stop Climate Change at climate strike in Melbourne Australia Climate movements may incentivize governments and industry to take collective action in the fight against climate change Contents 1 Divisions 1 1 Intrinsic and extrinsic incentive 2 Classification 3 Monetary incentives 4 Non monetary incentives 5 Incentives in the economic context 5 1 Misaligned incentives 5 2 CEO incentives 5 3 Tournament theory 5 4 Self selection effects of incentives 5 5 Team based incentives 5 6 Potential issues associated with the use of incentives in firms 5 6 1 Ratchet effect 5 6 2 Crowding out effect 5 6 3 Stock options 5 6 4 Conflicts generated by pay variance 6 Incentives in the context of voluntary contributions 7 Incentives in education 8 Conclusion 9 See also 10 ReferencesDivisions editAn incentive is a powerful tool to influence certain desired behaviors or action often adopted by governments and businesses 3 Incentives can be broadly broken down into two categories intrinsic incentives and extrinsic incentives 4 Overall both types of incentives can be powerful tools often employ to increase effort and higher performance according to the law of behavior Incentives are most studied in the area of personnel economics where economic analysts such as those who take part in human resources management practices focus on how firms make employees more motivated through pay and career concerns compensation and performance evaluation to motivate employees and best achieve the firms desired performance outcomes 5 Intrinsic and extrinsic incentive edit An intrinsic incentive is when a person is motivated to act in a certain way for their own personal satisfaction without seeking any external reward nor facing any external pressure to perform the task 6 For instance a singer who enjoys singing may be intrinsically motivated to spend several hours a day to improve their performance without receiving any recognition or awards from others 7 Often intrinsic incentives are useful in increasing one s empowerment utility level and autonomy and can reinforce employees work involvement and commitment 8 Intrinsic incentives and extrinsic incentives are both important in driving people s behavior Experts believe that intrinsic incentives are stronger motivators compared to extrinsic incentives as they increase employees work engagement and genuine enjoyment of work 9 However people s intrinsic motivation tends to decrease when they are offered too many extrinsic rewards In order to maintain the action constant incentives have to be provided This is known as the Overjustification Effect While both types of incentive are a fundamental concept in economics that play a crucial role in motivating behavior the extent to which and how they influence individual may depend on varies factors Factors to consider may include the type of activity being incentivized the individual s personal values and goals and the context in which the incentive is offered A well designed incentive system should take into account to avoid unintended consequences and ensure that they align with the desired outcomes There are some parties who oppose the benefits of using extrinsic incentives and believe that they cause more harm than good These opponents believe that the constant use of extrinsic incentives can lead to the crowding out of intrinsic incentives which are also valuable performance motivators 2 When people are constantly being incentivized by external pressures they neglect their intrinsic motives which could consequently be detrimental to their work ethic 10 Employees can become too comfortable with consistently gaining some reward for acting in a manner which is consistent with the interests of the firm As a result employees begin to believe that they deserve to earn rewards for doing certain things not for the benefit of the firm but rather for their own benefit which leads to them shirking if no extrinsic incentive is offered in return for high effort 10 Nonetheless incentives both intrinsic and extrinsic can be beneficial in altering a person s behavior and can be effectively used and executed within many different areas of life including in the workforce in education and within one s personal life 1 Classification editClassified by David Callahan the types of incentives can be further broken down into three broad classes according to the different ways in which they motivate agents to take a particular course of actions 11 12 Class DefinitionRemunerative incentives or financial incentives Exist where an agent can expect some form of a material reward like money in exchange for acting in a particular way 12 Moral incentives Exist where a particular choice is widely regarded as the right thing to do or is particularly admirable among others 12 An agent acting on a moral incentive can expect a sense of positive self esteem and praise or admiration from their community However an agent acting against a moral incentive can expect a sense of guilt condemnation or even ostracism from the community 12 Coercive incentives Exist where an agent can expect that the failure to act in a specific way will result in physical force being used against them by others for example by inflicting pain or by imprisonment or by confiscating or destroying their possessions 12 Monetary incentives editMonetary incentives are any form of financial good given to someone to incentivize their actions and align their incentives with those of the principal who provides the monetary incentive 13 This is a type of extrinsic incentive and is commonly seen in the workplace The effect of monetary incentive can be broken down into two categories the standard direct price effect and indirect psychological effect These two types of monetary effect often work in opposite direction and crowd out incentivised behaviour 14 However several studies have suggested that it is possible to manage the crowding out effects by utilising a principal agent model that incorporates nonstandard assumptions 14 For instance a monetary incentive may come in the forms of profit sharing bonuses stock options or even paid vacation time As such a well chosen monetary incentive programs can produce positive motivation and influence the productivity and output of individuals and firms 15 A common monetary incentive system used by firms is performance based pay where incentives are paid based on employees productivity or output over a particular period of time Some methods are commission based where the employee for example a salesperson receives a payment directly correlated to their output level Firms also pay additional wages or rewards for employees who work overtime and for their additional work above firm expectations Expectancy theory implies that provided employees place sufficient value on the monetary incentive to justify their extra effort and perceive that greater effort will result in better performance such incentives can motivate employees to maintain high levels of effort and discourage shirking This in turn increases the individual productivity of workers and the overall productivity of the firm 13 Other monetary incentives are less direct such as awarding periodic discretionary bonuses to top performers offering the possibility of a promotion to a higher paying position or profit sharing for team projects 16 Alternatively firms can also incentivize their employees to perform by threatening to demote or terminate them for poor performance 16 When employees feel that their careers are in jeopardy they are more likely to increase their efforts Monetary incentives do affect the effort and average performance of employees but are likely dependent on the scope of the job and the task variables For routine jobs such as clerical and administration jobs that are mundane the presence of monetary incentives will encourage employees to demonstrate consistent effort of diligence when the intrinsic incentive has been exhausted On the other hand if the task assigned is too challenging monetary incentives make little to no difference in increasing an employee s contribution to work 17 The effect of monetary incentives can depend on the framing of the rewards For example in cadaveric organ donation funeral aids are perceived to be more ethical particularly in showing gratitude and honoring the deceased donor and potentially increase donation willingness than direct cash payments of the same monetary value 18 19 Non monetary incentives editNon monetary incentives can act as an impactful reward system to employees with superior performance that is independent to predetermined targets 20 They refer to the use of rewards or benefits that are not directly related to money or financial compensation to motivate individuals to perform specific actions or achieve desired outcomes 21 The use of non monetary incentives is based on the recognition that individuals are motivated by a range of factors beyond financial rewards and acts as a reinforcement to encourage work engagement and productivity 22 Some examples of these incentives include extra paid holidays recognition praise opportunity for personal or professional growth gifts family benefits or even work based perks such as more interesting projects or work Individual may be motivated by a sense of purpose a desire for personal fulfillment or growth a need for social recognition or status or other non financial factors By providing these types of incentives tend to boost employees job satisfaction as they feel more appreciated for their efforts and lower turnover rates Compared to monetary incentives studies have shown that employees find non monetary incentives more memorable as they are separated from normal pay and hence are more distinguishable 23 In addition non monetary incentives are known to promote long term commitment and loyalty among employees 21 Effective use of non monetary incentives can positively influence employees perception of the company s image as well as increase the morale of firms 24 Compared to monetary incentives non monetary incentives hold a stronger and longer lasting influence on employees motivation as it results in a higher utility level 25 Employees with higher job satisfaction and morale were found to have better overall performance contribution and hence higher productivity 26 Another advantage of non monetary incentives that it allows a positive work culture that emphasizes cooperation teamwork and social responsibility However non monetary incentives also have some limitations and undesirable consequence 21 For instance it can be less effective in motivating individuals who are primarily motivated by monetary incentives such as financial rewards This may be especially true for individuals who are in low paying jobs or who face significant financial stress or insecurity Another concern is that non monetary incentives may be more difficult to quantify and evaluate than monetary incentives 21 This may create several challenges for a firm or organisation to design and implement effective incentive programs that are aligned with their goals and objectives Overall both monetary and non monetary incentives are important tools to influence individual and organizational behavior While monetary incentives may be more effective for some individuals or in some contexts non monetary incentives can be equally effective in promoting long term commitment fostering a positive work culture and promoting social responsibility Ultimately the most effective incentive programs will likely incorporate a combination of monetary and non monetary incentives to create a positive and comprehensive approach to motivation and performance Incentives in the economic context editThe economic analysis of incentives focuses on the systems that determine the incentives needed for an agent to achieve a desired outcome dictated by the principal 16 Incentives can help companies link employees rewards to their productivity When a firm wants their employees to produce a certain amount of output it must be prepared to offer a compensation scheme such as a monetary bonus to persuade employees to reach the target output 16 Compensation must achieve two goals The first is to reduce employee turnover and retain the highest performing and most productive employees Compensating employees can help attract workers to work harder and retain their ability The second is to improve productivity Compensation can not only stimulate the ability of workers to produce output but also improve the enthusiasm of employees to work thus promoting business development 16 A rise in pay variance across the firm reflects an increased demand for highly productive workers and therefore compensation has begun shifting towards pay for performance 27 This helps employees recognize the direct relationship between their work output and their reward While incentive has become one of a powerful tool to motivate and influence certain behaviour or action they can also have unintended consequences 28 Recent research indicated how extensive and intrinsic can come into conflict with other motivation For example a poorly designed incentive system can potentially lead to unintended behaviours and actions as such individuals or companies gaming the system to earn rewards without actually achieving the desired outcomes This is known as the principal agent problem where the incentives of the principal e g the government or a company do not align with the incentives of the agent e g individuals or employees This incentive conflicts can lead to adverse selection and moral hazard 22 A moral hazard refers to a situation in which a particular party engage in a risky behaviour because it fails to bear the full costs of that risk On the other hand an adverse selection occur when there is a asymmetric information between different parties As such adverse selection often creates an incentive for plans to inefficiently distorts benefits As incentive can bring conflicts between parties involve effective management plan is required to resolve incentive conflicts Misaligned incentives edit A misaligned incentive refers to a situation where the goals of different parties involved in a particular situation such as a firm or system are not aligned and may even conflict with each other Misaligned incentives can potentially arise in many other contexts such as in government policies healthcare education and environmental regulations Principals within a firm want their agents to work for the principals best interests but agents often have different goals than the principals 29 Due to this problem of misaligned incentives firms must design compensation plans to induce workers to act in the firm s best interest and generate a level of output that maximizes the firm s profits 16 The problem of asymmetric information means that the principal does not know exactly how to motivate its agents to act in the firm s best interests Consequently compensation plans are difficult for firms to design 30 The principal agent theory is used as the guiding framework when aligning incentives with the employee s effort to obtain the efficient level of output for the firm 16 For example a manager may want a certain level of output from an employee but does not know the capabilities of the employee in the presence of imperfect monitoring and to achieve the best outcome an optimal incentive scheme must be designed to motivate the worker to increase their productivity 30 Research shows that if a principal offers a high incentive the agent will also recompense with a higher effort 31 However in this relationship an informal advantage usually exists among agents over the principal A moral hazard could be present where principals are unable to know for sure if agents are giving their all on a delegated task and an adverse selection could exist as principals usually have insufficient knowledge on the agents capabilities and face difficulties in selecting the agent best suited for a task 32 In instances where principals have contradicting goals with the agents agents would have an incentive to shirk and to leak information to competing principals 33 Self interested agents may also want to maximize their own interest by lying 34 or deliberately hiding information from the principal to decrease their workload 32 CEO incentives edit The board of directors in a company plays an important role in creating incentives for CEOs so that their best interest aligns with that of the shareholders CEOs can be given incentives in many forms including salary bonuses shares and stock options to reward spectacular performance while penalties can be imposed for unsatisfactory performance To ensure that the CEOs are appropriately incentivized CEOs can be made the substantial owners of the company s stock by the board of directors CEOs that own a portion of the company s stock will have an incentive to work towards the common best interest of themselves and the company shareholders Threat to dismiss the CEOs for unsatisfactory performance can also act as an incentive to reinforce the performance of the CEOs which can in turn maximize the company s value The possibility of dismissal will increase CEOs accountability for their own actions considering that the possible dismissal would likely lead to a poor reputation for themselves As a result a potential increase in work engagement and performance can be seen 35 Apart from monetary incentives non monetary incentives also play a part in increasing the work performance of CEOs Non monetary incentives can be introduced in the form of benefits such as power public acknowledgement prestige and title However some argue that non monetary incentives are less impactful 35 Tournament theory edit Tournament theory describes a framework of compensation based on an individual s position within a firm s hierarchy 5 The theory demonstrates that individuals are not promoted on the basis of their absolute performance and output but instead based on their performance relative to other employees in the same position within the organization 5 Ceteris paribus the larger the difference in compensation between one position to the next the greater the incentive to exert more effort in order to achieve a promotion 13 However that incentive is diminished as the size of the firm and therefore the potential candidates for promotion increases Firms must address the risk that a relative compensation scheme could incentivize uncooperative behavior amongst co workers Accordingly firms encounter a trade off between incentivizing workers to increase their efforts by increasing pay variance between the promoted and the unpromoted and on the other hand minimizing disharmony amongst co workers by maintaining some level of pay compression 13 Self selection effects of incentives edit Employees know more about their own abilities competitiveness and risk attitudes than potential employers Due to this asymmetric information firms design incentives not only to enhance employees motivation to act in the interests of the firm and maximize their output but also to influence the type and quality of workers that they attract 36 This is known as the self selection or sorting effect of incentives For example empirical studies have shown that firms which implement pay for performance rather than fixed wage compensation schemes tend to attract more productive workers who are less risk averse 37 Greater risk aversion reduces workers willingness to work for variable as opposed to fixed pay 38 Accordingly firms may use incentives as a method of filtering out low productivity workers or workers who lack the personal characteristics that those firms are searching for Team based incentives edit Production is increasingly organized around teams in many large firms 5 Teamwork may enhance company productivity for firms that encounter multidimensional complex problems A firm may be able to solve a complex task which requires a high level of various different skills by assigning it to expert workers with complementary skills 5 Due to constantly advancing technologies seldom does an individual employee have an absolute advantage across all skills that are required to solve the complicated problems that firms face hence team collaboration is crucial and beneficial to ensure the success of a team 5 Individualized incentives are said to be dysfunctional in an interdependent working environment where individual performance is difficult to observe 39 and so firms may opt for team based incentives instead Team based incentive refers to the incentive system that rewards employees based on performance of the team 40 Team based incentives are described as more beneficial to companies than individual based incentives By paying a straight piece rate to individual employees they would have little to no motivation to help each other as the incentives they receive are irrespective of the result of others On the other hand paying team incentives based on team output can promote cohesiveness trust cooperation and support within a team 41 Researchers found a positive relationship between team based incentive and employees work efficacy stability and salary 42 as well as company output 43 Research shows that employees prefer individual based incentives over team based incentives due to a few reasons Firstly they believe that team based incentives are prone to unfairness Employees with more contributions may be discouraged from seeing employees that contributed less receiving the same level of incentive 44 Moreover as a team expands and the effect of team incentives weakens employees struggle to establish a clear link between effort given and incentives received 44 It is also inevitable that team incentives could induce the free rider problem because an employee s motivation to maximize their individual output could be diminished 45 Managers may need to offer a team incentive that is strong enough to ensure that each worker s individual payoff from exerting the level of effort that allows the company to maximize its profits is greater than their individual payoff from free riding on the efforts of other team members 46 nbsp Payoffs of two employees assigned to a group project and faced with the choice of working hard or free riding Using Game theory to illustrate this firms need to implement a team based incentive that results in the value of Y in Game 1 being greater than 100 and enforce a punishment for free riding that makes the value of X less than 40 This would ensure that both team members dominant strategy in Game 1 is to work hard and the Nash equilibrium is Work Hard Work Hard In contrast some studies have shown that peer pressure and employees intrinsic incentive to perform well in a team environment may mitigate the free rider problem associated with team based incentives 47 48 Such case studies demonstrate that team incentives increase firm productivity in settings that involve complex interdependent production where peer pressure and intrinsic incentives outweigh selfish preferences 47 Peer rating system can also be introduced for team members to rate each other s contribution to a task Research findings show that imposing a penalty on free riders is useful in decreasing the tendency of free riding 49 Potential issues associated with the use of incentives in firms edit Ratchet effect edit Incentives are arguably beneficial in increasing productivity however they can also have an adverse effect on the firm 16 This is evident through the ratchet effect A firm may use its observation of an employee s output level when they are first employed as a guide to set performance standard and objectives for the future 50 Knowing this an employee may deliberately reduce their output level when first employed or hide their ability to produce at a higher output with the intent of exploiting being rewarded in the future when they strategically increase their output level 50 Best performances of employees can be limited from it Thus the ratchet effect can significantly diminish production levels of a firm and planned economies 51 Crowding out effect edit Additionally in the 1970s psychologists began exploring the relationship between extrinsic and intrinsic motivation whilst economists were simultaneously studying the crowding out effects of monetary incentives This came as a result of Richard Titmuss 1970 publication The Gift Relationship which explained how the constant use of extrinsic incentives can result in conflict with intrinsic motivators and lead to the desired behavior being crowded out 52 In his publication Titmuss argued that the use of monetary incentives was disrupting social norms around the idea of voluntary contribution and would ultimately have a crowding out effect He acknowledged that if the incentives are large enough they are more likely to offset crowding out effects at least in the short run while the incentives are being offered However Titmuss noted that making the incentives too large could also have an adverse effect due to the possibility of negative inferences being drawn from the size of the incentives 53 Crowding out effects can also occur when temporary incentives are removed in the long run In the workplace the complete removal of extrinsic incentives can result in employee effort levels being lower than they were when the incentives were offered thereby hindering motivation and performance 52 Stock options edit Incentives are not always effective at aligning employees incentives with those of the firm 54 For example some corporate policies popular during the 1990s aimed to encourage productivity have led to failures as a result of unintended consequences 55 Moreover providing stock options was intended to boost CEO productivity through offering a remunerative incentive to align the CEOs interests with those of the shareholders to improve company performance 55 However CEOs were found to either make good decisions which resulted in a reward of a long term price increase of the stock or were found to have fabricated the accounting information to give the illusion of economic success and to retain their incentive based pay 55 Furthermore it has been found to be extremely costly for firms to incentivize CEOs with stock options Nevertheless firms are forced to pay substantial amounts of money to ensure that CEOs act in the best interest of the firms 16 Conflicts generated by pay variance edit Incentives can have a bipolar effect on the company On the one hand the company s incentives to employees may create a pay gap For example low paid employees may reduce their production or contribution to the company Low paid employees and high paid employees may not be able to communicate and cooperate effectively causing low paid employees to gradually lose their enthusiasm for work 56 Firms should provide a fair amount of incentives for both low paid and other employees incentives for low paid workers can be breaks rather than monetary incentives Motivating employees with financial rewards may make a difference That s because if the company is profitable in the first year it may have plenty of bonuses to hand out to employees However if the company makes less money in the second year than it did in the first year the company may not be able to give employees the same bonuses as in the first year even though they put in the same effort This also reduces employees motivation to work Therefore incentives may be counterproductive Firm can provide other types of incentives rather than monetary incentives such as promotion or vacation breaks for high performing employees Incentives in the context of voluntary contributions editWhen it comes to volunteering activities monetary incentives can bring negative effects According to the Self perception theory humans constantly seek explanations for their behavior 57 When individuals are involved in volunteering activities they most likely perceive themselves as prosocial and altruistic and attach a symbolic price to the act of volunteering 58 59 When a monetary reward is attached to an otherwise prosocial activity such as volunteering people may perceive that their originally altruistic actions are now linked to extrinsic incentives 60 causing their self image benefit 61 and prosocial motivation to decrease 62 A crowding out effect leads to a decrease in individuals desire to volunteer and people eventually stop contributing due to the rewards attached For example if monetary incentives are offered for voluntary blood donation it will have a negative effect on the number of people donating blood 60 Incentives in education editExtrinsic incentives offered to unmotivated students can potentially have positive short run effects on education 52 However the use of extrinsic incentives in education has been opposed on the basis that they are morally corrupt and have the potential to crowd out intrinsic incentives for educational effort 52 Furthermore there is scarce empirical evidence to support the success of monetary incentives awarded for educational outputs such as academic achievement as opposed to educational inputs such as attendance and enrolment 63 The dynamic effects of incentives are evident in the context of education Studies have demonstrated that the impact of monetary incentives is dependent on previous academic performance and individual ability 64 Monetary incentives tend to improve the academic results of high ability students but have an adverse effect on the performance of students with lower aptitude 64 Conclusion editUltimately there is always potential for conflicts to arise both in the short and in the long run during the application of incentives in different areas as incentives that seek to change behaviors can crowd out intrinsic motivators A growing pool of evidence suggests that economists must broaden their focus when exploring the effects of incentives as the effect they have is largely dependent on how they are designed and specifically how they interact with intrinsic and social motivators in the short run and the long run 26 See also edit nbsp Look up incentive in Wiktionary the free dictionary Climate finance Climate Investment Funds Bounty reward Eco investing Environmental Quality Incentives Program Externality Incentive centered design Incentive payments Incentive program Incentive trust Incentivization Investment incentive Long term incentive plan Loyalty marketing Loyalty program Motivation Motivational salience Motivations of open source programmers Motivations for online participation Performance related pay Perverse incentive Positive incentive value Profit motive Research and Development Tax Incentive Reward system Social Impact Incentives Steering tax Tax incentive Travel incentive Wicked problemReferences edit a b Gneezy Uri 2011 When and Why Incentives Don t Work to Modify Behavior Journal of Economic Perspectives 25 4 191 doi 10 1257 jep 25 4 191 a b Gneezy Uri Meier Stephan Rey Biel Pedro Fall 2011 When and Why Incentives Don t Work to Modify Behavior Journal of Economic Perspectives 25 4 191 doi 10 1257 jep 25 4 191 Clark Peter B Wilson James Q 1961 Incentive Systems A Theory of Organizations Administrative Science Quarterly 6 2 129 166 doi 10 2307 2390752 ISSN 0001 8392 JSTOR 2390752 Masterclass Understanding Incentives in Economics 5 Common Types of Economic Incentives Masterclass Retrieved 2022 04 29 a b c d e f Lazear Edward P Shaw Kathryn L 2007 Personnel Economics The Economist s View of Human Resources PDF Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 4 91 114 doi 10 1257 jep 21 4 91 Li Pamela 19 April 2019 What is Intrinsic Motivation amp How Does it Work Parenting for Brain Retrieved 2022 04 29 Benati Igor Coccia Mario 2018 Rewards in Bureaucracy and Politics In Farazmand Ali ed Global Encyclopedia of Public Administration Public Policy and Governance Cham Springer International Publishing pp 1 6 doi 10 1007 978 3 319 31816 5 3417 1 ISBN 978 3 319 31816 5 S2CID 158421245 O Reilly C A Chatman J Caldwell D F September 1991 People and Organizational Culture A Profile Comparison Approach to Assessing Person Organization Fit Academy of Management Journal 34 3 487 516 doi 10 2307 256404 ISSN 0001 4273 JSTOR 256404 S2CID 45619898 Waqas Zafarullah Saleem Sharjeel 2014 11 01 The Effect of Monetary and Non Monetary Rewards on Employee Engagement and Firm Performance The International Institute for Science Technology and Education IISTE OCLC 1358510932 a b Behavioral Science Solutions Incentives Behavioral Economics Retrieved 2022 04 29 Callahan David 2004 The cheating culture Why more Americans are doing wrong to get ahead Harcourt ISBN 9780156030052 a b c d e Dalkir Kimiz 2011 Knowledge Management in Theory and Practice Second ed The MIT Press ISBN 9780262015080 a b c d Lazear Edward P Summer 2018 Compensation and Incentives in the Workplace Journal of Economic Perspectives 32 3 195 214 doi 10 1257 jep 32 3 195 ISSN 0895 3309 S2CID 158410132 a b Gneezy Uri Meier Stephan Rey Biel Pedro 2011 11 01 When and Why Incentives Don t Work to Modify Behavior Journal of Economic Perspectives 25 4 191 210 doi 10 1257 jep 25 4 191 ISSN 0895 3309 Pokorny Kathrin May 2008 Pay but do not pay too much An experimental study on the impact of incentives Journal of Economic Behavior amp Organization 66 2 251 264 doi 10 1016 j jebo 2006 03 007 ISSN 0167 2681 a b c d e f g h i Neilson William S 2007 Personnel Economics Pearson Education Inc p 11 ISBN 9780131488564 Camerer Colin F Hogarth Robin M Budescu David V Eckel Catherine 1999 The Effects of Financial Incentives in Experiments A Review and Capital Labor Production Framework In Fischhoff Baruch Manski Charles F eds Elicitation of Preferences Dordrecht Springer Netherlands pp 7 48 doi 10 1007 978 94 017 1406 8 2 ISBN 978 90 481 5776 1 Arnold R Bartlett S Bernat J Colonna J Dafoe D 2002 Financial incentives for cadaver organ donation an ethical reappraisal Transplantation 73 8 1361 1367 doi 10 1097 00007890 200204270 00034 PMID 11981440 S2CID 29823737 Pham V 2021 Cash Funeral Benefits or Nothing at All How to Incentivize Family Consent for Organ Donation PDF Review of Behavioral Economics 8 2 147 192 doi 10 1561 105 00000136 S2CID 237705443 Hooi L W Abdullah A A 2013 Relationships of Non Monetary Incentives Job Satisfaction and Employee Job Performance International Review of Management and Business Research 2 4 1085 1091 a b c d Lefebvre Mathieu Stenger Anne 2020 01 17 Short amp long term effects of monetary and non monetary incentives to cooperate in public good games An experiment PLOS ONE 15 1 e0227360 doi 10 1371 journal pone 0227360 ISSN 1932 6203 PMC 6968839 PMID 31951622 a b Burgess S 2003 06 01 The Role of Incentives in the Public Sector Issues and Evidence Oxford Review of Economic Policy 19 2 285 300 doi 10 1093 oxrep 19 2 285 ISSN 1460 2121 Cassar Lea Meier Stephan Summer 2018 Nonmonetary Incentives and the Implications of Work as a Source of Meaning Journal of Economic Perspectives 32 3 215 238 doi 10 1257 jep 32 3 215 ISSN 0895 3309 S2CID 52834710 Depedri Sara Tortia Ermanno C Carpita Maurizio 2010 Incentives Job Satisfaction and Performance Empirical Evidence in Italian Social Enterprises Euricse Working Papers N 012 10 SSRN 1698598 Jeffrey S 2004 The benefits of tangible non monetary incentives University of Chicago 702 77 a b Gneezy Uri Meier Stephan Rey Biel Pedro Fall 2011 When and Why Incentives Don t Work to Modify Behavior Journal of Economic Perspectives 25 4 206 doi 10 1257 jep 25 4 191 Lazear Edward P Shaw Kathryn L 2007 Personnel Economics The Economist s View of Human Resources PDF The Journal of Economic Perspectives American Economic Association 21 4 91 114 doi 10 1257 jep 21 4 91 JSTOR 30033753 Edmans Alex Fang Vivian W Huang Allen 2018 The Long Term Consequences of Short Term Incentives SSRN Electronic Journal doi 10 2139 ssrn 3037354 ISSN 1556 5068 S2CID 53073899 Prendergast Canice March 1999 The Provision of Incentives in Firms Journal of Economic Literature 37 1 7 63 doi 10 1257 jel 37 1 7 a b Asymmetric Information The Principal Agent Problem PDF Archived from the original PDF on 2015 11 23 Irlenbusch Bernd Sliwka Dirk September 2005 Incentives Decision Frames and Motivation Crowding Out an Experimental Investigation IZA Discussion Paper No 1758 doi 10 2139 ssrn 822866 hdl 10419 33245 S2CID 16424059 SSRN 822866 a b Braun Dietmar Guston David H October 2003 Principal agent theory and research policy an introduction PDF Science and Public Policy 30 5 302 308 doi 10 3152 147154303781780290 ISSN 0302 3427 S2CID 144005311 Waterman Richard W Meier Kenneth J 1998 Principal Agent Models An Expansion Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 8 2 173 202 doi 10 1093 oxfordjournals jpart a024377 Williamson Oliver E 1985 The economic institutions of capitalism firms markets relational contracting The Free Press ISBN 978 0 684 86374 0 OCLC 12216444 a b Jensen Michael C Murphy Kevin J Winter 2010 CEO Incentives It s Not How Much You Pay But How Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 22 1 64 76 doi 10 1111 j 1745 6622 2010 00262 x ISSN 1078 1196 S2CID 219968200 Prendergast Canice March 1999 The Provision of Incentives in Firms Journal of Economic Literature 37 1 14 15 doi 10 1257 jel 37 1 7 Bram Cadsby C Song F Tapon F April 2007 Sorting and Incentive Effects of Pay for Performance An Experimental Investigation The Academy of Management Journal 50 2 389 392 Dohmen T Folk A 2010 Yout Get What You Pay For Incentives and Selection in the Education System The Economic Journal 120 546 257 258 doi 10 1111 j 1468 0297 2010 02376 x JSTOR 40784482 S2CID 12928709 Franco Santos Monica Gomez Mejia Luis R 2015 Creating a culture of collaboration innovation and performance through team based incentives Team based incentives Creating a Culture of Collaboration Innovation and Performance The Compensation Handbook 6th ed McGraw Hill pp 199 209 DeMatteo J S Eby L T Sundstrom E 1998 Team based rewards Current empirical evidence and directions for future research Research in organizational behavior Vol 20 B M Staw amp L L Cummings ed Elsevier Science JAI Press pp 141 183 Beersma B Hollenbeck J R Humphrey S E Moon H Conlon D E Ilgen D R 2003 Cooperation Competition and Team Performance Towards a Contingency Approach Academy of Management Journal 46 5 572 590 doi 10 2139 ssrn 325401 ISSN 0001 4273 SSRN 325401 Kruse Douglas May 2022 December 2016 Does employee ownership improve performance IZA World of Labor 311 doi 10 15185 izawol 311 hdl 10419 148536 ISSN 2054 9571 Hamilton Barton H Nickerson Jack A Owan Hideo June 2003 Team Incentives and Worker Heterogeneity An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Teams on Productivity and Participation Journal of Political Economy 111 3 465 497 doi 10 1086 374182 ISSN 0022 3808 S2CID 11969481 a b Gerhart Barry Rynes Sara L Fulmer Ingrid Smithey January 2009 6 Pay and Performance Individuals Groups and Executives Academy of Management Annals 3 1 251 315 doi 10 5465 19416520903047269 ISSN 1941 6520 Holmstrom Bengt 1982 Moral Hazard in Teams The Bell Journal of Economics 13 2 325 328 doi 10 2307 3003457 JSTOR 3003457 Alchian A Demsetz H 1972 Production Information Costs and Economic Organization The American Economic Review 62 5 779 781 JSTOR 1815199 a b Frederiksen A Hansen D Manchester C 2022 Does Group Based Incentive Pay Lead To Higher Productivity Evidence from a Complex and Interdependent Industrial Production Process IZA Institute of Labor Economics 2 4 Kandel E Lazear E 1992 Peer Pressure and Partnerships Journal of Political Economy 100 4 803 811 doi 10 1086 261840 JSTOR 2138688 S2CID 16757647 Hashim Matthew J Bockstedt Jesse C 5 8 January 2015 Overcoming Free Riding in Information Goods Sanctions or Rewards 2015 48th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences Kauai HI USA IEEE pp 4834 4843 doi 10 1109 hicss 2015 574 a b Kanemoto Yoshitsugu MacLeod W Bentley 1992 The Ratchet Effect and the Market for Secondhand Workers Journal of Labor Economics University of Chicago Press 10 1 85 98 doi 10 1086 298279 JSTOR 2535130 S2CID 154244118 Cooper David J Kagel John H Lo Wei Gu Qing Liang 1999 Gaming against Managers in Incentive Systems Experimental Results with Chinese Students and Chinese Managers PDF The American Economic Review 89 4 781 804 doi 10 1257 aer 89 4 781 ISSN 0002 8282 JSTOR 117159 a b c d Gneezy Uri Meier Stephan Rey Biel Pedro Fall 2011 When and Why Incentives Don t Work to Modify Behavior Journal of Economic Perspectives 25 4 192 doi 10 1257 jep 25 4 191 Ariely Dan Gneezy Uri Loewenstein George Mazar Nina 2009 Large Stakes and Big Mistakes PDF The Review of Economic Studies 76 2 451 469 doi 10 1111 j 1467 937X 2009 00534 x Retrieved 3 May 2022 Chiappori Salanie 2003 Testing contract theory a survey of some recent work In M Dewatripont L Hansen S Turnovsky eds Advances in Economics and Econometrics PDF Vol 1 Cambridge Cambridge University Press pp 115 149 doi 10 1017 CBO9780511610240 005 ISBN 9780511610240 S2CID 3067063 a b c Jain Abha 2019 Sports Psychology India Friends Publications p 215 ISBN 978 93 88457 75 0 Breza Emily Kaur Supreet Shamdasani Yogita 10 October 2017 The Morale Effects of Pay Inequality The Quarterly Journal of Economics 133 2 611 663 doi 10 1093 qje qjx041 Bem Daryl J 1972 Self Perception Theory In Leonard Berkowitz ed Advances in Experimental Social Psychology Vol 6 Academic Press pp 1 62 doi 10 1016 s0065 2601 08 60024 6 ISBN 9780120152063 Frey Bruno S Jegen Reto December 2001 Motivation Crowding Theory Journal of Economic Surveys 15 5 589 611 doi 10 1111 1467 6419 00150 ISSN 0950 0804 Heyman James Ariely Dan November 2004 Effort for Payment Psychological Science 15 11 787 793 doi 10 1111 j 0956 7976 2004 00757 x ISSN 0956 7976 PMID 15482452 S2CID 8573184 a b Bolle Friedel Otto Philipp E February 2010 A Price Is a Signal on Intrinsic Motivation Crowding out and Crowding in Kyklos 63 1 9 22 doi 10 1111 j 1467 6435 2010 00458 x ISSN 0023 5962 S2CID 154039981 Brekke Kjell Arne Kverndokk Snorre Nyborg Karine September 2003 An economic model of moral motivation Journal of Public Economics 87 9 10 1967 1983 doi 10 1016 s0047 2727 01 00222 5 hdl 10419 192272 ISSN 0047 2727 Qiao Dandan Lee Shun Yang Whinston Andrew B Wei Qiang 2021 01 02 Mitigating the Adverse Effect of Monetary Incentives on Voluntary Contributions Online Journal of Management Information Systems 38 1 82 107 doi 10 1080 07421222 2021 1870385 ISSN 0742 1222 S2CID 232765666 Fryer Roland November 2011 Financial Incentives and Student Achievement Evidence from Randomized Trials The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 4 1758 doi 10 1093 qje qjr045 a b Leuven E Osteerbeck H van der Klaauw B 2010 The Effect of Financial Rewards on Students Achievement Evidence from a Randomized Experiment Journal of the European Economic Association 8 6 1259 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Incentive amp oldid 1204668614, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.