fbpx
Wikipedia

Environmental economics

Environmental economics is a sub-field of economics concerned with environmental issues.[1] It has become a widely studied subject due to growing environmental concerns in the twenty-first century. Environmental economics "undertakes theoretical or empirical studies of the economic effects of national or local environmental policies around the world. ... Particular issues include the costs and benefits of alternative environmental policies to deal with air pollution, water quality, toxic substances, solid waste, and global warming."[2]

Growth, Development and Environmental Economics in Asia discussion at Chatham House, London

Environmental economics is distinguished from ecological economics in that ecological economics emphasizes the economy as a subsystem of the ecosystem with its focus upon preserving natural capital.[3] One survey of German economists found that ecological and environmental economics are different schools of economic thought, with ecological economists emphasizing "strong" sustainability and rejecting the proposition that human-made ("physical") capital can substitute for natural capital.[4]

History edit

The modern field of environmental economics has been traced to the 1960s[5] with significant contribution from Post-Keynesian economist Paul Davidson, who had just completed a management position with the Continental Oil Company.[6]

Topics and concepts edit

Market failure edit

 
Air pollution is an example of market failure, as the factory is imposing a negative external cost on the community.

Central to environmental economics is the concept of market failure. Market failure means that markets fail to allocate resources efficiently. As stated by Hanley, Shogren, and White (2007):[7] "A market failure occurs when the market does not allocate scarce resources to generate the greatest social welfare. A wedge exists between what a private person does given market prices and what society might want him or her to do to protect the environment. Such a wedge implies wastefulness or economic inefficiency; resources can be reallocated to make at least one person better off without making anyone else worse off." This results in a inefficient market that needs to be corrected through avenues such as government intervention. Common forms of market failure include externalities, non-excludability and non-rivalry.[8]

Externality edit

An externality exists when a person makes a choice that affects other people in a way that is not accounted for in the market price. An externality can be positive or negative but is usually associated with negative externalities in environmental economics. For instance, water seepage in residential buildings occurring in upper floors affect the lower floors.[9] Another example concerns how the sale of Amazon timber disregards the amount of carbon dioxide released in the cutting.[10][better source needed] Or a firm emitting pollution will typically not take into account the costs that its pollution imposes on others. As a result, pollution may occur in excess of the 'socially efficient' level, which is the level that would exist if the market was required to account for the pollution. A classic definition influenced by Kenneth Arrow and James Meade is provided by Heller and Starrett (1976), who define an externality as "a situation in which the private economy lacks sufficient incentives to create a potential market in some good and the nonexistence of this market results in losses of Pareto efficiency".[11] In economic terminology, externalities are examples of market failures, in which the unfettered market does not lead to an efficient outcome.

Common goods and public goods edit

When it is too costly to exclude some people from access to an environmental resource, the resource is either called a common property resource (when there is rivalry for the resource, such that one person's use of the resource reduces others' opportunity to use the resource) or a public good (when use of the resource is non-rivalrous). In either case of non-exclusion, market allocation is likely to be inefficient.

These challenges have long been recognized. Hardin's (1968) concept of the tragedy of the commons popularized the challenges involved in non-exclusion and common property. "Commons" refers to the environmental asset itself, "common property resource" or "common pool resource" refers to a property right regime that allows for some collective body to devise schemes to exclude others, thereby allowing the capture of future benefit streams; and "open-access" implies no ownership in the sense that property everyone owns nobody owns.[12]

The basic problem is that if people ignore the scarcity value of the commons, they can end up expending too much effort, over harvesting a resource (e.g., a fishery). Hardin theorizes that in the absence of restrictions, users of an open-access resource will use it more than if they had to pay for it and had exclusive rights, leading to environmental degradation. See, however, Ostrom's (1990) work on how people using real common property resources have worked to establish self-governing rules to reduce the risk of the tragedy of the commons.[12]

The mitigation of climate change effects is an example of a public good, where the social benefits are not reflected completely in the market price. Because the personal marginal benefits are less than the social benefits the market under-provides climate change mitigation. This is a public good since the risks of climate change are both non-rival and non-excludable. Such efforts are non-rival since climate mitigation provided to one does not reduce the level of mitigation that anyone else enjoys. They are non-excludable actions as they will have global consequences from which no one can be excluded. A country's incentive to invest in carbon abatement is reduced because it can "free ride" off the efforts of other countries. Over a century ago, Swedish economist Knut Wicksell (1896) first discussed how public goods can be under-provided by the market because people might conceal their preferences for the good, but still enjoy the benefits without paying for them.

Valuation edit

Assessing the economic value of the environment is a major topic within the field. The values of natural resources often are not reflected in prices that markets set and, in fact, many of them are available at no monetary charge. This mismatch frequently causes distortions in pricing of natural assets: both overuse of them and underinvestment in them.[13] Economic value or tangible benefits of ecosystem services and, more generally, of natural resources, include both use and indirect (see the nature section of ecological economics). Non-use values include existence, option, and bequest values. For example, some people may value the existence of a diverse set of species, regardless of the effect of the loss of a species on ecosystem services. The existence of these species may have an option value, as there may be the possibility of using it for some human purpose. For example, certain plants may be researched for drugs. Individuals may value the ability to leave a pristine environment for their children.

Use and indirect use values can often be inferred from revealed behavior, such as the cost of taking recreational trips or using hedonic methods in which values are estimated based on observed prices. Non-use values are usually estimated using stated preference methods such as contingent valuation or choice modelling. Contingent valuation typically takes the form of surveys in which people are asked how much they would pay to observe and recreate in the environment (willingness to pay) or their willingness to accept (WTA) compensation for the destruction of the environmental good. Hedonic pricing examines the effect the environment has on economic decisions through housing prices, traveling expenses, and payments to visit parks.[14]

State subsidy edit

Almost all governments and states magnify environmental harm by providing various types of subsidies that have the effect of paying companies and other economic actors more to exploit natural resources than to protect them. The damage to nature of such public subsidies has been conservatively estimated at $4-$6 trillion U.S. dollars per year.[15]

Solutions edit

Solutions advocated to correct such externalities include:

  • Environmental regulations. Under this plan, the economic impact has to be estimated by the regulator. Usually, this is done using cost–benefit analysis. There is a growing realization that regulations (also known as "command and control" instruments) are not so distinct from economic instruments as is commonly asserted by proponents of environmental economics. E.g.1 regulations are enforced by fines, which operate as a form of tax if pollution rises above the threshold prescribed. E.g.2 pollution must be monitored and laws enforced, whether under a pollution tax regime or a regulatory regime. The main difference an environmental economist would argue exists between the two methods, however, is the total cost of the regulation. "Command and control" regulation often applies uniform emissions limits on polluters, even though each firm has different costs for emissions reductions, i.e., some firms, in this system, can abate pollution inexpensively, while others can only abate it at high cost. Because of this, the total abatement in the system comprises some expensive and some inexpensive efforts. Consequently, modern "Command and control" regulations are oftentimes designed in a way that addresses these issues by incorporating utility parameters. For instance, CO2 emission standards for specific manufacturers in the automotive industry are either linked to the average vehicle footprint (US system) or average vehicle weight (EU system) of their entire vehicle fleet. Environmental economic regulations find the cheapest emission abatement efforts first, and then move on to the more expensive methods. E.g. as said earlier, trading, in the quota system, means a firm only abates pollution if doing so would cost less than paying someone else to make the same reduction. This leads to a lower cost for the total abatement effort as a whole.[citation needed]
  • Quotas on pollution. Often it is advocated that pollution reductions should be achieved by way of tradeable emissions permits, which if freely traded may ensure that reductions in pollution are achieved at least cost. In theory, if such tradeable quotas are allowed, then a firm would reduce its own pollution load only if doing so would cost less than paying someone else to make the same reduction, i.e., only if buying tradeable permits from another firm(s) is costlier. In practice, tradeable permits approaches have had some success, such as the U.S.'s sulphur dioxide trading program or the EU Emissions Trading Scheme, and interest in its application is spreading to other environmental problems.
  • Taxes and tariffs on pollution. Increasing the costs of polluting will discourage polluting, and will provide a "dynamic incentive", that is, the disincentive continues to operate even as pollution levels fall. A pollution tax that reduces pollution to the socially "optimal" level would be set at such a level that pollution occurs only if the benefits to society (for example, in form of greater production) exceeds the costs. This concept was introduced by Arthur Pigou, a British economist active in the late nineteenth through the mid-twentieth century. He showed that these externalities occur when markets fail, meaning they do not naturally produce the socially optimal amount of a good or service. He argued that “a tax on the production of paint would encourage the [polluting] factory to reduce production to the amount best for society as a whole.”[16] These taxes are known amongst economists as Pigouvian Taxes, and they regularly implemented where negative externalities are present. Some advocate a major shift from taxation from income and sales taxes to tax on pollution - the so-called "green tax shift".
  • Better defined property rights. The Coase Theorem states that assigning property rights will lead to an optimal solution, regardless of who receives them, if transaction costs are trivial and the number of parties negotiating is limited. For example, if people living near a factory had a right to clean air and water, or the factory had the right to pollute, then either the factory could pay those affected by the pollution or the people could pay the factory not to pollute. Or, citizens could take action themselves as they would if other property rights were violated. The US River Keepers Law of the 1880s was an early example, giving citizens downstream the right to end pollution upstream themselves if the government itself did not act (an early example of bioregional democracy). Many markets for "pollution rights" have been created in the late twentieth century—see emissions trading. According to the Coase Theorem, the involved parties will bargain with each other, which results in an efficient solution. However, modern economic theory has shown that the presence of asymmetric information may lead to inefficient bargaining outcomes.[17] Specifically, Rob (1989) has shown that pollution claim settlements will not lead to the socially optimal outcome when the individuals that will be affected by pollution have learned private information about their disutility already before the negotiations take place.[18] Goldlücke and Schmitz (2018) have shown that inefficiencies may also result if the parties learn their private information only after the negotiations, provided that the feasible transfer payments are bounded.[19] Using cooperative game theory, Gonzalez, Marciano and Solal (2019) have shown that in social cost problems involving more than three agents, the Coase theorem suffers from many counterexamples and that only two types of property rights lead to an optimal solution.[20]
  • Accounting for environmental externalities in the final price. In fact, the world's largest industries burn about $7.3 trillion of free natural capital per year.[21] Thus, the world's largest industries would hardly be profitable if they had to pay for this destruction of natural capital. Trucost has assessed over 100 direct environmental impacts and condensed them into 6 key environmental performance indicators (EKPIs).[22] The assessment of environmental impacts is derived from different sources (academic journals, governments, studies, etc.) due to the lack of market prices. The table below gives an overview of the 5 regional sectors per EKPI with the highest impact on the overall EKPI:
Ranking of the 5 region-sectors by EKPI with the greatest impact across all EKPIs when measured in monetary terms[22]
Rank IMPACT SECTOR REGION NATURAL CAPITAL COST, $BN REVENU, $BN IMPACT RATIO
1 GHG Coal Power Generation Eastern Asia 361.0 443.1 0.8
2 Land Use Cattle Ranching and Farming South America 312.1 16.6 18.7
3 GHG Iron and Steel Mills Eastern Asia 216.1 604.7 0.4
4 Water Wheat Farming Southern Asia 214.4 31.8 6.7
5 GHG Coal Power Generation Northern America 201.0 246.7 0.8

If companies are allowed to include some of these externalities in their final prices, this could undermine the Jevons paradox and provide enough revenue to help companies innovate.

Relationship to other fields edit

Environmental economics is related to ecological economics but there are differences. Most environmental economists have been trained as economists. They apply the tools of economics to address environmental problems, many of which are related to so-called market failures—circumstances wherein the "invisible hand" of economics is unreliable. Most ecological economists have been trained as ecologists, but have expanded the scope of their work to consider the impacts of humans and their economic activity on ecological systems and services, and vice versa. This field takes as its premise that economics is a strict subfield of ecology. Ecological economics is sometimes described as taking a more pluralistic approach to environmental problems and focuses more explicitly on long-term environmental sustainability and issues of scale.

Environmental economics is viewed as more idealistic in a price system; ecological economics as more realistic in its attempts to integrate elements outside of the price system as primary arbiters of decisions. These two groups of specialists sometimes have conflicting views which may be traced to the different philosophical underpinnings.

Another context in which externalities apply is when globalization permits one player in a market who is unconcerned with biodiversity to undercut prices of another who is - creating a race to the bottom in regulations and conservation. This, in turn, may cause loss of natural capital with consequent erosion, water purity problems, diseases, desertification, and other outcomes that are not efficient in an economic sense. This concern is related to the subfield of sustainable development and its political relation, the anti-globalization movement.

 EnvironmentEquitableSustainableBearable (Social ecology)ViableEconomicSocial
The three pillars of sustainability (clickable)

Environmental economics was once distinct from resource economics. Natural resource economics as a subfield began when the main concern of researchers was the optimal commercial exploitation of natural resource stocks. But resource managers and policy-makers eventually began to pay attention to the broader importance of natural resources (e.g. values of fish and trees beyond just their commercial exploitation). It is now difficult to distinguish "environmental" and "natural resource" economics as separate fields as the two became associated with sustainability. Many of the more radical green economists split off to work on an alternate political economy.

Environmental economics was a major influence on the theories of natural capitalism and environmental finance, which could be said to be two sub-branches of environmental economics concerned with resource conservation in production, and the value of biodiversity to humans, respectively. The theory of natural capitalism (Hawken, Lovins, Lovins) goes further than traditional environmental economics by envisioning a world where natural services are considered on par with physical capital.

The more radical green economists reject neoclassical economics in favour of a new political economy beyond capitalism or communism that gives a greater emphasis to the interaction of the human economy and the natural environment, acknowledging that "economy is three-fifths of ecology" - Mike Nickerson. This political group is a proponent of a transition to renewable energy.

These more radical approaches would imply changes to money supply and likely also a bioregional democracy so that political, economic, and ecological "environmental limits" were all aligned, and not subject to the arbitrage normally possible under capitalism.

An emerging sub-field of environmental economics studies its intersection with development economics. Dubbed "envirodevonomics" by Michael Greenstone and B. Kelsey Jack in their paper "Envirodevonomics: A Research Agenda for a Young Field", the sub-field is primarily interested in studying "why environmental quality [is] so poor in developing countries."[23] A strategy for better understanding this correlation between a country's GDP and its environmental quality involves analyzing how many of the central concepts of environmental economics, including market failures, externalities, and willingness to pay, may be complicated by the particular problems facing developing countries, such as political issues, lack of infrastructure, or inadequate financing tools, among many others.[24]

In the field of law and economics, environmental law is studied from an economic perspective. The economic analysis of environmental law studies instruments such as zoning, expropriation, licensing, third party liability, safety regulation, mandatory insurance, and criminal sanctions. A book by Michael Faure (2003) surveys this literature.[25]

Professional bodies edit

The main academic and professional organizations for the discipline of Environmental Economics are the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists (AERE) and the European Association for Environmental and Resource Economics (EAERE). The main academic and professional organization for the discipline of Ecological Economics is the International Society for Ecological Economics (ISEE). The main organization for Green Economics is the Green Economics Institute.

See also edit

Hypotheses and theorems edit

Notes edit

  1. ^ "Understanding Environmental Economics". Investopedia. Retrieved 2022-05-01.
  2. ^ "Environmental Economics". NBER Working Group Descriptions. National Bureau of Economic Research. Retrieved 2006-07-23.
  3. ^ Jeroen C.J.M. van den Bergh (2001). "Ecological Economics: Themes, Approaches, and Differences with Environmental Economics," Regional Environmental Change, 2(1), pp. 13-23 2008-10-31 at the Wayback Machine (press +).
  4. ^ Illge L, Schwarze R. (2009). A Matter of Opinion: How Ecological and Neoclassical Environmental Economists Think about Sustainability and Economics . Ecological Economics.
  5. ^ Pearce, David (2002). "An Intellectual History of Environmental Economics". Annual Review of Energy and the Environment. 27 (1): 57–81. doi:10.1146/annurev.energy.27.122001.083429. ISSN 1056-3466.
  6. ^ Rosser, Barkley Jr. (September 13, 1998). "Paul Davidson's Economics" (PDF). Working Paper No. 251. (PDF) from the original on 2010-12-29.
  7. ^ Hanley, N., J. Shogren, and B. White (2007). Environmental Economics in Theory and Practice, Palgrave, London.
  8. ^ Anderson, D. (2019). Environmental Economics and Natural Resource Management, [1] Routledge, New York.
  9. ^ Rita Yi Man Li (2012), The Internalisation Of Environmental Externalities Affecting Dwellings: A Review Of Court Cases In Hong Kong, Economic Affairs, Volume 32, Issue 2, pages 81–87
  10. ^ Chapman, Same (May 3, 2012). "Environmental degradation replaces classic imperialism". The Whitman College Pioneer: Whitman College.
  11. ^ Heller, Walter P. and David A. Starrett (1976), On the Nature of Externalities, in: Lin, Stephen A.Y. (ed.), Theory and Measurement of Economic Externalities, Academic Press, New York, p.10
  12. ^ a b Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  13. ^ UK Government Official Documents, February 2021, "The Economics of Biodiversity: The Dasgupta Review Headline Messages"
  14. ^ Harris J. (2006). Environmental and Natural Resource Economics: A Contemporary Approach. Houghton Mifflin Company.
  15. ^ UK Government Official Documents, February 2021, "The Economics of Biodiversity: The Dasgupta Review Headline Messages" p. 2
  16. ^ Kishtainy, Niall (2018-02-27). A little history of economics. ISBN 9780300234527. OCLC 1039849897.
  17. ^ Myerson, Roger B; Satterthwaite, Mark A (1983). "Efficient mechanisms for bilateral trading" (PDF). Journal of Economic Theory. 29 (2): 265–281. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(83)90048-0. hdl:10419/220829. ISSN 0022-0531. (PDF) from the original on 2006-09-01.
  18. ^ Rob, Rafael (1989). "Pollution claim settlements under private information". Journal of Economic Theory. 47 (2): 307–333. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(89)90022-7. ISSN 0022-0531.
  19. ^ Goldlücke, Susanne; Schmitz, Patrick W. (2018). "Pollution claim settlements reconsidered: Hidden information and bounded payments". European Economic Review. 110: 211–222. doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2018.08.005. ISSN 0014-2921.
  20. ^ Gonzalez, Stéphane; Marciano, Alain; Solal, Philippe (2019). "The social cost problem, rights, and the (non)empty core". Journal of Public Economic Theory. 21 (2): 347–365. doi:10.1111/jpet.12334. S2CID 158059174.
  21. ^ Roberts, David (2013-04-17). "None of the world's top industries would be profitable if they paid for the natural capital they use". Grist. Retrieved 2022-12-14.
  22. ^ a b Joseph (2013-04-01). "Natural Capital at Risk: The Top 100 Externalities of Business". Capitals Coalition. Retrieved 2022-12-14.
  23. ^ Greenstone, Michael; Jack, B. Kelsey (2015). "Envirodevonomics: A Research Agenda for an Emerging Field". Journal of Economic Literature. 53 (1): 5–42. doi:10.1257/jel.53.1.5. S2CID 73594686.
  24. ^ Inclusive green growth the pathway to sustainable development (PDF). Washington, D.C.: World Bank. May 2012. pp. 12–13. ISBN 978-0-8213-9552-3. (PDF) from the original on 2012-05-21. Retrieved 15 January 2015.
  25. ^ Faure, Michael G. (2003). The Economic Analysis of Environmental Policy and Law: An Introduction. Edward Elgar. ISBN 9781843762348.

References edit

  • Allen V. Kneese and Clifford S. Russell (1987). "environmental economics," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 2, pp. 159–64.
  • Robert N. Stavins (2008). "environmental economics," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract & article.
  • Maureen L. Cropper and Wallace E. Oates (1992). "Environmental Economics: A Survey," Journal of Economic Literature, 30(2), pp. (press +).
  • Pearce, David (2002). "An Intellectual History of Environmental Economics". Annual Review of Energy and the Environment. 27: 57–81. doi:10.1146/annurev.energy.27.122001.083429.
  • Tausch, Arno, ‘Smart Development’. An Essay on a New Political Economy of the Environment (March 22, 2016). Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2752988 or https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2752988
  • UNEP (2007). Guidelines for Conducting Economic Valuation of Coastal Ecosystem Goods and Services, UNEP/GEF/SCS Technical Publication No. 8.
  • UNEP (2007). Procedure for Determination of National and Regional Economic Values for Ecotone Goods and Services, and Total Economic Values of Coastal Habitats in the context of the UNEP/GEF Project Entitled: “Reversing Environmental Degradation Trends in the South China Sea and Gulf of Thailand”, South China Sea Knowledge Document No. 3. UNEP/GEF/SCS/Inf.3
  • Perman, Roger; et al. (2003). Natural Resource and Environment Economics (PDF) (3 ed.). Pearson. ISBN 978-0273655596. (PDF) from the original on 2018-06-18.
  • Field, Barry (2017). Environmental economics : an introduction. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill. ISBN 978-0-07-802189-3. OCLC 931860817.

Further reading edit

environmental, economics, confused, with, ecological, economics, field, economics, concerned, with, environmental, issues, become, widely, studied, subject, growing, environmental, concerns, twenty, first, century, undertakes, theoretical, empirical, studies, . Not to be confused with Ecological economics Environmental economics is a sub field of economics concerned with environmental issues 1 It has become a widely studied subject due to growing environmental concerns in the twenty first century Environmental economics undertakes theoretical or empirical studies of the economic effects of national or local environmental policies around the world Particular issues include the costs and benefits of alternative environmental policies to deal with air pollution water quality toxic substances solid waste and global warming 2 Growth Development and Environmental Economics in Asia discussion at Chatham House LondonEnvironmental economics is distinguished from ecological economics in that ecological economics emphasizes the economy as a subsystem of the ecosystem with its focus upon preserving natural capital 3 One survey of German economists found that ecological and environmental economics are different schools of economic thought with ecological economists emphasizing strong sustainability and rejecting the proposition that human made physical capital can substitute for natural capital 4 Contents 1 History 2 Topics and concepts 2 1 Market failure 2 2 Externality 2 3 Common goods and public goods 2 4 Valuation 2 5 State subsidy 3 Solutions 4 Relationship to other fields 5 Professional bodies 6 See also 6 1 Hypotheses and theorems 7 Notes 8 References 9 Further readingHistory editThe modern field of environmental economics has been traced to the 1960s 5 with significant contribution from Post Keynesian economist Paul Davidson who had just completed a management position with the Continental Oil Company 6 Topics and concepts editMarket failure edit nbsp Air pollution is an example of market failure as the factory is imposing a negative external cost on the community Central to environmental economics is the concept of market failure Market failure means that markets fail to allocate resources efficiently As stated by Hanley Shogren and White 2007 7 A market failure occurs when the market does not allocate scarce resources to generate the greatest social welfare A wedge exists between what a private person does given market prices and what society might want him or her to do to protect the environment Such a wedge implies wastefulness or economic inefficiency resources can be reallocated to make at least one person better off without making anyone else worse off This results in a inefficient market that needs to be corrected through avenues such as government intervention Common forms of market failure include externalities non excludability and non rivalry 8 Externality edit An externality exists when a person makes a choice that affects other people in a way that is not accounted for in the market price An externality can be positive or negative but is usually associated with negative externalities in environmental economics For instance water seepage in residential buildings occurring in upper floors affect the lower floors 9 Another example concerns how the sale of Amazon timber disregards the amount of carbon dioxide released in the cutting 10 better source needed Or a firm emitting pollution will typically not take into account the costs that its pollution imposes on others As a result pollution may occur in excess of the socially efficient level which is the level that would exist if the market was required to account for the pollution A classic definition influenced by Kenneth Arrow and James Meade is provided by Heller and Starrett 1976 who define an externality as a situation in which the private economy lacks sufficient incentives to create a potential market in some good and the nonexistence of this market results in losses of Pareto efficiency 11 In economic terminology externalities are examples of market failures in which the unfettered market does not lead to an efficient outcome Common goods and public goods edit When it is too costly to exclude some people from access to an environmental resource the resource is either called a common property resource when there is rivalry for the resource such that one person s use of the resource reduces others opportunity to use the resource or a public good when use of the resource is non rivalrous In either case of non exclusion market allocation is likely to be inefficient These challenges have long been recognized Hardin s 1968 concept of the tragedy of the commons popularized the challenges involved in non exclusion and common property Commons refers to the environmental asset itself common property resource or common pool resource refers to a property right regime that allows for some collective body to devise schemes to exclude others thereby allowing the capture of future benefit streams and open access implies no ownership in the sense that property everyone owns nobody owns 12 The basic problem is that if people ignore the scarcity value of the commons they can end up expending too much effort over harvesting a resource e g a fishery Hardin theorizes that in the absence of restrictions users of an open access resource will use it more than if they had to pay for it and had exclusive rights leading to environmental degradation See however Ostrom s 1990 work on how people using real common property resources have worked to establish self governing rules to reduce the risk of the tragedy of the commons 12 The mitigation of climate change effects is an example of a public good where the social benefits are not reflected completely in the market price Because the personal marginal benefits are less than the social benefits the market under provides climate change mitigation This is a public good since the risks of climate change are both non rival and non excludable Such efforts are non rival since climate mitigation provided to one does not reduce the level of mitigation that anyone else enjoys They are non excludable actions as they will have global consequences from which no one can be excluded A country s incentive to invest in carbon abatement is reduced because it can free ride off the efforts of other countries Over a century ago Swedish economist Knut Wicksell 1896 first discussed how public goods can be under provided by the market because people might conceal their preferences for the good but still enjoy the benefits without paying for them Global biochemical cycles nbsp Nitrogen cycle nbsp Water cycle nbsp Carbon cycle nbsp Oxygen cycleValuation edit Assessing the economic value of the environment is a major topic within the field The values of natural resources often are not reflected in prices that markets set and in fact many of them are available at no monetary charge This mismatch frequently causes distortions in pricing of natural assets both overuse of them and underinvestment in them 13 Economic value or tangible benefits of ecosystem services and more generally of natural resources include both use and indirect see the nature section of ecological economics Non use values include existence option and bequest values For example some people may value the existence of a diverse set of species regardless of the effect of the loss of a species on ecosystem services The existence of these species may have an option value as there may be the possibility of using it for some human purpose For example certain plants may be researched for drugs Individuals may value the ability to leave a pristine environment for their children Use and indirect use values can often be inferred from revealed behavior such as the cost of taking recreational trips or using hedonic methods in which values are estimated based on observed prices Non use values are usually estimated using stated preference methods such as contingent valuation or choice modelling Contingent valuation typically takes the form of surveys in which people are asked how much they would pay to observe and recreate in the environment willingness to pay or their willingness to accept WTA compensation for the destruction of the environmental good Hedonic pricing examines the effect the environment has on economic decisions through housing prices traveling expenses and payments to visit parks 14 State subsidy edit Almost all governments and states magnify environmental harm by providing various types of subsidies that have the effect of paying companies and other economic actors more to exploit natural resources than to protect them The damage to nature of such public subsidies has been conservatively estimated at 4 6 trillion U S dollars per year 15 Solutions editSolutions advocated to correct such externalities include Environmental regulations Under this plan the economic impact has to be estimated by the regulator Usually this is done using cost benefit analysis There is a growing realization that regulations also known as command and control instruments are not so distinct from economic instruments as is commonly asserted by proponents of environmental economics E g 1 regulations are enforced by fines which operate as a form of tax if pollution rises above the threshold prescribed E g 2 pollution must be monitored and laws enforced whether under a pollution tax regime or a regulatory regime The main difference an environmental economist would argue exists between the two methods however is the total cost of the regulation Command and control regulation often applies uniform emissions limits on polluters even though each firm has different costs for emissions reductions i e some firms in this system can abate pollution inexpensively while others can only abate it at high cost Because of this the total abatement in the system comprises some expensive and some inexpensive efforts Consequently modern Command and control regulations are oftentimes designed in a way that addresses these issues by incorporating utility parameters For instance CO2 emission standards for specific manufacturers in the automotive industry are either linked to the average vehicle footprint US system or average vehicle weight EU system of their entire vehicle fleet Environmental economic regulations find the cheapest emission abatement efforts first and then move on to the more expensive methods E g as said earlier trading in the quota system means a firm only abates pollution if doing so would cost less than paying someone else to make the same reduction This leads to a lower cost for the total abatement effort as a whole citation needed Quotas on pollution Often it is advocated that pollution reductions should be achieved by way of tradeable emissions permits which if freely traded may ensure that reductions in pollution are achieved at least cost In theory if such tradeable quotas are allowed then a firm would reduce its own pollution load only if doing so would cost less than paying someone else to make the same reduction i e only if buying tradeable permits from another firm s is costlier In practice tradeable permits approaches have had some success such as the U S s sulphur dioxide trading program or the EU Emissions Trading Scheme and interest in its application is spreading to other environmental problems Taxes and tariffs on pollution Increasing the costs of polluting will discourage polluting and will provide a dynamic incentive that is the disincentive continues to operate even as pollution levels fall A pollution tax that reduces pollution to the socially optimal level would be set at such a level that pollution occurs only if the benefits to society for example in form of greater production exceeds the costs This concept was introduced by Arthur Pigou a British economist active in the late nineteenth through the mid twentieth century He showed that these externalities occur when markets fail meaning they do not naturally produce the socially optimal amount of a good or service He argued that a tax on the production of paint would encourage the polluting factory to reduce production to the amount best for society as a whole 16 These taxes are known amongst economists as Pigouvian Taxes and they regularly implemented where negative externalities are present Some advocate a major shift from taxation from income and sales taxes to tax on pollution the so called green tax shift Better defined property rights The Coase Theorem states that assigning property rights will lead to an optimal solution regardless of who receives them if transaction costs are trivial and the number of parties negotiating is limited For example if people living near a factory had a right to clean air and water or the factory had the right to pollute then either the factory could pay those affected by the pollution or the people could pay the factory not to pollute Or citizens could take action themselves as they would if other property rights were violated The US River Keepers Law of the 1880s was an early example giving citizens downstream the right to end pollution upstream themselves if the government itself did not act an early example of bioregional democracy Many markets for pollution rights have been created in the late twentieth century see emissions trading According to the Coase Theorem the involved parties will bargain with each other which results in an efficient solution However modern economic theory has shown that the presence of asymmetric information may lead to inefficient bargaining outcomes 17 Specifically Rob 1989 has shown that pollution claim settlements will not lead to the socially optimal outcome when the individuals that will be affected by pollution have learned private information about their disutility already before the negotiations take place 18 Goldlucke and Schmitz 2018 have shown that inefficiencies may also result if the parties learn their private information only after the negotiations provided that the feasible transfer payments are bounded 19 Using cooperative game theory Gonzalez Marciano and Solal 2019 have shown that in social cost problems involving more than three agents the Coase theorem suffers from many counterexamples and that only two types of property rights lead to an optimal solution 20 Accounting for environmental externalities in the final price In fact the world s largest industries burn about 7 3 trillion of free natural capital per year 21 Thus the world s largest industries would hardly be profitable if they had to pay for this destruction of natural capital Trucost has assessed over 100 direct environmental impacts and condensed them into 6 key environmental performance indicators EKPIs 22 The assessment of environmental impacts is derived from different sources academic journals governments studies etc due to the lack of market prices The table below gives an overview of the 5 regional sectors per EKPI with the highest impact on the overall EKPI Ranking of the 5 region sectors by EKPI with the greatest impact across all EKPIs when measured in monetary terms 22 Rank IMPACT SECTOR REGION NATURAL CAPITAL COST BN REVENU BN IMPACT RATIO1 GHG Coal Power Generation Eastern Asia 361 0 443 1 0 82 Land Use Cattle Ranching and Farming South America 312 1 16 6 18 73 GHG Iron and Steel Mills Eastern Asia 216 1 604 7 0 44 Water Wheat Farming Southern Asia 214 4 31 8 6 75 GHG Coal Power Generation Northern America 201 0 246 7 0 8If companies are allowed to include some of these externalities in their final prices this could undermine the Jevons paradox and provide enough revenue to help companies innovate Relationship to other fields editThis section does not cite any sources Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed August 2012 Learn how and when to remove this template message Environmental economics is related to ecological economics but there are differences Most environmental economists have been trained as economists They apply the tools of economics to address environmental problems many of which are related to so called market failures circumstances wherein the invisible hand of economics is unreliable Most ecological economists have been trained as ecologists but have expanded the scope of their work to consider the impacts of humans and their economic activity on ecological systems and services and vice versa This field takes as its premise that economics is a strict subfield of ecology Ecological economics is sometimes described as taking a more pluralistic approach to environmental problems and focuses more explicitly on long term environmental sustainability and issues of scale Environmental economics is viewed as more idealistic in a price system ecological economics as more realistic in its attempts to integrate elements outside of the price system as primary arbiters of decisions These two groups of specialists sometimes have conflicting views which may be traced to the different philosophical underpinnings Another context in which externalities apply is when globalization permits one player in a market who is unconcerned with biodiversity to undercut prices of another who is creating a race to the bottom in regulations and conservation This in turn may cause loss of natural capital with consequent erosion water purity problems diseases desertification and other outcomes that are not efficient in an economic sense This concern is related to the subfield of sustainable development and its political relation the anti globalization movement nbsp The three pillars of sustainability clickable Environmental economics was once distinct from resource economics Natural resource economics as a subfield began when the main concern of researchers was the optimal commercial exploitation of natural resource stocks But resource managers and policy makers eventually began to pay attention to the broader importance of natural resources e g values of fish and trees beyond just their commercial exploitation It is now difficult to distinguish environmental and natural resource economics as separate fields as the two became associated with sustainability Many of the more radical green economists split off to work on an alternate political economy Environmental economics was a major influence on the theories of natural capitalism and environmental finance which could be said to be two sub branches of environmental economics concerned with resource conservation in production and the value of biodiversity to humans respectively The theory of natural capitalism Hawken Lovins Lovins goes further than traditional environmental economics by envisioning a world where natural services are considered on par with physical capital The more radical green economists reject neoclassical economics in favour of a new political economy beyond capitalism or communism that gives a greater emphasis to the interaction of the human economy and the natural environment acknowledging that economy is three fifths of ecology Mike Nickerson This political group is a proponent of a transition to renewable energy These more radical approaches would imply changes to money supply and likely also a bioregional democracy so that political economic and ecological environmental limits were all aligned and not subject to the arbitrage normally possible under capitalism An emerging sub field of environmental economics studies its intersection with development economics Dubbed envirodevonomics by Michael Greenstone and B Kelsey Jack in their paper Envirodevonomics A Research Agenda for a Young Field the sub field is primarily interested in studying why environmental quality is so poor in developing countries 23 A strategy for better understanding this correlation between a country s GDP and its environmental quality involves analyzing how many of the central concepts of environmental economics including market failures externalities and willingness to pay may be complicated by the particular problems facing developing countries such as political issues lack of infrastructure or inadequate financing tools among many others 24 In the field of law and economics environmental law is studied from an economic perspective The economic analysis of environmental law studies instruments such as zoning expropriation licensing third party liability safety regulation mandatory insurance and criminal sanctions A book by Michael Faure 2003 surveys this literature 25 Professional bodies editThe main academic and professional organizations for the discipline of Environmental Economics are the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists AERE and the European Association for Environmental and Resource Economics EAERE The main academic and professional organization for the discipline of Ecological Economics is the International Society for Ecological Economics ISEE The main organization for Green Economics is the Green Economics Institute See also editAgroecology Carbon fee and dividend Carbon finance Carbon negative fuel Circular economy Earth Economics policy think tank Eco capitalism Eco commerce Economics of global warming Ecometrics Eco Money Eco socialism Ecosystem Marketplace Ecotax Energy balance Environmental accounting Environmental economists category Environmental credit crunch Environmental enterprise Environmental Investment Organisation Environmental pricing reform Environmental tariff Fair trade Fiscal environmentalism Free market environmentalism Green banking Green libertarianism Green syndicalism Green trading Gross domestic product Further criticisms ISO 14000 environmental standards List of scholarly journals in environmental economics Natural capital Natural resource Natural resource economics Principles of ecopreneurship Property rights economics Renewable resource Risk assessment Strategic Sustainable Investing SSI Systems ecology World Ecological Forum Hypotheses and theorems edit Coase theorem Porter hypothesisNotes edit Understanding Environmental Economics Investopedia Retrieved 2022 05 01 Environmental Economics NBER Working Group Descriptions National Bureau of Economic Research Retrieved 2006 07 23 Jeroen C J M van den Bergh 2001 Ecological Economics Themes Approaches and Differences with Environmental Economics Regional Environmental Change 2 1 pp 13 23 Archived 2008 10 31 at the Wayback Machine press Illge L Schwarze R 2009 A Matter of Opinion How Ecological and Neoclassical Environmental Economists Think about Sustainability and Economics Ecological Economics Pearce David 2002 An Intellectual History of Environmental Economics Annual Review of Energy and the Environment 27 1 57 81 doi 10 1146 annurev energy 27 122001 083429 ISSN 1056 3466 Rosser Barkley Jr September 13 1998 Paul Davidson s Economics PDF Working Paper No 251 Archived PDF from the original on 2010 12 29 Hanley N J Shogren and B White 2007 Environmental Economics in Theory and Practice Palgrave London Anderson D 2019 Environmental Economics and Natural Resource Management 1 Routledge New York Rita Yi Man Li 2012 The Internalisation Of Environmental Externalities Affecting Dwellings A Review Of Court Cases In Hong Kong Economic Affairs Volume 32 Issue 2 pages 81 87 Chapman Same May 3 2012 Environmental degradation replaces classic imperialism The Whitman College Pioneer Whitman College Heller Walter P and David A Starrett 1976 On the Nature of Externalities in Lin Stephen A Y ed Theory and Measurement of Economic Externalities Academic Press New York p 10 a b Ostrom E 1990 Governing the Commons Cambridge Cambridge University Press UK Government Official Documents February 2021 The Economics of Biodiversity The Dasgupta Review Headline Messages Harris J 2006 Environmental and Natural Resource Economics A Contemporary Approach Houghton Mifflin Company UK Government Official Documents February 2021 The Economics of Biodiversity The Dasgupta Review Headline Messages p 2 Kishtainy Niall 2018 02 27 A little history of economics ISBN 9780300234527 OCLC 1039849897 Myerson Roger B Satterthwaite Mark A 1983 Efficient mechanisms for bilateral trading PDF Journal of Economic Theory 29 2 265 281 doi 10 1016 0022 0531 83 90048 0 hdl 10419 220829 ISSN 0022 0531 Archived PDF from the original on 2006 09 01 Rob Rafael 1989 Pollution claim settlements under private information Journal of Economic Theory 47 2 307 333 doi 10 1016 0022 0531 89 90022 7 ISSN 0022 0531 Goldlucke Susanne Schmitz Patrick W 2018 Pollution claim settlements reconsidered Hidden information and bounded payments European Economic Review 110 211 222 doi 10 1016 j euroecorev 2018 08 005 ISSN 0014 2921 Gonzalez Stephane Marciano Alain Solal Philippe 2019 The social cost problem rights and the non empty core Journal of Public Economic Theory 21 2 347 365 doi 10 1111 jpet 12334 S2CID 158059174 Roberts David 2013 04 17 None of the world s top industries would be profitable if they paid for the natural capital they use Grist Retrieved 2022 12 14 a b Joseph 2013 04 01 Natural Capital at Risk The Top 100 Externalities of Business Capitals Coalition Retrieved 2022 12 14 Greenstone Michael Jack B Kelsey 2015 Envirodevonomics A Research Agenda for an Emerging Field Journal of Economic Literature 53 1 5 42 doi 10 1257 jel 53 1 5 S2CID 73594686 Inclusive green growth the pathway to sustainable development PDF Washington D C World Bank May 2012 pp 12 13 ISBN 978 0 8213 9552 3 Archived PDF from the original on 2012 05 21 Retrieved 15 January 2015 Faure Michael G 2003 The Economic Analysis of Environmental Policy and Law An Introduction Edward Elgar ISBN 9781843762348 References editAllen V Kneese and Clifford S Russell 1987 environmental economics The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics v 2 pp 159 64 Robert N Stavins 2008 environmental economics The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition Abstract amp article Maureen L Cropper and Wallace E Oates 1992 Environmental Economics A Survey Journal of Economic Literature 30 2 pp 675 740 press Pearce David 2002 An Intellectual History of Environmental Economics Annual Review of Energy and the Environment 27 57 81 doi 10 1146 annurev energy 27 122001 083429 Tausch Arno Smart Development An Essay on a New Political Economy of the Environment March 22 2016 Available at SSRN https ssrn com abstract 2752988 or https dx doi org 10 2139 ssrn 2752988 UNEP 2007 Guidelines for Conducting Economic Valuation of Coastal Ecosystem Goods and Services UNEP GEF SCS Technical Publication No 8 UNEP 2007 Procedure for Determination of National and Regional Economic Values for Ecotone Goods and Services and Total Economic Values of Coastal Habitats in the context of the UNEP GEF Project Entitled Reversing Environmental Degradation Trends in the South China Sea and Gulf of Thailand South China Sea Knowledge Document No 3 UNEP GEF SCS Inf 3 Perman Roger et al 2003 Natural Resource and Environment Economics PDF 3 ed Pearson ISBN 978 0273655596 Archived PDF from the original on 2018 06 18 Field Barry 2017 Environmental economics an introduction New York NY McGraw Hill ISBN 978 0 07 802189 3 OCLC 931860817 Further reading editDavid A Anderson 2019 Environmental Economics and Natural Resource Management 5e 2 New York Routledge Banzhaf H Spencer 2023 Pricing the Priceless A History of Environmental Economics Cambridge University Press Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Environmental economics amp oldid 1202963520, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.