fbpx
Wikipedia

Era of Stagnation

The "Era of Stagnation" (Russian: Пери́од засто́я, romanizedPeríod zastóya, or Эпо́ха засто́я Epókha zastóya) is a term coined by Mikhail Gorbachev in order to describe the negative way in which he viewed the economic, political, and social policies of the Soviet Union that began during the rule of Leonid Brezhnev (1964–1982) and continued under Yuri Andropov (1982–1984) and Konstantin Chernenko (1984–1985).[1][2] It is sometimes called the "Brezhnevian Stagnation" in English.

Terminology edit

During the period of Brezhnev's leadership, the term "Era of Stagnation" was not used. Instead in Soviet ideology the term "period of developed socialism" (Russian: пери́од развито́го социали́зма) was used for the period that started in 1967. The latter Soviet concept was officially declared at the 24th Congress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union in 1971. It stemmed from the failure of Khrushchev's promise in 1961 of reaching communism in 20 years[3] and was a replacement of the concept "period of the extensive construction of communism" ("период развёрнутого строительства коммунизма"). It was in the 1980s that the Soviet leader Mikhail Gorbachev coined the term "Era of Stagnation" to describe the economic difficulties that developed when Leonid Brezhnev led the Soviet Union from 1964 to 1982.[4] Scholars have subsequently disagreed on the dates, significance and causes of the stagnation. Supporters of Gorbachev have criticised Brezhnev, and the Brezhnev administration in general, for being too conservative and failing to change with the times.[5]

History edit

After the death of Soviet leader Joseph Stalin in 1953, a program of policy change was begun, later known as de-Stalinization. Nikita Khrushchev, who succeeded Stalin's brief successor Georgy Malenkov as Soviet leader, introduced relatively liberal reforms during the period known as the Khrushchev Thaw. This period also brought an economic increase that topped at 6%. The Manege Affair of 1962, during which Khrushchev publicly criticised an exhibition of Soviet art, led to the reassertion of Communist Party control over the arts and marked the beginning of the end of the Cultural Thaw.[6]

Brezhnev replaced Khrushchev as Soviet leader in 1964. The Brezhnev Era (1964–1982) began with high economic growth and soaring prosperity, but gradually significant problems in social, political, and economic areas accumulated. Social stagnation began following Brezhnev's rise to power, when he revoked several of Khrushchev's reforms and partially rehabilitated Stalinist policies. Some commentators regard the start of social stagnation as being the Sinyavsky–Daniel trial in 1966, in which two writers were convicted of anti-Soviet agitation and which marked the end of the Khrushchev Thaw.[7] Others place it at the time of the Warsaw Pact invasion of Czechoslovakia in 1968 that suppressed the Prague Spring.[8] The period's political stagnation is associated with the establishment of gerontocracy, which came into being as part of the policy of stability.

The majority of scholars set the starting year for economic stagnation at 1975, although some claim that it began as early as the 1960s. Industrial growth rates declined during the 1970s as heavy industry and the arms industry were prioritized while Soviet consumer goods were neglected.[9] The value of all consumer goods manufactured in 1972 in retail prices was about 118 billion roubles.[10] Historians, scholars, and specialists are uncertain what caused the stagnation, with some arguing that the command economy suffered from systemic flaws that inhibited growth. Others have argued that the lack of reform, or the high expenditures on the military, led to stagnation.

Brezhnev has been criticised posthumously for doing too little to improve the economic situation. Throughout his rule, no major reforms were initiated and the few proposed reforms were either very modest or opposed by the majority of the Soviet leadership. The reform-minded Chairman of the Council of Ministers (Government), Alexei Kosygin, introduced two modest reforms in the 1970s after the failure of his more radical 1965 reform, and attempted to reverse the trend of declining growth. By the 1970s, Brezhnev had consolidated enough power to stop any "radical" reform-minded attempts by Kosygin.

After the death of Brezhnev in November 1982, Yuri Andropov succeeded him as Soviet leader. Brezhnev's legacy was a Soviet Union that was much less dynamic than it had been when he assumed power in 1964. During Andropov's short rule, modest reforms were introduced; he died little more than a year later in February 1984. Konstantin Chernenko, his successor, continued much of Andropov's policies. The economic problems that began under Brezhnev persisted into these short administrations and scholars still debate whether the reform policies that were followed improved the economic situation in the country.

The Era of Stagnation ended with Gorbachev's rise to power during which political and social life was democratised[11][12] even though the economy was still stagnating.[13] Under Gorbachev's leadership the Communist Party began efforts to accelerate economic development in 1985 through massive injections of finance into heavy industry (Uskoreniye). When these failed, the Communist Party restructured (perestroika) the Soviet economy and government by introducing quasi-capitalist (Khozraschyot) and democratic (demokratizatsiya) reforms. These were intended to re-energize the Soviet Union but inadvertently led to its dissolution in 1991.

Economy edit

Analysis edit

Robert Service, author of the History of Modern Russia: From Tsarism to the Twenty-first Century, claims that with mounting economic problems worker discipline decreased,[14] which the government could not counter effectively because of the full employment policy. According to Service, this policy led to government industries, such as factories, mines and offices, being staffed by undisciplined and unproductive personnel ultimately leading to a "work-shy workforce" among Soviet workers and administrators.[15] While the Soviet Union under Brezhnev had the "second greatest industrial capacity" after the United States, and produced more "steel, oil, pig-iron, cement and ... tractors" than any other country in the world,[16] Service treats the problems of agriculture during the Brezhnev era as proof of the need for de-collectivization.[17] In short, Service considers the Soviet economy to have become "static" during this time period,[18] and Brezhnev's policy of stability was a "recipe for political disaster".[19]

Richard Sakwa, author of the book The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Union: 1917–1991, takes a dimmer view of the Brezhnev era by claiming that growth rates fell "inexorably" from the 1950s until they stopped completely in the 1980s. His reasoning for this stagnation was the growing demand for unskilled workers resulted in a decline of productivity and labour discipline. Sakwa believes that stability itself led to stagnation and claimed that without strong leadership "Soviet socialism had a tendency to relapse into stagnation."[20]

According to Edwin Bacon and Mark Sandle, authors of Brezhnev Reconsidered, the economy under Brezhnev was as dynamic as the economy presided over by Nikita Khrushchev, but this dynamism had stalled by the time Yuri Andropov, and subsequently Konstantin Chernenko, became General Secretary.[21] Mark Harrison claims that the economic performance of the Brezhnev era has not been looked at objectively as analysis of the period sometimes used lower estimates.[22] Harrison further claims that in the period between 1928 and 1973 the Soviet economy grew in a phase that would surpass the United States "one day". During the international oil crisis, growth in the Soviet Union and the Eastern Bloc halted abruptly and stalled for a longer period than in the West[23] causing the economy to begin stagnating.[24] One explanation, according to Harrison, is that the Soviet economy could not sustain its extensive growth patterns.[25] Other explanations include: the lack of Soviet, and communist bloc, transparency with other nations hindering globalisation[26] and misinterpretation of a "permanent" post–World War II economic boom leading to faulty economic decisions.[27] He claims that the economic policies of Andropov, and Chernenko, had improved the economic situation in the country and Mikhail Gorbachev inherited a more dynamic and vibrant economy in a "pre-crisis situation" where the economy was still growing with low internal and external debts, compared to the economy that Andropov and Chernenko inherited.[28]

Archie Brown, author of The Rise and Fall of Communism, claims in his book that the term Era of Stagnation "was in many ways a fitting description, for this was a period of declining growth", but noted it could be misleading in non-economic spheres.[29] Brown states there were high growth rates in the mid-to-late 1960s (during the Eighth Five-Year Plan) claiming that the Soviet economy "enjoyed stronger growth in the second half of the 1960s than it ever did thereafter". The link between these growth rates and the Kosygin reform is, according to Brown, "tenuous",[30] but says that "From the point of view of communist rulers, the Brezhnev era was in many ways successful".[31] The Soviet Unions natural resources provided a strong economic foundation, which bore fruit during the 1973 oil crisis and "turned out to be an energy bonanza".[32] On the other hand, Brown states it was a sign of weakness that the Soviet Union grew so dependent on her natural resources, as she did in the 1970s.[31]

 
Scholars are generally unsure as to what effect the "Kosygin reform", named after its initiator Alexei Kosygin, had on economic growth

Philip Hanson, author of The Rise and Fall of the Soviet economy: an Economic History of the USSR from 1945, claims that the label stagnation is not "entirely unfair". Brezhnev, according to Hanson, did preside over a period of slowdown in economic growth, but claims that the era started with good growth that was at a higher rate than during the end of Khrushchev's rule. Economic slowdown began in 1973 "when even the official estimates began to show Soviet per capita production no longer closing the gap with the US." Before 1973, there was a reform period launched by Alexei Kosygin, which many believed would become as radical as those in the Socialist Republic of Czechoslovakia and the previous reform attempts in Hungary.[33] According to Hanson, many assumed that growth during the Brezhnev era did not stop but started to stagnate.[34] Not everything stagnated, as per capita consumption grew by 1.9% during the 1970s, which is a "highly respectable rate" of growth. Another point that Hanson makes is that, in contrast to the repressive policies of Joseph Stalin and instability-inducing policies of Khrushchev, the Brezhnev era was stable and a "period of (comparative) plenty".[35]

Robert Vincent Daniels in his book, Russia's Transformation: Snapshots of a Crumbling System, claimed that the hallmark of the Brezhnev era was the status quo, which in turn led to the development of a great paradox; "the contradictions of what it was and what it could be became obvious". Net growth, in excess of 50% and as high as two thirds, was primarily in the urban sector resulting in high population growth and urban growth higher than that of the United States. Industrial development continued to grow rapidly, and in certain sectors surpassed the United States.[36] As an example, coal production in the Soviet Union increased from 85 million metric tons in 1964 to 149 million metric tons in 1981 while in the United States it grew from 100 million to 130 million metric tons in the same period.[37] The Soviet Union became the largest exporter of petroleum in the world and by the end of the Tenth Five-Year Plan (1976–1981) the Soviet GNP "reached about 60% of the American level, and the net current investment was actually greater in absolute terms". The failure then, according to Daniels, was that the Soviet economy was not able to deliver in certain sectors; agriculture is a sector where this failure occurred. Throughout Soviet history, deficiencies in agriculture and consumer goods always existed. During Brezhnev's reign, the Soviet Union became the largest producer of wheat in the world but was unable to produce meat in sufficient quantities.[38] According to Daniels, the economy began to stagnate in 1975 rather than 1973 and that the following period contradicted the previous one "in almost every way".[39]

The research in second economy of the Soviet Union, pioneered by Gregory Grossman, indicated that during 1970s-1980s the effects of the central planning were progressively distorted due to the rapid growth of the shadow economy. It is suggested that failure to account for it by Gosplan contributed to the stagnation, and ultimately to the collapse of the Soviet economy.[40]

Causes edit

One of the suggested causes of stagnation was the increased military expenditure over consumer goods and other economic spheres.[41] Andrei Sakharov, the veteran dissident, claimed in a 1980 letter to Brezhnev that the increasing expenditure on the armed forces was stalling economic growth.[42] David Michael Kotz and Fred Weir, authors of Revolution from Above: The Demise of the Soviet System, argue that militarisation cannot be the prime cause for the economic stagnation, as military spending had historically been high (17% of GNP in 1950) and had increased on par with economic growth without previously destabilising the economy.[citation needed]

During the Nixon Shock and the 1973 oil crisis, economic growth in the rest of the world plummeted but the Soviet hard currency earnings grew as a result of oil exports. Following the crisis, overall economic activity decreased markedly in the Soviet Union, the Western Bloc and Japan, but in the Soviet Union it was much more pronounced. Kotz and Weir argued that ultimately, economic stagnation in the Soviet Union could only have been caused by internal problems rather than external.[43]

Some Marxist–Leninist writers have argued that economic stagnation was a result of revisionism in Soviet economic policy during Khrushchev's leadership. According to authors like Harpal Brar, Khrushchev's de-Stalinization program was also used to implement economic reforms that would move the USSR away from central planning and towards market socialism.[44]

Summary edit

Period Growth rates
GNP
(according to
the CIA)
NMP
(according to
G. I. Khanin)
NMP
(according to
the USSR)
1960–1965 4.8 4.4 6.5
1965–1970 4.9 4.1 7.7
1970–1975 3.0 3.2 5.7
1975–1980 1.9 1.0 4.2
1980–1985 1.8 0.6 3.5

One of the main causes for Khrushchev's dismissal from power was the relatively poor economic growth during the early 1960s. Overall economic growth was 6% from 1951 to 1955 but had fallen to 5.8% in the subsequent 5 years and to 5% from 1961 to 1965. Labour productivity, which had grown 4.7% from the 1950s to 1962, had declined to 4% by the early 1960s. Growth, capital out and investments were all showing signs of steady decline.[54] Another problem was Khrushchev's unrealistic promises such as committing to reach communism in 20 years, a near impossibility with the then-current economic indicators.[3] Ultimately, as a result of his failure to deliver on his promises and the problems engendered, Khrushchev was dismissed in October 1964[55] by a collective leadership led by Leonid Brezhnev and Alexei Kosygin. To counter Khrushchev's promise of reaching communism, the Soviet leadership created the term developed socialism, which meant that the Soviet Union had developed to a sufficiently advanced stage that the country would move "naturally" to communism (in an unspecified amount of time).[56]

Khrushchev's dismissal led to the establishment of a more conservative Politburo; Kosygin, Nikolai Podgorny and Andrei Kirilenko were the most liberal members, Brezhnev and Arvīds Pelše belonged to the moderate faction while Mikhail Suslov retained his leadership of the party's hardliners.[57] Kosygin and Brezhnev strongly disagreed over economic policy; Kosygin wanted to increase investments in consumer goods and light industry whereas Brezhnev wanted to increase investment in heavy industry, agriculture and defence.[58] In 1965, Kosygin introduced an economic reform, widely referred to as the "Kosygin reform", which aimed to reform the planned economy within a socialist framework. In a bid to improve the Soviet economy Kosygin copied some of the measures used in the Western Bloc, such as profit making,[59] which Brezhnev agreed to as the Soviet economy was entering a period of low growth.[60] Kosygin's reforms on agriculture gave considerable autonomy to the collective farms, giving them the right to the contents of private farming. As a result, during the Eighth Five-Year Plan (1966–1970), large-scale land reclamation programmes, construction of irrigation channels, and other measures, were enacted.[61][note 2] Overall, the reform failed and links to any high growth rates during the Eighth Five-Year Plan are considered to be "tenuous".[62]

The Brezhnev era, which had begun with high growth, began to stagnate some time in the early 1970s. Kosygin's "radical" reform attempts were halted in 1971 and his second reform was more modest. The second reform was halted because of the 1973 oil crisis, when an international increase in the price of oil prompted economic growth based on selling oil. Another reform was implemented in 1979 but this, too, failed as by this time the Soviet economy had become "addicted" to high oil prices.[61]

In 1980, RIA Novosti reported that the Soviet Union showed the highest, in Europe, and second highest, worldwide, industrial and agricultural output. The Soviet statistics claimed that in 1960, the Soviet Union's industrial output was only 55% that of America, but this increased to 80% by 1980.[61] The 18 years of Brezhnev's leadership of the Communist Party saw real incomes grow by more than 1.5 times.[61] More than 1.6 billion square meters of living space was commissioned and provided to over 160 million people. At the same time, the average rent for families did not exceed 3% of the family income. Housing, health care, and education were affordable and low priced. As the circulation of the work force could not be balanced by salaries, there was a lack of workers in some areas, largely in the agricultural sector. This was partly solved by forcing "nonproductive" urban population (older pupils, students, scientists, soldiers, etc.) to work during the harvesting time as agricultural workers. The practice has been informally called "naryady na kartoshku" (Russian: наряды на картошку "assignments to potato fields").[61]

Opposition edit

Acts of protest took place in reaction to the Warsaw Pact invasion of Czechoslovakia with protesters being dismissed from their jobs, beaten or arrested.[63] Eight protesters held a demonstration in Red Square in Moscow and were subsequently imprisoned.[64] A number of suspected dissidents had their homes and property searched[65] and a group of Moscow lawyers specialised in defending people charged with anti-Soviet activity.[66] Supporters of these meetings and demonstrations claimed that the arrests were illegal, because there is no criminality in the realization of the human right to obtain and distribute information. They asserted this right was part of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights (1948)[67] and the final act of the Conference on Security and Co-operation in Europe (1975).[68]

During the introduction of glasnost, many writers claimed that they did not know about the repression of citizens who did not support the Brezhnev politics.[69] Artists propagating "Soviet values" within the framework of socialist realism formed a well-paid, elite group that enjoyed an easy life and high social status. Nevertheless, a noticeable part of Soviet scientists and artists (collectively known as "the dissidents") continued both open and clandestine political opposition to the regime that they began during the Khrushchev rule. Prominent nuclear physicist Andrey Sakharov and Soviet Army General Pyotr Grigorenko are well-known representatives of this movement. Many other members of the Soviet intelligentsia systematically criticized the social and moral manifestations of the Stagnation without overtly challenging the authorities. Examples include writers Viktor Astafyev and Oles Honchar, playwright Grigory Gorin, directors Eldar Ryazanov and Mark Zakharov.

See also edit

References edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ Many economists argue that the net material product (NMP), the Soviet version of the gross national product (GNP), contained distortions and could not accurately determine a country's economic growth. Because of this, several specialists created GNP figures to estimate Soviet growth rates and to compare Soviet growth rates with the growth rates of capitalist countries.[46] Grigorii Khanin published his growth rates in the 1980s as a "translation" of NMP to GNP. His growth rates were (as seen above) much lower than the official figures, and lower than some Western estimates.[47] After the dissolution of the Soviet Union in 1991, Khanin's estimates led several agencies criticise the estimates made by the Central Intelligence Agency (CIA). Since then, the CIA has generally been regarded as having overestimated Soviet growth. In response to the criticism of CIA's work, a panel led by economist James R. Millar, was established to check out if this was in fact true. The panel concluded that the CIA were based on facts, and that Khanin's approach was methodologically naive, as it has not been possible for others to reproduce his results.[48] Growth figures for the Soviet economy varies widely (as seen below if compared to those at the table above):
    Eighth Five-Year Plan (1966–1970) Ninth Five-Year Plan (1971–1975)
    • GNP: 3.7%[49]
    • GNI: 5.1%[51]
    • Labour productivity: 6%[53]
    • Capital investments in agriculture: 27%[52]
    Tenth Five-Year Plan (1976–1980) Eleventh Five-Year Plan (1981–1985)
  2. ^ According to Soviet statistics, there were significant improvements made in the economy during the Eighth Five-Year Plan (1966–1970). The economy grew by 7.7% during the Eighth Five-Year Plan but slowed during the Ninth Five-Year Plan (1971–1975) and Tenth Five-Year Plan (1976–1981) when the economy grew by 5.7 and 4.2, respectively.[61]

References edit

  1. ^ "The World Factbook". Cia.gov. Retrieved 7 September 2015.
  2. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, pp. 1–2.
  3. ^ a b Dowlah & Elliott 1997, pp. 148–149.
  4. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 1.
  5. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 2.
  6. ^ Reid, Susan Emily (2005). "In the Name of the People: The Manege Affair Revisited". Kritika: Explorations in Russian and Eurasian History. Slavica Publishers. 6 (4): 673–716. doi:10.1353/kri.2005.0058. S2CID 159693587.
  7. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 143.
  8. ^ Bischof, Günter; Karner, Stefan; Ruggenthaler, Peter (2010). The Prague Spring and the Warsaw Pact invasion of Czechoslovakia in 1968. Rowman & Littlefield. p. 92. ISBN 978-0-7391-4304-9.
  9. ^ "1964-1982 – The Period of Stagnation". GlobalSecurity.org. Retrieved 2 August 2017.
  10. ^ Gillula, James W. (1983). The Reconstructed 1972 Input-output Tables for Eight Soviet Republics (Manufactured goods sector was worth 118 billion roubles in 1972). U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. Retrieved 2 January 2016.
  11. ^ Khazanov, Anatoly M. (1992). "Soviet Social Thought in the Period of Stagnation". Philosophy of the Social Sciences. SAGE Publications. 22 (2): 231–237. doi:10.1177/004839319202200205.
  12. ^ Grant, Ted (22 September 2006). . In Defence of Marxism (Part 6). Archived from the original on 6 February 2009. Retrieved 31 December 2011.
  13. ^ Service 2009, p. 427.
  14. ^ Service 2009, p. 416.
  15. ^ Service 2009, p. 417.
  16. ^ Service 2009, p. 397.
  17. ^ Service 2009, p. 402.
  18. ^ Service 2009, p. 407.
  19. ^ Service 2009, p. 409.
  20. ^ Sakwa, Richard (1999). The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Union: 1917–1991. Routledge. p. 339. ISBN 0-415-12290-2.
  21. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 38.
  22. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, pp. 43–44.
  23. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, pp. 44–45.
  24. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 47.
  25. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 53.
  26. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, pp. 50–51.
  27. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 54.
  28. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 63.
  29. ^ Brown 2009, p. 398.
  30. ^ Brown 2009, p. 403.
  31. ^ a b Brown 2009, p. 415.
  32. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, pp. 415–416.
  33. ^ Hanson 2003, p. 98.
  34. ^ Hanson 2003, pp. 98–99.
  35. ^ Hanson 2003, p. 99.
  36. ^ Daniels 1998, p. 46.
  37. ^ Daniels 1998, pp. 47–48.
  38. ^ Daniels 1998, p. 47.
  39. ^ Daniels 1998, p. 49.
  40. ^ Vladimir G. Treml and Michael V. Alexeev, "The Second Economy And The Destabilizing Effect Of Its Growth On The State Economy In The Soviet Union : 1965-1989", Berkeley-Duke Occasional Papers On The Second Economy In The Ussr, Paper No. 36, December 1993
  41. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 28.
  42. ^ Volkogonov, Dmitri; Shukman, Harold (1999). Autopsy for an Empire: The Seven Leaders Who Built the Soviet Regime. Simon & Schuster. p. 262. ISBN 978-0-684-87112-7.
  43. ^ Kotz, David Michael; Weir, Fred (1997). Revolution from Above: The Demise of the Soviet System. Routledge. p. 48. ISBN 978-0-415-14317-2.
  44. ^ Brar, Harpal (1992). Perestroika: The Complete Collapse of Revisionism. H. Brar. ISBN 1-874613-01-X.
  45. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 40.
  46. ^ Kotz & Weir 2007, p. 35.
  47. ^ Harrison, M. (1993). "Soviet economic growth since 1928: The alternative statistics of G. I. Khanin". Europe-Asia Studies. 45 (1): 141–167. doi:10.1080/09668139308412080.
  48. ^ Kotz & Weir 2007, p. 39.
  49. ^ a b c Kort, Michael (2010). The Soviet Colossus: History and Aftermath. M.E. Sharpe. p. 322. ISBN 978-0-7656-2387-4.
  50. ^ a b Bergson, Abram (1985). The Soviet economy: Toward the year 2000. Taylor & Francis. p. 192. ISBN 978-0-04-335053-9.
  51. ^ a b Pallot, Judith; Shaw, Denis (1981). Planning in the Soviet Union. Taylor & Francis. p. 51. ISBN 978-0-85664-571-6.
  52. ^ a b Wegren, Stephen (1998). Agriculture and the State in Soviet and Post-Soviet Russia. University of Pittsburgh Press. p. 252. ISBN 978-0-8229-8585-3.
  53. ^ a b Arnot, Bob (1988). Controlling Soviet Labour: Experimental Change from Brezhnev to Gorbachev. M.E. Sharpe. p. 67. ISBN 0-87332-470-6.
  54. ^ Dowlah & Elliott 1997, p. 148.
  55. ^ Dowlah & Elliott 1997, p. 149.
  56. ^ Dowlah & Elliott 1997, p. 146.
  57. ^ Law, David A. (1975). Russian Civilization. New York: Ardent Media. p. 221. ISBN 0-8422-0529-2.
  58. ^ Zemtsov, Ilya (1989). Chernenko: The Last Bolshevik: The Soviet Union on the Eve of Perestroika. Transaction Publishers. p. 86. ISBN 0-88738-260-6.
  59. ^ Moss, Walter (2005). A History of Russia: Since 1855. London: Anthem Press. p. 431. ISBN 978-1-84331-034-1.
  60. ^ Chauhan, Sharad (2004). Inside CIA: Lessons in Intelligence. APH Publishing. p. 207. ISBN 81-7648-660-4.
  61. ^ a b c d e f "Советская экономика в эпоху Леонида Брежнева" [The Soviet economy in the era of Leonid Brezhnev]. RIA Novosti. 8 November 2010. Retrieved 31 December 2011.
  62. ^ Bacon & Sandle 2002, p. 58.
  63. ^ [Chronicle of Current Events: Issue 3]. memo.ru (in Russian). 30 August 1968. Archived from the original on 29 September 2012. Retrieved 2 January 2016.
  64. ^ Andrew Roth (9 August 2018). "Nearly half of Russians ignorant of 1968's Czechoslovakia invasion – poll". The Guardian.
  65. ^ [Chronicle of Current Events: Issue 4]. memo.ru (in Russian). 31 October 1968. Archived from the original on 4 February 2017. Retrieved 2 January 2016.
  66. ^ . 10 July 1970. Archived from the original on 11 March 2007.
  67. ^ Universal Declaration of Human Rights, resolution 217 A (III), accepted 10 Dec. 1948.
  68. ^ "Conference On Security And Co-Operation In Europe Final Act". Helsinki: OSCE. 1 August 1975. Retrieved 27 February 2016.
  69. ^ Sofia Kallistratova. We were not silent! – open letter to writer Chingiz Aitmatov, in Russian. С. В. Калистратова. Открытое письмо писателю Чингизу Айтматову 2007-09-26 at the Wayback Machine, 5 мая 1988 г.

Bibliography edit

External links edit

  • By Ted Grant
  • The Decline of the Soviet Union: A Hypothesis on Industrial Paradigms, Technological Revolutions and the Roots of Perestroika by Angelo Segrillo
Preceded by History of Russia
History of the Soviet Union

14 October 1964 – 10 March 1985
Succeeded by

stagnation, russian, Пери, од, засто, romanized, períod, zastóya, Эпо, ха, засто, epókha, zastóya, term, coined, mikhail, gorbachev, order, describe, negative, which, viewed, economic, political, social, policies, soviet, union, that, began, during, rule, leon. The Era of Stagnation Russian Peri od zasto ya romanized Period zastoya or Epo ha zasto ya Epokha zastoya is a term coined by Mikhail Gorbachev in order to describe the negative way in which he viewed the economic political and social policies of the Soviet Union that began during the rule of Leonid Brezhnev 1964 1982 and continued under Yuri Andropov 1982 1984 and Konstantin Chernenko 1984 1985 1 2 It is sometimes called the Brezhnevian Stagnation in English Contents 1 Terminology 2 History 3 Economy 3 1 Analysis 3 2 Causes 3 3 Summary 4 Opposition 5 See also 6 References 6 1 Notes 6 2 References 6 3 Bibliography 7 External linksTerminology editDuring the period of Brezhnev s leadership the term Era of Stagnation was not used Instead in Soviet ideology the term period of developed socialism Russian peri od razvito go sociali zma was used for the period that started in 1967 The latter Soviet concept was officially declared at the 24th Congress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union in 1971 It stemmed from the failure of Khrushchev s promise in 1961 of reaching communism in 20 years 3 and was a replacement of the concept period of the extensive construction of communism period razvyornutogo stroitelstva kommunizma It was in the 1980s that the Soviet leader Mikhail Gorbachev coined the term Era of Stagnation to describe the economic difficulties that developed when Leonid Brezhnev led the Soviet Union from 1964 to 1982 4 Scholars have subsequently disagreed on the dates significance and causes of the stagnation Supporters of Gorbachev have criticised Brezhnev and the Brezhnev administration in general for being too conservative and failing to change with the times 5 History editThis section needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Era of Stagnation news newspapers books scholar JSTOR July 2021 Learn how and when to remove this template message After the death of Soviet leader Joseph Stalin in 1953 a program of policy change was begun later known as de Stalinization Nikita Khrushchev who succeeded Stalin s brief successor Georgy Malenkov as Soviet leader introduced relatively liberal reforms during the period known as the Khrushchev Thaw This period also brought an economic increase that topped at 6 The Manege Affair of 1962 during which Khrushchev publicly criticised an exhibition of Soviet art led to the reassertion of Communist Party control over the arts and marked the beginning of the end of the Cultural Thaw 6 Brezhnev replaced Khrushchev as Soviet leader in 1964 The Brezhnev Era 1964 1982 began with high economic growth and soaring prosperity but gradually significant problems in social political and economic areas accumulated Social stagnation began following Brezhnev s rise to power when he revoked several of Khrushchev s reforms and partially rehabilitated Stalinist policies Some commentators regard the start of social stagnation as being the Sinyavsky Daniel trial in 1966 in which two writers were convicted of anti Soviet agitation and which marked the end of the Khrushchev Thaw 7 Others place it at the time of the Warsaw Pact invasion of Czechoslovakia in 1968 that suppressed the Prague Spring 8 The period s political stagnation is associated with the establishment of gerontocracy which came into being as part of the policy of stability The majority of scholars set the starting year for economic stagnation at 1975 although some claim that it began as early as the 1960s Industrial growth rates declined during the 1970s as heavy industry and the arms industry were prioritized while Soviet consumer goods were neglected 9 The value of all consumer goods manufactured in 1972 in retail prices was about 118 billion roubles 10 Historians scholars and specialists are uncertain what caused the stagnation with some arguing that the command economy suffered from systemic flaws that inhibited growth Others have argued that the lack of reform or the high expenditures on the military led to stagnation Brezhnev has been criticised posthumously for doing too little to improve the economic situation Throughout his rule no major reforms were initiated and the few proposed reforms were either very modest or opposed by the majority of the Soviet leadership The reform minded Chairman of the Council of Ministers Government Alexei Kosygin introduced two modest reforms in the 1970s after the failure of his more radical 1965 reform and attempted to reverse the trend of declining growth By the 1970s Brezhnev had consolidated enough power to stop any radical reform minded attempts by Kosygin After the death of Brezhnev in November 1982 Yuri Andropov succeeded him as Soviet leader Brezhnev s legacy was a Soviet Union that was much less dynamic than it had been when he assumed power in 1964 During Andropov s short rule modest reforms were introduced he died little more than a year later in February 1984 Konstantin Chernenko his successor continued much of Andropov s policies The economic problems that began under Brezhnev persisted into these short administrations and scholars still debate whether the reform policies that were followed improved the economic situation in the country The Era of Stagnation ended with Gorbachev s rise to power during which political and social life was democratised 11 12 even though the economy was still stagnating 13 Under Gorbachev s leadership the Communist Party began efforts to accelerate economic development in 1985 through massive injections of finance into heavy industry Uskoreniye When these failed the Communist Party restructured perestroika the Soviet economy and government by introducing quasi capitalist Khozraschyot and democratic demokratizatsiya reforms These were intended to re energize the Soviet Union but inadvertently led to its dissolution in 1991 Economy editAnalysis edit Robert Service author of the History of Modern Russia From Tsarism to the Twenty first Century claims that with mounting economic problems worker discipline decreased 14 which the government could not counter effectively because of the full employment policy According to Service this policy led to government industries such as factories mines and offices being staffed by undisciplined and unproductive personnel ultimately leading to a work shy workforce among Soviet workers and administrators 15 While the Soviet Union under Brezhnev had the second greatest industrial capacity after the United States and produced more steel oil pig iron cement and tractors than any other country in the world 16 Service treats the problems of agriculture during the Brezhnev era as proof of the need for de collectivization 17 In short Service considers the Soviet economy to have become static during this time period 18 and Brezhnev s policy of stability was a recipe for political disaster 19 Richard Sakwa author of the book The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Union 1917 1991 takes a dimmer view of the Brezhnev era by claiming that growth rates fell inexorably from the 1950s until they stopped completely in the 1980s His reasoning for this stagnation was the growing demand for unskilled workers resulted in a decline of productivity and labour discipline Sakwa believes that stability itself led to stagnation and claimed that without strong leadership Soviet socialism had a tendency to relapse into stagnation 20 According to Edwin Bacon and Mark Sandle authors of Brezhnev Reconsidered the economy under Brezhnev was as dynamic as the economy presided over by Nikita Khrushchev but this dynamism had stalled by the time Yuri Andropov and subsequently Konstantin Chernenko became General Secretary 21 Mark Harrison claims that the economic performance of the Brezhnev era has not been looked at objectively as analysis of the period sometimes used lower estimates 22 Harrison further claims that in the period between 1928 and 1973 the Soviet economy grew in a phase that would surpass the United States one day During the international oil crisis growth in the Soviet Union and the Eastern Bloc halted abruptly and stalled for a longer period than in the West 23 causing the economy to begin stagnating 24 One explanation according to Harrison is that the Soviet economy could not sustain its extensive growth patterns 25 Other explanations include the lack of Soviet and communist bloc transparency with other nations hindering globalisation 26 and misinterpretation of a permanent post World War II economic boom leading to faulty economic decisions 27 He claims that the economic policies of Andropov and Chernenko had improved the economic situation in the country and Mikhail Gorbachev inherited a more dynamic and vibrant economy in a pre crisis situation where the economy was still growing with low internal and external debts compared to the economy that Andropov and Chernenko inherited 28 Archie Brown author of The Rise and Fall of Communism claims in his book that the term Era of Stagnation was in many ways a fitting description for this was a period of declining growth but noted it could be misleading in non economic spheres 29 Brown states there were high growth rates in the mid to late 1960s during the Eighth Five Year Plan claiming that the Soviet economy enjoyed stronger growth in the second half of the 1960s than it ever did thereafter The link between these growth rates and the Kosygin reform is according to Brown tenuous 30 but says that From the point of view of communist rulers the Brezhnev era was in many ways successful 31 The Soviet Unions natural resources provided a strong economic foundation which bore fruit during the 1973 oil crisis and turned out to be an energy bonanza 32 On the other hand Brown states it was a sign of weakness that the Soviet Union grew so dependent on her natural resources as she did in the 1970s 31 nbsp Scholars are generally unsure as to what effect the Kosygin reform named after its initiator Alexei Kosygin had on economic growthPhilip Hanson author of The Rise and Fall of the Soviet economy an Economic History of the USSR from 1945 claims that the label stagnation is not entirely unfair Brezhnev according to Hanson did preside over a period of slowdown in economic growth but claims that the era started with good growth that was at a higher rate than during the end of Khrushchev s rule Economic slowdown began in 1973 when even the official estimates began to show Soviet per capita production no longer closing the gap with the US Before 1973 there was a reform period launched by Alexei Kosygin which many believed would become as radical as those in the Socialist Republic of Czechoslovakia and the previous reform attempts in Hungary 33 According to Hanson many assumed that growth during the Brezhnev era did not stop but started to stagnate 34 Not everything stagnated as per capita consumption grew by 1 9 during the 1970s which is a highly respectable rate of growth Another point that Hanson makes is that in contrast to the repressive policies of Joseph Stalin and instability inducing policies of Khrushchev the Brezhnev era was stable and a period of comparative plenty 35 Robert Vincent Daniels in his book Russia s Transformation Snapshots of a Crumbling System claimed that the hallmark of the Brezhnev era was the status quo which in turn led to the development of a great paradox the contradictions of what it was and what it could be became obvious Net growth in excess of 50 and as high as two thirds was primarily in the urban sector resulting in high population growth and urban growth higher than that of the United States Industrial development continued to grow rapidly and in certain sectors surpassed the United States 36 As an example coal production in the Soviet Union increased from 85 million metric tons in 1964 to 149 million metric tons in 1981 while in the United States it grew from 100 million to 130 million metric tons in the same period 37 The Soviet Union became the largest exporter of petroleum in the world and by the end of the Tenth Five Year Plan 1976 1981 the Soviet GNP reached about 60 of the American level and the net current investment was actually greater in absolute terms The failure then according to Daniels was that the Soviet economy was not able to deliver in certain sectors agriculture is a sector where this failure occurred Throughout Soviet history deficiencies in agriculture and consumer goods always existed During Brezhnev s reign the Soviet Union became the largest producer of wheat in the world but was unable to produce meat in sufficient quantities 38 According to Daniels the economy began to stagnate in 1975 rather than 1973 and that the following period contradicted the previous one in almost every way 39 The research in second economy of the Soviet Union pioneered by Gregory Grossman indicated that during 1970s 1980s the effects of the central planning were progressively distorted due to the rapid growth of the shadow economy It is suggested that failure to account for it by Gosplan contributed to the stagnation and ultimately to the collapse of the Soviet economy 40 Causes edit One of the suggested causes of stagnation was the increased military expenditure over consumer goods and other economic spheres 41 Andrei Sakharov the veteran dissident claimed in a 1980 letter to Brezhnev that the increasing expenditure on the armed forces was stalling economic growth 42 David Michael Kotz and Fred Weir authors of Revolution from Above The Demise of the Soviet System argue that militarisation cannot be the prime cause for the economic stagnation as military spending had historically been high 17 of GNP in 1950 and had increased on par with economic growth without previously destabilising the economy citation needed During the Nixon Shock and the 1973 oil crisis economic growth in the rest of the world plummeted but the Soviet hard currency earnings grew as a result of oil exports Following the crisis overall economic activity decreased markedly in the Soviet Union the Western Bloc and Japan but in the Soviet Union it was much more pronounced Kotz and Weir argued that ultimately economic stagnation in the Soviet Union could only have been caused by internal problems rather than external 43 Some Marxist Leninist writers have argued that economic stagnation was a result of revisionism in Soviet economic policy during Khrushchev s leadership According to authors like Harpal Brar Khrushchev s de Stalinization program was also used to implement economic reforms that would move the USSR away from central planning and towards market socialism 44 Summary edit Period Growth ratesGNP according tothe CIA NMP according toG I Khanin NMP according tothe USSR 1960 1965 4 8 4 4 6 51965 1970 4 9 4 1 7 71970 1975 3 0 3 2 5 71975 1980 1 9 1 0 4 21980 1985 1 8 0 6 3 5 45 note 1 One of the main causes for Khrushchev s dismissal from power was the relatively poor economic growth during the early 1960s Overall economic growth was 6 from 1951 to 1955 but had fallen to 5 8 in the subsequent 5 years and to 5 from 1961 to 1965 Labour productivity which had grown 4 7 from the 1950s to 1962 had declined to 4 by the early 1960s Growth capital out and investments were all showing signs of steady decline 54 Another problem was Khrushchev s unrealistic promises such as committing to reach communism in 20 years a near impossibility with the then current economic indicators 3 Ultimately as a result of his failure to deliver on his promises and the problems engendered Khrushchev was dismissed in October 1964 55 by a collective leadership led by Leonid Brezhnev and Alexei Kosygin To counter Khrushchev s promise of reaching communism the Soviet leadership created the term developed socialism which meant that the Soviet Union had developed to a sufficiently advanced stage that the country would move naturally to communism in an unspecified amount of time 56 Khrushchev s dismissal led to the establishment of a more conservative Politburo Kosygin Nikolai Podgorny and Andrei Kirilenko were the most liberal members Brezhnev and Arvids Pelse belonged to the moderate faction while Mikhail Suslov retained his leadership of the party s hardliners 57 Kosygin and Brezhnev strongly disagreed over economic policy Kosygin wanted to increase investments in consumer goods and light industry whereas Brezhnev wanted to increase investment in heavy industry agriculture and defence 58 In 1965 Kosygin introduced an economic reform widely referred to as the Kosygin reform which aimed to reform the planned economy within a socialist framework In a bid to improve the Soviet economy Kosygin copied some of the measures used in the Western Bloc such as profit making 59 which Brezhnev agreed to as the Soviet economy was entering a period of low growth 60 Kosygin s reforms on agriculture gave considerable autonomy to the collective farms giving them the right to the contents of private farming As a result during the Eighth Five Year Plan 1966 1970 large scale land reclamation programmes construction of irrigation channels and other measures were enacted 61 note 2 Overall the reform failed and links to any high growth rates during the Eighth Five Year Plan are considered to be tenuous 62 The Brezhnev era which had begun with high growth began to stagnate some time in the early 1970s Kosygin s radical reform attempts were halted in 1971 and his second reform was more modest The second reform was halted because of the 1973 oil crisis when an international increase in the price of oil prompted economic growth based on selling oil Another reform was implemented in 1979 but this too failed as by this time the Soviet economy had become addicted to high oil prices 61 In 1980 RIA Novosti reported that the Soviet Union showed the highest in Europe and second highest worldwide industrial and agricultural output The Soviet statistics claimed that in 1960 the Soviet Union s industrial output was only 55 that of America but this increased to 80 by 1980 61 The 18 years of Brezhnev s leadership of the Communist Party saw real incomes grow by more than 1 5 times 61 More than 1 6 billion square meters of living space was commissioned and provided to over 160 million people At the same time the average rent for families did not exceed 3 of the family income Housing health care and education were affordable and low priced As the circulation of the work force could not be balanced by salaries there was a lack of workers in some areas largely in the agricultural sector This was partly solved by forcing nonproductive urban population older pupils students scientists soldiers etc to work during the harvesting time as agricultural workers The practice has been informally called naryady na kartoshku Russian naryady na kartoshku assignments to potato fields 61 Opposition editThis section needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section Unsourced material may be challenged and removed Find sources Era of Stagnation news newspapers books scholar JSTOR July 2021 Learn how and when to remove this template message Acts of protest took place in reaction to the Warsaw Pact invasion of Czechoslovakia with protesters being dismissed from their jobs beaten or arrested 63 Eight protesters held a demonstration in Red Square in Moscow and were subsequently imprisoned 64 A number of suspected dissidents had their homes and property searched 65 and a group of Moscow lawyers specialised in defending people charged with anti Soviet activity 66 Supporters of these meetings and demonstrations claimed that the arrests were illegal because there is no criminality in the realization of the human right to obtain and distribute information They asserted this right was part of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights 1948 67 and the final act of the Conference on Security and Co operation in Europe 1975 68 During the introduction of glasnost many writers claimed that they did not know about the repression of citizens who did not support the Brezhnev politics 69 Artists propagating Soviet values within the framework of socialist realism formed a well paid elite group that enjoyed an easy life and high social status Nevertheless a noticeable part of Soviet scientists and artists collectively known as the dissidents continued both open and clandestine political opposition to the regime that they began during the Khrushchev rule Prominent nuclear physicist Andrey Sakharov and Soviet Army General Pyotr Grigorenko are well known representatives of this movement Many other members of the Soviet intelligentsia systematically criticized the social and moral manifestations of the Stagnation without overtly challenging the authorities Examples include writers Viktor Astafyev and Oles Honchar playwright Grigory Gorin directors Eldar Ryazanov and Mark Zakharov See also editIndex of Soviet Union related articles History of the Soviet Union 1964 1982 Brezhnev Era Post World War II economic expansionReferences editNotes edit Many economists argue that the net material product NMP the Soviet version of the gross national product GNP contained distortions and could not accurately determine a country s economic growth Because of this several specialists created GNP figures to estimate Soviet growth rates and to compare Soviet growth rates with the growth rates of capitalist countries 46 Grigorii Khanin published his growth rates in the 1980s as a translation of NMP to GNP His growth rates were as seen above much lower than the official figures and lower than some Western estimates 47 After the dissolution of the Soviet Union in 1991 Khanin s estimates led several agencies criticise the estimates made by the Central Intelligence Agency CIA Since then the CIA has generally been regarded as having overestimated Soviet growth In response to the criticism of CIA s work a panel led by economist James R Millar was established to check out if this was in fact true The panel concluded that the CIA were based on facts and that Khanin s approach was methodologically naive as it has not been possible for others to reproduce his results 48 Growth figures for the Soviet economy varies widely as seen below if compared to those at the table above Eighth Five Year Plan 1966 1970 Gross national product GNP 5 2 49 GNP 5 3 50 Gross national income GNI 7 1 51 Capital investments in agriculture 24 52 Ninth Five Year Plan 1971 1975 GNP 3 7 49 GNI 5 1 51 Labour productivity 6 53 Capital investments in agriculture 27 52 Tenth Five Year Plan 1976 1980 GNP 2 7 49 GNP 3 50 Labour productivity 3 2 53 Eleventh Five Year Plan 1981 1985 According to Soviet statistics there were significant improvements made in the economy during the Eighth Five Year Plan 1966 1970 The economy grew by 7 7 during the Eighth Five Year Plan but slowed during the Ninth Five Year Plan 1971 1975 and Tenth Five Year Plan 1976 1981 when the economy grew by 5 7 and 4 2 respectively 61 References edit The World Factbook Cia gov Retrieved 7 September 2015 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 pp 1 2 a b Dowlah amp Elliott 1997 pp 148 149 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 p 1 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 p 2 Reid Susan Emily 2005 In the Name of the People The Manege Affair Revisited Kritika Explorations in Russian and Eurasian History Slavica Publishers 6 4 673 716 doi 10 1353 kri 2005 0058 S2CID 159693587 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 p 143 Bischof Gunter Karner Stefan Ruggenthaler Peter 2010 The Prague Spring and the Warsaw Pact invasion of Czechoslovakia in 1968 Rowman amp Littlefield p 92 ISBN 978 0 7391 4304 9 1964 1982 The Period of Stagnation GlobalSecurity org Retrieved 2 August 2017 Gillula James W 1983 The Reconstructed 1972 Input output Tables for Eight Soviet Republics Manufactured goods sector was worth 118 billion roubles in 1972 U S Department of Commerce Bureau of the Census Retrieved 2 January 2016 Khazanov Anatoly M 1992 Soviet Social Thought in the Period of Stagnation Philosophy of the Social Sciences SAGE Publications 22 2 231 237 doi 10 1177 004839319202200205 Grant Ted 22 September 2006 Russia from Revolution to Counter Revolution In Defence of Marxism Part 6 Archived from the original on 6 February 2009 Retrieved 31 December 2011 Service 2009 p 427 Service 2009 p 416 Service 2009 p 417 Service 2009 p 397 Service 2009 p 402 Service 2009 p 407 Service 2009 p 409 Sakwa Richard 1999 The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Union 1917 1991 Routledge p 339 ISBN 0 415 12290 2 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 p 38 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 pp 43 44 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 pp 44 45 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 p 47 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 p 53 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 pp 50 51 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 p 54 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 p 63 Brown 2009 p 398 Brown 2009 p 403 a b Brown 2009 p 415 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 pp 415 416 Hanson 2003 p 98 Hanson 2003 pp 98 99 Hanson 2003 p 99 Daniels 1998 p 46 Daniels 1998 pp 47 48 Daniels 1998 p 47 Daniels 1998 p 49 Vladimir G Treml and Michael V Alexeev The Second Economy And The Destabilizing Effect Of Its Growth On The State Economy In The Soviet Union 1965 1989 Berkeley Duke Occasional Papers On The Second Economy In The Ussr Paper No 36 December 1993 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 p 28 Volkogonov Dmitri Shukman Harold 1999 Autopsy for an Empire The Seven Leaders Who Built the Soviet Regime Simon amp Schuster p 262 ISBN 978 0 684 87112 7 Kotz David Michael Weir Fred 1997 Revolution from Above The Demise of the Soviet System Routledge p 48 ISBN 978 0 415 14317 2 Brar Harpal 1992 Perestroika The Complete Collapse of Revisionism H Brar ISBN 1 874613 01 X Bacon amp Sandle 2002 p 40 Kotz amp Weir 2007 p 35 Harrison M 1993 Soviet economic growth since 1928 The alternative statistics of G I Khanin Europe Asia Studies 45 1 141 167 doi 10 1080 09668139308412080 Kotz amp Weir 2007 p 39 a b c Kort Michael 2010 The Soviet Colossus History and Aftermath M E Sharpe p 322 ISBN 978 0 7656 2387 4 a b Bergson Abram 1985 The Soviet economy Toward the year 2000 Taylor amp Francis p 192 ISBN 978 0 04 335053 9 a b Pallot Judith Shaw Denis 1981 Planning in the Soviet Union Taylor amp Francis p 51 ISBN 978 0 85664 571 6 a b Wegren Stephen 1998 Agriculture and the State in Soviet and Post Soviet Russia University of Pittsburgh Press p 252 ISBN 978 0 8229 8585 3 a b Arnot Bob 1988 Controlling Soviet Labour Experimental Change from Brezhnev to Gorbachev M E Sharpe p 67 ISBN 0 87332 470 6 Dowlah amp Elliott 1997 p 148 Dowlah amp Elliott 1997 p 149 Dowlah amp Elliott 1997 p 146 Law David A 1975 Russian Civilization New York Ardent Media p 221 ISBN 0 8422 0529 2 Zemtsov Ilya 1989 Chernenko The Last Bolshevik The Soviet Union on the Eve of Perestroika Transaction Publishers p 86 ISBN 0 88738 260 6 Moss Walter 2005 A History of Russia Since 1855 London Anthem Press p 431 ISBN 978 1 84331 034 1 Chauhan Sharad 2004 Inside CIA Lessons in Intelligence APH Publishing p 207 ISBN 81 7648 660 4 a b c d e f Sovetskaya ekonomika v epohu Leonida Brezhneva The Soviet economy in the era of Leonid Brezhnev RIA Novosti 8 November 2010 Retrieved 31 December 2011 Bacon amp Sandle 2002 p 58 Hronika Tekushih Sobytij vypusk 3 Chronicle of Current Events Issue 3 memo ru in Russian 30 August 1968 Archived from the original on 29 September 2012 Retrieved 2 January 2016 Andrew Roth 9 August 2018 Nearly half of Russians ignorant of 1968 s Czechoslovakia invasion poll The Guardian Hronika Tekushih Sobytij vypusk 4 Chronicle of Current Events Issue 4 memo ru in Russian 31 October 1968 Archived from the original on 4 February 2017 Retrieved 2 January 2016 Letter by Andropov to the Central Committee 10 July 1970 Archived from the original on 11 March 2007 Universal Declaration of Human Rights resolution 217 A III accepted 10 Dec 1948 Conference On Security And Co Operation In Europe Final Act Helsinki OSCE 1 August 1975 Retrieved 27 February 2016 Sofia Kallistratova We were not silent open letter to writer Chingiz Aitmatov in Russian S V Kalistratova Otkrytoe pismo pisatelyu Chingizu Ajtmatovu Archived 2007 09 26 at the Wayback Machine 5 maya 1988 g Bibliography edit Brown Archie 2009 The Rise amp Fall of Communism Bodley Head ISBN 978 0 06 113879 9 Daniels Robert Vincent 1998 Russia s Transformation Snapshots of a Crumbling System Rowman amp Littlefield ISBN 978 0 8476 8709 1 Dowlah Alex Elliott John 1997 The Life and Times of Soviet Socialism Greenwood Publishing Group ISBN 978 0 275 95629 5 Hanson Philip 2003 The Rise and Fall of the Soviet economy an Economic History of the USSR from 1945 Pearson Education ISBN 978 0 582 29958 0 Kotz David Michael Weir Fred 2007 Russia s Path from Gorbachev to Putin The Demise of the Soviet System and the New Russia Taylor amp Francis ISBN 978 0 415 70146 4 Service Robert 2009 History of Modern Russia From Tsarism to the Twenty first Century 3 ed Penguin Books Ltd ISBN 978 0 674 03493 8 Bacon Edwin Sandle Mark eds 2002 Brezhnev Reconsidered Springer ISBN 978 0 230 50108 9 External links editStagnation The Brezhnev Era The Period of Stagnation By Ted Grant The Decline of the Soviet Union A Hypothesis on Industrial Paradigms Technological Revolutions and the Roots of Perestroika by Angelo SegrilloPreceded byKhrushchev Thaw History of RussiaHistory of the Soviet Union14 October 1964 10 March 1985 Succeeded byPerestroika Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Era of Stagnation amp oldid 1194379798, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.