fbpx
Wikipedia

Common-pool resource

In economics, a common-pool resource (CPR) is a type of good consisting of a natural or human-made resource system (e.g. an irrigation system or fishing grounds), whose size or characteristics makes it costly, but not impossible, to exclude potential beneficiaries from obtaining benefits from its use. Unlike pure public goods, common pool resources face problems of congestion or overuse, because they are subtractable. A common-pool resource typically consists of a core resource (e.g. water or fish), which defines the stock variable, while providing a limited quantity of extractable fringe units, which defines the flow variable. While the core resource is to be protected or nurtured in order to allow for its continuous exploitation, the fringe units can be harvested or consumed.[1]

Examples of a Common-Pool Resource edit

Common-pool goods are typically regulated and nurtured in order to prevent demand from overwhelming supply and allow for their continued exploitation. Examples of common-pool resources include forests, man-made irrigation systems, fishing grounds, and groundwater basins. For instance, fishermen have an incentive to harvest as many fish as possible because if they do not, someone else will—so without management and regulation, fish stocks soon become depleted. And while a river might supply many cities with drinking water, manufacturing plants might be tempted to pollute the river if they were not prohibited from doing so by law because someone else would bear the costs. In California, where there is a huge demand for surface water but supplies are limited, common pool problems are exacerbated because the state does not manage groundwater basins at the state level.[2] During the 2012-2016 drought, farmers with senior water rights dating back to the 19th century could use as much water as they wanted, while cities and towns had to make drastic cutbacks to water use.[3]

In James Bay, Quebec, the beaver was an important species for food and later commerce when the fur trade started in 1670. Amerindian groups in the area have traditionally used resources communally and have a heritage of customary laws to regulate hunting. However, in the 1920s the railroads caused a large influx of non-native trappers who took advantage of the high fur prices and the indigenous people losing control of their territories. Both non-native and native trappers contributed to the decline of the beaver population, prompting conservation laws to be enacted after 1930 and outsiders being banned from trapping in James Bay. Eventually, Amerindian communities and family territories were legally recognized, and customary laws became enforceable. This restoration of local control allowed for the beaver population to recover.[4]

Since 1947, the Maine lobster catch has been remarkably stable despite predictions of resource collapse. The state government has regulations in place but does not limit the number of licenses. The exclusion to this CPR is done through a system of traditional fishing rights which makes it so that one needs to be accepted by the community to be able to go lobster fishing. Those in a community are restricted to fishing in the territory held by that community. This is enforced by surreptitious violence towards interlopers. Fishermen in these exclusive territories catch significantly more and larger lobsters with less effort than those in areas where territories overlap.[4]

In the New York Bight region, a cooperative of trawl fishermen that specializes in harvesting whiting limits entry into the local fishery and establishes catch quotas among members. These quotas are based on regional market sales estimations and attempt to encourage initiative while discouraging “free-riding.” They limit entry to the whiting grounds and markets through a closed membership policy and by controlling the dock space. Due to these methods, they have access to the best whiting grounds, dominate the market during winter, and can maintain relatively high prices through supply management. The fishermen consider this type of self-regulation both flexible and effective in maintaining sustainable use.[4]

Common property systems edit

A common property rights regime system (not to be confused with a common-pool resource) is a particular social arrangement regulating the preservation, maintenance, and consumption of a common-pool resource. The use of the term "common property resource" to designate a type of good has been criticized, because common-pool resources are not necessarily governed by common property protocols. Examples of common-pool resources include irrigation systems, fishing grounds, pastures, forests, water or the atmosphere. A pasture, for instance, allows for a certain amount of grazing to occur each year without the core resource being harmed. In the case of excessive grazing, however, the pasture may become more prone to erosion and eventually yield less benefit to its users. Because the core resources are vulnerable, common-pool resources are generally subject to problems of congestion, overuse, pollution, and potential destruction unless harvesting or use limits are devised and enforced.[5]

Resource systems like pastoral areas, fishing grounds, forest areas are storage variables.[6] Under favorable conditions, they can maximize the flow without harming the total storage volume and the entire resource system. Different from the resource system, the resource unit is the amount that an individual occupies or uses from the resource system, such as the total amount of fish caught in a fishing ground, the amount of feed consumed by livestock in pastoral areas.[7] A resource system allows multiple people or enterprise to produce at the same time, and the process of using common-pool resources can be performed simultaneously by multiple occupants. However, the resource unit cannot be used by multiple people or enterprises at the same time.[6]

Management edit

The use of many common-pool resources, if managed carefully, can be extended because the resource system forms a negative feedback loop, where the stock variable continually regenerates the fringe variable as long as the stock variable is not compromised, providing an optimum amount of consumption. However, consumption exceeding the fringe value reduces the stock variable, which in turn decreases the flow variable. If the stock variable is allowed to regenerate then the fringe and flow variables may also recover to initial levels, but in many cases the loss is irreparable.[5]

Ownership edit

Common-pool resources may be owned by national, regional or local governments as public goods, by communal groups as common property resources, or by private individuals or corporations as private goods. When they are owned by no one, they are used as open access resources. Having observed a number of common pool resources throughout the world, Elinor Ostrom noticed that a number of them are governed by common property protocols — arrangements different from private property or state administration — based on self-management by a local community. Her observations contradict claims that common-pool resources must be privatized or else face destruction in the long run due to collective action problems leading to the overuse of the core resource[5] (see also Tragedy of the commons).

Definition matrix edit

Excludable Non-excludable
Rivalrous Private goods
eg. food, clothing, parking spaces
Common-pool resources
eg. fish stocks, timber
Non-rivalrous Club goods
eg. cinemas, software, private parks
Public goods
eg. free-to-air television, air, national defense

Common property protocols edit

Common property systems of management arise when users acting independently threaten the total net benefit from common-pool resource. In order to maintain the resources, protocols coordinate strategies to maintain the resource as a common property instead of dividing it up into parcels of private property. Common property systems typically protect the core resource and allocate the fringe resources through complex community norms of consensus decision-making.[8] Common resource management has to face the difficult task of devising rules that limit the amount, timing, and technology used to withdraw various resource units from the resource system. Setting the limits too high would lead to overuse and eventually to the destruction of the core resource while setting the limits too low would unnecessarily reduce the benefits obtained by the users.

In common property systems, access to the resource is not free and common-pool resources are not public goods. While there is relatively free but monitored access to the resource system for community members, there are mechanisms in place which allow the community to exclude outsiders from using its resource. Thus, in a common property state, a common-pool resource appears as a private good to an outsider and as a common good to an insider of the community. The resource units withdrawn from the system are typically owned individually by the appropriators. A common property good is rivaled in consumption.

Analysing the design of long-enduring CPR institutions, Elinor Ostrom identified eight design principles which are prerequisites for a stable CPR arrangement:[9]

  1. Clearly defined boundaries
  2. Congruence between appropriation and provision rules and local conditions
  3. Collective-choice arrangements allowing for the participation of most of the appropriators in the decision making process
  4. Effective monitoring by monitors who are part of or accountable to the appropriators
  5. Graduated sanctions for appropriators who do not respect community rules
  6. Conflict-resolution mechanisms which are cheap and easy to access
  7. Minimal recognition of rights to organize (e.g., by the government)
  8. In case of larger CPRs: Organisation in the form of multiple layers of nested enterprises, with small, local CPRs at their bases.

Common property systems typically function at a local level to prevent the overexploitation of a resource system from which fringe units can be extracted. In some cases, government regulations combined with tradable environmental allowances (TEAs) are used successfully to prevent excessive pollution, whereas in other cases — especially in the absence of a unique government being able to set limits and monitor economic activities — excessive use or pollution continue.

Adaptive governance edit

The management of common-pool resources is highly dependent upon the type of resource involved. An effective strategy at one location, or of one particular resource, may not be necessarily appropriate for another. In The Challenge of Common-Pool Resources, Ostrom makes the case for adaptive governance as a method for the management of common-pool resources. Adaptive governance is suited to dealing with problems that are complex, uncertain and fragmented,[10] as is the management of common-pool resources. Ostrom outlines five basic protocol requirements for achieving adaptive governance.[11] These include:

  • Achieving accurate and relevant information, by focusing on the creation and use of timely scientific knowledge on the part of both the managers and the users of the resource
  • Dealing with conflict, acknowledging the fact that conflicts will occur, and having systems in place to discover and resolve them as quickly as possible
  • Enhancing rule compliance, through creating responsibility for the users of a resource to monitor usage
  • Providing infrastructure, that is flexible over time, both to aid internal operations and create links to other resources
  • Encouraging adaption and change to address errors and cope with new developments

Influential factors in the management of common-pool resources edit

A new proposal of the management of CPR is to develop autonomous organizations that are not completely privatized and controlled by government power, which led and supervised by the community to manage common-pool resources in addition to directly through the government and the free market.[12] There are many factors that may affect the formation and development of these kinds of autonomous organizations.[6] Effectively identifying the influencing factors of the autonomous management system of CPRs increasing the feasibility of the system, and it is more conducive to the sustainable use of resources as well.[13]

In general, there are four variables that are very important for local common-pool resource management: (1) characteristics of the resource; (2) characteristics of the resource-dependent group; (3) institutional model of resource management; (4) the relationship between groups, external forces, and authorities.[6]

The government, market and interest groups are all considered as external forces that have an impact on CPR management system. Changes in market demand for CPR, in particular, technological innovation increases productivity and lowers costs, which undermines the sustainability of the management system.[12] In order to develop more resources, resource owners may seek to change the ownership of resources in the form of cooperation with the government, privatize CPR or even cancel the protection of CPR ownership by regulations. Such institutional changes prevent the implementation of policies that are beneficial to the majority of the population, while the power of the government and bureaucracy can be abused.[6]

The community is responsible for supervising and administering CPR under an autonomous management system, the characteristics of a community can affect how CPR is managed.[7] (1) the size of the community. The level of cooperation decreases as the number of community members grows; (2) Allocation mechanism for CPR. Encouraging the exploitation of the least used resources and reducing the exploitation of the most used resources will effectively increase the rate of resource supply and reduce the rate of resource consumption and individual demand. (3) Group identity. When people in a community have a strong sense of group identity, it helps to manage CPR within the community.[14]

Experimental Studies on Common Pool Resource Games edit

Common Pool Resource (CPR) games have been a focal point in experimental research, providing insights into the dynamics and dilemmas associated with communal resource management. A foundational work introduced a conceptual framework that elucidates the strategic content of CPR dilemmas, demonstrating how theoretical constructs, such as the Prisoner's Dilemma and coordination games, apply to these behavioral challenges.[15] Further, field experiments involving specific ecological features of CPRs, such as water irrigation, forestry, and fisheries, have revealed the impact of various resource-specific dynamics on collective action and resource management.[16] Additionally, a study explored the external validity of CPR laboratory experiments within the context of artisanal benthic fisheries in Chile, revealing a correlation between cooperative behaviors exhibited in laboratory settings and those in real-world co-managed and open-access fisheries.[17] These studies collectively underscore the complexity of CPR dilemmas and highlight the nuanced interplay between individual strategies, collective action, and resource sustainability, providing a multifaceted understanding of cooperation and norm internalization in the management of communal resources.

Open access resources edit

In economics, open access resources are, for the most part, rivalrous, non-excludable goods. This makes them similar to common goods during times of prosperity. Unlike many common goods, open access goods require little oversight or may be difficult to restrict access.[5] However, as these resources are first come, first served, they may be affected by the phenomenon of the tragedy of the commons.[18] Two possibilities may follow: a common property or an open access system.

However, in a different setting, such as fishing, there will be drastically different consequences. Since fish are an open access resource, it is relatively simple to fish and profit. If fishing becomes profitable, there will be more fishers and fewer fish. Fewer fish lead to higher prices which will lead again to more fishers, as well as lower reproduction of fish. This is a negative externality and an example of problems that arise with open access goods.[19]

See also edit

References edit

Citations edit

  1. ^ Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 0-521-40599-8.
  2. ^ "Sustainable Groundwater Management Act (SGMA)".
  3. ^ https://water.ca.gov/-/media/DWR-Website/Web-Pages/Water-Basics/Drought/Files/Publications-And-Reports/CNRA-Drought-Report-final-March-2021.pdf [bare URL PDF]
  4. ^ a b c Berkes, F.; Feeny, D.; McCay, B. J.; Acheson, J. M. (July 1989). "The benefits of the commons". Nature. 340 (6229): 91–93. Bibcode:1989Natur.340...91B. doi:10.1038/340091a0. ISSN 0028-0836. S2CID 4310769.
  5. ^ a b c d Environmental Economics Dictionary (2008-04-30). "Open Access Resource definition | Environmental Economics Dictionary". Economics.socialsciencedictionary.com. Archived from the original on 2013-07-03. Retrieved 2014-01-19.
  6. ^ a b c d e Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (Canto Classics). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/CBO9781316423936
  7. ^ a b Ostrom, Elinor (1977). Public Goods and Public Choices. Alternatives for Delivering Public Services. ISBN 9780429047978.
  8. ^ Mandal, B.N. (2009). Global Encyclopaedia of Welfare Economics. Global Vision Publishing House. ISBN 978-8182202597.
  9. ^ Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press. pp. 90, 91–102. [page needed]
  10. ^ "UNU-IAS. (2011). "Adaptive Governance". United Nations University". Ias.unu.edu. 2006-08-18. Archived from the original on 2012-08-02. Retrieved 2014-01-19.
  11. ^ Ostrom, Elinor. (2010). "The Challenge of common-pool resources". In: Environment: Science and Policy for Sustainable Development, 50:4, 8-21. [1]
  12. ^ a b Ostrom, Elinor; Gardner, Roy; Walker, James; Walker, James M.; Walker, Jimmy (1994). Rules, Games, and Common-pool Resources. University of Michigan Press. ISBN 978-0-472-06546-2.
  13. ^ Castilla-Rho J.C., Holley C., Castilla J.C. (2020) Groundwater as a Common Pool Resource: Modelling, Management and the Complicity Ethic in a Non-collective World. In: Valera L., Castilla J. (eds) Global Changes. Ethics of Science and Technology Assessment, vol 46. Springer, Cham.
  14. ^ Ostrom, Elinor (2008-07-01). "The Challenge of Common-Pool Resources". Environment: Science and Policy for Sustainable Development. 50 (4): 8–21. Bibcode:2008ESPSD..50d...8O. doi:10.3200/ENVT.50.4.8-21. ISSN 0013-9157. S2CID 154884533.
  15. ^ Gardner, R., Ostrom, E., & Walker, J. M. (1990). The Nature of Common-Pool Resource Problems. DOI
  16. ^ Cárdenas, J., Janssen, M., & Bousquet, F. (2013). Dynamics of rules and resources: three new field experiments on water, forests and fisheries. DOI
  17. ^ Gelcich, S., Guzman, R., Rodríguez-Sickert, C., Castilla, J. C., & Cárdenas, J. C. (2013). Exploring external validity of common pool resource experiments: insights from artisanal benthic fisheries in Chile. Ecology and Society, 18(3).
  18. ^ Tietenberg, T. (20 September 2006). "Open access resources". Encyclopedia of Earth. Retrieved 4 July 2017.
  19. ^ Mackenzie, John (2014). . Archived from the original (lecture notes) on 3 November 2017. Retrieved 4 July 2017.

Bibliography edit

  • Araral, Eduardo. (2014). Ostrom, Hardin and the Commons. A Critical Appreciation and Revisionist View. Env Science and Policy. Volume 36, Pages 1–92 (February 2014)
  • Acheson, James, M. (1988) The Lobster Gangs of Maine. ISBN 0-87451-451-7
  • Anderson, Terry L., Grewell, J. Bishop (2000) "Property Rights Solutions for the Global Commons: Bottom-Up or Top-Down?" In: Duke Environmental Law & Policy Forum, Vol. X, No. 2, Spring 2000. [2]
  • Copeland, Brian R.; M. Scott Taylor (2009). "Trade, Tragedy, and the Commons" (PDF). American Economic Review. 99 (3): 725–49. doi:10.1257/aer.99.3.725.
  • Baland, Jean-Marie and Jean-Philippe Platteau (1996) Halting Degradation of Natural Resources: Is There a Role for Rural Communities?
  • Daniels, Brigham (2007) "Emerging Commons and Tragic Institutions," Environmental Law, Vol. 37. [3]
  • Hess, C. and Ostrom, E. (2003), "Ideas, Artifacts, and Facilities: Information as a Common-Pool Resource", Law and Contemporary Problems 66, S. 111–146. [4]
  • Hess, C. and Ostrom, E. (2001), "Artifacts, Facilities, And Content: Information as a Common-pool Resource", Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis. [5]
  • Meinzen-Dick, Ruth, Esther Mwangi, Stephan Dohrn. 2006. Securing the Commons. CAPRi Policy Brief 4. Washington DC: IFPRI. [6]
  • Ostrom, Elinor (2003) "How Types of Goods and Property Rights Jointly Affect Collective Action", Journal of Theoretical Politics, Vol. 15, No. 3, 239-270 (2003).
  • Ostrom, Elinor (1990) "Governing the Commons. The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action". Cambridge University Press. ISBN 0-521-40599-8
  • Ostrom, Elinor, Roy Gardner, and James Walker (1994) Rules, Games, and Common-Pool Resources. University of Michigan Press. 1994. ISBN 978-0-472-06546-2
  • Rose, Carol M. (2000) "Expanding the Choices for the Global Commons: Comparing Newfangled Tradable allowance schemes to Old-Fashioned Common Property Regimes". In: Duke Environmental Law & Policy Forum, Vol. X, No. 2, Spring 2000. [7]
  • Saunders, Pammela Q. (2011) "A Sea Change Off the Coast of Maine: Common Pool Resources as Cultural Property". In: Emory Law Journal, Vol. 60, No. 6, June 2011. [8]
  • Thompson, Jr., Barton H. (2000) "Tragically Difficult: The Obstacles to Governing the Commons" Environmental Law 30:241.

External links edit

  • Digital Library of the Commons
  • Public vs. Private Goods

common, pool, resource, economics, common, pool, resource, type, good, consisting, natural, human, made, resource, system, irrigation, system, fishing, grounds, whose, size, characteristics, makes, costly, impossible, exclude, potential, beneficiaries, from, o. In economics a common pool resource CPR is a type of good consisting of a natural or human made resource system e g an irrigation system or fishing grounds whose size or characteristics makes it costly but not impossible to exclude potential beneficiaries from obtaining benefits from its use Unlike pure public goods common pool resources face problems of congestion or overuse because they are subtractable A common pool resource typically consists of a core resource e g water or fish which defines the stock variable while providing a limited quantity of extractable fringe units which defines the flow variable While the core resource is to be protected or nurtured in order to allow for its continuous exploitation the fringe units can be harvested or consumed 1 Contents 1 Examples of a Common Pool Resource 2 Common property systems 3 Management 4 Ownership 5 Definition matrix 6 Common property protocols 6 1 Adaptive governance 7 Influential factors in the management of common pool resources 8 Experimental Studies on Common Pool Resource Games 9 Open access resources 10 See also 11 References 11 1 Citations 11 2 Bibliography 12 External linksExamples of a Common Pool Resource editCommon pool goods are typically regulated and nurtured in order to prevent demand from overwhelming supply and allow for their continued exploitation Examples of common pool resources include forests man made irrigation systems fishing grounds and groundwater basins For instance fishermen have an incentive to harvest as many fish as possible because if they do not someone else will so without management and regulation fish stocks soon become depleted And while a river might supply many cities with drinking water manufacturing plants might be tempted to pollute the river if they were not prohibited from doing so by law because someone else would bear the costs In California where there is a huge demand for surface water but supplies are limited common pool problems are exacerbated because the state does not manage groundwater basins at the state level 2 During the 2012 2016 drought farmers with senior water rights dating back to the 19th century could use as much water as they wanted while cities and towns had to make drastic cutbacks to water use 3 In James Bay Quebec the beaver was an important species for food and later commerce when the fur trade started in 1670 Amerindian groups in the area have traditionally used resources communally and have a heritage of customary laws to regulate hunting However in the 1920s the railroads caused a large influx of non native trappers who took advantage of the high fur prices and the indigenous people losing control of their territories Both non native and native trappers contributed to the decline of the beaver population prompting conservation laws to be enacted after 1930 and outsiders being banned from trapping in James Bay Eventually Amerindian communities and family territories were legally recognized and customary laws became enforceable This restoration of local control allowed for the beaver population to recover 4 Since 1947 the Maine lobster catch has been remarkably stable despite predictions of resource collapse The state government has regulations in place but does not limit the number of licenses The exclusion to this CPR is done through a system of traditional fishing rights which makes it so that one needs to be accepted by the community to be able to go lobster fishing Those in a community are restricted to fishing in the territory held by that community This is enforced by surreptitious violence towards interlopers Fishermen in these exclusive territories catch significantly more and larger lobsters with less effort than those in areas where territories overlap 4 In the New York Bight region a cooperative of trawl fishermen that specializes in harvesting whiting limits entry into the local fishery and establishes catch quotas among members These quotas are based on regional market sales estimations and attempt to encourage initiative while discouraging free riding They limit entry to the whiting grounds and markets through a closed membership policy and by controlling the dock space Due to these methods they have access to the best whiting grounds dominate the market during winter and can maintain relatively high prices through supply management The fishermen consider this type of self regulation both flexible and effective in maintaining sustainable use 4 Common property systems editA common property rights regime system not to be confused with a common pool resource is a particular social arrangement regulating the preservation maintenance and consumption of a common pool resource The use of the term common property resource to designate a type of good has been criticized because common pool resources are not necessarily governed by common property protocols Examples of common pool resources include irrigation systems fishing grounds pastures forests water or the atmosphere A pasture for instance allows for a certain amount of grazing to occur each year without the core resource being harmed In the case of excessive grazing however the pasture may become more prone to erosion and eventually yield less benefit to its users Because the core resources are vulnerable common pool resources are generally subject to problems of congestion overuse pollution and potential destruction unless harvesting or use limits are devised and enforced 5 Resource systems like pastoral areas fishing grounds forest areas are storage variables 6 Under favorable conditions they can maximize the flow without harming the total storage volume and the entire resource system Different from the resource system the resource unit is the amount that an individual occupies or uses from the resource system such as the total amount of fish caught in a fishing ground the amount of feed consumed by livestock in pastoral areas 7 A resource system allows multiple people or enterprise to produce at the same time and the process of using common pool resources can be performed simultaneously by multiple occupants However the resource unit cannot be used by multiple people or enterprises at the same time 6 Management editThe use of many common pool resources if managed carefully can be extended because the resource system forms a negative feedback loop where the stock variable continually regenerates the fringe variable as long as the stock variable is not compromised providing an optimum amount of consumption However consumption exceeding the fringe value reduces the stock variable which in turn decreases the flow variable If the stock variable is allowed to regenerate then the fringe and flow variables may also recover to initial levels but in many cases the loss is irreparable 5 Ownership editCommon pool resources may be owned by national regional or local governments as public goods by communal groups as common property resources or by private individuals or corporations as private goods When they are owned by no one they are used as open access resources Having observed a number of common pool resources throughout the world Elinor Ostrom noticed that a number of them are governed by common property protocols arrangements different from private property or state administration based on self management by a local community Her observations contradict claims that common pool resources must be privatized or else face destruction in the long run due to collective action problems leading to the overuse of the core resource 5 see also Tragedy of the commons Definition matrix editMain article Goods Goods classified by exclusivity and competitiveness Excludable Non excludable Rivalrous Private goodseg food clothing parking spaces Common pool resources eg fish stocks timber Non rivalrous Club goodseg cinemas software private parks Public goodseg free to air television air national defenseCommon property protocols editCommon property systems of management arise when users acting independently threaten the total net benefit from common pool resource In order to maintain the resources protocols coordinate strategies to maintain the resource as a common property instead of dividing it up into parcels of private property Common property systems typically protect the core resource and allocate the fringe resources through complex community norms of consensus decision making 8 Common resource management has to face the difficult task of devising rules that limit the amount timing and technology used to withdraw various resource units from the resource system Setting the limits too high would lead to overuse and eventually to the destruction of the core resource while setting the limits too low would unnecessarily reduce the benefits obtained by the users In common property systems access to the resource is not free and common pool resources are not public goods While there is relatively free but monitored access to the resource system for community members there are mechanisms in place which allow the community to exclude outsiders from using its resource Thus in a common property state a common pool resource appears as a private good to an outsider and as a common good to an insider of the community The resource units withdrawn from the system are typically owned individually by the appropriators A common property good is rivaled in consumption Analysing the design of long enduring CPR institutions Elinor Ostrom identified eight design principles which are prerequisites for a stable CPR arrangement 9 Clearly defined boundaries Congruence between appropriation and provision rules and local conditions Collective choice arrangements allowing for the participation of most of the appropriators in the decision making process Effective monitoring by monitors who are part of or accountable to the appropriators Graduated sanctions for appropriators who do not respect community rules Conflict resolution mechanisms which are cheap and easy to access Minimal recognition of rights to organize e g by the government In case of larger CPRs Organisation in the form of multiple layers of nested enterprises with small local CPRs at their bases Common property systems typically function at a local level to prevent the overexploitation of a resource system from which fringe units can be extracted In some cases government regulations combined with tradable environmental allowances TEAs are used successfully to prevent excessive pollution whereas in other cases especially in the absence of a unique government being able to set limits and monitor economic activities excessive use or pollution continue Adaptive governance edit The management of common pool resources is highly dependent upon the type of resource involved An effective strategy at one location or of one particular resource may not be necessarily appropriate for another In The Challenge of Common Pool Resources Ostrom makes the case for adaptive governance as a method for the management of common pool resources Adaptive governance is suited to dealing with problems that are complex uncertain and fragmented 10 as is the management of common pool resources Ostrom outlines five basic protocol requirements for achieving adaptive governance 11 These include Achieving accurate and relevant information by focusing on the creation and use of timely scientific knowledge on the part of both the managers and the users of the resource Dealing with conflict acknowledging the fact that conflicts will occur and having systems in place to discover and resolve them as quickly as possible Enhancing rule compliance through creating responsibility for the users of a resource to monitor usage Providing infrastructure that is flexible over time both to aid internal operations and create links to other resources Encouraging adaption and change to address errors and cope with new developmentsInfluential factors in the management of common pool resources editA new proposal of the management of CPR is to develop autonomous organizations that are not completely privatized and controlled by government power which led and supervised by the community to manage common pool resources in addition to directly through the government and the free market 12 There are many factors that may affect the formation and development of these kinds of autonomous organizations 6 Effectively identifying the influencing factors of the autonomous management system of CPRs increasing the feasibility of the system and it is more conducive to the sustainable use of resources as well 13 In general there are four variables that are very important for local common pool resource management 1 characteristics of the resource 2 characteristics of the resource dependent group 3 institutional model of resource management 4 the relationship between groups external forces and authorities 6 The government market and interest groups are all considered as external forces that have an impact on CPR management system Changes in market demand for CPR in particular technological innovation increases productivity and lowers costs which undermines the sustainability of the management system 12 In order to develop more resources resource owners may seek to change the ownership of resources in the form of cooperation with the government privatize CPR or even cancel the protection of CPR ownership by regulations Such institutional changes prevent the implementation of policies that are beneficial to the majority of the population while the power of the government and bureaucracy can be abused 6 The community is responsible for supervising and administering CPR under an autonomous management system the characteristics of a community can affect how CPR is managed 7 1 the size of the community The level of cooperation decreases as the number of community members grows 2 Allocation mechanism for CPR Encouraging the exploitation of the least used resources and reducing the exploitation of the most used resources will effectively increase the rate of resource supply and reduce the rate of resource consumption and individual demand 3 Group identity When people in a community have a strong sense of group identity it helps to manage CPR within the community 14 Experimental Studies on Common Pool Resource Games editCommon Pool Resource CPR games have been a focal point in experimental research providing insights into the dynamics and dilemmas associated with communal resource management A foundational work introduced a conceptual framework that elucidates the strategic content of CPR dilemmas demonstrating how theoretical constructs such as the Prisoner s Dilemma and coordination games apply to these behavioral challenges 15 Further field experiments involving specific ecological features of CPRs such as water irrigation forestry and fisheries have revealed the impact of various resource specific dynamics on collective action and resource management 16 Additionally a study explored the external validity of CPR laboratory experiments within the context of artisanal benthic fisheries in Chile revealing a correlation between cooperative behaviors exhibited in laboratory settings and those in real world co managed and open access fisheries 17 These studies collectively underscore the complexity of CPR dilemmas and highlight the nuanced interplay between individual strategies collective action and resource sustainability providing a multifaceted understanding of cooperation and norm internalization in the management of communal resources Open access resources editThis section is about non excludable resources in economics It is not to be confused with Open access publishing of academic works In economics open access resources are for the most part rivalrous non excludable goods This makes them similar to common goods during times of prosperity Unlike many common goods open access goods require little oversight or may be difficult to restrict access 5 However as these resources are first come first served they may be affected by the phenomenon of the tragedy of the commons 18 Two possibilities may follow a common property or an open access system However in a different setting such as fishing there will be drastically different consequences Since fish are an open access resource it is relatively simple to fish and profit If fishing becomes profitable there will be more fishers and fewer fish Fewer fish lead to higher prices which will lead again to more fishers as well as lower reproduction of fish This is a negative externality and an example of problems that arise with open access goods 19 See also editCarrying capacity Common good economics Commons Enclosure Exploitation of natural resources Global commons Knowledge commons Occupancy abundance relationship Overexploitation Tragedy of the commons Tyranny of small decisionsReferences editCitations edit Ostrom Elinor 1990 Governing the Commons The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action Cambridge UK Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 40599 8 Sustainable Groundwater Management Act SGMA https water ca gov media DWR Website Web Pages Water Basics Drought Files Publications And Reports CNRA Drought Report final March 2021 pdf bare URL PDF a b c Berkes F Feeny D McCay B J Acheson J M July 1989 The benefits of the commons Nature 340 6229 91 93 Bibcode 1989Natur 340 91B doi 10 1038 340091a0 ISSN 0028 0836 S2CID 4310769 a b c d Environmental Economics Dictionary 2008 04 30 Open Access Resource definition Environmental Economics Dictionary Economics socialsciencedictionary com Archived from the original on 2013 07 03 Retrieved 2014 01 19 a b c d e Ostrom E 1990 Governing the Commons The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action Canto Classics Cambridge Cambridge University Press doi 10 1017 CBO9781316423936 a b Ostrom Elinor 1977 Public Goods and Public Choices Alternatives for Delivering Public Services ISBN 9780429047978 Mandal B N 2009 Global Encyclopaedia of Welfare Economics Global Vision Publishing House ISBN 978 8182202597 Ostrom Elinor 1990 Governing the commons the evolution of institutions for collective action Cambridge University Press pp 90 91 102 page needed UNU IAS 2011 Adaptive Governance United Nations University Ias unu edu 2006 08 18 Archived from the original on 2012 08 02 Retrieved 2014 01 19 Ostrom Elinor 2010 The Challenge of common pool resources In Environment Science and Policy for Sustainable Development 50 4 8 21 1 a b Ostrom Elinor Gardner Roy Walker James Walker James M Walker Jimmy 1994 Rules Games and Common pool Resources University of Michigan Press ISBN 978 0 472 06546 2 Castilla Rho J C Holley C Castilla J C 2020 Groundwater as a Common Pool Resource Modelling Management and the Complicity Ethic in a Non collective World In Valera L Castilla J eds Global Changes Ethics of Science and Technology Assessment vol 46 Springer Cham Ostrom Elinor 2008 07 01 The Challenge of Common Pool Resources Environment Science and Policy for Sustainable Development 50 4 8 21 Bibcode 2008ESPSD 50d 8O doi 10 3200 ENVT 50 4 8 21 ISSN 0013 9157 S2CID 154884533 Gardner R Ostrom E amp Walker J M 1990 The Nature of Common Pool Resource Problems DOI Cardenas J Janssen M amp Bousquet F 2013 Dynamics of rules and resources three new field experiments on water forests and fisheries DOI Gelcich S Guzman R Rodriguez Sickert C Castilla J C amp Cardenas J C 2013 Exploring external validity of common pool resource experiments insights from artisanal benthic fisheries in Chile Ecology and Society 18 3 Tietenberg T 20 September 2006 Open access resources Encyclopedia of Earth Retrieved 4 July 2017 Mackenzie John 2014 Market Failures Open Access Resources Public Goods Etc Archived from the original lecture notes on 3 November 2017 Retrieved 4 July 2017 Bibliography edit Araral Eduardo 2014 Ostrom Hardin and the Commons A Critical Appreciation and Revisionist View Env Science and Policy Volume 36 Pages 1 92 February 2014 Acheson James M 1988 The Lobster Gangs of Maine ISBN 0 87451 451 7 Anderson Terry L Grewell J Bishop 2000 Property Rights Solutions for the Global Commons Bottom Up or Top Down In Duke Environmental Law amp Policy Forum Vol X No 2 Spring 2000 2 Copeland Brian R M Scott Taylor 2009 Trade Tragedy and the Commons PDF American Economic Review 99 3 725 49 doi 10 1257 aer 99 3 725 Baland Jean Marie and Jean Philippe Platteau 1996 Halting Degradation of Natural Resources Is There a Role for Rural Communities Daniels Brigham 2007 Emerging Commons and Tragic Institutions Environmental Law Vol 37 3 Hess C and Ostrom E 2003 Ideas Artifacts and Facilities Information as a Common Pool Resource Law and Contemporary Problems 66 S 111 146 4 Hess C and Ostrom E 2001 Artifacts Facilities And Content Information as a Common pool Resource Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis 5 Meinzen Dick Ruth Esther Mwangi Stephan Dohrn 2006 Securing the Commons CAPRi Policy Brief 4 Washington DC IFPRI 6 Ostrom Elinor 2003 How Types of Goods and Property Rights Jointly Affect Collective Action Journal of Theoretical Politics Vol 15 No 3 239 270 2003 Ostrom Elinor 1990 Governing the Commons The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action Cambridge University Press ISBN 0 521 40599 8 Ostrom Elinor Roy Gardner and James Walker 1994 Rules Games and Common Pool Resources University of Michigan Press 1994 ISBN 978 0 472 06546 2 Rose Carol M 2000 Expanding the Choices for the Global Commons Comparing Newfangled Tradable allowance schemes to Old Fashioned Common Property Regimes In Duke Environmental Law amp Policy Forum Vol X No 2 Spring 2000 7 Saunders Pammela Q 2011 A Sea Change Off the Coast of Maine Common Pool Resources as Cultural Property In Emory Law Journal Vol 60 No 6 June 2011 8 Thompson Jr Barton H 2000 Tragically Difficult The Obstacles to Governing the Commons Environmental Law 30 241 External links editDigital Library of the Commons Public vs Private Goods Retrieved from https en wikipedia org w index php title Common pool resource amp oldid 1221055181, wikipedia, wiki, book, books, library,

article

, read, download, free, free download, mp3, video, mp4, 3gp, jpg, jpeg, gif, png, picture, music, song, movie, book, game, games.