fbpx
Wikipedia

Ricardian equivalence

The Ricardian equivalence proposition (also known as the Ricardo–de Viti–Barro equivalence theorem[1]) is an economic hypothesis holding that consumers are forward-looking and so internalize the government's budget constraint when making their consumption decisions. This leads to the result that, for a given pattern of government spending, the method of financing such spending does not affect agents' consumption decisions, and thus, it does not change aggregate demand.

Introduction edit

Governments can finance their expenditures by creating new money, by levying taxes, or by issuing bonds. Since bonds are loans, they must eventually be repaid—presumably by raising taxes in the future. The choice is therefore "tax now or tax later."[citation needed]

Suppose that the government finances some extra spending through deficits; i.e. it chooses to tax later. According to the hypothesis, taxpayers will anticipate that they will have to pay higher taxes in future. As a result, they will save, rather than spend, the extra disposable income from the initial tax cut, leaving demand and output unchanged.[citation needed]

David Ricardo was the first to propose this possibility in the early nineteenth century; however, he was unconvinced of its empirical relevance.[2] Antonio de Viti de Marco elaborated on Ricardian equivalence in the 1890s.[3] Robert J. Barro took the question up independently in the 1970s, in an attempt to give the proposition a firm theoretical foundation.[4][5]

Ricardo and war bonds edit

In "Essay on the Funding System" (1820), Ricardo studied whether it makes a difference to finance a war with £20 million in current taxes or to issue government bonds with infinite maturity and annual interest payment of £1 million in all following years financed by future taxes. At the assumed interest rate of 5%, Ricardo concluded that in terms of spending the two alternatives amounted to the same value. However, Ricardo himself doubted that this proposition had practical consequences. He followed up the initial exposition with a claim that individuals do not actually evaluate taxes in such a manner and, in particular, take myopic view of the tax path.[2]

Ricardo–de Viti–Barro equivalence edit

In 1974, Robert J. Barro provided some theoretical foundation for Ricardo's hesitant speculation[4] (apparently in ignorance of Ricardo's earlier notion and de Viti's subsequent extensions).[1][5][6] Barro's model assumed the following:

  • families act as infinitely lived dynasties because of intergenerational altruism[7]
  • capital markets are perfect (i.e., all can borrow and lend at a single rate)
  • the path of government expenditures is fixed

Under these conditions, if governments finance deficits by issuing bonds, the bequests that families grant to their children will be just large enough to offset the higher taxes that will be needed to pay off those bonds. Among his conclusions, Barro wrote:

... in the case where the marginal net-wealth effect of government bonds is close to zero ... fiscal effects involving changes in the relative amounts of tax and debt finance for a given amount of public expenditure would have no effect on aggregate demand, interest rates, and capital formation.

The model was an important contribution to the theory of new classical macroeconomics, built around the assumption of rational expectations.[6]

In 1979, Barro defined the Ricardian equivalence theorem as follows: "... shifts between debt and tax finance for a given amount of public expenditure would have no first-order effect on the real interest rate, volume of private investment, etc."[5] Barro noted that "the Ricardian equivalence proposition is presented in Ricardo". However, Ricardo himself was skeptical of this equivalence.[2]

Criticisms edit

Ricardian equivalence requires assumptions that have been seriously challenged.[1][8] The perfect capital market hypothesis is often held up for particular criticism because liquidity constraints invalidate the assumed lifetime income hypothesis.[citation needed] International capital markets also complicate the picture.[citation needed] However, even in a laboratory setting where all assumptions required are ensured to hold, behaviour of individuals is inconsistent with Ricardian equivalence.[9]

Martin Feldstein argued in 1976 that Barro ignored economic and population growth. He demonstrated that the creation of public debt depresses savings in a growing economy.[8] In the same issue James M. Buchanan also criticized Barro's model, noting that "[t]his is an age-old question in public finance theory", one already mooted by Ricardo and elaborated upon by de Viti.[1]

In a response to the comments of Feldstein and Buchanan, Barro recognized that uncertainty may play a role in affecting individual behaviour with respect to government finance. Nevertheless, he argued that "it is much less clear that this complication would imply systematic errors in a direction such that public debt issue raises aggregate demand."[10]

In 1977, Gerald P. O'Driscoll commented that Ricardo, in expanding his treatment of this subject for an Encyclopædia Britannica article, changed so many features of it as to result in a Ricardian Nonequivalence Theorem; he elaborated all the reasons why the proposition would not hold.[6][11]

In 1989, Barro offered a number of defenses against various other critiques.[12]

Empirical results edit

Ricardian equivalence has been the subject of extensive empirical inquiry.[13] Barro himself found some confirmation in post WW I years.[5]

However, research by Chris Carroll, James Poterba[14] and Lawrence Summers[15] shows that the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis is refuted by their results. In the Ronald Reagan era, the US government had a historically large budget deficit due to the Reagan administration tax cuts and increases in military spending. During 1976–80, government revenue was 10.01 percent of potential GNP, and it declined to 8.86 percent during 1981–1985. The ratio of the US government's budget deficit to its potential GNP did not exceed 4 percent from World War II until 1981, and exceeded 4 percent after 1981. The ratio of an inflation- and cycle-adjusted deficit to the potential GNP was 2.56 percent during 1981–1986, and this ratio was the largest between 1958 and 1986. If the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis is true, the rational consumers of the economy, who expect the government to raise taxes, try to reduce their consumption and increase their saving. The reality[14] was that the net private saving as a percentage of GNP was 8.55 in the 1976–1980 period, and it decreased to 7.47 percent in the 1981–1986 period. The ratio of consumption to GNP was 62.96 percent in the 1976–1980 period, and slightly increased to 64.72 percent in the 1981–1986 period.

Table 1
Saving and Consumption Measures 1961–86[14][15]
Year government saving
(% of potential
GNP)
inflation-adjusted
government saving
(% of potential
GNP)
consumption
(% of GNP)
private saving
(% of potential
GNP)
inflation-adjusted
private saving
(% of potential
GNP)
net private saving
(% of GNP)
1961–65 -0.3 0.4 63.05 8.2 7.5 8.25
1966–70 -0.5 0.9 62.09 8.5 6.9 8.23
1971–75 -1.1 1.0 62.47 8.4 6.4 9.10
1976–80 -0.8 1.5 62.96 7.3 5.1 8.55
1981–86 -2.8 -1.4 64.72 5.6 4.5 7.47

The facts about private saving, government saving and consumption in the US are shown in Table 1. Their finding[15] is that increases in government deficits are followed by decreases in private saving. They see the increase in the consumption-to-GNP ratio during 1981–86, when the governmental dissaving is accelerated by Reaganomics. Their results refute the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis.

An argument for countercyclical fiscal policies edit

Ricardian equivalence has crucial importance in the fiscal policy considerations of new classical macroeconomics. When assessing Ricardian equivalence or any of the new classical doctrines, one should bear in mind the conditional character of these theses. Thus the equivalence theorem should not be separated from the assumptions on which it is based. In other words, Ricardian equivalence does not mean that any countercyclical efforts will fail, but outlines the necessary conditions for that failure and, naturally, for success at the same time. Governments do not have any potential to exert countercyclical efforts if the path of government expenditures is fixed and if agents form rational expectations. If these conditions hold, cuts in taxes imply a later pressure to raise taxes, since government has to fill the resource gap in the budget which is the result of the initial tax cut. So, rational agents will put the additional income from the tax cut into saving, and consumption does not rise. In this story, if these processes can be changed by the government, or, in any way, the additional income can be believed not to be withdrawn later, the initial tax cut will induce a rise in public consumption expenditures.

So countercyclical fiscal policy can be effective if any one of the conditions necessary for the equivalence does not hold. Controlling the real economy is possible perhaps even in a Keynesian style if government regains its potential to exert this control. Therefore, actually, new classical macroeconomics highlights the conditions under which fiscal policy can be effective and not the inefficiency of fiscal policy. Countercyclical aspirations need not to be abandoned, only the playing-field of economic policy got narrowed by new classical macroeconomics. Keynes urged active countercyclical efforts of fiscal policy and these efforts are not predestined to fail not even in the new classical theory, only the conditions necessary for the efficiency of countercyclical efforts were specified by new classical macroeconomics. Ricardian equivalence underlines the importance of fiscal reforms, since such reforms are needed in order to change the path of government expenditures. When implementing comprehensive fiscal reforms which make public sector more efficient governments do not exert countercyclical efforts of course, but form the necessary conditions for regaining countercyclical potential. In this respect, Ricardian equivalence clarifies the exact conditions necessary for countercyclical fiscal policies.[16]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ a b c d Buchanan, James M. (1976). "Barro on the Ricardian Equivalence Theorem". Journal of Political Economy. 84 (2): 337–342. doi:10.1086/260436. S2CID 153956574.
  2. ^ a b c David Ricardo, "Essay on the Funding System" in The Works of David Ricardo. With a Notice of the Life and Writings of the Author, by J.R. McCulloch, London: John Murray, 1888
  3. ^ Handbook of public economics, Martin Feldstein, Alan J. Aurbach, eds., North Holland (August 1, 1985) ISBN 978-0-444-87612-6
  4. ^ a b Barro, Robert J. (1974). "Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?" (PDF). Journal of Political Economy. 82 (6): 1095–1117. doi:10.1086/260266. S2CID 154705295.
  5. ^ a b c d Barro, Robert J. (1979). "On the Determination of the Public Debt". Journal of Political Economy. 87 (5): 940–971. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.455.8274. doi:10.1086/260807. S2CID 165841. Retrieved 25 May 2010.
  6. ^ a b c Hsieh, Ching-Yao; Mangum, Stephen L. (1985). A Search for Synthesis in Economic Theory. p. 58. ISBN 978-0-87332-328-4.
  7. ^ Barro phrased this as "any operative intergenerational transfer", however imperfect
  8. ^ a b Feldstein, Martin (1976). "Perceived Wealth in Bonds and Social Security: A Comment". Journal of Political Economy. 84 (2): 331–336. doi:10.1086/260435. S2CID 153920120.
  9. ^ Meissner, Thomas & Rostam-Afschar, Davud (2014) "Do tax cuts increase consumption? An experimental test of Ricardian Equivalence" (PDF; 767 kB)
  10. ^ Barro, R (April 1976). "Perceived Wealth in Bonds and Social Security and the Ricardian Equivalence Theorem: Reply to Feldstein and Buchanan" (PDF). The Journal of Political Economy. 84 (2): 343–350. doi:10.1086/260437. JSTOR 1831906. S2CID 157099094.
  11. ^ O'Driscoll, G (February 1977). "The Ricardian Nonequivalence theorem". Journal of Political Economy. 85 (2): 207–210. doi:10.1086/260552. S2CID 154482674.
  12. ^ Barro, R (Spring 1989). "The Ricardian approach to budget deficits". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 3 (2): 37–54. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.321.4201. doi:10.1257/jep.3.2.37.
  13. ^ Briotti, M. Gabriella (October 2005). "Economic Reactions to Public Finance Consolidation: a Survey of the Literature". European Central Bank Occasional Paper (38). hdl:10419/154491.
  14. ^ a b c Poterba, J. M.; Summers, L. H. (1987). "Finite lifetimes and the effects of budget deficits on national saving". Journal of Monetary Economics. 20 (2): 369–391. doi:10.1016/0304-3932(87)90021-3.
  15. ^ a b c Summers, L.; Carroll, Chris (1987). "Why is U.S. National Saving so Low?" (PDF). Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1987 (2): 607–642. doi:10.2307/2534491. JSTOR 2534491.
  16. ^ Galbács, Peter (2015). "Fiscal Policy and New Classical Macroeconomics". The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics. A Positive Critique. Contributions to Economics. Heidelberg/New York/Dordrecht/London: Springer. pp. 221–281. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-17578-2. ISBN 978-3-319-17578-2.

Further reading edit

  • Blanchard, Olivier Jean; Fischer, Stanley (1989). "Fiscal Policy: Debt and Deficit Finance". Lectures on Macroeconomics. Cambridge: MIT Press. pp. 126–135. ISBN 978-0-262-02283-5.
  • Galbács, Peter (2015). The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics. A Positive Critique. Heidelberg/New York/Dordrecht/London: Springer. ISBN 978-3-319-17578-2.
  • Hoover, Kevin D. (1988). "Ricardian Equivalence". The New Classical Macroeconomics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. pp. 139–149. ISBN 978-0-631-14605-6.
  • Seater, John J. (1993). "Ricardian Equivalence". Journal of Economic Literature. 31 (1): 142–190. JSTOR 2728152.

ricardian, equivalence, proposition, also, known, ricardo, viti, barro, equivalence, theorem, economic, hypothesis, holding, that, consumers, forward, looking, internalize, government, budget, constraint, when, making, their, consumption, decisions, this, lead. The Ricardian equivalence proposition also known as the Ricardo de Viti Barro equivalence theorem 1 is an economic hypothesis holding that consumers are forward looking and so internalize the government s budget constraint when making their consumption decisions This leads to the result that for a given pattern of government spending the method of financing such spending does not affect agents consumption decisions and thus it does not change aggregate demand Contents 1 Introduction 2 Ricardo and war bonds 3 Ricardo de Viti Barro equivalence 4 Criticisms 5 Empirical results 6 An argument for countercyclical fiscal policies 7 See also 8 References 9 Further readingIntroduction editGovernments can finance their expenditures by creating new money by levying taxes or by issuing bonds Since bonds are loans they must eventually be repaid presumably by raising taxes in the future The choice is therefore tax now or tax later citation needed Suppose that the government finances some extra spending through deficits i e it chooses to tax later According to the hypothesis taxpayers will anticipate that they will have to pay higher taxes in future As a result they will save rather than spend the extra disposable income from the initial tax cut leaving demand and output unchanged citation needed David Ricardo was the first to propose this possibility in the early nineteenth century however he was unconvinced of its empirical relevance 2 Antonio de Viti de Marco elaborated on Ricardian equivalence in the 1890s 3 Robert J Barro took the question up independently in the 1970s in an attempt to give the proposition a firm theoretical foundation 4 5 Ricardo and war bonds editIn Essay on the Funding System 1820 Ricardo studied whether it makes a difference to finance a war with 20 million in current taxes or to issue government bonds with infinite maturity and annual interest payment of 1 million in all following years financed by future taxes At the assumed interest rate of 5 Ricardo concluded that in terms of spending the two alternatives amounted to the same value However Ricardo himself doubted that this proposition had practical consequences He followed up the initial exposition with a claim that individuals do not actually evaluate taxes in such a manner and in particular take myopic view of the tax path 2 Ricardo de Viti Barro equivalence editIn 1974 Robert J Barro provided some theoretical foundation for Ricardo s hesitant speculation 4 apparently in ignorance of Ricardo s earlier notion and de Viti s subsequent extensions 1 5 6 Barro s model assumed the following families act as infinitely lived dynasties because of intergenerational altruism 7 capital markets are perfect i e all can borrow and lend at a single rate the path of government expenditures is fixedUnder these conditions if governments finance deficits by issuing bonds the bequests that families grant to their children will be just large enough to offset the higher taxes that will be needed to pay off those bonds Among his conclusions Barro wrote in the case where the marginal net wealth effect of government bonds is close to zero fiscal effects involving changes in the relative amounts of tax and debt finance for a given amount of public expenditure would have no effect on aggregate demand interest rates and capital formation The model was an important contribution to the theory of new classical macroeconomics built around the assumption of rational expectations 6 In 1979 Barro defined the Ricardian equivalence theorem as follows shifts between debt and tax finance for a given amount of public expenditure would have no first order effect on the real interest rate volume of private investment etc 5 Barro noted that the Ricardian equivalence proposition is presented in Ricardo However Ricardo himself was skeptical of this equivalence 2 Criticisms editRicardian equivalence requires assumptions that have been seriously challenged 1 8 The perfect capital market hypothesis is often held up for particular criticism because liquidity constraints invalidate the assumed lifetime income hypothesis citation needed International capital markets also complicate the picture citation needed However even in a laboratory setting where all assumptions required are ensured to hold behaviour of individuals is inconsistent with Ricardian equivalence 9 Martin Feldstein argued in 1976 that Barro ignored economic and population growth He demonstrated that the creation of public debt depresses savings in a growing economy 8 In the same issue James M Buchanan also criticized Barro s model noting that t his is an age old question in public finance theory one already mooted by Ricardo and elaborated upon by de Viti 1 In a response to the comments of Feldstein and Buchanan Barro recognized that uncertainty may play a role in affecting individual behaviour with respect to government finance Nevertheless he argued that it is much less clear that this complication would imply systematic errors in a direction such that public debt issue raises aggregate demand 10 In 1977 Gerald P O Driscoll commented that Ricardo in expanding his treatment of this subject for an Encyclopaedia Britannica article changed so many features of it as to result in a Ricardian Nonequivalence Theorem he elaborated all the reasons why the proposition would not hold 6 11 In 1989 Barro offered a number of defenses against various other critiques 12 Empirical results editThis section needs expansion You can help by adding to it February 2016 Ricardian equivalence has been the subject of extensive empirical inquiry 13 Barro himself found some confirmation in post WW I years 5 However research by Chris Carroll James Poterba 14 and Lawrence Summers 15 shows that the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis is refuted by their results In the Ronald Reagan era the US government had a historically large budget deficit due to the Reagan administration tax cuts and increases in military spending During 1976 80 government revenue was 10 01 percent of potential GNP and it declined to 8 86 percent during 1981 1985 The ratio of the US government s budget deficit to its potential GNP did not exceed 4 percent from World War II until 1981 and exceeded 4 percent after 1981 The ratio of an inflation and cycle adjusted deficit to the potential GNP was 2 56 percent during 1981 1986 and this ratio was the largest between 1958 and 1986 If the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis is true the rational consumers of the economy who expect the government to raise taxes try to reduce their consumption and increase their saving The reality 14 was that the net private saving as a percentage of GNP was 8 55 in the 1976 1980 period and it decreased to 7 47 percent in the 1981 1986 period The ratio of consumption to GNP was 62 96 percent in the 1976 1980 period and slightly increased to 64 72 percent in the 1981 1986 period Table 1 Saving and Consumption Measures 1961 86 14 15 Year government saving of potential GNP inflation adjusted government saving of potential GNP consumption of GNP private saving of potential GNP inflation adjusted private saving of potential GNP net private saving of GNP 1961 65 0 3 0 4 63 05 8 2 7 5 8 251966 70 0 5 0 9 62 09 8 5 6 9 8 231971 75 1 1 1 0 62 47 8 4 6 4 9 101976 80 0 8 1 5 62 96 7 3 5 1 8 551981 86 2 8 1 4 64 72 5 6 4 5 7 47The facts about private saving government saving and consumption in the US are shown in Table 1 Their finding 15 is that increases in government deficits are followed by decreases in private saving They see the increase in the consumption to GNP ratio during 1981 86 when the governmental dissaving is accelerated by Reaganomics Their results refute the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis An argument for countercyclical fiscal policies editRicardian equivalence has crucial importance in the fiscal policy considerations of new classical macroeconomics When assessing Ricardian equivalence or any of the new classical doctrines one should bear in mind the conditional character of these theses Thus the equivalence theorem should not be separated from the assumptions on which it is based In other words Ricardian equivalence does not mean that any countercyclical efforts will fail but outlines the necessary conditions for that failure and naturally for success at the same time Governments do not have any potential to exert countercyclical efforts if the path of government expenditures is fixed and if agents form rational expectations If these conditions hold cuts in taxes imply a later pressure to raise taxes since government has to fill the resource gap in the budget which is the result of the initial tax cut So rational agents will put the additional income from the tax cut into saving and consumption does not rise In this story if these processes can be changed by the government or in any way the additional income can be believed not to be withdrawn later the initial tax cut will induce a rise in public consumption expenditures So countercyclical fiscal policy can be effective if any one of the conditions necessary for the equivalence does not hold Controlling the real economy is possible perhaps even in a Keynesian style if government regains its potential to exert this control Therefore actually new classical macroeconomics highlights the conditions under which fiscal policy can be effective and not the inefficiency of fiscal policy Countercyclical aspirations need not to be abandoned only the playing field of economic policy got narrowed by new classical macroeconomics Keynes urged active countercyclical efforts of fiscal policy and these efforts are not predestined to fail not even in the new classical theory only the conditions necessary for the efficiency of countercyclical efforts were specified by new classical macroeconomics Ricardian equivalence underlines the importance of fiscal reforms since such reforms are needed in order to change the path of government expenditures When implementing comprehensive fiscal reforms which make public sector more efficient governments do not exert countercyclical efforts of course but form the necessary conditions for regaining countercyclical potential In this respect Ricardian equivalence clarifies the exact conditions necessary for countercyclical fiscal policies 16 See also editPublic finance Government debt Policy ineffectiveness proposition Say s law Fiscal policyReferences edit a b c d Buchanan James M 1976 Barro on the Ricardian Equivalence Theorem Journal of Political Economy 84 2 337 342 doi 10 1086 260436 S2CID 153956574 a b c David Ricardo Essay on the Funding System in The Works of David Ricardo With a Notice of the Life and Writings of the Author by J R McCulloch London John Murray 1888 Handbook of public economics Martin Feldstein Alan J Aurbach eds North Holland August 1 1985 ISBN 978 0 444 87612 6 a b Barro Robert J 1974 Are Government Bonds Net Wealth PDF Journal of Political Economy 82 6 1095 1117 doi 10 1086 260266 S2CID 154705295 a b c d Barro Robert J 1979 On the Determination of the Public Debt Journal of Political Economy 87 5 940 971 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 455 8274 doi 10 1086 260807 S2CID 165841 Retrieved 25 May 2010 a b c Hsieh Ching Yao Mangum Stephen L 1985 A Search for Synthesis in Economic Theory p 58 ISBN 978 0 87332 328 4 Barro phrased this as any operative intergenerational transfer however imperfect a b Feldstein Martin 1976 Perceived Wealth in Bonds and Social Security A Comment Journal of Political Economy 84 2 331 336 doi 10 1086 260435 S2CID 153920120 Meissner Thomas amp Rostam Afschar Davud 2014 Do tax cuts increase consumption An experimental test of Ricardian Equivalence PDF 767 kB Barro R April 1976 Perceived Wealth in Bonds and Social Security and the Ricardian Equivalence Theorem Reply to Feldstein and Buchanan PDF The Journal of Political Economy 84 2 343 350 doi 10 1086 260437 JSTOR 1831906 S2CID 157099094 O Driscoll G February 1977 The Ricardian Nonequivalence theorem Journal of Political Economy 85 2 207 210 doi 10 1086 260552 S2CID 154482674 Barro R Spring 1989 The Ricardian approach to budget deficits The Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 2 37 54 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 321 4201 doi 10 1257 jep 3 2 37 Briotti M Gabriella October 2005 Economic Reactions to Public Finance Consolidation a Survey of the Literature European Central Bank Occasional Paper 38 hdl 10419 154491 a b c Poterba J M Summers L H 1987 Finite lifetimes and the effects of budget deficits on national saving Journal of Monetary Economics 20 2 369 391 doi 10 1016 0304 3932 87 90021 3 a b c Summers L Carroll Chris 1987 Why is U S National Saving so Low PDF Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1987 2 607 642 doi 10 2307 2534491 JSTOR 2534491 Galbacs Peter 2015 Fiscal Policy and New Classical Macroeconomics The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics A Positive Critique Contributions to Economics Heidelberg New York Dordrecht London Springer pp 221 281 doi 10 1007 978 3 319 17578 2 ISBN 978 3 319 17578 2 Further reading editBlanchard Olivier Jean Fischer Stanley 1989 Fiscal Policy Debt and Deficit Finance Lectures on Macroeconomics Cambridge MIT Press pp 126 135 ISBN 978 0 262 02283 5 Galbacs Peter 2015 The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics A Positive Critique Heidelberg New York Dordrecht London Springer ISBN 978 3 319 17578 2 Hoover Kevin D 1988 Ricardian Equivalence The New Classical Macroeconomics Oxford Basil Blackwell pp 139 149 ISBN 978 0 631 14605 6 Seater John J 1993 Ricardian Equivalence Journal of Economic Literature 31 1 142 190 JSTOR 2728152 Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Ricardian equivalence amp oldid 1215274910, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.