fbpx
Wikipedia

Emissions trading

Emissions trading is a market-based approach to controlling pollution by providing economic incentives for reducing the emissions of pollutants.[1] The concept is also known as cap and trade (CAT) or emissions trading scheme (ETS). Carbon emission trading for CO2 and other greenhouse gases has been introduced in China, the European Union and other countries as a key tool for climate change mitigation. Other schemes include sulfur dioxide and other pollutants.

In an emissions trading scheme, a central authority or governmental body allocates or sells a limited number (a "cap") of permits that allow a discharge of a specific quantity of a specific pollutant over a set time period.[2] Polluters are required to hold permits in amount equal to their emissions. Polluters that want to increase their emissions must buy permits from others willing to sell them.[1][3][4][5][6]

Emissions trading is a type of flexible environmental regulation[7] that allows organizations and markets to decide how best to meet policy targets. This is in contrast to command-and-control environmental regulations such as best available technology (BAT) standards and government subsidies.

Introduction

 
A coal power plant in Germany. Due to emissions trading, coal may become a less competitive fuel than other options.

Pollution is a prime example of a market externality. An externality is an effect of some activity on an entity (such as a person) that is not party to a market transaction related to that activity. Emissions trading is a market-based approach to address pollution. The overall goal of an emissions trading plan is to minimize the cost of meeting a set emissions target.[8] In an emissions trading system, the government sets an overall limit on emissions, and defines permits (also called allowances), or limited authorizations to emit, up to the level of the overall limit. The government may sell the permits, but in many existing schemes, it gives permits to participants (regulated polluters) equal to each participant's baseline emissions. The baseline is determined by reference to the participant's historical emissions. To demonstrate compliance, a participant must hold permits at least equal to the quantity of pollution it actually emitted during the time period. If every participant complies, the total pollution emitted will be at most equal to the sum of individual limits.[9] Because permits can be bought and sold, a participant can choose either to use its permits exactly (by reducing its own emissions); or to emit less than its permits, and perhaps sell the excess permits; or to emit more than its permits, and buy permits from other participants. In effect, the buyer pays a charge for polluting, while the seller gains a reward for having reduced emissions.

Emissions Trading results in the incorporation of economic costs into the costs of production which incentivizes corporations to consider investment returns and capital expenditure decisions with a model that includes the price of carbon and greenhouse gases (GHG).

In many schemes, organizations which do not pollute (and therefore have no obligations) may also trade permits and financial derivatives of permits.[10] In some schemes, participants can bank allowances to use in future periods.[11] In some schemes, a proportion of all traded permits must be retired periodically, causing a net reduction in emissions over time. Thus, environmental groups may buy and retire permits, driving up the price of the remaining permits according to the law of demand.[12] In most schemes, permit owners can donate permits to a nonprofit entity and receive a tax deductions. Usually, the government lowers the overall limit over time, with an aim towards a national emissions reduction target.[8]

According to the Environmental Defense Fund, cap-and-trade is the most environmentally and economically sensible approach to controlling greenhouse gas emissions, the primary cause of global warming, because it sets a limit on emissions, and the trading encourages companies to innovate in order to emit less.[13]

There are active trading programs in several air pollutants. An earlier application was the US national market to reduce acid rain. The United States now has several regional markets in nitrogen oxides.[14] For GHG, which cause climate change, carbon emission trade has been introduced in the European Union, China, the UK, Australia, New Zealand, some US states including California and a collection of Northeastern states, and other countries.

History

The efficiency of what later was to be called the "cap-and-trade" approach to air pollution abatement was first demonstrated in a series of micro-economic computer simulation studies between 1967 and 1970 for the National Air Pollution Control Administration (predecessor to the United States Environmental Protection Agency's Office of Air and Radiation) by Ellison Burton and William Sanjour. These studies used mathematical models of several cities and their emission sources in order to compare the cost and effectiveness of various control strategies.[15][16][17][18][19] Each abatement strategy was compared with the "least-cost solution" produced by a computer optimization program to identify the least-costly combination of source reductions in order to achieve a given abatement goal. In each case it was found that the least-cost solution was dramatically less costly than the same amount of pollution reduction produced by any conventional abatement strategy.[20] Burton and later Sanjour along with Edward H. Pechan continued improving[21] and advancing[22] these computer models at the newly created U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. The agency introduced the concept of computer modeling with least-cost abatement strategies (i.e., emissions trading) in its 1972 annual report to Congress on the cost of clean air.[23] This led to the concept of "cap and trade" as a means of achieving the "least-cost solution" for a given level of abatement.

The development of emissions trading over the course of its history can be divided into four phases:[24]

  1. Gestation: Theoretical articulation of the instrument (by Coase,[25] Crocker,[26] Dales,[27] Montgomery[28] etc.) and, independent of the former, tinkering with "flexible regulation" at the US Environmental Protection Agency.
  2. Proof of Principle: First developments towards trading of emission certificates based on the "offset-mechanism" taken up in Clean Air Act in 1977. A company could get allowance from the Act on a greater amount of emission when it paid another company to reduce the same pollutant.[29]
  3. Prototype: Launching of a first "cap-and-trade" system as part of the US Acid Rain Program in Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act, officially announced as a paradigm shift in environmental policy, as prepared by "Project 88", a network-building effort to bring together environmental and industrial interests in the US.
  4. Regime formation: branching out from the US clean air policy to global climate policy, and from there to the European Union, along with the expectation of an emerging global carbon market and the formation of the "carbon industry".

In the United States, the acid rain related emission trading system was principally conceived by C. Boyden Gray, a G.H.W. Bush administration attorney. Gray worked with the Environmental Defense Fund (EDF), who worked with the EPA to write the bill that became law as part of the Clean Air Act of 1990. The new emissions cap on NOx and SO2 gases took effect in 1995, and according to Smithsonian magazine, those acid rain emissions dropped 3 million tons that year.[30]

In 1997, the Kyoto Protocol was the first major agreement to reduce greenhouse gases. 38 developed countries (Annex 1 countries) committed themselves to targets and timetables.[31]

Economics of emission trading

It is possible for a country to reduce emissions using a command-and-control approach, such as regulation, direct and indirect taxes. The cost of that approach differs between countries because the Marginal Abatement Cost Curve (MAC)—the cost of eliminating an additional unit of pollution—differs by country.

Pricing the externality

An emissions trading scheme for greenhouse gas emissions (GHGs) works by establishing property rights for the atmosphere.[32] The atmosphere is a global public good, and GHG emissions are an international externality (p. 21). The emissions from all sources of GHGs contribute to the overall stock of GHGs in the atmosphere. In the cap-and-trade variant of emissions trading, a limit on access to a resource (the cap) is defined and then allocated among users in the form of permits. Compliance is established by comparing actual emissions with permits surrendered including any permits traded within the cap.[33] The environmental integrity of emissions trading depends on the setting of the cap, not the decision to allow trading.[34]

Efficiency and equity

For the purposes of analysis, it is possible to separate efficiency (achieving a given objective at lowest cost) and equity (fairness).[35] Economists generally agree that to regulate emissions efficiently, all polluters need to face the full costs of their actions (that is, the full marginal social costs of their actions).[36] Regulation of emissions that is applied only to one economic sector or region drastically reduces the efficiency of efforts to reduce global emissions.[37] There is, however, no scientific consensus over how to share the costs and benefits of reducing future climate change (mitigation of climate change), or the costs and benefits of adapting to any future climate change (see also economics of global warming).

Carbon leakage

A domestic ETS can only regulate the emissions of the country having the trading scheme. In this case, GHG emissions can "leak" (carbon leakage) to another region or sector with less regulation (p. 21). Leakages may be positive, where they reduce the effectiveness of domestic emission abatement efforts. Leakages may also be negative, and increase the effectiveness of domestic abatement efforts (negative leakages are sometimes called spillover) (IPCC, 2007).[38] For example, a carbon tax applied only to developed countries might lead to a positive leakage to developing countries (Goldemberg et al., 1996, pp. 27–28). However, a negative leakage might also occur due to technological developments driven by domestic regulation of GHGs.[39] This can help to reduce emissions even in less regulated regions.

Competitiveness risks

One way of addressing carbon leakage is to give sectors vulnerable to international competition free emission permits (Carbon Trust, 2009).[40] This acts as a subsidy for the sector in question. Free allocation of permits was opposed by the Garnaut Climate Change Review as it considered there were no circumstances that justify it and that governments could deal with market failure or claims for compensation more transparently with the revenue from full auctioning of permits.[41] The economically efficient option would, however, be border adjustments (Neuhoff, 2009;[42] Newbery, 2009).[43] Border adjustments work by setting a tariff on imported goods from less regulated countries. A problem with border adjustments is that they might be used as a disguise for trade protectionism.[44] Some types of border adjustment may also not prevent emissions leakage.

Issuing the permits: 'grandfathering' versus auctions

Tradable emissions permits can be issued to firms within an ETS by two main ways: by free allocation of permits to existing emitters or by auction.[45] Allocating permits based on past emissions is called "grandfathering" (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 38). Grandfathering permits, just like the other option of selling (auctioning) permits, sets a price on emissions. This gives permit-liable polluters an incentive to reduce their emissions. However, grandfathering permits can lead to perverse incentives, e.g., a firm that aimed to cut emissions drastically would then be given fewer permits in the future. Allocation may also slow down technological development towards less polluting technologies.[46] The Garnaut Climate Change Review noted that 'grandfathered' permits are not 'free'. As the permits are scarce they have value and the benefit of that value is acquired in full by the emitter. The cost is imposed elsewhere in the economy, typically on consumers who cannot pass on the costs.[41] However, profit-maximising firms receiving free permits will raise prices to customers because of the new, non-zero cost of emissions.[47]

A second method of "grandfathering" is to base allocations on current production of economic goods, rather than historical emissions. Under this method of allocation, government will set a benchmark level of emissions for each good deemed to be sufficiently trade exposed and allocate firms units based on their production of this good. However, allocating permits in proportion to output implicitly subsidises production.[48] The Garnaut Report noted that any method for free permit allocation will have the disadvantages of high complexity, high transaction costs, value-based judgements, and the use of arbitrary emissions baselines.[41]

On the other hand, auctioning permits provides the government with revenues. These revenues could be used to fund low-carbon investment, and also fund cuts in distortionary taxes. Auctioning permits can therefore be more efficient and equitable than allocating permits (Hepburn, 2006, pp. 236–237).[49] Ross Garnaut stated that full auctioning will provide greater transparency and accountability and lower implementation and transaction costs as governments retain control over the permit revenue.[41]

Recycling of revenue from permit auctions could offset a significant proportion of the economy-wide social costs of a cap and trade scheme.[50] As well as reducing tax distortions, Kerr and Cramton (1998) note that auctions of units are more flexible in distributing costs, they provide more incentives for innovation, and they lessen the political arguments over the allocation of economic rents.[51]

Lobbying for free allocation

According to Hepburn (2006, pp. 238–239),[49] "it should be expected that industry will lobby furiously against any auctioning". Hepburn et al. (2006) state that it is an empirical fact that while businesses tend to oppose auctioning of emissions permits, economists almost uniformly recommend auctioning permits.[52] Garnaut notes that the complexity of free allocation, and the large amounts of money involved, encourage non-productive rent-seeking behaviour and lobbying of governments, activities that dissipate economic value.[41]

Coase model

Coase (1960)[53][54] argued that social costs could be accounted for by negotiating property rights according to a particular objective. Coase's model assumes perfectly operating markets and equal bargaining power among those arguing for property rights. In Coase's model, efficiency, i.e., achieving a given reduction in emissions at lowest cost, is promoted by the market system. This can also be looked at from the perspective of having the greatest flexibility to reduce emissions. Flexibility is desirable because the marginal costs, that is to say, the incremental costs of reducing emissions, varies among countries. Emissions trading allows emission reductions to be first made in locations where the marginal costs of abatement are lowest (Bashmakov et al., 2001).[55] Over time, efficiency can also be promoted by allowing "banking" of permits (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 30). This allows polluters to reduce emissions at a time when it is most efficient to do so.

Equity

One of the advantages of Coase's model is that it suggests that fairness (equity) can be addressed in the distribution of property rights, and that regardless of how these property rights are assigned, the market will produce the most efficient outcome.[32] In reality, according to the held view, markets are not perfect, and it is therefore possible that a trade off will occur between equity and efficiency (Halsnæs et al., 2007).[56]

Trading

In an emissions trading system, permits may be traded by emitters who are liable to hold a sufficient number of permits in system. Some analysts argue that allowing others to participate in trading, e.g., private brokerage firms, can allow for better management of risk in the system, e.g., to variations in permit prices (Bashmakov et al., 2001).[57] It may also improve the efficiency of system. According to Bashmakov et al. (2001), regulation of these other entities may be necessary, as is done in other financial markets, e.g., to prevent abuses of the system, such as insider trading.

Incentives and allocation

Emissions trading gives polluters an incentive to reduce their emissions. However, there are possible perverse incentives that can exist in emissions trading. Allocating permits on the basis of past emissions ("grandfathering") can result in firms having an incentive to maintain emissions. For example, a firm that reduced its emissions would receive fewer permits in the future (IMF, 2008, pp. 25–26).[58] There are costs that emitters do face, e.g., the costs of the fuel being used, but there are other costs that are not necessarily included in the price of a good or service. These other costs are called external costs (Halsnæs et al., 2007).[59] This problem can also be criticized on ethical grounds, since the polluter is being paid to reduce emissions (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 38).[32] On the other hand, a permit system where permits are auctioned rather than given away, provides the government with revenues. These revenues might be used to improve the efficiency of overall climate policy, e.g., by funding energy efficiency programs (ACEEE 2019)[60] or reductions in distortionary taxes (Fisher et al., 1996, p. 417).[61]

In Coase's model of social costs, either choice (grandfathering or auctioning) leads to efficiency. In reality, grandfathering subsidizes polluters, meaning that polluting industries may be kept in business longer than would otherwise occur.[citation needed] Grandfathering may also reduce the rate of technological improvement towards less polluting technologies (Fisher et al., 1996, p. 417).

William Nordhaus argues that allocations cost the economy as they cause the under utilisation an efficient form of taxation.[62] Nordhaus argues that normal income, goods or service taxes distort efficient investment and consumption, so by using pollution taxes to generate revenue an emissions scheme can increase the efficiency of the economy.[62]

Form of allocation

The economist Ross Garnaut states that permits allocated to existing emitters by 'grandfathering' are not 'free'. As the permits are scarce they have value and the benefit of that value is acquired in full by the emitter. The cost is imposed elsewhere in the economy, typically on consumers who cannot pass on the costs.[41]

Market and least-cost

Economy-wide pricing of carbon is the centre piece of any policy designed to reduce emissions at the lowest possible costs.

Ross Garnaut, lead author of the Garnaut Climate Change Review[63]

Some economists have urged the use of market-based instruments such as emissions trading to address environmental problems instead of prescriptive "command-and-control" regulation.[64] Command and control regulation is criticized for being insensitive to geographical and technological differences, and therefore inefficient;[65] however, this is not always so, as shown by the WWII rationing program in the U.S. in which local and regional boards made adjustments for these differences.[66]

After an emissions limit has been set by a government political process, individual companies are free to choose how or whether to reduce their emissions. Failure to report emissions and surrender emission permits is often punishable by a further government regulatory mechanism, such as a fine that increases costs of production. Firms will choose the least-cost way to comply with the pollution regulation, which will lead to reductions where the least expensive solutions exist, while allowing emissions that are more expensive to reduce.

Under an emissions trading system, each regulated polluter has flexibility to use the most cost-effective combination of buying or selling emission permits, reducing its emissions by installing cleaner technology, or reducing its emissions by reducing production. The most cost-effective strategy depends on the polluter's marginal abatement cost and the market price of permits. In theory, a polluter's decisions should lead to an economically efficient allocation of reductions among polluters, and lower compliance costs for individual firms and for the economy overall, compared to command-and-control mechanisms.[67][9]

Measuring, reporting, verification and enforcement

Assuring compliance with an emissions trading scheme requires measuring, reporting and verification (MRV).[68] These measurements are reported to a regulator. For greenhouse gases, all trading countries maintain an inventory of emissions at national and installation level; in addition, trading groups within North America maintain inventories at the state level through The Climate Registry. For trading between regions, these inventories must be consistent, with equivalent units and measurement techniques.[69]

In some industrial processes, emissions can be physically measured by inserting sensors and flowmeters in chimneys and stacks, but many types of activity rely on theoretical calculations instead of measurement. Depending on local legislation, measurements may require additional checks and verification by government or third party auditors, prior or post submission to the local regulator.

Enforcement methods include fines and sanctions for polluters that have exceeded their allowances. Concerns include the cost of MRV and enforcement, and the risk that facilities may lie about actual emissions.

Pollution markets

An emission license directly confers a right to emit pollutants up to a certain rate. In contrast, a pollution license for a given location confers the right to emit pollutants at a rate which will cause no more than a specified increase at the pollution-level. For concreteness, consider the following model.[28]

  • There are   agents each of which emits   pollutants.
  • There are   locations each of which suffers pollution  .
  • The pollution is a linear combination of the emissions. The relation between   and   is given by a diffusion matrix  , such that:  .

As an example, consider three countries along a river (as in the fair river sharing setting).

  • Pollution in the upstream country is determined only by the emission of the upstream country:  .
  • Pollution in the middle country is determined by its own emission and by the emission of country 1:  .
  • Pollution in the downstream country is the sum of all emissions:  .

So the matrix   in this case is a triangular matrix of ones.

Each pollution-license for location   permits its holder to emit pollutants that will cause at most this level of pollution at location  . Therefore, a polluter that affects water quality at a number of points has to hold a portfolio of licenses covering all relevant monitoring-points. In the above example, if country 2 wants to emit a unit of pollutant, it should purchase two permits: one for location 2 and one for location 3.

Montgomery shows that, while both markets lead to efficient license allocation, the market in pollution-licenses is more widely applicable than the market in emission-licenses.[28]

International emissions trading

Example

Emissions trading through Gains from Trade can be more beneficial for both the buyer and the seller than a simple emissions capping scheme.

Consider two European countries, such as Germany and Sweden. Each can either reduce all the required amount of emissions by itself or it can choose to buy or sell in the market.

 
Example MACs for two different countries

Suppose Germany can abate its CO2 at a much cheaper cost than Sweden, i.e. MACS > MACG where the MAC curve of Sweden is steeper (higher slope) than that of Germany, and RReq is the total amount of emissions that need to be reduced by a country.

On the left side of the graph is the MAC curve for Germany. RReq is the amount of required reductions for Germany, but at RReq the MACG curve has not intersected the market emissions permit price of CO2 (market permit price = P = λ). Thus, given the market price of CO2 allowances, Germany has potential to profit if it abates more emissions than required.

On the right side is the MAC curve for Sweden. RReq is the amount of required reductions for Sweden, but the MACS curve already intersects the market price of CO2 permits before RReq has been reached. Thus, given the market price of CO2 permits, Sweden has potential to make a cost saving if it abates fewer emissions than required internally, and instead abates them elsewhere.

In this example, Sweden would abate emissions until its MACS intersects with P (at R*), but this would only reduce a fraction of Sweden's total required abatement.

After that it could buy emissions credits from Germany for the price P (per unit). The internal cost of Sweden's own abatement, combined with the permits it buys in the market from Germany, adds up to the total required reductions (RReq) for Sweden. Thus Sweden can make a saving from buying permits in the market (Δ d-e-f). This represents the "Gains from Trade", the amount of additional expense that Sweden would otherwise have to spend if it abated all of its required emissions by itself without trading.

Germany made a profit on its additional emissions abatement, above what was required: it met the regulations by abating all of the emissions that was required of it (RReq). Additionally, Germany sold its surplus permits to Sweden, and was paid P for every unit it abated, while spending less than P. Its total revenue is the area of the graph (RReq 1 2 R*), its total abatement cost is area (RReq 3 2 R*), and so its net benefit from selling emission permits is the area (Δ 1-2-3) i.e. Gains from Trade

The two R* (on both graphs) represent the efficient allocations that arise from trading.

  • Germany: sold (R* - RReq) emission permits to Sweden at a unit price P.
  • Sweden bought emission permits from Germany at a unit price P.

If the total cost for reducing a particular amount of emissions in the Command Control scenario is called X, then to reduce the same amount of combined pollution in Sweden and Germany, the total abatement cost would be less in the Emissions Trading scenario i.e. (X — Δ 123 - Δ def).

The example above applies not just at the national level, but also between two companies in different countries, or between two subsidiaries within the same company.

Applying the economic theory

The nature of the pollutant plays a very important role when policy-makers decide which framework should be used to control pollution. CO2 acts globally, thus its impact on the environment is generally similar wherever in the globe it is released. So the location of the originator of the emissions does not matter from an environmental standpoint.[70]

The policy framework should be different for regional pollutants[71] (e.g. SO2 and NOx, and also mercury) because the impact of these pollutants may differ by location. The same amount of a regional pollutant can exert a very high impact in some locations and a low impact in other locations, so it matters where the pollutant is released. This is known as the Hot Spot problem.

A Lagrange framework is commonly used to determine the least cost of achieving an objective, in this case the total reduction in emissions required in a year. In some cases, it is possible to use the Lagrange optimization framework to determine the required reductions for each country (based on their MAC) so that the total cost of reduction is minimized. In such a scenario, the Lagrange multiplier represents the market allowance price (P) of a pollutant, such as the current market price of emission permits in Europe and the USA.[72]

Countries face the permit market price that exists in the market that day, so they are able to make individual decisions that would minimize their costs while at the same time achieving regulatory compliance. This is also another version of the Equi-Marginal Principle, commonly used in economics to choose the most economically efficient decision.

Prices versus quantities, and the safety valve

 
Quarterly clearing price of an allowance to emit a ton of carbon dioxide in the US Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative, 2008–2021. The price of carbon emission has increased as the number of allowances issued has decreased.

There has been longstanding debate on the relative merits of price versus quantity instruments to achieve emission reductions.[73]

An emission cap and permit trading system is a quantity instrument because it fixes the overall emission level (quantity) and allows the price to vary. Uncertainty in future supply and demand conditions (market volatility) coupled with a fixed number of pollution permits creates an uncertainty in the future price of pollution permits, and the industry must accordingly bear the cost of adapting to these volatile market conditions. The burden of a volatile market thus lies with the industry rather than the controlling agency, which is generally more efficient. However, under volatile market conditions, the ability of the controlling agency to alter the caps will translate into an ability to pick "winners and losers" and thus presents an opportunity for corruption.

In contrast, an emission tax is a price instrument because it fixes the price while the emission level is allowed to vary according to economic activity. A major drawback of an emission tax is that the environmental outcome (e.g. a limit on the amount of emissions) is not guaranteed. On one hand, a tax will remove capital from the industry, suppressing possibly useful economic activity, but conversely, the polluter will not need to hedge as much against future uncertainty since the amount of tax will track with profits. The burden of a volatile market will be borne by the controlling (taxing) agency rather than the industry itself, which is generally less efficient. An advantage is that, given a uniform tax rate and a volatile market, the taxing entity will not be in a position to pick "winners and losers" and the opportunity for corruption will be less.

Assuming no corruption and assuming that the controlling agency and the industry are equally efficient at adapting to volatile market conditions, the best choice depends on the sensitivity of the costs of emission reduction, compared to the sensitivity of the benefits (i.e., climate damage avoided by a reduction) when the level of emission control is varied.

Because there is high uncertainty in the compliance costs of firms, some argue that the optimum choice is the price mechanism. However, the burden of uncertainty cannot be eliminated, and in this case it is shifted to the taxing agency itself.

The overwhelming majority of climate scientists have repeatedly warned of a threshold in atmospheric concentrations of carbon dioxide beyond which a run-away warming effect could take place, with a large possibility of causing irreversible damage. With such a risk, a quantity instrument may be a better choice because the quantity of emissions may be capped with more certainty. However, this may not be true if this risk exists but cannot be attached to a known level of greenhouse gas (GHG) concentration or a known emission pathway.[74]

A third option, known as a safety valve, is a hybrid of the price and quantity instruments. The system is essentially an emission cap and permit trading system but the maximum (or minimum) permit price is capped. Emitters have the choice of either obtaining permits in the marketplace or buying them from the government at a specified trigger price (which could be adjusted over time). The system is sometimes recommended as a way of overcoming the fundamental disadvantages of both systems by giving governments the flexibility to adjust the system as new information comes to light. It can be shown that by setting the trigger price high enough, or the number of permits low enough, the safety valve can be used to mimic either a pure quantity or pure price mechanism.[75]

All three methods are being used as policy instruments to control greenhouse gas emissions: the EU-ETS is a quantity system using the cap and trading system to meet targets set by National Allocation Plans; Denmark has a price system using a carbon tax (World Bank, 2010, p. 218),[76] while China uses the CO2 market price for funding of its Clean Development Mechanism projects, but imposes a safety valve of a minimum price per tonne of CO2.

Comparison with other methods of emission reduction

Cap and trade is the textbook example of an emissions trading program. Other market-based approaches include baseline-and-credit, and pollution tax. They all put a price on pollution (for example, see carbon price), and so provide an economic incentive to reduce pollution beginning with the lowest-cost opportunities. By contrast, in a command-and-control approach, a central authority designates pollution levels each facility is allowed to emit. Cap and trade essentially functions as a tax where the tax rate is variable based on the relative cost of abatement per unit, and the tax base is variable based on the amount of abatement needed.[citation needed]

Baseline and credit

In a baseline and credit program, polluters can create permits, called credits or offsets, by reducing their emissions below a baseline level, which is often the historical emissions level from a designated past year.[2] Such credits can be bought by polluters that have a regulatory limit.[77]

Pollution tax

Emissions fees or environmental tax is a surcharge on the pollution created while producing goods and services.[78] For example, a carbon tax is a tax on the carbon content of fossil fuels that aims to discourage their use and thereby reduce carbon dioxide emissions.[2] The two approaches are overlapping sets of policy designs. Both can have a range of scopes, points of regulation, and price schedules. They can be fair or unfair, depending on how the revenue is used. Both have the effect of increasing the price of goods (such as fossil fuels) to consumers.[79] A comprehensive, upstream, auctioned cap-and-trade system is very similar to a comprehensive, upstream carbon tax. Yet, many commentators sharply contrast the two approaches.

The main difference is what is defined and what derived. A tax is a price control, while a cap-and-trade system is a quantity control instrument.[79] That is, a tax is a unit price for pollution that is set by authorities, and the market determines the quantity emitted; in cap and trade, authorities determine the amount of pollution, and the market determines the price.[80] This difference affects a number of criteria.[78]

Responsiveness to inflation: Cap-and-trade has the advantage that it adjusts to inflation (changes to overall prices) automatically, while emissions fees must be changed by regulators.

Responsiveness to cost changes: It is not clear which approach is better. It is possible to combine the two into a safety valve price: a price set by regulators, at which polluters can buy additional permits beyond the cap.

Responsiveness to recessions: This point is closely related to responsiveness to cost changes, because recessions cause a drop in demand. Under cap and trade, the emissions cost automatically decreases, so a cap-and-trade scheme adds another automatic stabilizer to the economy—in effect, an automatic fiscal stimulus. However, a lower pollution price also results in reduced efforts to reduce pollution. If the government is able to stimulate the economy regardless of the cap-and-trade scheme, an excessively low price causes a missed opportunity to cut emissions faster than planned. Instead, it might be better to have a price floor (a tax). This is especially true when cutting pollution is urgent, as with greenhouse gas emissions. A price floor also provides certainty and stability for investment in emissions reductions: recent experience from the UK shows that nuclear power operators are reluctant to invest on "un-subsidised" terms unless there is a guaranteed price floor for carbon (which the EU emissions trading scheme does not presently provide).

Responsiveness to uncertainty: As with cost changes, in a world of uncertainty, it is not clear whether emissions fees or cap-and-trade systems are more efficient—it depends on how fast the marginal social benefits of reducing pollution fall with the amount of cleanup (e.g., whether inelastic or elastic marginal social benefit schedule).

Other: The magnitude of the tax will depend on how sensitive the supply of emissions is to the price. The permit price of cap-and-trade will depend on the pollutant market. A tax generates government revenue, but full-auctioned emissions permits can do the same. A similar upstream cap-and-trade system could be implemented. An upstream carbon tax might be the simplest to administer. Setting up a complex cap-and-trade arrangement that is comprehensive has high institutional needs.[81]

Command-and-control regulation

Command and control is a system of regulation that prescribes emission limits and compliance methods for each facility or source. It is the traditional approach to reducing air pollution.[2]

Command-and-control regulations are more rigid than incentive-based approaches such as pollution fees and cap and trade. An example of this is a performance standard which sets an emissions goal for each polluter that is fixed and, therefore, the burden of reducing pollution cannot be shifted to the firms that can achieve it more cheaply. As a result, performance standards are likely to be more costly overall.[78] The additional costs would be passed to end consumers.[82]

Trading systems

Apart from the dynamic development in carbon emission trading, other pollutants have also been targeted.

United States

Sulfur dioxide

An early example of an emission trading system has been the sulfur dioxide (SO2) trading system under the framework of the Acid Rain Program of the 1990 Clean Air Act in the U.S. Under the program, which is essentially a cap-and-trade emissions trading system, SO2 emissions were reduced by 50% from 1980 levels by 2007.[83] Some experts argue that the cap-and-trade system of SO2 emissions reduction has reduced the cost of controlling acid rain by as much as 80% versus source-by-source reduction.[64][84] The SO2 program was challenged in 2004, which set in motion a series of events that led to the 2011 Cross-State Air Pollution Rule (CSAPR). Under the CSAPR, the national SO2 trading program was replaced by four separate trading groups for SO2 and NOx.[85] SO2 emissions from Acid Rain Program sources have fallen from 17.3 million tons in 1980 to about 7.6 million tons in 2008, a decrease in emissions of 56 percent. A 2014 EPA analysis estimated that implementation of the Acid Rain Program avoided between 20,000 and 50,000 incidences of premature mortality annually due to reductions of ambient PM2.5 concentrations, and between 430 and 2,000 incidences annually due to reductions of ground-level ozone.[86][failed verification]

Nitrogen oxides

In 2003, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) began to administer the NOx Budget Trading Program (NBP) under the NOx State Implementation Plan (also known as the "NOx SIP Call"). The NOx Budget Trading Program was a market-based cap and trade program created to reduce emissions of nitrogen oxides (NOx) from power plants and other large combustion sources in the eastern United States. NOx is a prime ingredient in the formation of ground-level ozone (smog), a pervasive air pollution problem in many areas of the eastern United States. The NBP was designed to reduce NOx emissions during the warm summer months, referred to as the ozone season, when ground-level ozone concentrations are highest.[87] In March 2008, EPA again strengthened the 8-hour ozone standard to 0.075 parts per million (ppm) from its previous 0.08 ppm.[88]

Ozone season NOx emissions decreased by 43 percent between 2003 and 2008, even while energy demand remained essentially flat during the same period. CAIR will result in $85 billion to $100 billion in health benefits and nearly $2 billion in visibility benefits per year by 2015 and will substantially reduce premature mortality in the eastern United States.[citation needed] NOx reductions due to the NOx Budget Trading Program have led to improvements in ozone and PM2.5, saving an estimated 580 to 1,800 lives in 2008.[86][failed verification]

A 2017 study in the American Economic Review found that the NOx Budget Trading Program decreased NOx emissions and ambient ozone concentrations.[89] The program reduced expenditures on medicine by about 1.5% ($800 million annually) and reduced the mortality rate by up to 0.5% (2,200 fewer premature deaths, mainly among individuals 75 and older).[89]

Volatile organic compounds

 
Classification of Organic Pollutants

In the United States the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) classifies Volatile Organic Compounds (VOCs) as gases emitted from certain solids and liquids that may have adverse health effects.[90] These VOCs include a variety of chemicals that are emitted from a variety of different products.[90] These include products such as gasoline, perfumes, hair spray, fabric cleaners, PVC, and refrigerants; all of which can contain chemicals such as benzene, acetone, methylene chloride, freons, formaldehyde.[91]

VOCs are also monitored by the United States Geological Survey for its presence in groundwater supply.[92] The USGS concluded that many of the nations aquifers are at risk to low-level VOC contamination.[92] The common symptoms of short levels of exposure to VOCs include headaches, nausea, and eye irritation.[93] If exposed for an extended period of time the symptoms include cancer and damage to the central nervous system.[93]

China

In an effort to reverse the adverse consequences of air pollution, in 2006, China started to consider a national pollution permit trading system in order to use market-based mechanisms to incentivize companies to cut pollution.[94] This has been based on a previous pilot project called the Industrial SO2 emission trading pilot scheme, which was launched in 2002. Four provinces, three municipalities and one business entity was involved in this pilot project (also known as the 4+3+1 project). They are Shandong, Shanxi, Jiangsu, Henan, Shanghai, Tianjin, Liuzhou and China Huaneng Group, a state-owned company in the power industry.[95] This pilot project did not turn into a bigger scale inter-provincial trading system, but it stimulated numerous local trading platforms.[95]

In 2014, when the Chinese government started considering a national level pollution permit trading system again, there were more than 20 local pollution permit trading platforms. The Yangtze River Delta region as a whole has also run test trading, but the scale was limited.[96] In the same year, the Chinese government proposed establishing a carbon market, focused on CO2 reduction later in the decade, and it is a separate system from the pollution permit trading.[96]

A 2021 study in PNAS found that China's emissions trading system effectively reduced firm emissions despite low carbon prices and infrequent trading. The system reduced total emissions by 16.7% and emission intensity by 9.7%.[97]

Europe

 
European Allowance prices from 2009

The EU Emission Trading System was established in the year 2005 - in line with the commitment period of the Kyoto protocol. It follows the cap and trade model where one allowance permits the holder to emit 1 ton of CO2 (tCO2). The scheme was said to cover energy and heat generation industries and around 11,186 plants participated in the first stage. These plants only accounted for 45% of all European emissions at the time. More than 90% of all these allowances were free of cost in both periods to build a strong base of abatements for the future phases.[98] This free allocation resulted in the volume and value of allowances growing three-fold over 2006 with the price moving from €19/tCO₂ in 2005 to its peak of €30/tCO₂[99] which revealed a new problem. The overallocation of allowances caused the price to drop to €1/tCO₂ in the first few months of 2007 which created market price instabilities for businesses to reinvest in low carbon technologies.

Linked trading systems

Distinct cap-and-trade systems can be linked together through the mutual or unilateral recognition of emissions allowances for compliance. Linking systems creates a larger carbon market, which can reduce overall compliance costs, increase market liquidity and generate a more stable carbon market.[100][101] Linking systems can also be politically symbolic as it shows willingness to undertake a common effort to reduce GHG emissions.[102] Some scholars have argued that linking may provide a starting point for developing a new, bottom-up international climate policy architecture, whereby multiple unique systems successively link their various systems.[103][104]

In 2014, the U.S. state of California (which is the world's fifth largest economy if it were a nation, between Germany and the United Kingdom in size) and the Canadian province of Québec successfully linked their systems. In 2015, the provinces of Ontario and Manitoba agreed to join the linked system between Quebec and California.[105] On 22 September 2017, the premiers of Quebec and Ontario, and the Governor of California, signed the formal agreement establishing the linkage.[106]

Renewable energy certificates

Renewable Energy Certificates (occasionally referred to as or "green tags"[citation needed]), are a largely unrelated form of market-based instruments that are used to achieve renewable energy targets, which may be environmentally motivated (like emissions reduction targets), but may also be motivated by other aims, such as energy security or industrial policy.

Criticism

 
Chicago Climate Justice activists protesting cap and trade legislation in front of Chicago Climate Exchange building in Chicago Loop

Emissions trading has been criticised for a variety of reasons.

For example, in the popular science magazine New Scientist, Lohmann (2006) argued that trading pollution allowances should be avoided as a climate stabilization policy for several reasons. First, climate change requires more radical changes than previous pollution trading schemes such as the US SO2 market. It requires reorganizing society and technology to "leave most remaining fossil fuels safely underground". Carbon trading schemes have tended to reward the heaviest polluters with 'windfall profits' when they are granted enough carbon credits to match historic production. Expensive long-term structural changes will not be made if there are cheaper sources of carbon credits which are often available from less developed countries, where they may be generated by local polluters at the expense of local communities.[107]

Distributional effects

The US Congressional Budget Office (CBO, 2009) examined the potential effects of the American Clean Energy and Security Act on US households.[108] This act relies heavily on the free allocation of permits. The Bill was found to protect low-income consumers, but it was recommended that the Bill be made more efficient by reducing welfare provisions for corporations, and more resources be made available for consumer relief. A cap-and-trade initiative in the U.S. Northeast caused concerns it would be regressive and poorer households would absorb most of the new tax.[109]

Carbon Leakage

The current state of ETS shows that roughly 22% of global greenhouse emissions are covered by 64 carbon taxes and emission trading systems as of 2021.[110] This means that there are still several member states that have not ratified the Kyoto Protocol. This is a cause of concern for energy intensive industries that are covered by such instruments that claim that there is a loss of competitiveness. Such corporations are thereby forced to take strategic production decisions that contribute to the issue of carbon leakage.

See also

References

  1. ^ a b Stavins, Robert N. (November 2001). (PDF). Discussion Paper 01-58. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2011-05-01. Retrieved 2010-05-20. Market-based instruments are regulations that encourage behavior through market signals rather than through explicit directives regarding pollution control levels or methods
  2. ^ a b c d (PDF). Climate Change 101. Center for Climate and Energy Solutions. January 2011. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2017-10-05. Retrieved 27 October 2014.
  3. ^ "Allowance Trading". U.S. Environment Protection Agency. from the original on November 9, 2014. Retrieved Oct 21, 2014.
  4. ^ Judson Jaffe; Matthew Ranson; Robert N. Stavins (2009). (PDF). Ecology Law Quarterly. 36 (789). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2010-02-02. Retrieved 2010-08-25.
  5. ^ Tietenberg, Tom (2003). "The Tradable-Permits Approach to Protecting the Commons: Lessons for Climate Change". Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 19 (3): 400–419. doi:10.1093/oxrep/19.3.400.
  6. ^ Stavins, Robert N. (November 2001). (PDF). Discussion Paper 01-58. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2011-05-01. Retrieved 2010-08-25. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  7. ^ Teeter, Preston; Sandberg, Jorgen (2016). "Constraining or Enabling Green Capability Development? How Policy Uncertainty Affects Organizational Responses to Flexible Environmental Regulations" (PDF). British Journal of Management. 28 (4): 649–665. doi:10.1111/1467-8551.12188. S2CID 157986703. (PDF) from the original on 2020-05-06. Retrieved 2020-06-06.
  8. ^ a b Cap and Trade 101 2012-04-24 at the Wayback Machine, Center for American Progress, January 16, 2008.
  9. ^ a b Boswall, J. and Lee, R. (2002). Economics, ethics and the environment. London: Cavendish. pp.62–66.
  10. ^ "Emissions trading schemes around the world" 2020-01-10 at the Wayback Machine, Parliament of Australia, 2013.
  11. ^ "Cap and Trade 101". United States Environmental Protection Agency. from the original on 5 August 2015. Retrieved 27 October 2014.
  12. ^ O'Sullivan, Arthur, and Steven M. Sheffrin. Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey, 2003. ISBN 0-13-063085-3
  13. ^ "How cap and trade works". Environmental Defense Fund. from the original on 26 November 2019. Retrieved 27 October 2014.
  14. ^ "USEPA's Clean Air Markets web site". US EPA. from the original on 2010-07-24. Retrieved 2009-11-03.
  15. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour (1967) An Economic Analysis of the Control of Sulphur Oxides Air Pollution DHEW Program Analysis Report No. 1967-69 Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
  16. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1968). A Cost-Effectiveness Study of Particulate and SOx Emission Control in the New York Metropolitan Area. NTIS: PB-227 121/1. Contract Number: PH-86-68-37. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
  17. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1969). A Cost-Effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the Greater Kansas City Area. NTIS: PB-227 116/1. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
  18. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1969). A Cost-effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the National Capital Area. NAPCA Contract No. PH 86-68-37, NTIS: PB227110. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
  19. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1970). Applications of Cost-Effectiveness Analysis to Air Pollution Control. DHEW Contract No. CPA 22-69-17. Washington, D.C.: Ernst and Ernst.
  20. ^ Burton, E. S.; Sanjour, William (1970). "A Simulation Approach to Air Pollution Abatement Program Planning". Socio-Economic Planning Sciences. 4: 147–150. doi:10.1016/0038-0121(70)90036-4.
  21. ^ Burton, Ellison S., Edward H. Pechan III, and William Sanjour. (1973). A Survey of Air Pollution Control Models. Rolf A. Deininger, ed. Ann Arbor: Ann Arbor Science Publishers.
  22. ^ Burton, Ellison S.; Edward, H. Pechan III; Sanjour, William (1973). "Solving the Air Pollution Control Puzzle". Environmental Science and Technology. 7 (5): 412–5. Bibcode:1973EnST....7..412B. doi:10.1021/es60077a011. PMID 22283532.
  23. ^ U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (1972). The Economics of Clean Air, Annual Report of the Environmental Protection Agency to the Congress of the United States. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
  24. ^ Voss, Jan-Peter (2007). "Innovation processes in governance: the development of emissions trading as a new policy instrument". Science and Public Policy. 34 (5): 329–343. doi:10.3152/030234207x228584.
  25. ^ Coase, Ronald H. (1960). "The Problem of Social Cost". Journal of Law and Economics. 3 (1): 1–44. doi:10.1086/466560. S2CID 222331226.
  26. ^ Crocker, T. D. (1966). The Structuring of Atmospheric Pollution Control Systems. The Economics of Air Pollution. H. Wolozin. New York, W. W. Norton & Co.: 61–86.
  27. ^ Dales, John H (1968). "Land, Water, and Ownership". The Canadian Journal of Economics. 1 (4): 791–804. doi:10.2307/133706. JSTOR 133706.
  28. ^ a b c Montgomery, W.D (December 1972). "Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs". Journal of Economic Theory. 5 (3): 395–418. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(72)90049-X.
  29. ^ Gillenwater, Michael; Seres, Stephen (March 2011). (PDF). Pew Center on Global Climate Change. p. 6. Archived from the original (PDF) on 31 August 2016. Retrieved 26 November 2016.
  30. ^ Coniff, Richard (Aug. 2009). "The Political History of Cap and Trade" 2010-11-13 at the Wayback Machine. Smithsonian Magazine. Retrieved 1-13-2011
  31. ^ Grimeaud, D, 'An overview of the policy and legal aspects of the international climate change regime' (2001) 9(2) Environmental Liability 39.
  32. ^ a b c Goldemberg, J.; et al. (1996). "Introduction: scope of the assessment.". In J.P. Bruce; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. p. 29. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8.
  33. ^ Tietenberg, Tom (2003). "The Tradable-Permits Approach to Protecting the Commons: Lessons for Climate Change". Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 19 (3): 400–419. doi:10.1093/oxrep/19.3.400.
  34. ^ David M. Driesen. "Capping Carbon". Environmental Law. 40 (1): 1–55. Setting the cap properly matters more to environmental protection than the decision to allow, or not allow, trades
  35. ^ Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 29
  36. ^ Goldemburg et al., 1996, pp. 29, 37
  37. ^ Goldemburg et al., 1996, p. 30
  38. ^ IPCC (2007). "Glossary A-D". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). . Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. Archived from the original on 3 May 2010. Retrieved 25 August 2010.
  39. ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "Executive Summary". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). . Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. Archived from the original on 31 March 2010. Retrieved 6 May 2010.
  40. ^ Carbon Trust (March 2009). "Memorandum submitted by The Carbon Trust (ET19)". The role of carbon markets in preventing dangerous climate change. Minutes of Evidence, Tuesday 21 April 2009. UK Parliament House of Commons Environmental Audit Select Committee. The fourth report of the 2009-10 session. Retrieved 30 April 2010.
  41. ^ a b c d e f Garnaut, Ross (2008). "Releasing permits into the market". The Garnaut Climate Change Review. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-74444-7. Retrieved 28 April 2010.
  42. ^ Neuhoff, K. (22 February 2009). "Memorandum submitted by Karsten Neuhoff, Assistant Director, Electric Policy Research Group, University of Cambridge". The role of carbon markets in preventing dangerous climate change. Written evidence. UK Parliament House of Commons Environmental Audit Select Committee. The fourth report of the 2009-10 session. Retrieved 1 May 2010.
  43. ^ Newbery, D. (26 February 2009). "Memorandum submitted by David Newbery, Research Director, Electric Policy Research Group, University of Cambridge". The role of carbon markets in preventing dangerous climate change. Written evidence. UK Parliament House of Commons Environmental Audit Select Committee. The fourth report of the 2009-10 session. Retrieved 30 April 2010.
  44. ^ Grubb, M.; et al. (3 August 2009). . Climate Strategies: 5. Archived from the original on 6 February 2010. Retrieved 14 April 2010.
  45. ^ Gupta, S.; et al. (2007), "Section 13.2.1.3 Tradable permits", in B. Metz; et al. (eds.), Chapter 13: Policies, instruments, and co-operative arrangements, Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A., retrieved 10 July 2010
  46. ^ Fisher, B.S.; et al. (1996). "An Economic Assessment of Policy Instruments for Combating Climate Change.". In J.P. Bruce; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. p. 417. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8.
  47. ^ Goulder, Lawrence H.; Pizer, William A. (2006). The Economics of Climate Change (PDF). DP 06-06. Resources for the Future. (PDF) from the original on 2006-10-26.
  48. ^ Fischer, C; Fox, A (2007). "Output-based allocation of emissions permits for mitigating tax and trade interactions" (PDF). Land Economics. 83 (4): 575–599. doi:10.3368/le.83.4.575. S2CID 55649597. (PDF) from the original on 2004-12-17. Retrieved 10 August 2010. However, there often are important trade-offs in terms of efficiency because OBA implicitly subsidizes production, unlike conventional lump-sum allocation mechanisms like grandfathering.
  49. ^ a b Hepburn, C. (2006). "Regulating by prices, quantities or both: an update and an overview" (PDF). Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 22 (2): 226–247. doi:10.1093/oxrep/grj014. Retrieved 30 August 2009.
  50. ^ Stavins, Robert N. (2008). "Addressing climate change with a comprehensive US cap-and-trade system" (PDF). Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 24 (2 24): 298–321. doi:10.1093/oxrep/grn017. hdl:10419/53231. (PDF) from the original on 2020-05-10.
  51. ^ Kerr, Suzi; Cramton, Peter (1998). "Tradable Carbon Permit Auctions: How and Why to Auction Not Grandfather" (PDF). Discussion Paper Dp-98-34. Resources For the Future. (PDF) from the original on 2003-09-26. An auction is preferred to grandfathering (giving companies permits based on historical output or emissions), because it allows reduced tax distortions, provides more flexibility in distribution of costs, provides greater incentives for innovation, and reduces the need for politically contentious arguments over the allocation of rents.
  52. ^ Hepburn, Cameron J; Neuhoff, Karsten; Grubb, Michael; Matthes, Felix; Tse, Max (2006). "Auctioning of EU ETS Phase II allowances: why and how?" (PDF). Climate Policy. 6 (1): 137–160. doi:10.3763/cpol.2006.0608. Retrieved 19 May 2010.
  53. ^ Toth, F.L.; et al. (2001). . Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. Archived from the original on 2009-08-05. Retrieved 2010-01-10.
  54. ^ Helm, D. (2005). . The Economic and Social Review. 36 (3): 4. Archived from the original on 2011-05-01. Retrieved 2010-04-26.
  55. ^ Bashmakov, I.; et al. (2001). . Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. Archived from the original on 2009-08-05. Retrieved 2010-04-26.
  56. ^ Halsnæs, K.; et al. (2007). . Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Archived from the original on May 2, 2010. Retrieved 2010-04-26.
  57. ^ Bashmakov, I.; et al. (2001). "6.2.2.3 Tradable Permits. In (book chapter): 6. Policies, Measures, and Instruments.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). . Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. Archived from the original on 2009-08-05. Retrieved 2010-04-26.
  58. ^ IMF (March 2008). "Fiscal Implications of Climate Change" (PDF). International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Affairs Department. (PDF) from the original on 2010-08-06. Retrieved 2010-04-26.
  59. ^ Halsnæs, K.; et al. (2007). "2.4 Cost and benefit concepts, including private and social cost perspectives and relationships to other decision-making frameworks". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). . Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. p. 6. Archived from the original on May 2, 2010. Retrieved 2010-04-26.
  60. ^ eschwass (2019-01-02). "State and Provincial Efforts to Put a Price on Greenhouse Gas Emissions, with Implications for Energy Efficiency". ACEEE. from the original on 2019-01-09. Retrieved 2019-01-08.
  61. ^ Fisher, B.S.; et al. (1996). "An Economic Assessment of Policy Instruments for Combating Climate Change". In J.P. Bruce; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: IPCC website. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8.
  62. ^ a b Nordhaus, William (2007). (PDF). Oxford University Press. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2011-07-25. Retrieved 2010-04-28.
  63. ^ "Key points: Update Paper 6: Carbon pricing and reducing Australia's emissions". Garnaut Climate Change Review. 17 March 2011. from the original on 21 April 2013. Retrieved 16 July 2013.
  64. ^ a b Stavins, Robert N (1998). "What Can We Learn from the Grand Policy Experiment? Lessons from SO2 Allowance Trading". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 3. American Economic Association. 12 (3): 69–88. doi:10.1257/jep.12.3.69. JSTOR 2647033. from the original on 2015-09-21. Retrieved 2021-11-20.
  65. ^ Bryner, Gary C. Blue Skies, Green Politics: the Clean Air Act of 1990. Washington, D.C.:Congressional Quarterly Inc., 1951
  66. ^ Cox, Stan (2013). "Any way you slice it: The past, present and future of rationing" 2019-08-15 at the Wayback Machine. New Press Books.
  67. ^ Hall, JV and Walton, AL, "A case study in pollution markets: dismal science US. Dismal reality" (1996) XIV Contemporary Economic Policy 67.
  68. ^ "MRV&Enforcement". International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP). from the original on 27 October 2014. Retrieved 26 Oct 2014.
  69. ^ Tiwari, Gopal Nath; Agrawal, Basant (2010). Building integrated photovoltaic thermal systems : for sustainable developments. Cambridge: Royal Society of Chemistry. ISBN 978-1-84973-090-7.
  70. ^ Ramseur, Jonathan L. (April 16, 2010), (PDF), Congressional Research Service: 1, archived from the original (PDF) on September 27, 2013, retrieved February 15, 2011 {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  71. ^ Map: Pollution hotspots 2010-11-16 at the Wayback Machine, BBC map of areas that suffer from intense local pollution, BBC News, 2004-12-13. Retrieved 2009-10-19.
  72. ^ . Chicagoclimatex.com. 2009-08-04. Archived from the original on 2009-11-05. Retrieved 2009-11-03.
  73. ^ Weitzman, M. L. (October 1974). "Prices vs. Quantities". Review of Economic Studies. 41 (4): 477–491. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.1031.4819. doi:10.2307/2296698. JSTOR 2296698.
  74. ^ Philibert, Cédric (October 2006). (PDF). International Energy Agency Working Paper Series. Paris: International Energy Agency/OECD. LTO/2006/03. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2009-03-25. Retrieved 2010-01-24.
  75. ^ Jacoby, D.H.; Ellerman, A.D. (March 2004). "The safety valve and climate policy" (PDF). Energy Policy. 32 (4): 481–49. doi:10.1016/S0301-4215(03)00150-2. hdl:1721.1/3561. (PDF) from the original on 2007-06-28. Retrieved 2019-09-23.
  76. ^ "World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change" (PDF). World Bank. 2010. (PDF) from the original on 2016-03-04. Retrieved 2010-04-06.
  77. ^ Chomitz, Kenneth M. (1999). "Evaluating Carbon Offsets from Forestry and Energy Projects: How Do They Compare?". Policy Research Working Paper Series. 2357. World Bank. SSRN 630729. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  78. ^ a b c Rosen, Harvey S.; Gayer, Ted (2008). Public Finance. New York: McGraw-Hill Irwin. pp. 90–94. ISBN 978-0-07-351128-3.
  79. ^ a b Burney, Nelson E. (2010). Carbon Tax and Cap-and-trade Tools : Market-based Approaches for Controlling Greenhouse Gases. New York: Nova Science Publishers, Inc. ISBN 9781608761371.
  80. ^ Durning, Alan (July 2009). (PDF). Cap and Trade 101 a Federal Climate Policy Primer: 28. Archived from the original (PDF) on 7 July 2014. Retrieved 27 October 2014.
  81. ^ Calel, Raphael, "The Language of Climate Change Policy" 2021-02-24 at the Wayback Machine, 2010.
  82. ^ Yujie Lu; Xinyuan Zhu; Qingbin Cui (2012). "Effectiveness and equity implications of carbon policies in the United States construction industry". Building and Environment. Elsevier Ltd. 49: 259–269. doi:10.1016/j.buildenv.2011.10.002.
  83. ^ "Acid Rain Program 2007 Progress Report". Clean Air Markets - Air & Radiation. US EPA. January 2009. from the original on 2011-05-01. Retrieved 2011-07-25.
  84. ^ Carlson, Curtis; Burtraw, Dallas; Cropper, Maureen; Palmer, Karen L. (2000). "Sulfur dioxide control by electric utilities: What are the gains from trade?" (PDF). Journal of Political Economy. 108 (6): 1292–1326. doi:10.1086/317681. S2CID 3037737.
  85. ^ . United States Environment Protection Agency. 2011-07-09. Archived from the original on 2011-07-11. Retrieved 2011-07-10.
  86. ^ a b "Cap and Trade". United States Environmental Protection Agency. from the original on 8 November 2014. Retrieved 27 October 2014.
  87. ^ "NOx Budget Trading Program" 2017-04-26 at the Wayback Machine, Environmental Protection Agency. Retrieved 25 April 2017.
  88. ^ "Ozone Fact Sheet" 2017-02-22 at the Wayback Machine, Environmental Protection Agency. Retrieved 25 April 2017.
  89. ^ a b Deschênes, Olivier; Greenstone, Michael; Shapiro, Joseph (2017). "Defensive Investments and the Demand for Air Quality: Evidence from the NOx Budget Program". American Economic Review. 107 (10): 2958–2989. doi:10.1257/aer.20131002. ISSN 0002-8282.
  90. ^ a b EPA,OAR,ORIA,IED, US (18 August 2014). "Volatile Organic Compounds' Impact on Indoor Air Quality | US EPA". US EPA. from the original on 2017-11-22. Retrieved 2017-11-30.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  91. ^ . www.health.ny.gov. Archived from the original on 2018-01-11. Retrieved 2017-11-30.
  92. ^ a b Synthesis, NAWQA VOC National. "Chapter 1 - Major Findings and Conclusions". water.usgs.gov. from the original on 2017-05-18. Retrieved 2017-11-30.
  93. ^ a b . www.health.state.mn.us. Archived from the original on 2017-12-01. Retrieved 2017-11-30.
  94. ^ Bartson, Andrew (March 29, 2006). "China Considers Tradable Pollution-Rights Permits". The Wall Street Journal. from the original on December 14, 2017. Retrieved January 27, 2019.
  95. ^ a b Tu, Zhengge; Shen, Renjun (2014). "Can China's Industrial SO2 Emissions Trading Pilot Scheme Reduce Pollution Abatement Costs?". Sustainability. 6 (11): 7621–7645. doi:10.3390/su6117621. S2CID 17764664.
  96. ^ a b "China considers national pollution permit trading". Under2 Coalition. 2014-01-14. from the original on 2018-09-08. Retrieved 2018-09-08.
  97. ^ Cui, Jingbo; Wang, Chunhua; Zhang, Junjie; Zheng, Yang (2021-12-28). "The effectiveness of China's regional carbon market pilots in reducing firm emissions". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 118 (52). Bibcode:2021PNAS..11809912C. doi:10.1073/pnas.2109912118. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 8719898. PMID 34930839.
  98. ^ "Validate User". academic.oup.com. doi:10.1093/cje/bet028. Retrieved 2022-04-25.
  99. ^ Capoor, Karan; Ambrosi (May 2008). "State and Trends of the Carbon Market 2008". World Bank Group.
  100. ^ "Linking Emissions Trading Systems: A Summary of Current Research" 2021-11-20 at the Wayback Machine, ICAP 2015.
  101. ^ Burtraw, D., Palmer, K. L., Munnings, C., Weber, P., & Woerman, M., 2013: Linking by Degrees: Incremental Alignment of Cap-and-Trade Markets. SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2249955
  102. ^ Flachsland, C., Marschinski, R., & Edenhofer, O., 2009: To link or not to link: benefits and disadvantages of linking cap-and-trade systems. Climate Policy, 9(4), 358–372. doi:10.3763/cpol.2009.0626
  103. ^ Ranson, M., & Stavins, R., 2013: Linkage of Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading Systems - Learning from Experience. Discussion Paper Resources For The Future, No. 42
  104. ^ The House of Commons Energy and Climate Committee, 2015: Linking emissions trading systems. London.
  105. ^ "Quebec, Ontario, Manitoba sign agreement to link cap-and-trade systems" 2016-06-29 at the Wayback Machine, CBC News, 7 December 2015.
  106. ^ "California-Ontario-Québec Agreement on the Harmonization and Integration of their Cap-and-Trade Programs" (PDF). California Air Resources Board. Government of California. (PDF) from the original on 14 November 2017. Retrieved 14 November 2017.
  107. ^ Lohmann, Larry (2006-12-05). . New Scientist. 2580. Archived from the original on 2009-01-30. Retrieved 2010-07-17. Alt URL 2011-05-01 at the Wayback Machine
  108. ^ Stone, Chad; Shaw, Hannah (2009-07-10). "Senate can strengthen climate legislation by reducing corporate welfare and boosting true consumer relief" (PDF). Centre for Budget and Policy Priorities. (PDF) from the original on 2009-10-24. Retrieved 2010-01-27.
  109. ^ "Rising gas prices are fueling opposition to Transportation Climate Initiative". 17 November 2021.
  110. ^ World Bank. (2021, May 25). State and trends of carbon pricing 2021. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/35620

Further reading

  • Lin Feng; Jason Buhi (2009). "Emissions Trading Across China: Incorporating Hong Kong and Macau into an Urgently Needed Air Pollution Control Regime Under 'One Country, Two Systems'". Florida State University Journal of Transnational Law & Policy, Vol. 19, 2009. SSRN 1441395. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  • Gilbertson, T.; O. Reyes (1 November 2009). . Dag Hammarskjöld Foundation. Archived from the original on 25 August 2017. Retrieved 2010-05-14.
  • Chichilnisky, C.; Heal, G., eds. (2000). . Columbia University Press. Archived from the original on 2010-04-17. Retrieved 2010-05-12.
  • Norregaard, J.; V. Reppelin-Hill (1 January 2000). "Taxes and Tradable Permits as Instruments for Controlling Pollution: Theory and Practice. Working Paper No. 00/13". International Monetary Fund. Retrieved 2010-05-12.
  • Susanne Schennach (2000). "The Economics of Pollution Permit Banking in the Context of Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments". Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. Elsevier. 40 (3): 189–210. doi:10.1006/jeem.1999.1122. hdl:1721.1/45081.

External links

emissions, trading, this, page, about, emissions, trading, general, climate, related, concepts, carbon, price, carbon, emission, trading, market, based, approach, controlling, pollution, providing, economic, incentives, reducing, emissions, pollutants, concept. This page is about emissions trading in general For climate related concepts see Carbon price and Carbon emission trading Emissions trading is a market based approach to controlling pollution by providing economic incentives for reducing the emissions of pollutants 1 The concept is also known as cap and trade CAT or emissions trading scheme ETS Carbon emission trading for CO2 and other greenhouse gases has been introduced in China the European Union and other countries as a key tool for climate change mitigation Other schemes include sulfur dioxide and other pollutants In an emissions trading scheme a central authority or governmental body allocates or sells a limited number a cap of permits that allow a discharge of a specific quantity of a specific pollutant over a set time period 2 Polluters are required to hold permits in amount equal to their emissions Polluters that want to increase their emissions must buy permits from others willing to sell them 1 3 4 5 6 Emissions trading is a type of flexible environmental regulation 7 that allows organizations and markets to decide how best to meet policy targets This is in contrast to command and control environmental regulations such as best available technology BAT standards and government subsidies Contents 1 Introduction 2 History 3 Economics of emission trading 3 1 Pricing the externality 3 2 Efficiency and equity 3 3 Carbon leakage 3 4 Competitiveness risks 3 5 Issuing the permits grandfathering versus auctions 3 6 Lobbying for free allocation 3 7 Coase model 3 8 Equity 3 9 Trading 3 10 Incentives and allocation 3 11 Market and least cost 3 12 Measuring reporting verification and enforcement 3 12 1 Pollution markets 3 13 International emissions trading 3 13 1 Example 3 13 2 Applying the economic theory 3 14 Prices versus quantities and the safety valve 4 Comparison with other methods of emission reduction 4 1 Baseline and credit 4 2 Pollution tax 4 3 Command and control regulation 5 Trading systems 5 1 United States 5 1 1 Sulfur dioxide 5 1 2 Nitrogen oxides 5 1 3 Volatile organic compounds 5 2 China 5 3 Europe 5 4 Linked trading systems 5 5 Renewable energy certificates 6 Criticism 6 1 Distributional effects 6 2 Carbon Leakage 7 See also 8 References 9 Further reading 10 External linksIntroduction Edit A coal power plant in Germany Due to emissions trading coal may become a less competitive fuel than other options Pollution is a prime example of a market externality An externality is an effect of some activity on an entity such as a person that is not party to a market transaction related to that activity Emissions trading is a market based approach to address pollution The overall goal of an emissions trading plan is to minimize the cost of meeting a set emissions target 8 In an emissions trading system the government sets an overall limit on emissions and defines permits also called allowances or limited authorizations to emit up to the level of the overall limit The government may sell the permits but in many existing schemes it gives permits to participants regulated polluters equal to each participant s baseline emissions The baseline is determined by reference to the participant s historical emissions To demonstrate compliance a participant must hold permits at least equal to the quantity of pollution it actually emitted during the time period If every participant complies the total pollution emitted will be at most equal to the sum of individual limits 9 Because permits can be bought and sold a participant can choose either to use its permits exactly by reducing its own emissions or to emit less than its permits and perhaps sell the excess permits or to emit more than its permits and buy permits from other participants In effect the buyer pays a charge for polluting while the seller gains a reward for having reduced emissions Emissions Trading results in the incorporation of economic costs into the costs of production which incentivizes corporations to consider investment returns and capital expenditure decisions with a model that includes the price of carbon and greenhouse gases GHG In many schemes organizations which do not pollute and therefore have no obligations may also trade permits and financial derivatives of permits 10 In some schemes participants can bank allowances to use in future periods 11 In some schemes a proportion of all traded permits must be retired periodically causing a net reduction in emissions over time Thus environmental groups may buy and retire permits driving up the price of the remaining permits according to the law of demand 12 In most schemes permit owners can donate permits to a nonprofit entity and receive a tax deductions Usually the government lowers the overall limit over time with an aim towards a national emissions reduction target 8 According to the Environmental Defense Fund cap and trade is the most environmentally and economically sensible approach to controlling greenhouse gas emissions the primary cause of global warming because it sets a limit on emissions and the trading encourages companies to innovate in order to emit less 13 There are active trading programs in several air pollutants An earlier application was the US national market to reduce acid rain The United States now has several regional markets in nitrogen oxides 14 For GHG which cause climate change carbon emission trade has been introduced in the European Union China the UK Australia New Zealand some US states including California and a collection of Northeastern states and other countries History EditThe efficiency of what later was to be called the cap and trade approach to air pollution abatement was first demonstrated in a series of micro economic computer simulation studies between 1967 and 1970 for the National Air Pollution Control Administration predecessor to the United States Environmental Protection Agency s Office of Air and Radiation by Ellison Burton and William Sanjour These studies used mathematical models of several cities and their emission sources in order to compare the cost and effectiveness of various control strategies 15 16 17 18 19 Each abatement strategy was compared with the least cost solution produced by a computer optimization program to identify the least costly combination of source reductions in order to achieve a given abatement goal In each case it was found that the least cost solution was dramatically less costly than the same amount of pollution reduction produced by any conventional abatement strategy 20 Burton and later Sanjour along with Edward H Pechan continued improving 21 and advancing 22 these computer models at the newly created U S Environmental Protection Agency The agency introduced the concept of computer modeling with least cost abatement strategies i e emissions trading in its 1972 annual report to Congress on the cost of clean air 23 This led to the concept of cap and trade as a means of achieving the least cost solution for a given level of abatement The development of emissions trading over the course of its history can be divided into four phases 24 Gestation Theoretical articulation of the instrument by Coase 25 Crocker 26 Dales 27 Montgomery 28 etc and independent of the former tinkering with flexible regulation at the US Environmental Protection Agency Proof of Principle First developments towards trading of emission certificates based on the offset mechanism taken up in Clean Air Act in 1977 A company could get allowance from the Act on a greater amount of emission when it paid another company to reduce the same pollutant 29 Prototype Launching of a first cap and trade system as part of the US Acid Rain Program in Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act officially announced as a paradigm shift in environmental policy as prepared by Project 88 a network building effort to bring together environmental and industrial interests in the US Regime formation branching out from the US clean air policy to global climate policy and from there to the European Union along with the expectation of an emerging global carbon market and the formation of the carbon industry In the United States the acid rain related emission trading system was principally conceived by C Boyden Gray a G H W Bush administration attorney Gray worked with the Environmental Defense Fund EDF who worked with the EPA to write the bill that became law as part of the Clean Air Act of 1990 The new emissions cap on NOx and SO2 gases took effect in 1995 and according to Smithsonian magazine those acid rain emissions dropped 3 million tons that year 30 In 1997 the Kyoto Protocol was the first major agreement to reduce greenhouse gases 38 developed countries Annex 1 countries committed themselves to targets and timetables 31 Economics of emission trading EditIt is possible for a country to reduce emissions using a command and control approach such as regulation direct and indirect taxes The cost of that approach differs between countries because the Marginal Abatement Cost Curve MAC the cost of eliminating an additional unit of pollution differs by country Pricing the externality Edit An emissions trading scheme for greenhouse gas emissions GHGs works by establishing property rights for the atmosphere 32 The atmosphere is a global public good and GHG emissions are an international externality p 21 The emissions from all sources of GHGs contribute to the overall stock of GHGs in the atmosphere In the cap and trade variant of emissions trading a limit on access to a resource the cap is defined and then allocated among users in the form of permits Compliance is established by comparing actual emissions with permits surrendered including any permits traded within the cap 33 The environmental integrity of emissions trading depends on the setting of the cap not the decision to allow trading 34 Efficiency and equity Edit For the purposes of analysis it is possible to separate efficiency achieving a given objective at lowest cost and equity fairness 35 Economists generally agree that to regulate emissions efficiently all polluters need to face the full costs of their actions that is the full marginal social costs of their actions 36 Regulation of emissions that is applied only to one economic sector or region drastically reduces the efficiency of efforts to reduce global emissions 37 There is however no scientific consensus over how to share the costs and benefits of reducing future climate change mitigation of climate change or the costs and benefits of adapting to any future climate change see also economics of global warming Carbon leakage Edit A domestic ETS can only regulate the emissions of the country having the trading scheme In this case GHG emissions can leak carbon leakage to another region or sector with less regulation p 21 Leakages may be positive where they reduce the effectiveness of domestic emission abatement efforts Leakages may also be negative and increase the effectiveness of domestic abatement efforts negative leakages are sometimes called spillover IPCC 2007 38 For example a carbon tax applied only to developed countries might lead to a positive leakage to developing countries Goldemberg et al 1996 pp 27 28 However a negative leakage might also occur due to technological developments driven by domestic regulation of GHGs 39 This can help to reduce emissions even in less regulated regions Competitiveness risks Edit One way of addressing carbon leakage is to give sectors vulnerable to international competition free emission permits Carbon Trust 2009 40 This acts as a subsidy for the sector in question Free allocation of permits was opposed by the Garnaut Climate Change Review as it considered there were no circumstances that justify it and that governments could deal with market failure or claims for compensation more transparently with the revenue from full auctioning of permits 41 The economically efficient option would however be border adjustments Neuhoff 2009 42 Newbery 2009 43 Border adjustments work by setting a tariff on imported goods from less regulated countries A problem with border adjustments is that they might be used as a disguise for trade protectionism 44 Some types of border adjustment may also not prevent emissions leakage Issuing the permits grandfathering versus auctions Edit Tradable emissions permits can be issued to firms within an ETS by two main ways by free allocation of permits to existing emitters or by auction 45 Allocating permits based on past emissions is called grandfathering Goldemberg et al 1996 p 38 Grandfathering permits just like the other option of selling auctioning permits sets a price on emissions This gives permit liable polluters an incentive to reduce their emissions However grandfathering permits can lead to perverse incentives e g a firm that aimed to cut emissions drastically would then be given fewer permits in the future Allocation may also slow down technological development towards less polluting technologies 46 The Garnaut Climate Change Review noted that grandfathered permits are not free As the permits are scarce they have value and the benefit of that value is acquired in full by the emitter The cost is imposed elsewhere in the economy typically on consumers who cannot pass on the costs 41 However profit maximising firms receiving free permits will raise prices to customers because of the new non zero cost of emissions 47 A second method of grandfathering is to base allocations on current production of economic goods rather than historical emissions Under this method of allocation government will set a benchmark level of emissions for each good deemed to be sufficiently trade exposed and allocate firms units based on their production of this good However allocating permits in proportion to output implicitly subsidises production 48 The Garnaut Report noted that any method for free permit allocation will have the disadvantages of high complexity high transaction costs value based judgements and the use of arbitrary emissions baselines 41 On the other hand auctioning permits provides the government with revenues These revenues could be used to fund low carbon investment and also fund cuts in distortionary taxes Auctioning permits can therefore be more efficient and equitable than allocating permits Hepburn 2006 pp 236 237 49 Ross Garnaut stated that full auctioning will provide greater transparency and accountability and lower implementation and transaction costs as governments retain control over the permit revenue 41 Recycling of revenue from permit auctions could offset a significant proportion of the economy wide social costs of a cap and trade scheme 50 As well as reducing tax distortions Kerr and Cramton 1998 note that auctions of units are more flexible in distributing costs they provide more incentives for innovation and they lessen the political arguments over the allocation of economic rents 51 Lobbying for free allocation Edit According to Hepburn 2006 pp 238 239 49 it should be expected that industry will lobby furiously against any auctioning Hepburn et al 2006 state that it is an empirical fact that while businesses tend to oppose auctioning of emissions permits economists almost uniformly recommend auctioning permits 52 Garnaut notes that the complexity of free allocation and the large amounts of money involved encourage non productive rent seeking behaviour and lobbying of governments activities that dissipate economic value 41 Coase model Edit Coase 1960 53 54 argued that social costs could be accounted for by negotiating property rights according to a particular objective Coase s model assumes perfectly operating markets and equal bargaining power among those arguing for property rights In Coase s model efficiency i e achieving a given reduction in emissions at lowest cost is promoted by the market system This can also be looked at from the perspective of having the greatest flexibility to reduce emissions Flexibility is desirable because the marginal costs that is to say the incremental costs of reducing emissions varies among countries Emissions trading allows emission reductions to be first made in locations where the marginal costs of abatement are lowest Bashmakov et al 2001 55 Over time efficiency can also be promoted by allowing banking of permits Goldemberg et al 1996 p 30 This allows polluters to reduce emissions at a time when it is most efficient to do so Equity Edit One of the advantages of Coase s model is that it suggests that fairness equity can be addressed in the distribution of property rights and that regardless of how these property rights are assigned the market will produce the most efficient outcome 32 In reality according to the held view markets are not perfect and it is therefore possible that a trade off will occur between equity and efficiency Halsnaes et al 2007 56 Trading Edit In an emissions trading system permits may be traded by emitters who are liable to hold a sufficient number of permits in system Some analysts argue that allowing others to participate in trading e g private brokerage firms can allow for better management of risk in the system e g to variations in permit prices Bashmakov et al 2001 57 It may also improve the efficiency of system According to Bashmakov et al 2001 regulation of these other entities may be necessary as is done in other financial markets e g to prevent abuses of the system such as insider trading Incentives and allocation Edit Emissions trading gives polluters an incentive to reduce their emissions However there are possible perverse incentives that can exist in emissions trading Allocating permits on the basis of past emissions grandfathering can result in firms having an incentive to maintain emissions For example a firm that reduced its emissions would receive fewer permits in the future IMF 2008 pp 25 26 58 There are costs that emitters do face e g the costs of the fuel being used but there are other costs that are not necessarily included in the price of a good or service These other costs are called external costs Halsnaes et al 2007 59 This problem can also be criticized on ethical grounds since the polluter is being paid to reduce emissions Goldemberg et al 1996 p 38 32 On the other hand a permit system where permits are auctioned rather than given away provides the government with revenues These revenues might be used to improve the efficiency of overall climate policy e g by funding energy efficiency programs ACEEE 2019 60 or reductions in distortionary taxes Fisher et al 1996 p 417 61 In Coase s model of social costs either choice grandfathering or auctioning leads to efficiency In reality grandfathering subsidizes polluters meaning that polluting industries may be kept in business longer than would otherwise occur citation needed Grandfathering may also reduce the rate of technological improvement towards less polluting technologies Fisher et al 1996 p 417 William Nordhaus argues that allocations cost the economy as they cause the under utilisation an efficient form of taxation 62 Nordhaus argues that normal income goods or service taxes distort efficient investment and consumption so by using pollution taxes to generate revenue an emissions scheme can increase the efficiency of the economy 62 Form of allocationThe economist Ross Garnaut states that permits allocated to existing emitters by grandfathering are not free As the permits are scarce they have value and the benefit of that value is acquired in full by the emitter The cost is imposed elsewhere in the economy typically on consumers who cannot pass on the costs 41 Market and least cost Edit Economy wide pricing of carbon is the centre piece of any policy designed to reduce emissions at the lowest possible costs Ross Garnaut lead author of the Garnaut Climate Change Review 63 Some economists have urged the use of market based instruments such as emissions trading to address environmental problems instead of prescriptive command and control regulation 64 Command and control regulation is criticized for being insensitive to geographical and technological differences and therefore inefficient 65 however this is not always so as shown by the WWII rationing program in the U S in which local and regional boards made adjustments for these differences 66 After an emissions limit has been set by a government political process individual companies are free to choose how or whether to reduce their emissions Failure to report emissions and surrender emission permits is often punishable by a further government regulatory mechanism such as a fine that increases costs of production Firms will choose the least cost way to comply with the pollution regulation which will lead to reductions where the least expensive solutions exist while allowing emissions that are more expensive to reduce Under an emissions trading system each regulated polluter has flexibility to use the most cost effective combination of buying or selling emission permits reducing its emissions by installing cleaner technology or reducing its emissions by reducing production The most cost effective strategy depends on the polluter s marginal abatement cost and the market price of permits In theory a polluter s decisions should lead to an economically efficient allocation of reductions among polluters and lower compliance costs for individual firms and for the economy overall compared to command and control mechanisms 67 9 Measuring reporting verification and enforcement Edit This section needs additional citations for verification Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed September 2009 Learn how and when to remove this template message Assuring compliance with an emissions trading scheme requires measuring reporting and verification MRV 68 These measurements are reported to a regulator For greenhouse gases all trading countries maintain an inventory of emissions at national and installation level in addition trading groups within North America maintain inventories at the state level through The Climate Registry For trading between regions these inventories must be consistent with equivalent units and measurement techniques 69 In some industrial processes emissions can be physically measured by inserting sensors and flowmeters in chimneys and stacks but many types of activity rely on theoretical calculations instead of measurement Depending on local legislation measurements may require additional checks and verification by government or third party auditors prior or post submission to the local regulator Enforcement methods include fines and sanctions for polluters that have exceeded their allowances Concerns include the cost of MRV and enforcement and the risk that facilities may lie about actual emissions Pollution markets Edit An emission license directly confers a right to emit pollutants up to a certain rate In contrast a pollution license for a given location confers the right to emit pollutants at a rate which will cause no more than a specified increase at the pollution level For concreteness consider the following model 28 There are n displaystyle n agents each of which emits e i displaystyle e i pollutants There are m displaystyle m locations each of which suffers pollution q i displaystyle q i The pollution is a linear combination of the emissions The relation between e displaystyle e and q displaystyle q is given by a diffusion matrix H displaystyle H such that q H e displaystyle q H cdot e As an example consider three countries along a river as in the fair river sharing setting Pollution in the upstream country is determined only by the emission of the upstream country q 1 e 1 displaystyle q 1 e 1 Pollution in the middle country is determined by its own emission and by the emission of country 1 q 2 e 1 e 2 displaystyle q 2 e 1 e 2 Pollution in the downstream country is the sum of all emissions q 3 e 1 e 2 e 3 displaystyle q 3 e 1 e 2 e 3 So the matrix H displaystyle H in this case is a triangular matrix of ones Each pollution license for location i displaystyle i permits its holder to emit pollutants that will cause at most this level of pollution at location i displaystyle i Therefore a polluter that affects water quality at a number of points has to hold a portfolio of licenses covering all relevant monitoring points In the above example if country 2 wants to emit a unit of pollutant it should purchase two permits one for location 2 and one for location 3 Montgomery shows that while both markets lead to efficient license allocation the market in pollution licenses is more widely applicable than the market in emission licenses 28 International emissions trading Edit Example Edit Emissions trading through Gains from Trade can be more beneficial for both the buyer and the seller than a simple emissions capping scheme Consider two European countries such as Germany and Sweden Each can either reduce all the required amount of emissions by itself or it can choose to buy or sell in the market Example MACs for two different countries Suppose Germany can abate its CO2 at a much cheaper cost than Sweden i e MACS gt MACG where the MAC curve of Sweden is steeper higher slope than that of Germany and RReq is the total amount of emissions that need to be reduced by a country On the left side of the graph is the MAC curve for Germany RReq is the amount of required reductions for Germany but at RReq the MACG curve has not intersected the market emissions permit price of CO2 market permit price P l Thus given the market price of CO2 allowances Germany has potential to profit if it abates more emissions than required On the right side is the MAC curve for Sweden RReq is the amount of required reductions for Sweden but the MACS curve already intersects the market price of CO2 permits before RReq has been reached Thus given the market price of CO2 permits Sweden has potential to make a cost saving if it abates fewer emissions than required internally and instead abates them elsewhere In this example Sweden would abate emissions until its MACS intersects with P at R but this would only reduce a fraction of Sweden s total required abatement After that it could buy emissions credits from Germany for the price P per unit The internal cost of Sweden s own abatement combined with the permits it buys in the market from Germany adds up to the total required reductions RReq for Sweden Thus Sweden can make a saving from buying permits in the market D d e f This represents the Gains from Trade the amount of additional expense that Sweden would otherwise have to spend if it abated all of its required emissions by itself without trading Germany made a profit on its additional emissions abatement above what was required it met the regulations by abating all of the emissions that was required of it RReq Additionally Germany sold its surplus permits to Sweden and was paid P for every unit it abated while spending less than P Its total revenue is the area of the graph RReq 1 2 R its total abatement cost is area RReq 3 2 R and so its net benefit from selling emission permits is the area D 1 2 3 i e Gains from TradeThe two R on both graphs represent the efficient allocations that arise from trading Germany sold R RReq emission permits to Sweden at a unit price P Sweden bought emission permits from Germany at a unit price P If the total cost for reducing a particular amount of emissions in the Command Control scenario is called X then to reduce the same amount of combined pollution in Sweden and Germany the total abatement cost would be less in the Emissions Trading scenario i e X D 123 D def The example above applies not just at the national level but also between two companies in different countries or between two subsidiaries within the same company Applying the economic theory Edit The nature of the pollutant plays a very important role when policy makers decide which framework should be used to control pollution CO2 acts globally thus its impact on the environment is generally similar wherever in the globe it is released So the location of the originator of the emissions does not matter from an environmental standpoint 70 The policy framework should be different for regional pollutants 71 e g SO2 and NOx and also mercury because the impact of these pollutants may differ by location The same amount of a regional pollutant can exert a very high impact in some locations and a low impact in other locations so it matters where the pollutant is released This is known as the Hot Spot problem A Lagrange framework is commonly used to determine the least cost of achieving an objective in this case the total reduction in emissions required in a year In some cases it is possible to use the Lagrange optimization framework to determine the required reductions for each country based on their MAC so that the total cost of reduction is minimized In such a scenario the Lagrange multiplier represents the market allowance price P of a pollutant such as the current market price of emission permits in Europe and the USA 72 Countries face the permit market price that exists in the market that day so they are able to make individual decisions that would minimize their costs while at the same time achieving regulatory compliance This is also another version of the Equi Marginal Principle commonly used in economics to choose the most economically efficient decision Prices versus quantities and the safety valve Edit Quarterly clearing price of an allowance to emit a ton of carbon dioxide in the US Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative 2008 2021 The price of carbon emission has increased as the number of allowances issued has decreased There has been longstanding debate on the relative merits of price versus quantity instruments to achieve emission reductions 73 An emission cap and permit trading system is a quantity instrument because it fixes the overall emission level quantity and allows the price to vary Uncertainty in future supply and demand conditions market volatility coupled with a fixed number of pollution permits creates an uncertainty in the future price of pollution permits and the industry must accordingly bear the cost of adapting to these volatile market conditions The burden of a volatile market thus lies with the industry rather than the controlling agency which is generally more efficient However under volatile market conditions the ability of the controlling agency to alter the caps will translate into an ability to pick winners and losers and thus presents an opportunity for corruption In contrast an emission tax is a price instrument because it fixes the price while the emission level is allowed to vary according to economic activity A major drawback of an emission tax is that the environmental outcome e g a limit on the amount of emissions is not guaranteed On one hand a tax will remove capital from the industry suppressing possibly useful economic activity but conversely the polluter will not need to hedge as much against future uncertainty since the amount of tax will track with profits The burden of a volatile market will be borne by the controlling taxing agency rather than the industry itself which is generally less efficient An advantage is that given a uniform tax rate and a volatile market the taxing entity will not be in a position to pick winners and losers and the opportunity for corruption will be less Assuming no corruption and assuming that the controlling agency and the industry are equally efficient at adapting to volatile market conditions the best choice depends on the sensitivity of the costs of emission reduction compared to the sensitivity of the benefits i e climate damage avoided by a reduction when the level of emission control is varied Because there is high uncertainty in the compliance costs of firms some argue that the optimum choice is the price mechanism However the burden of uncertainty cannot be eliminated and in this case it is shifted to the taxing agency itself The overwhelming majority of climate scientists have repeatedly warned of a threshold in atmospheric concentrations of carbon dioxide beyond which a run away warming effect could take place with a large possibility of causing irreversible damage With such a risk a quantity instrument may be a better choice because the quantity of emissions may be capped with more certainty However this may not be true if this risk exists but cannot be attached to a known level of greenhouse gas GHG concentration or a known emission pathway 74 A third option known as a safety valve is a hybrid of the price and quantity instruments The system is essentially an emission cap and permit trading system but the maximum or minimum permit price is capped Emitters have the choice of either obtaining permits in the marketplace or buying them from the government at a specified trigger price which could be adjusted over time The system is sometimes recommended as a way of overcoming the fundamental disadvantages of both systems by giving governments the flexibility to adjust the system as new information comes to light It can be shown that by setting the trigger price high enough or the number of permits low enough the safety valve can be used to mimic either a pure quantity or pure price mechanism 75 All three methods are being used as policy instruments to control greenhouse gas emissions the EU ETS is a quantity system using the cap and trading system to meet targets set by National Allocation Plans Denmark has a price system using a carbon tax World Bank 2010 p 218 76 while China uses the CO2 market price for funding of its Clean Development Mechanism projects but imposes a safety valve of a minimum price per tonne of CO2 Comparison with other methods of emission reduction EditCap and trade is the textbook example of an emissions trading program Other market based approaches include baseline and credit and pollution tax They all put a price on pollution for example see carbon price and so provide an economic incentive to reduce pollution beginning with the lowest cost opportunities By contrast in a command and control approach a central authority designates pollution levels each facility is allowed to emit Cap and trade essentially functions as a tax where the tax rate is variable based on the relative cost of abatement per unit and the tax base is variable based on the amount of abatement needed citation needed Baseline and credit Edit In a baseline and credit program polluters can create permits called credits or offsets by reducing their emissions below a baseline level which is often the historical emissions level from a designated past year 2 Such credits can be bought by polluters that have a regulatory limit 77 Pollution tax Edit Main article Ecotax Emissions fees or environmental tax is a surcharge on the pollution created while producing goods and services 78 For example a carbon tax is a tax on the carbon content of fossil fuels that aims to discourage their use and thereby reduce carbon dioxide emissions 2 The two approaches are overlapping sets of policy designs Both can have a range of scopes points of regulation and price schedules They can be fair or unfair depending on how the revenue is used Both have the effect of increasing the price of goods such as fossil fuels to consumers 79 A comprehensive upstream auctioned cap and trade system is very similar to a comprehensive upstream carbon tax Yet many commentators sharply contrast the two approaches The main difference is what is defined and what derived A tax is a price control while a cap and trade system is a quantity control instrument 79 That is a tax is a unit price for pollution that is set by authorities and the market determines the quantity emitted in cap and trade authorities determine the amount of pollution and the market determines the price 80 This difference affects a number of criteria 78 Responsiveness to inflation Cap and trade has the advantage that it adjusts to inflation changes to overall prices automatically while emissions fees must be changed by regulators Responsiveness to cost changes It is not clear which approach is better It is possible to combine the two into a safety valve price a price set by regulators at which polluters can buy additional permits beyond the cap Responsiveness to recessions This point is closely related to responsiveness to cost changes because recessions cause a drop in demand Under cap and trade the emissions cost automatically decreases so a cap and trade scheme adds another automatic stabilizer to the economy in effect an automatic fiscal stimulus However a lower pollution price also results in reduced efforts to reduce pollution If the government is able to stimulate the economy regardless of the cap and trade scheme an excessively low price causes a missed opportunity to cut emissions faster than planned Instead it might be better to have a price floor a tax This is especially true when cutting pollution is urgent as with greenhouse gas emissions A price floor also provides certainty and stability for investment in emissions reductions recent experience from the UK shows that nuclear power operators are reluctant to invest on un subsidised terms unless there is a guaranteed price floor for carbon which the EU emissions trading scheme does not presently provide Responsiveness to uncertainty As with cost changes in a world of uncertainty it is not clear whether emissions fees or cap and trade systems are more efficient it depends on how fast the marginal social benefits of reducing pollution fall with the amount of cleanup e g whether inelastic or elastic marginal social benefit schedule Other The magnitude of the tax will depend on how sensitive the supply of emissions is to the price The permit price of cap and trade will depend on the pollutant market A tax generates government revenue but full auctioned emissions permits can do the same A similar upstream cap and trade system could be implemented An upstream carbon tax might be the simplest to administer Setting up a complex cap and trade arrangement that is comprehensive has high institutional needs 81 Command and control regulation Edit Command and control is a system of regulation that prescribes emission limits and compliance methods for each facility or source It is the traditional approach to reducing air pollution 2 Command and control regulations are more rigid than incentive based approaches such as pollution fees and cap and trade An example of this is a performance standard which sets an emissions goal for each polluter that is fixed and therefore the burden of reducing pollution cannot be shifted to the firms that can achieve it more cheaply As a result performance standards are likely to be more costly overall 78 The additional costs would be passed to end consumers 82 Trading systems EditApart from the dynamic development in carbon emission trading other pollutants have also been targeted United States Edit Sulfur dioxide Edit Main article Acid Rain Program An early example of an emission trading system has been the sulfur dioxide SO2 trading system under the framework of the Acid Rain Program of the 1990 Clean Air Act in the U S Under the program which is essentially a cap and trade emissions trading system SO2 emissions were reduced by 50 from 1980 levels by 2007 83 Some experts argue that the cap and trade system of SO2 emissions reduction has reduced the cost of controlling acid rain by as much as 80 versus source by source reduction 64 84 The SO2 program was challenged in 2004 which set in motion a series of events that led to the 2011 Cross State Air Pollution Rule CSAPR Under the CSAPR the national SO2 trading program was replaced by four separate trading groups for SO2 and NOx 85 SO2 emissions from Acid Rain Program sources have fallen from 17 3 million tons in 1980 to about 7 6 million tons in 2008 a decrease in emissions of 56 percent A 2014 EPA analysis estimated that implementation of the Acid Rain Program avoided between 20 000 and 50 000 incidences of premature mortality annually due to reductions of ambient PM2 5 concentrations and between 430 and 2 000 incidences annually due to reductions of ground level ozone 86 failed verification Nitrogen oxides Edit In 2003 the Environmental Protection Agency EPA began to administer the NOx Budget Trading Program NBP under the NOx State Implementation Plan also known as the NOx SIP Call The NOx Budget Trading Program was a market based cap and trade program created to reduce emissions of nitrogen oxides NOx from power plants and other large combustion sources in the eastern United States NOx is a prime ingredient in the formation of ground level ozone smog a pervasive air pollution problem in many areas of the eastern United States The NBP was designed to reduce NOx emissions during the warm summer months referred to as the ozone season when ground level ozone concentrations are highest 87 In March 2008 EPA again strengthened the 8 hour ozone standard to 0 075 parts per million ppm from its previous 0 08 ppm 88 Ozone season NOx emissions decreased by 43 percent between 2003 and 2008 even while energy demand remained essentially flat during the same period CAIR will result in 85 billion to 100 billion in health benefits and nearly 2 billion in visibility benefits per year by 2015 and will substantially reduce premature mortality in the eastern United States citation needed NOx reductions due to the NOx Budget Trading Program have led to improvements in ozone and PM2 5 saving an estimated 580 to 1 800 lives in 2008 86 failed verification A 2017 study in the American Economic Review found that the NOx Budget Trading Program decreased NOx emissions and ambient ozone concentrations 89 The program reduced expenditures on medicine by about 1 5 800 million annually and reduced the mortality rate by up to 0 5 2 200 fewer premature deaths mainly among individuals 75 and older 89 Volatile organic compounds Edit Classification of Organic Pollutants In the United States the Environmental Protection Agency EPA classifies Volatile Organic Compounds VOCs as gases emitted from certain solids and liquids that may have adverse health effects 90 These VOCs include a variety of chemicals that are emitted from a variety of different products 90 These include products such as gasoline perfumes hair spray fabric cleaners PVC and refrigerants all of which can contain chemicals such as benzene acetone methylene chloride freons formaldehyde 91 VOCs are also monitored by the United States Geological Survey for its presence in groundwater supply 92 The USGS concluded that many of the nations aquifers are at risk to low level VOC contamination 92 The common symptoms of short levels of exposure to VOCs include headaches nausea and eye irritation 93 If exposed for an extended period of time the symptoms include cancer and damage to the central nervous system 93 China Edit In an effort to reverse the adverse consequences of air pollution in 2006 China started to consider a national pollution permit trading system in order to use market based mechanisms to incentivize companies to cut pollution 94 This has been based on a previous pilot project called the Industrial SO2 emission trading pilot scheme which was launched in 2002 Four provinces three municipalities and one business entity was involved in this pilot project also known as the 4 3 1 project They are Shandong Shanxi Jiangsu Henan Shanghai Tianjin Liuzhou and China Huaneng Group a state owned company in the power industry 95 This pilot project did not turn into a bigger scale inter provincial trading system but it stimulated numerous local trading platforms 95 In 2014 when the Chinese government started considering a national level pollution permit trading system again there were more than 20 local pollution permit trading platforms The Yangtze River Delta region as a whole has also run test trading but the scale was limited 96 In the same year the Chinese government proposed establishing a carbon market focused on CO2 reduction later in the decade and it is a separate system from the pollution permit trading 96 A 2021 study in PNAS found that China s emissions trading system effectively reduced firm emissions despite low carbon prices and infrequent trading The system reduced total emissions by 16 7 and emission intensity by 9 7 97 Europe Edit Main article European Union Emissions Trading System European Allowance prices from 2009The EU Emission Trading System was established in the year 2005 in line with the commitment period of the Kyoto protocol It follows the cap and trade model where one allowance permits the holder to emit 1 ton of CO2 tCO2 The scheme was said to cover energy and heat generation industries and around 11 186 plants participated in the first stage These plants only accounted for 45 of all European emissions at the time More than 90 of all these allowances were free of cost in both periods to build a strong base of abatements for the future phases 98 This free allocation resulted in the volume and value of allowances growing three fold over 2006 with the price moving from 19 tCO in 2005 to its peak of 30 tCO 99 which revealed a new problem The overallocation of allowances caused the price to drop to 1 tCO in the first few months of 2007 which created market price instabilities for businesses to reinvest in low carbon technologies Linked trading systems Edit Distinct cap and trade systems can be linked together through the mutual or unilateral recognition of emissions allowances for compliance Linking systems creates a larger carbon market which can reduce overall compliance costs increase market liquidity and generate a more stable carbon market 100 101 Linking systems can also be politically symbolic as it shows willingness to undertake a common effort to reduce GHG emissions 102 Some scholars have argued that linking may provide a starting point for developing a new bottom up international climate policy architecture whereby multiple unique systems successively link their various systems 103 104 In 2014 the U S state of California which is the world s fifth largest economy if it were a nation between Germany and the United Kingdom in size and the Canadian province of Quebec successfully linked their systems In 2015 the provinces of Ontario and Manitoba agreed to join the linked system between Quebec and California 105 On 22 September 2017 the premiers of Quebec and Ontario and the Governor of California signed the formal agreement establishing the linkage 106 Renewable energy certificates Edit Main article Renewable Energy Certificates Renewable Energy Certificates occasionally referred to as or green tags citation needed are a largely unrelated form of market based instruments that are used to achieve renewable energy targets which may be environmentally motivated like emissions reduction targets but may also be motivated by other aims such as energy security or industrial policy Criticism EditThis article needs to be updated Please help update this article to reflect recent events or newly available information March 2021 Chicago Climate Justice activists protesting cap and trade legislation in front of Chicago Climate Exchange building in Chicago Loop Emissions trading has been criticised for a variety of reasons For example in the popular science magazine New Scientist Lohmann 2006 argued that trading pollution allowances should be avoided as a climate stabilization policy for several reasons First climate change requires more radical changes than previous pollution trading schemes such as the US SO2 market It requires reorganizing society and technology to leave most remaining fossil fuels safely underground Carbon trading schemes have tended to reward the heaviest polluters with windfall profits when they are granted enough carbon credits to match historic production Expensive long term structural changes will not be made if there are cheaper sources of carbon credits which are often available from less developed countries where they may be generated by local polluters at the expense of local communities 107 Distributional effects Edit The US Congressional Budget Office CBO 2009 examined the potential effects of the American Clean Energy and Security Act on US households 108 This act relies heavily on the free allocation of permits The Bill was found to protect low income consumers but it was recommended that the Bill be made more efficient by reducing welfare provisions for corporations and more resources be made available for consumer relief A cap and trade initiative in the U S Northeast caused concerns it would be regressive and poorer households would absorb most of the new tax 109 Carbon Leakage Edit The current state of ETS shows that roughly 22 of global greenhouse emissions are covered by 64 carbon taxes and emission trading systems as of 2021 110 This means that there are still several member states that have not ratified the Kyoto Protocol This is a cause of concern for energy intensive industries that are covered by such instruments that claim that there is a loss of competitiveness Such corporations are thereby forced to take strategic production decisions that contribute to the issue of carbon leakage See also Edit Global warming portal Ecology portal Environment portalAcid Rain Retirement Fund AP 42 Compilation of Air Pollutant Emission Factors Asia Pacific Emissions Trading Forum Cap and Dividend Cap and Share Carbon credit Carbon emissions reporting Carbon finance Carbon offset Carbon tax Emission standard Energy law Flexible Mechanisms Green certificate Green investment scheme Individual and political action on climate change Low carbon economy Low carbon power generation Renewable energy Mitigation of global warming Mobile emission reduction credit MERC Personal carbon trading Pigovian tax Public Smog Reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation Verified Carbon StandardReferences Edit a b Stavins Robert N November 2001 Experience with Market Based Environmental Policy Instruments PDF Discussion Paper 01 58 Washington D C Resources for the Future Archived from the original PDF on 2011 05 01 Retrieved 2010 05 20 Market based instruments are regulations that encourage behavior through market signals rather than through explicit directives regarding pollution control levels or methods a b c d Cap and Trade Key Terms Glossary PDF Climate Change 101 Center for Climate and Energy Solutions January 2011 Archived from the original PDF on 2017 10 05 Retrieved 27 October 2014 Allowance Trading U S Environment Protection Agency Archived from the original on November 9 2014 Retrieved Oct 21 2014 Judson Jaffe Matthew Ranson Robert N Stavins 2009 Linking Tradable Permit Systems A Key Element of Emerging International Climate Policy Architecture PDF Ecology Law Quarterly 36 789 Archived from the original PDF on 2010 02 02 Retrieved 2010 08 25 Tietenberg Tom 2003 The Tradable Permits Approach to Protecting the Commons Lessons for Climate Change Oxford Review of Economic Policy 19 3 400 419 doi 10 1093 oxrep 19 3 400 Stavins Robert N November 2001 Experience with Market Based Environmental Policy Instruments PDF Discussion Paper 01 58 Washington D C Resources for the Future Archived from the original PDF on 2011 05 01 Retrieved 2010 08 25 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Teeter Preston Sandberg Jorgen 2016 Constraining or Enabling Green Capability Development How Policy Uncertainty Affects Organizational Responses to Flexible Environmental Regulations PDF British Journal of Management 28 4 649 665 doi 10 1111 1467 8551 12188 S2CID 157986703 Archived PDF from the original on 2020 05 06 Retrieved 2020 06 06 a b Cap and Trade 101 Archived 2012 04 24 at the Wayback Machine Center for American Progress January 16 2008 a b Boswall J and Lee R 2002 Economics ethics and the environment London Cavendish pp 62 66 Emissions trading schemes around the world Archived 2020 01 10 at the Wayback Machine Parliament of Australia 2013 Cap and Trade 101 United States Environmental Protection Agency Archived from the original on 5 August 2015 Retrieved 27 October 2014 O Sullivan Arthur and Steven M Sheffrin Economics Principles in Action Upper Saddle River New Jersey 2003 ISBN 0 13 063085 3 How cap and trade works Environmental Defense Fund Archived from the original on 26 November 2019 Retrieved 27 October 2014 USEPA s Clean Air Markets web site US EPA Archived from the original on 2010 07 24 Retrieved 2009 11 03 Burton Ellison and William Sanjour 1967 An Economic Analysis of the Control of Sulphur Oxides Air Pollution DHEW Program Analysis Report No 1967 69 Washington D C Ernst and Ernst Burton Ellison and William Sanjour 1968 A Cost Effectiveness Study of Particulate and SOx Emission Control in the New York Metropolitan Area NTIS PB 227 121 1 Contract Number PH 86 68 37 Washington D C Ernst and Ernst Burton Ellison and William Sanjour 1969 A Cost Effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the Greater Kansas City Area NTIS PB 227 116 1 Washington D C Ernst and Ernst Burton Ellison and William Sanjour 1969 A Cost effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the National Capital Area NAPCA Contract No PH 86 68 37 NTIS PB227110 Washington D C Ernst and Ernst Burton Ellison and William Sanjour 1970 Applications of Cost Effectiveness Analysis to Air Pollution Control DHEW Contract No CPA 22 69 17 Washington D C Ernst and Ernst Burton E S Sanjour William 1970 A Simulation Approach to Air Pollution Abatement Program Planning Socio Economic Planning Sciences 4 147 150 doi 10 1016 0038 0121 70 90036 4 Burton Ellison S Edward H Pechan III and William Sanjour 1973 A Survey of Air Pollution Control Models Rolf A Deininger ed Ann Arbor Ann Arbor Science Publishers Burton Ellison S Edward H Pechan III Sanjour William 1973 Solving the Air Pollution Control Puzzle Environmental Science and Technology 7 5 412 5 Bibcode 1973EnST 7 412B doi 10 1021 es60077a011 PMID 22283532 U S Environmental Protection Agency 1972 The Economics of Clean Air Annual Report of the Environmental Protection Agency to the Congress of the United States Washington D C U S Government Printing Office Voss Jan Peter 2007 Innovation processes in governance the development of emissions trading as a new policy instrument Science and Public Policy 34 5 329 343 doi 10 3152 030234207x228584 Coase Ronald H 1960 The Problem of Social Cost Journal of Law and Economics 3 1 1 44 doi 10 1086 466560 S2CID 222331226 Crocker T D 1966 The Structuring of Atmospheric Pollution Control Systems The Economics of Air Pollution H Wolozin New York W W Norton amp Co 61 86 Dales John H 1968 Land Water and Ownership The Canadian Journal of Economics 1 4 791 804 doi 10 2307 133706 JSTOR 133706 a b c Montgomery W D December 1972 Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs Journal of Economic Theory 5 3 395 418 doi 10 1016 0022 0531 72 90049 X Gillenwater Michael Seres Stephen March 2011 The Clean Development Mechanism A Review of the First International Offset Program PDF Pew Center on Global Climate Change p 6 Archived from the original PDF on 31 August 2016 Retrieved 26 November 2016 Coniff Richard Aug 2009 The Political History of Cap and Trade Archived 2010 11 13 at the Wayback Machine Smithsonian Magazine Retrieved 1 13 2011 Grimeaud D An overview of the policy and legal aspects of the international climate change regime 2001 9 2 Environmental Liability 39 a b c Goldemberg J et al 1996 Introduction scope of the assessment In J P Bruce et al eds Climate Change 1995 Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Cambridge University Press Cambridge U K and New York N Y U S A p 29 ISBN 978 0 521 56854 8 Tietenberg Tom 2003 The Tradable Permits Approach to Protecting the Commons Lessons for Climate Change Oxford Review of Economic Policy 19 3 400 419 doi 10 1093 oxrep 19 3 400 David M Driesen Capping Carbon Environmental Law 40 1 1 55 Setting the cap properly matters more to environmental protection than the decision to allow or not allow trades Goldemberg et al 1996 p 29 Goldemburg et al 1996 pp 29 37 Goldemburg et al 1996 p 30 IPCC 2007 Glossary A D In B Metz et al eds Annex I Glossary Climate Change 2007 Mitigation Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Print version Cambridge University Press Cambridge U K and New York N Y U S A This version IPCC website Archived from the original on 3 May 2010 Retrieved 25 August 2010 Barker T et al 2007 Executive Summary In B Metz et al eds Mitigation from a cross sectoral perspective Climate Change 2007 Mitigation Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Print version Cambridge University Press Cambridge U K and New York N Y U S A This version IPCC website Archived from the original on 31 March 2010 Retrieved 6 May 2010 Carbon Trust March 2009 Memorandum submitted by The Carbon Trust ET19 The role of carbon markets in preventing dangerous climate change Minutes of Evidence Tuesday 21 April 2009 UK Parliament House of Commons Environmental Audit Select Committee The fourth report of the 2009 10 session Retrieved 30 April 2010 a b c d e f Garnaut Ross 2008 Releasing permits into the market The Garnaut Climate Change Review Cambridge University Press ISBN 978 0 521 74444 7 Retrieved 28 April 2010 Neuhoff K 22 February 2009 Memorandum submitted by Karsten Neuhoff Assistant Director Electric Policy Research Group University of Cambridge The role of carbon markets in preventing dangerous climate change Written evidence UK Parliament House of Commons Environmental Audit Select Committee The fourth report of the 2009 10 session Retrieved 1 May 2010 Newbery D 26 February 2009 Memorandum submitted by David Newbery Research Director Electric Policy Research Group University of Cambridge The role of carbon markets in preventing dangerous climate change Written evidence UK Parliament House of Commons Environmental Audit Select Committee The fourth report of the 2009 10 session Retrieved 30 April 2010 Grubb M et al 3 August 2009 Climate Policy and Industrial Competitiveness Ten Insights from Europe on the EU Emissions Trading System Climate Strategies 5 Archived from the original on 6 February 2010 Retrieved 14 April 2010 Gupta S et al 2007 Section 13 2 1 3 Tradable permits in B Metz et al eds Chapter 13 Policies instruments and co operative arrangements Climate Change 2007 Mitigation Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Cambridge University Press Cambridge U K and New York N Y U S A retrieved 10 July 2010 Fisher B S et al 1996 An Economic Assessment of Policy Instruments for Combating Climate Change In J P Bruce et al eds Climate Change 1995 Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Cambridge University Press Cambridge U K and New York N Y U S A p 417 ISBN 978 0 521 56854 8 Goulder Lawrence H Pizer William A 2006 The Economics of Climate Change PDF DP 06 06 Resources for the Future Archived PDF from the original on 2006 10 26 Fischer C Fox A 2007 Output based allocation of emissions permits for mitigating tax and trade interactions PDF Land Economics 83 4 575 599 doi 10 3368 le 83 4 575 S2CID 55649597 Archived PDF from the original on 2004 12 17 Retrieved 10 August 2010 However there often are important trade offs in terms of efficiency because OBA implicitly subsidizes production unlike conventional lump sum allocation mechanisms like grandfathering a b Hepburn C 2006 Regulating by prices quantities or both an update and an overview PDF Oxford Review of Economic Policy 22 2 226 247 doi 10 1093 oxrep grj014 Retrieved 30 August 2009 Stavins Robert N 2008 Addressing climate change with a comprehensive US cap and trade system PDF Oxford Review of Economic Policy 24 2 24 298 321 doi 10 1093 oxrep grn017 hdl 10419 53231 Archived PDF from the original on 2020 05 10 Kerr Suzi Cramton Peter 1998 Tradable Carbon Permit Auctions How and Why to Auction Not Grandfather PDF Discussion Paper Dp 98 34 Resources For the Future Archived PDF from the original on 2003 09 26 An auction is preferred to grandfathering giving companies permits based on historical output or emissions because it allows reduced tax distortions provides more flexibility in distribution of costs provides greater incentives for innovation and reduces the need for politically contentious arguments over the allocation of rents Hepburn Cameron J Neuhoff Karsten Grubb Michael Matthes Felix Tse Max 2006 Auctioning of EU ETS Phase II allowances why and how PDF Climate Policy 6 1 137 160 doi 10 3763 cpol 2006 0608 Retrieved 19 May 2010 Toth F L et al 2001 10 4 5 Who Should Pay for the Response Mitigation by Countries and Sectors Equity and Cost effectiveness Considerations In book chapter Decision making Frameworks In Climate Change 2001 Mitigation Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change B Metz et al Eds Print version Cambridge University Press Cambridge UK and New York N Y U S A This version GRID Arendal website Archived from the original on 2009 08 05 Retrieved 2010 01 10 Helm D 2005 Economic Instruments and Environmental Policy The Economic and Social Review 36 3 4 Archived from the original on 2011 05 01 Retrieved 2010 04 26 Bashmakov I et al 2001 6 3 1 International Emissions Trading In book chapter 6 Policies Measures and Instruments In Climate Change 2001 Mitigation Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change B Metz et al Eds Print version Cambridge University Press Cambridge UK and New York N Y U S A This version GRID Arendal website Archived from the original on 2009 08 05 Retrieved 2010 04 26 Halsnaes K et al 2007 2 6 5 Economic efficiency and eventual trade offs with equity In book chapter Framing issues In Climate Change 2007 Mitigation Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change B Metz et al Eds Cambridge University Press Cambridge UK and New York N Y U S A Archived from the original on May 2 2010 Retrieved 2010 04 26 Bashmakov I et al 2001 6 2 2 3 Tradable Permits In book chapter 6 Policies Measures and Instruments In B Metz et al eds Climate Change 2001 Mitigation Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Print version Cambridge University Press Cambridge UK and New York N Y U S A This version GRID Arendal website Archived from the original on 2009 08 05 Retrieved 2010 04 26 IMF March 2008 Fiscal Implications of Climate Change PDF International Monetary Fund Fiscal Affairs Department Archived PDF from the original on 2010 08 06 Retrieved 2010 04 26 Halsnaes K et al 2007 2 4 Cost and benefit concepts including private and social cost perspectives and relationships to other decision making frameworks In B Metz et al eds Framing issues Climate Change 2007 Mitigation Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Cambridge University Press Cambridge UK and New York N Y U S A p 6 Archived from the original on May 2 2010 Retrieved 2010 04 26 eschwass 2019 01 02 State and Provincial Efforts to Put a Price on Greenhouse Gas Emissions with Implications for Energy Efficiency ACEEE Archived from the original on 2019 01 09 Retrieved 2019 01 08 Fisher B S et al 1996 An Economic Assessment of Policy Instruments for Combating Climate Change In J P Bruce et al eds Climate Change 1995 Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change This version Printed by Cambridge University Press Cambridge UK and New York N Y U S A PDF version IPCC website ISBN 978 0 521 56854 8 a b Nordhaus William 2007 To Tax or Not to Tax Alternative Approaches to Slowing Global Warming PDF Oxford University Press Archived from the original PDF on 2011 07 25 Retrieved 2010 04 28 Key points Update Paper 6 Carbon pricing and reducing Australia s emissions Garnaut Climate Change Review 17 March 2011 Archived from the original on 21 April 2013 Retrieved 16 July 2013 a b Stavins Robert N 1998 What Can We Learn from the Grand Policy Experiment Lessons from SO2 Allowance Trading The Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 American Economic Association 12 3 69 88 doi 10 1257 jep 12 3 69 JSTOR 2647033 Archived from the original on 2015 09 21 Retrieved 2021 11 20 Bryner Gary C Blue Skies Green Politics the Clean Air Act of 1990 Washington D C Congressional Quarterly Inc 1951 Cox Stan 2013 Any way you slice it The past present and future of rationing Archived 2019 08 15 at the Wayback Machine New Press Books Hall JV and Walton AL A case study in pollution markets dismal science US Dismal reality 1996 XIV Contemporary Economic Policy 67 MRV amp Enforcement International Carbon Action Partnership ICAP Archived from the original on 27 October 2014 Retrieved 26 Oct 2014 Tiwari Gopal Nath Agrawal Basant 2010 Building integrated photovoltaic thermal systems for sustainable developments Cambridge Royal Society of Chemistry ISBN 978 1 84973 090 7 Ramseur Jonathan L April 16 2010 Estimating Offset Supply in a Cap and Trade Program PDF Congressional Research Service 1 archived from the original PDF on September 27 2013 retrieved February 15 2011 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Map Pollution hotspots Archived 2010 11 16 at the Wayback Machine BBC map of areas that suffer from intense local pollution BBC News 2004 12 13 Retrieved 2009 10 19 Chicago Climate Exchange prices Chicagoclimatex com 2009 08 04 Archived from the original on 2009 11 05 Retrieved 2009 11 03 Weitzman M L October 1974 Prices vs Quantities Review of Economic Studies 41 4 477 491 CiteSeerX 10 1 1 1031 4819 doi 10 2307 2296698 JSTOR 2296698 Philibert Cedric October 2006 Certainty versus ambition economic efficiency in mitigating climate change PDF International Energy Agency Working Paper Series Paris International Energy Agency OECD LTO 2006 03 Archived from the original PDF on 2009 03 25 Retrieved 2010 01 24 Jacoby D H Ellerman A D March 2004 The safety valve and climate policy PDF Energy Policy 32 4 481 49 doi 10 1016 S0301 4215 03 00150 2 hdl 1721 1 3561 Archived PDF from the original on 2007 06 28 Retrieved 2019 09 23 World Development Report 2010 Development and Climate Change PDF World Bank 2010 Archived PDF from the original on 2016 03 04 Retrieved 2010 04 06 Chomitz Kenneth M 1999 Evaluating Carbon Offsets from Forestry and Energy Projects How Do They Compare Policy Research Working Paper Series 2357 World Bank SSRN 630729 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help a b c Rosen Harvey S Gayer Ted 2008 Public Finance New York McGraw Hill Irwin pp 90 94 ISBN 978 0 07 351128 3 a b Burney Nelson E 2010 Carbon Tax and Cap and trade Tools Market based Approaches for Controlling Greenhouse Gases New York Nova Science Publishers Inc ISBN 9781608761371 Durning Alan July 2009 carBon tax vS cap and trade PDF Cap and Trade 101 a Federal Climate Policy Primer 28 Archived from the original PDF on 7 July 2014 Retrieved 27 October 2014 Calel Raphael The Language of Climate Change Policy Archived 2021 02 24 at the Wayback Machine 2010 Yujie Lu Xinyuan Zhu Qingbin Cui 2012 Effectiveness and equity implications of carbon policies in the United States construction industry Building and Environment Elsevier Ltd 49 259 269 doi 10 1016 j buildenv 2011 10 002 Acid Rain Program 2007 Progress Report Clean Air Markets Air amp Radiation US EPA January 2009 Archived from the original on 2011 05 01 Retrieved 2011 07 25 Carlson Curtis Burtraw Dallas Cropper Maureen Palmer Karen L 2000 Sulfur dioxide control by electric utilities What are the gains from trade PDF Journal of Political Economy 108 6 1292 1326 doi 10 1086 317681 S2CID 3037737 Cross State Air Pollution Rule CSAPR United States Environment Protection Agency 2011 07 09 Archived from the original on 2011 07 11 Retrieved 2011 07 10 a b Cap and Trade United States Environmental Protection Agency Archived from the original on 8 November 2014 Retrieved 27 October 2014 NOx Budget Trading Program Archived 2017 04 26 at the Wayback Machine Environmental Protection Agency Retrieved 25 April 2017 Ozone Fact Sheet Archived 2017 02 22 at the Wayback Machine Environmental Protection Agency Retrieved 25 April 2017 a b Deschenes Olivier Greenstone Michael Shapiro Joseph 2017 Defensive Investments and the Demand for Air Quality Evidence from the NOx Budget Program American Economic Review 107 10 2958 2989 doi 10 1257 aer 20131002 ISSN 0002 8282 a b EPA OAR ORIA IED US 18 August 2014 Volatile Organic Compounds Impact on Indoor Air Quality US EPA US EPA Archived from the original on 2017 11 22 Retrieved 2017 11 30 a href Template Cite web html title Template Cite web cite web a CS1 maint multiple names authors list link Volatile Organic Compounds VOCs in Commonly Used Products www health ny gov Archived from the original on 2018 01 11 Retrieved 2017 11 30 a b Synthesis NAWQA VOC National Chapter 1 Major Findings and Conclusions water usgs gov Archived from the original on 2017 05 18 Retrieved 2017 11 30 a b Volatile Organic Compounds VOCs in Your Home EH Minnesota Department of Health www health state mn us Archived from the original on 2017 12 01 Retrieved 2017 11 30 Bartson Andrew March 29 2006 China Considers Tradable Pollution Rights Permits The Wall Street Journal Archived from the original on December 14 2017 Retrieved January 27 2019 a b Tu Zhengge Shen Renjun 2014 Can China s Industrial SO2 Emissions Trading Pilot Scheme Reduce Pollution Abatement Costs Sustainability 6 11 7621 7645 doi 10 3390 su6117621 S2CID 17764664 a b China considers national pollution permit trading Under2 Coalition 2014 01 14 Archived from the original on 2018 09 08 Retrieved 2018 09 08 Cui Jingbo Wang Chunhua Zhang Junjie Zheng Yang 2021 12 28 The effectiveness of China s regional carbon market pilots in reducing firm emissions Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 118 52 Bibcode 2021PNAS 11809912C doi 10 1073 pnas 2109912118 ISSN 0027 8424 PMC 8719898 PMID 34930839 Validate User academic oup com doi 10 1093 cje bet028 Retrieved 2022 04 25 Capoor Karan Ambrosi May 2008 State and Trends of the Carbon Market 2008 World Bank Group Linking Emissions Trading Systems A Summary of Current Research Archived 2021 11 20 at the Wayback Machine ICAP 2015 Burtraw D Palmer K L Munnings C Weber P amp Woerman M 2013 Linking by Degrees Incremental Alignment of Cap and Trade Markets SSRN Electronic Journal doi 10 2139 ssrn 2249955 Flachsland C Marschinski R amp Edenhofer O 2009 To link or not to link benefits and disadvantages of linking cap and trade systems Climate Policy 9 4 358 372 doi 10 3763 cpol 2009 0626 Ranson M amp Stavins R 2013 Linkage of Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading Systems Learning from Experience Discussion Paper Resources For The Future No 42 The House of Commons Energy and Climate Committee 2015 Linking emissions trading systems London Quebec Ontario Manitoba sign agreement to link cap and trade systems Archived 2016 06 29 at the Wayback Machine CBC News 7 December 2015 California Ontario Quebec Agreement on the Harmonization and Integration of their Cap and Trade Programs PDF California Air Resources Board Government of California Archived PDF from the original on 14 November 2017 Retrieved 14 November 2017 Lohmann Larry 2006 12 05 A licence to carry on polluting New Scientist 2580 Archived from the original on 2009 01 30 Retrieved 2010 07 17 Alt URL Archived 2011 05 01 at the Wayback Machine Stone Chad Shaw Hannah 2009 07 10 Senate can strengthen climate legislation by reducing corporate welfare and boosting true consumer relief PDF Centre for Budget and Policy Priorities Archived PDF from the original on 2009 10 24 Retrieved 2010 01 27 Rising gas prices are fueling opposition to Transportation Climate Initiative 17 November 2021 World Bank 2021 May 25 State and trends of carbon pricing 2021 https openknowledge worldbank org handle 10986 35620Further reading EditLin Feng Jason Buhi 2009 Emissions Trading Across China Incorporating Hong Kong and Macau into an Urgently Needed Air Pollution Control Regime Under One Country Two Systems Florida State University Journal of Transnational Law amp Policy Vol 19 2009 SSRN 1441395 a href Template Cite journal html title Template Cite journal cite journal a Cite journal requires journal help Gilbertson T O Reyes 1 November 2009 Carbon Trading how it works and why it fails Dag Hammarskjold Foundation Archived from the original on 25 August 2017 Retrieved 2010 05 14 Chichilnisky C Heal G eds 2000 Environmental Markets Equity and Efficiency Columbia University Press Archived from the original on 2010 04 17 Retrieved 2010 05 12 Norregaard J V Reppelin Hill 1 January 2000 Taxes and Tradable Permits as Instruments for Controlling Pollution Theory and Practice Working Paper No 00 13 International Monetary Fund Retrieved 2010 05 12 Susanne Schennach 2000 The Economics of Pollution Permit Banking in the Context of Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments Journal of Environmental Economics and Management Elsevier 40 3 189 210 doi 10 1006 jeem 1999 1122 hdl 1721 1 45081 External links EditDr Daniel Fine of the New Mexico Center for Energy Policy on Cap and Trade Emissions Trading and CDM International Energy Agency Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading and Project based Mechanisms Organisation for Economic Co operation and Development US EPA s Acid Rain Program IllinoisEmissions Reduction Market System The Making of a Market Minded Environmentalist article by Fred Krupp in Strategy Business registration required that articulates some of the reasoning and history behind emissions trading in California Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Emissions trading amp oldid 1140362228, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.