fbpx
Wikipedia

Sharing economy

The sharing economy is a socio-economic system whereby consumers share in the creation, production, distribution, trade and consumption of goods, and services. These systems take a variety of forms, often leveraging information technology and the Internet, particularly digital platforms, to facilitate the distribution, sharing and reuse of excess capacity in goods and services.[1][2][3][4]

It can be facilitated by nonprofit organizations, usually based on the concept of book-lending libraries, in which goods and services are provided for free (or sometimes for a modest subscription) or by commercial entities, in which a company provides a service to customers for profit.

It relies on the will of the users to share and the overcoming of stranger danger.[5]

Origins edit

Dariusz Jemielniak and Aleksandra Przegalinska credit Marcus Felson and Joe L. Spaeth's academic article "Community Structure and Collaborative Consumption" published in 1978[6] with coining the term economy of sharing.[7]: 6 

The term "sharing economy" began to appear around the time of the Great Recession, enabling social technologies, and an increasing sense of urgency around global population growth and resource depletion. Lawrence Lessig was possibly first to use the term in 2008, though others claim the origin of the term is unknown.[8][9]

Definition and related concepts edit

There is a conceptual and semantic confusion caused by the many facets of Internet-based sharing leading to discussions regarding the boundaries and the scope of the sharing economy[10] and regarding the definition of the sharing economy.[11][7]: 7, 27  Arun Sundararajan noted in 2016 that he is "unaware of any consensus on a definition of the sharing economy".[12]: 27–28  As of 2015, according to a Pew Research Center survey, only 27% of Americans had heard of the term "sharing economy".[13] Survey respondents who had heard of the term had divergent views on what it meant, with many thinking it concerned "sharing" in the traditional sense of the term.[13]

The term "sharing economy" is often used in an ambiguous way and can imply different characteristics.[14] For example, the sharing economy is sometimes understood exclusively as a peer-to-peer phenomenon[15] while at times, it has been framed as a business-to-customer phenomenon.[16] Additionally, the sharing economy can be understood to encompass transactions with a permanent transfer of ownership of a resource, such as a sale,[17] while other times, transactions with a transfer of ownership are considered beyond the boundaries of the sharing economy.[18] One definition of the sharing economy, developed to integrate existing understandings and definitions, based on a systematic review is:

"the sharing economy is an IT-facilitated peer-to-peer model for commercial or non-commercial sharing of underutilized goods and service capacity through an intermediary without transfer of ownership"[14]

The phenomenon has been defined from a legal perspective as "a for-profit, triangular legal structure where two parties (Providers and Users) enter into binding contracts for the provision of goods (partial transfer of the property bundle of rights) or services (ad hoc or casual services) in exchange for monetary payment through an online platform operated by a third party (Platform Operator) with an active role in the definition and development of the legal conditions upon which the goods and services are provided."[19] Under this definition, the "Sharing Economy" is a triangular legal structure with three different legal actors: "1) a Platform Operator which using technology provides aggregation and interactivity to create a legal environment by setting the terms and conditions for all the actors; (2) a User who consumes the good or service on the terms and conditions set by the Platform Operator; and (3) a Provider who provides a good or service also abiding by the Platform Operator's terms and conditions."[19]

While the term "sharing economy" is the term most often used, the sharing economy is also referred to as the access economy, crowd-based capitalism, collaborative economy, community-based economy, gig economy, peer economy, peer-to-peer (P2P) economy, platform economy, renting economy and on-demand economy, through at times some of those terms have been defined as separate if related topics.[12]: 27–28 [20][21]

The notion of "sharing economy" has often been considered an oxymoron, and a misnomer for actual commercial exchanges.[22] Arnould and Rose proposed to replace the misleading term "sharing" with "mutuality".[23] In an article in Harvard Business Review, authors Giana M. Eckhardt and Fleura Bardhi argue that "sharing economy" is a misnomer, and that the correct term for this activity is access economy. The authors say, "When 'sharing' is market-mediated—when a company is an intermediary between consumers who don't know each other—it is no longer sharing at all. Rather, consumers are paying to access someone else's goods or services."[24] The article states that companies (such as Uber) that understand this, and whose marketing highlights the financial benefits to participants, are successful, while companies (such as Lyft) whose marketing highlights the social benefits of the service are less successful.[24] According to George Ritzer, this trend towards increased consumer input in commercial exchanges refers to the notion of prosumption, which, as such, is not new.[25] Jemielniak and Przegalinska note that the term sharing economy is often used to discuss aspects of the society that do not predominantly relate to the economy, and propose a broader term collaborative society for such phenomena.[7]: 11 

The term "platform capitalism" has been proposed by some scholars as more correct than "sharing economy" in discussion of activities of for-profit companies like Uber and Airbnb in the economy sector.[7]: 30  Companies that try to focus on fairness and sharing, instead of just profit motive, are much less common, and have been contrastingly described as platform cooperatives (or cooperativist platforms vs capitalist platforms). In turn, projects like Wikipedia, which rely on unpaid labor of volunteers, can be classified as commons-based peer-production initiatives. A related dimension is concerned with whether users are focused on non-profit sharing or maximizing their own profit.[7]: 31, 36  Sharing is a model that is adapting to the abundance of resource, whereas for-profit platform capitalism is a model that persists in areas where there is still a scarcity of resources.[7]: 38 

Yochai Benkler, one of the earliest proponents of open source software, who studied the tragedy of the commons, which refers to the idea that when people all act solely in our self-interest, they deplete the shared resources they need for their own quality of life, posited that network technology could mitigate this issue through what he called 'commons-based peer production', a concept first articulated in 2002.[26] Benkler then extended that analysis to "shareable goods" in Sharing Nicely: On Shareable Goods and the emergence of sharing as a modality of economic production, written in 2004.[27]

Actors of the sharing economy edit

There are a wide range of actors who participate in the sharing economy. This includes individual users, for-profit enterprises, social enterprise or cooperatives, digital platform companies, local communities, non-profit enterprises and the public sector or the government.[28] Individual users are the actors engaged in sharing goods and resources through "peer-to-peer (P2P) or business-to-peer (B2P) transactions".[28] The for-profit enterprises are those actors who are profit-seekers who buy, sell, lend, rent or trade with the use of digital platforms as means to collaborate with other actors. The social enterprise or referred to as cooperatives are mainly "motivated by social or ecological reasons" and seek to empower actors as means of genuine sharing. Digital platforms are technology firms that facilitate the relationship between transacting parties and make profits by charging commissions.[29] The local communities are the players at the local level with varied structures and sharing models where most activities are non-monetized and often carried out to further develop the community. The non-profit enterprises have a purpose of "advancing a mission or purpose" for a greater cause and this is their primary motivation which is genuine sharing of resources. In addition, the public sector or the government can participate in the sharing economy by "using public infrastructures to support or forge partnerships with other actors and to promote innovative forms of sharing".[28]

Commercial dimension edit

Lizzie Richardson noted that sharing economy "constitutes an apparent paradox, framed as both part of the capitalist economy and as an alternative".[30] A distinction can be made between free sharing, such as genuine sharing, and for-profit sharing, often associated with companies such as Uber, Airbnb, and TaskRabbit.[31][32][7]: 22–24  Commercial co-options of the 'sharing economy' encompass a wide range of structures including mostly for-profit, and, to a lesser extent, co-operative structures.[33] The sharing economy provides expanded access to products, services and talent beyond one-to-one or singular ownership, which is sometimes referred to as "disownership".[34] Individuals actively participate as users, providers, lenders or borrowers in varied and evolving peer-to-peer exchange schemes.[35]

The usage of the term sharing by for-profit companies has been described as "abuse" and "misuse" of the term, or more precisely, its commodification.[7]: 21, 24  In commercial applications, the sharing economy can be considered a marketing strategy more than an actual 'sharing economy' ethos;[7]: 8, 24  for example, Airbnb has sometimes been described as a platform for individuals to 'share' extra space in their homes, but in some cases, the space is rented, not shared. Airbnb listings additionally are often owned by property management corporations.[36][32] This has led to a number of legal challenges, with some jurisdiction ruling, for example, that ride sharing through for-profit services like Uber de facto makes the drivers indistinguishable from regular employees of ride sharing companies.[7]: 9  The escrow-like model practiced by several of the largest sharing economy platforms, which facilitate and handle contracting and payments on behalf of their subscribers, further underlines an emphasis on access and transaction rather than on sharing.[37]

Sharing of resources has been known in business-to-business (B2B) like heavy machinery in agriculture and forestry as well as in business-to-consumer (B2C) like self-service laundry. But three major drivers enable consumer-to-consumer (C2C) sharing of resources for a broad variety of new goods and services as well as new industries. First, customer behavior for many goods and services changes from ownership to sharing. Second, online social networks and electronic markets more easily link consumers. And third, mobile devices and electronic services make the use of shared goods and services more convenient.

Size and growth edit

United States edit

According to a report by the United States Department of Commerce in June 2016, quantitative research on the size and growth of the sharing economy remains sparse. Growth estimates can be challenging to evaluate due to different and sometimes unspecified definitions about what sort of activity counts as sharing economy transactions. The report noted a 2014 study by PricewaterhouseCoopers, which looked at five components of the sharing economy: travel, car sharing, finance, staffing and streaming. It found that global spending in these sectors totaled about $15 billion in 2014, which was only about 5% of the total spending in those areas. The report also forecasted a possible increase of "sharing economy" spending in these areas to $335 billion by 2025, which would be about 50% of the total spending in these five areas. A 2015 PricewaterhouseCoopers study found that nearly one-fifth of American consumers partake in some type of sharing economy activity.[38] A 2017 report by Diana Farrell and Fiona Greig suggested that at least in the US, sharing economy growth may have peaked.[39]

Europe edit

A February 2018 study ordered by the European Commission and the Directorate-General for Internal Market, Industry, Entrepreneurship and SMEs indicated the level of collaborative economy development between the EU-28 countries across the transport, accommodation, finance and online skills sectors. The size of the collaborative economy relative to the total EU economy was estimated to be €26.5 billion in 2016.[40] Some experts predict that shared economy could add between €160 and €572 billion to the EU economy in the upcoming years.[41]

China edit

In China, the sharing economy doubled in 2016, reaching 3.45 trillion yuan ($500 billion) in transaction volume, and was expected to grow by 40% per year on average over the next few years, according to the country's State Information Center.[42] In 2017, an estimated 700 million people used sharing economy platforms.[43]

Russia edit

According to TIARCENTER and the Russian Association of Electronic Communications, eight key verticals of Russia's sharing economy (C2C sales, odd jobs, car sharing, carpooling, accommodation rentals, shared offices, crowdfunding, and goods sharing) grew 30% to 511 billion rubles ($7.8 billion) in 2018.[44]

Japan edit

According to Sharing Economy Association of Japan, The market size of the sharing economy in Japan in FY2020 was 2.1004 trillion yen and FY2021 was 2.4198 trillion yen. It is expected to expand up to 14.2799 trillion yen in FY2030.[45] For ride-hailing services, there is no “Uber” like service which allow run your own ride-sharing fleet in Japan. This is because local regulations prohibit non-professional drivers from ferrying paying customers.

Economic effects edit

The impacts of the access economy in terms of costs, wages and employment are not easily measured and appear to be growing.[46] Various estimates indicate that 30-40% of the U.S. workforce is self-employed, part-time, temporary or freelancers. However, the exact percentage of those performing short-term tasks or projects found via technology platforms was not effectively measured as of 2015 by government sources.[47] In the U.S., one private industry survey placed the number of "full-time independent workers" at 17.8 million in 2015, roughly the same as 2014. Another survey estimated the number of workers who do at least some freelance work at 53.7 million in 2015, roughly 34% of the workforce and up slightly from 2014.[48]

Economists Lawrence F. Katz and Alan B. Krueger wrote in March 2016 that there is a trend towards more workers in alternative (part-time or contract) work arrangements rather than full-time; the percentage of workers in such arrangements rose from 10.1% in 2005 to 15.8% in late 2015.[49] Katz and Krueger defined alternative work arrangements as "temporary help agency workers, on-call workers, contract company workers, and independent contractors or free-lancers".[50] They also estimated that approximately 0.5% of all workers identify customers through an online intermediary; this was consistent with two others studies that estimated the amount at 0.4% and 0.6%.[50]

At the individual transaction level, the removal of a higher overhead business intermediary (say a taxi company) with a lower cost technology platform helps reduce the cost of the transaction for the customer while also providing an opportunity for additional suppliers to compete for the business, further reducing costs.[47] Consumers can then spend more on other goods and services, stimulating demand and production in other parts of the economy. Classical economics argues that innovation that lowers the cost of goods and services represents a net economic benefit overall. However, like many new technologies and business innovations, this trend is disruptive to existing business models and presents challenges for governments and regulators.[51]

For example, should the companies providing the technology platform be liable for the actions of the suppliers in their network? Should persons in their network be treated as employees, receiving benefits such as healthcare and retirement plans? If consumers tend to be higher income persons while the suppliers are lower-income persons, will the lower cost of the services (and therefore lower compensation of the suppliers) worsen income inequality? These are among the many questions the on-demand economy presents.[47][52]

Cost management and budgeting by providers edit

Using a personal car to transport passengers or deliveries requires payment, or sufferance, of costs for fees deducted by the dispatching company, fuel, wear and tear, depreciation, interest, taxes, as well as adequate insurance. The driver is typically not paid for driving to an area where fares might be found in the volume necessary for high earnings, or driving to the location of a pickup or returning from a drop-off point.[53] Mobile apps have been written that help a driver be aware of and manage such costs has been introduced.[54]

Effects on infrastructure edit

Ridesharing companies have affected traffic congestion and Airbnb has affected housing availability. According to transportation analyst Charles Komanoff, "Uber-caused congestion has reduced traffic speeds in downtown Manhattan by around 8 percent".[55]

Effects on crime and litigation edit

Depending on the structure of the country's legal system, companies involved in the sharing economy may shift legal realm where cases involving sharers is disputed. Technology (such as algorithmic controls) which connects sharers also allows for the development of policies and standards of service. Companies can act as 'guardians' of their customer base by monitoring their employee's behavior. For example, Uber and Lyft can monitor their employees' driving behavior, location, and provide emergency assistance.[56] Several studies have shown that In the United States, the sharing economy restructures how legal disputes are resolved and who is considered the victims of potential crime.

In the United States's civil law, the dispute is between two individuals, determining which individual (if any) is the victim of the other party. U.S. criminal law considers the actions of a criminal who "victimizes" the state or federal law(s) by breaking said law(s). In criminal law cases, a government court punishes the offender to make the legal victim (the government) whole, but any civilian victim does not necessarily receive restitution from the state. In civil law cases, it is the direct victim party, not the state, who receives the compensatory restitution, fees, or fines. While it is possible for both kinds of law to apply to a case, the additional contracts created in sharing economy agreements creates the opportunity for more cases to be classified as civil law disputes. When the sharing economy is directly involved, the victim is the individual rather than the state. This means the civilian victim of a crime is more likely to receive compensation under a civil law case in the sharing economy than in the criminal law precedent.[57] The introduction of civil law cases has the potential to increase victims' ability to be made whole, since the legal change shifts incentives of consumers towards action.[58]

Benefits edit

Suggested benefits of the sharing economy include:

Additional flexible job opportunities as gig workers edit

Freelance work entails better opportunities for employment, as well as more flexibility for workers, since people have the ability to pick and choose the time and place of their work. As freelance workers, people can plan around their existing schedules and maintain multiple jobs if needed. Evidence of the appeal to this type of work can be seen from a 2015 survey conducted by the Freelancers Union, which showed that around 34% of the U.S. population was involved in freelance work.[59]

Freelance work can also be beneficial for small businesses. During their early developmental stages, many small companies can't afford or aren't in need of full-time departments, but rather require specialized work for a certain project or for a short period of time. With freelance workers offering their services in the sharing economy, firms are able to save money on long-term labor costs and increase marginal revenue from their operations.[60]

The sharing economy allows workers to set their own hours of work. An Uber driver explains, "the flexibility extends far beyond the hours you choose to work on any given week. Since you don’t have to make any sort of commitment, you can easily take time off for the big moments in your life as well, such as vacations, a wedding, the birth of a child, and more."[61] Workers are able to accept or reject additional work based on their needs while using the commodities they already possess to make money. It provides increased flexibility of work hours and wages for independent contractors of the sharing economy[62]

Depending on their schedules and resources, workers can provide services in more than one area with different companies. This allows workers to relocate and continue earning income. Also, by working for such companies, the transaction costs associated with occupational licenses are significantly lowered. For example, in New York City, taxi drivers must have a special driver's license and undergo training and background checks,[63] while Uber contractors can offer "their services for little more than a background check".[64]

The percentage of seniors in the work force increased from 20.7% in 2009 to 23.1% in 2015, an increase in part attributed to additional employment as gig workers.[65]

Transparent and open data increases innovation edit

A common premise is that when information about goods is shared (typically via an online marketplace), the value of those goods may increase for the business, for individuals, for the community and for society in general.[66]

Many state, local and federal governments are engaged in open data initiatives and projects such as data.gov.[67] The theory of open or "transparent" access to information enables greater innovation, and makes for more efficient use of products and services, and thus supporting resilient communities.[68]

Reduction in unused value edit

Unused value refers to the time over which products, services, and talents lay idle. This idle time is wasted value that business models and organizations that are based on sharing can potentially utilize. The classic example is that the average car is unused 95% of the time.[69] This wasted value can be a significant resource, and hence an opportunity, for sharing economy car solutions. There is also significant unused value in "wasted time", as articulated by Clay Shirky in his analysis of the power of crowds connected by information technology.[citation needed] Many people have unused capacity in the course of their day. With social media and information technology, such people can donate small slivers of time to take care of simple tasks that others need doing. Examples of these crowdsourcing solutions include the for-profit Amazon Mechanical Turk[70] and the non-profit Ushahidi.

Christopher Koopman, an author of a 2015 study by George Mason University economists, said the sharing economy "allows people to take idle capital and turn them into revenue sources". He has stated, "People are taking spare bedroom[s], cars, tools they are not using and becoming their own entrepreneurs."[71]

Arun Sundararajan, a New York University economist who studies the sharing economy, told a congressional hearing that "this transition will have a positive impact on economic growth and welfare, by stimulating new consumption, by raising productivity, and by catalyzing individual innovation and entrepreneurship".[71]

Lower prices due to increased competition and reusing items edit

An independent data study conducted by Busbud in 2016 compared the average price of hotel rooms with the average price of Airbnb listings in thirteen major cities in the United States. The research concluded that in nine of the thirteen cities, Airbnb rates were lower than hotel rates by an average price of $34.56.[72] A further study conducted by Busbud compared the average hotel rate with the average Airbnb rate in eight major European cities. The research concluded that the Airbnb rates were lower than the hotel rates in six of the eight cities by a factor of $72.[72] Data from a separate study shows that with Airbnb's entry into the market in Austin, Texas hotels were required to lower prices by 6 percent to keep up with Airbnb's lower prices.[73]

The sharing economy lowers consumer costs via borrowing and recycling items.[74]

Environmental benefits edit

The sharing economy reduces negative environmental impacts by decreasing the amount of goods needed to be produced, cutting down on industry pollution (such as reducing the carbon footprint and overall consumption of resources)[75][74][76]

The sharing economy allows the reuse and repurpose of already existing commodities. Under this business model, private owners share the assets they already possess when not in use.[77]

The sharing economy accelerates sustainable consumption and production patterns.[78]

Access to goods without the requirement to purchase edit

The sharing economy provides people with access to goods who can't afford or have no interest in buying them.[79]

Increase in quality of products and services edit

The sharing economy facilitates increased quality of service through rating systems provided by companies involved in the sharing economy[80] It also facilitates increased quality of service provided by incumbent firms that work to keep up with sharing firms like Uber and Lyft[81]

Other benefits edit

A study in Intereconomics / The Review of European Economic Policy noted that the sharing economy has the potential to bring many benefits for the economy, while noting that this presupposes that the success of sharing economy services reflects their business models rather than 'regulatory arbitrage' from avoiding the regulation that affects traditional businesses.[82]

Additional benefits include:

  • Strengthening communities[74]
  • Increased independence, flexibility and self-reliance by decentralization, the abolition of monetary entry-barriers, and self-organization[83]
  • Increased participatory democracy[76]
  • Maximum benefit for sellers and buyers: Enables users to improve living standards by eliminating the emotional, physical, and social burdens of ownership. Without the need to maintain a large inventory, deadweight loss is reduced, prices are kept low, all while remaining competitive in the markets.[24]
  • New jobs are created, and products bought, as people acquire items such as cars or apartments to use in the sharing economy activities.[7]: 26 

Criticism edit

Oxford Internet Institute, Economic Geographer, Graham has argued that key parts of the sharing economy impose a new balance of power onto workers.[84] By bringing together workers in low- and high-income countries, gig economy platforms that are not geographically-confined can bring about a 'race to the bottom' for workers.

Relationship to job loss edit

New York Magazine wrote that the sharing economy has succeeded in large part because the real economy has been struggling. Specifically, in the magazine's view, the sharing economy succeeds because of a depressed labor market, in which "lots of people are trying to fill holes in their income by monetizing their stuff and their labor in creative ways", and in many cases, people join the sharing economy because they've recently lost a full-time job, including a few cases where the pricing structure of the sharing economy may have made their old jobs less profitable (e.g. full-time taxi drivers who may have switched to Lyft or Uber). The magazine writes that "In almost every case, what compels people to open up their homes and cars to complete strangers is money, not trust.... Tools that help people trust in the kindness of strangers might be pushing hesitant sharing-economy participants over the threshold to adoption. But what's getting them to the threshold in the first place is a damaged economy and harmful public policy that has forced millions of people to look to odd jobs for sustenance."[85][86][87]

Uber's "audacious plan to replace human drivers" may increase job loss as even freelance driving will be replaced by automation.[88]

However, in a report published in January 2017, Carl Benedikt Frey found that while the introduction of Uber had not led to jobs being lost, but had caused a reduction in the incomes of incumbent taxi drivers of almost 10%. Frey found that the "sharing economy", and Uber, in particular, has had substantial negative impacts on workers wages.[89]

Some people believe the Great Recession led to the expansion of the sharing economy because job losses enhanced the desire for temporary work, which is prevalent in the sharing economy. However, there are disadvantages to the worker; when companies use contract-based employment, the "advantage for a business of using such non-regular workers is obvious: It can lower labor costs dramatically, often by 30 percent, since it is not responsible for health benefits, social security, unemployment or injured workers' compensation, paid sick or vacation leave and more. Contract workers, who are barred from forming unions and have no grievance procedure, can be dismissed without notice".[55]

Treatment of workers as independent contractors and not employees edit

There is debate over the status of the workers within the sharing economy; whether they should be treated as independent contractors or employees of the companies. This issue seems to be most relevant among sharing economy companies such as Uber. The reason this has become such a major issue is that the two types of workers are treated very differently. Contract workers are not guaranteed any benefits and pay can be below average. However, if they are employees, they are granted access to benefits and pay is generally higher. This has been described as "shifting liabilities and responsibilities" to the workers, while denying them the traditional job security.[7]: 25  It has been argued that this trend is de facto "obliterating the achievements of unions thus far in their struggle to secure basic mutual obligations in worker-employer relations".[7]: 28 

In Uberland: How the Algorithms are Rewriting the Rules of Work, technology ethnographer Alex Rosenblat argues that Uber's reluctance to classify its drivers as "employees" strips them of their agency as the company's revenue-generating workforce, resulting in lower compensation and, in some cases, risking their safety.[90] In particular, Rosenblat critiques Uber's ratings system, which she argues elevates passengers to the role of "middle managers" without offering drivers the chance to contest poor ratings.[91] Rosenblat notes that poor ratings, or any other number of unspecified breaches of conduct, can result in an Uber driver's "deactivation", an outcome Rosenblat likens to being fired without notice or stated cause.[92] Prosecutors have used Uber's opaque firing policy as evidence of illegal worker misclassification; Shannon Liss-Riordan, an attorney leading a class action lawsuit against the company, claims that "the ability to fire at will is an important factor in showing a company's workers are employees, not independent contractors."[93]

The California Public Utilities Commission filed a case, later settled out of court, that "addresses the same underlying issue seen in the contract worker controversy—whether the new ways of operating in the sharing economy model should be subject to the same regulations governing traditional businesses".[94] Like Uber, Instakart faced similar lawsuits. In 2015, a lawsuit was filed against Instakart alleging the company misclassified a person who buys and delivers groceries as an independent contractor.[95] Instakart had to eventually make all such people as part-time employees and had to accord benefits such as health insurance to those qualifying. This led to Instakart having thousands of employees overnight from zero.[95]

A 2015 article by economists at George Mason University argued that many of the regulations circumvented by sharing economy businesses are exclusive privileges lobbied for by interest groups.[96] Workers and entrepreneurs not connected to the interest groups engaging in this rent-seeking behavior are thus restricted from entry into the market. For example, taxi unions lobbying a city government to restrict the number of cabs allowed on the road prevents larger numbers of drivers from entering the marketplace.

The same research finds that while access economy workers do lack the protections that exist in the traditional economy,[97] many of them cannot actually find work in the traditional economy.[96] In this sense, they are taking advantage of opportunities that the traditional regulatory framework has not been able to provide for them. As the sharing economy grows, governments at all levels are reevaluating how to adjust their regulatory schemes to accommodate these workers.

However, a 2021 research on Uber's downfall in Turkey, which was carried out with user-generated content from TripAdvisor comments and YouTube videos related to Uber use in Istanbul, finds that the main reasons for people to use Uber are that since the drivers are independent, they tend to treat the customers in a kinder way than the regular taxi drivers and that it's much cheaper to use Uber.[98] Although, Turkish taxi drivers claim that Uber's operations in Turkey are illegal because the independent drivers don't pay the operating license fee, which is compulsory for taxi drivers to pay, to the government. Their efforts led to the banning of Uber in Turkey by the Turkish government in October 2019. After being unavailable for approximately two years, Uber eventually became available again in Turkey in January 2021.[99]

Benefits not accrued evenly edit

Andrew Leonard,[100][101][102] Evgeny Morozov,[103] criticized the for-profit sector of the sharing economy, writing that sharing economy businesses "extract" profits from their given sector by "successfully [making] an end run around the existing costs of doing business" – taxes, regulations, and insurance. Similarly, In the context of online freelancing marketplaces, there have been worries that the sharing economy could result in a 'race to the bottom' in terms of wages and benefits: as millions of new workers from low-income countries come online.[104][105]

Susie Cagle wrote that the benefits big sharing economy players might be making for themselves are "not exactly" trickling down, and that the sharing economy "doesn't build trust" because where it builds new connections, it often "replicates old patterns of privileged access for some, and denial for others".[106] William Alden wrote that "The so-called sharing economy is supposed to offer a new kind of capitalism, one where regular folks, enabled by efficient online platforms, can turn their fallow assets into cash machines ... But the reality is that these markets also tend to attract a class of well-heeled professional operators, who outperform the amateurs—just like the rest of the economy".[107]

The local economic benefit of the sharing economy is offset by its current form, which is that huge tech companies reap a great deal of profit in many cases. For example, Uber, which is estimated to be worth $50B as of mid-2015,[108] takes up to 30% commission from the gross revenue of its drivers,[109] leaving many drivers making less than minimum wage.[110] This is reminiscent of a peak Rentier state "which derives all or a substantial portion of its national revenues from the rent of indigenous resources to external clients".

Other issues edit

  • Companies such as Airbnb and Uber do not share reputation data. Individual behavior on any one platform doesn't transfer to other platforms. This fragmentation has some negative consequences, such as the Airbnb squatters who had previously deceived Kickstarter users to the tune of $40,000.[111] Sharing data between these platforms could have prevented the repeat incident. Business Insider's view is that since the sharing economy is in its infancy, this has been accepted. However, as the industry matures, this will need to change.[112]
  • Giana Eckhardt and Fleura Bardhi say that the access economy promotes and prioritizes cheap fares and low costs rather than personal relationships, which is tied to similar issues in crowdsourcing. For example, consumers reap similar benefits from Zipcar as they would from a hotel. In this example, the primary concern is the low cost. Because of this, the "sharing economy" may not be about sharing but rather about access. Giana Eckhardt and Fleura Bardhi say the "sharing" economy has taught people to prioritize cheap and easy access over interpersonal communication, and the value of going the extra mile for those interactions has diminished.[113]
  • Concentration of power can lead to unethical business practices. By using a software named 'Greyball', Uber was able to make it difficult for regulatory officials to use the application.[114] Another schemes allegedly implemented by Uber includes using its application to show 'phantom' cars nearby to consumers on the app, implying shorter pick-up times than could actually be expected. Uber denied the allegation.[115]
  • Regulations that cover traditional taxi companies but not ridesharing companies can put taxis at a competitive disadvantage.[116] Uber has faced criticism from taxi drivers worldwide due to the increased competition. Uber has also been banned from several jurisdictions due to failure to comply with licensing laws.[117]
  • An umbrella sharing service named Sharing E Umbrella was started in 11 cities across China in 2017 lost almost all of the 300,000 umbrellas placed out for sharing purposes during the first few weeks.[118]
  • Treatment of workers/Lack of employee benefits: Since access economy companies rely on independent contractors, they are not offered the same protections as that of full-time salary employees in terms of workers comp, retirement plans, sick leave, and unemployment.[119][116] This debate has caused Uber to have to remove their presence in several locations such as Alaska. Uber stirred up a large controversy in Alaska because if Uber drivers were considered registered taxi drivers, that would mean they would be entitled to receiving workers' compensation insurance. However, if they were considered independent contractors they would not receive these same benefits. Due to all of the disputes, Uber pulled services from Alaska.[117] In addition, ride-share drivers’ status continues to be ambiguous when it comes to legal matters. On New Year's Eve in 2013, an off-duty driver for Uber killed a pedestrian while looking for a rider. Since the driver was considered a contractor, Uber would not compensate for the victim's family. The contract states that the service is a matching platform and "the company does not provide transportation services, and ... has no liability for services ... provided by third parties."[116]
  • Quality discrepancies: Since access economy companies rely on independent workers, the quality of service can differ between various individual providers on the same platform. In 2015, Steven Hill from the New America Foundation cited his experience signing up to become a host on Airbnb as simple as uploading a few photos to the website "and within 15 minutes my place was 'live' like an Airbnb rental. No background check, no verifying my ID, no confirming my personal details, no questions asked. Not even any contact with a real human from their trust and safety team. Nothing."[120] However, due to the reputation model, customers are provided with a peer-reviewed rating of the provider and are given a choice of whether to proceed with the transaction.
  • Inadequate liability guarantees: Though some companies offer liability guarantees such as Airbnb's "Host Guarantee" that promises to pay up to 1 million in damages, it is extremely difficult to prove fault.[121]
  • Ownership and usage: The access economy blurs the difference between ownership and usage, which allows for the abuse or neglect of items absent policies.
  • Replacement of small local companies with large international tech companies. For example, taxi companies tend to be locally owned and operated, while Uber is California-based. Therefore, taxi company profits tend to stay local, while some portion of access economy profits flows out of the local community.

Examples edit

Principles for regulation in the sharing economy edit

In order to reap the real benefits of a sharing economy and somehow address some issues that revolve around it, there is a great need for the government and policy-makers to create the “right enabling framework based on a set of guiding principles” proposed by the World Economic Forum. These principles are derived from the analysis of global policymaking and consultation with experts. The following are the seven principles for regulation in the sharing economy.[28]

  1. The first principle is creating space for innovation. This entails that “governments need to provide an initially encouraging environment while also building necessary infrastructure to allow for the development of innovation hubs.”[28]
  2. The second principle is that sharing economy should be people centered. This means that policies should be focused on “increasing the overall welfare of the population” as well as “improving the quality of life.”[28]
  3. The third principle is taking a proactive approach. This means that “new business models need to be brought into the mainstream and governments need to make clear frameworks that minimize uncertainty.”[28]
  4. The fourth principle is the assessment of the whole regulatory system which means administrative burdens on exiting systems should be lifted in order to give equal level of access to all actors in the network.[28]
  5. The fifth principle is the data-driven government. Since most sharing economy relies on the use of digital platforms, data can be easily collected, analyzed, and shared which can boost the urban environment through public-private partnerships.[28]
  6. The sixth principle talks about the flexible governance where actors should consider the nature of technology which is fast evolving. This calls for a sustained dialogue with key stakeholders, so all interests and rights are further protected and safeguarded.[28]
  7. The last principle is a shared regulation where all the players should be involved in regulatory discussions as well as in the enforcement of policy.[28]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ "What Is the Sharing Economy?". Dotdash Meredith. November 10, 2021.
  2. ^ David, Matthew (2017). "Sharing: post-scarcity beyond capitalism?". Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society. 10 (2): 311–325. doi:10.1093/cjres/rsx003.
  3. ^ Daglis, Theodoros (2022). "Sharing Economy". Encyclopedia. 2 (3): 1322–1332. doi:10.3390/encyclopedia2030088.
  4. ^ Bradley, Karin; Pargman, Daniel (2017). "The sharing economy as the commons of the 21st century". Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society. 10 (2): 231–247. doi:10.1093/cjres/rsx001.
  5. ^ Hyun, Hong Ji; Cho, Kim Byung; Sam, Park Kyung (June 2019). "Optimal risk management for the sharing economy with stranger danger and service quality". European Journal of Operational Research. 279 (3): 1024–1035. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2019.06.020. S2CID 197523623.
  6. ^ Felson, Marcus; Spaeth, Joe L. (1978). "Community Structure and Collaborative Consumption: A Routine Activity Approach". American Behavioral Scientist. 21 (4): 614–624. doi:10.1177/000276427802100411. S2CID 147181824.
  7. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m Jemielniak, Dariusz; Przegalinska, Aleksandra (2020). Collaborative Society. MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-35645-9.
  8. ^ Stephany, Alex (2015). The Business of Sharing: Making it in the New Sharing Economy. Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 978-1137376176.
  9. ^ "Homestay is the origin of Sharing Economy" (Press release). Homestayin.com. March 11, 2014 – via PR Newswire.
  10. ^ Trenz, Manuel; Frey, Alexander; Veit, Daniel (2018-08-06). "Disentangling the facets of sharing". Internet Research. 28 (4): 888–925. doi:10.1108/IntR-11-2017-0441. ISSN 1066-2243.
  11. ^ Cheng, Mingming (2016). "Sharing economy: A review and agenda for future research". International Journal of Hospitality Management. 57: 60–70. doi:10.1016/j.ijhm.2016.06.003.
  12. ^ a b Sundararajan, Arun (2016). The Sharing Economy: The End of Employment and the Rise of Crowd-Based Capitalism. MIT Press.
  13. ^ a b Kenneth Olmstead and Aaron Smith (20 May 2016). "How Americans define the sharing economy". Pew Research Center.
  14. ^ a b Schlagwein, Daniel; Schoder, Detlef; Spindeldreher, Kai (2019). "Consolidated, systemic conceptualization, and definition of the "sharing economy". Journal of the Association for Information Science and Technology. 71 (7): 817–838. doi:10.1002/asi.24300.
  15. ^ Gobble, MaryAnne M. (2015). "Regulating Innovation in the New Economy". Research Technology Management. 58 (2): 62–67.
  16. ^ Heinrichs, Harald (2013). "Sharing economy: A potential new pathway to sustainability". Gaia. 22 (4): 228–231. doi:10.14512/gaia.22.4.5.
  17. ^ Botsman, Rachel; Rogers, Roo (2010). What's mine is yours. The rise of collaborative consumption. New York: Harper Business.
  18. ^ Gutt, Dominik; Hermann, Philipp (2015). Sharing Means Caring? Hosts' Price Reaction to Rating Visibility. European Conference on Information Systems. Münster, Germany.
  19. ^ a b Diaz-Granados, Juan; Sheehy, Benedict (2021). "The Sharing Economy & the Platform-User-Provider 'PUP Model': Analytical Legal Frameworks". Fordham Intellectual Property, Media & Entertainment Law Journal. 31 (4).
  20. ^ Russell W. Belk; Giana M. Eckhardt; Fleura Bardhi. Handbook of the Sharing Economy. Edward Elgar Publishing. pp. 178–. ISBN 978-1-78811-054-9.
  21. ^ Geissinger, Andrea; Laurell, Christofer; Öberg, Christina; Sandström, Christian; Suseno, Yuliani (2020-02-18). "Assessing user perceptions of the interplay between the sharing, access, platform and community‐based economies". Information Technology & People. 33 (3): 1037–1051. doi:10.1108/ITP-12-2019-0649. ISSN 0959-3845. S2CID 212846123.
  22. ^ Slee, Tom (2015). What's yours is mine. OR Books. p. 216. ISBN 978-1-68219-022-7.
  23. ^ Arnould, Eric. J.; Rose, Alexander S. (2016). "Mutuality: Critique and substitute for Belk's sharing". Marketing Theory. 16 (1): 75. doi:10.1177/1470593115572669. S2CID 220081479.
  24. ^ a b c Eckhardt, Giana M.; Bardhi, Fleura (January 28, 2015). "The Sharing Economy Isn't About Sharing at All". Harvard Business Review.
  25. ^ Ritzer, George (2014). "Prosumption: Evolution, revolution, or eternal return of the same?". Journal of Consumer Culture. 14 (1): 3–24. doi:10.1177/1469540513509641. S2CID 147095174.
  26. ^ Benkler, Yochai (2002). "Coase's Penguin, or, Linux and The Nature of the Firm". The Yale Law Journal. 112 (3): 369–446. arXiv:cs/0109077. doi:10.2307/1562247. hdl:10535/2974. JSTOR 1562247. S2CID 16684329.
  27. ^ Benkler, Yochai (2004). "Sharing Nicely: On Shareable Goods and the emergence of sharing as a modality of economic production". The Yale Law Journal. 114 (2): 273–358. doi:10.2307/4135731. JSTOR 4135731.
  28. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k World Economic Forum (2017). "Collaboration in Cities: From Sharing to 'Sharing Economy'" (PDF). World Economic Forum. Retrieved December 26, 2020.
  29. ^ Sutherland, W; Jarrahi, M.H. (2018). "The sharing economy and digital platforms: A review and research agenda". International Journal of Information Management. 43: 328–341. doi:10.1016/j.ijinfomgt.2018.07.004. S2CID 52821010.
  30. ^ Richardson, Lizzie (2015-12-01). "Performing the sharing economy". Geoforum. 67: 121–129. doi:10.1016/j.geoforum.2015.11.004. ISSN 0016-7185.
  31. ^ Laurell, Christofer; Sandström, Christian (June 2016). "Analysing Uber in social media – disruptive technology or institutional disruption?". International Journal of Innovation Management. 20 (5): 1640013. doi:10.1142/S1363919616400132.
  32. ^ a b Tuttle, Brad (June 30, 2014). "Can We Stop Pretending the Sharing Economy Is All About Sharing?". MONEY.com.
  33. ^ Rosenberg, Tina (June 5, 2013). "It's Not Just Nice to Share, It's the Future". The New York Times.
  34. ^ Grant, Rebecca (April 3, 2013). "Disownership is the new normal: the rise of the shared economy (infographic)". VentureBeat.
  35. ^ "The Collaborative Economy". Altimeter Group. June 4, 2013.
  36. ^ Mead, Rebecca (April 22, 2019). "The Airbnb invasion of Barcelona".
  37. ^ "The PerfectKLIK Way". PerfectKLIK. 2017-07-21.
  38. ^ Cusumano, Michael A. (January 2018). "The Sharing Economy Meets Reality". Communications of the ACM.
  39. ^ Juliet Schor (17 May 2018). "The platform economy". University of California, Berkeley.
  40. ^ European Commission. Directorate General for Internal Market, Industry, Entrepreneurship and SMEs.; Technopolis.; VVA Consulting.; Trinomics. (2018). Study to monitor the economic development of the collaborative economy at sector level in the 28 EU Member States: final report. LU: Publications Office. doi:10.2873/83555. ISBN 9789279817281.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  41. ^ European Commission (2 Jun 2016). "A European agenda for the collaborative economy". European Commission Publications: 1–16.
  42. ^ "China's "sharing economy" up 103 pct in 2016: report". Xinhua News Agency. May 3, 2017.
  43. ^ Wang, Iris (November 7, 2018). "A glimpse at China's burgeoning sharing economy". Shareable.
  44. ^ "Sharing economy in Russia 2018" (PDF). TIARCENTER. November 22, 2018.
  45. ^ "【Press release】2021年、日本のシェアリングエコノミー市場規模が、過去最高の2兆4,198億円を記録。2030年度には「14兆2,799億円」に拡大予測。". Sharing Economy Association, Japan. June 10, 2022.
  46. ^ "The Gig Economy: Implications of the Growth of Contingent Work". Federal Reserve.
  47. ^ a b c "Gig Economy Hasn't Taken Over". Bloomberg News. August 28, 2015.
  48. ^ "Gig Economy Is Growing, But Not Growing Up". Bloomberg.com. October 1, 2015 – via www.bloomberg.com.
  49. ^ "The Gig Economy Is Just Part of the Unsettling New World of Work". Bloomberg.com. June 2, 2016 – via www.bloomberg.com.
  50. ^ a b (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on February 18, 2019. Retrieved March 23, 2019.
  51. ^ Hazlitt, Henry (1979). Economics in One Lesson. Three Rivers Press. ISBN 0-517-54823-2.
  52. ^ "GAO-Contingent Workforce: Size, Characteristics, Earnings, Benefits-April 2015" (PDF).
  53. ^ Guendelsberger, Emily (May 7, 2015). "I was an undercover Uber driver". Philadelphia City Paper.
  54. ^ Natasha Singer and Mike Isaac (May 9, 2015). "An App That Helps Drivers Earn the Most From Their Trips". The New York Times.
  55. ^ a b "How the Sharing Economy Screws American Workers". The Huffington Post. January 20, 2016.
  56. ^ Wiener, Martin; Cram, W.; Benlian, Alexander (2021-09-22). "Algorithmic control and gig workers: a legitimacy perspective of Uber drivers". European Journal of Information Systems. 32 (3): 485–507. doi:10.1080/0960085X.2021.1977729. ISSN 0960-085X. S2CID 239262702.
  57. ^ Stickle, Ben (2023-01-04). "Crime Sharing: How the Sharing Economy may Impact Crime Victims". Victims & Offenders: 1–20. doi:10.1080/15564886.2022.2159905. ISSN 1556-4886. S2CID 255704014.
  58. ^ Wiener, Martin; Cram, W.; Benlian, Alexander (2021-09-22). "Algorithmic control and gig workers: a legitimacy perspective of Uber drivers". European Journal of Information Systems. 32 (3): 485–507. doi:10.1080/0960085X.2021.1977729. ISSN 0960-085X. S2CID 239262702.
  59. ^ Kumar, S. (July 20, 2015). "3 reasons to cheer Uber and the sharing economy". Fortune.
  60. ^ Hakobyan, Margarita (February 22, 2017). "The Sharing Economy Benefits Business". Business.com.
  61. ^ Johnson, Holly. "How to Make Money Driving for Uber". The Simple Dollar.
  62. ^ Geron, Tomio (January 23, 2013). "Airbnb And The Unstoppable Rise Of The Share Economy". Forbes.
  63. ^ "How to become a New York Taxi Driver".
  64. ^ Given, Casey (January 11, 2015). "Uber Economics: How Markets are Changing in the Sharing Economy". Atlas Network.
  65. ^ VERNON, STEVE (August 26, 2016). "How seniors are tapping the gig economy". CBS News.
  66. ^ Geron, Tomio (November 9, 2012). "Airbnb Had $56 Million Impact On San Francisco: Study". Forbes.
  67. ^ Mazmanian, Adam (May 22, 2013). "Can open data change the culture of government?". Federal Computer Week.
  68. ^ Ross, Eleanor (August 18, 2015). "How open data can help save lives". The Guardian.
  69. ^ Morris, David Z. (March 13, 2016). "Today's Cars Are Parked 95% of the Time". Fortune.
  70. ^ Boudreau, Kevin; Lakhani, Karim R. (April 2013). "Using the Crowd as an Innovation Partner". Harvard Business Review. 91 (4): 60–9, 140. PMID 23593768.
  71. ^ a b "'Sharing economy' reshapes markets, as complaints rise". The Star. AFP. February 9, 2015.
  72. ^ a b "Comparing Airbnb and Hotel Rates Around the Globe". Busbud. February 18, 2016.
  73. ^ Zervas, G.; Proserpio, D.; Byers, J. W. (2017). "The Rise of the Sharing Economy: Estimating the Impact of Airbnb on the Hotel Industry". Journal of Marketing Research. 54 (5): 687–705. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.645.4284. doi:10.1509/jmr.15.0204. S2CID 4837143.
  74. ^ a b c Rudenko, Anna (16 August 2013). "The collaborative consumption on the rise: why shared economy is winning over the "capitalism of me"".
  75. ^ Brady, Diane (24 September 2014). "The Environmental Case for the Sharing Economy". Bloomberg News.
  76. ^ a b Parsons, Adam (5 March 2014). "The sharing economy: a short introduction to its political evolution". openDemocracy.
  77. ^ Lombardo, Crystal (October 29, 2015). "Pros and Cons of Sharing Economy". Vision Launch.
  78. ^ Cohen, Boyd; Muñoz, Pablo (2015). "Sharing cities and sustainable consumption and production: towards an integrated framework" (PDF). Journal of Cleaner Production. 134: 87–97. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2015.07.133.   | Post-print version  
  79. ^ Bradshaw, Della (22 April 2015). "Sharing economy benefits lower income groups". Financial Times.
  80. ^ Jerome, Joseph (June 8, 2015). "User Reputation: Building Trust and Addressing Privacy Issues in the Sharing Economy". Future of Privacy Forum.
  81. ^ Wallsten, Scott (June 1, 2017). "The Competitive Effects of the Sharing Economy: How is Uber Changing Taxis?". Technology Policy Institute.
  82. ^ Munkoe, M. (2017) "Regulating the European Sharing Economy: State of Play and Challenges". Intereconomics / The Review of European Economic Policy. Volume 52, January/February 2017, Number 1 | pp. 38–44
  83. ^ Williams-Grut, Oscar (20 March 2015). "Silicon Round-up: Blockchain banking to be on the slate for new regulator?". Evening Standard.
  84. ^ Graham, Mark (May 25, 2016). "Digital work marketplaces impose a new balance of power". New Internationalist.
  85. ^ Roose, Kevin (April 24, 2014). "The Sharing Economy Isn't About Trust, It's About Desperation". New York Magazine.
  86. ^ Roose, Kevin (September 18, 2014). "Does Silicon Valley Have a Contract-Worker Problem?". New York Magazine.
  87. ^ Benner, Katie (October 2, 2014). "A Secret of Uber's Success: Struggling Workers". Bloomberg News.
  88. ^ "Uber's audacious plan to replace human drivers". CBS News.
  89. ^ Frey, Carl Benedikt (January 2017). "Drivers of Disruption? Estimating the Uber Effect".
  90. ^ Rosenblat, Alex. (2019). UBERLAND : how algorithms are rewriting the rules of work. University of California Press. pp. 138–147. ISBN 978-0-520-32480-0. OCLC 1088531727.
  91. ^ Rosenblat, Alex (2019). UBERLAND : how algorithms are rewriting the rules of work. UNIV OF CALIFORNIA PRESS. p. 149. ISBN 978-0-520-32480-0. OCLC 1088531727.
  92. ^ Rosenblat, Alex (2019). UBERLAND : how algorithms are rewriting the rules of work. UNIV OF CALIFORNIA PRESS. p. 152. ISBN 978-0-520-32480-0. OCLC 1088531727.
  93. ^ Huet, Ellen. "How Uber's Shady Firing Policy Could Backfire On The Company". Forbes. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  94. ^ "Sharing Economy Companies Sharing the Heat In Contractor Controversy". Xconomy. July 17, 2015.
  95. ^ a b "Apoorva Mehta had 20 failed start-ups before Instacart". Los Angeles Times. January 27, 2017. ISSN 0458-3035.
  96. ^ a b Koopman, Christopher; Mitchell, Matthew D.; Thierer, Adam D. (May 15, 2015). "The Sharing Economy and Consumer Protection Regulation: The Case for Policy Change". The Journal of Business, Entrepreneurship & the Law. 8: 530–545. SSRN 2535345.
  97. ^ Taeihagh, Araz (19 June 2017). "Crowdsourcing, Sharing Economies, and Development". Journal of Developing Societies. 33 (2): 191–222. arXiv:1707.06603. doi:10.1177/0169796X17710072. S2CID 32008949.
  98. ^ Çakar, Kadir (11 January 2021). "The downfall of Uber in Turkey: a case study on tourism in Istanbul, Turkey". Anatolia. 32 (3): 521–524. doi:10.1080/13032917.2021.1874447. S2CID 234312568.
  99. ^ "Ride-share application Uber becomes available again in Turkey". duvaR English. 13 January 2021. Retrieved 12 December 2022.
  100. ^ Millennials will not be regulated, Andrew Leonard, Salon.com, 2013.09.20
  101. ^ Leonard, Andrew (September 17, 2013). "The sharing economy muscles up". Salon.com.
  102. ^ Leonard, Andrew (2014-06-27). "Libertarians' anti-government crusade: Now there's an app for that". Salon.com.
  103. ^ Morozov, Evgeny (September 2014). "Don't believe the hype, the 'sharing economy' masks a failing economy". The Guardian.
  104. ^ Graham, Mark (2016). "Digital work marketplaces impose a new balance of power". New Internationalist.
  105. ^ Graham, Mark (2016). "Organising in the "digital wild west": can strategic bottlenecks help prevent a race to the bottom for online workers?". Union Solidarity International.
  106. ^ The Case Against Sharing: On access, scarcity, and trust (2014-05-28), Susie Cagle, Medium.com
  107. ^ The Business Tycoons of Airbnb, The New York Times
  108. ^ "'Sharing economy' reshapes markets, as complaints rise". Bloomberg News. 2015-02-03.
  109. ^ Huet, Ellen (2015-05-18). "Uber Tests Taking Even More From Its Drivers With 30% Commission". Forbes.
  110. ^ "A Philadelphia journalist went undercover as an Uber driver — here's how much she made". MSN. 2015-05-09.
  111. ^ Kevin Montgomery, Airbnb Squatters Also Swindled $40,000 From Kickstarter, 2014-07-28
  112. ^ Patrick J. Stewart, Reputation And The Sharing Economy (2014-10-23), "Business Insider
  113. ^ Giana Eckhardt and Fleura Bardhi, The Sharing Economy isn't About Sharing at All (2015-02-09), Harvard Business Review
  114. ^ Isaac, Mike (March 3, 2017). "How Uber Deceives the Authorities Worldwide". The New York Times.
  115. ^ Hern, Alex (July 30, 2015). "Uber denies misleading passengers with 'phantom cars' on app". The Guardian.
  116. ^ a b c Malhotra, Arvind (November 2014). "The Dark Side of the Sharing Economy...and How to Lighten It". Communications of the ACM. 57 (11): 24–27. doi:10.1145/2668893. S2CID 207219285.
  117. ^ a b Rhodes, Anna (2017-04-28). "These are all the places in the world that have banned Uber". The Independent.
  118. ^ He, Huifeng (2017-07-07). "Chinese umbrella-sharing firm remains upbeat despite losing most of its 300,000 brollies". South China Morning Post.
  119. ^ Huet, Ellen (6 January 2015). "What Happens to Uber Drivers And Other Sharing Economy Workers Injured On The Job?". Forbes.
  120. ^ Hill, Steven (30 October 2015). "The two faces of Airbnb". Business Insider.
  121. ^ Bort, Julie (9 October 2014). "Airbnb Banned From Condo Complex After Guest Caused $10,000 Of Damage". Business Insider.

sharing, economy, sharing, economy, socio, economic, system, whereby, consumers, share, creation, production, distribution, trade, consumption, goods, services, these, systems, take, variety, forms, often, leveraging, information, technology, internet, particu. The sharing economy is a socio economic system whereby consumers share in the creation production distribution trade and consumption of goods and services These systems take a variety of forms often leveraging information technology and the Internet particularly digital platforms to facilitate the distribution sharing and reuse of excess capacity in goods and services 1 2 3 4 It can be facilitated by nonprofit organizations usually based on the concept of book lending libraries in which goods and services are provided for free or sometimes for a modest subscription or by commercial entities in which a company provides a service to customers for profit It relies on the will of the users to share and the overcoming of stranger danger 5 Contents 1 Origins 2 Definition and related concepts 3 Actors of the sharing economy 4 Commercial dimension 5 Size and growth 5 1 United States 5 2 Europe 5 3 China 5 4 Russia 5 5 Japan 6 Economic effects 6 1 Cost management and budgeting by providers 6 2 Effects on infrastructure 6 3 Effects on crime and litigation 7 Benefits 7 1 Additional flexible job opportunities as gig workers 7 2 Transparent and open data increases innovation 7 3 Reduction in unused value 7 4 Lower prices due to increased competition and reusing items 7 5 Environmental benefits 7 6 Access to goods without the requirement to purchase 7 7 Increase in quality of products and services 7 8 Other benefits 8 Criticism 8 1 Relationship to job loss 8 2 Treatment of workers as independent contractors and not employees 8 3 Benefits not accrued evenly 8 4 Other issues 9 Examples 10 Principles for regulation in the sharing economy 11 See also 12 ReferencesOrigins editDariusz Jemielniak and Aleksandra Przegalinska credit Marcus Felson and Joe L Spaeth s academic article Community Structure and Collaborative Consumption published in 1978 6 with coining the term economy of sharing 7 6 The term sharing economy began to appear around the time of the Great Recession enabling social technologies and an increasing sense of urgency around global population growth and resource depletion Lawrence Lessig was possibly first to use the term in 2008 though others claim the origin of the term is unknown 8 9 Definition and related concepts editThere is a conceptual and semantic confusion caused by the many facets of Internet based sharing leading to discussions regarding the boundaries and the scope of the sharing economy 10 and regarding the definition of the sharing economy 11 7 7 27 Arun Sundararajan noted in 2016 that he is unaware of any consensus on a definition of the sharing economy 12 27 28 As of 2015 according to a Pew Research Center survey only 27 of Americans had heard of the term sharing economy 13 Survey respondents who had heard of the term had divergent views on what it meant with many thinking it concerned sharing in the traditional sense of the term 13 The term sharing economy is often used in an ambiguous way and can imply different characteristics 14 For example the sharing economy is sometimes understood exclusively as a peer to peer phenomenon 15 while at times it has been framed as a business to customer phenomenon 16 Additionally the sharing economy can be understood to encompass transactions with a permanent transfer of ownership of a resource such as a sale 17 while other times transactions with a transfer of ownership are considered beyond the boundaries of the sharing economy 18 One definition of the sharing economy developed to integrate existing understandings and definitions based on a systematic review is the sharing economy is an IT facilitated peer to peer model for commercial or non commercial sharing of underutilized goods and service capacity through an intermediary without transfer of ownership 14 The phenomenon has been defined from a legal perspective as a for profit triangular legal structure where two parties Providers and Users enter into binding contracts for the provision of goods partial transfer of the property bundle of rights or services ad hoc or casual services in exchange for monetary payment through an online platform operated by a third party Platform Operator with an active role in the definition and development of the legal conditions upon which the goods and services are provided 19 Under this definition the Sharing Economy is a triangular legal structure with three different legal actors 1 a Platform Operator which using technology provides aggregation and interactivity to create a legal environment by setting the terms and conditions for all the actors 2 a User who consumes the good or service on the terms and conditions set by the Platform Operator and 3 a Provider who provides a good or service also abiding by the Platform Operator s terms and conditions 19 While the term sharing economy is the term most often used the sharing economy is also referred to as the access economy crowd based capitalism collaborative economy community based economy gig economy peer economy peer to peer P2P economy platform economy renting economy and on demand economy through at times some of those terms have been defined as separate if related topics 12 27 28 20 21 The notion of sharing economy has often been considered an oxymoron and a misnomer for actual commercial exchanges 22 Arnould and Rose proposed to replace the misleading term sharing with mutuality 23 In an article in Harvard Business Review authors Giana M Eckhardt and Fleura Bardhi argue that sharing economy is a misnomer and that the correct term for this activity is access economy The authors say When sharing is market mediated when a company is an intermediary between consumers who don t know each other it is no longer sharing at all Rather consumers are paying to access someone else s goods or services 24 The article states that companies such as Uber that understand this and whose marketing highlights the financial benefits to participants are successful while companies such as Lyft whose marketing highlights the social benefits of the service are less successful 24 According to George Ritzer this trend towards increased consumer input in commercial exchanges refers to the notion of prosumption which as such is not new 25 Jemielniak and Przegalinska note that the term sharing economy is often used to discuss aspects of the society that do not predominantly relate to the economy and propose a broader term collaborative society for such phenomena 7 11 The term platform capitalism has been proposed by some scholars as more correct than sharing economy in discussion of activities of for profit companies like Uber and Airbnb in the economy sector 7 30 Companies that try to focus on fairness and sharing instead of just profit motive are much less common and have been contrastingly described as platform cooperatives or cooperativist platforms vs capitalist platforms In turn projects like Wikipedia which rely on unpaid labor of volunteers can be classified as commons based peer production initiatives A related dimension is concerned with whether users are focused on non profit sharing or maximizing their own profit 7 31 36 Sharing is a model that is adapting to the abundance of resource whereas for profit platform capitalism is a model that persists in areas where there is still a scarcity of resources 7 38 Yochai Benkler one of the earliest proponents of open source software who studied the tragedy of the commons which refers to the idea that when people all act solely in our self interest they deplete the shared resources they need for their own quality of life posited that network technology could mitigate this issue through what he called commons based peer production a concept first articulated in 2002 26 Benkler then extended that analysis to shareable goods in Sharing Nicely On Shareable Goods and the emergence of sharing as a modality of economic production written in 2004 27 Actors of the sharing economy editThere are a wide range of actors who participate in the sharing economy This includes individual users for profit enterprises social enterprise or cooperatives digital platform companies local communities non profit enterprises and the public sector or the government 28 Individual users are the actors engaged in sharing goods and resources through peer to peer P2P or business to peer B2P transactions 28 The for profit enterprises are those actors who are profit seekers who buy sell lend rent or trade with the use of digital platforms as means to collaborate with other actors The social enterprise or referred to as cooperatives are mainly motivated by social or ecological reasons and seek to empower actors as means of genuine sharing Digital platforms are technology firms that facilitate the relationship between transacting parties and make profits by charging commissions 29 The local communities are the players at the local level with varied structures and sharing models where most activities are non monetized and often carried out to further develop the community The non profit enterprises have a purpose of advancing a mission or purpose for a greater cause and this is their primary motivation which is genuine sharing of resources In addition the public sector or the government can participate in the sharing economy by using public infrastructures to support or forge partnerships with other actors and to promote innovative forms of sharing 28 Commercial dimension editLizzie Richardson noted that sharing economy constitutes an apparent paradox framed as both part of the capitalist economy and as an alternative 30 A distinction can be made between free sharing such as genuine sharing and for profit sharing often associated with companies such as Uber Airbnb and TaskRabbit 31 32 7 22 24 Commercial co options of the sharing economy encompass a wide range of structures including mostly for profit and to a lesser extent co operative structures 33 The sharing economy provides expanded access to products services and talent beyond one to one or singular ownership which is sometimes referred to as disownership 34 Individuals actively participate as users providers lenders or borrowers in varied and evolving peer to peer exchange schemes 35 The usage of the term sharing by for profit companies has been described as abuse and misuse of the term or more precisely its commodification 7 21 24 In commercial applications the sharing economy can be considered a marketing strategy more than an actual sharing economy ethos 7 8 24 for example Airbnb has sometimes been described as a platform for individuals to share extra space in their homes but in some cases the space is rented not shared Airbnb listings additionally are often owned by property management corporations 36 32 This has led to a number of legal challenges with some jurisdiction ruling for example that ride sharing through for profit services like Uber de facto makes the drivers indistinguishable from regular employees of ride sharing companies 7 9 The escrow like model practiced by several of the largest sharing economy platforms which facilitate and handle contracting and payments on behalf of their subscribers further underlines an emphasis on access and transaction rather than on sharing 37 Sharing of resources has been known in business to business B2B like heavy machinery in agriculture and forestry as well as in business to consumer B2C like self service laundry But three major drivers enable consumer to consumer C2C sharing of resources for a broad variety of new goods and services as well as new industries First customer behavior for many goods and services changes from ownership to sharing Second online social networks and electronic markets more easily link consumers And third mobile devices and electronic services make the use of shared goods and services more convenient Size and growth editThis article needs to be updated Please help update this article to reflect recent events or newly available information March 2023 United States edit According to a report by the United States Department of Commerce in June 2016 quantitative research on the size and growth of the sharing economy remains sparse Growth estimates can be challenging to evaluate due to different and sometimes unspecified definitions about what sort of activity counts as sharing economy transactions The report noted a 2014 study by PricewaterhouseCoopers which looked at five components of the sharing economy travel car sharing finance staffing and streaming It found that global spending in these sectors totaled about 15 billion in 2014 which was only about 5 of the total spending in those areas The report also forecasted a possible increase of sharing economy spending in these areas to 335 billion by 2025 which would be about 50 of the total spending in these five areas A 2015 PricewaterhouseCoopers study found that nearly one fifth of American consumers partake in some type of sharing economy activity 38 A 2017 report by Diana Farrell and Fiona Greig suggested that at least in the US sharing economy growth may have peaked 39 Europe edit A February 2018 study ordered by the European Commission and the Directorate General for Internal Market Industry Entrepreneurship and SMEs indicated the level of collaborative economy development between the EU 28 countries across the transport accommodation finance and online skills sectors The size of the collaborative economy relative to the total EU economy was estimated to be 26 5 billion in 2016 40 Some experts predict that shared economy could add between 160 and 572 billion to the EU economy in the upcoming years 41 China edit In China the sharing economy doubled in 2016 reaching 3 45 trillion yuan 500 billion in transaction volume and was expected to grow by 40 per year on average over the next few years according to the country s State Information Center 42 In 2017 an estimated 700 million people used sharing economy platforms 43 Russia edit According to TIARCENTER and the Russian Association of Electronic Communications eight key verticals of Russia s sharing economy C2C sales odd jobs car sharing carpooling accommodation rentals shared offices crowdfunding and goods sharing grew 30 to 511 billion rubles 7 8 billion in 2018 44 Japan edit According to Sharing Economy Association of Japan The market size of the sharing economy in Japan in FY2020 was 2 1004 trillion yen and FY2021 was 2 4198 trillion yen It is expected to expand up to 14 2799 trillion yen in FY2030 45 For ride hailing services there is no Uber like service which allow run your own ride sharing fleet in Japan This is because local regulations prohibit non professional drivers from ferrying paying customers Economic effects editThe impacts of the access economy in terms of costs wages and employment are not easily measured and appear to be growing 46 Various estimates indicate that 30 40 of the U S workforce is self employed part time temporary or freelancers However the exact percentage of those performing short term tasks or projects found via technology platforms was not effectively measured as of 2015 by government sources 47 In the U S one private industry survey placed the number of full time independent workers at 17 8 million in 2015 roughly the same as 2014 Another survey estimated the number of workers who do at least some freelance work at 53 7 million in 2015 roughly 34 of the workforce and up slightly from 2014 48 Economists Lawrence F Katz and Alan B Krueger wrote in March 2016 that there is a trend towards more workers in alternative part time or contract work arrangements rather than full time the percentage of workers in such arrangements rose from 10 1 in 2005 to 15 8 in late 2015 49 Katz and Krueger defined alternative work arrangements as temporary help agency workers on call workers contract company workers and independent contractors or free lancers 50 They also estimated that approximately 0 5 of all workers identify customers through an online intermediary this was consistent with two others studies that estimated the amount at 0 4 and 0 6 50 At the individual transaction level the removal of a higher overhead business intermediary say a taxi company with a lower cost technology platform helps reduce the cost of the transaction for the customer while also providing an opportunity for additional suppliers to compete for the business further reducing costs 47 Consumers can then spend more on other goods and services stimulating demand and production in other parts of the economy Classical economics argues that innovation that lowers the cost of goods and services represents a net economic benefit overall However like many new technologies and business innovations this trend is disruptive to existing business models and presents challenges for governments and regulators 51 For example should the companies providing the technology platform be liable for the actions of the suppliers in their network Should persons in their network be treated as employees receiving benefits such as healthcare and retirement plans If consumers tend to be higher income persons while the suppliers are lower income persons will the lower cost of the services and therefore lower compensation of the suppliers worsen income inequality These are among the many questions the on demand economy presents 47 52 Cost management and budgeting by providers edit Using a personal car to transport passengers or deliveries requires payment or sufferance of costs for fees deducted by the dispatching company fuel wear and tear depreciation interest taxes as well as adequate insurance The driver is typically not paid for driving to an area where fares might be found in the volume necessary for high earnings or driving to the location of a pickup or returning from a drop off point 53 Mobile apps have been written that help a driver be aware of and manage such costs has been introduced 54 Effects on infrastructure edit Ridesharing companies have affected traffic congestion and Airbnb has affected housing availability According to transportation analyst Charles Komanoff Uber caused congestion has reduced traffic speeds in downtown Manhattan by around 8 percent 55 Effects on crime and litigation edit Depending on the structure of the country s legal system companies involved in the sharing economy may shift legal realm where cases involving sharers is disputed Technology such as algorithmic controls which connects sharers also allows for the development of policies and standards of service Companies can act as guardians of their customer base by monitoring their employee s behavior For example Uber and Lyft can monitor their employees driving behavior location and provide emergency assistance 56 Several studies have shown that In the United States the sharing economy restructures how legal disputes are resolved and who is considered the victims of potential crime In the United States s civil law the dispute is between two individuals determining which individual if any is the victim of the other party U S criminal law considers the actions of a criminal who victimizes the state or federal law s by breaking said law s In criminal law cases a government court punishes the offender to make the legal victim the government whole but any civilian victim does not necessarily receive restitution from the state In civil law cases it is the direct victim party not the state who receives the compensatory restitution fees or fines While it is possible for both kinds of law to apply to a case the additional contracts created in sharing economy agreements creates the opportunity for more cases to be classified as civil law disputes When the sharing economy is directly involved the victim is the individual rather than the state This means the civilian victim of a crime is more likely to receive compensation under a civil law case in the sharing economy than in the criminal law precedent 57 The introduction of civil law cases has the potential to increase victims ability to be made whole since the legal change shifts incentives of consumers towards action 58 Benefits editSuggested benefits of the sharing economy include Additional flexible job opportunities as gig workers edit Freelance work entails better opportunities for employment as well as more flexibility for workers since people have the ability to pick and choose the time and place of their work As freelance workers people can plan around their existing schedules and maintain multiple jobs if needed Evidence of the appeal to this type of work can be seen from a 2015 survey conducted by the Freelancers Union which showed that around 34 of the U S population was involved in freelance work 59 Freelance work can also be beneficial for small businesses During their early developmental stages many small companies can t afford or aren t in need of full time departments but rather require specialized work for a certain project or for a short period of time With freelance workers offering their services in the sharing economy firms are able to save money on long term labor costs and increase marginal revenue from their operations 60 The sharing economy allows workers to set their own hours of work An Uber driver explains the flexibility extends far beyond the hours you choose to work on any given week Since you don t have to make any sort of commitment you can easily take time off for the big moments in your life as well such as vacations a wedding the birth of a child and more 61 Workers are able to accept or reject additional work based on their needs while using the commodities they already possess to make money It provides increased flexibility of work hours and wages for independent contractors of the sharing economy 62 Depending on their schedules and resources workers can provide services in more than one area with different companies This allows workers to relocate and continue earning income Also by working for such companies the transaction costs associated with occupational licenses are significantly lowered For example in New York City taxi drivers must have a special driver s license and undergo training and background checks 63 while Uber contractors can offer their services for little more than a background check 64 The percentage of seniors in the work force increased from 20 7 in 2009 to 23 1 in 2015 an increase in part attributed to additional employment as gig workers 65 Transparent and open data increases innovation edit A common premise is that when information about goods is shared typically via an online marketplace the value of those goods may increase for the business for individuals for the community and for society in general 66 Many state local and federal governments are engaged in open data initiatives and projects such as data gov 67 The theory of open or transparent access to information enables greater innovation and makes for more efficient use of products and services and thus supporting resilient communities 68 Reduction in unused value edit Unused value refers to the time over which products services and talents lay idle This idle time is wasted value that business models and organizations that are based on sharing can potentially utilize The classic example is that the average car is unused 95 of the time 69 This wasted value can be a significant resource and hence an opportunity for sharing economy car solutions There is also significant unused value in wasted time as articulated by Clay Shirky in his analysis of the power of crowds connected by information technology citation needed Many people have unused capacity in the course of their day With social media and information technology such people can donate small slivers of time to take care of simple tasks that others need doing Examples of these crowdsourcing solutions include the for profit Amazon Mechanical Turk 70 and the non profit Ushahidi Christopher Koopman an author of a 2015 study by George Mason University economists said the sharing economy allows people to take idle capital and turn them into revenue sources He has stated People are taking spare bedroom s cars tools they are not using and becoming their own entrepreneurs 71 Arun Sundararajan a New York University economist who studies the sharing economy told a congressional hearing that this transition will have a positive impact on economic growth and welfare by stimulating new consumption by raising productivity and by catalyzing individual innovation and entrepreneurship 71 Lower prices due to increased competition and reusing items edit An independent data study conducted by Busbud in 2016 compared the average price of hotel rooms with the average price of Airbnb listings in thirteen major cities in the United States The research concluded that in nine of the thirteen cities Airbnb rates were lower than hotel rates by an average price of 34 56 72 A further study conducted by Busbud compared the average hotel rate with the average Airbnb rate in eight major European cities The research concluded that the Airbnb rates were lower than the hotel rates in six of the eight cities by a factor of 72 72 Data from a separate study shows that with Airbnb s entry into the market in Austin Texas hotels were required to lower prices by 6 percent to keep up with Airbnb s lower prices 73 The sharing economy lowers consumer costs via borrowing and recycling items 74 Environmental benefits edit The sharing economy reduces negative environmental impacts by decreasing the amount of goods needed to be produced cutting down on industry pollution such as reducing the carbon footprint and overall consumption of resources 75 74 76 The sharing economy allows the reuse and repurpose of already existing commodities Under this business model private owners share the assets they already possess when not in use 77 The sharing economy accelerates sustainable consumption and production patterns 78 Access to goods without the requirement to purchase edit The sharing economy provides people with access to goods who can t afford or have no interest in buying them 79 Increase in quality of products and services edit The sharing economy facilitates increased quality of service through rating systems provided by companies involved in the sharing economy 80 It also facilitates increased quality of service provided by incumbent firms that work to keep up with sharing firms like Uber and Lyft 81 Other benefits edit A study in Intereconomics The Review of European Economic Policy noted that the sharing economy has the potential to bring many benefits for the economy while noting that this presupposes that the success of sharing economy services reflects their business models rather than regulatory arbitrage from avoiding the regulation that affects traditional businesses 82 Additional benefits include Strengthening communities 74 Increased independence flexibility and self reliance by decentralization the abolition of monetary entry barriers and self organization 83 Increased participatory democracy 76 Maximum benefit for sellers and buyers Enables users to improve living standards by eliminating the emotional physical and social burdens of ownership Without the need to maintain a large inventory deadweight loss is reduced prices are kept low all while remaining competitive in the markets 24 New jobs are created and products bought as people acquire items such as cars or apartments to use in the sharing economy activities 7 26 Criticism editOxford Internet Institute Economic Geographer Graham has argued that key parts of the sharing economy impose a new balance of power onto workers 84 By bringing together workers in low and high income countries gig economy platforms that are not geographically confined can bring about a race to the bottom for workers Relationship to job loss edit New York Magazine wrote that the sharing economy has succeeded in large part because the real economy has been struggling Specifically in the magazine s view the sharing economy succeeds because of a depressed labor market in which lots of people are trying to fill holes in their income by monetizing their stuff and their labor in creative ways and in many cases people join the sharing economy because they ve recently lost a full time job including a few cases where the pricing structure of the sharing economy may have made their old jobs less profitable e g full time taxi drivers who may have switched to Lyft or Uber The magazine writes that In almost every case what compels people to open up their homes and cars to complete strangers is money not trust Tools that help people trust in the kindness of strangers might be pushing hesitant sharing economy participants over the threshold to adoption But what s getting them to the threshold in the first place is a damaged economy and harmful public policy that has forced millions of people to look to odd jobs for sustenance 85 86 87 Uber s audacious plan to replace human drivers may increase job loss as even freelance driving will be replaced by automation 88 However in a report published in January 2017 Carl Benedikt Frey found that while the introduction of Uber had not led to jobs being lost but had caused a reduction in the incomes of incumbent taxi drivers of almost 10 Frey found that the sharing economy and Uber in particular has had substantial negative impacts on workers wages 89 Some people believe the Great Recession led to the expansion of the sharing economy because job losses enhanced the desire for temporary work which is prevalent in the sharing economy However there are disadvantages to the worker when companies use contract based employment the advantage for a business of using such non regular workers is obvious It can lower labor costs dramatically often by 30 percent since it is not responsible for health benefits social security unemployment or injured workers compensation paid sick or vacation leave and more Contract workers who are barred from forming unions and have no grievance procedure can be dismissed without notice 55 Treatment of workers as independent contractors and not employees edit There is debate over the status of the workers within the sharing economy whether they should be treated as independent contractors or employees of the companies This issue seems to be most relevant among sharing economy companies such as Uber The reason this has become such a major issue is that the two types of workers are treated very differently Contract workers are not guaranteed any benefits and pay can be below average However if they are employees they are granted access to benefits and pay is generally higher This has been described as shifting liabilities and responsibilities to the workers while denying them the traditional job security 7 25 It has been argued that this trend is de facto obliterating the achievements of unions thus far in their struggle to secure basic mutual obligations in worker employer relations 7 28 In Uberland How the Algorithms are Rewriting the Rules of Work technology ethnographer Alex Rosenblat argues that Uber s reluctance to classify its drivers as employees strips them of their agency as the company s revenue generating workforce resulting in lower compensation and in some cases risking their safety 90 In particular Rosenblat critiques Uber s ratings system which she argues elevates passengers to the role of middle managers without offering drivers the chance to contest poor ratings 91 Rosenblat notes that poor ratings or any other number of unspecified breaches of conduct can result in an Uber driver s deactivation an outcome Rosenblat likens to being fired without notice or stated cause 92 Prosecutors have used Uber s opaque firing policy as evidence of illegal worker misclassification Shannon Liss Riordan an attorney leading a class action lawsuit against the company claims that the ability to fire at will is an important factor in showing a company s workers are employees not independent contractors 93 The California Public Utilities Commission filed a case later settled out of court that addresses the same underlying issue seen in the contract worker controversy whether the new ways of operating in the sharing economy model should be subject to the same regulations governing traditional businesses 94 Like Uber Instakart faced similar lawsuits In 2015 a lawsuit was filed against Instakart alleging the company misclassified a person who buys and delivers groceries as an independent contractor 95 Instakart had to eventually make all such people as part time employees and had to accord benefits such as health insurance to those qualifying This led to Instakart having thousands of employees overnight from zero 95 A 2015 article by economists at George Mason University argued that many of the regulations circumvented by sharing economy businesses are exclusive privileges lobbied for by interest groups 96 Workers and entrepreneurs not connected to the interest groups engaging in this rent seeking behavior are thus restricted from entry into the market For example taxi unions lobbying a city government to restrict the number of cabs allowed on the road prevents larger numbers of drivers from entering the marketplace The same research finds that while access economy workers do lack the protections that exist in the traditional economy 97 many of them cannot actually find work in the traditional economy 96 In this sense they are taking advantage of opportunities that the traditional regulatory framework has not been able to provide for them As the sharing economy grows governments at all levels are reevaluating how to adjust their regulatory schemes to accommodate these workers However a 2021 research on Uber s downfall in Turkey which was carried out with user generated content from TripAdvisor comments and YouTube videos related to Uber use in Istanbul finds that the main reasons for people to use Uber are that since the drivers are independent they tend to treat the customers in a kinder way than the regular taxi drivers and that it s much cheaper to use Uber 98 Although Turkish taxi drivers claim that Uber s operations in Turkey are illegal because the independent drivers don t pay the operating license fee which is compulsory for taxi drivers to pay to the government Their efforts led to the banning of Uber in Turkey by the Turkish government in October 2019 After being unavailable for approximately two years Uber eventually became available again in Turkey in January 2021 99 Benefits not accrued evenly edit Andrew Leonard 100 101 102 Evgeny Morozov 103 criticized the for profit sector of the sharing economy writing that sharing economy businesses extract profits from their given sector by successfully making an end run around the existing costs of doing business taxes regulations and insurance Similarly In the context of online freelancing marketplaces there have been worries that the sharing economy could result in a race to the bottom in terms of wages and benefits as millions of new workers from low income countries come online 104 105 Susie Cagle wrote that the benefits big sharing economy players might be making for themselves are not exactly trickling down and that the sharing economy doesn t build trust because where it builds new connections it often replicates old patterns of privileged access for some and denial for others 106 William Alden wrote that The so called sharing economy is supposed to offer a new kind of capitalism one where regular folks enabled by efficient online platforms can turn their fallow assets into cash machines But the reality is that these markets also tend to attract a class of well heeled professional operators who outperform the amateurs just like the rest of the economy 107 The local economic benefit of the sharing economy is offset by its current form which is that huge tech companies reap a great deal of profit in many cases For example Uber which is estimated to be worth 50B as of mid 2015 108 takes up to 30 commission from the gross revenue of its drivers 109 leaving many drivers making less than minimum wage 110 This is reminiscent of a peak Rentier state which derives all or a substantial portion of its national revenues from the rent of indigenous resources to external clients Other issues edit Companies such as Airbnb and Uber do not share reputation data Individual behavior on any one platform doesn t transfer to other platforms This fragmentation has some negative consequences such as the Airbnb squatters who had previously deceived Kickstarter users to the tune of 40 000 111 Sharing data between these platforms could have prevented the repeat incident Business Insider s view is that since the sharing economy is in its infancy this has been accepted However as the industry matures this will need to change 112 Giana Eckhardt and Fleura Bardhi say that the access economy promotes and prioritizes cheap fares and low costs rather than personal relationships which is tied to similar issues in crowdsourcing For example consumers reap similar benefits from Zipcar as they would from a hotel In this example the primary concern is the low cost Because of this the sharing economy may not be about sharing but rather about access Giana Eckhardt and Fleura Bardhi say the sharing economy has taught people to prioritize cheap and easy access over interpersonal communication and the value of going the extra mile for those interactions has diminished 113 Concentration of power can lead to unethical business practices By using a software named Greyball Uber was able to make it difficult for regulatory officials to use the application 114 Another schemes allegedly implemented by Uber includes using its application to show phantom cars nearby to consumers on the app implying shorter pick up times than could actually be expected Uber denied the allegation 115 Regulations that cover traditional taxi companies but not ridesharing companies can put taxis at a competitive disadvantage 116 Uber has faced criticism from taxi drivers worldwide due to the increased competition Uber has also been banned from several jurisdictions due to failure to comply with licensing laws 117 An umbrella sharing service named Sharing E Umbrella was started in 11 cities across China in 2017 lost almost all of the 300 000 umbrellas placed out for sharing purposes during the first few weeks 118 Treatment of workers Lack of employee benefits Since access economy companies rely on independent contractors they are not offered the same protections as that of full time salary employees in terms of workers comp retirement plans sick leave and unemployment 119 116 This debate has caused Uber to have to remove their presence in several locations such as Alaska Uber stirred up a large controversy in Alaska because if Uber drivers were considered registered taxi drivers that would mean they would be entitled to receiving workers compensation insurance However if they were considered independent contractors they would not receive these same benefits Due to all of the disputes Uber pulled services from Alaska 117 In addition ride share drivers status continues to be ambiguous when it comes to legal matters On New Year s Eve in 2013 an off duty driver for Uber killed a pedestrian while looking for a rider Since the driver was considered a contractor Uber would not compensate for the victim s family The contract states that the service is a matching platform and the company does not provide transportation services and has no liability for services provided by third parties 116 Quality discrepancies Since access economy companies rely on independent workers the quality of service can differ between various individual providers on the same platform In 2015 Steven Hill from the New America Foundation cited his experience signing up to become a host on Airbnb as simple as uploading a few photos to the website and within 15 minutes my place was live like an Airbnb rental No background check no verifying my ID no confirming my personal details no questions asked Not even any contact with a real human from their trust and safety team Nothing 120 However due to the reputation model customers are provided with a peer reviewed rating of the provider and are given a choice of whether to proceed with the transaction Inadequate liability guarantees Though some companies offer liability guarantees such as Airbnb s Host Guarantee that promises to pay up to 1 million in damages it is extremely difficult to prove fault 121 Ownership and usage The access economy blurs the difference between ownership and usage which allows for the abuse or neglect of items absent policies Replacement of small local companies with large international tech companies For example taxi companies tend to be locally owned and operated while Uber is California based Therefore taxi company profits tend to stay local while some portion of access economy profits flows out of the local community Examples editAgriculture Garden sharing Heifer International Seed swapFinance Crowdfunding Peer to peer banking Peer to peer lending Virtual economyFood Cafeteria Food bank Social diningTravel ToursByLocals Click and Boat BoatsetterReal estate Airbnb Co housing Coliving Collaborative workspace CouchSurfing Emergencybnb Home exchange Renting HomeAway Vacasa Swimply Labor Expert network Open Innovation Open source product development Coworking Freelance marketplace LETS Time banks UpworkProperty Bartering Book swapping Borrowing center Clothes swapping Fractional ownership Give away shop Library of things Timeshare Toy libraryTransportation Bicycle sharing system Carpool Carsharing and peer to peer carsharing Flight sharing Lyft Mobike Share taxi Ridesharing company Uber Vanpool Zipcar Governance Government by algorithmBusiness Product service systemTechnology Cloud computing GNU Project Open source software Volunteer computing WiFi Master KeyDigital rights Copyleft Free art license Open contentOther Club theory GreenPal Wikimedia movement WikipediaPrinciples for regulation in the sharing economy editIn order to reap the real benefits of a sharing economy and somehow address some issues that revolve around it there is a great need for the government and policy makers to create the right enabling framework based on a set of guiding principles proposed by the World Economic Forum These principles are derived from the analysis of global policymaking and consultation with experts The following are the seven principles for regulation in the sharing economy 28 The first principle is creating space for innovation This entails that governments need to provide an initially encouraging environment while also building necessary infrastructure to allow for the development of innovation hubs 28 The second principle is that sharing economy should be people centered This means that policies should be focused on increasing the overall welfare of the population as well as improving the quality of life 28 The third principle is taking a proactive approach This means that new business models need to be brought into the mainstream and governments need to make clear frameworks that minimize uncertainty 28 The fourth principle is the assessment of the whole regulatory system which means administrative burdens on exiting systems should be lifted in order to give equal level of access to all actors in the network 28 The fifth principle is the data driven government Since most sharing economy relies on the use of digital platforms data can be easily collected analyzed and shared which can boost the urban environment through public private partnerships 28 The sixth principle talks about the flexible governance where actors should consider the nature of technology which is fast evolving This calls for a sustained dialogue with key stakeholders so all interests and rights are further protected and safeguarded 28 The last principle is a shared regulation where all the players should be involved in regulatory discussions as well as in the enforcement of policy 28 See also edit nbsp Wikiquote has quotations related to Sharing economy Collaborative consumption Gig worker Holiday cottage List of gig economy companies Platform economy Post capitalism Vacation rentalReferences edit What Is the Sharing Economy Dotdash Meredith November 10 2021 David Matthew 2017 Sharing post scarcity beyond capitalism Cambridge Journal of Regions Economy and Society 10 2 311 325 doi 10 1093 cjres rsx003 Daglis Theodoros 2022 Sharing Economy Encyclopedia 2 3 1322 1332 doi 10 3390 encyclopedia2030088 Bradley Karin Pargman Daniel 2017 The sharing economy as the commons of the 21st century Cambridge Journal of Regions Economy and Society 10 2 231 247 doi 10 1093 cjres rsx001 Hyun Hong Ji Cho Kim Byung Sam Park Kyung June 2019 Optimal risk management for the sharing economy with stranger danger and service quality European Journal of Operational Research 279 3 1024 1035 doi 10 1016 j ejor 2019 06 020 S2CID 197523623 Felson Marcus Spaeth Joe L 1978 Community Structure and Collaborative Consumption A Routine Activity Approach American Behavioral Scientist 21 4 614 624 doi 10 1177 000276427802100411 S2CID 147181824 a b c d e f g h i j k l m Jemielniak Dariusz Przegalinska Aleksandra 2020 Collaborative Society MIT Press ISBN 978 0 262 35645 9 Stephany Alex 2015 The Business of Sharing Making it in the New Sharing Economy Palgrave Macmillan ISBN 978 1137376176 Homestay is the origin of Sharing Economy Press release Homestayin com March 11 2014 via PR Newswire Trenz Manuel Frey Alexander Veit Daniel 2018 08 06 Disentangling the facets of sharing Internet Research 28 4 888 925 doi 10 1108 IntR 11 2017 0441 ISSN 1066 2243 Cheng Mingming 2016 Sharing economy A review and agenda for future research International Journal of Hospitality Management 57 60 70 doi 10 1016 j ijhm 2016 06 003 a b Sundararajan Arun 2016 The Sharing Economy The End of Employment and the Rise of Crowd Based Capitalism MIT Press a b Kenneth Olmstead and Aaron Smith 20 May 2016 How Americans define the sharing economy Pew Research Center a b Schlagwein Daniel Schoder Detlef Spindeldreher Kai 2019 Consolidated systemic conceptualization and definition of the sharing economy Journal of the Association for Information Science and Technology 71 7 817 838 doi 10 1002 asi 24300 Gobble MaryAnne M 2015 Regulating Innovation in the New Economy Research Technology Management 58 2 62 67 Heinrichs Harald 2013 Sharing economy A potential new pathway to sustainability Gaia 22 4 228 231 doi 10 14512 gaia 22 4 5 Botsman Rachel Rogers Roo 2010 What s mine is yours The rise of collaborative consumption New York Harper Business Gutt Dominik Hermann Philipp 2015 Sharing Means Caring Hosts Price Reaction to Rating Visibility European Conference on Information Systems Munster Germany a b Diaz Granados Juan Sheehy Benedict 2021 The Sharing Economy amp the Platform User Provider PUP Model Analytical Legal Frameworks Fordham Intellectual Property Media amp Entertainment Law Journal 31 4 Russell W Belk Giana M Eckhardt Fleura Bardhi Handbook of the Sharing Economy Edward Elgar Publishing pp 178 ISBN 978 1 78811 054 9 Geissinger Andrea Laurell Christofer Oberg Christina Sandstrom Christian Suseno Yuliani 2020 02 18 Assessing user perceptions of the interplay between the sharing access platform and community based economies Information Technology amp People 33 3 1037 1051 doi 10 1108 ITP 12 2019 0649 ISSN 0959 3845 S2CID 212846123 Slee Tom 2015 What s yours is mine OR Books p 216 ISBN 978 1 68219 022 7 Arnould Eric J Rose Alexander S 2016 Mutuality Critique and substitute for Belk s sharing Marketing Theory 16 1 75 doi 10 1177 1470593115572669 S2CID 220081479 a b c Eckhardt Giana M Bardhi Fleura January 28 2015 The Sharing Economy Isn t About Sharing at All Harvard Business Review Ritzer George 2014 Prosumption Evolution revolution or eternal return of the same Journal of Consumer Culture 14 1 3 24 doi 10 1177 1469540513509641 S2CID 147095174 Benkler Yochai 2002 Coase s Penguin or Linux and The Nature of the Firm The Yale Law Journal 112 3 369 446 arXiv cs 0109077 doi 10 2307 1562247 hdl 10535 2974 JSTOR 1562247 S2CID 16684329 Benkler Yochai 2004 Sharing Nicely On Shareable Goods and the emergence of sharing as a modality of economic production The Yale Law Journal 114 2 273 358 doi 10 2307 4135731 JSTOR 4135731 a b c d e f g h i j k World Economic Forum 2017 Collaboration in Cities From Sharing to Sharing Economy PDF World Economic Forum Retrieved December 26 2020 Sutherland W Jarrahi M H 2018 The sharing economy and digital platforms A review and research agenda International Journal of Information Management 43 328 341 doi 10 1016 j ijinfomgt 2018 07 004 S2CID 52821010 Richardson Lizzie 2015 12 01 Performing the sharing economy Geoforum 67 121 129 doi 10 1016 j geoforum 2015 11 004 ISSN 0016 7185 Laurell Christofer Sandstrom Christian June 2016 Analysing Uber in social media disruptive technology or institutional disruption International Journal of Innovation Management 20 5 1640013 doi 10 1142 S1363919616400132 a b Tuttle Brad June 30 2014 Can We Stop Pretending the Sharing Economy Is All About Sharing MONEY com Rosenberg Tina June 5 2013 It s Not Just Nice to Share It s the Future The New York Times Grant Rebecca April 3 2013 Disownership is the new normal the rise of the shared economy infographic VentureBeat The Collaborative Economy Altimeter Group June 4 2013 Mead Rebecca April 22 2019 The Airbnb invasion of Barcelona The PerfectKLIK Way PerfectKLIK 2017 07 21 Cusumano Michael A January 2018 The Sharing Economy Meets Reality Communications of the ACM Juliet Schor 17 May 2018 The platform economy University of California Berkeley European Commission Directorate General for Internal Market Industry Entrepreneurship and SMEs Technopolis VVA Consulting Trinomics 2018 Study to monitor the economic development of the collaborative economy at sector level in the 28 EU Member States final report LU Publications Office doi 10 2873 83555 ISBN 9789279817281 a href Template Cite book html title Template Cite book cite book a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link European Commission 2 Jun 2016 A European agenda for the collaborative economy European Commission Publications 1 16 China s sharing economy up 103 pct in 2016 report Xinhua News Agency May 3 2017 Wang Iris November 7 2018 A glimpse at China s burgeoning sharing economy Shareable Sharing economy in Russia 2018 PDF TIARCENTER November 22 2018 Press release 2021年 日本のシェアリングエコノミー市場規模が 過去最高の2兆4 198億円を記録 2030年度には 14兆2 799億円 に拡大予測 Sharing Economy Association Japan June 10 2022 The Gig Economy Implications of the Growth of Contingent Work Federal Reserve a b c Gig Economy Hasn t Taken Over Bloomberg News August 28 2015 Gig Economy Is Growing But Not Growing Up Bloomberg com October 1 2015 via www bloomberg com The Gig Economy Is Just Part of the Unsettling New World of Work Bloomberg com June 2 2016 via www bloomberg com a b Katz amp Kruger Princeton The Rise and Nature of Alternative Work Arrangements in the United States 1995 2015 Retrieved June 2 2016 PDF Archived from the original PDF on February 18 2019 Retrieved March 23 2019 Hazlitt Henry 1979 Economics in One Lesson Three Rivers Press ISBN 0 517 54823 2 GAO Contingent Workforce Size Characteristics Earnings Benefits April 2015 PDF Guendelsberger Emily May 7 2015 I was an undercover Uber driver Philadelphia City Paper Natasha Singer and Mike Isaac May 9 2015 An App That Helps Drivers Earn the Most From Their Trips The New York Times a b How the Sharing Economy Screws American Workers The Huffington Post January 20 2016 Wiener Martin Cram W Benlian Alexander 2021 09 22 Algorithmic control and gig workers a legitimacy perspective of Uber drivers European Journal of Information Systems 32 3 485 507 doi 10 1080 0960085X 2021 1977729 ISSN 0960 085X S2CID 239262702 Stickle Ben 2023 01 04 Crime Sharing How the Sharing Economy may Impact Crime Victims Victims amp Offenders 1 20 doi 10 1080 15564886 2022 2159905 ISSN 1556 4886 S2CID 255704014 Wiener Martin Cram W Benlian Alexander 2021 09 22 Algorithmic control and gig workers a legitimacy perspective of Uber drivers European Journal of Information Systems 32 3 485 507 doi 10 1080 0960085X 2021 1977729 ISSN 0960 085X S2CID 239262702 Kumar S July 20 2015 3 reasons to cheer Uber and the sharing economy Fortune Hakobyan Margarita February 22 2017 The Sharing Economy Benefits Business Business com Johnson Holly How to Make Money Driving for Uber The Simple Dollar Geron Tomio January 23 2013 Airbnb And The Unstoppable Rise Of The Share Economy Forbes How to become a New York Taxi Driver Given Casey January 11 2015 Uber Economics How Markets are Changing in the Sharing Economy Atlas Network VERNON STEVE August 26 2016 How seniors are tapping the gig economy CBS News Geron Tomio November 9 2012 Airbnb Had 56 Million Impact On San Francisco Study Forbes Mazmanian Adam May 22 2013 Can open data change the culture of government Federal Computer Week Ross Eleanor August 18 2015 How open data can help save lives The Guardian Morris David Z March 13 2016 Today s Cars Are Parked 95 of the Time Fortune Boudreau Kevin Lakhani Karim R April 2013 Using the Crowd as an Innovation Partner Harvard Business Review 91 4 60 9 140 PMID 23593768 a b Sharing economy reshapes markets as complaints rise The Star AFP February 9 2015 a b Comparing Airbnb and Hotel Rates Around the Globe Busbud February 18 2016 Zervas G Proserpio D Byers J W 2017 The Rise of the Sharing Economy Estimating the Impact of Airbnb on the Hotel Industry Journal of Marketing Research 54 5 687 705 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 645 4284 doi 10 1509 jmr 15 0204 S2CID 4837143 a b c Rudenko Anna 16 August 2013 The collaborative consumption on the rise why shared economy is winning over the capitalism of me Brady Diane 24 September 2014 The Environmental Case for the Sharing Economy Bloomberg News a b Parsons Adam 5 March 2014 The sharing economy a short introduction to its political evolution openDemocracy Lombardo Crystal October 29 2015 Pros and Cons of Sharing Economy Vision Launch Cohen Boyd Munoz Pablo 2015 Sharing cities and sustainable consumption and production towards an integrated framework PDF Journal of Cleaner Production 134 87 97 doi 10 1016 j jclepro 2015 07 133 nbsp Post print version nbsp Bradshaw Della 22 April 2015 Sharing economy benefits lower income groups Financial Times Jerome Joseph June 8 2015 User Reputation Building Trust and Addressing Privacy Issues in the Sharing Economy Future of Privacy Forum Wallsten Scott June 1 2017 The Competitive Effects of the Sharing Economy How is Uber Changing Taxis Technology Policy Institute Munkoe M 2017 Regulating the European Sharing Economy State of Play and Challenges Intereconomics The Review of European Economic Policy Volume 52 January February 2017 Number 1 pp 38 44 Williams Grut Oscar 20 March 2015 Silicon Round up Blockchain banking to be on the slate for new regulator Evening Standard Graham Mark May 25 2016 Digital work marketplaces impose a new balance of power New Internationalist Roose Kevin April 24 2014 The Sharing Economy Isn t About Trust It s About Desperation New York Magazine Roose Kevin September 18 2014 Does Silicon Valley Have a Contract Worker Problem New York Magazine Benner Katie October 2 2014 A Secret of Uber s Success Struggling Workers Bloomberg News Uber s audacious plan to replace human drivers CBS News Frey Carl Benedikt January 2017 Drivers of Disruption Estimating the Uber Effect Rosenblat Alex 2019 UBERLAND how algorithms are rewriting the rules of work University of California Press pp 138 147 ISBN 978 0 520 32480 0 OCLC 1088531727 Rosenblat Alex 2019 UBERLAND how algorithms are rewriting the rules of work UNIV OF CALIFORNIA PRESS p 149 ISBN 978 0 520 32480 0 OCLC 1088531727 Rosenblat Alex 2019 UBERLAND how algorithms are rewriting the rules of work UNIV OF CALIFORNIA PRESS p 152 ISBN 978 0 520 32480 0 OCLC 1088531727 Huet Ellen How Uber s Shady Firing Policy Could Backfire On The Company Forbes Retrieved 2019 11 25 Sharing Economy Companies Sharing the Heat In Contractor Controversy Xconomy July 17 2015 a b Apoorva Mehta had 20 failed start ups before Instacart Los Angeles Times January 27 2017 ISSN 0458 3035 a b Koopman Christopher Mitchell Matthew D Thierer Adam D May 15 2015 The Sharing Economy and Consumer Protection Regulation The Case for Policy Change The Journal of Business Entrepreneurship amp the Law 8 530 545 SSRN 2535345 Taeihagh Araz 19 June 2017 Crowdsourcing Sharing Economies and Development Journal of Developing Societies 33 2 191 222 arXiv 1707 06603 doi 10 1177 0169796X17710072 S2CID 32008949 Cakar Kadir 11 January 2021 The downfall of Uber in Turkey a case study on tourism in Istanbul Turkey Anatolia 32 3 521 524 doi 10 1080 13032917 2021 1874447 S2CID 234312568 Ride share application Uber becomes available again in Turkey duvaR English 13 January 2021 Retrieved 12 December 2022 Millennials will not be regulated Andrew Leonard Salon com 2013 09 20 Leonard Andrew September 17 2013 The sharing economy muscles up Salon com Leonard Andrew 2014 06 27 Libertarians anti government crusade Now there s an app for that Salon com Morozov Evgeny September 2014 Don t believe the hype the sharing economy masks a failing economy The Guardian Graham Mark 2016 Digital work marketplaces impose a new balance of power New Internationalist Graham Mark 2016 Organising in the digital wild west can strategic bottlenecks help prevent a race to the bottom for online workers Union Solidarity International The Case Against Sharing On access scarcity and trust 2014 05 28 Susie Cagle Medium com The Business Tycoons of Airbnb The New York Times Sharing economy reshapes markets as complaints rise Bloomberg News 2015 02 03 Huet Ellen 2015 05 18 Uber Tests Taking Even More From Its Drivers With 30 Commission Forbes A Philadelphia journalist went undercover as an Uber driver here s how much she made MSN 2015 05 09 Kevin Montgomery Airbnb Squatters Also Swindled 40 000 From Kickstarter 2014 07 28 Patrick J Stewart Reputation And The Sharing Economy 2014 10 23 Business Insider Giana Eckhardt and Fleura Bardhi The Sharing Economy isn t About Sharing at All 2015 02 09 Harvard Business Review Isaac Mike March 3 2017 How Uber Deceives the Authorities Worldwide The New York Times Hern Alex July 30 2015 Uber denies misleading passengers with phantom cars on app The Guardian a b c Malhotra Arvind November 2014 The Dark Side of the Sharing Economy and How to Lighten It Communications of the ACM 57 11 24 27 doi 10 1145 2668893 S2CID 207219285 a b Rhodes Anna 2017 04 28 These are all the places in the world that have banned Uber The Independent He Huifeng 2017 07 07 Chinese umbrella sharing firm remains upbeat despite losing most of its 300 000 brollies South China Morning Post Huet Ellen 6 January 2015 What Happens to Uber Drivers And Other Sharing Economy Workers Injured On The Job Forbes Hill Steven 30 October 2015 The two faces of Airbnb Business Insider Bort Julie 9 October 2014 Airbnb Banned From Condo Complex After Guest Caused 10 000 Of Damage Business Insider Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Sharing economy amp oldid 1189117467, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.